SfcCffflte, orTti D£WEY HB31 .M415 working department of economics MONEY, OUTPUT, AND PRICES: EVIDENCE FROM A NEW MONETARY AGGREGATE Julio J. Rotemberg John C. Driscoll James M. Poterba No. 585 May 1991 Rev. July 1991 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 tttj • ! MONEY, OUTPUT, AND PRICES: EVIDENCE FROM A NEW MONETARY AGGREGATE Julio J. Rotemberg John C. Driscoll James M. Poterba May 1991 No. 585 Rev. July 1991 NOV J 4 1991 MONEY, OUTPUT, AND PRICES: EVIDENCE FROM A NEW MONETARY AGGREGATE Julio J. Rotemberg MJT&NBER John C. Driscoil Harvard University James M. Poterba MIT&NBER May 1991 Revised July 1991 ABSTRACT This paper develops a new utility-based monetary aggregate which we label the currencyThis aggregate equals the stock of currency that would be required for equivalent aggregate. households to obtain the same liquidity services that they get from their entire collection of monetary assets. It equals rb,t ' where rb t is the rate of return on a zero and n\, respectively the ability of the and M2, and other indicators of liquidity asset, while represent the yield and stock of monetary asset i at time t. r- , We compare aggregate and conventional aggregates, such as Ml monetary policy to forecast real activity. The CE aggregate has more predictive power for output and prices than standard aggregates, and the time path of the estimated output response is more consistent with broad classes of theoretical models. new We are Michael Woodford and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Board and the NBER 1991 Summer Institute for suggestions, as well as to William Barnett, Anil Kashyap, Richard Porter, Brian Reid and Piyu Yue for providing us with data. This research is part of the NBER Programs in Economic Fluctuations and Financial Markets and Monetary Economics. grateful to the National Science Foundation for research support, to Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/moneyoutputprice00rote2 1 How monetary shocks affect prices and real activity are two of the central questions in macroeconomics. The implications of various theoretical models addressing these issues have been explored in in literally what money does, there hundreds of empirical papers. which studies use relatively arbitrary rules in deciding By choosing not. to study how activity, researchers implicitly Narrow definitions of liquidity services. the monetary base, or money, such A GNP more is. Most previous empirical assets are monetary, and Ml, made judgments about the or M2, which are affects prices identity of monetary and real assets. as the base, exclude a variety of assets that provide Broader definitions, such as with arguably quite different liquidities. measure of money consensus on what is little Despite the substantial interest This M2, is give equal weight to a variety of assets hardly more defensible than constructing a by adding together the physical volume of output attractive approach involves weighting different assets in different industries! by the value of the monetary services they provide. This principle underlies Barnett's (1980) derivation of Divisia monetary aggregates. The continued widespread use of conventional aggregates particularly surprising, since research has repeatedly as good at predicting GNP. In this paper we currency-equivalent (CE) aggregate, which aggregate is is shown Divisia aggregates to be is at least propose a new monetary aggregate, the related to the Divisia aggregates. The CE a time-varying weighted average of the stocks of different monetary assets, with weights which depend on each asset's yield relative to that on a benchmark "zero liquidity" asset. One it is attractive feature of the CE aggregate the stock of currency that yields the is that it has a straightforward interpretation: same transactions services as the complete 2 constellation of monetary Thus, currency gets a weight of one in our aggregate. assets. Other assets with higher rates of return get a smaller weight because their marginal liquidity services are lower. After deriving our aggregate and summarizing Divisia aggregates, We output. we first test use it to develop its relation to both conventional and new evidence on the correlation between whether, in post-1959 U.S. data, there money and any correlation between is changes in various monetary aggregates, including CE, and subsequent movements in output. We then study whether these correlations suggest that changes in money cause changes in output. Most models where exogenous changes this effect will be short lived and in money have an that, eventually, effect on output predict that a one percent increase in money leads to a one percent increase in prices. Thus the impulse response function of output with respect monetary shocks ought to exhibit pronounced, short lived that fail to display this property, so that output not causal. due to effects. Indeed, monetary shocks responds permanently to them are probably Rather, money-income correlations of this type can easily be interpreted as being monetary endogeneity with respect to either income or other variables which income. to Our evidence suggests that shocks to the CE affect aggregate are both more strongly correlated with subsequent changes in output, and have a shorter lived "effect" on output, than shocks to more traditional monetary aggregates. Several recent papers, for example Bernanke and Blinder (1990) and Friedman and Kuttner (1990) have suggested that interest rates and interest rate spreads are better indicators of monetary policy than the monetary aggregates themselves. We therefore compare the 3 predictive power of comparison CE is aggregate. these variables to the predictive CE CE aggregate. This of particular interest because some changes in interest rates directly affect the We find that the correlation and subsequent movements the power of the On aggregate. between interest rates, and in output is stronger than the correlation interest rate spreads, of these variables and the other hand, the impulse responses of output to these variables do not correspond to the pattern one would expect if the economy were responding to a monetary disturbance. This paper is divided into five sections. monetary aggregate and compares it The first derives the currency-equivalent with existing Divisia aggregates. the data inputs needed to construct our aggregate, and reports univariate time series properties. The causes real output, and compares its monetary policy. It third section tests Section two describes summary whether the statistics new on its aggregate Granger- predictive performance to that of other indicators of also tests the long run neutrality of money with respect to output. Section four presents a parallel analysis of the effect of monetary shocks on prices, comparing the findings for the currency equivalent aggregate with those for more measures. There is traditional a brief conclusion which sketches the implications of our findings for competing theories of the monetary transmission mechanism. 4 1. The Currency-Equivalent Monetary Aggregate and 1.1 Its Properties Derivation Some assets can readily be used for transactions. Individuals pay for the these assets offer by foregoing the higher expected returns that are available liquid assets. account, and liquidity that on other, less Holding one dollar in currency costs more than holding one dollar in a it presumably generates greater liquidity services. assuming that individuals derive utility from holding We certain assets. NOW formalize this idea by Our results could also be obtained by assuming that individuals and firms incur transactions costs which depend negatively on asset-holdings and positively on the volume of transactions. We consider an individual whose expected V=E t lifetime utility in period t is given by ±VUN (D /-o where E, takes expectations as of time the level of instantaneous utility at and the levels of n monetary currency holdings at t. We t. assets, assume is t, an intertemporal discount factor, and U, gives This instantaneous m it . that We let U t i utility range from depends on consumption, C„ to n-1, equals U(C„L,), which is and define m<, it as concave in both arguments, where Lt'f(mot ,mu ,... m„. u). (2) t The function f Any is an aggregator function for liquidity services. desirable monetary aggregate under two assumptions about this must in some way correspond to L,. We show that aggregator function, L, equals the currency equivalent (CE) 5 Our monetary aggregate introduced by Rotemberg (1991). aggregator function is homogeneous of degree one. separable in currency and other monetary assets: f(mot ,mu ,m^ t ,...) = 1 Second, assets by holding h(mot) sufficient currency. might be controversial, assumption we assume the that f is additively k(mu ,m^ t ,...) + it is While the (3) possible to obtain any level of inessentiality consistent with the fact that circulating it is is that 2 This assumption gives a central role to currency, since liquidity services first of other monetary media of exchange appear to predate the introduction of other liquid assets. Our assumption that the aggregator function f has constant returns to scale implies