FARM OPERATIONS, FARM OPERATORS, AND COMMODITY PAYMENTS IN 2007: A STATISTICAL AND GEOSPATIAL APPROACH A THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE GRADUATE SCHOOL IN PARTIAL FULLFILMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE MASTER OF SCIENCE NATURAL RESOURCE AND ENVIRONMENTAL MANAGEMENT BY DAVA R. MCCANN DR. AMY GREGG DR. JOSHUA GRUVER BALL STATE UNIVERSITY MUNCIE, INDIANA DECEMBER 2012 2 FARM OPERATIONS, FARM OPERATORS, AND COMMODITY PAYMENTS IN 2007: A STATISTICAL AND GEOSPATIAL APPROACH A THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE GRADUATE SCHOOL IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE MASTER OF SCIENCE NATURAL RESOURCES AND ENVIRONMENTAL MANAGEMENT BY DAVA R. MCCANN Committee Approval: Committee Chairperson Date Committee Member Date Committee Member Date Departmental Approval: Departmental Chairperson Date Dean of Graduate School Date BALL STATE UNIVERSITY MUNIE, INDIANA (DECEMBER 2012) 3 Abstract The Farm Bill is a large omnibus bill that covers many titles, including commodity programs, and accounted for $23.9 billion in government spending in 2006. The purposes of this study are to determine if commodity variables are the only variables that are closely correlated to government commodity payments, and if government payments are distributed equitably by Farm Resource Region, based on the inequitable distribution of payments cited by other researchers. Data included economics, operator characteristics, farm typologies, tenure, and geographic variables. Kendall’s correlations and location quotients examined the relationship between these variables and government payments. Choropleth maps were created to visually examine the relationships. This study found that corn, soybean, wheat, and cropland variables were strongly correlated to government payment variables, supporting the hypothesis. However, other variables were also strongly correlated to government payment variables, and payments varied widely by Farm Resource Region. The hypotheses were rejected. 4 Acknowledgements It is a great pleasure to give respect to the people who made this thesis possible. I owe sincere gratitude to Dr. Joshua Gruver, Dr. Amy Gregg, and Dr. James Eflin, without whom this thesis would never have come to fruition. I would like to express my thankfulness to my family and friends for their unending support over these past years. I would also like the thank Dr. Paul Chandler, who had nothing to do with this thesis but so much to do with growth throughout my formal education at Ball State University. 5 Table of Contents Abstract .............................................................................................................................. iii Acknowledgements............................................................................................................ iv List of Tables .................................................................................................................... vii List of Figures ..................................................................................................................... x Chapter I: Introduction........................................................................................................ 1 Statement of the Problem ................................................................................................ 1 Purpose of the Study ....................................................................................................... 2 Methods........................................................................................................................... 4 Chapter II: Literature Review ............................................................................................. 6 History of the Farm Bill .................................................................................................. 6 Farm Security and Rural Investment Act........................................................................ 9 Broader Implications of the Farm Bill .......................................................................... 11 Previously Cited Problems Derived from the Farm Bill............................................... 16 Farm Resource Regions ................................................................................................ 19 Chapter III: Methods......................................................................................................... 23 Data ............................................................................................................................... 23 6 Analysis......................................................................................................................... 26 Chapter IV: Results........................................................................................................... 32 Salient Variables ........................................................................................................... 33 National ......................................................................................................................... 34 County Level Analysis.................................................................................................. 35 Government Payment Variables ............................................................................... 36 Economic Variables .................................................................................................. 42 Occupation and Tenure Variables............................................................................. 54 Typology Variables................................................................................................... 67 Commodity Variables ............................................................................................... 81 Farm Resource Regions .............................................................................................. 102 Chapter V: Discussion and Conclusion .......................................................................... 115 Relation to Previous Studies ....................................................................................... 119 Broader Implications of the Farm Bill ........................................................................ 122 Future Research .......................................................................................................... 128 References ....................................................................................................................... 130 Appendix A ..................................................................................................................... 134 Appendix B ..................................................................................................................... 140 Appendix C ..................................................................................................................... 158 7 List of Tables Table 1. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of farms with commodity payments by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .37 Table 2. