- .. . j 3 . ynaj 4-g Fmancial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 ~~~,~~~~~ts of outsiders to Japanese boards B Dererminants and implications for managers Steven 1% Kaplan**“, Bernadette A. Mintonb ‘Graduate School” of Business, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL 60637, USA bOhio State University, Columbus, OH 43210, USA (Received March 1993; final version received February 1994) Abstract This paper investigates the determinants of appointments of outsiders - directors previously employed by banks (bank directors) or by other nonfinancial firms (corporate directors) - to the boards of large nonfinancial Japanese corporations. Such appointments increase with poor stock performance; those of bank directors also increase Jslith earnings losses. Turnover of incumbent top executives increases substantially in the year of both types of outside appointments. We perform a similar analysis for outside appointments in large U.S. firms and find different patterns. We conclude that banks and corporate shareholders play an important monitoring and disciplinary role in Japan. Key words: Corporate governance; Boards of directors; Relationship investing JEL classification: G32; G21; D23 * Corresponding autS;or. Etsuko Hashimoto, Rochelle Kopp, Naoki Shigetake, Keiko Tanaka, Mari Tanigawa, and Yaz Tanigawa provided able research assistance. We have received helpful comments from Charles Calomiris, Eugene Fama, AniI Kashyap, Wayne Mikkeison (the editor), Kevin M. Murphy, Megan Partch (the referee), Robert Vishny, Michael Weisbach, Luigi Zingales, and seminar participants at the CEPR/ESF Workshop in Corporate Finance, Columbia University, the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Harvard Business School, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Michigan State, the University of Chicago, the University of Michigan, Washington University, and Yale Law School. The first author acknowledges research support from the Wilham Ladany Faculty Research Fund, the Lynde and Harry Bradley Foundation, the Qlin Foundation, and the Center for Research in Security Prices. Previous versions of this paper were titled: ‘Outside’ Intervention in Jap,?nese Companies: Its Determinants and Its Implications for Managers. 0304-405X,94/$07.00 0 SSDI 0304405x9400781 1994 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved u 226 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Minton/ Journal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 1. Introduction In contrast to market-oriented corporate governance in the U.S., corporate governance in Japan is generally characterized as a stable, relationship-based system. A company’s relationships with its main bank, corporate shareholders, and corporate group supposedly play important roles in governance.’ Takeovers, proxy fights, and public contests for control are rare. Although the existence of the three types of relationships in Japan is well-documented, the impact on managers is less so. Some have argued that these relationships reduce agency costs, discipline managers, and substitute for an external market for corporate control.2 Others believe that these relationships both entrench managers and serve as a form of insurance against liquidation. Because shareholdings are stable and boards are dominated by insiders, it is very difficult to oust incumbent management. In the event a company encounters financial difficulties, the relationships help ensure the company’s survival whether or not it is efficient to do SO.~Between these two extreme views is the intermediate view that Japanese managers must earn enough to satisfy their banks and meet debt payments. Conditional on earning a satisfactory profit, however, managers can run their firms in the interests of employees or themselves.4 All of these views are based largely on anecdotal or indirect evidence. In this paper, we attempt to distinguish between these views by studying the determinants and implications for managers of appointments of outsiders - individuals previously employed by banks (bank directors) or other nonfinancial corporations (corporate directors) - to the boards of large, nonfinancial Japanese corporations from 1980 to 1988. Based on a large body of case evidence, we use such appointments as indicators that the main bank or nonfinancial corporation is paying particular attention to the governance of the appointing company. We find that appointments of both bank and corporate directors increase significantly with poor stock performance; appointments of bank directors increase with earnings losses as well. Appointments of outsrLers also increase with measures of the intensity of the relationships said to govern Japanese companies: appointments of bank directors increase in firms with larger borrowings from banks; appointments of corporate directors increase in firms with more concentrated shareholders and in firms affiliated with a corporate group. To test for differences in the governance roles of such outsiders in the two countries, we compare the Japanese results to those for large, nonfinancial U.S. ‘See Aoki (1990) and Aoki, Patrick, and Sheard (1994). 2See Grundfest (1990), Hoshi et al. ( 1990, 1991), Porter (1992), and Prowse (1990). 3See Abegglen and Stalk (1983, Blinder (1992), Coffee (1991), and Nakatani 4See Aoki ( 1990) and Kester ( 1991). (1984). S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Mintort,Liournal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 227 outside directors in U.S. corporations are generally less sensitive to stock and earnings performance than are outside appointments in Japanese companies. While appointments of directors affiliated with large blockholders are roughly as sensitive to corporate performance in U.S. companies as outside appointments are in Japanese companies, they are less frequent, occurring less than 20% as often as outside appointments in Japan. These initial results are consistent with governance relationships in Japan playing a monitoring and disciplinary role. They are also consistent, however, with an insurance interpretation in which the presence of an outsider signals to suppliers, customers, or others that the bank or the affiliated corporation will support - i.e., bail out and, therefore, insure - the appointing company. We distinguish between the two interpretations by considering the relation between outside director appointments and top executive turnover. Turnover increases substantially in periods when outsiders are appointed, even when we control for company perform,nce. We conclude that banks and corporate shareholders play an important monitoring and disciplinary role in Japan. Two additional pieces of evidence support this interpretation. First, we examine the relation of top executive turnover to outside and blockholder appointments in large U.S. corporations. Top executive turnover in the 1J.S. is insensitive to outside appointments, which indicates that appointments offoutside directors play a different role in the U.S. than they do in Japan. Appointments of directors affiliated with blockholders are, in contrast, associated with modestly increased top executive turnover (as well as poor company performance). Such blockholder appointments, when they occur, may play a similar role to outside appointments in Japan. However, the relative infrequency of blockholder appointments in the U.S. suggests they play an appreciably smaller governance role’than do outside appointments in Japan. Second, we examine company performance in Japan around the years of outside appointmeirts. The monitoring or disciplining interpretation predicts that managers of poorly performing companies will be replaced by managers who will reverse the poor performance. We find that bank directors are appointed in companies that are contracting or financially distressed, while corporate directors are appointed in companies that have temporary problems. Company performance stabilizes and improves modestly after both types of appointments. Overall, we interpret our results as favoring the view that the set of bank and intercorporate relationships in Japan plays a monitoring and disciplinary role. In this sense, the relationships may act as a substitute for the more market-oriented U.S. control mechanisms. Because outside appointments are driven most strongly by poor stock performance, our results do not support the intermediate view that managers can xun their companies in the interests of employees or themselves as long as they earn a satisfactory profit. 228 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Min ton/ Journal of Financial Economics 36 ( 1994) 225-258 Our results support a monitoring role for banks and other corporations. However, the primary importance of stock returns and current income in outside appointments sharply contradicts the view of Porter (1992), among others, that the corporate governance system in Japan pays little, if any attention to current stock prices and other measures of ‘short-term’ performance. Recently, Woshi? Kashyap, and Scharfstein (1993) and Kester (1991) have argued that financial market deregulation and operating successes in the 1980s weakened the governance relationships in Japan. We conclude the paper by testing for a deterioration in the sensitivity of bank and corporate appointments over time. We do not find such a deterioration. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the sample selection, companies, and data sources. Section 3 examines the performance-related determinants of outside appointments. Section 4 adds relationship-based explanatory variables. Section 5 measures top executive turnover in firms that make outside appointments. Section 0 presents evidence on pre- and post-appointment financial performance. Section 7 considers changes in relations between appointments and performance over time. Section 8 concludes. 