that Lt = E fu mu <4) /-o where f i>t is the partial derivative of f with respect to the quantity of monetary asset evaluated in period t. i Since (3) implies fo,i=h „ 'The key part of this assumption is that f be nomothetic since it can then be converted into a homogeneous function by transforming U. As shown by Samuelson and Swamy(1964), homotheticity considerably simplifies the construction of index numbers. It is required for Divisia aggregates to be path independent as well as to ensure that the true economic index lies between the Paasche and the Laspeyres index. *We would obtain identical results if we treated currency as a collection of disparate assets (denominations) which provide different types of liquidity. Letting cjtt denote the holding of currency of type j at t, so that f is f would have to be given by additively separable in a function that depends function that depends on the other monetary assets. on the various currency assets and a h(mot ) The must be equal, so the second and This implies that h constants. is all (5) and of h^nio,, with respect to m^, higher derivatives of h with respect to m^, must be a linear function, and that the derivatives ho and , f0> , are 3 Our assumptions thus imply that currency does not lose the quantity of currency rises. appear, because function = f r^,r 0> equality in (5) implies that the derivatives of h first zero. hot mot = it does not imply U is concave in We also assume we and t+1 known with certainty at time rbt . not as disturbing as total liquidity so that, indirectly, it is focus on a particular asset of nominal return equal is might it that overall utility is linear in currency. that there are assets that simplicity, is This implication to provide liquidity as its ability 4 t. concave Rather, the in currency as well. do not provide monetary this at first services. For form whose nominal return between time We call In our empirical work, this the benchmark we measure rb , asset and t let its by the return on prime 'Interpreting traditional simple-sum monetary aggregates as equalling total liquidity services also on f but these are much stronger than those implies by our separability and homogeneity assumptions. In particular, the function f must be linear in all its arguments with equal coefficients for each. But this implies that all monetary assets provide the same return. requires linearity assumptions 'Even if all actual assets without liquidity services had stochastic returns, the analysis However, the benchmark return would have to be the return on an imaginary liquidity services and with a nonstochastic payoff in period t+1. apply. would asset with no 7 grade commercial paper. The benchmark 5 return has the standard property that UAC„L,) - fl.frj qSgMMAfl? where Pt measures the price of a unit of consumption Equation (4) says that the consumer profile and a profile in is indifferent which he increases in terms (6) of currency at date t. between his current (optimal) consumption his holdings of the benchmark asset by reducing current consumption and uses the proceeds to increase future consumption. Monetary assets do not share their stock raises the level utility by this property of liquidity services received by the consumer. from lowering current consumption further liquidity services. is offset UL(Cv L Substituting the expectation^ term from t) f (1 u Thus the loss in by both additional future consumption and In particular, for monetary asset UJLC„Lt) - *We chose of the benchmark asset because increasing + i r,,)E,^^M (6) into (7), we (7) obtain the commercial paper rate because the market for prime grade commercial paper We also tried the Federal is funds rate, which even safer (though less widely held) instrument. The results were identical, so we only report the results for commercial paper. We did not use Treasury bill returns because during much of the 19601980 period, these yields were below the interest rates on passbook saving accounts. Since saving broad and the instrument is fairly safe. accounts would appear to be puzzling. Our own more pertains to useful for transactions purposes than T-bills, this behavior tentative explanation is an is that Treasury bills provide other types of services. They are well understood throughout the world, they can easily be used as collateral and they can be posted as margin services in financial transactions. we do Because we not include Treasury bills in L. our analysis as long as the utility function is think these services are different from transactions The existence of these services does not invalidate separable in consumption, L, and these services. 1 8 UJU This says that the consumer by one unit, is indifferent his holdings and increasing %& U - c (8) . between reducing his holdings of monetary asset of the benchmark asset by (l+rit)/(l+rbl). This change leaves the value of the individual's portfolio at the beginning of period t+ unaffected, so that future consumption can remain unaffected as well. However, portfolio change allows the individual to raise his current consumption by The gain in utility from his reduced holdings of For currency, this this (rbt-rit)/(l consumption increase must therefore equal the monetary asset i +rb ,). fall in utility from i. the analogue of equation (8) is: r UJo, « WL U ii j*~ c (9) 'b,t Since U is an arbitrary concave function, normalization ensures that equations (8) and (9) now total liquidity, we L, is measured in units of currency. This Combining yields fkt = The can normalize f so that f0jt equals one. level of the liquidity aggregate L, Lf = [tLJu. (10) rb,t from equation E^m (4) then satisfies tfS CE f . This expression defines the currency-equivalent monetary aggregate. (11) 9 Actually, our derivation has considered an individual's holding of monetary assets so that L» in (11) is the level However, because (11) of liquidity held by an individual. in individual asset holdings, the to aggregate asset holdings. sum of the L's held by all is linear individuals is simply (11) applied Thus CE, provides an accurate measure of the sum of the individual L's even if the aggregator functions f differ for different individuals. CE The as currency aggregate has the attractive property that assets which do not pay interest, such and travelers' checks, are added together with weights of unity. Other assets are added with weights between zero and one, with higher-yield assets receiving lower weights. This makes intuitive sense since these assets must, given their higher returns, provide smaller liquidity services. The benchmark asset, in particular, provides no liquidity services. Therefore, by the same logic, assets whose returns equal or exceed those of the benchmark asset do not contribute CE The new assets, to the currency equivalent aggregate. such as interest-bearing shows that is are introduced, they can be added to the is resolved by reference to their interest yield. interesting interpretation of this aggregate is developed in Barnett (1991). assuming static expectations, expenditures on liquidity services. which NOW accounts, deciding whether such accounts are "liquid enough" to be included in the monetary aggregate One When aggregate also adapts easily to changes in the financial environment. The problem of aggregate. 6 He CE, equals the expected present discounted value of These expenditures in period t equal E, (rb , - r^m^,, the total amount of interest foregone by holding monetary assets instead of the 'Although many assets promise yields greater than those on the benchmark necessarily evidence that liquidity services are provided simply reflect differential risk across assets. by the benchmark asset, this is asset. Rather, it not could 10 benchmark asset. their level divided 1.2 Under by static expectations, the present the rate of return on the Properties of Divisia and value of these expenditures equals benchmark asset, yielding CE. CE Ag gre gates The currency equivalent aggregate closely resembles the Divisia monetary aggregates proposed by Bamett (1980). Both types of aggregates attempt to measure the derived from monetary assets. sub-utility, L,, This sub-section compares these two approaches to monetary aggregation. The principal advantage of Divisia aggregates is that their derivation requires assumptions only that the aggregator function f be homogeneous of degree one. weak assumption and in only under stronger assumptions, However, it it would appear to be Since the D„ this CE aggregate equals strictly inferior in this case. has five advantages in comparison with divisia aggregates. First, in discrete time, the Divisia aggregate tends to drift while the Under a continuous time setting without uncertainty, the change in the Divisia aggregate gives the exact value for the change in L,. L weaker CE away from The Theil-Tornquist approximation aggregate does not. the level of L to the Divisia index, is logDM +£-1 (y^Mr r m ( m fo.M-'/.f-Mn Vlog^t ' logD, = E Kr V / i) i.t x > , E J (*itM ~r j.t-i) m j.t-i mu-\) (12) 11 Diewert (1976) shows change in L if f change that the in this index becomes unboundedly Since large. The CE this error is eventually aggregate does not suffer from this problem. If