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of commodity payments by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 Table 3. The mean, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of income dependence by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .41 Table 4. The mean, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of market value by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43 Table 5. The mean, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranking of gross income by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .45 Table 6. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of production expenses by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 Table 7. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of net income by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52 Table 8. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of farming occupation by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54 8 Table 9. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of part owner farms by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .56 Table 10. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of part owner farm acres by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59 Table 11. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of tenant farms by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .61 Table 12. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of tenant farm acres by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .64 Table 13. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of small family higher sales farms by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .67 Table 14. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of large family farms by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70 Table 15. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of large family farm acres by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72 Table 16. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of very large family farms by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75 Table 17. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of very large family farm acres by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77 Table 18. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of corn farms by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81 Table 19. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of corn farm acres by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .85 9 Table 20. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of soybean farms by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .86 Table 21. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of soybean farm acres by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90 Table 22. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of wheat farms by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91 Table 23. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of wheat farm acres by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .93 Table 24. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of total cropland farms by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97 Table 25. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of total cropland farm acres by Farm Resource Region. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98 Table 26. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Heartland. . . . . . . . . .102 Table 27. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Northern Crescent. . . 103 Table 28. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Northern Great Plains. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104 Table 29. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Prairie Gateway. . . . .105 Table 30. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Eastern Uplands. . . . .107 Table 31. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Southern Seaboard. . .108 Table 32. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Fruitful Rim. . . . . . . .109 Table 33. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Basin and Range. . . . 110 Table 34. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Mississippi Portal. . . 111 1 List of Figures Figure 1. The Farm Resource Regions as created by the Economic Research Service. . 19 Figure 2. The location quotient of farms receiving commodity payments was highest on average in the Heartland, Northern Great Plains, and Prairie Gateway region. . . . . . . . .36 Figure 3. The location quotients of commodity payment dollars were highest in the Heartland, Southern Seaboard, and Mississippi Portal. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38 Figure 4. The location quotients of income dependence was highest in the Mississippi Portal, Heartland, and Prairie Gateway. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 Figure 5. The mean location quotient of market value of agricultural products sold was highest in the Fruitful Rim, Northern Crescent, and Southern Seaboard. . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 Figure 6. The location quotients of gross income were highest in the Northern Crescent, followed by the Fruitful Rim and Southern Seaboard. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .46 Figure 7. The location quotients of production expenses were above normal in the Fruitful Rim, Northern Crescent, Southern Seaboard, and Heartland. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .49 Figure 8. The location quotients of net income of operation were highest in the Fruitful Rim, Northern Crescent, and Heartland. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .51 Figure 9. The location quotients of farming occupation were above normal in the Northern Great Plains. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 Figure 10. The location quotients of part owner farms were above normal in the Northern Great Plains and below normal in the Fruitful Rim. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .57 11 Figure 11. The location quotients of part owner farm acres were lowest in the Fruitful Rim. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .60 Figure 12. The location quotients of tenant farms were highest in the Mississippi Portal and lowest in the Eastern Uplands. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .62 Figure 13. The location quotients of tenant farm acres were above normal only in the Mississippi Portal. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .65 Figure 14. The location quotients of small family farming occupation higher sales farms were above normal in the Northern Great Plains and Heartland. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .68 Figure 15. The location quotients of large family farms were highest in the Northern Great Plains and Heartland, and lowest in the Eastern Uplands. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71 Figure 16. The location quotients of large family farm acres were highest in the Northern Great Plains and Heartland. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73 Figure 17. The location quotients of very large family farms were above normal in the Northern Great Plains, Heartland, and Mississippi Portal. