I ^^ HD28 .M414 no. 3?57- 96 The International Center for Research on the Management of Technology Market Segmentation and the Sources of Rents from Innovation: Personal Computers in the late 1980's Timothy F. Scott Bresnahan Stem ** Manuel Trajenberg *** WP # 154-96 August 1996 Sloan * * WP # 3927 Stanford University and NfBER * MIT Sloan School of NBER *** Tel © Aviv University and NBER 1996 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Sloan School of Management Massachusetts Institute of Technology 38 Memorial Drive, E56-390 02139 Cambridge, MA li),--^ Wwl FEB g^ -^^37 Market Segmentation and the Sources of Rents from Innovation: Personal Computers in the late 1980's By Timothy F. Scott Stem**, and Bresnahan*, Manuel Trajtenberg* August, 1996 NBER NBER Tel Aviv University and NBER Stanford University and MIT Sloan School and We would like to thank seminar participants at Harvard, Princeton, UCLA, Stanford, MIT, the Justice Department, the NBER 10 and Productivity Workshops, Econometrics in Tel Aviv 1995, and especially the Conference criticisms. honor of Richard Quandt's retirement for helpful comments and Cristian Santesteban and Michele Sullivan provided able research assistance. We are in grateful to the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation, to the Technology and Economic Growth Program (Stanford), to the International Center for Research in the Management of Technology (MIT), and to the Stanford Computer Industry Project for support. ABSTRACT Market Segmentation and the Sources of Rents from Innovation: Personal Computers in the late 1980's By Timothy Bresnahan, F. Scott Stem, and Manuel Trajtenberg This paper evaluates the sources of transitory market power computers (PCs) during the PC to entry into the manufacturers. We late 1980s. Our analysis is in the market for personal motivated by the coexistence of low barriers industry and high rates of innovative investment by a small number of PC attempt to understand these competing phenomena by measuring the role that of product differentiation (PDs) may have played in segmenting this dynamic reflects some notion of product similarity and offers a potential source of market different principles market. Each PD segmentation, in that products which share similar characteristics products which belong to separate groups. Our first PD may be closer substitutes than measures the substitutability between Frontier and Non-Frontier products, where the technological fi-ontier is defined to include those computers which incorporate the Intel 80386 chip. The second PD measures the differentiation between those products sold by brand-name firms (IBM, Compaq, etc..) and those products sold by the non-branded fiinge. Our modeling strategy is flexible enough so that neither PD is assumed, a priori, to be of product more important than differentiation, the other. Expanding we measure upon recent advances in the measurement the separate roles that technical advance (incorporating the (e.g., by IBM) played in contributing to transitory market power. In so doing, paper attempts to account precisely for the market origins of innovative rents in the PC industry. 80386) and branding this Our principal finding is that, during the late 1980s, the PC market was indeed highly segmented along both the Branded (B versus MB) and Frontier (F versus NF) dimensions. The effects of competitive events (e.g., entry, imitation, price cuts) in any one cluster were confined mostly to that particular cluster, with little repercussion on other clusters. For example, less than 5% of the market share achieved by a hypothetical clone entrant would be market-stealing fi-om other clusters. In addition, the product differentiation advantages of B and F were qualitatively different. The principal benefit associated with F was limited to the isolation it provided fi^om the large number of NF competitors. segmenting B In contrast, brand products fi-om transitory market innovation in the power PC NB names competition. (arising fi^om shifted out the product These demand curve results help explain, in a precise as well as way, how market segmentation) shaped the underlying incentives for industry during the mid to late 1980s. INTRODUCTION I. Product innovations contribute to economic progress by expanding the range of choices available to consumers and by improving the performance dimensions of existing products. However, the incentives to innovate do not stem directly from the social value of new or improved products but from the private returns that innovators manage to capture in the marketplace. In order to be an effective inducement, these potential rents must be secured from the competitive threats posed by pre-existing products, from imitators, and, at least for some As Arrow (1962) pointed technological frontier even further. from products extending the time, out, iimovators have to enjoy degree of transitory market power in order to pay for their innovations. In this paper, some of the critical measurement issues transitory market power computers, or just PCS) in we examine by evaluating the sources of that arise in this context, the market for microcomputers some (commonly referred to as personal in the late 1980s. In differentiated, fast changing product markets, innovative firms might be able to take advantage of several different sources of transitory market power. incorporate novel features, Second, firms making protective umbrella of a pre-existing brand-name reputation over premium; this branding, Of in the new good. marketplace by extending the new product introductions. To take innovators might exploit a widespread willingness to pay a brand alternatively, the innovator latest offerings new products might existing products only an imperfect substitute for the may try to slow down the pace of rent-dissipation advantage of First, might concentrate on serving high-margin niche markets for the from "high-quality" branded producers (Teece, 1988). course, the classical justification for patents, trademarks, and other forms of formal intellectual property protection is precisely their ability to provide temporary order to prompt innovation and creativity; yet, these forms of protection a minor role in ensuring innovative rents in the PC industry during the seem monopoly power in to have played only late 1980s.' Consequently, we focus here on the role that pushing the technological frontier (in this case meaning the incorporation of the 80386 microprocessor) and relying on a brand name reputation (such as that of IBM) played ' Patents did not substantially delay the entry of imitators as the industry an open technical standard. Thus, our industry (1987) in the modest role played by is like is organized around the majority of those studied by Levin et patents in ensuring appropriability. al. in ensuring transitory market power to innovative Our starting point is PC firms. the fact that markets for differentiated products often exhibit some form of segmentation or clustering according to a small number of "principles of differentiation" (PDs). Each PD defines a distinct notion of product similarity according to the presence or absence of some key product characteristic and offers a potential source of market segmentation. Thus, products that belong to the same cluster (defined by these PDs) would be closer substitutes to each other than to products belonging to other product clusters. We associated with a strong brand is or not the product is at the cutting consider here two such principles: whether or not the name (Branded, B, versus Non-Branded, NB) and whether edge of the technological fi-ontier (Frontier, F, versus Non-Frontier, NF). Both contemporary industry sources as well as retrospective analysis support the view that the late 1980s market for personal computers indeed exhibited the 4-way clustering implied by these two PDs: {B, F}, {B, NF}, (NB, F}, and {NB, NF}.^ estimate, the instruments that estimates all we The model of demand use for that purpose, and the issues that we draw stem fi-om and build upon these two principles of differentiation. that allows us to evaluate the substitution patterns within fi-om we address with the We devote the bulk of the paper to the estimation of a discrete choice model PCS that and extend recent methodological advances and across these PDs. in the empirical of demand for To do so, we study of product differentiated markets (Bresnahan 1981, 1987; Trajtenberg, 1990; Berry, 1994; Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes, 1995). Following Berry (1994), we motivate the fiinrtional form for the demand system by modeling a discrete choice maximization problem faced by a set of heterogeneous consumers. for the potential correlation between price and unobserved quality by We then account utilizing a set of instruments based on the attributes of competing products using a model of competition. The specific model that we put forward, the "Principles of Differentiation (PD) Generalized Extreme Value (GEV)," particular application of the GEV class of models suggested by McFadden (1978). The is a PD GEV allows us to treat different potential sources of segmentation symmetrically, thus overcoming the hierarchical structure (and Finally, we concomitant limitations) of the familiar Multi-Level Nested Logit model. take advantage of our priors about the prevailing principles of differentiation and use As a matter of semantics, we shall refer to each of these groupings as clusters PCS belonging to the {NB, NF} cluster are commonly referred to as "clones"). ^ (notice that instmmental variables that reflect "local" (i.e., within-PD) competitive conditions, thus exploiting an additional source of variation in the context of our short panel dataset. Our main findings are, 1980s, along both the F and first, that the B dimensions. the one as entry, imitation, or price cuts) in any with PC market was indeed highly segmented during the Consequently, the effects of competitive events (such cluster were confined mostly to that particular cluster, repercussion on the others. For example, our simulations imply that less than little 5% market share achieved by a hypothetical clone entrant would be market-stealing fi^om other The second finding that the is The advantage different. product differentiation advantages of B and contrast, The paper qualitatively quite provided from the large number of it NF competitors. was By is non-branded PCS, but also shifted out the product demand curve a great deal. organized as follows. in the late 1980s, including scheme proposed. clustering attributes for each Principle clusters. bestowing a brand name reputation on a new product not only provided some protection fi-om competition fi-om market F were of the associated with positioning a product at the technological fi^ontier limited to the relative isolation that late PC in 1987 and 