ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT THE ROLE OF PRIVATE PENSIONS Daniel M. Holland WP #1031-78 November, 1978 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 THE ROLE OF PRIVATE PENSIONS Daniel M. Holland WP #1031-78 November, 1978 Grovs/th of Pension Plans , While private industrial pension plans have least, at set it is long history, their accumulated funds have become capacity for vigorous growth is A picture of rapid growth a in retirement. major financial is It institution. deserves a plans Is to the point, This closer look. 2 for state-local Table in 1 government planb. While, on the various dimensions of growth, the Tables "tell trial major Over this same period, borne out by any of the indicia industrial plans or Table few highlights can be noted. a important evidence of the viability and inherent strength of private pension plans; a back to 1875 only within the last 35 years that they have emerqed as of arrangements for income support for private a their own story," The number of vvorkers covered by private Indus- now (1975) over seven times as great as thirty years ago. the percentage of employees in non-agricultural More industry (excluding government workers who are covered by their own plans) has gone from under fifteen to close to fifty. Coincident with the growth of coverage, of course, has been a huge expansion of the fiscal operations of industrial pension plans. a) Contributions b) The number of beneficiaries in 1975 ran at 100 Thus: times their 19^0 level. increased more than 35 times over this period and benefit payments were ]k8 times higher. c) With contributions exceeding benefit payments (and previous accumu- lations earning interest, dividends, and capital gains the pension funds hcive continued to grow. net balances, Indeed, by 1975 the fundr. themselves had Increased to over 100 times their value terms. In 19''0 level In book Much the same story, with different orders of magnitude, of course, can be told for state-local we forego pension funds. But in the interests of brevity, here, except to note that there are suggestions that these funds it are accelerating vis-a-vis those of industrial pension plans. It is these latter that receive prime attention when the impact of pension fund accumulation is discussed. But the plans have great accumulative potential _/ for employees of state and Pensions: A Summary Repor t l^lational and Daniel M. of Economic Research, F. — Murray, Economic Aspects of Bureau of Economic Research, Private Pension Funds: Inc., governments that has not been properly appreciated, For a discussion of this matter, wee Roger Holland, local Inc., 1968) Projected Growth (National Bureau 1966). Summary data appear in Table What we have in essence, then, wi tnessea over the last 35 years, has been the emergence of a 2. private pension structure of imposing magnitude. Underlying this development are and demographic factors. a number of broad soc iologi cal -economi c changes Particular influences such as income tax encourage- ments and advantages have also been important. The introduction of high and sliarply progressive rates of personal income tax made compensation arrangements on which tax payments could be deferred more attractive. For they provided a way of injecting some long-run averaging taxation of the income stream, and, liability. for the usual During the war, more particularly, case, a in the lower life-time tax interest of workers in pensions was enhanced because the stabilization policy limited direct wage increases. For the same reason employers utilized pension arrangements to a greater extent to attract or hold scarce workers. Quite likely, although perhaps not rationally, the high corporate rates levied at that time made pensions seem relatively "costless" and so hastened their adoption or extension to more workers "perhaps not rationally" because wage increases would also be _/ a deductible business expense, and because high wartime rates might well not be expected to prevail peacetime. in as did the provision of the Internal Revenue Code of 19'<2 required that that for a pension plan to be non-discriminatory, and hence have the employer's contributions to it free of corporate tax, to top officers or selected small it groups of employees. the spread of pension programs came from the of the coal strike settlement Relations Board in IS'iS in must not narrowly be directed 19'^6, Further impetus to inclusion of a pension as a part the decision by the National (upheld by the Supreme Court in IS'iS) Inland the in Steel Case that pensions are a bargainable issue, and the Steel Labor Industry Fact Finding Board's recommendation of a pension program in ]3hS. But all Is The growth of pension programs these are immediate factors. also a response to deeper underlying needs and changes structure and economy. An than 7 times, the country's important demographic basis for the grov/th pension programs has been the steady and substantial population. in increase in in the older Between 1900 and 1975, those 65 and over increased almost more from 3-1 million to 22. h million, a rate of increase considerably greater than that for the total population. Thus, persons 65 and over repre- sented A.l percent of the U.S. population 1900, 9.5 by 1965, and 10.5 percent by 1975/ For the 1900 data see Historical — in 5-3 in 1929, 7-5 by ig'iS, These figures reflect increasing Statis tics of the United States , p. 7; for the data for other years see Economic Report of the President, January, 1978. p. 287. life expectancy, but an even stronger thrust for pensions comes from the steady decrease in the number of years those who survive to say, 60, can be expected to spend _/ in — employment. So while there has been a rather mild This trend predates the rapid growth of pensions, but could very well also have been accelerated by their development. So to some extent there is a chicken-egg argument here. increase in life expectancies, of non-working old age. _/ — there has been which 11.5 years would be spent counterpart in in life expectancy of the labor force and 2.8 ]ShO had only a slightly increased but expected time in the the years l4.3 years of in retirement. life expectancy--l 5. 1 His years-- labor force had declined to 9.2 years and expected retirement increased to 5-9 years. This sharp change in years of non-working old age predates the groundsv^ell of pensions. not much change since 19'^0, as in The movement of population from the countryside 1900 a white male at age 60 had a In sharp increase a for similar data the data of I96O refers to all A more recent estimate shows (although not strictly comparable male workers), indicate that a male worker who survived to 60, could expect to live 15-8 more years of which 8.5 would be in the labor force and 7-3 in retirement. (The data for 1900 and 19^0 are from United States Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Tables of Working Life; Length of Working Life for Men Washington, 1950, of Working Life, p. hi. for Men, The , BSL Bulletin No. I96O estimate appears in I96O," Monthly Labor Review , 1001, Stuart Garfinkle, "Tables July, 19&3, p. 822.) to the city and from agriculture to manufacturing and service trades also pushes support in in the direction of the replacement of informal family-oriented income old age to more formal work-related arrangements. The growth of pensions, then, appears to be a response to underlying structural changes in the economy as well as to particular tax advantages. And this growth also suggests that income support old age may be a "commodity" in with an income elasticity greater than one; as income expands the portion of it devoted to providing for old age increases more than proportionately. Perliaps, it not coincidence that is change last 25 years or so there the in the way workers prefer to receive their appears to have been a productivity gains. Traditionally, the fruits of economic progress have been realized hours worked. Since IS'^O, _/ In in It in income and some decline in real manufacturing have, prior years there was a if anything, risen somewhat, tendency for the average work week to decline. I9A0 the average weekly hours worked for production workers facturing was 38.1, was in with the except im of the war years, average weekly hours of production workers whereas increase the form of some in in 39.'