KIT. U BRARI18 - PEWEf Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/optimalincometaxOOdiam HB31 Dewey .M415 working paper department of economics Optimal income taxation: an example with a U-shaped pattern of optimal marginal tax rates Peter Diamond massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 Optimal income taxation: an example with a U-shaped pattern of optimal marginal tax rates Peter Diamond 94-14 April 1994 M.I.T. JUL LIBRARIES 1 2 1994 RECEIVED April 15, 1994 Optimal income taxation: an example with a U-shaped pattern of optimal marginal tax rates Peter Diamond 1 In the presence of Income effects complicate tax analysis. distorting taxes, income effects imply that lump-sum taxes have efficiency effects. Thus it is instructive to examine the optimal income tax in the Mirrlees (1971) model for the case of no income effects 2 the case where everyone has the utility function , (1) u(x,y) = x + v(l-y) and v is where x is consumption, y is labor (in percentage terms) assumed to be strictly concave. 3 The only difference assumed across individuals is a difference in skills, with an individual of The optimal income skill n having a marginal product egual to n. taxation problem is the maximization of the integral over the population of a concave function of utilities, subject to an aggregate budget constraint and subject to the constraint that individuals optimize in their choice of labor supply given the relationship between work and after-tax income. , If, above some income level, the distribution of skills is the exponential distribution and the utility-of-leisure function, v(l-y) Other is the logarithm, then the marginal tax rate is increasing. combinations of utility function and skill distribution yielding the same conclusion are also given, including the combination of a constant elasticity labor supply and the Pareto distribution of skills With either a logarithmic utility-of-leisure or a constant elasticity of labor supply, the marginal tax rate is falling where the density of skills is rising and the income level is high enough to want to transfer resources from that skill level to the government budget. Combining this result with that above, we have examples with a U-shaped pattern of optimal marginal taxes I am grateful to Jon Gruber for suggesting the inclusion of data in this paper and providing me with the figures presented below, 1 and to Jay Wilson for helpful suggestions. I am also grateful to the National Science Foundation for research support. 2 This assumption is probably more appropriate at high income levels, since people at the top of the income distribution are likely to leave large estates and may not adjust their earnings to the exact level of estate. 3 For a discussion of this case with a constant elasticity of labor supply, see Atkinson (1990). The complementary case where utility is linear in leisure has been studied; see Lollivier and Rochet (1983) -1- This argument if the density of skills first rises and then falls. does not refer to the lowest skill levels, only to the levels of skills from which it is desired to transfer income. The argument for a U-shaped pattern of marginal tax rates assumes that there is no upper bound to skill levels. As is well known, in the presence of an upper bound the marginal rate on the highest skill should be zero. 4 This analysis shows that the shape of the distribution near the top is essential for determining the pattern of taxation near the top. There is no need for tax rates to decline slowly toward zero as one approaches the