1988. in GEV model, some discuss some key features of the PC then describe the data, consisting of market shares, prices and the estimation. robustness, and perform n we sources of buyer heterogeneity and the appropriateness of the product sold of Differentiation of instruments used We In Section review We its In Sections IV and V, we develop the implementation, and present and discuss the set present the main results in Section VI, assess their simulations that highlight the extent of segmentation. Section Vn concludes. THE PC MARKET IN THE LATE n. 1980s^ Technical change in personal computing has been extremely fast and sustained; moreover, the nature of competition among PC 1987-88 catches the technology ^ at firms has changed over time as in swift transition well. wath the introduction of a We limit our analysis IBM PCS and IBM-compatible PCS. the time, we Our snapshot of the market new microprocessor, the Following industry convention exclude both older, 8-bit computers (Apple H, CP/M, etc.) and incompatible architectures such as Apple Macintosh. While Macintosh and IBM-compatible machines converge overiap in in capabilities over time (particularly during the early 1990s), there was among commercial customers during the period under study. little would important here with the Frontier. The role played by brand-name reputation we associate 80386, which highlighted, a role that would evolve and mutate substantial brand capital changed. and required substantial only the most technically capable handful of other making PC PC makers would effective use also and types of firms with At the time when the 80386 was introduced design and production of microcomputers technical difficulties, later on, as the identities is (in late 1986), the of the new chip posed considerable R&D efforts fi-om PC makers.* By the end of 1986, A firms had succeeded in introducing an 80386-based system. see their development efforts succeed during our sample period, whereas most other firms took even longer to come out with marketable 386 designs. A key question posed in this paper is the extent to which PCS that belonged to the Frontier (or were marketed by a Brand) were insulated fi^om competition by Non-Frontier (Non-Branded) products. The answer buyers their valuation in to this question crucially depends of Frontier and/or Branded on the degree of heterogeneity among status. In the presence of substantial heterogeneity. Frontier (and Brand) can be protected fi-om the competition of Non-Frontier (and Non-Brand), while same time coexisting with these products, at the neither group eliminating the other. A close-up look at the transition fi^om 286- to 386-based PCS suggests that there were indeed pronounced differences across buyers in their assessment of the prospective benefits of 386- based PCS. From an engineering perspective, the new systems yielded substantial improvements in the ability to run software due to the increased speed of the microprocessor and an model for the main memory. However, some users (and analysts) saw 386-based systems just PCS. Others, already rurming or planning faster versions of older improved address to run as more advanced and demanding software (such as the new Microsoft/IBM operating environment, Windows), saw them as the only sufficient platform that * By the mid-1990s, design. This is it would has become satisfy their much computing needs within the usefijl life easier to incorporate frontier technology into because a much higher share of PC innovation has become embedded of the PC in the components themselves (such as an Intel microprocessor) rather than in the integration among components (see Henderson and Clark (1990) for a discussion between component-based versus integration-based innovation). In the era under study in this paper, the opposite equipment manufacturers had to develop specialized skills was true. PC and make substantial expenditures order to market a product on the technological frontier (Steflfens, 1994). in current purchase. These conflicting opinions, led to significant differences among buyers echoed in their willingness to much more expensive 386-based PCS.' also steeply sloped demand curve for the Frontier and Non-Frontier systems. Our model to which Frontier PCS PCS were insulated differed not only in terms in lively debates in the trade press, will We pay for the much more capable but would expect such heterogeneity PCS, as well as in poor substitutability indication that the product name in the PC was reliable of of their technical features, but also in terms of the brand-name and support from quality service buyers valued an selling firms, as well as and practical for business applications. IBM, the leading brand market for many years, was not just the inventor of the dominant design in PCS but and technical excellence from making and marketing we treat AT&T and Hewlett Packard as branded based on, technological leadership in industry segments close to business-oriented PC we The Compaq. The largest advertiser in the fourth firm treat as branded, PC establishing a reputation for innovation in IBM) and by prior to 1994). PCS; and (/;) their (/) their stated market and commitment to the market segment, backed up by substantial advertising and marketing expenditures.* market PCS and the only specialized at the time, (such as its Compaq PC firm so treated, built its introduction of the brand name by first 386-based PC Within a few years after our sample, several other firms strategy; built substantial brand reputations however, except for Compaq, none had been successfiil prior to O'Malley (1989) summarized both sides of the debate: "While a 386 or 386SX system often a wiser purchase than a 286, those suggesting the demise of the 286 misunderstand the scope and diversity of PC applications." * than is providing reliable service and support for these frontier products (Steffen, by imitating Compaq's is PC computers to business customers. Other large electronics firms also had preexisting reputations; these, ' between Frontier fi^om Non-Frontier competition at that time. also enjoyed a reputation for service, support, larger to result in a measure these features of demand, and hence the extent reputation that the manufacturers bestowed on them. During our sample period, Brandedness as an indicator of high presumably Other large computer companies sold PCS, but primarily to their existing customers rather a mass market. We treat these, including Burroughs, Honeywell and Wang, as Non- in Branded. 1988.^ As with Frontier status, the issue of the degree of insulation from competition firms enjoyed vis a vis non-branded ones, Some and product buyers, however, presumably will reliability may have branded hinges largely on the extent to which buyers heterogeneously value the attributes signaled by brandedness. service, support, that presumably is A branded company's reputation for valued by a// buyers (and we will measure that). particularly high valuations for these firm-related attributes, and be willing to pay an even higher premium for Branded products. In heterogeneity was widely reported for PC purchases in fact, this sort our sample period.* Buyers organizations (e.g. those in the Fortune 500) tended to favor branded PCS of in large over those offered by clone makers. Other, usually smaller, organizations valued brandedness significantly less tending to buy the cheaper clone computers. Compaq In our primary specification, as a separate branded group, and seek to measure how we treat IBM, AT&T, HP and insulated their PCS were from competition from clones.' In principle, not just Frontier and Brand but other aspects of PCS, technical and otherwise, could have been the source of market segmentation and hence of temporary monopoly power. However, IBM's PC historic decision to firms at the time of our sample to class have an open architecture for be strictly PCS (and the decision of the other compatible), allows us to eliminate outright a whole of potential sources of market segmentation. IBM's open architecture meant that buyers could "mix and match" a wide range of peripherals and add-in cards; therefore, price PCS due to ^ Dell differentials between such components could be arbitraged away.'" Given the existence of a competitive Computer would be retail the next entrant into the Branded segment through the development of a reputation for excellent service and support in conjunction with substantial advertising. * SeeRyan(1987), Jenkins ' In related specifications, branded firms. (1 987), we also and Kolodziej( 1988). examine whether IBM was fiirther separated We also experiment with the boundary of the branded variables, such as distribution channels (store/mail order) from other segment. Other marketing may have been important but do not receive special treatment in our models. RAM Some PCS are limited in the amount of they can maximally hold. Up to this limit, however, buyers can typically populate the computer with more of less according to their '" RAM market for unbundled components, variations of the hard disk, could not in attributes make one PC a poor PC for each We therefore treat these substitute for another. characteristics as hedonic attributes, in the sense that demand such as the amount of RAM, or the size we allow them to shift but not to affect the substitution patterns between products." Having focused here on the sources of transitory market power, sample period in perspective, and the demand for desktop computing are being The PC processes. it important to put our is sketch the forces that brought rapid change to the transformed time and again the patterns of competition in PCS the relative level of it. shifted continuously invention-possibilities curve in industries advance memory PCS lie These relentless era, a still, Shortly after our period, a newer and faster we much number of firms improved marketing operations, The losing in our sample period.'