HD28 .M414 ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT ECONOMETRIC EVALUATION OF ASSET PRICING MODELS by Lars Peter Hansen John Heaton Erzo Luttmer WP# 3606-93 August 1993 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 ECONOMETRIC EVALUATION OF ASSET PRICING MODELS by Lars Peter Hansen John Heaton Erzo Luttmer WP# 3606-93 August 1993 M.I.T. OCT LIBRARIES 1 1993 RECEIVED Econometric Evaluation of Asset Pricing Models August 1993 Lars Peter Hansen University of Chicago, NBER and NORC John Heaton and NBER M.I. I. Erzo Luttmer Northwestern University We thank Craig Burnside, Bo Honore, Andrew Lo, Marc Roston, Whitney Newey, Jose Scheinkman, Jean-Luc Vila, Jiang Wang, Amir Yaron and especially Ravi Jagannathan for helpful comments and discussions. We also received valuable remarks from seminar participants at the 1992 meetings of the Society of Economic Dynamics and Control, the 1992 NBER Summer Institute and at Cornell, Duke, L.S.E. and Waterloo Universities. Finally, we gratefully acknowledge the financial assistance of the International Financial Services Research Center at M.I.T. (Heaton) and the National Science Foundation (Hansen) and the Sloan Foundation (Luttmer). Abstract In this paper we provide econometric tools for the evaluation of intertemporal asset pricing models using specification-error and volatility bounds. We formulate analog estimators of these bounds, consistency and derive analysis the limiting distribution of incorporates market frictions proportional transactions costs. use the methods to assess such as give conditions for these short-sale estimators. The constraints and Among several applications we show how to specific asset pricing models nonparametric characterizations of asset pricing anomalies. and to provide Introduction I. Frictionless market models of asset pricing imply that asset prices can be represented example, given stochastic a constant a portfolio. discount factor Capital Asset Pricing Model the in by by the In plus a scale (CAPM) multiple Consumption-Based CAPM pricing or the (CCAPM) the For discount factor return the of kernel. on the discount is market factor is given by the intertemporal marginal rate of substitution of an investor. r is the net return on an asset and m is the marginal If rate of substitution, then the CCAPM implies that: (l.n = 1 £[m(l+r)|^] where ? is the information set of the investor today. is the stochastic discount factor, p, tomorrow is given by: = n(p) (1.2) £(mp|^) today's price, More generally, nip), if m of an asset payoff, . Thus a stochastic discount factor m "discounts" payoffs in each state of the world and, as a consequence, adjusts the price according to the riskiness of From the vantage point of an empirical analysis, we envision the the payoff. stochastic discount factor the as vehicle linking the stochastic a theoretical model to observable implications. Given implications a particular of (1.2) expectations, yielding model can be for assessed by first discount taking factor, the unconditional = Enip) (1.3) Eimp). When m is observable (at least up to a finite-dimensional parameter vector) by the econometrician, test of a can be performed using a time series (1.2) of a vector of portfolio payoffs and prices by examining whether the sample analogs of the left and right sides of (1.2) are significantly different from Examples of this type of procedure can be found in Hansen and each other. Singleton (1982), Brown and Gibbons (1985), MacKinlay and Richardson (1991) and Epstein and Zin (1991). While tests such as these can be informative, Further, interpret the resulting statistical rejections. directly when applicable are there (1.2) frictions to these tests are not such as transactions For example, when an asset cannot be sold costs or short-sale constraints. short, market is often difficult it is replaced with the pricing inequality: (1.4) 7t(p) Finally, these 2: E{mp\9) can tests . not used be when the discount candidate factor depends on variables unavailable to the econometrician. As an alternative consider a different specification-error volatility to bounds bounds of testing directly pricing errors using set of Hansen of Hansen tests and and and diagnostics Jagannathan Jagannathan (1991). using (1993), We (1.3), also and we the the consider extensions of these tests and diagnostics, developed by He and Modest (1992) and Luttmer (1993), that handle and other market frictions. transactions costs, short-sale restrictions We develop an econometric methodology to provide consistent estimators of the specification-error and volatility bounds. Further, we develop asymptotic distribution theory that is easy to implement and that can be used to make statistical inferences about pricing The specification-error and models and asset market data using the bounds. along with the econometric methodology volatility bounds, asset that we develop, can be applied to address several related issues. The specification-error bounds of Hansen and Jagannathan can be (1993) used to examine a discount factor proxy that does not necessarily correctly price the assets under consideration (see also Bansal, 1992 for an application). of Hsieh and Viswanathan This is important since formal statistical tests many particular models of asset pricing imply that the hypothesis their pricing errors are zero is a very low probability event. models are typically very simple, it is that Since these perhaps not surprising that they do not completely capture the complexity of pricing in financial markets. The specification-error bounds give measures of the maximum pricing error made by This provides a way to assess the usefulness of a the discount factor proxy. model even when it is technically misspecif led. Further, this tool can easily accommodate market frictions such as transactions costs and short-sale constraints. Given a vector of asset payoffs and prices, uniquely determine work. m. Instead there is a (1.3) typically does not whole family of m' s that will Any parametric model for m imposes additional restrictions on that family, often sufficient to identify a unique stochastic discount factor. Rather than imposing these extra restrictions, Hansen and Jagannathan (1991) showed how asset market data on payoffs and prices can be used to construct feasible factors. sets for means and standard deviations of stochastic discount The boundary points of these regions provide lower bounds on the volatility (standard deviation) and Luttmer (IS indexed by the mean. He and Modest (1992) showed how to extend this analysis to the case where some 3) of the assets are subject to transactions costs or short-sales constraints. of means and standard deviations of Ue sets These fea- the stochastic discount factor can be used to isolate those aspects of the asset market data informative about the stochastic discount factor. that are most One way to do this is to ask whether the volatility bound becomes significantly sharper market data is added as more asset stochastic without analysis security market data in an limit to generally, More factors. discount having This would help one the analysis. importance of additional assess the incremental econometric to a priori is it the valuable family of have to a characterization of the sense in which an asset market data set is puzzling without having to take a precise stand on the underlying valuation model. When testing a particular model of asset pricing in which the candidate m is specified, feasible region. it is valuable sufficiently Moreover, when diagnosing the failures of a specific model, to determine whether volatile distribution of to examine whether the candidate is in the is often useful it wh or payoffs asset \er and candidate the the other is it candidate discount factor aspects of discount the factor is not Joint that are problematic. As we remarked previously, direct observations of it may still sometimes it is not possible to construct making pricing-error tests infeasible. m, However, be possible to calculate the moments of a stochastic discount factor implied bounds. For by a example model in which Heaton can then (1993) a be compared to the volatility consumption-based CAPM model is examined in which the cous-umption lata is time averaged and preferences are such that a simple linearization of the utility function can not be done to consistency result uninterested in estimators for consistency the arbitrage the of who but results, calculations necessary for conducting statistical Sections III. A., In Section are bounds. Those interested inference, the in need only read III.C and III.D before moving to Section IV. IV we present applications and extensions of our several results each of which can be read independently after reading Sections III. A, III.C and III.D. entire feasible In Section we discuss the sense in which the IV. A and standard discount factor can be estimated. Section means of set II, deviations IV. for B provides the stochastic discussion of a tests of whether the volatility bound becomes sharper with additional asset Section market data. models of the discount specification-error shows how to use the volatility bounds to test IV. C Finally factor. bound to case a in where Section there we IV. D extend parameters are discount factor proxy that are unknown and must be estimated. of the the Section V contains some concluding remarks. II. General Model and Bounds Our starting point is a model a stochastic discount market pricing short-sale factor subject to constraints short-sale constraint for is or in which asset prices are represented by pricing kernel. transactions costs, subset the a of an extreme version of a To we accommodate permit security there securities. to Although transactions cost, be a other proportional transactions costs such as bid-ask spreads can also be handled with this formalism. This is done as in Foley (1970), Jouni and Kallal (1992) and Luttmer (1993) by constructing two payoffs according to whether a security is purchased or sold. A short-sale constraint is imposed on both artificial securities to enforce the distinction between a buy and a sell, and a bid-ask spread is modeled by making the purchase price higher than the sale price. Suppose the vector of security market payoffs used in an econometric analysis is denoted x with a corresponding price vector The vector of q. X is used to generate a collection of payoffs formed using portfolio weights in a closed convex cone C of P (2.1) = {p : IR : p = a' X for some a e C>. incorporate all of the short-sale constraints The cone C is constructed to If there are no price imposed in the econometric investigation. two components: = x' More generally, then C is r". induced by market frictions, [x"',x°'] where contains x" prices are not distorted by market frictions and x subject to short-sale constraints. partition x into components contains the I whose components Then the cone C is formed by taking the and the nonnegative orthant of R Cartesian product