absolute top of the skill distribution. The absence of income effects also allows an intuitive grasp Increasing of the factors that determine the optimal tax structure. some skill level involves marginal tax rate affecting an the increase in the deadweight burden for people at this skill level. Thus, the optimal marginal tax rate at some income level depends on the elasticity of labor supply at that income level, since this is important for marginal distortions. Increasing the marginal tax rate also transfers income from all individuals with higher skills to the government, without changing the distortions of their labor supplies. The weights on these two elements depend on the ratio of individuals with skills above this level to individuals with skills at this level. This intuition is displayed in the equations below, where the first order condition for the optimal income tax is written with a product of these three terms. Model We assume that a person of type n has a marginal product n with the distribution of skills written as F(n). Thus, the ratio of people with higher skills to those with given skills is (l-F(n) /f (n) where f is the density associated with the distribution F. Moreover, it is assumed that the social welfare function is the integral of a strictly concave function of utility, G(u) with utility written in the form given in equation (1) and G independent of n. Thus the objective function to be maximized is ) , /c(x(n) + v(l-y(n)))f (n)dn so with (x(n) y(n)) chosen optimally by individuals of type n given the tax function, T, that determines individual budget constraints, (2) , (3) x(n) = ny(n) - T(ny(n)) To examine the optimal tax, we start with the optimal tax formula for the case of the additive utility function, equation (21) in Mirrlees, specialized for the utility function linear in consumption. 4 Sadka (1976), Seade (1977) -2- (4) p(n - v')f = [(v'-yv")/n][/ (p-G')dF]. where p is the Lagrange multiplier on the government's budget constraint and the functions v and G are evaluated at the appropriate labor supplies. We note that p is equal to the average of G' over the entire population since consumption can be transferred one-for-one between the government and the Thus, the households, provided the tranfers are equal per capita. integral in (4) is first increasing and then decreasing as a function of n. It is convenient to use the marginal condition for individual choice, (5) V = (l-T')n, where T" is the marginal tax rate, and the definition of the elasticity of labor supply (6) e = -v'/yv". Then, we can write (7) (4) as T'/(l-T') = [(e- 1 +l)/n][/(p-G')dF]/[pf]. -A Multiplying and dividing (7) by (1-F) to turn the integral into an average term, we can rewrite the first order condition as (8) Using (9) T'/(l-T') = [(e-i+lJ/nH (5) J (p-G')dF/p(l-F)][(l-F)/f]. again, we can write it as T'/(1"T') 2 = [(v'-yv")/(v') 2 ][f (p-G' dF/p 1-F) ) ( ] [ ( 1-F) /f ] Rising Marginal Tax Rates We are now prepared to examine the pattern of marginal tax rates given by these optimality conditions, considering the levels of skills at which labor supply is positive. Equation (8) shows the three terms mentioned above. The second term reflects the gain from transferring resources from workers with skill levels above n to the government, averaged over the people paying the higher taxes. The first term reflects the distortion associated with such a change, recognizing the fact that a one dollar increase in taxes paid requires a smaller increase in tax rates the larger the level of skill at the income level at which