^ budget and the software they seek to run. Sellers typically picked these bind on customers early in the An arbitrage intermediate case it, since speed is is life number of new frontier. In the early 1990s, the principal suppliers of IBM was standards that larger especially delivery and customer came " out the seek to measure. microprocessors heralded a microprocessors and operating systems, Intel and Microsoft respectively, PC shifts word processors, and spreadsheets changes mean that both sources of segmentation that support, thereby approaching Branded status. control of introduction pushing out the demand for more technically advanced PCS. companies sold 386-based PCS. Later same The and disk drives frequently like operating systems, Frontier and Brand, were shifting rapidly. In the other fast-paced, themselves. There are also a variety of technically progressive downstream. Software products rapidly, chips, and by powerful dynamic sector itself is technically progressive. Immediately upstream microprocessors, faster industry, Both the supply of technically advanced innovative industries such as integrated circuits, mass storage devices, and so on. of ever PC to hold current much of the PC industry limits so that they did not of the machine. microprocessor speed, expressed in MHZ. Buyers could not "designed into" the microprocessor and controller card. The of several different processor speeds with most models somewhat mitigated this effect most cases, buyers could find their ideal point nearly met by an offered variation. We examine this issue in a variant of our base specification. availability since, in '^ During and after standard setting via the our sample period, IBM attempted to regain control of PC market OS/2 operating system and the introduction of a novel (and proprietary) capable structure, with multiple technicaUy There in a measurement of transitory market power in is power that we seek fi-om the the private incentives to innovate arise moment of transition. However, which discounted (expected) value of the rents transitory market much of the doubt that these changes destroyed is Uttle measure to branded firms competing, emerged fi-om these evems. accme in each period; in this sense, the period-specific investment a key step towards understanding innovative dynamic technology-intensive markets. THE DATA ffl. Estimating a product-level differentiated prices, demand system and characteristics of each make/model The also needed. dataset that we in requires data on quantities sold, each year. Estimates of total market size are gathered for the present study consists of all PC make/ models 1988. attributes could be obtained for 1987 and (boxes) for which accurate data on price and set Identifying a comprehensive, weU-defined block. The gathering accurate data for each and every box, we relevant market presence (see Table scope of the dataset to those vendors with a 1). Because of the restricted the difficulties resulting sample consists Quantities encountered in and 137 for 1988.'^ of 121 make/models (observations) for 1987, were obtained from a database provided by 1987 and 1988. covering the years technology (IT) equipment (including in of distinct make/models constituted a major stumbling the U.S.'' Using calculate the total COMTEC's COMTEC PCS) by a COMTEC Market Analysis reports in great detail purchases of information large, weighted sample of business establishments sample data to weighting scheme, one can extrapolate from the number of PCS sold for each make/model. Since COMTEC purchased PCS, one can use the establishments in the U.S. whether or not they PC Services, design (Micro-Chamiel Architecture). Ultimately, IBM's samples business same weighting strategy to regain standard setting leadership failed. '^ See Appendix A for a detailed description of the data gathering methodology. Appendix analysis. provides precise definitions of all variables used in the •* The COMTEC establishments. Note "Wave 6" dataset that we use here that the sample excludes households. is based on a sample of over 6,000 B scheme to estimate the total potential market size for desktop business PCS. For our purposes take the potential market to be the total number of oflBce-based employees (39 million.) that we estimate includes an "outside good" (that is, price and characteristics data come from from a wide variety of additional sources. We the focused on a small number of RAM provided speed (MHZ), and the standard hard disk provided (DISK, in above, our principles of differentiation in the analysis PC technological frontier and whether or not with a dummy variable microprocessor, and mentioned in Section (FRONTIER) to those with 11, we relies market it at the time: identified variable BRANDED (expressed in KB), the whether or not the was produced by a branded of to 1 firm. PCS 8088, and older). As name was AT&T, to products produced the at incorporating the 80386 four vendors for which a brand 1 PC was We capture the former other microprocessors (the 286, assigns critical technical MB).'' important determinant of demand and substitution patterns: IBM, Compaq.'* The as well as on the possible existence of two heavily that assigns the value all million. GML Microcomputer Guide, characteristics including the microprocessor, the standard As mentioned The model the option of not buying), and therefore market shares are computed as unit sales of each make/model divided by 39 Our we a potentially Hewlett-Packard and by these four firms and to products produced by other vendors. Tables 2-4 provide a Though the two samples usefijl portrait are only a of the PC industry in each of the years under study. year apart, there are substantial differences in the average price/performance of PCS sold. Whereas the average price changed only slightly between the years ($3,225 to $3,205), the average hard disk size (DISK), speed increased substantially. For example, the average standard all 688 KB. Indeed, the average two years. " These The rate level (MHZ), and memory (RAM) RAM is accentuated if the (B&W or Color), KB 10% between We also collected whether the machine was portable, model vintage, etc. '* Other configurations were attempted; the qualitative inclusion or exclusion of branded firms at the margin. to the observations are weighted by the are the characteristics actually used in the estimation. information on the monitor type increased from 611 of each of these characteristics rose over of technical advance two results are not affected by the quantities sold. The rate For example, the weighted average standard of advance shows also 10% of which grew from BRANDED marketed price in in the the share of 386-based sample 1987 to in RAM rises PCS 15% in 1988. characteristics are estimated to The characteristics (Table 3). By to 716 KB. FRONTIER), contrast, the number of of the number of make/models both years. The advance in the price/performance ratio on the observed product the average for (i.e., 30% averaging products stayed nearly constant, KB from 584 is highlighted in a regression of coefiBcients for each be positive, while the 1988 coeflBcient is of the technical substantially lower than for 1987. While a substantial amount of price variation exists in each year, our sample reflects the rapidly falling real prices for inception (Bemdt and Finally, B/NF cluster. statistic in the NB/NF data according to our from this table cluster, at least is PDs (Branded and NB/F market segment since its Frontier) in Table 4. Perhaps of that while a relatively high share 60% of the boxes sold Moreover, the average price for boxes cluster through this Griliches, 1993). we "slice" the the most striking concentrated computing power which has characterized rises as in all products are each year are drawn from the one moves from the "clone" (or B/NF), with the highest average prices in the B/F cluster. NB/NF While this preliminary cut of the data suggests the presence of substantial returns to membership in either the F or B group, one cannot identify the precise (through the benefit of a large demand curve, Instead, our way or, alternatively, more systematic evaluation of the returns the estimation of the differentiated product which these returns manifested themselves in to a steep one) from this simple table. membership demand system, in the B or F group the model to which will follow we now turn. MODELING THE DEMAND FOR PCS IV. The rest of this paper is devoted to estimating a model of PC demand which allows us to evaluate precisely the origins of transitory market market during 1987-88. We different competitive positions power and measure the demand for PCS of PCS which incorporated isolation at the from competition in the PC product level and explore the different attributes. '^ Our model, based We exploit and extend recent methodological advances which have expanded the range of economic models which can be estimated with product-level data (Bresnahan, 1981, 1987; '^ Trajtenberg, 1990; Berry, 1994; Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes, 1995). 10 on the familiar random utility model, aggregates from individual buyer heterogeneity to product level PC market reality, this products and of products no longer being sold. Our model demand. Besides corresponding to permits straightforward treatment of new is novel in that it permits the existence of non-overlapping principles of differentiation (like brandedness and frontiers status) without calling for difficult numerical integration. A. THE RANDOM UTILITY APPROACH TO DEMAND ESTIMATION Our model of PC demand developed motivated by the theory of random is (GEV) "Generalized Extreme Value" in the class utility (Quando, 1956), as of models put forward by McFadden Our (1978) and following Berry's recent proposal for the estimation of such models (Berry, 1994). point of departure choosing is among J,+l a discrete choice random alternatives (J, utility model. Each buyer marketed products is assumed to maximize by year t and the option of no purchase 0=0)), in as follows, v„ j.":":,} where Vjj is the value of product characteristics, Pj is x/p to buyer j the price and = ^j is I. ap, . For product], 6. = x/p + ap. + riy is product j from the average valuation in the population which is a realization of the but a given buyers' draw of similar product characteristics. characteristics X. r\,j of parameters to be estimated random variable Xj is (I) n, a vector of observed product distribution dimensional) in this discrete of rj CDF choice 11 parts. Let (2) ^. the difference between buyer I's value for (6j). t|. two Each buyer receives a draw of the The draws need not be independent of The We write this (J+1 . the level of unobserved product quality. be the mean valuation by buyers for product j. Thus, r\^ 5^ (1994), decomposing Vy into Our treatment follows Berry vector, * J,+l are independent across buyers ri^ if products j and k share depends on parameters p and the product as F(ti; X, p). demand system. Thus, {p, a, p} is the vector Since the work of Quandt to valuation, here x], is choice model, there is (1956), we have known that the distribution a key determinant of the shape of demand. in fact a precise relationship buyer level and the pattern of cross-product between the elasticities at the of the random shocks In the context of our discrete distribution of r| aggregate market at the individual level. The modeler picks a family of distributions F(r|; X, p). Particular values of the parameter vector p correspond across products sharing common to patterns of dependence Our model contains a parameter pp, for example, which permits dependence across the idiosyncratic in r] For certain values of shocks to Frontier products. product if k » (T]ij 0) is also likely to strongly prefer and j share Frontier Now product j a rate a) and in the distribution other Frontier products. competition will in r| [tii^ | riy of particular product some portion of those consumers whom had of r|, a relatively high share More generally, positive » »0] 0] the value of chosen j are Because of the of these second-best alternatives dependence in the distribution of r| among The parameters p measure across products with similar products characteristics become more "segmented," j: initially their second-best alternatives. products makes those products closer substitutes.'