of R k the distortions . Let q denote the random vector of prices corresponding to the vector x of These prices are observed by investors at securities payoffs. assets reflect are traded and conditioning are permitted to be information available random to the because investors. the the time prices Since it may is difficult to model empirically this conditioning information, we instead work with the average or expected price vector Eq. While information may be lost in our conditioning information of investors, failure to model explicitly the some conditioning information can be incorporated in the following familiar ad hoc manner. security payoffs used in an Suppose some of the econometric analysis are one-period stock or bond-market returns with prices equal to one by construction. Additional synthet ic payoffs can be formed by an econometrician by taking one of original returns, say x the and multiplying it by a random variable, , information conditioning set economic of constructed payoff is then x z with a price of synthetic payoff is random even though constant. is subject x If to a agents. the the say z, in corresponding The Hence the price of the z. security price of original short-sale constraint, is then z should be nonnegative. The vehicle linking payoffs to average prices is a stochastic discount To represent formally this link and provide a characterization of a factor. stochastic discount factor, we introduce the dual of This dual consists of all vectors in More generally, zero vector. described previously, if the elements of C . whose dot product with every element For instance, when C is all of R of C is nonnegative. the IR which we denote C C, x • n , C consists only of can be partitioned the in are of the form {0,^')' manner where g is nonnegative. A stochastic discount factor m is a random variable that satisfies the pricing relation: Eq (2.2) - Emx e C . To interpret this relation, there are no market relation element, (2.2) is first consider the case in which C is r". frictions and we have the familiar namely the zero vector. partitioned into the two linear pricing. pricing equality because C In has this only Then case one Consider next the case in which x can be components comparably, and relation (2.2) becomes: described previously. Partition q Eflix" = Eq^ - Emx^ a £q" - (2.3) 0. The inequality restriction emerges because pricing the vector of payoffs x^ subject to short-sale constraints must allow for the possibility that these constraints bind and hence contribute positively to the market price vector. I I. Maintained Assumptions A: There are three restrictions on the vector of payoffs and prices that The first is a moment restriction, are central to our analysis. the second is equivalent to the absence of arbitrage on the space of portfolio payoffs, and the third eliminates redundancy in the securities. For pricing relation (2.2) to have content, we maintain: 2 Assumption 2.1: E\x\ Assumption 2.2: There exists an m < a, E\q\ < oo. > satisfying (2.2) such that Em 2 < oo. The positivity component of Assumption 2.2 can often be derived from the Principle of No-Arbitrage (e.g., Kallal 1992 and Luttmer 1993). the smallest identically (2.2), (2.4) a see Kreps 1981, Prisman 1986, Jouni and The Principle of No-Arbitrage specifies that associated with any payoff cost equal zero to must be strictly that positive. stochastic discount factor m satisfies: a' Eimx) s a' Eq for any a e C, is nonnegative and not Notice that from which Assumption that shows implies 2.2 Principle the of No-Arbitrage (applied to expected prices). Next we limit the construction of x by ruling out redundancies in the securities: • • If a'x = a 'x and Assumption 2.3: a = a In Eq = a • ' Eq for some a and a in C, then precludes the . absence the possibility transaction of that the there would exist a second moment nontrivial nontrivial this linear costs, Assumption matrix of x is In light of combination would (2.2), have 2.3 singular. combination of linear that is zero with probability one. of oc' Otherwise, the payoff vector x the (expected) price be to zero, violating To accommodate securities whose purchase price differs from Assumption 2.3. the sale price, we permit the second moment matrix of the composite vector x to be used weights prices. 2.3 Assumption singular. to construct then same the requires payoff distinct that must have portfolio distinct expected analysis. Let 1 Minimum Distance Problems II. B: There denote the are set two of problems all that random underlie most variables with of our finite second moments M that satisfy (2.2), and let M* be the set of all nonnegative random variables in M. both sets are nonempty. Let y denote some variable for a stochastic discount factor that, strictly speaking, In light of Assumption 2.2, "proxy" does not satisfy relations (2.2). Following Hansen and Jagannathan (1993), 10 consider we following the two hoc ad squares least measures of misspecif ication: 8^ (2.5) min £[(y = - m)^] , meM and 5^ (2.6) minjliy = - m)^] meM When the proxy bounds finding constructed on the Hansen by zero, to second and minimization the moment of Jagannathan In particular, Luttmer (1993). (1991) set is y problems He to factors as discount stochastic (1991), collapse and Modest and (1992) the bounds derived in Hansen and Jagannathan are obtained by setting y to zero and solving (2.5) there are no short-sale constraints imposed (when C is set to and IR ) (2.6) when the bound ; derived in He and Modest is obtained by solving (2.5) for y set to zero; and the bound derived by Luttmer (1993) is obtained by solving (2.6) for y set to These zero. feasible second regions for moment means bounds and moment bound implied by (2.6) it will subsequently be standard deviations. is no smaller than that used Clearly, in the second implied by (2.5) since is obtained using a smaller constraint set. Next consider the case in which the proxy y is not degenerate. and deriving Jagannathan (1993) showed that the least squares distance Hansen between a proxy and the set M of (possibly negative) stochastic discount factors has an alternative norm of payoffs interpretation of being the maximum pricing error per unit '" P, where the norm of a payoff is the square root of its 11 s When the constraint set is shrunk to M second moment. dual the derivative hypothetical abstract from account takes interpretation constraints short-sale potential of Hansen While claims. pricing and their in interpretations are applicable more generally. errors Jagannathan analysis, for (1993) pricing-error 2 Conjugate Maximization Problems II. C: In solving development of convenient most as in problem (2.6), the squares least problems (2.5) and econometric methods associated with to study those in problems, maximization problems. conjugate the and (2.6) our is it They are given by (2.7) 5^ = maxiEy^ aeC S^ = max {Ey^ aeC - Eliy - - x'a.)^] Zol' Eq) , and (2.8) where the notation h by - £[(y - x'a)*^] Eg} The conjugate problems are obtained denotes max{h,0}. introducing Lagrange multipliers - 2a' on the pricing constraints exploiting the familiar saddle point property of the Lagrangian. (2.2) The and a' then have interpretations as the multipliers on the pricing constraints. The conjugate problems in (2.7) and (2.8) are convenient because the choice variables are finite-dimensional vectors whereas the choice variables in the original possibly least squares problems are random variables infinite-dimensional constraint 12 sets. The that reside specifications of in the conjugate problems are justified formally in Hansen and Jagannathan and Luttmer problems maximization the Of particular (1993). interest concave are in to a us is and that that (1993) the criteria for the first-order conditions for the solutions are given by: - Eq (2.9) £[(y - x'a)x] e C* in the case of problem (2.7) and Eq (2.10) - £[(y - x'a)*x] e C* along with the respective complementary slackness conditions (2.11) a'Eq - a'£[(y - x'a) x] = a'Eq - a'£[(y - = 0, and (2.12) In fact, optimization x'a)*xl problem . (2.7) is a standard that associated with a solution to problem (2.7) in M to is a random variable m = {y and associated with a solution to problem (2.8) is a nonnegative random variable m = (y (up programming Interpreting the first-order conditions for these problems, observe problem. - x'a) quadratic the usual - x'a) in M These random variables are the unique . equivalence class of random variables that are equal with probability one) solutions to the original least squares problems. Since Assumption 2.3 eliminates redundant 13 securities and the random variable - (y problem (2.7) x'a) uniquely is criterion must be This unique. also is determined, same for all the uniquely determined, hand, the random variable a because the implying that conjugate to value of they all as the must The solution to conjugate problem (2.8) In this case the truncated random variable may not be unique, however. is follows solutions, have the same expected price a'Eq. x'a) solution the is (y - x'a) (y - the expected price a'Eq. On the other is not necessarily unique, so we can not exploit Assumption 2.3 to verify that the solution a is unique. As we will now demonstrate, the set of solutions is convex and compact. immediately from the concavity of The convexity follows function and solutions the convexity of closed be must constraint the because the Similarly, set. constraint set is criterion the the closed set and of the criterion function is continuous. Boundedness of the set of solutions can be demonstrated by investigating the properties tail directions 9 the of which for criterion 9'x (2.8) and divide it by 1 two cases: probability and To study the former case we take directions 9 for which 9'x is nonnegative. the criterion in consider positive with negative is We functions. + 2 |a| For . large values of |a| the scaled criterion is approximately: - (2.13) Hence |9| payoff in £[(-x'9)*^] where 9 = large values of is approximately one for P. Consequently, Consider next directions . Moreover, 9'x is a Ia|. unsealed criterion will the quadratically for large values a/[l + |a|^]^'^^ decrease (to -co) |a|. 9 for which Assumption 2.2 and relation (2.4) we have that 14 9'x is nonnegative. From (2.14) s £fli(G'x) e'Eq for some m that is strictly positive with probability one. be strictly positive unless G'x is identically zero, it identically zero. Hence e'Eq must when G'x is However, follows from Assumption 2.3 and inequality (2.14) that e'Eq is still strictly positive. we study the For directions 9 for which the payoff e'x is nonnegative, tail behavior of the criterion after dividing by approximately e'Eq for large values of - the unsealed criterion must diminish + 2 1/2 |al ) which yields , Hence in these directions the |a|. (to -m) (1 at least linearly in Thus |a|. we find that the set of solutions to conjugate problem (2.8) in either case, is bounded. For some but not all of the results in the subsequent sections, we will need for there to exist a unique solution to conjugate problem (2.8). the set of solutions To display a is sufficient convex, local uniqueness condition for local Since implies global uniqueness. uniqueness, let x denote the component of the composite payoff vector x for which the pricing relation is satisfied with equality: (2.15) where q = £mx* is the Eq' corresponding price vector. indicator function for the event {fli>0>. Ex x '^i~yn\ is nonsingular. 