2. Sample and variable description 2. I. Sample and data sources The sample of Japanese companies includes the 119 publicly traded Japanese industrial corporations on Fortune Magazine’s List of the 5cO Largest Foreign Industrials by Sales in 1981. Because the fiscal years of most Japanese companies end in March, the Fortune list is largely based on fiscal years ended March 1980. Financial data on the Japanese companies come from several sources. Financial statement, employment, and stock price data come from annual issues of Diamond’s Kaisha Yoran Zenjojo Kaishabarr and the Daiwa Institute of Research Analysts’ Guide. Data on shareholdings, borrowings, corporate executives, and directors are obtained from editions of Kigyo Keiretsu Soran and from the 1982 and 1984 Yuka Shoken Hokokusho (the Japanese equivalent of U.S. 10-K filings). Additional data on corporate executives and directors are obtained from annual issues of Diamond’s Kaisha Shokuin Roku (Diamond’s Company Personnel). 3anel A of Table 1 presents data on equity market value, sales, and current or pre-tax income in 1980 and 1988 for the 119 Japanese firms. The panel indicates that sales and equity market values for the sample firms increased substantially in dollar terms over the sample period. These increases were driven by the appreciation of the yen and the rise in the Japanese stock market. The sales and equity values are presented in dollars for the benefit of U.S. readers. In the S. N. Kaplan, B.A. Min ton/ Journal of Financial Economic: 36 ( 1994) 225-258 229 regressions, the performance variables are measured in yen. Consistent with most previous work on Japanese companies, the accounting measures (here and throughout the paper) come from unconsolidated financial reports. We obtain similar results using consolidated financial data for the subset of firms for which we have such data. The sample of U.S. companies includes the 146 publicly traded industrial firms among Fortune Magazine’s 1981 list of the 150 industrial companies with the highest sales. The Fortune list is largely based on fiscal years ended December 1980. Financial data on the U.S. companies come from COMPUSTAT; stock return data from the CRSP tapes. Data on corporate executives and directors are obtained from proxy statements, 10-K filings, and issues of Moody’s industrial Manuals. Because Moody ‘s publication deadline is mid-July, we measure turnover from July 1 to June 30. To synchronize with the Fortune list, we begin the sample with the 1981 edition and record the relevant data on all board members through the 1989 edition. The sample, therefore, begins iv fiscal year 1980 and ends in fiscal year 1988. We used firm proxy statements to confirm executive and director appointment dates. As reported in Table 1, the U.S. firms are larger than their Japanese counterparts. In 1980, the U.S. firms have median sales of $4.9 billion versus $1.6 billion for the Japanese firms. The gap narrows by 1988 when the U.S. firms have roughly twice the sales of the Japanese firms. The true differences in sales are actually smaller, because the Japanese sales measures are for parent operations only. Consolidated sales would be higher. 2.2. Governance measures 2.2. I. Japan As in the U.S., boards of directors in Japan are legally responsible for managing the corporation. 5 The directors are elected at a shareholder meeting to terms of not more than, and usually equal to, two years. Shareholder meetings are held annually, but shareholders holding at least 3% of a company’s shares have the right to convene a meeting to vote on the dismissal of directors. Qur sample firms have a median of 21 directors. The most important director is typically the president. He is considered the chief executive officer., although, in some cases, the chairman has greater power. Most companies give three or four directors, always including the president, the right to represent the company in dealings with third parties and to make decisions on matters delegated by the board. These directors are a company’s representative directors. If the chairman is powerful, e.g., Sony’s Akio Morita, he will have representative ‘The discussion in this section is taken largely from Heftel(l983). and Gorlach (1993). See also Ballon and Tomita (1988) 691 6,638 2,40 1 5,649 0.054 0.043 0.285 0.141 0.396 0.647 0.168 Sales in fiscal year 1980 ($ M) Sales in fiscal year 1988 ($ M) Current or pre-tax income to assets 1980 Current or pre-tax income to assets 1988 Debt to total assets 1980 Debt of top lender to total debt 1980 Fraction of shares owned by top 10 shareholders 1980 Member of financial group (Dodwell 1982) Member of enterprise group (Dodwell 1982) Mean 0.368 0.307 0.132 0.047 0.039 1,580 3,456 449 3,703 Median 0.119 0.180 0.069 0.032 0.044 2,464 6,845 733 7,604 Std. dev. 0.125 0.090 8,556 11,988 3,852 7,652 Mean U.S. firms ____ -___--- - ----- ___-- Japanese firms Market value of equity 1980 ($ M) Market value of equity 1988 ($ M) (A) Levels _ --_-___ ~___-_____ 0.126 0.093 4,85 1 7,065 2,022 4,447 IvIedian _I__-- -- 0.089 0.070 12,313 17,017 5,673 10,265 Std. dev. -.______ Summary statistics for firm financial and governance characteristics for 119 large Japanese firms and 146 large U.S. firms. Japanese companies are listed in Fortune Muyuzine’s 1981 list of the largest international companies (by sales). U.S. companies are among the 150 largest companies (by sales) in Fortune Maguzine’s 1981 list of the largest industrial companies in the U.S. U.S. stock returns are total calendar year returns. Japanese stock returns are fiscal year stock returns not including dividends. Dividends would increase returns by approximately 1.25% per year. Sales growth is the annual change in (log) sales. Change in pre-tax income to assets is the annual change in the ratio of pre-tax income to total assets. Yet values are converted into dollars using year-end yen-dollar exchange rates. Representative directors are directors with representative rights. Japanese data are from DiamonZr Kaisha Yoran Zenjojo Kaishatm, the Daiwa Institute of Research Analysts’ Guide, Kigyo Keiretsu Soran, and the 1982 and 1984 Yuka Shoken Hokokusho. U.S. data are from COMPUSTAT, proxy statements, 10-K filings, and Moody’s Industrial Manuals. Summary statistics for financial and governance characteristics of Japanese and U.S. firms Table 1 Q 2 3 I G 2 ; ti 3r \2 2 2 ‘2 k 3’ s * 4 $” & L _. ---__ At least one new outside director appointed (per firm-year) Percentage of new outside directors appointed (per firm-year) At least one new blockholder director appointed (per firm-year) - At least one new director appointed with bank experience (per firm-year) At least one new director appointed with other nonfinancial corporation experience (per firm-year) At least one new director appointed with bank or other nonfinancial corporation experience (per firm-year) Stock returns Sales growth Change in pre-tax income to assets Pre-tax income is negative (per firm-year) (B) Panel data, one-year periods, 1980-1988 - 0.000 - 0.000 0.088 0.129 0.059 0.075 0.122 0.036 0.150 0.032 0.12 0.02 0.26 0.515 0.089 0.023 - 0.033 0.005 0.115 0.122 - 0.050 0.001 0.133 0.16 0.07 0.26 - $z 232 S. N. Kaplan, B.A. Minton/ Journal of Financial Economics 36 (I 994) 225-258 rights, The median number of representative directors in our sample firms is three (the average is 4.22). Very few of the directors in Japan are outside directors as we know them in the U.S. At the start of fiscal year 1981, all of the directors of the median firm in our sample are currently employed by the firm. In fact, the sample firms have a median of only two directors who have ever worked for another firm. In this paper, we study board appointments of those few directors with previous experience at another firm. We refer to such directors as ‘outsiders’. We distinguish between previous employment at a bank or at a different Japanese corporation, referring to directors with bank experience as bank directors, and to those with corporate experience as corporate directors. Our use of the term outsider follows Aoki, Patrick, and Sheard (1994) who describe the board of directors as largely composed of two kinds of incumbent managers: ‘insiders or so-called lifetime employees who have risen to top management positions through internal promotion hierarchies and outsiders, ex-employees of other organizations (such as banks, affiliated companies, or government ministries) who have entered the firm usually at board level’ (p. 15). We focus on appointments of outsiders because they are unusual, and are generally considered an indication that the main bank or outside corporation is paying particular attention to the governance of the appointing firm. Aoki (1990),Aoki et al. (1994),Hoshi et al. (1990 and 1991),and Sheard (1994) provide anecdotal and case evidence of such attention. We follow the boards of directors of our sample Japanese companies from 1980 to 1988. An outside appointment is defined as an appointment of one or more outsiders to a board in a given year. Panel B of Table 1 indicates that firms appoint at least one bank director in 7.5% (or 70) of firm-years, at least one corporate director in 5.9% (or 55) of firm-years, and at least one of either in 12.9?6 (or 120) of firm-years. We do not distinguish between single and multiple appointments because in most appointment-years 90% for bank and 83% for corporate appointments - only one outsider is appointed. Bank and corporate appointments, therefore, are unusual, but not rare. (We note that because firms appoint an average of three new directors each year, bank and corporate directors make up only slightly more than 5% of all director appointments in the sample. Another 1.8% are previous government employees, with at least one government director being appointed in 5.5% of firm-years.) Over 90% of the outside directors joined the sample firms in the same year they were appointed directors. Based on Aoki et al. (1994) and private conversations with bankers, we consider the few directors with prior experience at the appointing firms to be outsiders. Our results are qualitatively identical when we do not consider them outsiders. Among the outside directors, 72% of bank directors and 49% of corporate directors are described only as employees of the sample firm. The remaining outside directors retain a concurrent affiliation - as S.N. Kaplan, B.A. MintonlJournal of Financial Econonlics 36 (1994) 225-258 233 either a director or employee - with their previous firm. In what follows, we make no distinction between those with and without a concurrent affiliation. Our results are qualitatively similar when we consider directors with concurrent affiliations separately fro,m those without such affliations. In 45% of bank appointments and 37% of corporate appointments, the new outsider appears to replace