f does arguments remain bounded, its CE second advantage of the a random walk with drift, it CE not satisfy the linearity restriction that makes the A to another is equal to the 7 has the translog functional form. Otherwise each change in the index introduces an approximation error. with respect to from one period aggregate it aggregate exact, but the derivatives of f will not drift arbitrarily far is that its level has a definite meaning. Divisia indices seek to measure the changes in the sub-utility from assets, be used in international liquidity held A third, by comparisons of L,. They cannot liquidity, or to evaluate the different levels of different individuals. and perhaps the most important, advantage of the easily handle situations where the function f changes over time. CE assets changes constantly. their liquidity properties, For example, when and therefore that the utility NOW accounts their respective f;, aggregate is that it Such changes of the most important challenges of monetary aggregation since the assume instead from L. set can constitute one of available monetary eliminate charges on checks, change. Divisia aggregates provided by each asset remains immutable. The CE aggregate deals with changes in asset characteristics by incorporating the idea that, for asset holdings not to change, (rb ,-r; )/rb>t if interprets increases in (rb must rise as ,-rit)/rb , much as f ; . The CE aggregate thus correctly with an unchanged asset stock as an increase in the assets' liquidity services. ^Because the translog Divisia aggregate is is itself a quadratic approximation to any homogeneous function "superlative" in the terminology of Diewert (1976). f, the 12 The function f changes most dramatically when new introductions cannot be addressed using Divisia aggregates, they present no CE is aggregate. As equation (12) shows, the change in the Divisia index changes in the logarithms of its A new minus infinity when an assets. fourth advantage of the consumers. is Barnett and his collaborators therefore use a different index method to asset is introduced. incorporate difficulty for the based on the components. Because the logarithm of zero growth rate of the Divisia aggregate equals infinity, (12) implies that the While these assets are introduced. CE aggregate concerns aggregation across different Equation (12), which defines the change in the Divisia aggregate, is a good approximation to the change in an individual's liquidity. However, the version of (12) that uses the aggregate value of the components does not generally bear any relationship to an It does so other individuals. While individual's L. paradigm if each individual's asset holdings are proportional to those of this is is unattractive in implied by the representative individual paradigm, money is linear in asset Such transactions reduce one holdings while raising those of someone else. holdings, this the case of monetary assets because monetary transactions generally involve a payment from one individual to another. individual's all it Because the CE aggregate remains equal to the sum of individual L's even when individuals engage in transactions with each other. A final advantage of the research, is that it aggregate, which simplifies the estimation to one, equation (9) can individual's CE demand we hope will provide the basis for future of money demand equations. With fo, t normalized be viewed as a conventional money demand equation relating an for total liquidity, L,, to the "market" interest rate and a measure of his 13 transactions, in this case consumption. across individuals if either utility function is all This equation applies directly to the sum of the L's individuals have identical L's and C's or if each individual's quadratic with the same parameters. often use the commercial paper rate, which to paper as our benchmark asset. other interest rates as well. interest rates have no role In contrast to the interest rate to include in a Our some degree justifies our use of commercial on f implies the restriction of aggregate, which money demand additional unit of the Divisia aggregate is testable proposition that other (9). makes a simple prediction about the appropriate equation, the foregone interest cost of holding an a complicated function of Moreover, for a given Divisia quantity aggregate, there are two price indices. The first by the Divisia many interest rates. different, equally valid, can be computed using a formula analogous to that for the Divisia quantity index applied to prices, while the second is obtained liquidity money demand equations However, conventional money demand equations often add in the estimation CE Estimates of quantity index. by dividing expenditure on of demand Serletis (1991) estimates systems equations for Divisia aggregates using the latter approach. Before closing this sub-section, it is worth remembering that Divisia and CE aggregates have many things in common. Changes in monetary assets affect both aggregates only to the extent that their rate of return broker-dealer are in on M2 is lower than that of a benchmark money market mutual Thus, changes in funds and in time deposits at commercial banks, which significant impact This contrasts with the conventional wisdom, which holds that money but essentially yield the commercial paper either aggregate. asset. rate, do not have a market accounts can be used for making payments and so must be "like" checking accounts. 14 The conventional view confuses average and marginal liquidity services. money market accounts do provide dollars invested in broker-dealer individuals are likely to write checks The first few liquidity services since on them. Because these accounts pay interest rates equal to those on zero-liquidity, assets, however, they also attract additional funds which will not be used to make payments in the near future. changes in these asset stocks do not affect One difficulty with this portfolio of all assets. argument total liquidity services. is that Some consumers So, starting from the equilibrium holdings, not all consumers money market accounts do not consumers are only slowly drifting into such "regular" checking accounts into CE assets, money market For these consumers, from regular checking to money market accounts 1.3 rate, As is these consumers convert their not too severe gradual since whatever form of aggregation is it if the then has fall as the conversion little effect on used. Comparison with Other Methods of Monetary Ag gregation There are two alternatives the is further Other raise their liquidity. accounts, their liquidity does not and Divisia aggregates would imply. This problem money's monthly growth the optimal thereby gaining the inframarginal consumers already enjoy. liquidity services the optimizing by holding are very sophisticated and hold their wealth in assets that provide liquidity services with negligible losses in return. increases in their holdings of start CE aggregates. The first is to the sort of aggregation that underlies both the Divisia and the estimation of a parametric utility function along the lines of Chetty (1969) or Poterba and Rotemberg (1987). Armed with the utility function's parameters, one can obviously construct a measure of the utility derived from liquidity 15 services. While we are sympathetic to this approach, Spindt (1985) correctly argues that copes poorly with changes in the liquidity characteristics of the underlying A second approach, introduced by Spindt (1985), is to measure the provided by various monetary assets using data on their turnover. The it assets. liquidity services idea is that assets with large turnover must be more useful in transactions and so have higher liquidity services. The problem is that turnover need not be a good measure of liquidity services. For instance, relatively small denominations of currency turn over more quickly than larger ones. Yet, one would not want money outstanding changes. to say the The reason services at the margin. rarely large 1.4 by being sums of Slow The change supply changed is that one expects when all the composition of currency currency to provide the same Large denominations make up for the fact that they are used only particularly useful in certain circumstances, such as cash. when one must carry 8 Portfolio Adjustment currency-equivalent aggregate does encounter difficulty if individuals are slow to their portfolios in response to interest rate changes. will not always hold variations in f<. and the variations This problem in (r^-r^/rfc,, is likely to do not necessarily correspond to be important, particularly since our benchmark rate on monetary is quite volatile while the rates is not very useful in predicting output or prices. *We do In this case, equations (6)-(8) assets tend to change sluggishly. 