15 let A sufficient uniqueness is that Assumption 2.4: Also, lf~>Q» be the the condition for local To why see this valid a is sufficient condition, observe complementary slackness condition (2.12), m is given by (y vector - x '3) from the for some Consequently, p. = Eq' (2.16) that £yl^~^Q^ - £(xV' 1^-^^^ )3 When the matrix £(x x '1,~^„.) is nonsingular, we can solve (2.16) for \in>vr S. Volatility Bounds and Restrictions on Meains II. D: The second moment bounds described in the previous subsection can be converted into standard deviation bounds via the formulas: (2.17) 0- = [5^ - (£m)^]^^^ ? = [6^ - (£m)^]^^^ "2 where 5 and ~2 5 constructed are by setting the proxy to When zero. P contains a unit payoff, Em is also equal to the average price of that payoff and hence is unit payoff. available, restricted to be between the sale and purchase prices of However, so that data on the price of a riskless payoff is often not is difficult it the to determine Em. In these circumstances, bounds can be obtained for each choice of Em by adding a unit payoff to P (augmenting x with a £q with v). constraints 1) and assigning a price of v to that payoff (augmenting In forming imposed on the augmented cone, the additional distortions should be introduced. mean assignment for m. there should be no short security and hence no new sale price The price assignment v is equivalent to a Mean-specific volatility bounds can then be obtained 16 (2.8) and using (2.7). (2.17). The Principle of No-Arbitrage puts a limit on the admissible values of v. V e ,v \ where X ] lower arbitrage the is is i; the upper '^ computed using formulas familiar from These bounds are arbitrage bound. bound and derivative claims pricing: (2.18) X s - V = infia'Eq infia'Eq : a e C and a'x i -1> and (2.19) While A not : a. C and a'x i 1> e is always well defined via exist payoff a in P circumstances, we define v (2.18), dominates that to be may not be because there may v unit a payoff. +oo. Econometric Issues III. In this section we develop consistency and asymptotic distribution results for the specification-error bounds presented in Section presumption underlying our analysis is that prices are replicated associated with {(x ',q ',y )'} the over time composite some in vector whose sequence of joint distribution of (x',q',y)'. the data on asset stationary (x',q',y)' empirical is a (Borel measurable! payoffs and a That stochastic is, process approximate the We denote integration with respect to the function moment, we will approximate Ez by is A key II. fashion. distributions empirical distribution for sample size T as Tthat such In Yz of where 17 More precisely, (x',q',y) with a for any z finite first . j;z (3.1) Among other = . (i/T)Z^^iZ, we require things, this approximation becomes that good as the sample size T gets large. That is we presume that {z Law of Large Numbers. A sufficient condition for this is: Assumption composite The 3.1: arbitrarily process iix ' ,q ' ,y )} obeys a } stationary is and ergodic. Under assumption, this we can think (x',q',y) of as {x ' ,q ' ,y ) Assumption 3.1 could be weakened in a variety of ways, but it is maintained for pedagogical process iix to ' ,q simplicity. ' )) ,y is More generally, we might asymptotically stationary, the stationary distribution is sufficiently fast of Large Numbers applies to averages of joint distribution of the process {(.x ' ,q ' ,y ix'.q'.y) is the form imagine that the where the convergence to ensure (3.1). In that the Law this case, the given by the stationary limit point of )} To estimate the specification-error bounds, we suppose that a sample of size T is available and that the empirical distribution implied by this data is used in place of the population distribution. Analogy Principle of Goldberger random functions (3.2) ^(a) = <p and 1968 and Manski 4>' y^ - iy - a'x)^ - 2a'q, and 18 (Thus we are applying the 1988). We introduce two y^ - iy - a.'x)*^ - 2a'q = $(a) (3.3) The sample analog estimators of interest are given by = (d )^ (3.4) max aeC "^ y[<p{a)] and (d )^ [3.5) = max Consistent Estimation of the Specification-Error Bovinds III. A: establish first We sequences id } and {d T Proposition 3.1: The proof of the the consistency statistical 5, {d } and {d this proposition is given in Appendix A. and sample criterion functions The basic for the criterion functions converge pointwise the of the concavity of the criterion functions, uniform on compact sets almost surely (for example, Finally, since the sets of maximizers of 19 the idea conjugate (in a and P) this is By Assumptions surely to the population criterion functions introduced in Section light converge } respectively. problems are concave and the sets of maximizers are convex. 2.1 and 3.1, estimator the >: Under Assumptions 2.1-2.3 and 3.1, population of T almost surely to 5 and that T^4><^oi] almost II. C. convergence In is see Rockafellar 1970). limiting criterion functions ) for sufficiently large T one can find a compact set such that are compact, the maximizers of the sample and population criteria are contained in that compact set the (for 1974 and Haberman see Hildenbrand example, conclusion follows from the uniform convergence of the 1989). Hence criteria on a compact set. Asymptotic Distribution of the Estimators of the Bounds III.B: consider We sequences of the next distribution limiting specification-error bounds. interest objects of the solutions as the to of analog the ability Our to estimator express conjugate problems permits us the to obtain results very similar to those in the literature on using likelihood ratios devices as selection model for possibly misspecified (for example, see Vuong 1989). specification error bounds are positive, when environments in models are We show that when the we obtain a limiting distribution that is equivalent to the one obtained by ignoring parameter estimation, and when bound specification error the zero is the is the corresponding (See Theorem 3.3 of Vuong 1989 page 307 for degenerate. distribution limiting result for likelihood ratios. Let Yi, be a maximizer of a and a a maximizer of a r(/>, E4>. a maximizer of study To the a E<p, limiting a behavior estimators, we use the decompositions: (3.6) VT[(d )^ - 5^] = - iCa)] VTY^liu^) + VlY^l^U) - E^(a)] and (3.7) A((d )^ - 5^] = VTY^[4>U^) - 0(a)] + ^^.[^(a) - £^(a)] 20 maximizer of of the now demonstrate, As we will limiting distributions the for the maximized values depend only on the second terms of these decompositions. words, impact the population unknown the replacing of In maximizers other by the sample maximizers in the sample criterion functions is negligible. ~ Take the case of the sequence {(d) 2 Then by the concavity of >. ^, we have the following gradient inequalities: 5(a (3.8) - 0(a) ) = [ • {a - a) for - a) . (including conditions first-order the conditions) slackness complementary £(mx - q) from follows it - a) (mx - q) - Eimx - q)]-(.a + However, U^T (mx - q) £ T conjugate population the the problem that (3.9) The £(mx - inequality while a is (3.10) Therefore, q)-U in - a) (3.9) = is E[mx - q) -a^ s VTY^[4>U^) - ^(a)] s VTY^Hmx WTT[4>(a ) sample counterparts to - . obtained because £(q constrained to be in - q) ^ mx) is - q]]-{a^ converges - a) the dual C in . probability the pricing errors obey a Central the maximizers can be chosen so in Combining (3.8) and (3.9) we have that C. - E(.mx 0(a)]} - that - {(a T 21 a)} to zero if the Limit Theorem and converges almost surely to ] This zero. concavity convergence latter of demonstrated be criterion population the can . function and by the exploiting convexity the of the constraint set (for example, see the discussion on page 1635 of Haberman 1989 and Appendix A). 0(a) - £<^(a) Assumption 3.2: converges in distribution to a l^'^T[ imx - q) - E(mx - q)] normally distributed random vector with mean zero and covariance matrix (p(a) Assumption 3.3: - E(f>{a) imx - q) - E(mx - q) a normally distributed random vector More converges in distribution to l^'^Y^ [ primitive assumptions that V. with mean zero and covariance matrix imply central the limit V. approximations underlying Assumptions 3.2 and 3.3 are given by Gordin (1969) and Hall and Heyde (1980). Let followed denote u by k a + selection vector a one limiting The zeros. £ with in its first distributions position for the specification-error bound estimators are: Proposition 3.2: 2.3, 3.1 - 3.2, 5*0 Suppose that WTld - converges 5]} vector with mean zero and variance 3.1 and 3.3, {VT[d - and u' to Vu/(Ad) converges 5]> 5*0. a . in Under Assumptions 2.1 - normally distributed Under Assumptions distribution to 2. a 1 random - 2.4, normally distributed random variable with mean zero and variance u'Vu/iiS) To use u'Vu or Proposition 3.2 u'i^'u. Consider the in practice requires consistent estimation of case of 22 u'Vu. For each T form the scalar sequence (a {4> t=l,2,3, ): ... the frequency zero spectral T} and use one c density estimators described by Newey and West (1987) or Andrews (1991), for example. As is shown in Appendix A, when the price vector q is a vector of real the asymptotic distribution for numbers (degenerate random variables), problem fails lack the case, have a unique solution to (Assumption 2.4 identification of of violated). is =pecial case considerable of is conditioning using Section the payoffs synthetic form to rules out it While this possibil: y of described as that y if solutions to degenerate if the (a) valid results or and 5 = ^ (a) the discount both are ^ce are which in = a = a * / {vT(d of the establish that the rate of convergence of {(d) 2 {vT(d parameters ~ 2 can and {(d) > ~ , and } ) T 2 > This case identically zero giving for conver,^ factor problems conjugate distribution on Proposition 3.2 breaks down. 0, stochastic population limiting suDsequent = 5 a is consequence, the 0. As a rise to a 2 ) used be is Our >. id } and {d > converge at the rate VT , although to and is T, T given by a weighted sum of chi-squared distributions (see Vuong 1989). result in II. Notice occurs information interest, In parameter vector a does not the alter the distribution theory for the specification-error bound. As a limiting the distribution is not normal. III.C: In Asymptotic Distribution of the Parameter Estimators several situations conjugate problems of T remains valid even when the population version of the conjugate maximum - 6l> this Wild interest to it is useful to examine :ed in constructing the bounds. the solutions For example, to the it may be examine whether a particular asset or group of assets are 23 important whether in the degenerate. the coefficient vector inference, assets are subject estimation problem is covariance short to posed as matrices in consider interest of which to case the case determine the where constraints. sales bound there other In no words, we unconstrained maximization problem, an is are in the absence of market frictions, for asymptotic the coefficient estimators have a form that (e.g., may limit approximation to do this type of Since, . it zero, is initially we assume that the cone C is R limiting or In developing a central statistical that bound determining is distribution of the the the familiar both from H estimation see Huber 1981) and from GMM estimation (e.g., see Hansen 1982). Our formal derivation of this distribution theory is given in Appendix C and uses a result from Pakes and Pollard A byproduct from our analysis in the (1989). appendix is a (modest) weakening of the assumptions imposed in Hansen (1982) to accommodate kinks in the moment conditions used in estimation. The population moment conditions of interest are: (3.11) for £[x(y-x'a) - q] = 0, the specification-error bound in which the no-arbitrage restriction is not fully exploited, and (3.12) £[x(y-x'a)* - ql = 0, Equalities (3.11) and (3.12) are simply when the no-arbitrage is exploited. the first-order problems when conditions short-sale (2.9) and constraints (2.10) are estimators satisfy: 24 not for the imposed. conjugate The sample maximum analog ' Y^[x(y-x'a^) - q] = (3.13) and (3.14) Lj.