an outside incumbent. Our results are qualitatively similar for replacement and nonreplacement appointments, and, therefore, we do not distinguish between them in our analysis. Once appointed to the board, the outside appointments serve what appear to be normal directors’ terms. The average terms as director for bank and corporate directors (for whom we have completed terms) are respectively, 8.2 and 8.4 years, similar to the 8.3.year average term (12.1% annual turnover) for all directors. The outside directors tend to go in at the level of director, rather than at the more senior level of representative director. While an outsider is appointed to the board in 12.9% of firm-years, an outsider is appointed a representative director in only 2.6% of firm-years. This indicates that it is unusual for outsiders to explicitly take over the management of the firm. Our definition of directors does not include appointments of statutory auditors. All Japanese firms hire one to three statutory auditors who are generally retired employees of the firm, the main bank, or some other firm. The auditors can attend, but cannot vote at, board meetings. Merck and Nakamura (1993) also estimate the determinants of bank appointments and include statutory auditor appointments as director appointments. They note, however, that they obtain similar results when auditors are excluded. We also exclude board appointments of government officials and nonJapanese directors. When government officials retire in Japan, they occasionally obtain board positions in firms they previously regulated. This is known as a ‘descent from heaven’. Because such appointments are generally considered rewards, we do not consider them as outside appointments. Similarly, we exclude board appointments of non-Japanese directors because they are unlikely to be part of the Japanese corporate governance system. 2.2.2 United States We consider two types of outside apoointments in the U.S. First, we consider new appointments of outside directors - directors who are neither current or former executives of the compan 1~. While not identical to the definition of Japanese outsiders, this definition identifies directors who come from outside the firm. The U.S. firms have a median of 15 directors, ten of whom are outside directors. We measure appointments of outside directors in two ways. First, we create a dummy variable equal to one if a firm appoints at least one new outside directcr. Because such appointments are so common, occurring in 51S% of firm-years, we also measure appointments of outside directors as a fraction of initial outside directors to gauge the magnitude or intensrty of appointments of 234 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Minton/ Journal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 new outside directors. We refer to this variable as the percentage of outside appointments. The percentage of outside appointments averages 0.089 or 8.9% per firm-year. pointments The second type of outside appointment we consider is boar ore of the company’s stock. We of individuals affiliated with holders of 5% e use a dummy variable equal to refer to these as blockholder appointments. one if such an appointment occurs, and zero otherwise. Blockholder appointments occur in only 2.3% of firm-years, significantly less often than outside appointments in Japan. We believe that blockholder appointments in the U.S. correspond most closely to bank and corporate appointments in Japan, because the main bank and other corporate shareholders typically own nontrivial equity stakes in the appointing firms. In our Japanese sample, the main bank holds an ownership stake of at least 3% in almost 75% of the firms; and the largest stockholding by a corporate shareholder is at least 5% in more than 90% of the firms. 2.3. Performance measures We measure firm performance in the year of the director appointment and the two previous years. We use four measures of performance: (1) company stock returns, (2) sales growth, (3) change in pre-tax income as a fraction of total assets, and (4) a dummy variable equal to one if pre-tax income is negative. The dummy variable for negative pre-tax income indicates that a firm’s accounting earnings are less than its accounting operating and financial expenses. Throughout the paper, we interpret negative pre-tax income as an indicator of firms that are having difficulty meeting their financial obligations. Panel B of Table 1 presents summary statistics for the performance variables for the Japanese and U.S. firms. 2.4. Relationship measures In addition to considering the association between performance and appointments, we also consider variables that measure the strength of the three types of relationships said to govern Japanese 6rms. We measure the strength of bank relationships in two ways. First, we use the ratio of bank borrowings to total assets in 1980, the year before our analysis begins. The median value of bank borrowings to total assets is 0.307. We measure debt levels at the beginning of our sample period to reduce the likelihood that performance - particularly earnings performance - determines debt levels. Second, we follow oshi, Kashyap, and Scharfstein (1990) and estimate the strength of a firm’s relationship with its main bank as the fraction of a firm’s borrowing that is provided by its largest lender. Over 75% of the bank directors in our sample were previously employed by the appointin st lender. The median sample firm obtains 0.132 of its total borrowings from its E lender. The variable is set to zero for firms with no borrowings. As a measure of the importance of large intercorporate shareholders, we obtain the ownership concentration of the top ten shareholders in 1980. large shareholders in Japan are corporate shareholders. Finally, we measure group relationships. There are tws types of groups in Japan: financial keiretsu or financial group firms that are linked by relationships to a main bank, by cross-holdings of equity, and by product-market links; and enterprise group firms that are organized around a particular enterprise and linked by cross-holdings of equity and stronger product -market links. We consider a firm to be a member of a financial group if Do associates the firm with one of the six financial groups: DKB, Fuyo Mitsui, Sanwa, and Sumitomo. Almost 65% of our sample firms have an association with one of these financial groups. We obtain qualitatively similar results when we use two different definitions for financial group membership: (1) members of any of the president’s councils associate with the six financial groups or (2) firms listed by Dodwell as being strongly inclined to one of the financial groups. We also use Dodwell (1982) to determine whether a firm was associated with one of six large enterprise groups in Japan: Hitachi, Matsushita, Nippon Steel, Nissan Motors, Toshiba, and Toyota. Almost 17% of our sample firms are associated with one of these enterprise groups. Summary statistics for all five relationship variables are presented in panel A of Table 1. 3. Outside appointments and performance 3.1. Outside appointments in Japan Panel A of Table 2 presents maximum likelihood logit regression estimates of the likelihood of an outside appointment - eiiher from a bank or another corporation - as a function of performance. Separate estimations are run for each of the four performance measures. [To make sure that outliers do not drive the results, we also transformed the continuous performance variables into their decile ranks. We obtained results qualitatively similar to those presented in what follows.) The regressions also include time-period dummy variables which are intended to control for economy- or market-wide shocks that vary over time. (The regressions do not report the time-period coefficients,) The results are qualitatively and statistically similar when the time-period variables are excluded. The tab!e also presents the sensitivities of the likelihood of an outside of outside directors versus performal,ie in Japan Logit 0.22 - 0.79 0.05 -_- Sales growth Sitme period One lag TB~ lags ----- - 0.58 -- 1.37 0.05 variables Stock ret urn Same period One lag Two lags Indeppndent - 0.059 - 0.140” 0.00~1 Slope 0.023 - 0.083 0.005 Model p = 0.87 CO.981 co.933 co.991 Model p = 0.01” [0.44-J co.441 co.451 [S.E.] (A) Bank or nonfinancial corporation - 0.45 - 0.58 - 0.35 - 0.01 - 1.48 0.30 Logit (B) Bank - 0.029 - 0.037 - 0.023 Model p = 0.18 Cl.241 Cl.181 [ 1.243 0.37 - 1.52 0.89 - 1.39 - 0.34 - 0.091” 0.019 [0.56-J [0.52] Model p = 0.06’ - 1.59 Logit - 0.001 Slope co.53J [S.E.] ____~__ - 0.067b 0.059b - 0.014 Model p = 0.69 Cl.381 Cl.311 [ 1.407 0.017 - 0.069 0.04 1 Model p = 0.01” CO.613 COW [0.66-J -____ Slope corporation [S.E.) (C) Nonfinancial Logit regression estimates that at least one new director previously employed by Logi. regressions of the likelihood that a new director was previously employed by (A) a bank or a different nonfinancial corporation, (B) a bank and (C) a diflzenl nonfinancial corporation as a function of stock return?, sales growth, earnings growth, and negative pre-tax income for 119 Japanese firms from NXCt%31QllX. Separate regressions are run for each performance measure (current and lagged values). All regressions include dummy variables for the time pt’r:od. S!ope measures the change in the probability of an appointment to a change in the independent variable irilplied by the logit coefficienrs evaluated at sample mear;^,. Model p-value reports the joint significance level of the current and lagged coefkients of the performance variable. _______. -__--__. - - Regression estimates of the likelihood of appointments 2 5 3 I z X cSipnifk~~ntly a Significantly bSipniticantly vrtriable 0.73 0.32 - 5.92 1.73 0.12 933 933 Model p = 0.01 b CO.381 co.393 0.079b 0.050’ - 0.101 0.563 0.304 Model p = 0.45 [6.66] [6.07] C6.43) 0.075 0.92 0.64 - 1.57 8.80 4.70 0.129 Model p = 0.02b CO.321 ro.341 o.095b 0.037 - 0.626 0.183 0.013 Model p = 0.66 [5.16-J [4.8 I] [SS 1-J different from zero at the 1% level . different from zero at the 5% level. different from zero at the BO% level. Mean dependent Pre-tax incomt is negative Same period One lag Same period 01;; klg Two lags Change in prc-1 ax income, assets - 0.20 - 0.35 4.78 - 11.41 - 9.19 - 0.512 - 0.412 933 0.059 IModel p = Q.92 co.531 [0.58-J 0.013 - 0.014 [7.23] - 0.214 Model p = 0.25 [6.98]’ [6.67] - k 3N. s -? k 2 ;c * F ia a 238 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Minton/ Journal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 appointment to a unit change in the performance variables implied by the logit coefficients. These sensitivities are labeled ‘slopes’, and are economically equivalent to the coeficient estimates that would be obtained in an ordinary least squares regression. The discussion below focuses on these slope estimates. Panel A indicates that outside appointments are most closely related to stock performance and negative current income. A two-standard-deviation drop in stock returns (52%) is associated with 3.10/o and 7.3% increases, respectively, in the likelihood of an outside appointment in the same and following year. The cumulative 10.4% increase (significant at 1%) is economically and statistically large compared to the overall likelihood of 12.9%. Similarly, negative income is associated with an increased likelihood of an outside appointment in the same and following year, for a total increase of 13.2% (significant at 2%). It is important to note that outside appointments are most sensitive to current measures of performance - earnings and stock returns. Sales growth, which some would consider a proxy for market share and a firm’s long-term health, has no explanatory power. 