taxes are increased. The third term gives the ratio of individuals above this skill level to individuals at this skill level. If, above some income level, the distribution of skills is the exponential distribution, then the third term, the ratio (l-F)/f, is a constant, independent of skill level. If the utility-of-leisure v(l-y) is the logarithm, then, where labor supply is positive, the first -3- is equal to 1 independent of skill level. (v'-yv") / (v' 2 term in (9), With these two assumptions, the marginal tax rate will vary with This yields an increasing marginal tax rate the remaining term. since the social marginal utility of income is decreasing with income ] [ , Thus, over the range where the distribution of skills is exponential, marginal tax rates increase if the utility-of -leisure function is logarithmic. The same conclusion would hold for a distribution that goes to zero more slowly than the exponential, so that the third term in (9) was increasing. 5 In addition, the result follows for any utility function that showed the first term increasing as one moved up the skill distribution (and so the level of labor) Another combination of assumptions yielding the same from the conclusion can be found by moving n, in equation (8) first term to the third term. Then, we have rising marginal rates where the elasticity of labor supply is constant or falling and (1The latter holds for the Pareto F) /nf is constant or rising. 6 distribution, where the density is proportional to l/n 1+a for a>0. , Asymptotic Marginal Rates With a known finite top to the skills distribution, the optimal marginal tax rate should be zero at the top of the income This need not imply that rates decline until very distribution. close to the top. 7 Thus it has been natural to consider the behavior of the optimal marginal tax rate satisfying the conditions above as skills rise without limit. If the welfare weight of those at the top tends to zero as skill rises without limit, then the tax rate tends to the revenue maximizing rate. This can be derived from the equations above after noting that if G' goes to zero as n rises without limit, then the middle term in (9) goes to 1. If the utility-of-leisure function is logarithmic, then the first term in (9) is also equal to 1 and the tax rate converges to the solution to (10) T'/(1"T') 2 = (l-F)/f. If the distribution of skills is exponential toward the top, (l-F)/f is equal to 1/b, where b is the coefficient in the exponential distribution. (11) Thus the tax rate converges to 1-T' = ((b 2 + 4b) 1/2 - b)/2, The logarithmic utility function has the first term in (9) equal 1. Varying the value of the constant equalling the first term generates utility functions klog(l-y) for constants k, utility functions that do not differ in this implication. 6 Hausman has estimated the elasticity of labor supply by quintile and finds. 7 This point is also made by the numerical calculations in Tuomala (1984) 5 to -4- For values of (l-F)/f, that is, 1/b, of 5, 10, and 15, (see Tables and 2, below), the optimal marginal tax rate tends to 64%, 73%, and 77%. 1 One can do a similar calculation for the Pareto distribution. Assuming a constant elasticity of labor supply, e, and a Pareto distribution with coefficient a, so that (l-F)/(nf) equals 1/a, (8) becomes (12) T'/(l-T') = (e _1 +l)/a. Thus, the the optimal tax rate coverges to (13) T' = (e -1 +l) / (a+e -1 +l) Identifying skill with the wage yields an elasticity based on adjusting hours of labor supply; identifying skill with an underlying ability implies a larger elasticity since education is For values of the elasticity of 0.2 and of a of 0.5, also variable. Raising a to 1.5 lowers the the asymptotic optimal tax rate is 92%. tax rate to 80%.