[x(y-x'a^)* - q] = . While the equations for a are linear, the latter case, those for a are nonlinear. In we use a linear approximation to the moment conditions in deriving the central limit approximation for the parameters: xiy-x'a)* (3.15) - q « xiy-x'a.)* - q - xx' 1^^_^, -^^^ (a-a) = x(y-x'a)l, ^ aaO} {y-x i~^n\ - <J • Notice that the function of a on the left side of (3.15) except at values of a such that y-x'a = 0. . We assume is dif ferentiable that such sample points are "unusual": Assumption 3.4: Pr{y-x' a = 0> = 0. To evaluate further the quality of the approximation in (3.15), denote the random approximation error: (3.16) It r(a) = l^(y-^' «) ^^y-^' a^O>-^y-x' a^0> follows from the Cauchy-Schwarz Inequality that 25 let r(a) r(a) (3.17) \-^y--' -^ . \ \ ^Uy-x' a.orUy-x'a.O) {y-x aiO> {y-x aiO} £ )\ U|^|a-a| where the second inequality follows because |x'a - x'a| dominates |x(y-x'a)| whenever y-x'a opposite have y-x'a and Therefore, signs. the random approximation error satisfies: r(a)/|a-a| (3.18) \x\^ rs for a * a implying that the modulus of differentiability (3.19) is dmodic) dominated by |x| positive value of when except '^ that |a-a| sup{r(a)/ |a-a| = 2 Combined with Assumption 2.1 this implies that for any £[dmod(E)] c, ,~ „, 1, = {y-x a=0> < for a*a> |a-a|<c, : e and 1, , 1. ,„, {y-x a<0> is this case In = finite. 1 ks c it is so that r(a) = ^ 0, dmodic) possible to choose a such Ixx'l- However Assumption 3.4 implies that this occurs with probability zero so that as c converges almost surely to As zero. is goes to zero shown in ^^ Appendix 0, C, dmodic) these restrictions are sufficient for us to study the asymptotic behavior of the estimator {a (3.20) > using the linearization on the right side of (3.15): £[x(y-x'a)l _^,~^Q^ - q] = 26 0. To use matrix E{xx'l, condition is /''>n\^ this rank *'° equivalent coincide when no system equation linear (3.20) one Assumption in short-sale constraints condition for a moment second the this rank and x must x counterpart The imposed. are the that is because 2.4 need we a, Given Assumption 3.4, ^® nonsingular. to identify to matrix E{xx' to be ) nonsingular as required by Assumption 2.3. with Working the conditions, moment linear two we obtain the approximations: (3.21) ~^'^'^^^^^^"''' ""^^ " •T(a^ - a) « " t^^^^' - a) « -[£(xx' )l"VT^[x(y-x'a) •T(a ^{y-x' aaO ^ ^ - '^^ q] where the notation ~ is used to denote the fact that the differences between the left and right app roximations sides of justified are Combining approximations (3.21) formally (3.21) These converge in probability to zero. in Appendix Let B. w = [0 / n ] with Assumptions 3.2 and 3.3 gives us the asymptotic distribution of the analog estimators. Proposition 3.3: 2.1-2.3, Suppose Assumptions 3.1 and 3.2 are satisfied. Then {v^T(a-a)> converges in distribution to a normally distributed random T vector with mean zero and covariance [£(xx')] matrix: Suppose Assumptions 2.1-2.4, 3.1 and 3.3-3.4 are satisfied. wVw'(E(xx')] Then {v'T(a^-a)} converges in distribution to a normally distributed random vector with mean zero and covariance matrix: To apply these [£(xx' 1 , _^, ~^q^ limiting distributions ) ] wVw' [£(xx' 1^^_^, -^^^ in practice estimators of the asymptotic covariance matrices. 27 ) ] . requires consistent The terms wWw' and wWw' can be estimated using one of assumptions Under £(xx'l, _ /~>oy) the maintained can where the estimator a Proposition 3.3, in estimated be used is spectral methods consistently in place of a referenced previously. matrices the by their E(.xx' sample in estimating ) and analogs, second of the these matrices. We now briefly describe how the distribution theory some short-sale constraints are will focus on the behavior limiting VTia -a) are very similar. imposed (C of in Section As is II, Emx = £q or Emx , < modified when proper subset of r"). VT{a -a), not m prices the payoffs with equality or not, (3.22) a is but results the We for we partition x by whether or that is by whether Eq The component coefficient estimators that multiply x 's for which there is strict inequality will equal zero with arbitrarily high probability as the sample size gets large. Hence the limiting distribution is degenerate for these component estimators. Consider next the estimator of the remaining subvector of denote Because of p. degeneracy just described, the we can, lower-dimensional interior point of C, imitated to estimator. cone associated with estimating p. effect, in treat the limiting distribution of the estimator of p separately. the which we a, If Let C be 3 is an then the argument leading up to Proposition 3.3 can be deduce a However if limiting 3 is at normal the distribution boundary of the for cone C, the the parameter limiting distribution may be a nonlinear function of a normally distributed random vector (see As Haberman 1989, page 1545). 3 in any econometric estimation problem with 28 inequality constraints, the problematic feature of in which limiting distribution theory is the manner iepends on the true parameter vector p including the associated 1 This feature makes the distribution theory harder to use discontinuities. in this practice in and, other has settings, approximate bounds on probabilities led statistics test of researchers Wolak 1991 and Boudoukh, Richardson and Smith 1992). in our derivation of the distribution theory (see, Recall, for to compute for example however, that specification-error the bounds, we were able to circumvent the need for a distribution theory for the parameter estimators. parameter estimators frictions, Thus becomes even more though the complicated distribution the in theory presence for the market of the distribution theory for the specification-error bounds remains simple. III.D: As Consistent Estimation of the Arbitrage Bounds we discussed in Section the II second moments bounds can be converted into standard deviation bounds if the mean of m is known or if it can be estimated using the price of a risk-free asset. it must be prespecif led. free asset is price assignment admissible, it Let v be the hypothesized mean of m when not available. In v. must not the ) risk case bound estimators for each admissible ~2 5 of , for the price induce arbitrage opportunities collection of asset payoffs and prices. interval (A ,u open *^ h Proposition 3.1 can be applied to establish the second moment the consistency of When Em is not known assignment onto the to be augmented Any price (mean) assignment in the is admissible in this sense. The final question we explore in this section is whether the arbitrage bounds, A and v given in (2.18) and (2.19), using the sample analogs: 29 can be consistently estimated (3.23) i^ -infia'Y^q = a € C and : a'x i -1 for all t=1.2 T} and u^ (3.24) s infia'Y^q : a e C and a'x The i 1 for all t=l,2 arbitrage bound u estimated upper always is T> finite when there is a payoff on a limited liability security that is never observed to be zero in the sample. Our estimated range of the admissible values for the (average) price of a unit payoff and hence mean of m is bounds can be computed by solving simple [I ,u ] Notice that these . linear programming problems. In Appendix A we prove: Under Assumptions 2.1-2.3 and 3.1, Proposition 3.4: almost surely. and if u IV. = +oo, If u then {u is } then <u diverges to +oo > } converges converges to v to X almost surely; almost surely. Applications and Extensions In this section we discuss several analysis of Section III. of finite, {i feasible means and applications and extensions of the First we discuss consistent estimation of the set standard deviations of stochastic discount factors. Previously we showed that for a given mean of the stochastic discount factor, the standard deviation bound can be consistently estimated. mean of the stochastic discount factor typically is not known. it is However, the As a result important to understand the sense in which the entire feasible region 30 can be approximated. examine extensions of We next are useful that whether, First we extend given initial an set analysis the portfolio stocks of firms of information about additional and asset to examine asset returns III additional III We call this set of tests region Snow (1991) used this type of test to examine whether returns subset tests. a the bounds Section of returns, asset of result in a change in the volatility bound. on theory of Section answering several questions about in pricing models. distribution the contained stochastic discount volatility of the capitalization small with factors over and above that found in the return on the market portfolio; Cochrane and Hansen used (1992) determine to it conditioning whether information is (1993) used it in his investigation of the links between the important; Knez markets for Treasury bills, certificates of deposit and commercial paper; and De Santis used (1993) vis-a-vis securities volatility bounds. particular A whether a domestic the significance securities the in of returns on construction foreign of the 4 example of region the factor would constant discount consideration. study to it subset test occurs correctly price when checking assets under the This is a test of whether the volatility bounds have content and is an important initial hypothesis to examine since, if true, the bounds do not preclude constant discount factors (risk-neutral pricing). We then show standard-deviations how can be feasible the used to test a regions for the specific model of