9 Because this not pursue the empirical properties of this index here because Serletis (1988) shows that it 'Of course, violations of the consumer's fust order conditions also degrade the approximation properties of Divisia aggregates. In the case of interest rate changes that do not lead to rebalancing of individual portfolios it is possible that Divisia's errors are smaller than CE's because changes in 16 sluggish adjustment is due in part to regulatory inertia, it is hard to attribute the resulting changes in (r^-r^J/r^, to changes in the assets' liquidity services. When individuals rebalance their portfolios only occasionally, they choose a portfolio of monetary assets such that the each f/s at any f is close to the (r b -rj)/rb s moment therefore depend expected to prevail in current and future periods. on the The current, past, as well as expected future values of the interest rate differentials. In implementing the CE by constructing averages of is aggregate, (rb ,-r; ,)/rb , we address the problem of slow portfolio adjustment and using them to Our benchmark measure CE. constructed using weights corresponding to a 13-month centered moving average. consider a 37-month centered moving average, as well a "fixed weight" ri,i)/ rb,t's are replaced 2. by Data and Summary CE in case We also which the (rbl- overall sample averages. Statistical Properties Data Construction 2.1 We include eight component assets in the currency equivalent aggregate. currency (CUJ, travelers' checks (TQ), and demand deposits (DD,) The interest paying assets are other checkable deposits (OCD,) such as savings accounts at money market interest rates ~ thrift institutions (SS10, savings accounts accounts at commercial banks have a bigger effect on the latter. (MMCB^ at Three do not yield ~ interest. NOW accounts, commercial banks (SCBJ, and money market accounts at thrift 17 institutions aggregate (MMSL,). 10 Using given by: is CE = CU t t * TC + t DD t y-^)SCB t * * (l-^Of)OCD, For the reasons given t weights currency equivalent." rate spreads with the overall we * (13j -!™*d)MMSL (1 rcp,t rate, are . t our benchmark estimates of the currency moving averages of interest rate spreads as high also consider a second aggregate, labelled the "fixed In this aggregate we replace the 13-month average interest sample average differentials. quantities of various commercial paper t this aggregate's short-term fluctuations are sensitive to frequency interest rate changes, Data on the + rcp,t in the previous section, Because even rcp,t {\-!™2*±)MMCB equivalent aggregate use 13-month centered 11 {\-^d)SSL + rcp.t rcp,t weights. CE these symbols as subscripts to identify returns, the monetary assets that enter equation drawn from Federal Reserve Board Statistical (8), as well as the Release H.6. The data are available at a monthly frequency, seasonally adjusted, for the period since January 1959. Data on available. 10 M1 deposits. Our measure of equals the M2 monetary interest rates corresponding to the Tqcd.i, sum of currency, includes all the interest rate on other checkable travellers checks, monetary assets in Ml assets are not as readily demand deposits, is an average deposits and other checkable plus savings deposits, small denomination time and Eurodollar deposits, and money-market components of this aggregate yield market returns deposits, short-term (overnight) repurchase agreements mutual fund shares. We assume that the last two and consequently give them no weight in our CE aggregate. M3, a still broader aggregate, includes large-denomination time deposits and term repurchase agreements and Eurodollar deposits. "We For each of its 13-month average centered in month t. months of the sample, we use the average interest rate ratio for the first Oast) 13 months instead of the centered moving average. replace, for example, roco,,/^,, with the first Oast) 13 18 across various types of interest-bearing accounts computed The interest rate accounts, on savings accounts r^,, r^c^, and Tmms^u were constructed the interest rate 1986, at when these accounts, as reported maximum occasional FHLBB by also provided the Federal Reserve Board. at thrifts, we were deregulated, r^m, in two parts. use the average interest rate paid on Our imputation commercial banks. allowable interest rates at thrifts We Since mid- by the Federal Reserve Board. Before 1986, we impute rates for thrifts using rates at relating the the Federal Reserve Board. commercial banks as well as those on money market on savings accounts interest rates at thrifts by relies interest on regulations and commercial banks, as well as surveys of average interest rates paid at these institutions. 12 For part of our sample, the interest rate on passbook savings accounts exceeded that on commercial We assume paper. that these interest rates were equal in these cases, thereby setting the weight on the associated asset stock to zero. Figure 1 plots Ml and the currency-equivalent aggregate defined in (13). The two aggregates are drawn on the same scale so the Figure shows that their size and growth rate are generally similar. In particular, OCD t is difference between the much more periods. When 12 While CE includes more given a smaller weight in two aggregates sharply than Ml in is that assets, CE Mi's some periods and These pronounced changes in CE than in rate CE Ml. The most of growth is striking smoother. CE rises also declines steadily during certain on regulated monetary assets often we assumed r^, = r^,, + .75. This additive factor was .50 for we assume r^ = 5.24%, and for the 1979-1986 period, we 1970-1973. For the 1973-1979 period make crude these are given small weight. are associated with changes in interest rates. the commercial paper rate changes, the rates For the 1959-1970 period, many of estimates using occasional surveys of interest rates paid. 19 change Thus, as an example, declines in the commercial paper less than proportionately. on OCD, rate tend to raise rocD.Acp.t so that the weight falls. The result is that aggregate itself falls as well. 2.2 Stationaritv Properties of Alternative Aggregates The apparently cyclical behavior of CE raises the question traditional aggregates exhibit different stationarity properties. CE of whether This issue and important because is part of our subsequent analysis will focus on the long-run effects of monetary shocks on the level of economic Table two CE 1 activity. reports standard Dickey-Fuller tests of the null hypothesis that These aggregates contain unit roots. tests Ml, M2, and the are equivalent to testing whether in an equation of the form log/If, the 7i's sum to one. The trend, to equal to zero reported in the first = a * pf tests column, suggests rejected for any of the aggregates. aggregates. that the <™> e? table reports tests constraining B, the coefficient and also the hypothesis that there 2^ Y/logM,., + allowing it be unrestricted. contrast when fi is unrestricted (the second column), a unit root can be rejected for CE, though not for the other is CE are a unit root cannot be This rejection reflects the cyclical patterns displayed in Figure dependence of linear The former, which that the hypothesis that there is By on the on high frequency movements rejection of nonstationarity. 1, and suggests in interest rates accounts for the 20 These to results leave us with compare the properties of specifications, for CE a choice as to with those of the traditional aggregates. Our has one unit root as well. However, 3. to treat the stationarity We wish of CE. Conventional example Kormendi and Meguire (1984) and Stock and Watson (1989), treat the latter as nonstationary. assume instead how that CE basic specifications will be therefore assume that we will also discuss how CE when we the results change is stationary. Testing Methods Developing a new monetary aggregate is of some intrinsic interest for what it about the evolution of the money supply in the United States. The new aggregate differ from previous aggregates real activity. 13 We in the evidence it reveals may also presents on whether monetary shocks affect follow the tradition of Sims (1972) and perform causality tests to see whether various measures of money and monetary policy have significant predictive power for future output realizations. Under the assumption exogenous monetary impulses, these We measure for married men. real activity The latter is tests by both M that the residuals in (14), e „ are inform us about the influence of money on output. industrial production and by the unemployment rate a particularly useful measure of labor market tightness because, unlike other unemployment rates which are partly contaminated by decisions to leave the labor force, very few married When we men withdraw from the labor force. use industrial production as our measure of activity y, the estimated equations are of the form "Blanchard (1990) surveys the voluminous prior literature on this issue. 