*, in in 1950 it was AO.5, 1965 in it was A 1.2, in manu- and in 1975 it 1977 it was A0.3. was this observation that led to Roger Murray's suggestive conclusion that "employee preferences have shifted to some extent, from the desire for more leisure during their v;orking years to a greater degree of financial during retirement or to earlier retirement." _/ Roger F. — Murray, Economic Aspects of Pensions: Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., 1968, p. independence 5. A Summary Report , National Murray notes, however, that vacations and paid holidays did increase over the period during which average hours worked remained ostensibly unchanged (or even increased slightly). the point study. is not unambiguous. V/e leave it as suggestive and deserving So further Coverage Private industrial pension plans, despite their extraordinary growth in last 30 years, the still cover less than half the work force that seems eligible for them--employee5 non-agricultural establishments, excluding in government employees who are covered by plans of their own. is shown Table in 1, the rate of growth of the coverage appears to have tailed off over last decade. the And, as percentage's So private industrial pension plans may, very well, never cover much more than half the seemingly eligible working population. To some observers this writing in 1971, is a being voluntary they now cover And he added, " only about half of all employees pensions are ever tofijlfull _/ Gilbert Burck, considered this to be "....the most important deficiency of private pensions." cover nearly all very serious defect. a in the private economy. social private they must be expanded to role, the working population." if — Gilbert Burck, "That Ever Expand ng .Pens ion Balloon," Fort vine i 1971, p. October, 13'4 Private pensions, are, Workers participating tnconie , tax is due in in fact, not a strictly private affair. them receive preferred tax t reatment ,--no from the covered worker at the time the contributions are made into the fund by the employer on the worker's behalf, and fund earnings accumulate free of tax. he receives the benefits paid out taxed when In retirement the worker if the employer's contributions and is earnings on both the employee's and employer's contributions. of the extent of the "public" interest aggregate of income tax postponed for is a the long period tiiis way. One measure In Fiscal 1976, the foregone tax revenue was about $6 billion, for the Tax Expenditure Budget States Government, _/ individual worker the For the $1,000 pp. . pre 108-109). - ference can be illustrated as follows: year earning interest at Gt would, a estimated Special Analyses, Budget of the United in Year 1976 Fiscal (as in the absence of taxes, accumulate to $79,058 over 30 years. For a worker in the bracket who could invest the interest free of 20'^ tax but had to pay tax on the And for a be $63,2'47. If initial contribution, the accumulation will bracket worker 502; it would be $39,529- neither the interest nor tha annual contribution were free of personal Income tax, the accumulations would be $51,361 (20% bracket) and $23,782 (50% bracket) While, in the workers are retirement, likely to be in lower tax brackets, even were that not the case, substantial savings would result. Paying personal tax on his pension fund accumulation as it would leave the worker •$51|36l in is paid out the 20<^ bracket with $63,2'i6 as compared with he'd have left after current tax on annual principal and interest. For the 50% bracket worker the after-tax amount would be $39,529 compared with S23,782. Therefore, given the public investment a legitimate concern with how well to expect substant ial ly full all workers Is in unrealistic. in they achieve coverage in a social purpose. is But of the apparently eligible population-- non-agricultural establishments For private pensions, there (except government employees)-- the underlying potentially eligible population are 10 two large groups of workers who, in a realistic sense are not "suitable" for employment- rel ated pension plan coverage. in It is not the industries which they work that account for this characteristic; rather their conditions of employrrent. Thus, it is people who characteristically are employed part-time do not really constitute grist for the pension mill in the sense that they do not have a strong enough association with the employer, and would be inconvenient to service. A similar conclusion applies for young workers who are still exploring, seeking to discover their employment and occupational niche, and highly mobile. "Young" in this connection v^ho, is, consequently, are of course, arbitrary. But twenty-five or under might be a suitable cut-off point. If adjustments both on the score of young workers and part-time workers were made, we would have a more relevant base against which to assess pension plan coverage. I have made these two adjustments on an earlier occasion, and found these two groups of workers to represent about 30 percent of the underlying — population. _/ Daniel M. Assuming this percentage to apply Holland, Private Pens ion Funds: Bureau of Economic Research, 1966, p. in more recent years Projected Grov/th, National 21. percent as well, we can estimate that private pensions now cover about 70 of those we can realistically expect them to cover. Thus, although the extent of coverage seems to be increasing only slowly over time, currently is it quite high--in the aggregate about 70 percent of those who realistically could be expected to participate in a pension plan. Closely related to the criticism that the coverage of private pension plans is unduly low, however, is the criticism that coverage is very diverse as between different industries and among firms in Information on country-wide industry coverage appears Estimated coverage of Table 1 in this Table is 1 do^ given industry. Table in 3. not comparable with the magnitudes above, being defined differrntly. data of Table a and those of Table 3 do not Among other things, the workers under include: profit-sharing plans with retirement features and other plans that make lump-sum payments, those in plans that cover less than 26 vvorkers, and covered employees of non-profit ornan zat ions (other than labor unions). i Despite these differences, Table Indeed, the data therin are, to 3 tiie is a primary body of information. best of my knowledge, the most recent and thorough summary of pension covereage by industry sector. From Table 3 we get an interesting and essentially valid picutre of coverage differentials among industries, albeit / a general understatement of coverage. Because of the exclusion alreay noted. Finally, j-espect — / the Table also provides a sense of how coverage has grown with to the As to the labor force. latter point first, mild headway seems to have been made in the extension of coverage. government workers) as a For the employed civilian in 1967, (excluding whole, coverage has grown more rapidly than employment; the coverage percentage increasing from of the total labor force and to hS percent by 1972. 3'*^ in 1S61 to 36^ 13 Manufacturing, Mining and Transportation and Public Utilities are industries of "high" coverage (from 60% 70^); Construction, Wholesale - and Retail Trade, and Service are industries of "low" coverage (30^ These averages reflect the varying proportions (typically high coverage) and small firms coverage).— _/ firms Insurance and Real low coverage reflects a Estate (which tend to have multiplicity of small from other sources suggests that coverage is institutions, but this information a sector whose firms and agencies. very high is low in mixed bag of a is 35?). each industry of large The average picture has not changed much Finance, financial in - in Evidence larger the swamped by the predominance of smaller firms characterized by low coverage. years recent (from I96I through 196?) . Relative rankings among industries remained the same, and except for Construction and Transportation and Public Utilities, the degree of coverage did not change much. So it appears from this review of the 1. In a industry data that: number of industries, private pension plans cover a minority fraction of employed workers. 