means the and discount factor. Burnside (1992) and Cecchetti, Lam and Mark (1992) have developed a version of this test when there constraints or transactions costs. in a relatively simple manner by are no assets subject to short-sale We show how this test can be implemented exploiting 31 the results of Section III. Further we formulate the test so that it also applicable when there are is assets subject to short-sale constraints. As a result this provides (large sample) statistical foundation to the tests of asset pricing models suggested by He and Modest outline we Finally analysis that and (1992). Luttmer (1993). extension an the of bound useful when the discount factor proxy under consideration is depends upon a vector of unknown parameters. parameter specification-error vector that minimizes We consider an estimator of the specification-error the bound and briefly describe how to develop an asymptotic distribution for this estimator and for the implied bound. Some of the formal discussion in this section focuses on the case when positivity is imposed the in specification-error bounds. construction volatility and data on the prices of a unit payoff are not used in the econometric analysis. payoff the Moreover, when considering volatility bounds, we study the more usual case in which or with a unit of require the Comparable results without positivity obvious modifications and are sometimes computationally simpler. Consistent Estimation of the Feasible Region of Means and Standard IV. A: Deviations As discussed in Section I and it II, is often of interest to construct approximations to the feasible region of ordered pairs of means and standard deviations of stochastic discount factors Such a region can be computed with or implied by security market data. without imposing the restriction that the stochastic discount factors be positive. the region positivity. without positivity Similarly, let S and S the and the S 32 (closure) denote the of the no-arbitrage Let S denote region with sample counterparts. The results From our in Section know we III and S when there price of the points of origin and S . In the more usual case when data on a unit payoff and its price no instead are unions of rays but represented (possibly extended) as convergence mean) and mean), (hypothetical sample the of real-valued previous our such rays resulting The boundaries of convex sets with nonempty interiors. analysis implies in these sets can be functions functions analog is not The feasible regions are matters are a little more complicated. longer vertical unit a can be estimated consistently by the points of origin and S of the corresponding rays S available, good S is (average) the In this case this payoff is the mean discount factor. of the rays S are that rays because regions are vertical four all sense what in is to and S ? approximations to S payoff, turn now we question of the pointwise to their ordinate the (in population This result implies uniform convergence of the sample analog counterparts. functions in following sense. Since estimated, lower the for and large enough upper T, (A ,u ). functions are finite on any compact subset of functions result (see of Theorem converge uniformly, the 10.8 hypothetical of can be consistently the sample analog functions under positlvity are finite on any compact subset of convex bounds arbitrage R. mean of Rockafellar almost surely, When positivity is ignored the 1970) Further these functions are the discount the sample analog functions on any compact subset of factor. ('^-•^q) As iri case of positivity and on any compact set when positivity is ignored. difficulty is that the approximations deteriorate as the mean assignment, approaches the arbitrage bounds in the large when positivity is ignored. 33 case of positivity, or when a the One v, v gets deterioration The arbitrage finite instead viewing of point in R '^ the analog not be to of the S to T regions as vicinity To of see functions a this, of the approximation error from a set-theoretic vantage an approximation is the in problematic. Consider first the case in which u . size sample of out boundaries the we explore ordinate, turns bound sample the of error as < Associated with a +00. measured by the Hausdorff metric: (4.1) max{7iS*,S*).7iS*.S*)} = T} T T T where: (4.2) y(/C ,K sup = ) {v Since the boundaries of {S compact interval sequence {tj } ordinate. can approach within [v the be )eK consistently lower arbitrage the )| 222 ,v estimated boundary of bound, the S and the uniformly lower on approximation any error converges to zero almost surely. Measuring ordered > )eK bounds arbitrage \{v ,w )-{v ,w inf 111 ,w pairs the approximation get to close In other words, measures of distance, as error without via the restricting Hausdorff them to metric have allows same the we no longer confine our attention to "vertical" is the case when we view the boundaries of the regions as functions of the hypothetical (expected) prices of a unit payoff. The added flexibility in the Hausdorff metric permits us to exploit better the consistent estimation of the upper (Proposition 3.5). 34 and lower arbitrage bounds When V P ^ = ) {v ,w 11 is bound A W 2 ,w 2 )eK 1 finite for )e/C 2 O^v SO ^ 2 any arbitrary positive number greater Then . l(v.w)-(v,v)| inf sup ^ Q*v So ^ 1 where p will (4.1) T (C ,C y defined by t} As a remedy, we replace r by be infinite. (4.3) the approximation error infinite, is than modified approximation error will the sufficiently large will and T converge be arbitrage lower the defined and well surely almost to zero. Thus we still get uniform convergence as long as the ordinate is restricted to a finite interval. Region Subset Tests IV. B: The first set of tests we consider are whether the volatility bounds can be constructed using a smaller vector of subject to uniquely under vector initially consider we II I. C, short-sale the case where and constraints, identified. Let consideration with denote z price including the k-1 an vector payoffs ass bound augmented by a unit payoff. security payoffs. we there assume are that the ) that and let are to Formally, f be be used section in assets no (n-1 -dimensional s, As that are parameters are vector the to the hypothesis of of assets k-dimensional construct the interest can be represented as: (4.4) E[z{.f'9)* - s] £[(f'e) - V One possibility is ] to = 0, = 0. test this hypothesis 35 for a prespecified v , and the other is to test whether it is satisfied for some u Consider first the case in which v the setup of Section payoff with a unit III, and form the is > 0. prespecif ied. To map this into n-dimensional vector x by augmenting z form q by augmenting s with the "price" v Then . hypothesis (4.4) can be interpreted as a zero restriction on the coefficient vector a employed in Sections II and The III. components of coefficient vector a set to zero are just the entries of z that are omitted from A f. large sample Wald test of this zero restriction can be formed by applying the Alternatively, we could construct limiting distribution in Proposition 3.3. a test by solving the GMM optimization problem: ..„ .4.5, where [wWw' ^Tj;[^;f;^j:-j-„„v„-,^i-VTj;flj;^j>j is ) one of the . estimators referenced in Section III. spectral Since this test is embedded within a GMM estimation problem, Section III.C. the analysis in can be easily modified to show that the minimized value of the criterion function is distributed as a chi-square random variable with n degrees of freedom (see Hansen modified to be for some v > 0, When the hypothesis of 1982). interest - k is this GMM approach is modified by minimizing the criterion in (4.5) by choice of 9 and v with a corresponding loss in the degrees of freedom. One special case of this setup is a test for risk-neutral pricing. this case k is one and f contains only a unit payoff. In other words, In a constant discount factor prices the securities correctly on average and the volatility bound is zero. the volatility bound Furthermore, estimator the central (without imposing limit approximations for risk-neutral pricing) degenerate since the second moment of the discount factor is a constant. 36 is For both of these reasons, test for risk-neutral pricing is a useful a starting point in an empirical investigation. Conducting such tests can proceed as described with one modification. sampling error associated with the second moment condition in There is (4.4) implying that wVw' be no imposed = v (6 ) conditions. moment omitted and 9 Instead this second condition should singular. is and testing should be based only on the initial set of When v should not is be known, restricted this second condition should be nonnegative be to when solving minimization problem (4.5). Region subset tests without positivity turn out to be closely connected to factor of tests intersection tests This connection frontier for structure (e.g., follows stochastic see Braun 1992 and Knez from the duality factors discount deviation mean-standard and boundary 1993 for an elaboration). of the mean-standard and the comparable returns (see Hansen and Jagannathan 1991 for an elaboration). deviation frontier Also, for the Wald and GMM test statistics coincide because the moment conditions are linear in the parameter vector 9. The tests using the criterion (4.5) rely upon the distribution theory of the estimator of a. To use the theory of Section II are no securities subject to short-sale constraints. the subsection, presence of the inequality I. C requires that there As we discussed in that restriction on the parameter vector a can complicate the distribution theory of the parameter estimators. As a result, remaining testing zero restrictions on a subvector of a when some of the coefficients problematic. are against On the other hand, a nonnegativity constraint can be the results of Haberman (1989) could be used to develop such a test when the zero restrictions are imposed on at least all of the securities to which the short-sale constraints apply. 