* As dependence Frontier products (E in the price induced to switch to what had been previously dependence all buyer strongly preferring any Frontier status.) consider the impact of an increase falls (at pp, a (or similar) product characteristics. will be similar that dependence. becomes stronger, the sense that the impact of competitive events (such in as a price decrease or entry) will be confined mostly to those products with similar characteristics. In other words, in this fi^amework a model of which classes of products are close substitutes model of dependence among the elements oft) related to product is a characteristics. A PRINCIPLES OF DIFFERENTIATION GEV MODEL OF PC DEMAND B. Of course, may be '* a separate question exists as to how to identify those product characteristics which important for understanding diflferentiation and market segmentation. Fortunately, economic This type of dependence across observations can be contrasted with the case where across choices (as in the multinomial logit). introduction of a new product will Under the assumption of independence, the effect on all products in have the same (proportional) market, regardless of characteristics. This implication of the iid assumption of the "Red Bus/Blue Bus" problem emphasized by McFadden (1973). 12 is t^ is iid the just a restatement theory, in conjunction with an understanding of the particular market under study, provides considerable guidance. (such as the Like many other consumer products, there exists several features of the amount of RAM or the away price of the hard drive) for which there In the presence for that feature (or component). arbitrage size exists a separate PC market of competitive component markets, buyers will premiums associated with the incorporation of these components into particular products. In other words, to the extent that consumers can "repackage" products along a specific dimension, each consumer will equate their marginal utility for this dimension to sales market. Accordingly, there will be no ex-post heterogeneity valuations for this dimension. Thus, in choosing X, p), one should incorporate how to price in the post- among consumers in their marginal parameterize the distribution function among products which share potential correlation its characteristics F(r|; which are not "repackageable." Guided by repackageable this mle, ~ Branded cannot be marketed technical expertise in we focus on two product characteristics which the post-sales market. was required As to incorporate the 80386 microprocessor memory of McFadden (1978), which model. PC. In options (e.g., we McFadden contrast, RAM and (MHZ). need to parameterize F(r|; p) can be incorporated symmetrically into the distribution function. To do (NML) into a the presence of non-mutually exclusive product groupings computationally straightforward specification, 1 under study, considerable well, during the period and, to a lesser extent, the speed of their microprocessor To accommodate argue are not and Frontier. The existence of a Brand name reputation, by construction, buyers could entertain several post-sales options to reconfigure their DISK) we states a significant generalization so, we (i.e., PDs) so that several rely PDs upon Theorem of the nested multinomial introduces the Generalized Extreme Value in a logit (GEV) model through a constructive proof demonstrating that a wide variety of dependencies (and thus patterns of substitution) are consistent with random utility maximization: 13 Proposition 1 (Adapted from Theorem rJ+1 R -. > is a non-negative, I, McFadden (1978)): If G: homogeneous of degree one function satisfying certain restrictions," then „-n,j^ -nio F(Tiio.-->nn) = exp-G(e "'"......e is (3) the cumulative distribution function of a multivariate extreme value distribution, and e*' ore*" G(e e*'^ »,.... e is the corresponding equation determining the market share of product j, where Gj McFadden (1978) purpose specification is the partial derivative of j with respect to suggests that Proposition tool: 1 cross-product substitution matrix. model which incorporates In order to make Our model can serve as a straightforward and general 1 provides a method for parameterizing the will utilize this theorem to parameterize a random /Jow-we5/ec/ cross-product correlations in t].^" more understandable, consider the logic of the theorem associated with a traditional specification, the one-level among products according e*^. by specifying the function G(-), the modeler chooses the pattern of dependency of r|yS across products. Thus, Proposition utility '•') NML. To to whether or not the product is at the G(.) function incorporate potential correlation the technological frontier (F versus NF), the flmction G(-) takes the form. " The limit must alternate of G(-) as any argument goes to in sign and first partials «> must be equal to +~. Mixed partials of G(-) must be non-negative (McFadden, 1978). Most previous research has implemented some version of the NML (a special case of the structure in Theorem 1). We are aware of only one other empirical study (Small, 1987) which utilizes McFadden (1978) to parameterize a non-nested structure. ^° 14 «\ G(o') Pf = «j/pF Pf (5) IjeF VjeNF ; where the parameter pp parameterizes the degree of substitutability among products with the same Frontier status (F or NF) relative to the substitution consistent with (1), the distributional parameter pp dependence across products which share F or to 1, (5) simplifies to the element oft] is G function (at least) we two becomes stronger. As pp goes to 0, the Conversely, as pp goes (i.e., are interested in parameterizing the potential correlation distinct functions, as follows: ( = the unit interval. associated with a simple multinomial logit model dimensions (F/NF and B/NB). most straightforward way, we compose G(-) G(e») status lie in To be products.^* each independent).^ In our application, products along NF must among non-matching ap s)*^ to be the weighted To accommodate sum of two one-level among this in the NML G(-) contributes to a term which measures (F or NF) and in a term which measures (B or NB). Note that model is its if pp = substitution with products its the model 1 is which share technological status which share marketing status substitution with products a nested logit by Branded status only, and if pg = the 1 nested by Frontier status only. The implications of (6) for substitution in the market can be seen more clearly in terms of the market share equation for each product. Letting B(j) and F(j) denote the groups to which product j belongs, — gVPp E ^F S^/pp ,.VPb -^-— E Pf . a3 e-^^^^ «i/Pb gVPB \h VkeBO) (7) keF(j) ^ keB(i) J Notice that which is changes G{^') this share equation is composed of two proportional to the one-level in the prices NML. a relatively strong impact on the market share of product share just one PD for B, the numerator of Consider a product located or attributes of products located also in the neither in B(j) nor in F(j) will F and one terms, one for j, same in {B(j), F(j)}; then, (B(j), F(j)} will cluster whereas changes in products which are have a lesser impact. Clearly, the impact of changes with product j will be somewhere in have in between. Each of these effects products that is stronger as the relevant p goes to zero. While our proposed model, of (6), is quite simple. Proposition different clustering structures, including a larger interactions between them, differentiation simply requires etc. number of Incorporating additional adding suitable terms to 1 (6).^'* can accommodate a wide range "principles of differentiation," dimensions of potential product In this sense, the McFadden Theorem provides a useful and underutilized modeling tool with potentially wide applicability. We have estimated several variant models (only a subset of which are presented in the Results Section). We have experimented wath additional clustering by MHZ (as in Small ,1987), ^* an "IBM" cluster, as well as others. 16 THE PD GEV VERSUS ALTERNATIVE MODELS OF SUBSTITUTION C. Given our goal to measure the degree of segmentation afforded by (B/NB and F/NF), which make the most several issues arise (at least) two PD's distinct traditional (and computationally straightforward) parameterizations of the joint distribution oft] inappropriate for our problem. First, because we want to distinguish between several different sources of product differentiation, we cannot employ a simple unidimensional vertical product differentiation (VPD) specification (Bresnahan, 1981, 1987; Berry, Camall and distributional quality. As parameter measures variation well, a nested multinomial logit Spiller, 1996; Stavins, 1996), in which a single among consumers (NML) model in their preferences for overall product (Trajtenberg, 1990; Goldberg, 1995; Stem, 1996), in which several mutually exclusive dimensions of product differentiation can be incorporated, is also inappropriate. For example, if we were to top level of the nesting determined by the potential correlation in r| B/NB specify (1) to be a two-level nested logit with the be assuming away among (and the resulting implications for market-level substitution) products which share Frontier status but do not match along the VPD and NML we would distinction (Figure 1), B/NB models can parameterize our principal hypotheses dimension. Thus, neither the ~ the separate existence directly of segmentation along two overiapping dimensions (F/NF and B/NB). In order to assess the relative merits to the two-level NML (see Figure 1). richly parameterized than a two-level the PD GEV accommodates It is of the PD GEV, it is worth comparing in important to note that our proposed model (6) NML. Instead, the difference substitution in a way that we substitutes to each other than to other products, the models more is argue is more appropriate B is that for our and F status are closer differ in their treatment the partially matching products (note that the groups in the detail no more between the two models application. In particular, while in both models products sharing both among it PD GEV of substitution are not mutually exclusive). Consider the two-level Pf determines this sense, the how much NML is NML (with B on top) in the upper panel of Figure "closer" products sharing both B 1: the parameter and F are than those sharing only B. In parameterizing segmentation along more than one dimension. However, lowering the price of a {B, F} product has the same effect on market shares in the partially matching 17 as in the completely unmatching {NB, F} category permits only one of the two partially {NB, NF} category." In this sense, the NML Moreover, reversing matching clusters to be close substitutes. the order of nesting just reverses the problem.