2. This condition is not tending to improve substantially over time. These data on differences in the degree of coverage reflect, extent, particular characteristics of the various industries. In to some a number of industries, Construction for example, the employee's association with a particular employer tends to be transient, and pension coverage on this score could be expected to be lower than in industries where workers have a long-lived relationship with a single rMiiployer, since mul t i -employer pension arrangements are more difficult to work out than plans tor individual firms. But industry variations in coverage ratios also reflect ]k differences between industries tn levels of pay, degree of unionization — and size of employer establishment. _/ Of course, these characteristics, too, are correlated. Larger employers tend to pay higher v^ages and be more unionized. Evidence to this effect appears of tiie previous paragraph for a in Tables h and 5. To pursue the point moment, note in Table 5 that the fact that Transportation, Construction and Utilities are high coverage industries (expenditure for retirement plans are made on behalf of 77 percent of employees) and Trade and Service, Is'iundoubtedly explained in industries of low coverage (38 percent), part, at least, by the fact that the latter coverage is are characterized by smaller "establishments." The two Tables {k and 5) confirm that, general in more likely among higher paid workders than those who are lower paid, workers who belong to unions than those who don't, and workers ments than those in smaller places of work. which these Tables are taken puts Or as in larger establish- the brief report from it: "In summary, workers who are employed in small, non-union establishments at relatively low levels of pay are the least likely to be participating in a retirement plan. Rapid improvement poor economic position of many small is firms. effectively blocked by the This situation is a matter of serious concern because these workers are among those least able to provide for themselves _/ , July 1971 later years." — "Incidence of Private Retirement Pla'is," Monthly Labor Errerson Bier, Review in , p. ^0. The phrase "poor economic position of many small firms" directs attention to 17 the margi nal f i rm , the Similarly, the phrase worke r, firm that apparently cannot afford pensions. "relatively low levels of pay" suggests the marginal the worker who cannot afford to defer current receipt of any portion of what the employer can afford to pay him. These suggestions are set forth more explicitly in another section of this same report: "While the economic fortunes of a funds available for its employees, company, or industry, limit the their preferences largely dictate how these funds are allocated among wages and other forms of comWages are pensation. a very large part of the total at of compensation, and must be the employees' low levels first concern. Unless workers' earnings are sufficient to meet their ordinary living expenses, many of the common employee benefits are viewed as frills, particularly those payable in the distant future. Consequently, In establishments with average compensation below $2.50 an hour, 8 out of 10 employees were in groups without Ibid., _/ In a p. — retirement expenditures." 38. nutshell, the root causes of low private pension plan coverage are marginal and marginal workers. firm.s If many small firms lack the financir;! strength to take on pension cists and many workers, receiving low pay, cannot afford to "save" any of it, should we expect private pension plans to encompass them? role" In In my judgement, requiring private pension plans to "fulfill respect to these employers and employees objective for a is work-related private sector program. never pay workers more ttian to set an a social inappropriate For employers can they are vjorth, and workers whose marginal net 18 low cannot afford to accept any of it as deferred pay, revenue product is but need to live on now. it all 19 Benefits and Other Plan Provisions The 35-year record of the capture the real past summarized in Tables 1 and 2 does not importance of the benefit payments to be expected from private pension plans. Only sizable numbers of those in the most recent years of the Tables have were viho in the work were instituted gone into retirement. force when pension plans From now on the growth in beneficiary numbers and amounts will be more substantial. Even so, the dimensions reached in the Table are not the number of old-age beneficiaries under private By 1975, state-local government plans came to ^3 (Those receiving private pensionsvere OASI.) in percent of OASI inconsequential. industrial and recipients. very large part also recipients of in While the average benefit payment of private industrial plans grew four-fo' current dollars from IS'^O-IS/S, in real terms average benefits grew very slight Incorporating the older provisions of plans, subsequently substantially modified, or the more modest pensions paid to workers who had been under the plan for a relatively short period, is . not this behavior of benefit payments likely to characterize the future. Most workers are covered by "conventional" plans whose benefit formulae are related to salary (as contrasted with pattern plans which cover the workers who are members of the major international unions and under which benefits are set as a given amount per month per year of credited service). And most conventional plans are now based on final pay. _/ — Therefore if wages This represents a major transformation in private pension plan benefit formulae. In 1955 only 38 percent of plans surveyed by the Bankers Trust had final-pay formulas. Dy 197'*, 78 percent of conventional Survey had benefits based on final pay. plans in the See summary of Bankers Trust studies 20 Alfred In Bui letin , Skolnik, "Private Perjsion Plans, M. June 1976, p. 1950-7'*," Social 13- and salaries continue their long-run trend of participants private plans are promised in indexed for actual be essence in growth, benefit that will a With inflation running at benefit payments could decline Understandably, therefore, purchasing power during returement. in real inflation over their working life. the brisk pace of the last five years, seriously to 3-5 percent 3 indexing ceases on retirement. But this Security there has been increaded interest in cost of living adjustments for retirees. To date, however, such arrangerrtents are not characteristic of private pensions. The Bankers Trust Survey reported adjustments of this kind percent of the conventional plans in its 197'* for about 6 Some un ions--al umi num, Survey. container and auto, for example, have bargained for cost-of-living increases for ret rees i . — Skolnik, p. _/ \k. Some companies have sought to achieve the same objective with a variable annuity option under the basic plan. About 11 percent Trust sample of conventional plans provided this option companies adjustments to pension benefits of retirees in 197'*. In other recognition of cost- in of-living increases, have been made on an ad hoc basis. — Of the companies Ibid. _/ surveyed by the National Industrial Conference Board a variable annuity system was available, and al ready ret red. / p. the Bankers in Z'l in 1975, in 2k percent percent increased pensions to tho; / i The Conference Board, Compensating Employees: 5k. Lessons of the 1970s , 1976 This sample was made up predominantly of large, established companies, 21 The Internal discriminate in Revenue Code requires that pension benefit formulae not favor of higher paid workers, but defines discrimination with respect to social security plus private plan benefits combined. rule here is that the benefit formula a not discriminating if the sum of is security benefit plus the private plan's benefit of the primary sociol constitute flat or declining fraction workers earnings. reading from low to high levels of Since the replacement as average earnings The rise, rate of Social Security declines that of the private plan alone could rise v;i th average earnings and still not be discriminatory. In fact, for conventional plans this is the typical pattern. median wage replacement for final-pay plans ranged from 33 to average compensation of $8,000- $^40,000 for workers with final and the higher the salary, the higher the replacement ratio." _/ h] in "The percent ig^^ — Ibid. These numbers are generated by service at the same salary. earnings increase at final a calculation which assumes 30 years of By an alternative method which assumes percent, an employee wi th 5 years of service and 3D a salary of $9,000 would have received from the 197^ median private plan a benefit equal to 29 percent of his final who earned $20,000, the private plan benefit Adding the primary OAS equal that I for the employee have come to 35 percent. v/ould tenefit to both, gives them to 68 percent and 50 percent, the extent thct salary; a combined benefit respectively, of their final pay. they received additional OAS I To benefits because of their spouse, the replacement rate would be higher. Whether 68 percent or 50 percent is enough, i.e. whether they represent about as much in the way of retirement income as workers would like to have we have not way of telling. There has been plan provisions over the post-war years. In the a But targeted benefit replacenxsnt rates as great liberalization of private this has not shown up as much in other features of the plans. 