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .76 Figure 18. The location quotients of very large family farm acres were above normal in the Mississippi Portal, Heartland, and Northern Great Plains. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .78 Figure 19. The location quotients of corn farms were highest in the Heartland. . . . . . . .82 Figure 20. The location quotients of corn acres were highest in the Heartland and the Northern Crescent. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84 Figure 21. The location quotients of soybean farms per county were highest in the Heartland followed distantly by the Mississippi Portal. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .87 Figure 22. The location quotients of soybean acres were highest in the Heartland and Mississippi Portal. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .89 12 Figure 23. The location quotients of wheat farms were highest in the Northern Great Plains and Prairie Gateway. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92 Figure 24. The location quotients of wheat acres were highest in the Northern Great Plains and Prairie Gateway. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94 Figure 25. The location quotients of total cropland farms were normal for all regions. .96 Figure 26. The location quotients of total cropland acres were highest in the Heartland, Northern Crescent, and Mississippi Portal. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .99 Chapter I: Introduction The United States Department of Agriculture’s (USDA) 2002 Farm Security and Rural Investment Act, better known as the Farm Bill, is an omnibus bill that contains legislation controlling forestry, agricultural trade, energy and fuels development, conservation, agricultural commodity production, and nutrition and food distribution programs such as food stamps. The Farm Bill is of interest to people because it directly affects the food system of the United States, the food security of millions of Americans, and federal spending of taxpayer dollars as income to people and agribusinesses enrolled in conservation and commodity programs. The purpose of this study is to determine if commodity payments are distributed inequitably, like previous researchers suggest, based on farm operator and operation variables and Farm Resource Regions. Statement of the Problem When Farm Bill legislation began in1933, the government attempted to control the supply of commodities by providing price support to farmers who participated in voluntary production reduction programs. It was an effort to provide financial security to the 25 percent of the U.S. population residing on farms by reducing commodity surpluses. In the 1970s, the Farm Bill was revolutionized into direct payments to people 2 who produced certain commodities, thereby reinvigorating the surpluses of these certain commodities. By the 2002 Farm Bill, the social goal of saving the family farm had transformed to the economic goal of mitigating financial risks for farm businesses, despite numerous objections to the legislation (Flinchbaugh and Knutson, 2004). This shift in goals resulted in: (1), the absorption of small farms into large agricultural businesses (Goodwin, 2000); (2), the limited number of farms reached by government payments (Westcott & Young, 2000); (3), increased dependence on government payments for income (Barnard, Nehring, & Collender, 2001); (4), increased farmland values based on government payments (Barnard et. al, 2001; Burfisher & Hopkins, 2003); and (5), payments being received by non-family or very large family farms that do not need income support, thereby leaving out small family and limited resource farms (Hoppe & MacDonald, 2001). In 2007, farm support subsidies provided for by the 2002 Farm Bill accounted for $11.2 billion in government spending with over $8 billion paid in commodity subsidies (Chite, 2008). The Farm Bill is due to be rewritten in 2012. According to the Congressional Budget Office, the Farm Bill will be up for budget cuts. Exploring the complexity of factors related to the commodity payments of the Farm Bill will provide insight in the efficacy of the legislation. Purpose of the Study The purpose of this research is to explore the previously cited inequitable distribution of Farm Bill program payments. In order to do this, this research seeks to determine the farm and land, economic, operator characteristic, geographic, commodity, and farm organization and typology variables that are related to government commodity 3 payments and to examine these relationships by Farm Resource Regions. In other words, is commodity production the only variable that influences participation in programs and distribution of program payments? Commodity payments are calculated by the USDA using set target prices or payment rates for certain commodities as well as the acreage and the yield of the commodity produced. Therefore, the only variables that directly affect commodity payments are variables based on the commodities covered under the program. However, previous studies show that certain types of farm operators, such as renters (Monke, 2004), and farm typologies, such as nonfamily or very large family (Hoppe & MacDonald, 2001), are underrepresented in terms of payments received. This study analyzes if commodity production is the only variable correlated to government payment, or if there are other variables also correlated to payments. By combining geospatial and statistical analysis of farm data, including operator characteristics and economic variables, this study provides a unique contribution to the literature. The hypotheses that only commodity variables are strongly correlated to commodity payment variables and the payments are equitably distributed based on Farm Resource Region are based on the previous research that suggests that distribution of program payments is inequitable. The Farm Bill directly affects the food system and food security of Americans. Not only does it directly determine the price of food, but also indirectly impacts the types of food (whole versus processed) available to and consumed by Americans by artificially deflating the price of meat and processed foods (Pollan, 2007). The Farm Bill is indirectly linked to both obesity and heart disease in Americans (“Fresh Fruit”, 2012). However, it also affects the food system and food security of other developing nations 4 (Pollan, 2007). It distorts trade, depresses world prices of agricultural products (Mayrand et al., 2003), and cotton subsidies have been ruled illegal by the World Trade Organization (Pollan, 2004). The Farm Bill also directly affects soil land and water resources by promoting agricultural intensification (Plantinga, 1996), and encourages the addition of chemicals that cause pollution (Lingard, 2002). Methods This study used data collected by the National Agricultural Statistics Service (NASS) in the 2007 Census of Agriculture. The Census is conducted once every five years. Kendall’s rank correlations identified trends on the national level between payment variables and other operator and farm characteristic variables. Descriptive statistics identified operator and farm characteristics that vary by Farm Resource Region (FRR), regions created by the Economic Research Service (ERS) to group geographic areas with similar farm