° Raising the elasticity to 0.5 with a at 1.5 lowers the tax rate to 67%. Falling Marginal Rates It is also interesting to consider the case of a distribution of skills with a density that first rises and then falls. For this analysis we consider only the levels of skills at which G' is less than p, so that it is desirable to transfer resources away from this skill level (if it could be done costlessly) We assume that G' equals p at a skill level that is below the skill level that is the mode of the distribution of skills. It is now convenient to cancel the two (1-F) terms in equations (8) and (9). When the density is rising and p exceeds G' the latter two terms in equations (8) and Thus with either a constant elasticity of labor (9) are declining. supply or a logarithmic utility-of-leisure, the marginal tax rate must be falling. . , Similarly, one can compare tax rates at two income levels on either side of the maximum in the density, and such that the density is equal at the two points. Provided that G' is less than p at the lower of the two skill levels being compared, the marginal tax rate would be higher at the lower income level with either a constant elasticity of labor supply or a logarithmic utility-ofleisure. Thus we can see the pattern of tax rates when the density of skills is first rising and then falling (and such that the workers 8 Feenberg and Poterba (1992) use tax data to estimate the Pareto coefficients each year from 1951 to 1990 for the distribution of total incomes for the top 0.5% of the population. They find values of a that vary between 0.54 and 1.46. -5- with the modal skill work and have G' less than p in equilibrium) With the logarithmic utility and an exponential distribution of skills where the density is falling the pattern of marginal tax rates is U-shaped above the level where G' equals p, with the minimum of marginal rates occurring at the maximum of the density of Since there is probably a positive density of skills at the skills. level of skills where labor supply is zero, it does not follow from this argument that marginal tax rates are higher at the bottom of The same conclusion the income distribution than at the top. about a U-shaped pattern holds with a constant elasticity of labor supply and a Pareto distribution for skills where the distribution is falling. Data While a careful attempt to fit this model to available data is beyond the scope of this note, it does seem interesting to examine For this purpose, calculations have the distribution of wages. the March, 1992 CPS. This survey asked been done using individuals for annual earnings in 1991, as well as weeks worked From these numbers one can and typical hours per week. implied average wage. Figure 1 presents the calculate an distribution of wages for males aged 21 to 62. 9 In order to have a visible scale, (and to ignore very low earnings) the figure shows wage rates from $1 to $100, with intervals of size $2 and is based Approximately 17% of on a sample size of approximately 34,000. the sample report lower wages or no work; less than 0.1% of the sample report higher wages. The figure shows the single peaked distribution one would have expected. Table 1 reports calculations from the same data set. The columns show the mean wage per cell; the number of observations per cell, adjusted by cell size in order to be proportional to the density; the