22 From initial pre-occupat ion with retirement benefits per se, the plans have branched out to death benefits, disability retirement, and early retirement options. They have also liberalized vesting provisions substan- tially, over most of the period under their own steam, (since 197^) as and more recently required by ERISA. Vesting provisions have been design, until quite recently. In a major sore point of private pension plan principle employers and workers had opposing preferences, with employers preferring late vesting in order to "tie" workers to the firm and keep pension costs down and workers pre- ferring early vesting which would give them the freedom to change employers witliout penalty. Within the working force delayed vesting benefitted steady, long-term workers at the expense of transient and short-term workers. Vesting provisions of private plans were liberalized somewhat over time. Generally based on age and/or years of service, the typical ments as summarized younger age and/or In in a the Bankers Trust Surveys tended to move to a shorter term of service. \S7^ by ERISA which required all three specified formulae which in plans to provide vesting under one of fully vested after 15. The private pension plan structure, in This development was accelerated effect would have all workers at least 50 percent vested after 10 years and evolve require- the direction of improvement, then, has shown an ability to liberalization and a wider range of options. The current level of replacement rates provided by private pension plans and social security, would appear to compare favorably with programs in other countries. International comparisons are inherently ambiguous, and more than usually so for social security arrangements, especially combinations 23 of public and private plans. Haanes-01 sen however, has developed , careful set of estimates for the countries listed in Table 6. a For the single worker Social Security alone, there are three countries higher than the U.S., and another as high. combined, if For Social Security and Private Plans the example cited above the the U.S. worker with final pay of $9,000 is representative of the average v^orker in manufacturing for 1975, the 68 percent replacement rate Average gross weekly earnings $9,000 is a reasonable figure. Report of the President, 1978 Over the longer pull , the highest of all countries with — the possible exception of Germany. _/ is in manufacturing in 1975 were $I89.51, so (For manufacturing earnings see Economic p. 299.) there are good reasons to expect programmed pension benefits and/or associated features of private pension plans to continue to become more generous the past suggests. scholars (l8 in And all), it vjho is in the future. the judgement, participated in This is what the record of too, of an expert group of the "Delphi" study of the for the Future whose results were published in 1969- It v;as Institute their consensus that the following features of private pension plans would " increase greatly": a. "Higher prospective pension incomes for future retirees permitting them to enjoy higher standard of living relative to their final pay than do current pensioners." b. "Periodic increases to pensioners income during retirement to reflect cost of living increases." 25 "Pension portability (i.e., on changing jobs employee's vested c. retirement equity transfers to new employee's fund or becomes his to do with as he chooses." _/ T.J. — Gordon, A Study of Potential Changes Summary and Conclusions , in Employee Benefits. Volume I Institute for the Future, Middletown, Connecticut, 27. 1969, p. The majority of them also expected the following new retirement benefits to emerge in the next (counting from 1968) a. "Optimal retirement at age 55 with full b. "Pension plans extended to include benefits for retirees other than money, such as: communities, Legal services." Ibid. , p. Finally, benefits for all employees." Recreation, Education, Medical services. Residential Costs, Apartment _/ ten years: in Company-sponsored Retirement — 29. they also expected a number of other retirement benefits to "increase slightly." ' a. Less stringent conditions for medical b. Survivor benefits. c. Deferred compensation for a significant fraction of workers to to supplement pensions. d. / Earlier or imnx^diate vesting. Ibid., p. 27. retirement. — 26 An additional reason for expecting private pension plans to grow that they have been considered a useful lever in an t i - i is nf lat ionary policy, particularly for programs that rely primarily on persuasion. Such policies sometimes encourage higher pensions compensation for lower current wage increases. for example, in one of his annual wage negotiators to "keep a (deferred pay) as a Thus President Eisenhower, reports exhorted business and labor statesman- 1 i ke eye on the future," and set lower pay increases currently but with higher deferred pay, such as pensions, as part of the package. It is interesting to note that considerable liberalization and enrichment of private pension plan terms and characteristics appear to have been accomplished over most of the period with a constant ratio of pension cost to payroll. (See Table 7.) 28 Pensions and Savings By a homey analogy, the fiscal operations of pension funds can be likened to a bathtub with contributions plus fund earnings running from the faucet and benefit payments flowing out the drain. been (and will continue for many years to be) every year the level of the water in the tub The rate of outflow has less rapid than the is intake. So higher than the year before. Indeed these annual accumulations by pension funds are a major component of the household sector's net asset acquisitions 1975, for example pension fund asset growth for employees of state and as measured by oi: its measured savings. In (private industrial plans plus those governments) came to h8% of personal saving local the National of Income Accounts; or, to use a variant measure, more In keeping with the Flow of Funds Accounts, to }2% of household financial asset acquisition. On either measure, then, for pension plans--the long income tax liability on contributions to the fund of personal term deferral the tax incentives made by the employer on behalf of his employees and on the earnings of the fund (plus, of course, all other conditioning factors) --seem to have been an effective and important incentive. Pension fund accumulations are an important fraction of personal saving and, of course, the more meaningful that industrial in a definitional sense they are. relates to how "real" the saving is. question pension funds accumulated $32.5 billion in But The fact 1975 does not establish that because of their increased funding an additional $32.5 billion that would not otherwise have been forthcoming is available for capital formation. For it could be that compensatory offsets to savings that might otherwise have been made occur Suppose the price of Scotch stantially. in response to pension fund accumulation. alone of all spirituous liquors v^as cut sub- Sales of Scotch would go up, and sales of competing beverjges 29 Sales of spirituous liquors as would go down. probably by nothing like the increase class might well a go up, but the sales of Scotch alone. in Preferred tax treatment for pension plans vis-a-vis other forms of saving is equivalent to a cut in their price return they provide to savers). but savings in other forms, (really it is a relative increase So pension saving should go up, which (i.e., made via other arrangements) the in has, it insofar as they could serve some of the purposes that pension savings are made for, may be expected to decline. On net balance, considerably less than the increase then, in saving may rise, but by total This pension fund saving per se. is where we would come out by deduction. The argument says something about the nature of the effect, but has nothing to say about its magnitude. depend importantly on the degree of subst tutabi i 1 i That vjould ty between pension fund accumulation and other forms of saving. • Additional theoretical support for the view that pension saving is made primarily at the expense of other saving comes from the life-cycle They assume hypothesis developed by Modigliani and others working with him. that "consumption and saving decisions of households at each point of time reflect a more or less conscious attempt at achieving the preferred dis- tributionof consumption over life cycle," but do not