productions, performance, and economics. Location quotients determined counties and Farm Resource Regions where operator and farm characteristics, and payment variables were concentrated or underrepresented. Kendall’s correlations were also calculated to determine trends among the location quotients of variables on the national level and by Farm Resource Region. County level choropleth maps were created to provide a spatial representation of these variables at the county level. To limit this study to the most salient variables, only those variables with strong national correlations were included in this paper. Chapter II: Literature Review The Farm Security and Rural Investment Act of 2002, better known as the Farm Bill, contains legislation to provide government payments to farmers to increase farm financial security, to mitigate for financial risks inherent in agricultural production, and to promote conservation. These price and income support programs, started in the 1930s to relieve disparity between farm and non-farm incomes (Gardner, 1992), continue today despite the fact that this disparity is no longer as great of a concern (Goodwin, 2000; Mishra et. al, 2002). Numerous objections have been voiced against the Farm Bill, including the inequitable distribution of payments (Hoppe & MacDonald, 2001). The purpose of this study is to examine the disparity in government payments suggested by previous researchers based on numerous variables, including Farm Resource Regions. History of the Farm Bill Farm Bill programs, as most people think of them, have their origins in the New Deal legislation of the Great Depression. The 1933 Agricultural Adjustment Act (AAA, 1933), set in motion by Secretary of Agriculture Henry A. Wallace, was an attempt to increase the value of agricultural products. The government enacted price supports to guarantee that commodity prices did not fall below a set level for producers 6 who voluntarily participated in production reduction programs (Cain & Lovejoy, 2004). When commodity prices fell below the target, the government purchased these commodities from participating farmers and stored them. This led to large government stocks of commodities significant enough to start many domestic and international food distribution programs (Flinchbaugh & Knutson, 2004). Over the years the price support guarantee was offered to farmers who participated in conservation programs instead of production reduction programs (Cain & Lovejoy, 2004). In 1935, the Soil Conservation Act (SCA, 1935) established the Soil Conservation Service (SCS). This made money available to farmers who established soil conservation practices from payments through the SCS. The 1936 Soil Conservation and Domestic Allotment Act (SCDAA, 1936) attempted to protect land resources from soil erosion by paying farmers to replace soil depleting crops with cover crops. These soil depleting crops (i.e., corn, cotton, wheat) were also in surplus. This was an attempt to control surplus, commodity prices, and soil conservation. However, this did not stop the surplus. Farmers would enroll their worst land in conservation programs and use the payments to buy machinery and fertilizer to increase yields on their land still in production (Cain & Lovejoy, 2004). The 1956 Agricultural Act (AA, 1956) created the Soil Bank and took 29 million acres out of production to decrease surpluses and protect soil from erosion even further than previous Farm Bills. This bill paid farmers for conservation improvements on land that they could not harvest or graze for three years. During the 1970s, under Secretary Earl L. Butz, the price support system that began in the New Deal era was revolutionized into an income support system. These programs created target prices and loan rates for agricultural commodities that paid 7 farmers when commodity prices fell below these set targets, much the same way programs pay farmers today. The most revolutionary part of this shift was that money was transferred from the government directly to the farmer neither for commodities that the government was purchasing nor for conservation efforts. The inception of these programs affected planting decisions as farmers were more likely to plant commodities that would yield the highest government payment (Flinchbaugh & Knutson, 2004). This shift in the way money was transferred to farmers was accompanied by a shift in conservation practices as well. To accommodate the increased world demand on food, the Secretary of Agriculture told American farmers to plant from fence row to fence row, thus damaging the conservation efforts made so far by the Farm Bill. Farmers met the needs by adding their few remaining acres of idled cropland, woodland, and grassland into production. In fact, a 1977 Congressional survey found that 26 percent of farmers who had participated in the Great Plains Conservation Program, set up in the 1940s, took their new conservation grasslands out of the program for wheat production (Cain & Lovejoy, 2004). The 1985 Farm Bill (FSA, 1985) was the first one to have a separate title for conservation and attempted to again make the conservation advancements that were interrupted in the 1970s. It introduced Sodbuster, Swampbuster, Conservation Reserve Program (CRP), and Conservation Compliance to the legislation. Payments were no longer made to people based on a voluntary conservation program. In fact, violation of conservation practices set forth in the Farm Bill now meant heavy penalties. These included not only loss of price-support program income but also the loss of crop insurance benefit payments, and commodity loans (Cain & Lovejoy, 2004). 8 The 1996 Federal Agriculture Improvement and Reform Act (FAIRA, 1996) was an attempt to make the Farm Bill more market oriented (Goodwin, 2000). Planting decisions had been linked to income support programs since the 1970s. The new bill attempted to allow farmers to plant what they wanted based on market prices instead of price and income support programs (Flinchbaugh & Knutson, 2004). This new bill also cut the grain reserve program, thereby inducing farmers to plant as much as they could, creating a surplus as well as a drop in grain prices. In 1998 the government enacted adhoc emergency payments to support farm income (Imhoff, 2012c). Under the 2002 Farm Bill, these ad-hoc programs were made permanent. This lead to the adoption of policy that no longer attempted to control supply and price, but rather a policy that encourages low prices and market instability and then supports income to the farmer in the form of subsidies (Imhoff, 2012c). Also, the goal of decoupling payments, removing the ties between payments and price or production, was pushed even further, though still was not successful. Payments were made directly to farmers based on set payment rates for a commodity, even if that commodity was not currently produced (Monke, 2004) This, in effect, decoupled payments from production. However, there were still programs, (e.g., Counter Cyclical Income Support Program, Marketing Assistance Loans, and Loan Deficiency Payments) which were still tied to commodity prices. Since payments were made when commodity prices fell below set prices, technically, the 2002 Farm Bill still has not fully decoupled payments (Flinchbaugh & Knutson, 2004). 