3.1.2. Bank appointments Panel B of Table 2 presents logit estimates of the likelihood of bank director appointments. The likelihood of a new bank director is most closely associated with negative pre-tax income. The estimates imply that the likelihood of a new bank director increases by 7.9% in the year of negative income and by 5.0% in the subsequent year, for a cumulative increase of 12.9% (significant at 1%). This result indicates that bank appointments respond relatively quickly to measures of recent performance. Furthermore, the increased likelihoods are both large relative to the unconditional likelihoods of 7.5%. There is also a negative relation betwee the likelihood of a bank director appointment and stock returns. A two-standard-deviation decline in stock returns is associated with a 4.7% increase in the likelihood of a bank appointment in the following year (significant at lo/,). This is also a large increase relative to the unconditional likelihood of 7.5%. 3. I .3. Corporate appointments Panel C of Table 2 reports logit estimates of the likelihood of appointments of new corporate directors. Such appointments are most closely associated with poor stock performance. The estimates associate a two-standard-deviation decline in stock returns with an increased likelihood of a corporate director of 3.5% in the current year and 3.19/o in the next year. This 6.6% cumulative increased likelihood is economically significant relative to the unconditional likelihood of 5.9%. Corporate appointments are also related to changes in pre-tax income. The coefficient on the contemporaneous earnings change, as well as the sum of the three coefficients, are significant at the POoh level. (The sum of the coefficients is sign+I,,ant at the 10% Eevcl while the model p-value S. N. Kaplan, B.A. Minton/ Journal of Financial Ecmomics 36 (I 994) 225-258 239 presented in Table 2 is not. The model p-value tests if and canGot reject that the three coefficients are jointly equal to zero.) Strikingly, corporate appointments are not related to negative income. The patterns for outside appointments suggest that bank and corporate appointments occur under different circumstances. Bank appointments are most likely in firms with poor stock performance and difficulty meeting their financial obligations. Corporate appointments, in contrast, are most likely in firms with poor stock performance that is unrelated to an inability to meet financial obligations. We estimated a bivariate probit model to test whether one type of appointment affects the likelihood of the other, conditional on performance (as measured by stock returns and negative current income). We find that bank and corporate appointments are negatively, but not significantly related. This suggests that the appointment of one type of outsider does not have an appreciable effect on the decision to appoint the other type of outsider. 3.2. Comparison to United States Table 3 reports regression estimates of the likelihood of outside appointments and blockholder director appointments in U.S. firms. The regressions of new outside appointments and blockholder appointments are estimated using a logit specification, while those of the fraction of new outside directors appointed are estimated using ordinary least squares. Table 3 also reports p-values (labelled p-value Japan vs. U.S.) for differences between the coefficient estimates in the :rnnese logit regressions for U.S. logit regressions and the coeficients in the Ja,,, bank or corporate appointments in panel A of Table 2. The p-values are negative when the coefficients are smaller in Japan than in the U.S. The p-value for the Joint test that all coefficients are zero is reported below the p-values for individual coefficients. Panel A of Table 3 indicates that the likelihood of at least one outside appointment in the U.S. is significantly related only to contemporaneous negative income, with the coefficient implying an increased likelihood of 10.70//o (significant at 10%) relative tc the sample likelihood of 51.5%. The likelihood of at least one outside appointment is not significantly related to stock performance. Furthermore, the stock return coefficients differ significantly (at the 10% level) from those in the Japanese regressions. Therefore, outside appointments in the U.S. are not as sensitive: to poor performance as in Japan In panel B, appointments of new outside directors as a percentage of initial outside directors in the U.S. are significantly related to current-period stock returns and negative income, as well as to sales growth lagged two years. [The results for stock returns and earnings changes are consistent with Hermalin and Weisbach (1988) who find that the number of new board appointments is negatively related to (industry-adjusted) stock returns, but not to earnings Logit - 0.04 - 0.29 0.24 Independent variables Stock return Same period One lag Two lags -- 0.010 - 0.072 0.060 Slop Model p = 0.57 CO.281 CO.271 co.251 [S.E.] (A) At least one new outside director -___ U.S. 0.08’ - 0.16 - o.04b 0.63 vs. p-value Japan CO.01 6) IO.016) [0.015] [S.E.J Model p = 0.14 - 0.028’ - 0.023 0.005 OLS (B) New outside directors (as fraction of ail outside directors) -- - 0.63 - 1.22 - 1.33 Logit - 0.012 - 0.023b - 0.025b Slope Model p = 0.07” CO.721 co.711 CO.721 [S.E.] 0.38 0.92 - 0.82 O.G7’ p-value Japan vs. U.S. (C) At least one new director affiliated with 5% blockholder Regression estimates of (A) the likelihood of an outside director appointment, (B) the fractional turnover of outside directors, and (C) the likelihood that a new director is affiliated with a 5% biockhoiCer by one-year periods for 146 US. firms as a function of sales growth, stock returns, earnings growth, and negative pre-tax income from 1980 to 1988. Panels A and C preb,t-nt loeit _ c regression estimates and standard errors. Slope measures the change in the probability of an appointment to is change in the independent variable implied by the iogit coeficients evaluated at sample means. Panel B reports coefficients and standard errors from OLS regressions. In ail panels, a separate regression is run for each performance measure. Ail regressions include dummy variables for the time period. Model p-value reports the joint significance level for the current and lagged values of the performance variable. The p-value Japan vs. U.S. reports the p-value of tests that the coefficients in the U.S. regressions in panel A and panei C (both individually and jointly) equal the coefficients in the Japanese regressions in panel A of T&le 2 for the iikebhood of a new outside appointment. Negative Japan vs. U.S. p-values indicate that the coefficient in Japan is less than the coefficient in the U.S. Regressions estimates of the likelihood of appointments of outside directors and directors affiliated with blockholders and performance in the U.S. Table 3 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. MintonlJournal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 -vr& - 000 c c‘!\99 o\-vr -0OrA . --c\J I . . I I TX%3 000 ddd I I I I 241 242 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Minton/ Journal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 changes.] A two-standard-deviation decline in stock returns (5 1%) is associated with a cumulative 2.6% increase in the percentage of new outside directors appointed versus an unconditional likelihood of 8.9%. Negative income is associated with an increase in the percentage of new outside directors of 3.0%. Although not directly comparable to the Japanese regression, these results indicate that the number of new appointments responds modestly to firm performance in the U.S. Panel C of Table 3 indicates that blockholder director appointments are significantly related to stock returns and sales growth, but not to negative income. In contrast to the results for ou~sidt; director appointments, joint tests fail to reject the restriction that all coeflicients for the individual performance variables in the U.S. blockholder equal those in the Japanese outside appointment regressions. In fact, the individual coefficients on two-year lagged stock returns and sales are more negative in the U.S. than in Japan. Blockholder appointments in the U.S., therefore, appear to be roughly equally sensitive to performance as outside appointments in Japan. It is worth noting, however, that blockholder appointments are appreciably less frequent, occurring less than 20% as often as outside appointments in Japan. As a result, the slope estimates in the respective regressions imply economically different responses to stock performance or negative income in the two countries. The sensitivities to stock returns in Japan (sum of - 0.195) imply that a 50% stock decline increases the likelihood of an outside appointment by 10% in Japan, compared to onlv 3% for a blockholder appointment in the U.S. (sum of - 0.060). Similarly, the iercit* iD..ivities imply that negative income in Japan increases the appointment likelihood by 13.2% versus 2.3% in the U.S. Over+, therefore, appointments of outside directors in U.S. firms are generally less sensitive to stock and earnings performance than are outside appointments in Japanese firms. Mockholder director appointments in U.S. firms are roughly as sensitive to firm performance as are outside appointments in Japanese firms, but are appreciably less frequent, occurring in 2.3% of firmyears in the U.S. versus 12.9% of firm-years in Japan. 