number of observations with higher wages; the ratio (l-F)/f; and the ratio (l-F)/nf, where n is the wage. In order to have reasonable cell sizes, the wage intervals are first $0.50, but are expanded above a wage of $2 6. The table shows sharply falling values of (l-F)/f through the range where the density is first rising and then roughly flat, that is, up to a wage of roughly Beyond this point (l-F)/f is $13, a little below the mean of $13.7. roughly constant. This implies a downward trend in (l-F)/nf. With a longer time horizon than one year, one would consider education to be an endogenous variable somewhat responsive to tax incentives. One might also be interested in the distribution of skills within a cohort. Thus a further calculation was done by regressing the log of the wage on education, age and age squared, and plotting the exponentiated residuals. Figure 2 shows the density of skills from this calculation. In Table 2 are the same calculations for this distribution as shown in Table 1 for the No attempt was made to consider both earners in a two-earner family or wages of single females. 9 -6- distribution of wages. This distribution shows a fatter tail than the distribution of wages, with (l-F)/f rising and (l-F)/nf roughly constant for the top 15% of the skill distribution. There is not a simple route between the Mirrlees model and policy implications for annual income taxes levied on families and covering both capital and labor incomes. The assumption of a zero income elasticity of labor supply and the limited information on the pattern of wage elasticities of supply by skill level would Nevertheless limit inferences even if there were a simple route. some lessons from analysis. The sharp are the fall in (l-F)/f there approach the mode of the skill distribution from below skills as seems highly relevant, especially if one wants to redistribute from This finding on the people near the mode, rather than to them. shape of an optimal (negative) income tax seems relevant in thinking about the phaseout of the earned income tax credit, and, This model confirms the implication of possibly, welfare reform. Mirrlees' calculations that the optimality of a zero tax rate at the highest income level is not a finding that sheds much light on optimal taxes, especially in the absence of knowledge of exactly where the top is. That is, if one replaced an unbounded distribution of skills by a bounded one with the same distribution up to some level and a (small) atom of skills at the highest level, the result of rising marginal tax rates continues to hold until the top itself is reached. Third, the sensitivity of the pattern of marginal rates to the measure of skill seems potentially relevant, although different formulations of skill will be associated with different estimates of the elasticities of labor supply. Apart from direct relevance for setting taxes, consideration of this case clarifies some of the elements that matter for understanding optimal taxation, particularly the role of the shape of the distribution of skills. References Atkinson, A. B. 1973, How progressive should income tax be?, in M. Parkin and A. R. Nobay, eds., Essays in Modern Economics London: Longmans, 90-113. , , Atkinson, A. B. 1990, Public economics and the economic public, European Economic Review 34, 225-248. , , Feenberg, Daniel R. and James M. Poterba, 1992, Income inequality and the incomes of very high income taxpayers: evidence from tax returns, paper presented at the NBER Tax Policy and the Economy meeting, November 17, 