distinguish among the different assets accumulated for this purpose. _/ — Implicitly, to the Franco Modigliani, "The Life Cycle Hypotliesis of Saving, the Demand for Wealth and the Supply of Capital," Social Research , Summer, 1966, p. 162. extent that the desired total of saving contains pension fund accumulations, it will incorporate commensuratel There is y less in other forms. also some crude empirical evidence that seems to support the 30 expectation that pension fund savings will not, to the flow of personal saving, but will in the main, be net new additions rather be made at the exnense of Over half a century--'f rom 1897 through \Sh3-- alternative forms of saving. Raymond Goldsmith in his study of saving the American economy discovered in saving (including consumer durables) that the ratio of personal to personal income appears to have been substantially constant, as have been proportions of total savings made by the personal, corporate, and government sectors, respectively (if saving ttirough social security funds _/ is included Raymond W. in personal saving). — other governmental trust This outcome over along period of Goldsmith, A Study of Savings Princeton University Press, and in the United States , Volume I, 1955, pages 6-9. years encompassing significant institutional changes, particularly the rapid development of financial saving (for example, intermediaries and life insurance and, a relative growth in "contractual" later, amortization of mortgage payments as general practice), suggests that there were powerful and persistent forces making for constancy hand" of empirical in savings shares. A resort to the "invisible regularities never proves anytliing, of course, but the record of the past suggests that accompanying the growth of pension funds as with the rapidly burgeoning financial will be adjustnients in institutions of early periods, there choice and use of savings media that would keep aggregate savings ratios approximately unchanged. Both the deductive and the empirical argument just presented have assumed, Implicitly, that pension plan savings are reasonably good substitutes for other forms of saving. If not, the offsets need not be substantial. fact, there are good reasons to consider that accumulation in this form is In 31 quite an imperfect substitute for other household _/ See: Roger Murray, Economic Aspects of Pensions: F. National Bureau of Economi a) Equity saving.— in c Ffesearch, Inc., New York, 1968, A Sumn.ary Report p. , 55. pension fund cannot be drawn on to meet emergency needs a or for purpose other than retirement income. They lend little liquidity to the household's asset portfolio. b) Pension plan participation is compulsory. Some accumulations are made on behalf of workers v/ho would not otherwise save or would not save as much. c) There appears to be considerable ignorance and uncertainty among employee: of the facts of pension plan coverage and accumulation. that, the deductive argument In addition, in common with most economic reasoning, consumer preferences viere assumed to be fixed and invariant. But, is to revert- to Scotch once people attracted by its lower price had tried recognized that it filled a subject to the further qualification it more, suppose some and grown to like need no other liquor quite served. it, had Then sales of Scotch would increase but not primarily at the expense of other hard liquors. These qualifications suggest that the savings effect of private pension fund accumulation is a more open question than the earlier arguments would hold, an argument to be settled by recourse to the evidence rather than deductively. Early evidence (from the late 50s and early 50s) garnered Investigations indicated that personal saving cet. par. in all in two separate other forms was as great for those covered by pension plans as those not covered, pointing to 32 the conclusion that pension plan saving was a net addition to total saving. One study drev^ on a large but not very "representative" sample, and the other on a smaller sample structured to be representative of the United States population as a whole. Phillip Cagan summarized his primary finding and his explanation for it, this way: "...covered households make no net reduction in all likelihood make a net increase though it in other forms of saving and may be less on the average than one percentage point. "Pens ion coverage draws attention to the problems of providing for retirenen; and goes a long way in helping to solve them. "It facilitates the rapidly spreading shift to financial means of providing for retirement from the older reliance on family, family farm or business. But by itself it the average household supplements it is rental property, and the small apparently found inadequate; by additional accumulations, mostly in bank accounts and government bonds, at the expense of consumer durable purchases. I shall better term." a / call this a " recognition" effect of coverage for want of — Phillip Cagan, The Effect of Pension Plans on Aggregate Saving Bureau of Economic Psesearch, sample consisted Inc., New York, I965, pp. 28 and 53- , National Cagan's of about 11,000 households who subscribed to Consumer's Union and answered a mail questionnaire distributed to them. 2. From another inquiry with the same purpose, but using a very different sample and methodology, George Katona concluded "that coverage by private pensions makes a difference in explaining saving performance, encouraging 33 more saving rather than inhibiting it." _/ George Katona. Center, Pr i — The explanation, as he sees vate Pension Plans and Individual Saving it Survey Research , Institute for Social Research, University of Michigan, I965, pp. 81-82. runs as fol lows "The prospect of receiving pr vate pens ions made many people feel i that they were close enough to their goal of achieving a satisfactory income after retirement so that with some additional saving effort they would be able to reach that goal. pension plans often felt that a the other hand, On it people without private was not possible to assure themselves satisfactory standard of living during their old age; whatever they could save would not suffice, so that they were not greatly motivated Aspirations appear to rise with accomplishment, and attainable to save. rewards have as well __/ a stimulating effect not only on spending but on saving because both arc held to be of great value." George Katona, Burkhard Strumpel, and Ernest Zahn, Aspi rat o ns and i Influence: Comparative Studies McGraw-Hill Book Company, Some years concluded that later "iiis 1971, (197'0 in the United States and \/estern Europe p. 103. , Munnell analyzing the data used by Cagan, published results seem less convincing, and the conclusion that pensions stimulate saving more questionable." _/ — — And on closer study Alicia Haydock Munnell, The Effect of Social Security on Personal Saving Bal linger Publisliing Company, of a sub-sample of Cagan' s Cambrdige, MA, data (and soir.e to his study from the same population) 197^*, P- 98. collected immediately subseque.Uly she obtained "results that directly , 3^ contradicted his original conclusion. Coverage by either security was accompanied by social rate among persons aged 55"65, Ibid., p. a 3 a pension plan or percentage point decline the retirement savers. in the savings — 98. Even more recently working with a new body of data (covering the saving behavior for the years 1966~71 of about 5,000 men who were between kS and 59 in 1966), Munnell concludes on the basis of coverage reduces savings efforts for whom retirement _/ Alicia of Pol i t H. ical in a very careful analysis that "pension other areas--at least for those older men — the primary savings motive." is Munnell, "Private Pensions and Saving: Economy , October, 197^, p. New Evidence," Journal lOl't. Because the sample was representative of the country as a whole, Munnell was able to estimate the aggregate effect on saving of annual provision of private pensions. in _/ In all, "....the reduction in . ann'jal aggregate saving 1973 due to future private pension benefits would be about $13 billion.