9 Farm Security and Rural Investment Act The 2002 Farm Bill includes ten titles covering Commodity Programs, Conservation, Trade, Nutrition Programs, Credit, Rural Development, Agricultural Research, Forestry, and Energy (FSRIA, 2002). This research is concerned with the first title. Title I Commodity Programs include: Fixed Direct Payments (DP), Counter Cyclical Income Support Program (CCP), Marketing Assistance Loans (MALs), Loan Deficiency Payments (LDP), Sugar, and Dairy. Direct Payments (DPs) replaced Production Flexibility Contracts in the 2002 Farm Bill. Eligible landowners receive annual DPs that are equal to government payment rates per specific crop multiplied by eligible crop acres. Producers sign annual agreements to receive payments. DPs are limited to $40,000 per year per crop. Producers who earn more than $2.5 million per year for three years cannot qualify for DPs, unless more than 75% of their income comes from agriculture. Enrolled land must remain in agricultural uses and must meet conservation and wetland provisions to be eligible to receive DPs. A farmer may receive payments for a commodity without producing that commodity as long as they have a production history of that commodity. For example, they may receive payments for corn but grow soybeans on those acres instead. However, farmers may not plant fruits and vegetables on the land that is enrolled in DPs. DPs apply only to wheat, corn, grain sorghum, barley, oats, upland cotton, rice, soybeans, oilseeds, and peanuts (FSRIA, 2002; Monke, 2004). In contrast, the Counter Cyclical Income Support Program (CCP) is a new program for the 2002 Farm Bill created to replace most ad-hoc market loss assistance payments that were used between 1998 and 2001. CCP payments vary by crop and 10 depend both on historic and current production rates by crop. CCPs are available for a crop when the effective commodity price is lower than the target price set by the federal government. Payment limits on CCPs are $65,000 per year per crop, and the same limits apply to farmers earning more than $2.5 million. CCPs apply to the same commodities as DPs (FSRIA, 2002; Monke, 2004). Marketing Assistance Loans (MALs) are administered by the Farm Service Agency through the Commodity Credit Corporation (CCC). By pledging the crop as collateral the producer receives a loan from the government at crop specific loan rates, set in federal legislation. The producer may receive a full or partial loan on their crop for the next year’s production. MALs cover the same commodities as DPs and CCPs, but also cover mohair, wool, honey, small chickpeas, lentils, and dry peas. There are three ways to repay MALs: at the loan rate plus interest costs, by forfeiting the pledged crop to CCC at loan maturity, or at the alternative loan repayment rate. Alternative loan repayment rates are used when market prices for the commodity drop below the loan rate thus creating a profit for the producer (FSRIA, 2002; Monke, 2004). Farmers may choose to receive direct loan deficiency payments when market prices are lower than commodity loan rates. The LDP is equal to the profit a producer would have earned using the alternative loan repayment rate with MALs. When an LDP is paid on a portion of the crop, that portion cannot be used for subsequent loans. LDPs apply to the same commodities as MALs and payment is limited to $75,000 per year per crop. The same limits apply to farmers earning more than $2.5 million (FSRIA, 2002; Monke, 2004). 11 Broader Implications of the Farm Bill The Farm Bill, by paying producers to produce certain commodities, affects the food system and food security of Americans. The Farm Bill directly affects the health of the environment through soil erosion, water pollution, habitat degradation, and greenhouse gas emissions (Lingard, 2001). This American legislation also impacts the economies and environments of less developed countries (Mayrand et al., 2003), even being ruled illegal by the World Trade Organization (Pollan, 2007). Closer to many American’s wallets and waistlines are the impacts of the Farm Bill food prices and unhealthy diets. The Farm Bill artificially depresses the prices of processed foods and meats (Pollan, 2007), and indirectly contributes to heart disease, obesity, and diabetes (“Fresh Fruit”, 2012). The environmental impacts of agricultural subsidies are hard to quantify due to the highly tangled nature of the equation. However, agricultural subsidies have been tied to soil erosion, decreased water quality, increased water pollution, increased greenhouse gas emissions, decreased biodiversity, habitat degradation, and introduction of non-native plants and diseases (Lingard, 2001; Mayrand et al., 2003; Plantinga, 1996). Agricultural subsidies encourage intensive agricultural practices that increase the above noted environmental problems (Lingard, 2001), as well as give an incentive to increase acreages and yields to get higher payments (Mayrand et al., 2003). Not to mention that agriculture contributes eight percent of U.S. greenhouse gas emissions (Imhoff, 2012b). Highly erodible land is marginal farmland for commodity production. In the U.S., about one-third of total agricultural land is susceptible to erosion at rates that jeopardize its future use in agricultural production (Mayrand et al., 2003). When agricultural prices 12 (or price supports as agricultural subsidies) are higher, more land is kept in production. Marginal land would normally be taken out of production when prices are low, since the production costs of keeping this lower quality land in production would exceed the income received from the land. However, when prices are high this land is kept in production because the income exceeds the production costs. This marginal land is highly erodible and increases sediment in bodies of water (Plantinga, 1996). In addition to the increased sedimentation from highly erodible agricultural land the runoff from fertilizers and pesticides is also increased on this land (Plantinga, 1996). Agricultural chemicals are responsible for roughly 80 percent of the added nitrogen and phosphates in surface water (Mayrand et al., 2003). In addition, 80 percent of samples of water from rivers in agricultural areas, as well as fish from these rivers, have pesticides in them (Mayrand et al., 2003). The nitrogen balance in the U.S. has increased 24 percent from 1985-1987 to 1995-1997 (Mayrand et al., 2003). Chemical runoff from agriculture is a major contributor to the 7,000 square mile dead zone in the Gulf of Mexico off the coasts of Louisiana and Texas (Borders & Burnett, 2006; Imhoff, 2012a). The environmental impacts of the Farm Bill also extend to wildlife species. The increased intensification of agriculture based on subsidies also decreases agrobiodiversity. This is because subsidies encourage large monocultures of very limited crops (Imhoff, 2012a; Mayrand et al, 2003). These monocultures reduce the natural biodiversity, result in habitat fragmentation, and introduce non-native pests (Mayrand et al., 2003). In 1995, agriculture was estimated to affect roughly 58 percent of threatened and endangered species in the United States, due to agrochemical exposure and habitat