2992. , Lollivier, Stefan, and Jean-Charles Rochet, 1983, Bunching and Second-Order Conditions: A Note on Optimal Tax Theory, Journal of Economic Theory 31, 392-400. . Mirrlees, J. A., 1971, An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation, Review of Economic Studies 38, 175-208. , -7- 1976, On income distribution, incentive effects and Sadka, E. optimal income taxation, Review of Economic Studies 43, 261-8. , , Seade, J. K. 1977, On the shape of optimal tax schedules, Journal of Public Economics 7, 203-236. , , Slemrod, Joel, Shlomo Yitzhaki, Joram Mayshar and Michael Lundholm, 1994, The optimal two-bracket linear income tax, Journal of Public Economics 53, 269-290. , Stern. N. H. 1976, On the specification of models of optimum income taxation, Journal of Public Economics 6, 123-162. , , Tuomala, Matti, 1984, On the Optimal Income Taxation: Some Further Numerical Results, Journal of Public Economics 23, 351, 366. -8- .120394 - c o c TfL^TL i l r 10 25 50 hrwage 100 5TaTa T FIGURE 1 .10964 c o " u i 05 i .5 i 1 i 2 i i 4 3 r 5 skills Empirical Skills Distribution sTaTa FIGURE 2 T r- « IK w ci ^ cn w C ci II /-^ !*; ?*> si- i NO ON in NO CO Cl r-4 rm CN o m On ON >n NO CO 2 c Q. £ c u<u If | a 8 <u 8 On 1- rs CO 1/1 rsi r»i /•> © © © o o o o O o o T o © © © O o CI 3 o © o m ON -r © © O m m O c t © © © O o © m CO © O m rN © -r © © co On c> ON CI rs ON ON CO rs ci rCN r- ON Cl ON ci CN ON CO CO r- NO O O cc On U"l CN| rsi rsi rsi m NO ir, tr, © ir. rsi On ir, t t •r. m NO CI ON r- X cc -f ON rsi r~rsi «-| v-, CO so NO CN CO r- rs CN co CO rOn CN CS CO <N fi ON r~ NO CO CO r~ NO rsi NO CO NO ci r~ CO in NO NO NO ON CN On' r-' NO NO <N ci CN <D 3 O ON CN -t CO t rrON t t- CO O © U1 t ON T © ON CI r- 1- © o fN CN r- rS o -t NO NO o ON r- O t CN NO r>n CC ON NO ON ci © rd © © d © © © © © d © © d S nON JL CO CI On NO © CI ©' rnO NO 1w-i r-' rsi © Cl CO r- -t ON Cl cc -1- rc, © NO cc rsi ©' NO -t © c, u-i rco ON NO ©' r- 00 d © © '/-, ON rON r» NO NO ^— ON ir, ON iri c iri rsi T t CC -r © rsi NO CI Cl rs rsi c. rs ON rsi © NO cc rsi r-i ci rs o © Cl NO r- ON CC — —© © | o o o © o © o o o O O © © © o © © © © © © © © © © o © o o o o o © © q © © © © © © © © ©' q o o O CO Cl ci cc d NO ©' Cl NO CI T m rs © CO d On © NO NO rN Cl m <° U ON NO ci CO rs NO rs T3 .H ON CO rs NO On Q> c/l ci •n r- NO 1- O 3 ^"> CO Ci £ g -a If ° rsi r-i ~r' cc ©' co Cl CO Cl © NO On -*' rs so © O O © s c m o o ri o r= © © -T cc ON c, m o NO o o m o< Cl tN ON o r~ NO rs m X en CO o tm CI cc n co «t NO Cl rs 1) &^ in -r ON rs 5 <nO Cn| o © ©' rs NT! O © © © © © © ©' © © r© © ON © © © cc rs © © © © © © ON © ON rs © NO NO ON Cl rs © NO rs Cl CO un o © c ON © fS CO © NO cc Cl rsi CO -t r-t CO Cl ON w-i Cl r-4 u-i -)• c, r-4 On r- -t u-i rs ©' ©' ©' DO ON CO -1- -1- NT, w S 8 s r- rs r» rs NO r- o o m Cl a CN ci ci c, r- rs r> cc ci m ci rcc NO C! rs r- On' On' -r r-1- NO O d CC fS rN) ci -T r-l rsi -1- -i- B -i- rsi ir> r-i (~4 © © © © © © © ON o © © © © © in © © cc © © © © © cc r- CC NO On NO © © cc © © r~ On r-T -r On cc Wl cc un rs On cc NO r- Cl -f NO Cs l~ -T Cl -T © On Cl NO NO © NO rNO r- CO ci ci I" © r-' rs fS rs cs CS Cl c rsi rsi NO -I" -1- cc -f w-i r-4 ON -T r-4 r-4 On' rsi I" in r-4 © ir, r-4 ir, Cl NO CO wIo s CO w-i _ c o o © rf NO rs 0) (5) (3)/(l)x(2) © © © © On c, sO 1- NO Cl © CN ON w, NO ci NO On' r-' cc ON ON © r-4 r- NO CC NO © © NO NO (l-F)/nf= o r-4 -t rsi r-4 © © © Cl rsi ~r c © o- rs rs c. r-4 r-4 ON CC o ri in r-4 rs cs •n Cl sO ON -r m rs' rs' rs' rs' © © © O© cc rs o- Cl Cl un o rs ci c cc NO cc Cl >n X sO sO CN r-~ r-4 T, Cl