^* These properties can be stated also in terms of cross-elasticities, where e^y the average is cross-price elasticity of a product in cluster y with respect to a change in the price of a product in cluster X." According to the two-level nested ^bf.bf ^ NML with B/NB on top (as in Figure 1), ^bnf,bf ^ ^nbf,bf " ^nbnf,bf (8) ^nbf.bf ^ ^bnf.bf ^ ^nbnf.bf (9) Reversing the order of nesting renders, ^bf.bf Having between to choose equalities seems likely to ^ and (9) (8) is an uncomfortable specification choice. Neither of the hold in the present context, since this case, as many others, is not naturally nested. The PD GEV overcomes this limitation by permitting both a parallel fashion (see the second panel in Figure ^' principles As we have of differentiation, is As all " For of dependence among this exercise, it is in ^^^ ^nbf.bf picture, it in < (^^) ^bnCbf a completely symmetric way. also has the Of same impact on the possible to add a further parameter, say p,., and a PC's versus the outside good. well, a four cluster one-level possibility drawn the not fiindamental as third level nest that has ' and F, are thus treated written the model and outside good. This ^* B of "local" to work 1), i.e., ^bCbf ^ V^nbtbP ^bnf.bF " ^nbntbf The two definitions assume NML (F/B, F/NB, NF/B, NF/NB) also excludes the partially all matching products. products have equal market shares and prices. The elasticities vary with price and market share monotonically. This assumption just simplifies the exposition. 18 course, this specification related products to the nested logit, it is still be better substitutes. only is no more for our specific application closely richly parameterized than which is to identify the impact PDs. V. IMPLEMENTING THE PD GEV MODEL A. THE ECONOMETRIC PROCEDURE We two parameters permitting more Thus, while the model more appropriate is arising fi-om separate restrictive, as there are outline here the procedure by which the parameters of the PD GEV model can be consistently estimated fi"om a product-level dataset such as the one described in Section in. Essentially, we follow the suggestion of Berry (1994) and construct a of expectations of the of unobserved product level instruments (discussed below). express the J it products can be written on the exogenous quality, ^, conditional In order to implement this procedure as a fiinction of data and parameters to be estimated. demand system. Recall GMM estimator fi^om the set we need to isolate ^ and We are able to do so by above that the market share of product fi^om eq. (7) j "inverting" market with in a as. gVPr Sj=7;7-i^ '' G(e«) [V "^ Y, e*'"^ UfO) ^^ j U^) ("> I keB(j) keFO") Notice that every element of e*^*^ 6, the (J+1) vector of average product quality, enters the market share equation of each product. Thus, with a complete cross-section of products, the market share equations form a system of J equations with (J+1) for the implicit function 6(s, p). Setting s We use this functional unknowns (the vector 6). 6„ the mean value of the outside good, equal to = s(6(s, p),p) relationship to estimate the parameter vector {a use our assumption that 6j is We invert this system also the average level 19 0, we solve (12) &, p} We now of utility associated with product j, b. Rearranging (13) in terms of E„ = X;^ ^ap. and substituting . ^ in 6(s, p), (13) we can define the sample version of the disturbance for our estimator as, 6/s,p) - (X/p . ap.) = I. (14) Since E(^)=0, and under the assumption that Z, the matrix of instruments, standard GMM estimator is is exogenous, then the defined as, L - 5(ZQ 'Z% (15) p.a,P Q where is the standard weighting matrix. Thus, the estimation techniques, and is of the model requires only standard computationally straightforward.^* INSTRUMENTS B. The GMM estimator in (15) requires an instrumental variables (IV) vector, Z, with rank at least as large as the dimensionality vector is composed of the current application it is derivatives of the disturbance (E,) (p, a, p}. PD GEV As suggested above (and in Of course, the efiBcient FV with respect to the parameters. In the quite difficult to construct the optimal Z, so for the construction of Z for ^* of the parameter vector, we propose a simpler strategy models. BLP (1995)), a two-step procedure is appropriate. First, 6 is solved for as a fijnction of the observed market shares and a "guess" for p (Eq. (12)). This procedure involves a well-behaved numerical nonlinear procedure. With 6(s, p) in hand, the remaining (mean-value) parameters (a,P) can be estimated with a linear instrumental variables estimator. Because the market share function can be expressed in closed form (see (11)), there no need for integration of the market share fiinction comes relative to the simulated at a substantial implemented available in BLP computation savings on each iteration (1995). Additional information (including by public access ftp archive. 20 is of the estimation. This method of moments estimator GAUSS estimation programs) are Our strategy relies In the spirit of the recent literature, characteristics, X. functions of X which make plausible instruments. Xj, the This section on the econometric exogeneity of the ^' we entire matrix of product use a model of supply to point out A row of our proposed Z(X) consists of observed product characteristics of product j counts and means of X for products sharing a cluster with product counts and means of X for products sold by the firm oflfering product counts and means of X for products sharing both cluster and seller. first visits the general econometrics issues briefly. j j We then explain how our IV strategy follows fi-om an assumption of equilibrium pricing behavior by sellers in an industry with PD GEV demand. We face diflScult to justify two challenges an assumption that price is product quality, meaning that a higher E(P^)>0.'*' Similar arguments ^j, so that the difficult, first mean independent of ^; framework last is E, term side, it is has the interpretation of unobserved should lead suppliers to set a higher E„ that the prices term as well as the the econometric With market power on the supply constructing Z. in p. As a result, and share of other products are correlated v^th in the RHS of (14) calls for FV. To make this more inherently nonlinear.'' In the face of such nonlinearity (and without additional assumptions), the efficient FV vector will contain elements which are themselves functions of the parameters to be estimated, leading to substantial computational difiBculties (Chamberiain, 1987). In response to the difficulties, observed product characteristics ^' their in we year propose to t, is utilize exogenous. our assumption that X, the matrix of The immediate implication of this of BLP (1995), who impose some of the economic restrictions of model on Z(X). Unlike BLP, we offer no proof that our Z is the first under term in a series Our approach is most like approximation to the optimal FV. '" CT This problem was emphasized by Trajtenberg (1989, 1990), who found that the demand scanners was estimated to he positively sloped in the context of an exogenous the culprit for the positive bias. ''_i dp = NML model with prices. Further analysis revealed that omitted quality, correlated Our solution follows Berry (1994). —dp L^EZ isahighly nonlinear function of p. 21 for with price, was indeed assumption that is we are able to include Xj we are looking for easy-to-calculate variables which are likely to In general, coeflBcients is ^^'^^ ) ( supply." but are independent of highlight this source of a multiproduct firm selling several products, ^. A natural source of instruments, suppose of a non-cooperative Bertrand-Nash to the solution j To price-setting which we *" variable PD-specific indices to reflect the which group that firms game. Consider the G shifts the RHS is will in substitutes a particular group increases, the will shift in is exogenous for each product. for observation j j (in and become flatter in (16). First, we Table in we on a group-specific demand curve Both basis. associated effects should impact number of products in exploit our assumption that the group-specific entry 5, we implement which includes the number of products sums over this idea in F(j) by calculating an instrument vector and B(j), the groups to which product the characteristics of other products in F(j) and B(j). also calculate "Ownership" instruments (labelled so in Table 5) which exploit the economics of multiproduct pricing as reflected in the RHS of (16). For example, as a particular firm '^ In our base model, which has two distributional parameters, each row of Z must have minimum of (K+3) elements (where K is the number of observed product characteristics). " specify an econometric sense) to create a "local" index of the number of substitutes As shown belongs, as well as We for product be correlated with the impact of the segmentation parameters, a and p, on prices and the implicit fianction 6(s,p). Essentially, process FOC (16) the observed price and the product's within-group market share. Thus, the each group behave according Q a candidate instalment.'* number and strength of close For example, as the number of products in that of instruments for demand represent by the set 0(j) (for ownership). 1 with each product be correlated with c(q^.w.)^.E(p,-c,)-^^ Pj = Any exogenous number of ^^ excluded instruments needed to dim{a,p}. price and/or directly in Z. This immediately reduces the This approach was (1981, 1987), in critical to which model the identification of the (simpler) a demand models of Bresnahan simplicity allowed for the analytical solution of equilibrium prices and market shares. ^* As in many other industries, it is diflBcult to obtain observable product-specific cost shifters PCS; consequently, we do not attempt identification via that route. However, this strategy can sometimes be used appropriately (Bresnahan and Baker, 1986; Hausman, 1994). for 22 sells a larger share of the number of total products available, it will charge a higher price on each product (as compared to the prices which would be observed under a more unconcentrated market structure). Similarly, the sum of the characteristics positively correlated with price, since that two analytical ownership and of the products of the firm (other than j) would mean higher in the literature because some groups, (BLP differentiation to construct the like Frontier, different instruments than (1995)). In particular, saw much more we error. It is usefiil economic We include while returns, this dummies for both B is entry than others. This entry, which in successful we assume the short panel considered in the to note that our exogeneity assumption at first blush. In particular, its are using our assumption about the excluded IVS. This strategy across groups means that our proposed instruments vary even present application. our immediate by changing competition. The different rates of entry to be exogenous, shifts prices and market shares determined by these cluster. group structure of product seems we blend Finally, be arguments and use the characteristics and count of products which share both By using PD-specific instruments, we use somewhat predecessors % in eq.