— Ibid., p. 1031. It v;ould be less than this "if younger persons are very insensitive to pension coverage." However contributions (employer and employee combined) plan funds were $21.1 billion in 1973, so pension savings are only partially In 1973, for example, with running about 60 percent of contributions, total personal savings offset by displacement of savings the offset to private pension in other forms. were higher by about $8 billion because of i.idustrial pension plans. cites as the reason for a partial Munnell (rather than full) offset "the fact that the substitution of pension saving for other saving is imperfect probably 35 because of lack of vesting and other uncertainties." / — If lack of vesting is Ibid. important in expla i n i ng the partial offset, we can expect over time a higher percentage tradeoff of other savings against pension fund saving, because vesting conditions have improved substantially in recent years as required by ERISA. Substantially, the same story on savings effects should apply for those employees covered by pension plans of state and local governments, which characteristically have had more generous vesting provisions than private industrial plans. Munnell concludes, "On the basis of these rough calculations, private pension plans appear to increase aggregate savings on net and contribute to capital _/ accumulation." — Ibid. The effect of OAS I on saving appears to be quite different. Essentially a pay-as-you-go operation, with a pension promise validated by the full faith and credit and the taxing power of the federal government, the social security system provides promises which those presently working can "count on," but does not build up a fund. effect of OAS I on saving and reached the conclusion from analyzing a variety of evidence that the social on saving. Both Feldstein and Munnell have researched the security system exercises a negative effect 36 Feldstein, too, is currently studying the effect of private pension The most recent paper of his that plans on saving. I have seen on the subject notes first in its conclusions that: "The analysis and statistical estimates presented an important difference the aggregate economic in in impact of private pension programs and unfunded public social security programs. social this paper point to Although such public security programs are likely to reduce national savings by acting as a substitute for household retirement saving, this tendency is offset funding private pension programs by the combination of the companies' partial response to unfunded liabilities." and the shareholders' Martin Feldstein, "Do Private Pensions _/ 1957, Harvard Discussion Paper 553, May, May, 1977, much more study Increase National Saving?", Institute of Economic Research, is is, in needed before solid estimates can be made. an important question" is , pp. 33 and that His own first attempt to answer a "that the $11.5 billion growth of pension reserves 197^ added $^.0 billion to private saving...." Ibid. He emphasizes theory, unambiguous. preliminary estimate, which he describes "as only _/ He goes on, however, 33. p. to note that neither effect in — in — 32. With respect to saving, then, there is a real complementarity between the two major systems that have emerged in the last 30 years for income support in retirement. there is a lower than (OASI) und "private" plans (in which public interest) dovetail neatly-the one tending to make saving it aggregate. otherwise would be, the other tending to raise saving a in the lesser "distortion" Reliance on both systems, in effect, means than would occur if we relied on either one alone, and of the savings level argues for The "public" plan continuance of a a major role for the combination public and private system for income sufiport in retirement. , 37 Additional Saving for How Long ? During working life, then, plans tend to save more, in appears that those covered by pension the aggregate partially offset by less saving support consumption life will it (because pension plan saving other forms). in retirement. in plan fiscal operations on saving in But their saving Hence, is only working in the net effect of pension the aggregate depends on the net balance of contributions plus fund earnings on the one hand and benefit payments on Reverting to the bathtub analogy, at the outset of the other. a plan, with many workers and few retirees, contributions geared to expected future benefit payments run at much higher levels than current benefits. the bathtup more rapidly than drains out. it each year as the fund accumulates assets. added to and vs/ater ttie Aid V/ater flows into "The "dirt rings" will be higher the earnings on those reserves are But over time the number of retirees picks up momentum inflow. starts to flow out at more rapid rate. a This tends to tone down on annual accumulation. If we were dealing with a steady-state population of workers and retirees, the fund would level off at the point where contributions plus earnings just equalled benefits. As long, however, as the working population grew and/or plan provisions were liberalized, contributions plus earnings would tend to exceed benefits. Casual Pension funds would be net accumulators. inspection of Table 1 and 2 indicates that while benefits are catching up on contributions plus earnings there is some way to go. Private industrial plans are still accumulating assets, and so are state-local government employee plans. Indeed, the asset accumulation propensities of the latter are impressively large given that they cover a much smaller 38 population than industrial plans, are notoriously underfunded. a/id accumulation continue, i.e. For how long will for how long can we expect private pension plans to continue to add to aggregate saving on net balance? A dozen years ago than, as / turns out, it Daniel made correct. stab at this question which was more courageous a — Projecting for the period 1965 through 1975, Holland, Private Pension Funds: M. of Economic Research, for example, I I inc.. New York, Projected Growth National Bureau 19^6 seriously underestimated the level of annual and prematurely projected a tendency for the annual I , fund accumulation, accumulation to level off. did capture the surprising vigor of state-local plan fiscal operations relative to private industrial plans, however. Nothing is from my guesses in lost, and something is likely to be gained, if we turn to more recent conjectures and estimates. discussing the future pattern of private industrial pension fund accumulations William Hsiao identified two Important forces that would tend to keep contributions plus earnings kO years, "at tiie larger than benefit payments over the next end of which time, pension plan funds migiit well become net sellers of financial assets. 1. EPxISA starting In 197^, This will cause a "....bulge requires funding of past service credits. in' funding patterns [that] may continue for the next 20-30 years." 2. He also expects that when the baby-boom of the Post-War period fully impacts the labor force between contributions will 1975 and 1985, covered workers and increase substantially, and fund assets will continue 39 6 'O to grow. _/ in —/ William C.L. Hsiao, "Demographic Changes and Funding for Pension Plans," Funding Pensions: Series No. 16, Reserve Bank of Boston Federal Held in October, Implications for Financial Markets issues and 1976) , (Proceedings of a , Conference Conference 2k. p. "Yet as the age cohort groups born between 1950-60 reach retirement year 2015 and after, the pension funds benefits. pay out the accumulated funds as Meanwhile, with the expectation that the lower fertility rate we have experienced will continue, the proportion of active workers will Accordingly the aggregate contributions are likely to decrease. decline. It v;ill in seems highly probable therefore, that the balance of pension funds will be depressed because the net cash f low--cont ri but ons minus benefit payments-i may be negative." _/ Ibid. As a comparison of Tables and 1 suggests, state-local employee plans 2 are accumulating reserves at a faster rate than private industrial And this despite the fact that they tend to fund moreover Munnel 1-Connol ly ' s and would extend over Alicia Local, it), To the extent that their degree of stepped up, perhaps because of the danger that they might otherwise be put under ERISA or a similar _/ (or lack of projections suggest very impressive annual additions to fund assets over the next 20 years. is lower proportion of their Even at their current rate of funding pension liabijities. funding a plans. H. Civil for Financial Munnel a M. Connolly, "funding Government Pensions: Service and Military," Markets , the accumulations would be heavier, — longer period and Ann 1 regimen, in Conference Series No. (Proceedings of a Conference Held in Issues and Funding Pensions: October, 16, Federal 1976) pp. State- Implications Reserve Bank of Boston 9^* ^nd 117- 41 Meeting Pension Promises receive a defined benefit Most workers covered by Pension plans will which is the pension under this plan shall the following: annual compensation in the retirement 2/3 