21 Alny, = o + The polynomials /S(L) M+ M p(L)Alny + and 7(L) are of 12th order which seems natural given analyzing monthly data. industrial production has to use its a unit When we root. level, not its first difference, in (15) be stationary. we assume deterministic trend in this regression even of money is 14 This because the unemployment rate when we is These are changes in central changes in the demand for monetary and it would be justifiable exogenous changes of argue that, if these money itself included a first difference has a unit root for, in this type it effect of the e^'s makes sense to on output. judge monetary aggregates bank policy, changes assets. The first two to treat the correlations in the financial system affect the supply of were the only influence on the stock of money. were the only disturbances, theoretically data, the inclusion of this trend has a relatively and money of money and output as causal We now more appropriate monetary aggregates ought to be more closely linked to output than other aggregates. "For our likely In practice, there exist three separate kinds of monetary their correlation with output. directly we have more monetary shocks of (14) are functions only of current and lagged differences in This brings us to the question of whether shocks. is are explaining the behavior of the change reasonable if money. Equation (15) can thus capture the causal by of study the behavior of the unemployment rate Equation (IS) assumes that only the logarithmic correlated with output. this case, the are that the logarithm Following the suggestion of Stock and Watson (1989) in industrial production. we that Industrial production enters the equation in logarithmic first differences because, following Nelson and Plosser (1982), we (15) Y(^)Alnmr + <. minor effect, After making however. if 22 we this case, return to the issues that plague the interpretation of all studies of money-output correlations. Both changes in central bank policy and changes in financial institutions affect the economy only through their effect interest rates and economic these shocks on economic that the more activity. L L which, via the L summarize the (9), affects effect of all ought to be more closely linked to subsequent changes in be more closely linked to output than arbitrary aggregates or even than variables which are exogenous changes in L equation This means that one should fmd that monetary aggregates particular, they should such as the monetary base. money demand Therefore, measures of activity. closely approximate economy. In on more strongly influenced by the central bank, These variables would be particularly poor proxies for if the monetary authority chooses its policy to neutralize some of the changes in financial institutions. Any money study of the correlation of is set endogenously. money with output In particular, faces the problem that the level of when money demand changes exogenously, money supply probably accommodates the change in money demand cannot be fully resolved without a structural model of the assets which is well beyond the scope of this paper. neglect of this endogeneity this may is some extent. demand and supply This problem for liquid While our, and our predecessors', mainly a matter of expedience it is important to point out that not be a very large problem in practice. Endogeneity has two components. The that to money demand rises when economic first, stressed activity rises by King and Plosser (1984), exogenously and that the money is 23 money demand. 13 One expects supply then accommodates the increased increases in economic activity to lower prices so this story rise less rapidly after positive be the case, so monetary shocks. We these exogenous would predict show below that prices that this does not would seem to of endogeneity may not be very important. The second form of this type endogeneity arises when there are increases in money demand that are unrelated to exogenous changes have the same supply is in output. effect as money supply response, In the absence of any monetary contractions, reducing output and prices. endogenous and responds partially, the resulting increases in associated with subsequent reductions in output and prices. associated with both price and output With these provisos, we by increases, changes in money affect economic rigidities could activity. and issues pertaining to the make monetary shocks — and we If the money money ought to be Insofar as monetary increases are problem may be minor as absence of correlation between test for the testing the null hypothesis that y(L) this these ought to well. money and output interpret rejections as suggesting that There are many factors, such as nominal distribution of newly supplied monetary non-neutral in the short run. It is much more assets, that difficult, however, to explain permanent, long-run effects of money on output. Insofar as monetary , shocks do affect output in the long run, the interpretation that the money-income relationship represents true causation more either from money likely that the relationship is income "We itself a to income statistical is called into question. fluke or is Instead it the result of responses of or to third variables which affect income as well. money to This endogeneity problem to some extent by excluding the contemporaneous change from our regressions although this exclusion has no material effect on our results. deal with this becomes in money 24 could well be a serious problem for conventional aggregates if non-monetary shocks which of assets for a given level of overall affect output also affect the subsequent allocation liquidity. In the case where both output and the monetary indicator have a unit root, our monetary neutrality corresponds to the this case, (15) one proposed Kormendi and Meguire (1984). In can be rewritten as Aln;'f * - c 5fn(L)Aln/"'* e{: < 16 > . So, a one permanent one percent increase in percent. in test for money raises long-run output by (1-/3(1))" 1 7(1) Testing long-run neutrality therefore requires testing whether the estimated value of this quantity is significantly different One from zero. 16 issue that arises at this point is given the criticism levelled by McCallum showed, Lucas' why our McCallum (1984) (1980) method coefficients in a regression of output is tests of long run neutrality at the earlier attempt equivalent to computing the this sum of is and Seater (1990), measuring the response to a once and itself. the true of our method applies only when money Then, monetary shocks have no long run effect on money sense by Lucas (1980). As on many lags of money and the same method. McCallum's (1984) criticism of make is stationary. So, as argued by Fisher for all increase in money is then impossible because such increases never occur in practice. l6 They Note that long run neutrality will fail to shocks do. be cointegrated if money and output are not cointegrated. monetary impulses have no long run effect on output but other is perfectly possible even if 25 Suppose however that money has a unit one percent raises money at t plus infinity by root. Z Then a shock percent. The that raises quantity Z money at t by can be estimated from univariate regressions of money growth on lagged values of money growth using standard methods. to a once and for The quantity neutrality. From Then the sum of increases in all Z money method works because an event analogous actually takes place every period. generally not equal to one but this does not matter for testing long run is (15) and the univariate regressions for things: Z, the long run response l coefficients money growth we can compute two of money to a unit innovation in money growth and y(\)Z, the long run response of output to a unit innovation in money. that Z is nonzero (so that money (HWtO) A is certain effects, If nonstationary), long run neutrality prevails only if form of long run neutrality, whether monetary shocks can have permanent can be tested even when if is itself stationary, one accepts money is stationary. money rose and then that industrial it is cannot be tested by the 17 all This is not identical to the question stayed higher forever but it is closely related. If production has a unit root, then analysis of the long run effects sum of is For the reasons stressed the coefficients output have a unit root. (14) and the equation which 17 impossible for monetary shocks to have long run effects. of monetary shocks becomes interesting. money and Thus, under the null zero. of what would happen output is (1-/3(1))" Instead, method we used what is required is in McCallum in the case (1984) this where both a simultaneous analysis of analogous to (15) and relates output growth to the current and Fisher and Seater (1990) feel instead that long run monetary neutrality means only that once for changes in money have no real effects. This hypothesis can obviously be tested only shocks have permanent effects on the level of money. if monetary 26 past levels of money. Using both these equations simultaneously one can compute the impulse response function of output with respect to monetary shocks and analyze the long run response to these shocks. We carry out these tests for our currency-equivalent aggregate, which stationary. We also apply this test to two variables, which may also be may be stationary, that have recently been proposed as measures of monetary policy: the federal funds rate and the spread between the yield on commercial paper and the yield on Treasury is bills. If monetary policy indeed the predominant force acting upon these variables, then their changes ought not to have any long run effects on output. We also test whether money has any effect on prices by considering regressions of the form Alnp, = a' + where we measure the price hypothesis that there