(16).'' will we believe that may not be as strong as entry into specific clusters is it endogenously does not mean that our instruments are correlated v^th the and F in observable product quality; which means that E, is merely the deviation of the products' quality fi^om the cluster means. been predicated on the assumption that firms engage Finally, the discussion so far has Bertrand competition. However, if firms play a different type of non-cooperative game in (e.g. Coumot), then the precise form of (16) would change, but our instruments would be unaffected, since the logic of ownership-based and group-based instruments remains the same. Outright collusion though would make a More difference, since generally, the point is ownership-based instruments would be longer be relevant. that the instruments should reflect the underlying supply conditions that prevail in the market, that is, the type of price setting behavior of firms, and the nature of the heterogeneity of consumers as manifested in the groups. For the case at hand, firms used individualistic pricing strategies; the pace of technical change in intensity ^^ we closely follow BLP (1995). 23 we assume that PCS and the ensuing we will explore the of competition seems to have prevented price collusion. However, In this argument and demand importance of this assumption by removing the ownership-based and PD-based instruments from Z the course of evaluating the robustness of our results. in RESULTS VI. We turn now to the presentation and analysis of results from the estimation of the PD GEV for a variety of specifications. We also PD GEV. models and contrast them with the model, we present estimates of alternative Two-Level NML and VPD After exploring the robustness and limitations of the meaning of the estimates by drawing hypothetical demand functions for illustrate the Branded and Frontier PCS and perform a highlight the high degree set of counterfactuals involving hypothetical entry to of market segmentation that these estimates imply. PRINCIPAL FINDINGS A. We first preview our main findings (drawn from Model 1 in Table 6) in a concise fashion to help frame the discussion of the results: < (i) (Pp smaller than B , «1. Both of the Pb) 1), substitution parameters are estimated to be small (significantly suggesting that there is indeed a high degree of market segmentation along both the and F dimensions: Non-Branded products are poor substitutes for Branded products and Non-Frontier products are poor substitutes for Frontier products. The parameter pg quite precisely in most specifications, while the estimate of Pp is much is estimated less precise. Nevertheless, the estimates for both distributional parameters are quite stable across specifications. (//) The product differentiation advantages frontier is limited to the insulation it of B and F are provides from NF different. The advantage of being competition (pF«l). Perhaps surprisingly, incorporating Frontier technology did not necessarily shift the product is small, usually negative, out the product demand curve out (Pfrontier and always imprecisely estimated). In contrast, having a brand name demand curve (Pbrand ^ competition (pg < at the 0) a«^ provides B products with some 1). 24 shifts protection from NB (/77) As expected, the price coefiScient, a, is sensitive to whether or not the model accounts for price endogeneity, and to the type of instruments used. Models that ignore the correlation of price with unobserved quality exploit the full set (iv) result in smaller (in absolute value) estimates of a; models which much of proposed instruments severely reduce the precision of The choice of model that are highly sensitive to the order PD GEV model, of nesting. In substitution parameters are reversed in the a vis the one with the F/NF nest on top. Thus, the alternative, at least in those cases the Two-Level particular, the relative sizes Two-Level this estimate. be important for analyzing the market under specification turns out indeed to study. In fact, the leading alternative to the NML, yields estimates and significance of the NML model with the B/NB nest on top, vis PD GEV model offers an attractive methodological where the nesting order is not well defined a priori. MAIN SPECIFICATION, ROBUSTNESS AND IDENTIFICATION B. We which present in Table 6 our base specification (Model we vary the elements of two 1), X (the set of product characteristics), alternative specifications in and a fourth one where an additional PD. The parameters estimated are the distributional coefficients pp and coeflBcient, a various Ps , a sub-set of DISK, (a constant, RAM, In fact, even though pp and/or Pp = 1 • The is and coefficients for and MHZ), as well as p^Hz As previewed above, 1 Models positive, 1 and and FRONTIER, BRANDED, IBM, and for Model 4. all these specifications. estimated very imprecisely, one can easily reject the hypotheses that pg Models significant while the in fact negative in three add a price i" results for the price coefficient, 2, nil in we Pb, the estimates of pp and Pe are quite small in negative and quite stable across specifications; however, in do not 3 and its are encouraging: level out of four specifications). The estimated to be BRANDED bit (fair coefficient is large, cannot be distinguished fi-om zero (and is IBM coefficient is positive and gives (at the 50% incremental boost to IBM products above and beyond other Branded products. Finally, our technological control variables (DISK, 25 it is of significance varies quite a four models, the 4). In all FRONTIER coefficient point estimate in the base specification) a a, = RAM, and MHZ) have the expected sign, though only the It and coefficient significant (in is Model 1).^* should be noted that the coefficients that determine the level and slope associated with which are of particular F, DISK interest here, are relatively stable across the four specifications. Moreover, the point estimates suggest differentiation B that there was a F versus B advantage afforded along the the qualitative difference in the product dimension. In fact, we are able to reject the hypothesis: Pf= Ho: at the at the 95% level), fi^om having a brand F parameter (p^o^z ^ coeflBcients name, being in at the Frontier -99).^^ little we compare of the Two-Level 5, substitutability reject advantages arising we include a MHZ substitution evidence that there existed segmentation along the MHZ ~ !)• The most is on top. PD GEV troubling feature of Models 5 and 6 In particular, with of products across branches PD that governs the split PC is NF p at that level, B/NB on top, at pg is the « Pf, a given level of the tree and hence a high degree of between branches. According to branded or not (pg However, Model 6 implies the opposite, confers insulation from competition from with those from two alternative Recall that a small the crucial distinction resides in whether a precisely estimated). cannot and F NML model. market segmentation according to the Model we B the estimates from the while the reverse occurs when F/NF poor (e.g., high proved to be beneficial more in the sense of insulating high sensitivity ofthe estimates to the order of nesting. signifies ~ 4.61). While the In contrast to the substantial segmentation found along both the dimension (we cannot reject H^. p^nz specifications 2) relative to the is that, pushing out the demand cune. In Model 4 dimensions, there seems to be In Table 7, 5.22, X^o.so, do not allow us to draw firm conclusions a cautious interpretation of this result from competition than '^ Pb 90% level in our main specification (Wald test statistic = standard errors of the Ho Pf= Pb> that is, is both very small and that having Frontier status products, whereas Branded status does not provide We tried also combinations of these attributes, but the extremely high collinearity between them, as well as between them on the one hand and PRICE and FRONTIER on the other, rendered highly imprecise estimates. " Recall that specifying this model to (6), each of which is is easy. All that is required is the addition of several terms a summation over sets of products which share a similar 26 MHZ rating. additional protection. Obviously, there models, contradictory as they are, the PD GEV is no way of telling within this the "right" one. In contrast to these is context which of the two awkward modeling choices, confronts the issue of relative importance directly by treating the two principles of differentiation symmetrically. we In Table 8 vary the instrument set in order to examine the robustness of our findings to Model 7 alternative identification assumptions. dependence on unobserved absolute value), providing quality. The Model exogenous, ignoring their presumed result is that the price coeflBcient shrinks dramatically (in weak evidence that the overidentifying restrictions). In treats prices as we eliminate the 8, we cannot reject endogenous (though prices are indeed ownership-based instruments, that is, those that stem from the optimizing behavior of multi product firms. Similarly, Model 9 removes PD-based instruments, that those associated with the variance in competition across groups. Each is, of these exercises dramatically reduces the measured precision of the important parameters of the model. The implication is quite clear: to identify our model, on a behavioral assumption about supply and a of these assumptions are necessary We ran several which appeared in other structural we constructed instruments that relied one about the market. As no GEV specifications, accounting for serial correlation (across much specification in that these data by Model suggests 1 we can which can Pm)-^* While there reject the qualitative results described above, the inclusion tell (at least of most estimates, implying to accommodate for finer distinctions: the basic is that A look is only Tables 2 and 4 anew and overwhelming in the (B, NF) cluster. By contrast, (clone) product sold less than 5,000 units/year. Thus, finer distinctions '* at fact that IBM accounted for 60% of the market (about per year), and the bulk of those sales were out to the stark contrast between that there of through these models). In other words, the results implied cannot be made more precise by additional modeling. why we cannot hope would have products both years), arbitrary heteroskedasticity, and additional potential substitution additional parameters drastically reduces the precision so turns out, both order for us to provide evidence for our main findings. in patterns (e.g., the inclusion of four separate substitution parameters, Pe, Pnb, Pf^ exists it 1 any model million unit sales the average between non-IBM NB/NF PCS lose IBM and the rest of the pack. These sections are not reported in tables but are available directory has been set up for public access. 