percent of average 1 highest consecutive years of the 10 preceding 5 had been under the plan for 30 years would, to 50 percent of his equal be Thus a worker who years of service (not exceeding 30 years). X for example is A characteristic formula, related to final pay. (a retirement, receive a benefit pay. final The record of the past in long extensive record) suggests that real say, wages tend to grow at about the same rate as productivity, Nominal wages then tend to grow at 3.5 percent. rate of inflation. the actual If effective and more pronounced in thei r work 1 i to to 3-5 percent plus 3 anything, de facto indexing has become more recent years, and therefore tins relation- ship of the past can be expected to persist over the future. therefore characteristically have 3 a Workers pension claim indcKed to wages over fe. As a hedge to meet workers' pension claims, pension funds cannot find precisely similar market investment instrument. Were they to invest expect, over solely in short-term debt, say Treasury Bills, they could long periods a return equal a real to about the average rate of inflation, i.e. variability return of close to zero over the long pull, with some around the average, of course. term expectation is a real long-term corporate bonds the long- On return of about 1.5 percent, with greater variability around the expectation. over the long pull percent real (on On common stock, they could expect the basis of the record of the past) about 6 greater annual return, but, of course, with a substantially variability than on bonds.— / for Treasury Bilk, Corporate The annual standard deviations of return . - ,. . __.- _.:..„,, L A-?' 7 7;. nnd 23.5'i. The i!<ila a 1^2 on historically-experienced returns and their variability are fron: Roger Ibbotson and Rex A. G. Year-by-Year Historical Inflation: Business 1976, Returns (1926-7^)," Journal of 11-^47. pp. pension plans have had the past, as Treynor notes,— In / January, , Sinquefield, "Stocks, Bonds, Bills, and Jack L. a "something Treynor, "The Principles of Corporate Pension Finance," The Journal of Finance, May, 1977, for nothing" aspect about P- them, 627. the sense that they represented in claims that potential beneficiaries took seriously, but corporate managers, actuaries, accountants, creditors and stockholders "have regarded pension funds lightly." More recently, however, they have and will continue to be taken more seriously on the corporate side. One reason for this lies in the poor stock market results of recent years. The precipitous decline for many corporations a stock value destroyed in v/hat had been comfortable cover for pension plan obligations. Another was the introduction of more stringent funding requirements, regulations and potential sanctions under ERISA. Legally, at least, up to 30 percent of corporate net worth is attachable to meet pension plan obligations should accumulated funds fail when a good number of firms were in to be sufficient. this condition, the PBGC (Whether, (Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation), established by ERISA as the insurer" of plan obligations, would choose to exercise this power, is, of course, highly debatable.) And there are intimations that investors have now become keenly aware of the obi iyat ions that pension plan promises represent. Oldficld found that "Although not directly reported in a Thus [unfunded pension] obligations are firm's balance sheet, thoy influence the A3 value of a firm's common stock." _/ George / Oldfield, "Financial Aspects of the Private Pension System," S. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking degree of influence is debatable. , February, 1S77 Part 1, p. The S**. Oldfield concluded that for each dollar of unfunded vested liability the share price was reduced by about one dollar. Since aggregate unfunded liabilities exceed unfunded vested liabilities, Feldstein (op. cit., p. 23) concludes that "this implies that share prices are depressed by substantially less than the total And he adduces additional evidence to support the same pension benefits." belief, viz. the failure of corporations to float debt to fund pension obligations even though there would be (op. cit. p. unfunded expected future a tax advantage in so doing because "the interest cost incurred by the firm on its new debt 23) would be tax deductible while the nev^ interest income received by the pension fund v;ould not be taxes" has as "one plausible explanation" the possibility that "the market would recognize the explicit debt accordingly) in recognized." (p. a (and depress share prices way that the implicit "debt" to the pension fund 2^4) Is not ^li In Bull the pre-ERISA, market years, a heavy reliance by pension funds on stock which could be expected to generate on average over the long pull to meet the real returns sufficient pension plan obligations was the "natural" way to go. real regulatory environment and market "tone" suggests market tone _/ record of the past persisted) the (if is a transient phenomenon, — it is Now both The negative not. but the regulatory environment is Waiving aside the question, addressed below, as to whether the generosity of the pension plan promise and the increased certainty of its excercise have brought about a permanent decline in profit prospects, and, therefore, in the price level of common stocks. here to stay. Literally and narrov^ly interpreted the regulatory requirements of ERISA do not seem particularly irksome. standards of prudent i al i They substitute for the older that a more sophisticated "rule" that ty requires diversification to avoid undue risk. These and other features of ERISA some commentators believe have tended to push pension fund management toivard more _/ Cf. conservative investment. Randall D. Issues and Conference held in But on an Weiss, "Private Pensions: Growth of Retirement Funds," Pen sions: ~ Impl i in Federal firm basis Impact of ERISA on the Reserve Bank of Boston, Fund ing cat ons for Capital i The individual Markets , Proceedings of a October, 1976. Weiss concluded that "The fiduciary responsibility rules will increase iA investments and thus lower their overall the conservatism of plan of return." (August ^, (p. And he cites I'lS). 1976) that in "indicates that overall (p. a survey of pension fund managers investment strategy has become more conservative." \h8). the push the reporting on Street Journal article Wall a rate in this direction would not be as severe as it would be if PGBC took aggregate pension fund structure as the relevant domain for standards of prudent i al i ty An individual firm or two that sought a high return/risk position for its pension fund position could be handled by PGBC. too heavy an equity position, occurrence of an event it If all firms took however, PGBC would be faced with the possible could not insure against. So, depending on how ERISA and PGBC requirements are interpreted have one of several emerging possibilities. the pension promise If vie is not adjusted downward, 1. Firmscould impose a more conservative funding regimen on their pension funds than they have in the past. This means that the old level of "foregone cash wage payments" that employer contri- butions to the pension fund represent will not be sufficiently large, given the lower rate of fund earnings, to aggregate to the promised pension. Either workers will have to "save" more (or, as they would see it,- take a first derivative cut in cash wage increases); or companies will hove to contribute additionally to pension funds out of profits, of shareholders. / and, therefore, at the expense — Whether this implies further deterioration in equity prices depends k5 on whether we think that recognition of this contingency already depressing stocPc prices. effect, "taken their lumps"oi hovN/ever, 2. a If is, it a factor then, equities have, once and for all basis. further cause for (historically) a is If In not, is it low stock prices exists. Again with the pension promises unchanged, firms could seek higher return for their pension funds, with of stock, a heavy loading thus creating the possibility for a substantial number of plans that at some time stock values could be so low that current flov-vs could not meet promised benefits and pension fund resources would have to be called on.— _/ Given the Ponzi -game- force is 1 But while PBGC appears ike nature of pension plans as growing relative to retirees (or more long as the v/ork strictly as long as con- tributions on behalf of work force plus earnings are greater than benefit payments) there could be a sufficient cash flow to mset current obli- gations to retirees, but at the expense of funding future obligations incurred on behalf of current workers. generational conflict. 