are 6't + pU)Alnp, + y '(L)A\nm t + level (p) as the money has no no plausible theories effect that Consumer Price Index. this null hypothesis. analyze the long run response of prices to monetary shocks. (1990) this can be done using the same method to the one run effect on output. In the case where hypothesis that permanent increases in (1-/3'(1))V(1) equals one. We then on prices by testing whether 7'(L) imply money and money we It is < ef = 0. thus of As shown by 17 > test the null Admittedly, more interest to Fisher and Seater used for measuring the long prices both have a unit root, the eventually raise prices one for one implies that 27 4. Money and Output 4.1 Granger Causality Tests We first first report tests of whether results do not significant effect monetary null of the Divisia By matters at all in equations such as (15). The 8 rows of Table 2 reports the rejection p-values for the null hypothesis of no link between current real The money M3 activity and past money for a range of yield a consistent pattern, except for on real activity. When traditional monetary aggregates. M2, which always the measure of activity has a is industrial neutrality is rejected at high levels for both ordinary but neither Divisia M2 nor unemployment M3, nor ordinary rate, M3, we production, the and Divisia aggregate proposed by Bamett and his co-authors, but not by contrast, in the case of the statistically Ml obtain high rejections for M2 or Ml and M3. u and M2, yield strong rejections of neutrality. Other conventional monetary aggregates yield even weaker evidence against neutrality. For currency and the money multiplier, either industrial production or the rejected when we we do not reject the null of monetary neutrality for unemployment rate. For the monetary base, the focus on the unemployment rate, but not for industrial production. Our benchmark CE aggregate, which is based on a 13-month moving average of interest rate spreads, yields strong evidence against neutrality regardless of activity of this we CE rejections null is analyze; this rejection pattern resembles that for which index of M2. Because real the current value aggregate depends on future interest rate spreads, the interpretation of these might be viewed as problematic. In particular, it might be thought that these "The ease with which we can accept that Ml has no effect on industrial production contrasts with Stock and Watson (1989) who show that Ml does affect output in specifications like (13). The reason our results are different is that our sample is longer than theirs. We obtain the same results as them when we restrict attention to the period before 1985. 28 future spreads simply contain information about future output and that this is the cause of our significant correlations. We consider three variations which CE "fixed weight" are not subject to this problem. interest rates but, leaving aside to 18 months months. Thus it is As we to the next affect output seems implausible this CE influenced only by the change in yields from 18 after the current period. money growth from one month This too uses future information changes in the component stocks, the change in aggregate from one month to the next months before first is the which uses the overall sample average yield spreads as weights. The second uses a three-year moving average of yield spreads. on The will see below, changes in growth only for approximately 6 that the yield changes in the 3-year through their inclusion of future information on output. The final CE CE is affect output only based only on contemporaneous yield spreads and would be the appropriate aggregate in the absence of costs to portfolio adjustment. As can be The seen in Table 2 the results are fairly robust to these changes in specification. "fixed weight" CE leads to strong rejections of neutrality for both industrial production and unemployment. The "3-year" its effect on CE industrial production is also leads to rejections at conventional levels though weaker. Finally, the contemporaneous CE, which is very volatile, only affects industrial production. The remaining rows of Table 2 present Granger causality tests for several recently proposed alternative measures of monetary policy. Bernanke (1990) argues that shifts in policy are captured by the yield spread between commercial paper and Treasury bills. correlation of this spread with subsequent output was first The demonstrated by Friedman and 29 Kuttner (1990). We too rejections of 7(L) = find strong correlations with output. when we use We find the federal funds rate suggested similarly strong by Bernanke and Blinder (1990) or the commercial paper rate itself as a measure of monetary policy. One important limitation of the interest-rate based measures of monetary stance the estimated effects of these aggregates are sensitive to the time period in question. the CE is that Using aggregate, within-sample stability tests for the coefficients in (15) for industrial production, for example, do not reject the null hypothesis that 7(L) and 0(L) are identical for the pre- and post- 1980 period. By contrast, this hypothesis is rejected at the .01 level for the commercial paper-Treasury bill yield spread. for Ml and M2 is The evidence against sub-sample stability also weak, suggesting that these aggregates behave more like the CE aggregate. The results in Table 2 suggest that the CE aggregate provides stronger and more consistent evidence against the monetary neutrality hypothesis than measures of the money supply. predictors of output. whether CE Since CE However, many, but not all, other the interest rate variables are actually better based on interest rates this raises the question of is partially has any incremental explanatory power once the other measures of money or monetary policy are included in an equation for output. Table 3 addresses that all coefficients this question by reporting p-values for the F-tests of the hypothesis on the lagged values of other indicators of monetary stance. The CE are zero in equations which already include findings suggest that CE's information content remains even after the other measures of money or monetary policy are controlled most surprising finding in the table is that CE for. The remains a significant explanator of industrial 30 Ml production (though not of the unemployment rate) after controlling for both commercial paper benchmark 4.2 CE rate. and the This suggests that the variations in interest rates that affect the are not solely responsible for its explanatory power. Long Run Neutrality We now the long run. whether once and for We thus measure (1-/3(1))''7(1), the percentage increase in long run output when money increases measure and its The by one all increases in percent, and test whether standard error for conventional, CE M2 rejected for all these assets and M3. 19 Not only Table 4 displays equals zero. M3, where this and Divisia aggregates. Ml, M2, and both the hypothesis that (l-/3(l))" ly(l) equals zero is but the point estimates exceed one; they suggest that a one percent increase in the asset raises real output by for it output significantly in results provide strong evidence against long-run neutrality for the Divisia aggregates Even money change test more than one percent -1 the hypothesis that (l-/8(l)) -y(l) is in the long run. zero cannot be rejected, the point estimate exceeds 0.5. In contrast, the null cannot be rejected for the contemporaneous weights variants. CE aggregate nor for its 3-year and For the benchmark CE, the point estimate of the long- run elasticity of output with respect to money is very small (.05). For the contemporaneous and three year versions the point estimates are somewhat larger but still On below 0.15. other hand, the long run response of output to a one percent change in the fixed weight similar to that of output to Ml. The point estimate of this response is "Fisher and Seater (1990) also report rejections of long run neutrality for longer time series. near one and Ml using a is much the CE is 31 significantly different from So, the zero. utility based aggregates that do characteristics vary over time, such as the fixed weight be long run neutral. 20 CE let asset and the Divisia aggregates, fail to This suggests that changes in the liquidity characteristics of assets are important. 