4. Outside appointments, performance, arndrelationship variables The results in Section 3 indicate that outside board appointments in Japan are related to company stock performance and to low earnings. In this section, we add variables that measure the intensity of the Japanese governance relationships. This analysis can provide evidence as to whether outsiders are appointed in firms in which banks or other corporations have an ongoing financial interest. Adding the relationship variables also eliminates any s’purious correlations between appointments and performance tha,t may be driven by unobserved correlations between the relationship variables and financial performance. For S.N. Kaplan, B.A. MintonlJournal of Financiai Economics 36 (1994) 22.5-258 243 example, if firms with high debt tend to appoint bank directors and also tend to have negative income and poor stock returns, the regressions in Section 3 would find a spurious correlation between appointments and performance. To conserve space and focus on the stronger relations, we restrict performance measures to stock returns and negative current income for bank appointments, and to stock returns for corporate appointments. 4.1. Bank appointments Panel A of Table 4 presents estimates of the determinants of appointments of bank directors. The likelihood of a bank appointment is significantly related to firm stock returns m the previous year. Negative current income is also associated with an increased likelihood of a bank appointment of 3.4% in the same year and 2.0% in the following year, for a total increase of 5.4% (significant at 5%). Appointments of bank directors are significantly associated with the two measures of the strength of the main bank relationship. Bank appointments are most strongly associated (in terms of variation explained) with borrowings to total assets. In a given year, the likelihood of an a pointment of a bank director increases by 6.2% (significant at 1%) with a two-standard-deviation (36%) increase in borrowings to total assets. Bank appointments also are significantly related to the fraction of borrowings from the largest lender. A two-standarddeviation (14%) increase is associated with a 3.9% increase in the likelihood of a bank appointment. These patterns provide additional support for the view that bank directors are appointed when there is a bank loan to protect. In contrast, the appointment of bank directors is not related to the variables measuring shareholdings and group relationships. Although not reported, we obtain similarly insignificant results when we measure shareholdings as the equity owned by a firm’s main bank. 4.2. Corporate appointments Panel B of Table 4 presents estimates of the determinants of appointments of corporate directors. Again, stock performance remains significant in the presence of the relationship variables. The coefficients for the relationship variables are almost the mirror image of their values for bank appointments. The two ,main bank variables are not significantly related to corporate appointments. Instead, corporate appointments are strongly related to share ownership and to the two corporate group membership variables. The coefficient for the enterprise group variable is particularly noteworthy. The coefficient indicates that the likelihood of a corporate appointment is 18.4% greater for a member of an enterprise group. This is six 244 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Minton/ Journal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 Table 4 Regressions estimates of the likelihood of appointments of bank and corporate directors versus performance and relationship measures in Japan Logit regression estimates of the likelihood that a new director was (A) previously employed by a bank and (B) previously employed by a different nonfinancial corporation over one-year periods in Japanese firms as a function of performance and relationship measures for 119 Japanese firms from 1980 to 1988. For bank appointments, performance is measured by stock returns and negative current income; for corporate appointments, by stock performance only. Relationship measures are (i) total borrowings to total assets, (ii) the fraction of total borrowings lent by the largest lender, (iii) the percentage of shares owned by the ten largest shareholders, (iv) a dummy variable equal to one if Dodwell (1982) indicates the firm is associated with a financial group and equal to zero otherwise, and (v) a dummy variable equal to one if Dodwell (1982) indicates the firm is associated with an enterprise group and equal to zero otherwise. All estimations include dummy variables for the time period. Slope measures the change in the probability of an appointment to a change in the independent variable implied by the logit coefficients evaluated at sample means. Model p-value reports the joint significance level of the current and lagged coefficients of the performance variable. ___________~__~ _ _ -.____- (A) At least one new director previously employed by bank (B) At least one new director previously employed by nonfinancial corporation Independent variables Logit [S.E.] Logi t [S.E.] Stock return Same period One lag Two lags 0.27 - 1.30 0.61 [OS41 0.013 CO.573 - 0.067b co.541 0.032 - 1.54 - 1.21 0.37 CO.761 - 0.038b [0.7@] - 0.030’ 0.009 co.7 13 Slope Pre-tax income is negative Same period One lag 0.55 0.33 co.401 co.4 13 0.034 0.020 Total borrowings/total assets 3.37 [O.SI] 0.173” 0.80 Fraction of total borrowings from largest holder 5.50 c2.213 0.282b Percentage ownership top 10 shareholders - 0.51 Cl.061 Member financial group - 0.08 Member enterprise group 0.38 Slope CO.941 0.019 - 1.35 [2.15] 0.032 - 0.026 3.43 Cl.173 0.082” CO.301 - 0.004 1.35 co.401 0.030” co.401 2.74 [0.40] 0.184” 0.022 Model p = 0.01” Model p = 0.01” 0.075 0.059 Mean dependent variable N 933 - “Significantly different from zero at the 1% level. bSignificantly different from zero at the 5% level. ‘Significantly different from zero at the lO?b level. 93.3 - - S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Minton / Journal of Financial Economb 36 (1994) 225- 258 245 times greater than the 3.0% increase implied by the coefficient for financial group membership. These patterns provide further support for the view that the two types of appointments, although related to performance, serve different purposes and protect different interests. The results suggest that corporate appointments are meant to protect or support intercorporate shareholdings and relationships. Such appointments do not appear to be intended to protect the main bank. 4.3. Performance and relationshipinteractions The previous analyses do not allow for interactions between the performance and relationship variables. Previous work by Hoshi et al. (i991) and 1991)finds evidence of such interactions: Investment is less sensitive to internal cash flow and to financial distress for firms in financial groups and with strong main bank relationships. In this section we discuss (but do not report) the results of regressions that include performance and relationship variable interactions. For bank appointments, we run separate estimations foi (1) stock returns and (2) negative current income, and interact those variables with the two measures of borrowing intensity. For corporate appointments, we run estimations that interact qtock returns with shareholder concentraticn, financial group membership, and enterprise group membership. We + not find any significant interactions between the two performance variab. 5 and the two borrowing variables in the bank appointment estimations. It is possible that two characteristics of stronger bank relationships - greater incentives to send an appointment, but better information on the appointing firm - offset each other. The absence of an interaction is also consistent with Aoki et al. (1994), who argue that all firms have a main bank whether they have borrowings or not. For corporate appointments, we find a significant interaction between shareholdings of the top ten shareholders and stock returns in the same year. The coefficient indicates that corporate appointments are more sensitive to poor performance in firms with more concentrated shareholdings. This is consistent with larger ownership positions giving shareholders a greater incentive and greater power to send outside appointments after poor performance. 5. The impact of outside appointments on iucumbent managers The results in the previous sections indicate that outside appointments in Japanese firms increase significantly with poor firm performtince. Bank, shareholding, and group relationships a,lso play a role. As noted earlier, there are two interpretations of those results. 