O- -1- cc 00 X ^i On r- © rcs X -f Cl CN rs rs Cl -r Cl i» 5 * 1> co S CO 1*8 ON in r~ r-4 rs > E s o "cn5 co in © © © © © cc © © © © © © © © © © © © © ON © © © © © © © c © © © Cl sC rsO NO -r cc cc © ON © On -f -r NO © © © © rs -r rin c, NO sO in ON -r c, © © nO Cl >> ON 0> NO © ON rs NO cc cc OS I" CO cc CO X NO © Cl On 1- Cl Cl cc Cl ON cc rs © ON ON On -T cc © © NO C X NO © sO X Os * r- Cl ON cc Cl NO •o c. On rs rs in Cl >n CS © co -T X © rin cc mi rs rrs ci -t NO ©' ©' NO ci CO ON rS ON rs NO Cl © rs rs rs rs cs rs r-4 ON in NO = (4) (3)/(2) (l-F)/f rsi -1- rsi «-, r-4 ON O c o © higher (3) Cl C r- -o U~l CC Cl Cl NO Cl Cl rsi Cl Cl Cl CO rs «"1 r-i ir, rsi CD O Cl Cl rr-4 «-i rsi Cl Cl c, CO NO © c © On' r-l r-4 NO -f NO r-i t r- NO Cl ON rs NO v-, -t -t rs ON CC NO ir, w-, r-4 rs rs rs rs NO m c cc -t Cl c, r-4 c, rs r-4 r-4 Cl rs r- CC rs rs rs iri rs' cc' r-4 © c Cl ON X © X o Cl ON rs c. NO Cl NO -T NO rNC NT, Cl Cl X © rs in NO r-4 X ON © r-l wages observations with X) •c en by © © © © © 3 © © © © © O © © © © © © © © © © © © s © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © p © © © © ©' ci ©' NO NO Cl ci wi rs X ci © © ©' o' Cl NO rs Cl rON rs Cl X c, Cl c, cc cc rs X X © ON © rs rs Cl Tf ON © O- © © © © ON © © ON cc m X X NO CN -*' On' size (2) observations rsi r~' ir, u-, tr,' On' r-' /-, r-4 r-4 adjusted cell co sO wage ON (1) Cs! r-4 mean 8 r-4 r-l 1- c. r- **r-4 CC r- On r-4 ON ~r rsi cc NO 1r- rsi CN ci ci -t CC ^^ fS Cl T NO r-4 u-. ON NO CC c c c NO rr~ ON r-4 NO r- co ON Cl NO n cc © © o © Cl r- rs ON NO NO no" r-' © ~ r-i Cl r-4 s On rON NO -f NO r~ rsi IT ( CC rcc NO C rs cc rs rcc rs ON m © NO © rs © © © © © Cs © rs © © -t Os © in © © © ON X sO rs X X © CN NO CC © Cl X OS NO m rt r- X © Cl © t- OS X NO X Cl t~ rs NO NO ON ©' ©> rs ci ci t w". NO r- CC ir, -1- r-l * r-4 r-4 r-4 r-4 ir, rrl r-l r-i u-i r-i o- s r-4 cs rs r-l c rl -t in sO r-i r-l co r-4 X X CN X © fin m X NO © rs m X -t X © 3 r-i ir. r- to C/3 "l "H 00 go so 'C "sf ^ I Cl -C X r-4 rs On rs s? r- ci -f ON fN U1 Tf OS ci in r- OS mi in O (3)/(l)x(2) (5) ^ (l-F)/nf= Sw Cs! <n <n r~ 00 CH 1 T3 % o 00 O fN o in r- oo m 00 oo OO oo SO 00 oo 00 o ci ci 00 o -f m Tf oo r- r» SO OS r^ m' Tf Tf Tf wi ci Tf MO SO fN Ci so 1- Tf u-i 00 ci Tf OS os ON r»' O wi cm u-1 Tf Tf 00 00 SO OS rmi ci 00 00 00 -it © © SO fN Wl wi SO OS Tf OS 00 OS SO Cl 00 Tf 00 SO «-> rCM 00 Tt it Tf' wi >* Tf m m m © © © © SO ci r~ rci OS OS OS OS SO in fN OS 00 ob rso © © © © © © © © © © © © © © Tf © OS © © © © © © © © © © © © © (N so Tf Cl © SO © in © OS © © OS © OS Tf © Tf © Tf © © © OS r- Cl © © Cl m © SO SO OS 00 © Cl SO Cl Tf Cl © Tf © Tf SO 00 OS SO SO © © (N OS 00 Cl in SO © (N Tf © ©' ©' in Cl OS so Tf Tf Tf Tf fCI <N Tf Tf Tf <N Tf <N CI OS r^ Tf Wl os (N wi 00 ©' OS OS 00 © © (3) OS m SO <N © Tf © fS © m © © © Tf r^ os r00 00 u-i 1—1 OS © © wi wi Tf Tf fN «1 os os Tf OS WI r- 00 Tf 00 SO Cl 00 00 00 os wi Cl SO r- <r> rCM os oo SO 00 Cl SO so in OS Cl OS r- so 00 fN SO OS Tf os SO fN os SO ci Tf Cl CM so so WI Tf Tf ci ci ci fN CM CM u-1 o © o o o o © © © O © o © © © © © © o © © © © © © o © © © © © © © © © © © © © p o p o o o © © © © © mi ©' OS Tf -T SO c> 00 wi Tf 00 OS Tf SO OS (N ci OS OS OS OS 00 SO os c> r- so Wl ci os CM •n m fN © SO m SO Tf o ci ci CM cm © © (N © © o o higher © in OS (N Tf 00 rCl OS Tf Tf 00 00 SO oo oo SO Cl OS OS SO OS Cl SO 00 <N so 00 Tf 00 SO Cl os SO OS Tf 00 Tf Tf Tf Tf ci Tf" Tf wi Tf 00 00 r- © m © © skills observations with c J3 by r-' size (2) observations ir, Cl «-i 00 r- r- mi ©' Tf Tf fN CN adjusted rs) cell 