degradation (Mayrand et al., 2003). One of the largest sources of habitat degradation is 13 the conversion of wetlands to agricultural land. Between 1986 and 1997, roughly onehalf (300,000 acres) of wetlands lost in the United States were converted to agricultural use (Borders & Burnett, 2006). Another problem associated with the Farm Bill is the harm that agricultural subsidies create on the economies of other countries. Agricultural subsidies artificially deflate the prices of commodities on the world market. This occurs because subsidies pay for the inputs (i.e., production expenses such as agro-chemicals) of commodities as well as supporting the price of commodities in developed nations (Mayrand et al., 2003). Also, due to the incentives subsidies offer to increase yield and acreage of, certain commodities are overproduced, surpluses are created (Pollan, 2007), and world production and trade of these commodities are distorted (Mayrand et al., 2003). When these surpluses of low priced commodities hit the world market, farmers in less developed countries cannot compete with the prices (Mayrand et al., 2003). When farmers in less developed countries cannot compete with the prices of the commodities being imported from countries with subsidies, they are forced off their land. Many people migrate off-farm to cities or to other countries. Since the creation of the North American Free Trade Agreement, Mexican immigration into the U.S. has been fueled by American corn flowing into Mexico (Pollan, 2007). This results in lower food security and higher levels of poverty in developing nations (Mayrand et al., 2003). One example of agricultural subsidies as large obstacles to agricultural growth in developing countries is cotton. World cotton prices, in 2006, were down by one-half since the mid-1990s. This price was lower than even during the Great Depression, adjusting for inflation. However, cotton production in the U.S. from 1998 to 2001 grew 14 by 42 percent in the midst of a global price fall. Cotton subsidies provided by the Farm Bill meant that U.S. farmers were getting up to 73 percent more than the world market price for cotton. These cotton subsidies cost $302 million in lost production and export revenue in sub-Saharan Africa in 2001 and 2002 alone, even though the cost to produce cotton there is one-third of what it is in the United States (Borders & Burnett, 2006). In fact the World Trade Organization has ruled U.S. cotton subsidies illegal (Pollan, 2007). The commodities covered under the commodity title of the Farm Bill are limited in their scope. One common theme among the covered variables is that they rarely reach the dinner table of American consumers as whole foods. Crops that may reach the consumer in whole forms include roasted peanuts or rice. Some grains, including corn and soybean, end up in the fuel tanks of vehicles as biodiesel or ethanol (ERS, 2102c). In 2011, about 40 percent of U.S. corn was used for ethanol production. Ethanol production, while meant to bolster energy independence, requires about two-thirds of a gallon of fossil fuels to create one gallon of ethanol (Imhoff, 2012b). Most of the covered commodities are used for livestock feed, including corn, barley, oats, and grain sorghum (ERS, 2012b). Subsidies on these commodities decrease the cost of feed grain for livestock, thereby reducing meat prices. In 2010, it cost $27.33 of feed for an $81.11 return on each hundredweight gain of hogs in the U.S. (ERS, 2012a). Imhoff (2012c) went so far as to say the largest beneficiaries of subsidies are the large livestock and processed-food manufacturers. The top four chicken and hog producers saved a total of $20 billion between 1996 and 2006 (Imhoff, 2012c). Carbonated beverage manufactures save roughly $100 million each year, as corn is used for high fructose corn syrup. This high fructose corn syrup, and other foods 15 processed from commodities, is produced by companies like Archer Daniels Midland and Cargill, large grain trading businesses who turn large profits by buying low cost commodities, processing them into food ingredients, and then selling them off to other businesses who process these ingredients into food (Imhoff, 2012c). Other commodities end up in our food in such a form as to make them almost invisible to the consumer. For example, corn is used for high fructose corn syrup, corn starch, modified corn starch, and xantham gum (bacteria harvested from fermented corn) (ERS, 2012b). Soybeans are used for soybean oil, partially hydrogenated soybean oil, soy lecithin, and soy protein isolate (ERS, 2012c). All of these ingredients are found in a box of Hostess Ding Dongs. The inclusion of ingredients produced from these subsidized commodities keeps the cost of highly processed foods lower than the cost of whole foods, despite the increased cost of production (Pollan, 2007). Processed foods are more energy dense than whole foods. They contain less water and fiber but more added fats and sugars (Pollan, 2007). Most of the added fats and sugars some from the products made of covered commodities, such as soybean oil and corn syrup. Two researchers found that, at the supermarket, one dollar will buy 1200 calories of chips or cookies, but only 250 calories of carrots (“Fresh Fruit”, 2012). Why? Because processed foods and cheap meat are products of agricultural subsidies, thereby keeping prices lower. From 1985 to 2000, the price of soft drinks, made with commodities covered under the Farm Bill, decreased 23 percent. However, the real price of fruits and vegetables increased 40 percent in that same amount of time (Pollan, 2007). This is because fruits and vegetables, labeled “specialty” crops by the USDA, do not receive subsidies or crop insurance (“Fresh Fruit”, 2012). 16 Although most American consumers don’t analyze their food choices based on the number of calories purchased per dollar, many are on a budget. When given the choice between four $1 boxes of pasta mix or one $4 pineapple, processed food choices are sometimes the most economical (“Fresh Fruits”, 2012). However, they can also be the most damaging. Corn, processed into sweeteners, increases the risk of type 2 diabetes. These sweeteners are commonly found in soft drinks, sports drinks, and juice. In 2006, children consumed an extra 130 calories per day from these drinks, leading to not only obesity but also diabetes (“Fresh Fruits”, 2012). Health care costs in America due to the obesity crisis are roughly $150 billion annually and are predicted to more than double in the next six years (Imhoff, 2012b). Also, in order to bring cattle up to slaughter weight faster, they are kept in feed lots and given a diet of corn and other commodities that they are not accustomed to eating. It takes 10 pounds of corn to produce 1 pound of beef (Pollan, 2008). Although this helps them gain weight, it produces meat with more calories per gram than grass-fed beef. It also has higher amounts of omega-6 fatty acids and lower amounts of omega-3 fatty acids. This combination is linked to heart disease (“Fresh Fruits”, 2012). In fact the least healthy calories in the supermarket are the cheapest ones, as well as the ones the Farm Bill encourages farmers to produce (Pollan, 2007). Previously Cited Problems