246 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Mintonl Journal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 One interpretation in that banks, corporate shareholders, and related corporations play a monitoring and disciplining role in Japanese corporate governance. One aspect of this role is to send directors to poorly performing companies to oversee or implement responses to that oar perfori3ance. Aoki et al. (1994) and Sheard (1994) describe how or t::ain bank’s power to have one of its employees appointed, often in spite uf opposition from incumbent management, comes from the bank’s position as lender, shareholder, and settler of intercorporate payment accounts. Similarly, the power of a corporate shareholder to have a director appointed stems from the shares it owns or controls. Under this interpretation, the bank and intercorporate relationships in Japan play a similar role to the external market for corporate control in the U.S. Alternatively, the appointment of an outsider in response to poor performance may be required to signal to suppliers, customers, or others that the bank, the related corporation, or the group is committed to supporting the appointing firm. According to this view, the main bank more than recoups any costs of such support by charging above-market fees for services in normal times. For corporate managers, such a support scheme is attractive because it provides support for their firm and their jobs when their firms experience difhculties. [See Coffee (1991) for a detailed discussion of this interpretation.] This second interpretation suggests that the primary role of an outside appointment is one of insurance, rather than discipline or monitoring. The fact that most outside appointments are at the level of director - not the more senior, representative director level - is, on the surface, consistent with this interpretation. The monitoring and insurance interpretations have different implications for incumbent management. If the relationships serve to insure managers, then the appointment of an outsider should not affect executive turnover. Alternatively, if the relationships serve to monitor and discipline management, then outside appointments should be associated with unusually high turnover of incumbent management. Accordingly, in this section, we test for abnormai top executive turnover in years of outside appointments. 5.1. Outside appointments and executive turnover In our tests of incumbent management turnover, we measure turnover in four ways: (I) turnover of the president, (2) nonstandard turnover of the president, (3) percentage turnover of representative directors, and (4) percentage turnover of all directors. We define presidential turnover as nonstandard when a president steps down and does not become chairman, because a president becomes the company’s chairman almost 70% of the time he relinquishes the presidency. Kaplan (1994) finds that nonstandard presidential turnover is more closely related to poor performance than overall presidential turnover. S.N. Kaplan, B.A. MintonlJournal of Financial Economics 36 (1994_.l 225-258 247 We regress these four measures of top executive turnover against a dummy variable that equals one if there is an outside appointment, and zero otherwise. We present results for one- and two-year periods. Because most firms appoint directors on two-year cycles, the one-year regressions include a duAmmy variable that indicates whether a firm is in the year of board appointments or in an off year. We assume a firm operates on an even-year (odd-year) cycle if the average number of directorship appointments over the entire sample period is greater in even (odd) years for that firm. The regressions also include dummy variables for president age, president tenure, and for the time period. [Kaplan (1994) finds that the age and tenure variables have significant explanatory power for top executive turnover in Japan. The time-period variables, as in the previous regressions, are meant to control for economy- or market-wide shocks.] Panel A of Table 5 presents the results for one-year periods. The results indicate economically and statistically significant increases in all four measures of execu:;ve turnover. Representative director turnover, for example, increases by 12.00%, 7.57%, and 10.07%, respectively, in the year a firm appoints a new bank director, a new corporate director, or either type of outside director. These increases are large relative to the average turnover of 14.36% per year. 5.2. Outside appointments, executive turnover, and performance Panel A indicates that outside appointments and abnormally high executive turnover coincide. The results in this paper and Kaplan (1994) document that both are associated with poor firm performance. To control for the possibility that outside appointments have no marginal effect on top executive turnover, we repeat the tests in panel A, controlling for stock performance and negative current income. Panel B of Table 5 presents the estimated increase in turnover controlling for performance. The coefficients decline slightly compared to those in panel A, but the results are similar. Turnover still increases significantly in the year of outside appointments. Although not reported, the coefficients on the performance variables are largely unaffected by the inclusion of the appointment dummy variables. It is possible that the types of firms that make outside appointments normally have high top executive turnover. To control for this, we repeated the analyses in this section using firm fixed effects (the equivalent of including dummy variables for each sample firm). This focuses on within-firm variation, eliminating variation across firms. We obtain qualitatively similar results. Panel C of Table 5 presents the analogous estimates for two-year periods. The coefficients for a bank appointment or for any outside appointment are similar to those in panel B. For corporate appointments, the coefficients for president and director turnover are smaller than over the one-year periods, while the coefficient for representative director turnover is larger. _.-_-_.___ ._.__ 8 080hb [4:15] 12.70” [4.64] 9.76” C3.27) New director from (outside) nonfinancial corporation New director from bank or (outside) nonfinancial corpordtion -- New director from bank (A) One-year periods, control for directorship cycle _ .---_-. Increase in % president turnover 4.15” co.9 1] 10.07” Cl.91J 7.17” [1.91-J 933-944 933-944 2.49’ C1.31) 7.57” C2.76) 3.04 C2.73) N 933-944 Increase in % director turnover 4 87%” [1:15] Increase in % representative director turnover 12.00%” C2.43J 10.08%” [2.41-J Increase in % nonstandard president turnover Increase in Iikelihood of president turnover, nonstandard president turnover, representative director turnover, and director turnover in periods when new directors are appointed who have (1) previous experience at banks, (2) previous experience at other nonfinancial companies, and (3) previous experience at either a bank or nonfinancial corporation. (President turnover is nonstandard when president gives up presidency, but does not become chairman.1 Reported increases in turnover are coefficients on dummy variables for outside appointments in OLS regressions in which management turnover measures are the dependent variables. Control for directorship cycle controls for whether the firm’s board is appointed on an even- or odd-year cycle. Controls for performance include stock performance and negative current income variables. The regressions also include dummy variables for president age, president tenure, and time period. The mean likelihood of president turnover, president turnover not becoming chairman, representative director turnover, and director turnover are, respectively, 15.1l%, 3.86%, 14.36%, and 12.05% over one year; 30.50%, 7.84%, 28.64%, and 2396% over two years. Standard errors are in brackets. The number of observations differs because president deaths are considered missing observations. -- --_-- Top executive turnover in years of outside appointments in Japan Table 5 periods, control for directorship from (outside) nonfinancial L. New director corporation Significantly “Significantly ‘Significantly - -- drflerent from zero at the 1% level. different from zero at the 5% level. different from zero at the 10% level. -.-- ~______ 3.74 [4.64-j 3. New director from bank or (outside) nonfinancial corporation _ - .- __I___l___________ 5.52’ [3.07] 2.19 [4.31-J 6.66 La.231 2. New drrector from (outside) nonfinancial curporat ion I. New director 7.70h [3.86-J Is, control for performance 5.50” [I.921 8.49b [3.34] 2.57% [S.SS J per] 2.67 C2.71J 7 64%” [2:46] 13.04” [4.68] 5.67% C4.281 from bank (C) Two-year 3. New director from bank or (outside) nonfinancial corporation from bank 1. New director cycle and performance (3) One-year ------- -- _- - _.-__. _ __- -_F___I_ __ 3.55” [1.29] 11.71” [2.88-j ___--_ 0.” 3 Cl.751 12.11” [3.91-J 3.19” co.90 3 9.36” Cl.943 5 05%” Cl:61 J 2.45’ [1.27-j 7.28” 12.761 9 78%” [3:65] 3 26%” [1:15-j 11 10%” [2:48 J 452-466 452-466 452-466 919-933 919-933 919-933 9 * 4 Z? .3 ? 250 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Minton/ Jb ,dmal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 Although mt reported in the table, we also estimated abnormal turnover in years of appointments of directors with previous government experience. Government appointments are associated with small declines, not increases, in standard president, nonstandard president, and representative director turnover, suggesting that government appointments play a different role than bank and corporate appointments. 5.3. Compariw to United Stala In this section, we estimate the relation between top execlltive turnover and outside ; ppointments in the U.S. to examine whether , ‘P- *ale of outside appoir tments in Japan and the U.S. are different. We use two measures of top executive turnover: CEO and executive director turnover. An executive director is both a current firm executive and a member of the board of directors, a definition similar to that of representative directors in Japan. The U.S. firms have a median of four executive directors. An executive director turns over when he loses his executive position, his board position, or both. CEO and executive director turnover average, respectively, 10.4% and 11.7’?/0 per year. We regress the two measures of top executive turnover against the measures of outside and blockholder appointments. The regressions include the performance variables associated with outside appointments - stock returns, sales growth, and negative inc ome - and dummy variables for CEO age, CEO tenure, and time period. Table 6 reports the results. They differ from those for outside appointments in Japan. Top executive turnover does not increase significantly with the appointment of at least one new outside director. For example, the coefficients associate a new outside appointment with only a 0.35% increase in executive director turnover. Similarly, the relation of top executive turnover to the percentage of outside director appointments is insignificant. For example, the coefficients imply that executive director turnover increases by only I.1 % in a year in which five new outside directors replace five of ten old outside directors. We find a somewhat stronger association between turnover and blockholder director appointments. At a one-year frequency, a blockholder appointment is associated witn an 8.17% increase in CEO turnover and a 4.64% increase in executive director turnover. The increases are not statistically significant. At the same time, however, the increases are not significantly different from the increases in president (8.49?