5 O o m C/5 skill £ c (1) I— © © © m © © © m m © m IT, Cs Cs Tf r- SO fN ci SO Tf CI OS so Tf r~ -f Tf in 00 00 rr- 00 r~ (N Cl ON Tf SO ci SO OS CM Tf r- Tf Cl (S wi so Tf Tf mi Tf in in ci Cl SO Cl Cl Tf SO Tf 00 00 1^ <N rOS OS fN r- <N r- fN r- Csl r- fN CM <N rin SO sq Cl Cl Tf -+ w-i in SO r-_ 00 00 OS OS CM r-i (N (N (N rsi mean O ci o © O © rsi Cl Tf fN Cl SO 00 OS >n SO 00 OS 1- Tf Tf Cl C) ci ci ci ci Cl ci Tf Tf Tf Tf Tf Tf o u-i in so OS in Cl Tf r- OS m © OS Tf 00 oo Tf fS OS Cl Cl in in Tf © Cl © © SO OS © © in mi fS mi fN fN ci Tf S o a © m m SO m O oo mi mi 0X1 c 3 u. rsi n o o S o a O >> © o © © Q © © © Q © © © © © mi © © © © r^ oo OS Tf SO Tf 00 so T> © © •^ Cl © O © © © © © © © © © © © Cs OS r- SO 00 00 so Cl r^ r» Tf o Tf oo © SO OS Tf OS © © OS OS fN Cl so IN 00 © r~ m Tf OS fN OS Cl © SO © fN r- Cl Cl mi mi fN r^ — r- -f r~ Tf Tf 1— OS O Tf Cl mi SO ^— r- r- Cl 00 mi fN fN so fN so mi fN fN OS fN so SO © so OS Tf Cs mi so OS ci ©' © fN sd ci ©' cc mi ci fN mi Tf © Tf mi ci © CS Tf Tf in fN SO mi © r^ SO m, Tf Cl fN fN fN <— i— so OS OS m Cl r- ~* <-T C O "a x — ^^ >- ^—t *o 03 U rsi Cl OS 00 mi fN ^h fN Cs' © Tf OS so 00 mi Tf CS Cl fN r^ Tf Cl mi Tf 00 Tf fN mi od r-' sd >r> "s.™*^ SO u X CO # © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © o © © © © © O © © 00 fN r- fN © Tf fN © Cl Tf CS r^ o Cs O SO OS 00 r- Cs fN O © © © © O © CS — — fN mi oo SO Cl SO ~H SO Tf Tf Cl ^^ r^ mi r> mi Tf SO © Cs OS mi fN Cl OS fN r- oo © ^^ © 00 SO so Tf 00 mi © SO so SO Cl oo © oo fN © mi rfN fN mi —1 Tf Tf 00 fN ^m so m r- m Tf mi OS © 00 r» Tf © cs fN so fN Tf Cl SO 00 00 Cl (N so OS © Cl © r- Tf m, ©' ©' i— mi mi Tf ci fN fN ^T ci OS mi fN OS 00 Tf ©' 00 © fN Tf r~ r- mi Tf Cl Cl fN fN fN © so fN "* rt -* 'Si »—* F«H ^-i SO Cl Tf rmi SO os ,-H 00 00 r- — © r» Tf mi rfN OS os 00 •— ""^ C/3 8 — t0> C 32 J3 serva ithhi S3 M B fN Cl os OS mi mi so — 00 mi Tf Tf Cl Cl Cl Cl Cl Cl © 00 Cl fN Cl Cl fN rr~ fN Cl Cl — fN fN Cl Tf fN mi I"H Cl Tf r~ i-* »-^ oo fN 00 00 Tf fN 00 r^OS r^ Cl fN fN fN t~~ © 00 fN mi so fN Cl © fN m, fN 00 in 00 SO CS OS r^ fN in Os 00 mi fN 00 Tf Cl fN «-H OS 00 fN fN fN rTf ^^ r- CS © OS m, Tf rSO Tf ^^ Tf r- ^-* SO 00 OS 00 00 SO Cs Tf Cl Cl ci Tf Tf Cl fN —H Cs 00 © so Tf SO r- skil JO 'B o > Q by (N © © © © © © © © © © © O © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © © O © © © © © © © © © © © © © O © © © © © © © © © © © © mi OS OS Tf ^ so OS OS © r~ OS Tf so m mi Cl r- fN Tf mi 00 mi Cl rSO mi 00 CN OS 00 © OS fN © fN Tf r- SO Tf Cl Cl Cs os i— r- r- ^H in mi Cl OS 00 Cl so mi 00 ~^ fN Cl Tf mi SO 00 OS OS ,— ™* Cl Cl Cl Cl Cl Cl Cl fN fN "- © © CS OS OS 00 r-- size ^~* ervation usted ell •—j , «_, **s _H Tf Cl mi ci OS ^H oo ^M 00 r^ -T © »H mi Cl so OS SO CO ^^ r- CM r~ in SO SO fN r^ fN rfN fN Cl Cl fN fN mi SO fN Tf OS mi fN SO r~ Tf oo Tf CO Cl m> os Cl mi OS mi Tf fN r- fN mi 1/-1 SO fN r~ Cl mi r^ so mi fN so Tf fN t> © — Cl Tf Cl © © © m r~ m Tf r- fN — CS ^^ mi r^ in so r~ ci Cl r- mi Tf t^ mi Cl Cl 00 fN 00 mi 00 Cl Tf CS t^ i-^ Cl Tf Tf Tf mi mi fN r^ fN r- fN r» fN —* i— fN 00 OS OS CA t—t c CO u E 00 m m m © »— r- 00 © © © © © O © © © © © © © © © © © © © <--j © m © © " (N Cl © fN £4 c o •a £ «+H O S3 O 3 VI _0J 61) r~t PL, tn © mi © 00 © © © © •—i r~- ™ a 4= r-i 00 *_ mi r^ o Tf m SO r- 00 CS fN 00 OS fN fN fN Cl fN Tf fN fN 00 mi Tf r^ fN Tf SO Tf Cl fN Cl mi fN SO fN rCl OS mi Cl 00 rTf fN rTf Tf fN 00 fN Tf r~ © © Tf Tf OS fN <— o OS 00 SO TT mi © i— || II 3 2 t/i iyi a ci e t3 e MIT LIBRARIES 3 ^OflO OOflMbbMD a j. f"X Date Due g&WW* Lib-26-67