4.3 Impulse Response Functions In this sub-section monetary shocks. stationary. do For these we estimates of (15). impulses. We we We From present impulse response functions of output with respect to this first for the monetary indices which are arguably non- report the effects of a these we once and for all increase in money using the learn the time profile of the effects of these monetary then study the impulse response functions for the indicators of monetary policy which appear stationary. These impulse response functions, which are based on simulating the analogues to equations (14) and (15) simultaneously, also serve to test the long run neutrality of these shocks. Figures 2a through 2c display these impulse response functions for the effects on industrial production of a also report 1% once and for all increases in one standard-error bands on Ml, M2 and CE. either side of the point estimates. the cumulative effect of a shock to the monetary variable on real output. The figures Each figure shows Long run neutrality therefore implies a zero effect at long horizons. by simply adding together all the components of our CE aggregate. We created this aggregate to see whether our results were attributable to the fact that our menu of included assets does not correspond to any conventional aggregate. "The same is true of an aggregate we created 32 The impulse response M2 do not correspond money on virtually functions (IRFs) of industrial production with respect to to the predictions of standard models. output rises for the no reduction first The cumulative fourteen months after a monetary shock. in the cumulative output effect thereafter, which leads Ml and effect of There is to the finding in Table 4 of strong evidence against the long-run neutrality hypothesis. The IRF pattern is substantially different for the currency equivalent aggregate. innovation in the money to increase for seven stock raises industrial production, and the cumulative months after the shock. shock. By is after the shock, the total estimated to be only one tenth as large as seven months after the eighteen months after the shock, the point estimate of the cumulative effectively zero. continues After this point, however, the lagged monetary shock has a negative effect on output and by fourteen months increase in real output IRF A positive This suggests not only that the long-run effects of the CE IRF is aggregate are consistent with monetary neutrality, but also that any non-neutralities implied by these estimates are resolved in a relatively short time span. We now turn to the effect of the stationary monetary impulses. functions for shocks to the commercial paper-Treasury rate are given in Figures 2d and 2e. bill The impulse response spread and to the federal funds Figure 2d shows that a 100 basis point increase in the spread between the annualized yield on commercial paper and that on Treasury permanently lowers industrial production by 5%. a monetary shock since the maximal reduction months) is essentially It is hard to interpret this as a response to in output equal to the long run reduction. bills (which occurs after about 10 Figure 2e shows a similar pattern for the response of output to a 100 basis point increase in the annualized Federal funds rate. 33 Output falls steadily and becomes about 5% This too seems hard to lower in the long run. reconcile with typical analyses of monetary contractions. We also assuming and (IS) M c, that in CE which We did . computed the impulse response of this The stationary. CE In other words results are CE we considered the system of equations (14) suggest that the CE aggregate might be very similar to those obtained when CE is first raise no significant long run effect. 5. Money and 1 assumed to also be used to examine the effects level. shocks and velocity prices should rise one-for-one with increases in the This section is stable, tests In the long run, if output first column in is Table 5 reports tests effects in the price of Granger-causality between traditional correspond to p-values for rejecting the null hypothesis that y'(L) CE money of monetary shocks. monetary aggregates, other indicators of monetary policy, and the price of the of not affected by monetary whether monetary impulses Granger-cause changes and investigates the long-run price-level The have a unit Prices monetary shocks on the price level, to output significantly and then lower output so that they have The new currency equivalent aggregate can stock. CE computed the response of both variables enters only in levels and because the results of Table Increases in root. is stationary. industrial production to shocks in = level. The entries in equation (17). All aggregates except that with time-invariant weights display strong predictive power for future movements traditional monetary aggregates. in the price level. The Granger The monetary base is causality results are much weaker for the only such aggregate for which we 34 can reject the null hypothesis of no effect. The rows of the last three Federal Funds rate and the commercial paper rate do show table show strong predictive that the power for changes in the price level, while the null hypothesis of no causality cannot be rejected for the commercial paper-Treasury The second column bill yield in Table 5 presents our estimates The monetary shocks on prices. relative merits spread. results do not permit us of the various monetary aggregates. For of the long-run effects of to all draw sharp conclusions about the of the monetary aggregates consider, the hypothesis that in the long run prices rise proportionately to the rise in cannot be rejected at conventional significance levels. however, and the point estimates for the long-run range from .3 to 3.7. permanent 1 % money standard errors are large, elasticity of price with respect to money Figures 3a and 3b report estimates of the CPI's response to a increase in Ml and CE. In the case of reached three years after the monetary shock. respond to monetary shocks 6. The we is relatively CE half of the long-run effect (.62) is This implies that the process by which prices slow and gradual. Conclusions This paper develops a liquidity services. We new monetary compare monetary aggregate, other aggregate based on the amount households spend on the performance of this "currency-equivalent" (CE) traditional monetary policy in forecasting real monetary aggregates, and various other indicators of activity. The than any of the traditional monetary aggregates. CE aggregate has more predictive power While some other indicators of monetary policy based on nominal interest rates can forecast output as well as the CE aggregate, they 35 money. This suggests also suggest long-run non-neutrality of output with respect to changes in the assets. best CE that aggregate are a more plausible indicator of changes in the supply of liquid This result in turn supports the idea that the monetary aggregate with which one can measure monetary shocks is which measures the the one utility (or the services) that people derive from their liquid assets. Our results also contain disturbances affect output. rigidities are important, some information on the channel through which monetary The literature make people hold lowers investment. this topic stresses and whether "money" or "credit" "money" view, monetary contractions rise to on the new According initially important. 21 is money findings provide some support view, there for the situation where the A According to the a direct reduction in investment is to curtail the "money" view. stock which has the most plausible effect on output point of view of holders of money. whether nominal This increase in interest rates then which comes about because monetary contractions force banks Our issues: reduce money balances and interest rates must constellation of assets. to the "credit" two We have one is that volume of shown loans. that the makes sense from the monetary expansion can thus be thought of as a level of liquid assets is high, at least for some consumers. In the "credit" view, the level of consumers' liquid assets does not matter, except insofar as it is The correlated with funds available for loans. correlated with broad aggregates like M2 than with the CE latter are aggregate. presumably more From the point of "The distinction between the "money" and the "credit" view has been stressed mainly by authors working with models of sticky prices, including Bernanke and Blinder (1990), Gertler, Hubbard and Kashyap (1990), Kashyap, Stein and Wilcox (1990) and Romer and Romer (1990). However, this distinction is just as important if nominal rigidities are absent and different people carry out financial transactions at different times. Grossman and Weiss (1983) and Rotemberg (1984) and Fuerst money matters only because This can be seen by comparing (1990). 36 view of credit availability, whether banks raise their funds accounts at zero interest, or through expensive CD's suggest that this distinction is is through "regular" checking probably irrelevant. Because the data important for the subsequent evolution of output they also suggests that the "credit" view is incomplete. 37 REFERENCES Barnett, William A., 1980, Economic Monetary Aggregates: An Application of Index Number and Aggregation Theory, , 1983, New Journal of , Indices of Bu siness Money & Economic Journal of Econometrics 14. 11-48. . Supply and the Flexible Laurent Demand System, Statistics 1, 7-23. 1991, Reply, in Michael T. Belongia, ed. Monetary Policy on the 75th Anniversary of the Federal Reserve System. Barnett, William A., (Boston: Edward K. Offenbacher, and Paul A. Monetary Aggregates, Journal of Bernanke, Ben S., 1990, Spreads, NBER Bemanke, Ben S. Kluwer Academic), 1991. On Political the Predictive Economy Power of Spindt, 1984, The New Divisia 92, 1049-1086. Interest Rates and Interest Rate Working Paper 3486. and Alan Blinder, 1990, The Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of Monetary Transmission, Blanchard, Olivier J., 1990, NBER Why Working Paper 3487. Does Money Affect Output? A Survey, in B. Friedman and F. Hahn, eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers), 779-835. Chetty, V. Karuppan, 1969, On Measuring the Nearness of Near-Monies, American Economic Review .59. 