%) and representative director turnover. (9.36%) associated with an outside appointment in Japan. At a two-year frequency, a blockholder appointment is associated with an increase of 20.83% in CEO turnover and 9.27% in executive director turnover (both significant at 10%). The increase in executive dkector turnover is similar to the 11.71% increase in representative director turnover associated with an outside appointment in Japan. Table 6 Top executive turnover in years of outside appointments in the U.S. The relation of CEO turnover and executive director turnover to (1) the appointment of any new outside director, (2) the fraction of new outside directors appointed, and (3) the appointment of a new director affiliated with a blockholder (of at least 5% of the firm’s equity) from 1980 to 1988 for 146 U.S. firms in the 1981 k‘urtrtrreMagazine listing of the 150 U.S. companies with the greatest sales. At least one new outside director is appointed La 51.5% of one-year periods and 76.4% of two-year periods; the percentage of new directors appointed is 8.9% and 17.6%, respectiveiy, in one- and two-year periods; and a blockholder-affiliated director is appointed in, respectively, 2.3% and 3.9% of one- and two-year periods. Reported increases in turnover are coefficients on variables for outside and blockholder appointments in OLS regressions in which management turnover measures are the dependent variables. Controls for performance include stock return, negative current income, and sales growth variables. The regressions also include dummy variables for CEO age, CEO tenure, and time period. The mean likelihood of CEO turnover and executive director turnover are, respectively, 10.4% and 11.7% over one year; 20.6% and 23.6% over two years. Standard errors are in brackets. The number of observations differs because CEO deaths are considered missing observations. Increase in % turnover of CEO increase in % turnover of executive directors At least one - -w outside director 1.45% Cl.831 0.35% p.131 978-981 New outside directors as % of initial outside directors 0.065 co.0793 0.022 [0.048] 978-98 1 At least one new director from blockholder 8.17 C6.083 4.64 [3.72] 978-98 1 0.70% [2.45] 481-484 0.02 1 CO.0661 481-484 9.27’ [5.58] _ -.- ______~_ 481-484 N (A) One-year periods, control for performance (B) Two-year periods, control for performance 1. At least one new outside director 3.95% [3.87] 2. New outside directors as % of initial outside directors 0.164 [O.1;35] 20.83b 3. At least one new director from [8.79] blockholder _ ____.__ --_- P_______-_P_ bSignifican t1y different from zero at the 5% level. ‘Significantly different from zero at the 10% level. -- --~ ----- -- Overall, these results provide additional evidence that outside appointments in the U.S. play a different role from those in Japan. Unlike in Japan, appointments of outside directors are not associated with increased turnover of incumbent top executives. Blockholder appointments are both less strongiy associated with increased executive turnover and, as noted previously, much less frequent than outside appointments in Japan. 252 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. Minton/ Journal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 5.4. Dismssion Outside appointments in Japan are associated with poor firm performance, and such appointments coincide with unusually high turnover of incumbent management. Taken together, these results are consistent with an important monitoring and disciplining role for banks, corporate shareholders, and corporate groups. It is important to stress that it is not critical for our purposes that the outside appointments be the actual instruments of discipline or monitoring. Our only assumption is that outside appointments indicate that the main bank, corporate shareholder, or corporate group is paying particular attention to the appointing firm. Nevertheless, anecdotal and case evidence from Aoki et al. (1994), Sheard (1994), and bankers in private conversations suggest that outside directors initially perform a monitoring role, providing information to the previous employers, as well as identifying and firing poorly yerforming managers. That an outside director in Japan performs these functions and gives his primary allegiance, at least initially, to his old company rather than to the appointing company should not be surprising. A main bank, with the ability to withhold funds, and a corporate shareholder, with the ability to exercise shareholder votes, can present real and cost ixr f threats to an outside director and incumbent managers at a poorly perf:rl ail.;;:; 5,i. The differences between Jan~n ci;id ?i~ tJ,S. are also consistent with bank and intercorporate relationships su BS.__;.utiq $12scrn~ extent for an external market for corporate control. While outsi& q?tMntl;zents tied to a lending or shareholding relationship were much morz i;ommon in Japan, the external market for corporate control was much more active in the U.S. during the sample period. Only 2.5% of the Japanese firms were taken over, compared to 21.9% of the U.S. firms. This understates the differences in external pressure (versus monitoring from ongoing relationships) because it excludes unfriendly blockholder share accumulations and unsuccessful takeover attempts, which are virtually unknown in Japan. 6. Pre- and post-appointment financial performance If outside appointments in Japan are disciolinary, the appointments ought to reverse, or at east stop, the deterioration in k3or firm performance. Accordingly, we estimate the abnormal pre- and post-appointment performance of firms that appoint outside directors. We perform these estimations separately for bank and corporate appointments because the two types of appointments raicly coincide, and, therefore may be motivated by different internal problems? 6M~rck and Wakamura (1993) perform a simiiar analysis fcjr financial performance after bank appointments and find qualitatively similar results. S.IU. Kaplan, B.A. Minton / Journal of Financial Economics 36 i 1994) 225-258 253 We calculate abnormal performance for each of the seven years from year - 1 to year +5, where year 0 is the base firm-year. We regress firm perfcrmance: for year t against dummy variables for the calendar year, and for whether the firm made the relevant outside appointment. Abnormal performance is estimated as the coefficient on the outside appointment dummy variable. The abnormal performance estimate for year t, therefore, measures the average difference in performance between firms that made the relevant outside appointment in year 0 and firms that did not. Because the regressions include calendaryear dummy variables, abnormal performance is relative to the average performance of all firms in a given calendar year. Panel A of Table 7 presents the results for bank appointments. Sales growth is negative from the year before the appointment through two years after; the decline in year + 1 is significant. Asset growth is negative in all six years from year - 1 to year + 4, with two of those declines being significant. The declines finally reverse in year + 5. The ratio of current income to assets follows a similar patterir. In all seven years presented, current income to assets is significantly negative (i.e., less than market) for the sample firms. The ratio improves (i.e., moves closer to zero), although not significantly, from - 1.99% in year + 1 to - 1.04% in year _p 5. Finally, stock returns are significantly negative in the year before a bank director is appointed. In the years that follow, the returns do not differ significantly from zero. Panel B reports the analogous patterns for firms with corporate appointments. Firms making corporate appointments do not appear to be contracting or financially distressed. Pre-tax income to assets is not significantly different from that of the average firm, and is significantly greater than that of firms with bank appointments. Instead, changes in pre-tax income are negative in both the year before and the year of the corporate appointments. (The sum of the changes is significantly negative at the 10% level.) In the same two years, company stock returns are significantly negative. After year 0, none of the performance measures differ significantly from zero except for sales and asset growth in year + 1, which equal 2.39% and 2.51% (significant at 10% )*Those two growth rates also exceed growth after bank appointments (at the 5% level). The results in Table 7 suggest that bank directors are appointed to firms that are contracting or in financial distress. After the bank directors arrive, these firms continue to contract, but their performance - as measured by stock returns and earnings changes - does not deteriorate. Corporate directors, in contrast, appear to be appointed to firms with other problems that may be partially earnings related. After the corporate dirF;ictors arrive, the firm sales and asset growth rebound, and their performance - as measured by stock returns and earnings - does not deteriorate; if anything, it improves. For these firms, there is no evidence of the sustained decline or contraction present in firms that appoint bank directors. I j’ear + 5 Year + 4 Year + 3 Year + 2 Year + I Year 0 \rcar - I .90 il. 15 - 3.45’ [l.SSJ 2.43 [ I.863 1.73 [ I .66] r 1.661 - [ 1.533 [ 1.56) 1.56 - 3.00h 0.32 [ 1.37-J [ I .24] [I .29] - - 3.94’” 2.32’ -(1.39, - - 1.48 [ 1.281 Il.311 - 0.57 1.53 [ 1.35) - Asset growth (in o/o) [ I .37] -- 0.X6 Sales growth (in %) (A) At least one ncu director appointed from bank co.413 0.15 0.20 CO.361 10.341 -- 0.11 10.3 I] 0.40 - 0.09 [O.291 10.25) - 0.13 LO.26J 037 Change pretax income to assets (in o/o) 1.77” l.41b [O.SS] LO.531 1.99” [0.53;] 1.90” co.553 - - 1.04” [O.641 l.22h [0.60-- -- 1.27h [0.59 J - - - - Pretax income to assets (in o/o) - - [4.59] 2.88 E4.001 1.00 [3.71] 3.22 13.38-j - 0.17 - 0.02 13.141 C3.021 0.00 [ 3.073 - 8.21” Stock ret urn (in o/o) 41 458 585 48 53 702 62 819 936 72 935 72 72 934 N = All firm-years N = Rank appointments Abnormrrl firm sales growth, asset growth, change in prc-tax income to assets, prc-tax income Icvcls,and stock r&urns before and after appointments of directors with previous experience at banks or other nonfinancial corporations for 119 Japanese firms from 1980 to 1988. Sales and asset growth are, rcspectivcly, the annual change in (log) sales and total assets. Change in pre-tax income to assets is the annual change in the ratio of pretax income to total assets. Abnormal performance is the coefficient [and standard error] from ;L regression of pcerformanccagainst a dummy variable for the relevant atside appointment. The rcgrcssions include dummy variables for the c&n&r year, so performance is rclativc to average performance for all firms in a given year. Year 0 is the year of the appointment. Abnormal firm pcrformancc around years of outside director appointments in Japan z < 2 $ i . 