37 Testing IV. C: Specific Model a the of Discoiint Factor using Volatility Bounds Suppose that in addition to asset market data, a model the discount of factor is posited and a time series of observations of the discount factor is available: {m One way to T>. t=l : test the model whether it satisfies the volatility bounds discussed in Sections Since observations of the discount factor are available, a unit payoff can be estimated by the mean of augmenting the original vector of m. payoffs with a examine to is and III. II the average price of Specifically, form x by unit form payoff; augmenting the original vector of prices with the random variable we had subject to a results of Section functions (p and II constraint. forming a In III.B with and minor one are now constructed by setting 4> R. In is not can apply the payoff with an average price m an unit short-sale subtracting m (4.6) added test, we by and form m; C by constructing the the Cartesian product of the original cone with effect, q that modification. The the proxy y to random zero and : ^(a) s - 5(a) s - (-a'x)^ - 2a'q - m^ , and (4.7) Subtracting m 2 (-a'x) does not - 2a'g alter population maximization problems. values of the criteria functions. - m . solutions the It does, The 38 to however, either change volatility bounds sample the the for or maximized Em will be satisfied, (4.8) if, and only if max aeC = ^ £^(a) s 0, when positivity is ignored, or (4.9) when s ? max aeC positivity Proposition 3.2 of E<t>{a) s 0, limiting The imposed. is distribution formulated estimation problem the plays role no in so approximation that the in can be applied to construct a test (appropriately modified) these hypotheses using sample analog estimators of have reported limiting E, and ~ 7 Again, ^. error due to distributions for these we parameter sample analogs. In practice we find the solutions for the sample maximization problems, estimate the asymptotic particular, let c Then {^T[c - in and errors, form one-sided tests. In be the maximized value of 7 (0) over the constraint set C. converges in distribution to a normal random variable with £,] mean zero and variance described standard Section hypothesis (4.9), u'l^u. II I. B. This variance can be estimated in the manner Since the "conservative" is | not specified choice of ^ = under the null is used in constructing the test statistic. Finally when there are no transactions costs, short sales-constraints or other constraints estimators can Likelihood Ratio be to be used test) considered, to that construct exploits 39 asymptotic the a different the distribution test, inequality of (analogous restriction the to in a the Considering the case when positivity is first-stage estimation of the bound. imposed, vector parameter the a problem solves that satisfies (4.9) the moment conditions: Elx(x'a)* (4.10) = - q] . The inequality restriction (4.9) implies the further E{[0(a) - |]} = (4.11) moment condition: 0. for some ^ s 0. Without a constraint on the parameter (4.11) exactly identify a and we nonpositive, using can set moment the up GMM criterion a conditions subject to the constraint that ^ £ the boundary of appropriately the feasible scaled and (4.10) GMM and (4.10) the parameter vector and minimize (a,^) function this the population moments of m are on region S minimized in (4.11) If 0. conditions with the restriction that ^ be However, ^. moment £,, (that criterion = when | is, function then 0), has the limiting a distribution that has probability one-half of being zero and the remaining half of probability the is according allocated distribution with one degree of freedom. bounds the hypothesis) distribution for other of negative test values of statistics 0, it one (p (under the positivity null of the random function is used in can be shown that the resulting test statistic coincides with the test statistic based solely on (4.6). Similar When ^. stochastic discount factor is ignored and the place of chi-square a This chi-square distribution then GMM the to approaches to testing a g model 40 of the discount factor can be applied when a instead of series time actual for data. decomposed additively can m case this In be from randomness the simulated of $(a) data can security market payoffs and prices and the other due to the simulation of As in the work of McFadden Duffie and (1991) Pakes and Pollard (1989), (1989), Singleton and be one due to the randomness of the wo components, int constructed asymptotic the (1993), m. Lee and Ingram variance in the limiting distribution will now have an extra component due to the sampling error induced by simulation. When the first moments of m can be two computed numerically with an arbitrarily high degree of accuracy, we can proceed as follows. price vector with Em instead of m and subtract Em of m 2 the as in deviations and (4.7). of the estimated stochastic of from the criteria instead This same strategy can be employed to assess (4.6) accuracy 2 Augment the feasible discount mean-standard deviation pair for m, region for factors. one means any For can compute and standard hypothetical corresponding test the statistic and probability value. Minimizing the Specification-Error Bound for Paurameterized Families of IV. D: Models Recall that the specification-error bounds provide a way to assess the usefulness asset an of misspecif led. In many unknown parameters. pricing model situations For example, the in a even discount when it factor is proxy technically depends on representative consumer model with constant relative risk aversion preferences, the pure rate of time preference and the coefficient of relative risk aversion are typically unknown. way to estimate specification er ;r. case ,;ne the parameters Alternatively, in 41 model of the an observable is to factor In this minimize model, the the discount factor proxy depends on a unknown coefficients. As linear combination of the work of Shanken in (1987) factors with the one could selecting factor coefficients to minimize the specification error. imagine We now sketch how the results of Section III.B extend in a straightforward manner to obtain a distribution theory for the minimized value of specification-error bound. Suppose that the discount factor proxy y depends on the parameter vector P € S where B is a compact The population optimization problems set. of interest are now: (4.12) 5^ - Eiiyifi) max [syO)^ a&C min = fi€B - x'a)^> - Za'Eql, and (4.13) When 5^ = 5 and 5 are discount min an satisfies the extended version of sample analog estimators of 5 and the same as if . strictly positive and the parameterized family of stochastic factors restrictions, max |£y(|3)^ - £{[(yO) - x'a)*]^} - Za'Eql the solutions to 5. the smoothness appropriate Theorem 3.2 can be and obtained moment for the Again the limiting distribution will be population optimization problems were known a priori. The approach can be extended to compare specification-errors for two nonnested families of models. the smallest Such a comparison potentially can be used as a device for selecting between the two families of models. Vuong (1989) examined a very similar 42 problem by using the large behavior sample ratios likelihood of misspecified models (in particular, we and 1989); precisely, let can and 5 5=5 1 parameterized This accounted for. our to specification-error the the smallest problem. bounds More associated can families hypothesis specification-error associated with As a consequence the performance of each parameterized family is the same. two analysis his 2 Under the null hypothesis, the of Take the null hypothesis to be: with two such families. (4.14) denote 5 families see the discussion in Section 5 of Vuong adapt and imitate nonnested two for not can ranked be tested be by sampling once using error is corresponding the distribution theory for the difference between the analog estimators of 5 scaled by the square root of the sample size. and 5 Finally, we sketch the distribution theory for the coefficient estimators when there is a parameterized family of discount factor proxies. Suppose that the unique solution p of (4.13) is contained in the interior of B, the moment parameterization restrictions, family and satisfies short-sale no the constraints population moment conditions are given by: (4.15) E{x[y(.^)-x'a]* - q} = 0; and (4.16) £[^(p){y(p) - [y(p) - a'xl*}1 43 = appropriate 0. are smoothness and imposed. The the analog estimators The distribution theory for {b and } T taking respectively can be deduced by {a approximations linear of > and a 8 T sample the to moment conditions (4.15) and (4.16) and appealing to the results of Appendix C. V. Concluding Remarks In pricing paper this provided we developing these procedures, represent and conjugate the measurements maximization computations procedures and can it was advantageous of This problems. market for duality asset bounds. In due unconstrained to approach simplifies resulting The frictions assessing exploit duality theory to solutions as inferences. statistical account interest for volatility and specification-error using models methods statistical statistical transactions to both costs or short-sale constraints, and are often easier to interpret than standard tests For the most part these methods are quite easy to of asset pricing models. implement, They are designed to even when market frictions are considered. provide a better understanding of the statistical failures of some popular asset pricing models and to offer guidance in improving these models. Among following: other (i) to things, the results in this test whether a specific model paper of allow the one to do stochastic discount factor satisfies the volatility bounds implicit in asset market returns; compare to the information about the means and standard discount factors contained in different sets of asset returns; test hypotheses about asset pricing models. the size of the (ii) deviations and (iii) of to possible pricing errors of misspecified An advantage of (i) is that the resulting test is robust to misspecif ication of the Joint distribution of asset returns and the 44 stochastic discount factor. In regards to (ii), our results permit these comparisons among data sets to be made independent of a specific stochastic discount factor model. Our motivation for (iii) is to shift the focus of statistical analyses of asset pricing models away from whether the models are correctly specified and towards measuring misspecif led. 45 the extent to which they are Appendix Consistency A: this appendix we demonstrate formally the results of Section In denote a compact set in 11 denote the closure of subsets of (A. 1) 11. K denote on K given by - a I, ) = maxi sup a eh inf 112 I a a €h sup construct the of a 2 2 sup Jim inf a eh a eh to define notions of convergence of compact sets. use cHh) we let the collection of all nonempty closed t) ,h Ti(h Let h. For any subset h of U, r". We use the Hausdorff metric ^ will II. A, We maintain Assumptions 2.1-2.3, and 3.1 throughout. and III.D. Let I of - a |> . 11 2 For some of our results we sequence a a I in We K. follow Hildenbrand (1974) and define: Definition A.l: For a sequence {h > in 11, lim sup h Since the sets, it lim sup is is the = J J intersection of a decreasing n cl m (. u h J^ sequence ) . J of closed An alternative way to characterize the lim closed and not empty. sup is to imagine forming sequences of points by selecting a point from each h . and, All of the in fact, limit points of convergent subsequences are in the Jim sup, all of elements of the lim sup can be represented in this manner. We shall make reference to an implication of a Corollary on page 30 of Hildenbrand (1974) that characterizes the set "approximating" function over an "approximating set." 46 of minimizers of an Suppose Lemma A.l: (i) {^ is > continuous functions mapping a sequence oi converges uniformly to 11 into R that i/» and {h (ii) converges to h ) J Then lim si. and lim min h where c g i = v^ min h ' J t// " .