270-281. Diewert, E., 1976, Exact and Superlative Index Numbers. Journal of Econometrics .4. 115-45. Fisher, Mark ARIMA E. and John J. Seater, 1990, Long-Run Neutrality and Superneutrality in an Framework, mimeo, Federal Reserve Board of Governors. Friedman, Benjamin M. and Kenneth N. Kuttner, 1990, Money,Income, Prices and Interest 38 Rates after the 1980s, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper Fuerst, Timothy S, 1990. Liquidity, Loanable Funds, and Real J.L. Kellogg Graduate School of Gertler, Constraints and Investment Fluctuations: Working paper 3495 mimeo, Management, Northwestern University. Mark, R. Glenn Hubbard and Anil Kashyap, 1990, NBER Activity, . An Interest Rate Spreads, Credit Empirical Investigation . Grossman, Sanford and Lawrence Weiss, 1983, A Transactions Based Model of the Monetary Transmission Mechanism, American Economic Review 73, 99-122. . Kashyap, Anil, Jeremy Stein and David Wilcox, 1990, The Monetary Policy Transmission NBER Mechanism: Evidence from the Composition of External Finance Working Paper . King, Robert and Charles Plosser, 1984, Money, Credit and Prices in a Real Business Cycle, American Economic Review 74, 363-80. . Kormendi, Roger and Phillip Meguire, 1984, Cross-Regime Evidence of Macroeconomic Rationality, Journal of Political Lucas, Robert E. Jr., 1980, Two Economy Illustrations . 92, 875-908. of the Quantity Theory of Money, American Economic Review 70, 1005-14. . McCallum, Bennett T., 1984, On Low Frequency Estimates of Long-Run Relationships in Macroeconomics, Journal of Monetary Economics 14, 3-14. Poterba, James M. and Julio J. Rotemberg, 1987, Empirical Implementation, in W. Money in the Utility Function: Barnett and K. Singleton, eds., New An Approaches to Monetary Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), 219-240. . Poterba, James M., Julio J. Rotemberg and Lawrence H. Summers, A Tax-Based Test 39 for Nominal Rigidities. American Economic Review 76, 659-675. . Romer, Christina D. and David H. Romer, 1990, New Evidence on the Monetary Transmission Mechanism, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity Rotemberg, Julio 1984, J., Journal of Political , A . 149-98. Monetary Equilibrium Model with Transactions Costs, Economy . 92, 40-58. 1991, Monetary Aggregates and Their Uses, in M. Belongia, ed., Monetary Policy on the 75th Anniversary of the Federal Reserve System (Boston: Kluwer Academic), 224-232. Samuelson, Paul A., and Swamy, 1964, S. Invariant Index Numbers and Canonical Duality: Survey and Synthesis. American Economic Review 64, 566-593. . Serletis, Apostolos, 1988, The Empirical Relationship Between Money, Economic Revisited, Journal of Business and , A 1991, Dynamic The Demand Flexible for Divisia Money Demand System, Statistics . 6, Prices and Income 351-358. in the United States: Journal of Money. Credit and Banking . 23 (February), 35-52. Sims, Christopher, 1972, Money, Income and Causality, American Economic Review . 62, 250-257. Spindt, Paul, 1985, Money is of Exchange, Journal of Stock, James H. and What Money Does: Monetary Aggregation and Political Economy Mark W. Watson, 1989, causality, Journal of Econometrics . . the Equations 93, 175-204. Interpreting the Evidence of 40, 161-82. Money-Income Table 1 : Unit Root Tests for Various Monetary Aggregates Aggregate 0=0 Unrestricted M1 .999 .429 M2 .994 .750 Divisia M2 .988 .591 Divisia M3 .977 .669 .993 .012 CE Notes: Each entry reports the confidence leveKbased on Fuller(1976)) at which the null hypothesis in the regression that k = A lnM =a + p t+ylnM _, +d(L) A In AfM +e" t t can be rejected. The regressions are estimated using monthly data for the 1960:2- 1989:6 period. d(L) is a twelfth-order lag polynomial. 6 Table 2: Causality Tests: Monetary Aggregates and Real Activity Monetary Aaareaates Industrial Proi Traditional Unemployment Rate Married M1 .205 .019 M2 .003 .005 M3 .160 .068 Monetary Base .174 .007 Money .223 .179 .517 .473 Multiplier Currency Divisia for Men Aaareaates Divisia M2 .013 .093 Divisia M3 .025 .580 <. 00001 .0005 Alternative Indicators of Monetarv Policv Commercial Paper Federal Funds Rate .001 <. 00001 Commercial Paper-Treasury Bill Yield Spread <. 00001 <. 00001 Currency Eauivalent Aggregates Currency Equivalent <. 00001 .0002 Fixed Weight <. 00001 Currency Equivalent .002 Three- Year Currency Equivalent .042 .0003 Contemporaneous Currency .031 .721 Equivalent Notes: Each entry reports the confidence level at which the null hypothesis that be rejected in the specification A \ny = a + t 1+ gamma(L)=0 can y p (L) A lny,+ y (/.) A \nm t *e t . Both £(L) and y{L) are 1 2th order lag polynomials, so the statistics reported above test the joint hypothesis that Ki = Yi= ••• =Ki2 = 0. Th e sample period for all estimates except Divisia M2 and is 1960:2 to 1989:6. For the two Divisia aggregates, the sample is 1961:2-1989:6. M3 Table 3:lncremental Explanatory Power of Different Monetary Aggregates Challenger Incumbent Industrial Unemployment Production Rate for Married Men M1 CE .002 .011 M2 CE .003 .005 Divisia M2 CE .023 .009 Divisia M3 CE .015 .006 CE .002 .003 CE .002 .004 CE .009 .097 Commercial PaperTreasury Spread Bill Yield Federal Funds Rate Commercial Paper and M1 Note: Each entry reports the p-value for the null hypothesis that GIL) =0 in the specification Alny =a +6f+p(Z.)Alny,+Y(^)Alnm1 f+e(L)Aln/nif+€{'. f m 2 denotes the "challenger" 2th order, so the statistics reported above test the joint = 0. The sample period for all estimates except those for the where m, denotes the incumbent aggregate and , aggregate. All lag polynomials are hypothesis that 0, Aggregates 1989:6. Divisia =0 2 = is ... =G 12 1 1960:2 to 1989:6. For the , Divisia aggregates, the sample is 1961:2 to Table 4: Long-Run Effects of Monetary Shocks on Industrial Production Traditional Monetary Aggregates Estimated Long-Run Effect ^ M1 1.04 (0.44) M2 1.57 (0.52) M3 0.53 (0.50) Monetary Base 1 .42 (0.63) Money 0.99 Multiplier (0.61) 0.13 Currency (0.61) Divisia Oivisia Aggregates M2 1.31 (0.53) Divisia M3 1.15 (0.44) Currency Eguivalent Aggregates Currency Equivalent 0.05 (0.10) Fixed-Weight Currency Equivalent 1 .08 (0.28) Three-Year Currency Equivalent 0.17 (0.16) Contemporaneous Currency Equivalent -0.10 (0.09) Notes: Each entry reports the long-run effect of a unit shock to the monetary aggregate on the logarithm of industrial production. The estimates are computed as f05,K) = (1-/?(U)'V(U evaluated at L= 1, where the lag polynomials are estimated in A Iny, = a + 6 1+ p (Z.) A lnyr+ y (L) A \nm +e y t t . Standard errors, which are shown in parentheses, are calculated as in Poterba, Rotemberg and Summers(1986) as Idf/dfi df/dy)*Vi0,Y)*ldf/d/3 dt/dy)' where V(0,k) is the variance-covariance matrix of the estimated parameters. Table 5: Causality Tests and Long-Run Effects: Monetary Aggregates and Prices Traditional Aggregates Ml Causality .241 Long-Run Effect 2.42 (2.02) M2 .394 0.86 (0.87) M3 .693 0.95 (0.70) Monetary Base .003 2.49 (1.06) Money Multiplier .439 1 .75 (2.35) Currency .159 1.52 (0.55) Divisia Divisia Aggregates M2 .802 0.94 (1.07) Divisia M3 .640 1.21 (1.34) Currency Equivalent Aooreoates Currency Equivalent .002 0.62 (0.38) Fixed-Weight Currency .141 Equivalent Three-Year Currency .002 Equivalent Contemporaneous Currency 3.71 (7.68) 0.81 (0.42) .046 Equivalent 0.31 (0.17) Alternative Indicators of Monetary Policy Commercial Paper Federal Funds Rate Commercial Paper-Treasury Bill Yield Spread .0004 <. 00001 .666 Notes: Entries in column 2 are p-values for Granger-Causality tests of the sort reported in table 2, while entries in column 3 are long-run responses of the price level to shocks in the growth rate of the monetary aggregates, whose analogue for industrial production was reported in table 3. Standard errors are in parentheses. Billions of Current Dollars H I m O c a s m z 5 s 5 S Q 3D rn s CD PERCENT RESPONSE "0 CD -cm 0(53 ?cc pi CO 3 PERCENT RESPONSE i p p fo fo p p O CO ->• ro o> OD S3 1° fo to -fe. "0 CD o c m 30 0) jo (A > Z CD m |8 c -9 ozH JO2 I CO fO cr "Tl CD 3 PERCENT RESPONSE I o N3 o o to 04 o o 01 — ojH *.— —OH >H CO — 01 {£> ~ o~ _l -• 04 ^^ -I Nj" C0~ o to fo*3^ roid_ C CD fO_ 04 .=±1 ro 04 04 0j_ 04 04 A or o»tr 04 Vl" 00 04 t>. tO 0"5~] is C 5 m O CO 0) 33 W js. CD Js. tour tni±_ *»> 01 01 SZL. Up O o>_ > is* O 2 5i ® ! M m o) CO o mO D C 3o "0 o (D o CD ro C7> "TJ CD 3 PERCENT RESPONSE o> Ol 03 ro > 8* c "0 r- O co 2LC m 0) o 2 E! "n 5> Sgoo oi z co ro m Q. -n c z CO 3 o H S o o z a z o O 33 o O D C co CD en -±_ k>T/T *> cn_ cnic_ a> PERCENT RESPONSE CO 00 en en 03 ro -*- o 8 03 » O no C -oz r3 Cm co ' 33 si °i z• CV) £o m S° c Tl s z go H o si Q. (A 31 0J CD z ro cd PERCENT RESPONSE TJ <D 3 0) 3 <d 3 TJ C CO m J 5" 33 a ° =•0 3 ii TJ CO CO cr a o (D 3 mo -n c i O PERCENT RESPONSE p b o o p b> -o CD 2 3 3 CO CD cen m 3 m CO,? I g, 3 o o) O % "n rO 3 TJ O" m CX «< CD -i O CD 3 O_ z mc -n c z 3 o z MIT LIBRARIES 3 TDflD DD?n5Sb