27 from the authors. An ftp archive C. A GLIMPSE AT DEMAND CURVES FOR BRANDED AND FRONTIER PRODUCTS We noted above that the estimates of Pbranded 's positive, PiBM 'S also positive, and that PpRomTER we as to the meaning of these results, demand construct hypothetical hypothetical 1987 demand 's and highly significant, that negative and insignificant. In order to gain fiirther intuition moment take for a the point estimates at face IBM, Non-Frontier PC, curves, one associated with a typical One point on each demand curve value and Figure 2 displays two of PCS. fiinctions for different types with a typical Non-Branded, Frontier PC. large, is the other the actual average price and quantities for these two typical products. The other marked point on the demand curve for the IBM/NF PC corresponds to the price at which the mean buyer's valuation of an just equal that of a "clone" product, that calculate the price that renders 6^8, f ~ is, the price at which very early stage in the difiusion Likewise, 6nb,nf- it clear that the main advantage of Frontier status, of the 386, seems to have been a steep demand curve rather than a large one (recall the argument in section 2 about the type of users that chose 386-based back then). The converse was true for IBM/Branded demand characterizing sellers' behavior, these we ^nb.nf- The demand curves thus constructed make at that 6^^^^ = IBM/NF PC would While status. distinctions we PCS have not estimated equations would explain why IBM chose to take the bulk of its product differentiation advantage as higher quantities rather than as higher prices (recall IBM the negative coefficient on manufacturers of Frontier PCS took the large demand curve and in the reverse course. the steep one, were both at 2)), whereas the pioneer The two mechanisms of appropriability, work in the industry, but within dififerent the PDs. COUNTERFACTUALS D. In order to shed further light counterfactual exercises. In each and, using the estimates from would the hedonic pricing equation (Table induce. same The main goal cluster, vis we Model is to 1, on the meaning of our introduce a hypothetical compute the changes compare the a vis the impact on sales effects and present in Table 9 four new product into a particular cluster in sales in other clusters. pg. 28 of other products that such entry of entry on sales of competing brands within degree of insulation from competition enjoyed by products substitution parameters p^ we findings, We can thus provide a sense of the in different clusters, as captured by the we In each case, introduce a hypothetical product with a value of 6 mean value attractiveness) set equal to the means fixed (which in particular that recompute the implied maricet shares for all expected of all other products for that cluster.'' Holding the 6s we do its (i.e. not allow for any pricing responses to this entry), products, including the outside good. We then calculate the difference in sales for each product before and after the hypothetical introduction. Finally, over the sales in which an average F/B product of this hypothetical from within the F/B had not purchased segmentation PC would total is introduced (with 6 851 1 units, PCS statistic The remainder comes from before. and its the outside good, that In the last part of the table, 9(E), (linearized) standard error. is is, predicts that "market-stealing" drawing 1700 from individuals who simple market-stealing the percentage change in is of the entry experiment. This negative larger (in absolute value) as the entrant product's. This positive statistics The model we show a The numerator segmentation becomes more important. The denominator These -5.2). of which 5270 (61%) unit sales of existing products within the cluster as a result number becomes = cluster. Market-stealing across clusters is significantly smaller, additional units (20%). PC we sum products in each cluster to evaluate the competitive effect of entry across clusters. Consider all Table 9 (A), all we is becomes more important and as the percentage change in unit sales of number increases with the importance of the product introduced. confirm the importance of intracluster market stealing implied by the high level of measured segmentation. While the overwhelming product comes from /«/racluster the estimation. a vis F/B) partially is The is trivial first result is (16 examining the /'n/ercluster effects highlights the results on the completely non-matching which matches along the 303 units stolen from the F/NB cluster B in in the among the dimension (NF/B, which loses 1350 units versus cluster) the effect in terms of percentages which matches along the F dimension (F/NB, which For example, vis terms of unit quantities loses over 1 is much NB/NF 1988 category, \y^= -5.44, cluster in 1988. 29 larger for the percent of its unit sales, whereas NF/B's 1350 units represent just one tenth of one percent of total units '' of (NF/NB Intercluster market-stealing occurs almost exclusively matching clusters (NF/B and F/NfB). Moreover, while the effect larger for the cluster cluster effects, that the effect units). most of the market share of the hypothetical new result is that sold). the average level of 8 in that A similar story (a large /w/racluster effect, and /w/ercluster effects confined to partially matching clusters) is hypothetical low-end clone the For example, a told in each of the other hypothetical presented in Table 9. (NF/NB) sells Branded group (the B/F and B/NF over 2,500 clusters); units, of which only 3 1 are market-stealing from an additional 75 are drawn from the F/NB cluster. According to our counterfactuals and contrary to some widely held perceptions of this industry, these clones posed little CONCLUDING REMARKS Vn. For the economy; fly in competitive threat to Branded and Frontier competitors. last at the 1 same 5 years, the time, is it PC industry has been one of the one of the most competitive. Such conjunction of forces seems to the face of the intuition suggested by Arrow about the necessity of monopoly power to induce, and -ndeed pay for, costly and risky innovation. where quality-adjusted ever lower and new prices most innovative sectors of the fall at Where do rents come from in in order a world a rate of 25% per year, low-cost imitators keep driving prices distribution channels eradicate the advantages of existing brand Motivated by a desire to identify the market origins of innovative rents, this capital? paper develops a simple discrete choice model that uses just aggregate data and can easily incorporate prior knowledge of the structure of the industry. We propose the Principles of Differentiation drawing primarily from McFadden (1978) and Berry (1994). multinomial logit models, ours is of substitution to conform to a In applying the market exhibited two not hierarchical; therefore, specific order it Compared of of what follows differentiation, according to relies heavily cross-elasticities of nesting. regarded as having a brand name, and to whether or not the product Much to Multi-Level nested does not constrain the model to the case of PCS during 1987 and 1988, principles GEV, on the above we begin by noting that the whether or not the firm could be was at the technological frontier. testable hypothesis: the model is structured accordingly (there are two key substitution parameters associated with these PDs); an important subset of the instruments used are predicated on the assumption that these slicing the fiirther demand PDs are a good way of market so as to capture the different degrees of competition faced by products computations using the estimates are designed so as to compare fiinctions facing products in different clusters, 30 in salient properties them; of the and to gauge inter-cluster market-stealing effects. The hypothesized PDs even if the market as a whole insulation from competition frontier can generate rents also oflFer a suitable is highly competitive, market segmentation in certain clusters. more mundane market was by no means an clusters. demand These may provide (temporary) Developing a brand name and/or innovating B or F products can have either large demand curves or be poor all encompassing phenomenon, but that name conferred a whereas being early on results refer just to it was large advantage in the sense of shifting out the at the technological frontier did not. 1987 and 1988 and, given the rapid pace of change of the PC in the industry, sector before and after. Yet interpret the evolution one inference stands out as eminently plausible: contrary to widely-held perceptions, the IBM as the paramount leader in this industry seems to have been caused demise of not by relentless competitive pressures from clones, but rather by the erosion of IBM's quasi-monopoly stand within is in some own specific, cases also positioning themselves at the frontier. two-way grouping postulated here an appropriate representation of the PC market is just a starting point for at the time. Other industries, what we believe and perhaps even the sector itself at a different time, would require different ways of structuring and grouping the PC competing products and firms. Indeed, all, its by Compaq, then by other entrepreneurial firms that invested heavily on developing a brand name, and The PC largely localized within one should be wary of using them to cluster, first at the competitors. Indeed, our findings indicate that competition in the Further, having a brand function, raised above: by increasing buyers' willingness to pay; depending on the strength and the heterogeneity of this increase, substitutes for framework to address the puzzles consist just of an amorphous it seems that product differentiated markets very collection they appear to be structured according to a a corresponding way menu of strategies opened of n different products produced by few principles to firms. m of differentiation, which rarely, if at firms. Rather, relate in turn to A systematic study of those principles, of the they differ across markets, and of their dynamics seems to be a promising and exciting line of research in empirical Industrial Organization. 