LIBRARY OF THE INSTITTJTE MASSACHUSETTS OF TECHNOLOGY ^^ l/'fl ALFRED P. SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT COMPACTNESS AND CONVEXITY OF STATIC CONTRACTUAL SETS by Murat 433 - 69 R. Sertel December, 1969 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 COMPACTNESS AND CONVEXITY OF STATIC CONTRACTUAL SETS by Murat 433 - 69 R. Sertel December, 1969 no. cjECt'^'^'^ FEc ^33-^9 A COMPACTNESS AND CONVEXITY OF STATIC CONTRACTUAL SETS Murat R. Sertel This is a sequel of an earlier paper (Sertel, 1969), where, among other things, a static social contract is defined for a collectivity of and shown to exist (sub jectlvely-)expected-utility maximizing behavors if behavors' impressions of social states are continuous in the latter. Here it is shown that the static contractual set is compact and that, if behavors' impression functions are linear on it, the set is then convex also. Some implications of these results are briefly discussed. , Introduction ; This brief paper is meant to be intelligible after having read Sertel (1969). There it was shown that the static contractual set , which is the briefer term we adopt here to designate the set of static social contracts, is non-empty. Here we demonstrate a compactness and n certain convexity property for that set. For the sake of continuity, the notation of the mentioned paper is adhered to. For the same reason, we also continue with the numbering of results, etc., from where we left it there. First we take up the compactness, and then the convexity result to be proved. Remarks follow. Compactness : Without delay, we prove the following fact. 32. COR . The static contractual set C of a collectivity N is compact. Proof: Since C is a subset of the compact social state space P, C is 534 '.)."; a bounded. Therefore, we need only prove that C is closed. Let {c sequence of points in C converging to so that = c^ <c, exists an open ball C. ^ Then c be a S(c), i Since (Sertel, 1969)], this implies that there LEM. 6) B(c^; c the graph of the social evolution S. c> i G(S), C(S) is closed [by 21. Suppose c. } with radius fl B(c; 6) ' about c_, such that G(S) = 0. ' Let K be large enough so that, for all c*^, 6 greater than or equal to K, C < c| 6 I Then, for all dieting that Convexity C greater than or equal to c c e C. Hence, c C, e K, = <c c_ , c > s^ G(S), contra- so that C is closed. : Now we prove the following fact. 33. C(Jt\ . if, for all j the impression function I. in N, is linear on C, Chen C is convex. Proof A e : [0, Let c, c' be static social contracts, i.e., elements of C; let 1], X' = 1 - A, and correspondingly for c c'. = Ac , c + A'c'. Denote , and for c,, c. c . = f.(c), Denote also V.(p) = U.(I.(p)) = U.(p. * I^(f^(p))). 3 IJ J J c-^ = f-" (c) , Since I. is linear on C, and since U. J J is linear [by 8. ASS. (Sertel, (A2) 1969)], V. is linear on C. Hence, V.(C) = AV.(c) + A'V.(c'), J J J But * I^(cJ)) V,(c) = U,(c. > U.(p. * I^(c^)), / p'. (p., 3 V.(c') = U,(c'. J Also, c. = Ac, 2 2 + 2 2 REM . ..., c -22 U.(p'. > 3 I^(c'^)), 2 2 = V J 3 A. 2 * since f. is linear. Hence, denoting p. = Ap. + X'c',5 V.(?!) Thus, y = (c„, * I^Cc'^)) (Z. Jl ) c * I^(c^)) >. U.(p. * I^(e^)), J J Y(c), implying c e J P.) e 1 A 'pi 2 (p. e 2 P.), J 2(Y(c)) = S(c). Hence, J c e C. Without following them through very far, we may briefly indicate some implications of the last two results. Apart from giving some motiv- ation for these results, the remarks below are hoped to be suggestive and inviting to other researchers. As a result of 32. COR., every continuous functional defined on C will attain a maxiraura (mininiu-m) on that set. As a result of 33. COR. , allows us to define concave or convex functionals on itself. Thus, one may now go ahead and consider continuous objective functionals on C, specify the risk aversion reflected by their curvatures, and speak of maximizing (minimizing) then-i on C, C The relevance of all this is clearer when one begins to consider "social leaders" or "controllers" who may be willing and able to influence the equilibrium outcomes, i.e., social contracts, obtaining for collect- ivities such as N, by control over the environment, impression functions, or tastes (utility vectors) involved. Such controllers may be imagined as forming a "higher level" "controllers' collectivity" of their own, which may be analyzed quite the same as N. In that case, it will be useful to be able to specify well-defined and tractable optimization prob- lems for the controller-type behavors of this new sort of collectivity, which is precisely where the last two results should be welcome indeed. It is hoped that these remarks may be justified by an undelayed excursion in the indicated direction. NOTES * This research is part of an ongoing effort inthe area of Management Information and Controls at the Sloan School of Management of M.I.T., and was partially supported by a NASA grant under the direction of Prof. Zenon S. Zannetos. REFERENCES (Sertel, 1969) Murat R. : Sertsl^^ "A Formal Framework and Fundamental Results for Social Analysis", SSM Working Paper 429-69, October, 1969. 5:^^KBiate- Due 5 DEC FEB 05 7^ f^ OCT 1 2 198:! FEB 23 78) FfBi4r9,^ SEP 24 jf P^ AUG 2 1^ ^• \ Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES '^30-h'i 3 DD3 TDb TDflD bflT MIT .IBRAHIES 3 jro28 0D3 TOb 7DS TDflD H3Z' DD3 TDb 721 TDflD 3 MIT LIBRARIES i^-^n-CoH DD3 TDb 73T 3 lOflO Ml' I lfl«A»IF<. V5t/-fe«J Ill nil II III: llll mil 7bT TDfiD D 03 fi7S 3 MIT LIBRARIES 43?"- 3 TDflD DD3 675 fe'? lift Mil LlBRAHIES ni,-70 3 TDflO DD3 fl7S 7T3 L{%-10 3 TDfiD 0D3 675 627 MIT LIBRARIES i/3f'70 3 T06D 0D3 675 635 MIT LIBRARIES l{^D~7d 3 'oan it MIT LIBRARIES TD6D DD 3 TOb 7bB