3 s * f/, :< S. N. Kaplan, B.A. Min ton/ Journal of Financial Economics 36 ( 1994) 225-258 - c2 . . O- o,Ez . . &l . . OCCI u I- -z -7 O- n r‘. U zig . . s;E -r-i O- 0 u 255 256 S.N. Kaplan. B.A. Minton/ Journal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 7. Changes in performance-appointment relations over time Some authors have argued that the deregulation of the corporate bond market in Japan, which began in the early 1980~~has led to a weakening of the corporate relationships in Japan, particularly those between firms and their main banks. For example, Hoshi, Kashyap, and Scharfstein (1993) find that healthier firms reduced their reliance on bank borrowings in the 1980s. They conjecture that this may have weakened the ability of banks to monitor or intervene in firms’ management. Similarly, Kester (1991) argues that deregulation, as well as the operating successes of Japanese companies in the 198Os, allowed those companies to reduce their bank debt, and thus allowed managers to distance themselves from monitoring by the main bank and other firms. If these arguments are correct, appointments of bank and corporate directors should be less sensitive to performance in the latter part of the 1980s than in the earlier rPrt. We test for a declining sensitivity by estimating appointment-performance regressions that allow for an interaction between time and performance. The interaction terms equal the product of the performance variables and a dummy variable for the period that equals one for firm-years in the latter half of our sample, from 1985 to 1988. We use both stock returns and negative current income as performance variables. If the reLtion between appointments and performance deteriorated over the 198Os, the coefficients on these interaction terms should be positive. We find no evidence of a deterioration in appointment-performance sensitivity. None of the coefficients on the interaction terms in any of our estimations is significant. At the same time, the coefficients on the noninteracted performance variables are almost identical to their values in Table 2. While we recognize that our test using only eight years of data may have limited power to detect a slow deterioration, it is precisely over those eight years that relationships are alleged to have weakeired. 8. Summarv. and discussion This paper has examined the determinants and implications for managers of appointments of bank and corporate directors in Japanese firms. Appointments of both types of directors increase significantly with poor stock performance; those of bank directors increase with negative current income as well. Such appointments are also associated with variables measuring the intensity of the relationships governing Japanese firms. We distinguish between monitoring and insurance interpretations of outside appointments by considering the implications of those appointments for incumbent managers of the sample firms. Top executive turnover increases substantially in years of outside appointments. We also compare the post-appointment performance of firms appointing outside S.N. Kaplan. B.A. MintonlJournal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 257 directors with the performance of the other Japanese firms. Performance does not deteriorate, but improves modestly after outside appointments. In large U.S. firms, the patterns are different. Appointments of outside directors in U.S. firms are both less sensitive to performawe and less strongly associated with top executive turnover than in Japanese firms. While blockholder director appointments in the U.S. are both sensitive to performance and somewhat related to top executive turnover, such appointments are relatively infrequent. These patterns are consistent with an important monitoring and disciplining role for banks, corporate shareholders, and corporate groups in Japan. The results are also consistent with the view that the relationship-oriented system of corporate governance in Japan substitutes for the more marketoriented system in the U.S. Banks, corporate shareholders, and corporate groups appear to play a role that is similar to that of takeovers and proxy tights in the U.S. We are unable to say, however, which of the two systems is more effective. The results in this paper complement and extend those in Kaplan (1994) and Merck and Nakamura (1993). Kaplan (1994) documents that top executive turnover and compensation in Japanese firms are related to firm earnings and stock performance, particularly to low earnings. Both Kaplan (1994) and Merck and Nakamura (1993) find that appointments of bank directors increase significantly with poor stock performance and with low earnings. Neither paper, however, considers the impact of bank or outside appointments on incumbent managers, and therefore neither distinguishes between the two interpretations of such appointments. Our results strongly suggest that pressures from banks, corporate shareholders, and corporate groups play an important Cole in linking firm performance and managerial rewards. Finally, our results, like those in Kaplan (1994), dispute one of the supposedly major advantages of Japanese corporate governance - the ability to ignore short-term measures of performance. Current earnings and, particularly, current stock returns are important determinants of outside appointments in Japan. We favor a simple interpretation to reconcile our results to the widely-held view that Japanese managers are more long-term-oriented than their U.S. counterparts a company’s current stock price provides a good measure of its current and future prospects. References Abegglen, James and George Stalk, 1985, Kaisha, the Japanese corporation (Basic Books, New York, NY). Analysts’ Guide, 1989 (Daiwa Institute of Research, Tokyo). Aoki, Masahiko, 1990, Towards an economic model of the Japanct5e firm, Journal of Economic Literature 28, 1-27. 258 S.N. Kaplan, B.A. M:rt,*on/Journal of Financial Economics 36 (1994) 225-258 Aoki, Masahiko, Hugh Patrick, and Paul Sheard, 1994,The Japanese main bank system: An introductory overview, in: Masahiko Aoki and Hugh Patrick, eds., The Japanese main bank system: relevancy for developing and transforming economies (Oxford University Press, Oxford). Ballon, Robert and Iwao Tomita, 1988, The financial behavior of Japanese corporations (Kodans International, Tokyo). Blinder, Alan, 1992, More like them, The American Prospect, Winter, 51-62. Coffee, John, 1991, Liquidity versus control: The institutional investor as corporate monitor, Columbia Law Review 6, 1277-1368. Diamond’s Kaisha Yoran Zenjojo Kaishaban. 1980 to 1990 (in Japanese). Diamond’s Kaisha Shokuin Roku, 1980 to 1990 (in Japanese). Dodwell Marketing Consultants, 1982, Industrial groupings in Japan (Dodweil, Tokyo). Gerlach, Michael, 1993, Alliance capitalism: The social organization of Japanese business (University of California Press, Berkeley CA). Grundfest, Joseph, 1990, Subordination of American capital, Journal of Financial Economics 27, 89-116. Heftel, Christopher, 1983, Corporate governance in Japan, University of Hawaii Law Review 5, 135-206. Hermalin, Benjamin and Michael Weisbach, 1988; The determinants of board composition, Rand Journal of Economics 19, 589-606. Hoshi, Takeo, Anil Kashyap, and David Scharfstein, 1990, The role of banks in reducing the costs of financial distress in Japan, Journal of Financial Economics 27, 67-88. Hoshi, Takeo, Anil Kashyap, and David Scharfstein, 1991, Corporate structure, liquidity, and investment: Evidence from Japanese panel data, Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 33-60. Hoshi, Takeo, Anil Kashyap, and David Scharfstein, 1993, The choice between public and private debt: An analysis of post-deregulation corporate financing in Japan, NBER working paper, July. Kaplan, Steven, 1994, Top executive rewards and firm performance: A comparison of Japan and the U.S., Journal of Political Economy 102. Kester, W. Carl, 1991, Japanese takeovers: The global contest for corporate control (Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA). Kigyo Keiretsu Soran, 1982, 1985, and 1988 (in Japanese). Merck, Randall and Masao Nakamura, 1993, Banks and corporate control in Japan, Working paper (University of Alberta, Edmonton). Nakatani, I., 1984, The economic role of financial corporate grouping, in: M. Aoki, ed., Economic analysis of the Japanese firm (Elsevier, New York, NY). Porter, Michael, 1992, Capital disadvantage: America’s failing capital investment system, Harvard Business Review, Sept.-Oct., 65-83. Prowse, Stephen, 1990, Institutional investment patterns and corporate financial behavior in the U.S. and Japan, Journal of Financial Economics 27, 43-66. Prowse, Stephen, 1992, The structure of corporate ownership in Japan, Journal of Finance 47, 1121- 1140. Ramseyer, J. Mark, 1994,Explicit reasons for implicit contracts: The legal logic to the Japanese main bank system, in: Masahiko Aoki and Hugh Patrick, eds., The Japanese main bank system: Its relevancy for developing and transforming economies (Oxford University Press, Oxford). Sheard, Paul, 1989, The main bank system and corporate monitoring and control in Japan, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 11, 399-422. Sheard, Paul, 1994, Main banks and the governance of financial distress, in: Masahiko Aoki and Hugh Patrick, eds., The Japanese main bank system: Its relevancy for developing and transforrr?ing economies (Oxford University Press, Oxford). Weisbach, Michael, 1988, Outside directors and CEO turnover, Journal of Financial Economics 20, 431-460. Yuka Shaken Hokokusho, 1982, 1984, and 1988 (in Japanese).