31 BIBLIOGRAPHY Arrow, K. (1962). "Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention." The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, ed. R. Nelson, Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton (NT), pp. 609-625. Bemdt, E. and Z. Griliches (1993). "Price Indexes for Microcomputers: Price Measurements and Their Uses, ed. Murray Foss, et Chicago An Exploratory Study," University of Chicago Press, al, (IL), pp. 63-93. Berry, S. (1994). "Estimating Discrete-Choice Models of Product Differentiation," RAND Journal of Economics, 25(2): 242-262. Berry, S., M. Camall and P. Spiller (1995), "Airline Hubs: Cost and Demand," mimeo, Yale University. Berry, S., J. Levinsohn, and A. Pakes (1995). "Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium," Econometrica, 63(4): 841-90. Bresnahan, T. (1981). "Departures from Marginal-Cost Pricing in the American Automobile Industry: Estimates for 1977- \91%,'' Journal of Econometrics," 17: 201-227. Bresnahan, T. (1987). "Competition and Collusion in the American Automobile Industry: The 1955 Price V^dLT," Journal of Industrial Economics, 35 Bresnahan, T. and Baker (1988). "Estimating the Residual Demand Curve Facing a Single J. (4): International Journal of Industrial Organization, Cardell, N.S. (1991). "Variance 6: 457-82. Components Structures Washington State University Working Paper. Chamberlain, G. Restrictions," Journal "Buyer's Guide: "Asymptotic Efficiency in Extreme Value and Logistic for the Distributions," (1987). firm," 283-300. Estimation with Conditional Moment of Econometrics, pp. 305-334. Microcomputer Hardware," ComputerWorld, September 26, 1984. COMTEC Wave 6, COMTEC Market Analysis Sen/ices, "Complete Computer Product Book," DataSources, (1986; 1987). GML Microcomputer Guide, GML Corporation, Goldberg, P. (1995). "Imperfect Competition Lexington (MA), various years. in International Automobile Industry," £co/iomemcfl, 63(4): 891-951. 32 Markets: the case of the US Hausman, J. (1996). "Valuation of New Goods Under Perfect and Imperfect Competition," The Economics of New Goods, ed. T. Bresnahan and R.J. Gordon, University of Chicago Press, Chicago (IL). ' Hendel, I. (1994). "Estimating Computerization Returns," Multiple-Discrete NBER Technical Choice Models: An Application To Working Paper #168, Cambridge (MA). Henderson, R. and K. Clark (1990). "Architectural Innovation: The Reconfiguration of Existing Product Technologies and the Failure of Established Firms," Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1): 9-30. Jenkins, A. (1987). "In the Market for Micros," Computerworld, 2(32A): Kolodzicj, S. (1988). "The Levin, R., et al (1987). 23-24. Growth of PC Clones," Computerworld, 20(45A): 35-36. "Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and Development," Brookings papers on Economic Activity, pp. 783-831. Lua, K.T. (1989). "Relative Performance Measurement of 80386, 80286 and 8088 Personal Computers," Microprocessing & Microprogramming. 2(2): 85-95. McFadden, D. (1973). "Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behaviour," Frontiers in Econometrics, ed. P. Zarembka, Academic Press, New York (NY). McFadden, D. (1978). "Modelling the Choice of Residential Lxxation," in Spatial Interaction Theory and Planning Models, ed. A. Karlqvist, et al., North-Holland Publishing, Amsterdam (NE). McFadden, D. (1981). "Econometric Models of Probabilistic Choice," Structural Analysis of Discrete Data with Econometric Applications, ed. C. Manski and D. McFadden, MIT Press, Cambridge (MA). PC Tech Journal, various issues. "Annual Hardware Review," PC World, June 1984. O'Malley, C. (1988). "Winning the Battle of Systems Overkill," Personal Computing, 12(12): 99-106. Quando, R. (1956). "A Probabilistic Theory of Consumer Behavior," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70: 507-36. Ryan, A. (1987). "Buyers Skirt Clone Service Woes," Computerworld, 21(50): 35, 41. 33 Small, K. (1987). "A Discrete Choice Model for Ordered Alternatives," Econometrica, 55(2): 409-424. Stavins, J. (1995). "Estimating Demand Elasticities in a Differentiated Product Industry: The Personal Computer Market," mimeo. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston (MA). Steffens, J. (1994). NewGames: Strategic Competition in the PC Revolution. Pergamon Press, Oxford (GB). Stem, S. (1996). "Product Demand in Pharmaceutical Markets," mimeo, Teece, D. (1988). "Technological Change and the Nature of the Firm," Economic Theory, Trajtenberg, M. ed. G. (1990). Dosi et al, Pinter Publishers, MIT Sloan School. Technical Change Economic Analysis of Product Innovation, Harvard University Cambridge (MA). 34 and New York (NY). Press, Appendix A Dataset Methodology and Sources PC DATASET CONSTRUCTION METHODOLOGY We arrived at the sample of make/models used in the analysis by a process of elimination I. First, we restricted ourselves to products sold by the top 25 eliminated makes for which the number of units sold was less and 1), than 300 (approximately equivalent to sales of $1,000,000). This eliminates a substantial number according to the following criteria. vendors of PCs (see Table of very small IBM clones, but each of these small vendors accounted for a very small fraction of the business market at the time. In fact, over 90% of the 1988 were marketed by the top 25 vendors. Secondly, on Intel number of PCs sold in microprocessors (the laPX 80x86 family), including "close" variation from The etc. total principal alternative microprocessor (Motorola's 68000 family) computers marketed primarily by Apple.' These computers were only Intel-based machines at this time.^ Finally, we 1987 and we constrained the sample to PCs based AMD, NEC, was incorporated into distant substitutes to we could eliminated makes/models for which not obtain reliable data on prices and/or characteristics. DATA ON PRICES AND CHARACTERISTICS n. Unfortunately there is no which provides consistent and of marketed PCs. Thus, we had to single data source reliable rely on a of sources, and invested a great deal of effort in trying to establish consistency and comparability. The primary data source for this purpose was the GML Microcomputer Guide, a quarterly publication which provides list prices and technical characteristics of all PC's marketed. The GML data was complemented and confirmed with an extensive set of additional primary and secondary data sources. These included 1987 and 1988 back issue catalogues and company histories (provided directly by vendors) and a number of contemporary surveys in ComputerWorld, Data Sources, PC World, and PC Technical Journal. Finally, a complementary dataset with prices and characteristics of marketed PCs was graciously provided by Zvi Griliches information about the price and characteristics variety and Ernie Bemdt (see Bemdt and Griliches (1993)). In order to be included complete and matched or in able set of prices and characteristics needed to be in the sample, a identified in the two or more of the additional sources. For many, if not most, of the to identify at least two mutually consistent sources.' GML data observations, we were There were also a small number of PCs (mostly concentrated at the very low or very high end of the quality dimension) which were based on other microprocessors (HP workstations. Commodore PETs, etc.). We excluded them as well from the sample. ' ^ Graphics and marketing people tended to purchase Apple technology, whereas accounting, manufacturing, and sales management tended to buy Apple as an additional Branded firm in the qualitative difference to the estimates. context of the ' year. IBM. We experimented with including context of nested logit models, but this made little However, we have not conducted such experiments in the PD GEV model. For a small number of observations, we observed sales in both years but price in only one When this occurred, we imposed a price depreciation rate of 10% between the two years. 35 APPENDIX B VARIABLE DEFINITIONS QUANTITY Number of PC j QUAN^, COMTEC MARKET SIZEj Total Sold in Year t as Estimated by Market Analysis Services Number of Non-Proprietary Workers; Includes Workers Business Office Who Choose Not to Purchase MARKET SHAREj , Market Share of Product j in Year t QUAN / 39,000,000 CHARACTERISTICS FRONTIER^, Dummy Equal to 1 if Product j Incorporates 80386 1 if Product j Microprocessor BRANDED:, Dummy Equal AT&T, HP, PRICEjj or to is Marketed by IBM, Compaq List Price of Product j in Microcomputer Guide or Year in t as Reported in Two or More GML Additional Sources RAMj, Standard Year MHZ:, t, Random Access Memory (RAM) for Product Kilobytes (KB) Standard Microprocessor Speed Provided, in Year Product j; DISK,, j; in Provided, in in t, MHZ Standard Size of Hard Disk Provided, in Year Product j; in Megabytes (MB) 36 t, for for nCUREl Nested Multinomial Logit and PD GEV Buy? F|B B,F B,NF NB,F NB,NF None none NB,F B,F F <cr^ Pf j|F/NF;B/NB ^ //V B,NF 37 /V NB,NF TABLE 1 SUMMARY OF TOP 25 VENDORS FUUVf TABLE 2 SUMMARY STATISTICS BY YEAR TABLES HEDONIC PRICING EQUATION 1987 & 1988 PC MARKET (Standard Errors DEPENDENT VAR = PRICE in Parentheses) TABLE 4 SUMMARY STATISTICS BY CLUSTER BY YEAR YEAR =1987 Table 5 Definitions of Instruments (Used In Model (1))* Principles of Differentiation F(j,t) = 52 (other products sold in year 1 that share F or NF Disk^ 5] B(j,t) s (other 1 products sold E year in t that share Disk,^ Branded^ B or NB 51 status with product j} Frontier^ B(j,t) B(j.t) BG.t) status with product j} FO.t) FG.t) FO.t) 52 52 t Ownership 0(j,t) = (other E ocj.t) 1 products sold E oG.t) in year t Disk, by seller of product j} TABLE 6 PD GEV MODEL 1987 & 1988 PC MARKET 1 TABLE 7 PD GEV VERSUS TWO-LEVEL NML MODELS 1987 & 1988 PC MARKET TABLES PD GEV MODEL ALTERNATIVE TREATMENTS OF THE INSTRUMENTS VECTOR 1987 & 1988 PC MARKET PARAMETERS Table 9 (A, B) Etemand Impact of Entry of One Additional F/B Product Affected Category Change in Unit Sales Percent Change This Product +8569 Other F/B Products All All NF/B Products -5390 -1350 -.0265 -.0012 F/NB AU NF/NB Products Products -303 -16 -.0107 -.000041 Outside Good -1512 -.000041 One Additional NF/NB Product Outside good -806.00 -.0000022 All NF/B All F/B Products Products -26 -5 -.000024 All F/NB Other Products NF/NB Products -1590 -75 -.0000026 -.0027 This Product +2502 47 Table 9 (C, D) Demand Impact of Entry of One Additional F/NB Product Affected Category Change in Unit Sales Percent Change Outside good -463 -.0000124 All F/B Products Other All NF/B Products -196 -14 -.0010 -.0000124 F/NB Products All NF/NB Products -51 -854 -.00182 -.0022 This Product +1578 One Additional NF/B Product This Product + 7940 All All Outside F/B Products Other NF/B Products -207 -5212 -.0010 -.0047 F/NB Products All NF/NB Products -2 -29 -.000067 -.000 Good -2490 -.000067 48 Table 9 (E) Market-Stealing Segmentation AQfH ^tb 'Cb Product Introduced in / AQ,PC fpc oo fr •) v> -> :> 007 Date Due Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 01428 2054 MHaMBMMMiaHiil