Derived from the Farm Bill Previous studies conducted on the Farm Bill have cited numerous problems, including: (1), the absorption of small family farms into large agricultural businesses (Goodwin, 2000); (2), the limited number of farms reached by government payments (Westcott & Young, 2000); (3), payments being received by non-family or very large 17 family farms that do not need income support thereby leaving out small family and limited resource farms (Hoppe & MacDonald, 2001); (4), the increased dependence on government payments for income (Barnard, Nehring, & Collender, 2001); and (5), the increased farmland values based on government payments (Barnard et. al, 2001; Burfisher & Hopkins, 2003). The small family farm is on the decline in the United States, leading to larger agricultural businesses. In 1935, there were over 6.5 million American farms with an average of 150 acres each. By 1997, there were only two million American farms with an average size of 500 acres. While farmland acreage has remained roughly the same, numerous small family farms have been absorbed into larger commercial farms. Consider that in 1940 11.6 percent of farms, roughly 745,000 farms, accounted for 50 percent of all American agricultural production. By 1997, only 3.2 percent, or 64,000 farms, accounted for 50 percent of production (Goodwin, 2000). Despite the decline in the number of farms, payments still reach a limited number of farms. In 1997, 36 percent of farms received government payments (Westcott & Young, 2000). The limited number of farms reached by government payments is partly due to the limited number of covered commodities. Farm Bill programs are limited to 16 commodities with an additional 2 commodities being covered under individual programs (FSRIA, 2002). Five major crops accounted for 93 percent of all commodity programs in 2006: 46 percent corn, 23 percent upland cotton, 10 percent wheat, 8 percent rice, and 6 percent soybeans. These five crops, while dominating payments, only accounted for 21 percent of total U.S. agricultural production (ERS, 2006). 18 Most payments are going to larger farms and agricultural businesses. In 1998, 91 percent of all U.S. farms were in one of the small family farm typologies, and these typologies owned 68 percent of all farmland. However, 66 percent of agricultural production came from the mere 9 percent of U.S. farms that were in the large, very large, and nonfamily farm typologies. Even more, roughly half of all government payments went to farms in these farm typologies (Hoppe & MacDonald, 2001). Again in 1998, 60 percent of government payments went to farms with gross sales of more than $50,000. In 1997, farms with sales greater than $250,000 received roughly 40 percent of the government payments. Large farms, by sales class, not only have higher income but receive higher government payments (Westcott & Young, 2000). Despite the limited number of farms receiving payments, dependence on payments for income is increasing. In 1980 Farm Bill program payments accounted for less than 4 percent of the net cash farm income of American farmers. By 2000 these government payments accounted for 40 percent of net cash farm income. Eight percent of these payments came from conservation and miscellaneous payments while 92 percent of government farm transfers were generated from commodity payments and disaster relief payments (Barnard, Nehring, & Collender, 2001). The increased dependence on Farm Bill payments applies to landlords, too. About 60 percent of acres enrolled in Farm Bill programs are rented (Monke, 2004). The USDA intends for payments to go to the person who assumes the risk of agricultural production. Unless the landlord and operator have a shared rental agreement, according to the USDA, payments should go to the operator, rather than the landlord. However, most agricultural economists believe that a large percent of the payments pass through to 19 the landlord in the form of increased farmland rent prices and that payments raise the price of land (Burfisher & Hopkins, 2003). Direct government payments, meant to boost farm income, increase farmland value and thereby increase the cost of production. This increased cost of production, either in cash rent or in farmland purchases, comes without a corresponding increase in productivity or farm income. In 1999, landlords owned much of the land where land values have increased based on commodity payments, varying from 39 percent in the Eastern Uplands to 75 percent in the Mississippi Portal (see Figure 1 for Farm Resource Region References) (Barnard et. al, 2001). Farm Resource Regions In 2000, the USDA’s Economic Research Service created Farm Resource Regions (FRR) to geographically represent areas with similar productions in U.S. farm commodities (ERS, 2000). These regions were created by a detailed analysis and combination of USDA Farm Production Regions, NASS Crop Reporting Regions, USDA Land Resource Regions, and a cluster analysis of farm characteristics. These regions were intended to identify patterns in farming to better understand differences in farm production, performance, and economics (Eathington & Swenson, 2001). The Heartland (Figure 1) covers 543 counties in Iowa, Illinois, Indiana, and parts of Ohio, Kentucky, Missouri, Nebraska, South Dakota, and Minnesota. The Heartland has the highest number of farms and cropland, and specializes in cash grain and cattle farms (ERS, 2000). More than 37 percent of all farms that receive government payments are in the Heartland (Eathington & Swenson, 2001). Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Great Plains Prairie Gateway Eastern Uplands Southern Seaboard Fruitful Rim Mississippi Basin and Range Mississippi Basin and Portal Figure 1. The Farm Resource Regions as created by the Economic Research Service (ERS, 2000). 20 21 The Northern Crescent (Figure 1) covers 423 counties in Maine, New Hampshire, Vermont, New York, Massachusetts, Rhode Island, Connecticut, New Jersey, Michigan, Wisconsin, and parts of Minnesota, Ohio, Pennsylvania, Maryland, and Delaware. It is the most populous region and is dominated by dairy, general crop, and cash grain farms (ERS, 2000). The Northern Great Plains (Figure 1) covers 179 counties in North Dakota and parts of Montana, Wyoming, Colorado, Nebraska, South Dakota, and Minnesota. Wheat, cattle, and sheep are the dominant commodities in this region, which has the largest farms and the lowest population (ERS, 2000). The Northern Great Plains has the highest mean percent of farms receiving payments, the highest mean percent of rented farmland, as well as the lowest mean percent of principal operators who reported working off-farm (Eathington & Swenson, 2001). The Prairie Gateway (Figure 1) covers 394 counties in Kansas and parts of Nebraska, Colorado, New Mexico, Texas, and Oklahoma. The region specializes in cattle, wheat, sorghum, cotton, and rice production (ERS, 2000). The Eastern Uplands (Figure 1) is a noncontiguous region that covers 410 counties in parts of Missouri, Oklahoma, and Arkansas, as well as parts of Kentucky, Tennessee, Alabama, Georgia, North Carolina, Virginia, Maryland, Pennsylvania, and Ohio, and all of West Virginia. The Eastern Uplands specializes in part-time cattle, poultry, and