^ . {u = e h : i/( (u) ^ (u' i// {\b ) " in conjunction with i/» J in light of (ii), the Al then Proposition Turning 1 follows the {h in > Corollary of page 22 in Hildenbrand. to the result in in light of conjunction with h the (i), defines a continuous function on J " sequence from let ^ and endow } with the Then continuous compact correspondence mapping } into Lemma }, . metric for a one-point compactif ication. sequence h € " denote the set of positive integers augmented by +«, and for all u' To verify that this follows from the Corollary in Hildenbrand, Proof: usual ) x Ii; defines a The conclusion of the Ii. together with part (ii) of Q.E.D. Section III. A, we formally establish Proposition 3.1: Proof of Proposition 3.1: We treat only the consistency of {d 47 } because the corresponding argument for {d very is } surely to E^(a) converges almost concave as is Assumptions similar. uniformly on any compact set in R i |a| : implies that = {a e C =N}. \a\ : Then C and D we have . be the maximized value of E0 over D 5 < Since 5. in D the By convexity of sufficiently large C. T, concavity of 7 C and arbitrage E4> on C turn to results the bounds X in v id to 5 } III.D that and {t compact explore "directions set for to the choice these in these study investigate {u arbitrage the variables We infinity." follows from the and ) the for } bounds the are Since there is no representable as solutions to linear programming problems. natural for Q-E.D. • Section Recall . that coincide with those over analog estimators sample and almost are also not follows it ^, the maximizers of T ^ over C consistency of statistical to the maximizers of V.^ over C almost sure uniform convergence of {7 ^^ °^ ^ now Then by choice of N . N the almost sure convergence of Consequently, We contains all of the "T for sufficiently large T, . By N converges uniformly {T ^^ N surely, are compact. over the constraint set C and that none of the maximizers E4> Let 5 that = {a e C N choosing N to be sufficiently large we can ensure that C are in D is the set II, define C N N maximizers of 7 ^ T, {7^} converges Further as argued in Section . iY4>(.<x.)} N and D N> that Since for each For a positive number N, is bounded. E4> imply 3.1 each aeC. for Theorem 10.8 of Rockafellar E4>, of maximizers of and 2.1 problems, we "directions" must using a compactif ication of the parameter space. First consider any a € C such that a'x £ -1 with probability one. with probability one a'x > -1 converges almost surely to a'Eq. f s a'y g, it follows that for all Define liin sup 48 t with probability one and ~ - £ f £ ( X and X with = -X Then {a'T g> . probability Since one. Similarly, I T if u and lim inf u < lim sup a oo, ^ v Hence our interest is in the lim . i nf . T To construct a compact parameter space, we map the original which we denote as space for each problem into the closed unit ball in R We consider explicitly the case of u The proofs . completely analogous to the case for u parameter for the case of i \L. are and are omitted. can be represented as Notice that the constraint set used in defining v the set of all a e C satisfying the equation: E((l - a'x) (A. 2) = ] . Consider now a transformation of the parameter space by mapping the parameter The mapping space into the unit ball. = (x/(l + |a|) maps r" To compactify the transformed parameter space, unit ball. the C, points boundary of the unit Notice ball. that into the open we consider adding we can recover the original parameterization by considering the inverse mapping: a (A. 3) C/(l - = K|) Using the transformation in for 1^1 a' s that satisfy (A. 2) we consider: (A. 4) This < 1. D s { ^ e transformation Vf^ I £{[(1 - Kl) potentially boundary of the unit ball. adds (A. 3), - instead of considering those = x'C]*> solutions to > (A. 2) by including the The potentially problematic values of ^ are those 49 for which x' and <€C s 0, C, I (^ = I 1 We rule this out by limiting attention . to values of ^ in D H (A. 5) < e line { Notice that any effect in D for which C, focusing by C'£q s (I-ICDCUq+D I on satisfies 1 we D in ^' s * Kl > eliminating are concerned with estimated upper arbitrage bounds Also, any ^ in D for which Suppose that u First Proof: notice < to are that too low, not too must have an (average) price that . We first : T Yq since that D r\ T Then iim sup D oo. converges almost sure to 7)(D ,D) T corresponding be the sample analog of D. and D be the sample analog of D A. 2: =1 \C,\ consider the limiting ^ behavior of D Lemma <' s In This eliminates the troublesome points (directions) from D is nonpositive. Let D Eq/[l-\<;\) s (u +1). This does not cause us problems because we are payoffs with "high" prices. high. C.' r\ converges D to D c Eq r\ almost D. surely, We next establish that Iim D 0. = D then . To T converges uniformly to This is sufficient for the Uniform Law of Large Numbers of Hansen (1982) to do we this £[(1 - ICI ) first - x'C]* - (A. 6) £J|[(1 show on that Note that IZ. KJ) - V [(1 - x'Cj* - 1^1) li Hence from Lemma A.l, the x'<]* n C is compact and that: [(1 - ^ (1 . apply. - KJ) - ^'<2^*l} (£|x|^)^^^)K^- C3I Iim sup of the sequence of minimizers of 50 y - [(1 - £[(1 Kl) - x' C,]* - x' C,]* ICI) over U n C Since v . of minimizers of £[(1 - < - |<|) for all Tsl. must also be in D C,] in the set Lemma = D Since D is separable, The conclusion follows. . T Suppose that u '^^ A. 3: < co. minimizers of is the set With probability one, any point in . Then lim inf u t? a common probability DSD measure one set of sample points can be selected so that As a result lim D of is not empty and D the set D m, x' contained is for all Tsi. Q.E.D. TO 2 u . First note that Proof: (A. 7) u = mini C'L.q/(l-lCl) V = mini C'Eq/(l-|Cl)| C e D* a D I } for sufficiently large T, and C, € D* r\ D } Hypothetical expansions of the constraint set D in smaller values constraint set Lemma A. 2 to D r\ D. of the maximized Proof: A. 4: n D For for u can only result instance, augmented to include all of the points in D is suppose r\ the Then D. implies that this sequence of augmented constraint sets converges The conclusion then follows from Lemma A.l. Finally, we consider the case in Lemma criterion. . Suppose that v Since u = oo, = a. li Then {u = Q.E.D. oo. > diverges with probability one. there are no values of a € C such that a'x s 51 1 with Consequently, probability one. 1^1 = the only values of convergence of J^[(l - sufficiently large - Kl) = D T, x'<]* to £[(1 = and u there are no arbitrage opportunities such that D 0. > ll^'xll ^'£g Furthermore, D is closed implying that infiCEq s : for > < e D*} > any (^ , it follows from Lemma A. x'^]* implies that for C,' Eq C'IL<7 with the fact > c/2 for all that all diverges almost surely. 1 in D such that In B: C, e D ll^'xll = 0. converges almost surely to with probability one that for The convergence of {D . sufficiently • } to D • coupled have norm one then implies that elements of D {u > Q.E.D. Taken together. Lemmas Appendix Since 0. for any ^ in > • large T, * . Since {7 q) converges to Eq almost surely and D D - (Assumption 2.2), imply c Kl) The uniform Next suppose that D oo. Assumption 2.3 (A. 8) - = a. Assumption 2.2 together with the no-redundancy Also, that are ones for which First suppose that D We consider two cases. 1. in D C, A. 2, A. 3 and A. 4 imply Proposition 3.4. Asymptotic Distribution of Bounds Estimators this appendix we show that in the case in which the prices of the payoffs are constant, the asymptotic distribution of the estimated bounds can be demonstrated even when the parameter vector (even when Assumption 2.4 is not satisfied). 52 is not uniquely identified Proof of Proposition 3.2: We consider the case of d The case of d . T let be a measurable selection from h a T Since Jim sup h page 54). (1974), {a there is a sequence ^ T result in Theorem 1 A. 1 | T =0 For each of Hildenbrand almost surely and h 00 that all a e h is h (see T Further an implication of Lemma Appendix A). (1991) = be the T such that lim |a -a in h > T Let h be the set of maximizers of £^. set of maximizers of T4> and let h T, similar. is T is compact, almost surely (see of Hansen and Jagannathan the same random variable m = (y-a'x)*. 00 Also (2.12) implies that for a e h 00 a' a ^ Ul is the same for e h <x a' , q = E{y(y-a' x)* - (y-a'x)* }, so that As a result the random variable 0(a) . is the 00 ash same for all . Now consider the decomposition of v^TF [(d ) - 5 ] as in (3.7): •T[(d (B.l) )^ - 5^] = /T^.[0(a^) - ^(a^)] + •JVQ.~4>Coi^'\ - £0(a^)] As in relation (3.10), we have: (B.2) Since |a -a Appendix C: In parameter £ •JVi^\.~^{'k^^ £ /TT [(mx | - 0(a^)] - g) - £(mx - q)\-Ca.^ - a^] converges almost surely to 0, the result follows. Q.E.D. Asymptotic Distribution this appendix estimator. we We consider the asymptotic begin by demonstrating that distribution of restrictions used our in Hansen (1982) can be extended along the lines of Pollard (1985) and Pakes and 53 . in the functions used Pollard (1989) to accommodate "kinks" it is from Then conditions. moment straightforward show to discussion the represent the Section in Proposition 3.3 that to follows . from III.C, the main result in this appendix. The notation used in this appendix conflicts with some of the notation used elsewhere We paper. the in let interest and p any hypothetical point denote 3 in the parameter vector the underlying parameter of space T The parameter space is restricted to satisfy: Assumption C.l: T contains an open ball in R about S We will use the construct of a random function. . A random function i/» maps the set of sample points into the space of vector-valued continuous functions on T . We require that be an n-dimensional random vector for each p in i//0) T We also consider an approximating function = 0!'O) that is linear 3. Assumption C.2: ^,0 + A. (3-3 ) ) The composite random function satisfies: { (i/», ' ,i/'f ' ) ' } is stationary and ergodic and has finite first moments. We now specify the sense in which i/» The approximation error induced by using is r^O) = I0^O) - 0^O)I . 54 is required to approximate ^ in place of i/» is . Define: dmodA5) = sup{r. t t Note that dmodA-) is 0)/l3-3 o monotone in ip-p l<6. P*P : I o Assumption C.3: lim dmod AS) = 5^0 Assumption C.4: Eldmod AS]] behaved for < oo for some 5 when at 3 sample other the > almost take sure in . 