50 years from now, Thus the prospect of inter- And this becomes more severe if, as may well happen the working force growth rate declines. td have the power to take up to 30 percent of net worth of firms In this position to meet be folly to exercise this power at such a time. back up pension plan promises? last resort, their pension promises, One possibility they would be made good by the full and credit of the Federal Government. Then what would is that, this a likely story? is tiie Private pensioners, taxpayer. No one knows, of course, but It clear that the contingency in faith the retired elite, would be supported by the general Is would it is fraught with the possibility of deep ^40- H community 3. di vis I veness. A third possibility is that full recognition of the range of responsibilities assured by ERISA and PGBC, involves these entities with a concern not only with the funding process, but with the nature and size of the pension promise. present graded. levels, Compared to future pension promises would have to be down- This would involve conflict between younger workers, who would bear the brunt of this adjustment, and older v/orkers and retirees who had more generous promises. k. The possibilities discussed to this point all way or other in represent some which workers v/ould shift the risk of their pensions as presently designed to some other group. there is another possibility. But Pension design could be changed. We could switch from defined benefit plans to defined contribu- tion plans, v;ith the pension being the annuity that can be purchased with the sum accumulated for each worker. Company obligation and risk would be limited to the contribution promised by the plan formula. Workers would bear the risks associated with their pension plan portfolios. TABLE 1 GROWTH OF PRIVATE INDUSTRIAL PENSION AND DEFERRED PROFIT-SHARING PLANS IN THE UNITED STATES, 19^0-1975 19^0 ]3h5 1950 1 955 19^0 1965 1970 1975 ^.1 G.k 9.8 1 ^f 2 18.7 21.8 26.3 30.3 Civilian Employees (Excluding Government and Agriculture) (Millions) 28.2 3'^.^ 39-2 '(3.8 'iS.g 50.7 58. A 62.3 Percentdgc Covered ]h.5 Coverage (Kill ions) Contributions ($ billions) Contributions per Covered Worker (S) Beneficiaries (Millions) Benefit Payments ($ Billions) Per Beneficiary (Current Per Beneficiary (Constant Assets ($ $) a $) Bill ions) Assest per Covered Worker ($) . TABLE 2 GROWTH OF STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT EKPLOYt:E PENSION PLAND AND FUNDS, 19'<0-75 19^0 [950 I960 1970 1975 Coverage (Millions) l.^ 2.6 h.S 7.3 9.5 Employees of State and Local Governments (Millions) 3.3 0.59 1.17 1-59 9'<0 2,905 6,300 Percentage Covered Contributions ($ Billions) Per Covered Employee ($) Retired Beneficiaries (Millions) 0.13 0.25 Benefit Payments ($ Millions) 113 27^ 869 1,096 1,593 2,^)83 3,962 2,069 1,520 1,796 2,135 2,^68 Per Retiree (Current Per Retiree (Constant $) $) 12 15 TABLE ^ Prevalence of Expenditm^es for Retirement Plans in the Nonfarm Economy, by Selected Characteristics, 1968 (in percent) 16 TABLE 5 Prevalence of Expenditures for Retirement Plans in the Private Nonfarm Economy and Industry Di^dsion, by Selected Characterictics, 1968 (in percent) Tola! privals nonfarm Mjnuf jctur Ing All nonmanufacturing Mining Construction TrsnEportatlon, F Iri.Tnce, Trade and communication and ullllllea Insurance, and rcdl estate service El- Noei- E>- Ei- Noei- fi- Er- Ho ea- Ei- No oa- pend- fend- pend- fiend- pend- tips nd- No rr- ftend- prnd- pcnd- fi^nd- ppnd- pend- pend- pr:iid- pend- nend* turea Ituree lures Ituree lurea Ituree lluret Ituret ituree tures Iturel tturea Itures ituret Iturot Iturea Ci- No ei- \ No ei- No ei- I Type of employee employees All NonofTice Olfice 55 50 67 45 50 33 73 70 27 30 S3 17 80 49 2S 19 ;3 59 86 93 47 53 40 62 f.O 18 20 38 52 54 28 48 46 77 74 39 38 (2 19 70 81 31 84 23 26 16 61 72 30 56 69 44 Avertje Hourly Compensetlon lesslhiin{;sa ... n J?50lo J349 $3 50 10 1199 51 74 is end over. tl 72 18 41 47 66 72 14 7 82 53 (') ('1 34 28 (5 83 34 33 85 98 21 63 15 17 13 8 87 92 16 45 84 54 23 77 18 4 'J 51 82 52 49 5! 81 19 21 59 41 71 29 97 3 79 75 25 61 39 20 4 70 24 47 59 56 41 53 13 67 61 33 39 70 44 34 30 66 79 71 15 20 52 80 48 2 9i Av6r*ge Annual Cirnlnci Undei J5 000 JSCM Sid undet JO »IO,000 (10,000 and o«ei... 74 36 ^6 29 ft 16 90 10 66 67 56 S4 62 16 38 79 37 73 26 60 93 71 59 29 57 70 43 30 fO 9« 80 73 15 20 85 87 56 42 72 58 28 44 75 92 J5 15 2 44 employee Organlzillon Umon 18 82 44 Nonunion Number of Cmploycet in Cttabllshmenti Under 100 100 lo *j9 500 and over * ?7 _. S3 32 38 M 68 36 7 93 7 • 74 40 71 7 98 ^ 12 56 25 9f Insufficient data to warrant publication. Source: Bnerson Bier, "Incidence of Private Retirement Plans", Monthly Labor Review July 1971, p. 38. . 2^ TABLE 6 REPLACEMENT RATE OF SOCIAL SECURITY ALONE AND SOCIAL SECURITY AMD PRIVATE PENSI0M3 COMBUJED, FOR AVERAGE WORKER IN MANUFACTURING, SIX COUNTRIES, 1975 Pension as % of Earninqs in Year Prior to Ret i reiT'snt 27 TABLE 7 AVERAGE EMPLOYER PENSION PLAN COSTS AS A PERCENT OF PAYROLL, 1953-75 Year 1953 1955 1957 1959 IS61 1963 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 Al 1 Indust ries TABLE 8 NET PURCHASES OF CORPORATE AND FOREIGN BONDS BY STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT RETIREMENT FUNDS AND PRIVATE PENSION FUNDS, 1966-75 (1) Net Purchases by State and Local Funds (2) (3) Net Purchases by Private Pension Funds Total = 1+?. (M (5) Total Net Total Punch; Bond Issues of Pension " as Percent Net Is: - Zlk Total Year 1966 2.9 2.5 5.^ 11.2 kZ 67 3.7 1.1 't.B 16.6 29 68 2.6 0.6 3.2 1^.'4 22 69 ^.0 0.6 h^ 13.8 33 70 ^.5 2.1 6.6 23.3 28 71 3.9 -0.7 3.2 23.5 \^ 72 ii.S -0.8 3.7 18. if 20 73 6.0 2.1 8.1 13.6 60 Ik 6.^ ^.7 11.1 23.9 A6 75 5.0 2.8 7.8 36.3 21 Source: Flow of Funds Accounts TABLE 9 NET PURCHASES OF CORPORATE EQUITIES BY STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT RETIREMENT FUNDS AND PRIVATE PENSION FUNDS, 1966-75 (1) k (2) (3) W (5) TABLE 10 ASSET HOLDINGS OF STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT EMPLOYEE RETIREMENT FUNDS, 1950-75, SELECTED YEARS Un Bi 11 ions of Del lars) I960 1950 ^ of % of Asset Demand Deposits + Currency Amounts Total 1970 Amounts Total 1975 % of Amounts Total ^ of Amounts Total 119 2.5 ?-^3 1-2 601 1.0 1,700 1.6 29 0.6 600 3-0 10,100 16.7 25,800 l^^.h Government Securities 2,')98 51.^ 5,907 29-9 6,595 10.9 6,812 S.k State C Local Obligations 1,5^9 31.9 ^,^06 11. 1 2,032 }>.k 2,500 l.k 585 12.0 7. 12^4 36.1 35,055 58.1 60,889 57-5 75 1-5 1,^50 7-3 5,920 9-8 8,250 7-8 Corporate Equities U.S. Corporate Bonds Mortgages Total Financial i»,855 Assets Source: 19,730 60,303 105,95! Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds Accounts, 19'i6-1975 TABLE 11 SHARE OF PRIVATE PENSION FUNDS AND STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT EMPLOYEE RETIREMENT FUNDS IN TOTAL OF BONDS AND CORPORATE EQUITY OUTSTANDING, SELECTED DATES, 1950-75 1$ Amounts in Billions) 950 Asset 2.8 I960 1970 1975 TABLE 12 HOLDINGS OF PRIVATE INDUSTRIAL PENSION FUNDS 1950-75, Selected Years (In Bill ions of Do] lars) i960 1950 Asset Demand Deposits + Time Depos ts + Currency i Amounts ^ of Total % of Amounts Total 1970 1975 of % of Amounts Total Amounts Total ?; JY 2 "87 DC 2 S '89 MAR 3 1 1990 SEP 27 1991 ACME BOOKBIfDiNG SEP 6 CO., INC. 1983 100 CAMBRIDGE STREET CHARLESTOWN, MASS. mil 3 Hill lull I III III III I Hill TDflD ODM I I I II III nil S2M II Mfll Ml' .IBftflRlES )0V-7? 3 TDfiD DOM 52M SD7 H028.IV1414 no.l032- 78 Kalwani, Manoh/Structure of 73626J. D*.BKS . repeat buy Q,(JP6,95U TOaO DOl EMD bSl 3 HD28-M414 Kalwani. no. 103278 Manoh/Structure 737571 D»BKS |i!ni lip |!!i III I ill II 11 1 I: TDflQ 3 II 1979 repeat buy of 00137169 flip 'hfmk M IILJiiil 002 OSD Olfl HD28.WI414 no.l033- 78 Baldwin. Carli/Liquidity preference un 73601.1^ D*BKS _ 00OS6623 Plipi TOflO 3 001 20T HD28.IVI414 no 1034- 78 Van Breda, Mic/Bayes vs. 736013 . TOfiO 3 the D»BKS. _ 3fl3 lens 0006.6.6.2 001 20T M33 H028.M414 no.l035- 78 §l!!!?,",v of ^^'"'^^""^'^y^^'^'cs 736015 D»BKS price ioao 001 20^ 3 elast QlineRB." MSfl no.1036- 78 Schmalensee. R/A simple model of HD28.I\/I414 n»BKS 736017 llllllll llllilllll TOflO 3 001 20T HD28.M414 no.1038Choflray, 73601? m 79 Jean/Methodology for seqment .D»BKJ.. 1)0066621 . iillliilili llllllll TOaO 001 20 3 risk 00066625 3ME HD28.M414 no 1039- 79 ^.r'5™n. Jeffr/Decision support system 827646 3 0«BKS M. TOflO L 00069325 001 2M fl?S HD28.M414 no.1040- 79 Kaplan. Nancy /A computer code for 73602.1 D»BKS 00066622 3 TOaO 001 2DT sol 3t,?