0. is typically taken to be the matrix of is differentiable at P i/» points. The random interpreted as the modulus of differentiability for The approach adopted can almost surely. To satisfy Assumptions C.3 and C.4, A i/» . We impose the following restrictions on mod limits as 5 declines to zero. partial derivatives of we Therefore, 5. } o Hansen continuity of the derivative of i/» (1982) is to variable to i//. and be well at p mod (5) is . restrict the modulus of converge almost surely to zero and to to have a finite expectation for some neighborhood of the parameter. It follows from the Mean-Value Theorem that restrictions imposed in Hansen (1982) on the local behavior of We use ip imply Assumptions C.3 and C.4. Assumptions C.3 - stochastically differentiable. G^(5) = sup {\Y^<p{fi) C.4 to study the sense in which Hence look at the approximation error - Y^iP^i!i)\/\p-pJ By the Triangle Inequality we have that 55 : ||3-^J<5.p*p^> JAP ^^ (5) : s l^dmod(S) Thus by Assumptions C.1-C.2, we have that (CD s lim lim sup c (5) 5^ = This (1985) implies turn in + o in 0. stochastic differentiability condition in Pollard the because the counterpart to v^TI3-3 1/(1 VTO-P o I), which implies (C.l) Edmodid) lim 5^ T^oo the limit c (5) in Pollard's less than one. is taken 5. condition because The differentiability of limiting moment function directly from Assumption C.4. 7^ Therefore, - Ei/i differentiability condition with derivative at p is iterated limit the is e T monotone in {i/(^} Also, Pollard's in condition is scaled by stationary and ergodic, follows satisfies the stochastic given by r.A-£A. converges {7 A-£A> £i/» almost surely Since to zero hence the derivative is asymptotically negligible. Next we function can i/»^. also function be tp. impose a global Since the approximation of viewed rank as a local i// by i// identification is this condition local, condition on the original . Assumption C.5: £|A This identification condition on the approximating |<oo condition differentiability has full rank k. and £A on the conditions derivative already together established 56 with imply the the stochastic equicontinuity condition Theorem in (iii) of 3.3 Pakes Pollard and (1989) (see the discussion on page 1043 of Pakes and Pollard). We study the behavior of an estimator b ^^^(b. that solves the equations: = ) for sufficiently large T. The (k x n) random matrix a selects the linear combination of moment conditions to be used in estimation. Assumption C.6: Assumption {b C.7: } {a converges in probability to ^ converges } in probability . to a nonrandom matrix a where a £A is nonsingular. Finally, to obtain a limiting distribution for {b_} we assume: Assumption {/TV C.8: 1 00 o )> converges in distribution to a normally distributed random vector with mean zero and nonsingular covariance matrix V . Sufficient conditions for Assumption C.8 described approximations as Hansen (1985). This condition implies that by Gordin can be Hall (1969), £i//0 obtained using martingale ) and is equal Heyde (1980) and to zero. The following extension of Theorem 3.1 in Hansen (1982) is now a direct consequence of Theorem 3.3 and Lemma 3.5 in Pakes and Pollard (1989). 57 Theorem Wl{h Suppose C.l: that Assumptions C.1-C.8 satisfied. Then -& )> converges in distribution to a normally distributed random vector with mean zero and covariance matrix [a £(A. )] t Estimation of terms are of a EL. a ' to [£(A,' )a ]~ . follows as in Hansen (1982) as long as A can be expressed in random matrix function D continuous at p aV that satisfies A = DO ) where D is with probability one and has a modulus of continuity with a finite first moment for some 5 > In 0. probability to EL. 58 this case, {TDCb )> converges in Footnotes A weaker version of Assumption does 2.3 this restriction would more than eliminate replace Eq by redundant q. In securities. effect, It also precludes cases in which distinct portfolio weights give rise to the same payoff, possibly different prices but the same expected prices. 2 Formally, S the pricing-error interpretation for least squares problem (2.6) = sup meM p&P Ep^ = l inf \Emp - Eyp\ is , and for (2.7) is S where 3 // = sup \Emp m^M* peH £p^=l inf - Eyp\ is a complete set of derivative claims on the payoffs in P. Haberman characterized this nonlinear function as a particular projection onto a closed convex set formed by translating C by -p. (1989) only considers the case in which the data Although Haberman are iid, his characterization of the limiting distribution applies more generally with a covariance matrix replaced by a spectral density matrix at frequency zero. 59 4 The impetus for this work was the econometric discussion in an unpublished precursor to this paper: Hansen and Jagannathan (1988). The Hausdorff metric is usually employed for compact sets to ensure that Because of the vertical character of the the resulting distance is finite. regions and the existence of finite arbitrage bounds, the Hausdorff distance will be finite even though the sets are not bounded. The Euclidean distance in (4.2) could be replaced by the square root of a quadratic form in the differences between two points as long as a positive weight is given to both dimensions. 7 Even if hypothesis making (4.9) is satisfied, implementation problematic. This the outside the estimated arbitrage bounds. sample analog may be happens when the sample infinite, mean is This phenomenon does not arise for hypothesis (4.8). Q Burnside (1992) alternative and Cecchetti, versions of the Lam and Mark volatility bounds (1992) tests developed and studied when from positivity and can be formulated equivalently using (1992) for transactions The test used by Cochrane and Hansen (1992) abstracted costs are introduced. Burnside no a Monte Carlo comparison including the ones proposed here. 60 of various <(> (4.6). See volatility tests in References Andrews, D.W.K., 1991, "Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Covariance Matrix Estimation," Econometrica 59:3, 817-858. Consistent and S. Viswanathan, D.A. Hsieh, 1992, "A New Approach to Bansal, R. International Arbitrage Pricing," Duke University, Fuqua School of Business manuscript. , "Testing Models." Richardson, and T. Smith, J., M. 1992, Boudoukh, Restrictions Implied from Conditional Asset Pricing University manuscript. P. A., "Tests of Consistent Pricing Braun, 1992. Northwestern University, unpublished manuscript. and No Inequality New York Arbitrage," "A Simple Econometric Approach Brown, D.P. and M.R. Gibbons, 1985, Utility-based Asset Pricing Models," Journal of Finance 40, 359-381. Burnside, C. 1992, "Hansen-Jagannathan Bounds as Classical Pricing Models," NBER Workshop manuscript. , for Tests of Asset N.C. Cecchetti, S.G. P. Lam, and Mark, 1992, "Testing Volatility Restrictions on Intertemporal Marginal Rates of Substitution Implied by Euler Equations and Asset Returns," Ohio State University manuscript. , "Asset Cochrane J.H., and L.P. Hansen, 1992, Macroeconomics," NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1992, Pricing Explorations for Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 115-165. De Santis, G. 1993, "Volatility Bounds for Stochastic Discount Factors: Tests and Implications from International Stock Returns," University of Chicago Ph.D. Dissertation. , Duffie, D. and K.J. Singleton, 1993, "Simulated Moments Estimation of Markov Models of Asset Prices," Econometrica 61:4, 929-952. , Epstein, L.G., and S.E. Zin, 1991, "Substitution, Risk Aversion, and Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: An Empirical Analysis," Journal of Political Economy 99:2, 263-286. D.K. 1970, "Economic Equilibrium with Costly Marketing," Journal of Economic Theory 2:3, 276-291. Foley, Goldberger, , A. , 1968, Topics in Regression Analysis New York: Macmillan. , Gordin, M.I., 1969, "The Central Limit Theorem for Soviet Mathematics Doklady 10, 1174-1176. Haberman, S.J., 1989, 17:4, 1631-1661. "Concavity and Estimation," 61 Stationary Processes," The Annals of Statistics P., and C.C. Heyde, Academic Press. Hall, NY: 1980, Martingale Limit Theory and Its Application, Hansen, L.P., 1982, "Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators," Econometrica 50, 1029-1054. "A Method for Calculating Bounds on the Asymptotic 1985, L.P., Covariance Matrices of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators," Journal of Econometrics 30, 203-238. Hansen, Jagannathan, 1988, and R. Hansen, L.P., Implied Marginal Rates of Substitution manuscript. "Restrictions on Intertemporal by Asset Prices," unpublished Hansen, L. P., and R. Jagannathan, 1991, "Implications of Security Market Data for Models of Dynamic Economies," Journal of Political Economy 99:2, 225-262. and R. Jagannathan, 1993, "Assessing Specification Errors Factor Models," manuscript. Discount Stochastic L.P., Hansen, L.P., and K.J. Singleton, Estimation of Nonlinear Rational 1269-1286. Hansen, H. and D.M. Modest, Pricing," manuscript. He, , Heaton, J. Temporally 1993, , Dependent 1992, in 1982, "Generalized Instrumental Variables Expectations Models," Econometrica 50:5, "Market Frictions and Consumption-Based Asset Investigation of Asset Pricing with Empirical Preference Specification," MIT Sloan School Working "An Paper. Hildenbrand, W. 1974, Core and Equilibria of a Large Economy, Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press. , Huber, P., 1981, Robust Statistics, Wiley, New York. and H. Kallal, 1992, "Martingales, Arbitrage and Equilibrium in Jouni, E. Securities Markets with Transaction Costs," University of Chicago manuscript. , Knez, P.J., 1993, "Pricing Money Market Securities with Stochastic Discount Factors," University of Wisconsin manuscript. Kreps, D.M., 1981, "Arbitrage and Equilibrium in Economies with Many Commodities," Journal of Mathematical Economics, 15-35. Infinitely B. and B. Ingram, 1991, "Simulation Estimation of Time Series Models," Journai of Econometrics, 47, 197-205. Lee, , Luttmer, E. 1993, "Asset Pricing in Economies with Frictions," Northwestern University, Department of Finance Working Paper #151. , 62 MacKinlay, A.C., and M.P. Richardson, 1991, Moments to Test Mean-Variance Efficiency," 511-527. Manski, Hall. C. 1988, , "Using Generalized Method of The Journal of Finance 46, Analog Estimation Methods in Econometrics, NY: Chapman and 1989, "A Method of Simulated Moments for Estimation of Discrete McFadden, D. Response Models without Numerical Integration," Econometrica, 57, 995-1026. , West, "A 1987, and K. Autocorrelation and Heteroskedasticity Econometrica 55, 703-708. Newey, W.K., Positive Semi-definite, Simple Consistent Covariance Matrix, "Simulation and Pollard, 1989, and D. A. Fakes, Optimization Estimators," Econometrica 57:5, 1027-1057. , 1985, Pollard, D. Theory 1. 295-314. , "New Ways to Prove Central Limit the Asymptotics Theorems," of Economic 1986, "Valuation of Risky Assets in Arbitrage Free Economies Prisman, E.Z. with Frictions," The Journal of Finance, 41, 545-559. , Rockafellar, R.T., 1970, Convex Analysis, Princeton: Princeton University Press. 1987, "Multivariate Proxies and Asset Pricing Relations: Shanken, J. with the Roll Critique," Journal of Financial Economics 18, 91-110. , Living Snow, K.N., 1991, "Diagnosing Asset Pricing Models Using the Distribution of Asset Returns," Journal of Finance 46, 955-984. Vuong, Q.H., 1989, "Likelihood Ratio Tests for Model Selection and Non-Nested Hypotheses," Econometrica 57:2, 307-333. Involving 1991, "The Local Nature of Hypothesis Tests Wolak, F. A., Inequality Constraints in Nonlinear Models," Econometrica 59:4, 981-995. 2935 i39 63 MIT 3 iQfiD UBBARIES 0Qfi3ST32 5 Date Due SEP. 3 JUN. 019941 9 18195 Lib-26-67