tobacco farms and has a high number of small farms (ERS, 2000). The Eastern Uplands had the lowest mean market value of agricultural products sold, the lowest mean percent of farms receiving government payments, the lowest mean amount 22 of government payments, and the highest percent of principal operators who worked offfarm (Eathington & Swenson, 2001). The Southern Seaboard (Figure 1) is another noncontiguous region that covers 478 counties in parts of Delaware, Maryland, Virginia, North and South Carolina, Georgia, Alabama, and Mississippi, as well as parts of Arkansas, Louisiana, and Texas. The region is comprised of both small and large farms and specializes in part-time cattle, poultry, and general field crops (ERS, 2000). The Fruitful Rim (Figure 1) is comprised of four broken regions that cover 280 counties in: parts of South Carolina and Georgia as well as all of Florida; southern parts of Texas; parts of Arizona and California; and parts of Oregon, Washington, and Idaho. Farms here specialize in fruits and vegetables, nursery products, and cotton, and have the largest share of very large family and nonfamily farms (ERS, 2000). The Fruitful Rim had the highest mean market value of agricultural products sold and the highest mean amount of government payments (Eathington & Swenson, 2001). The Basin and Range (Figure 1) region is comprised of 197 counties covering all of Utah and Nevada, and parts of Oregon, California, Arizona, New Mexico, Colorado, Wyoming, Montana, Idaho, and Washington. Cattle, wheat, and sorghum are the major commodities of this region (ERS, 2000). The Mississippi Portal (Figure 1) covers 165 counties in parts of Tennessee, Mississippi, Louisiana, and Arkansas along the Mississippi River. The region specializes in cotton, rice, poultry, and hog operations (ERS, 2000). The Mississippi Portal had the highest mean ratio of government payment to income (Eathington & Swenson, 2001). Chapter III: Methods The purpose of this study is to determine if commodity variables are the only variables that are closely correlated to government commodity payments, based on the inequitable distribution of Farm Bill payments cited by other researchers. Since commodity production acreages and yields are included in the calculation of government commodity payments, only commodity variables should be tied to the government payment variables in this study. This study begins with the hypotheses that the only variables that will be closely tied to government payment variables are commodity variables, and that payments are distributed equitably amongst Farm Resource Regions based on commodities. Data The data used in this study were collected by the National Agricultural Statistics Service (NASS) in the 2007 Census of Agriculture. The Census is conducted once every five years according to the Census of Farm and Land Variables (NASS, 2009) Farms. The number of farms reporting to the NASS, defined as a place that produced and sold a minimum of $1000 of agricultural products per year, or would have under normal circumstances. Land in farms. The acres of land in farm production plus acres of woodland and wasteland that are not under production, including conservation program land and land rented under government permit in 2007. 24 Agriculture Act of 1997. Data were published by the NASS as county level aggregates available to the public online (http://quickstats.nass.usda.gov/) and through a downloadable data query (http://www.agcensus.usda.gov/Publications/2007/ Online_Highlights/Desktop_Application/index.asp). Data were omitted based on a nondisclosure policy that suppresses information when it would be possible to calculate individual responses (NASS, 2009). Economic Variables (NASS, 2009) Market value of agricultural products sold. The gross value of all agricultural products sold or removed from the farm in 2007, regardless of who received payment for the goods. Total income from farm-related sources, gross before taxes and expenses. Any direct income in 2007 from agri-tourism and recreation, state and local government payments, crop and livestock insurance payments, custom-work and other agricultural services unless they constitute a separate business, cash rent or share payments excluding non-farm rent, patronage dividends and refunds from cooperatives, sales of forest products excluding non-farm timber tracts and separate businesses, and other related income such as boarding fees and state fuel tax refunds. This income excludes federal government payments from the Farm Bill programs. Total farm production expenses. Expenses include livestock purchased or leased, cash rent for land and buildings, chemicals and fertilizers, contract labor, hired farm labor, custom-work, feed purchased, gasoline and fuels, interest paid on debts, property taxes, rent and lease for equipment and machinery, supplies and maintenance, seeds and plants, and other expenses incurred in 2007. Landlords only reported expenses for land that they operated while tenants reported expenses that they and the landlords paid for land they operated. Net cash farm income of operation. Net cash income is gross income, including government payments, less total expenses, excluding depreciation in 2007. The Census defines a farm as any place that produced and sold, or would have under normal circumstances, $1,000 or more of agricultural products during the Census year. A mailing list was composed by the NASS containing 3,194,373 records of 25 operations that met or potentially met this requirement to which Census packets were mailed. The response rate of the Census was 85.2% (NASS, 2009). A full description of the methods of the Census preparation and data collection can be obtained in Appendix A of the 2007 Census of Agriculture. The county level aggregates provided by the Census were considered individual datum for this study. There are 3,079 counties with published data in the Census (2009). Of these counties, 3,069 are included in Farm Resource Regions excluding Hawaii and Alaska (ERS, 2000). When county level aggregates were real zeros, zeros were used in calculations. When county level aggregates were suppressed to prevent disclosure of individual data or when they were omitted from the published data for any number of reasons, they were treated as missing values in the preparation of the data for analysis. FRR were used to break data into groups for analysis. Operator Characteristic Variables (NASS, 2009) Farming occupation. Principal operators who spent 50% or more of work-time in 2007 on farm operation are classified as farming occupation. Other occupation. Principal operators who spent less than 50% of work-time in 2007 on farm operation are classified as other occupation. Worked off farm any days. Principal operators who worked off farm any day in 2007. Worked off farm 200 days or more. Principal operators who worked off farm 200 or more days in 2007. Race. The race of the principal operator self-reported to the NASS. Operators could select more than one race including American Indian or Alaskan Native, Asian, Black or African American, MultiRace, or White. Spanish, Hispanic, or Latino origin. The ethnicity of the principal operator reported to the NASS, not mutually exclusive from race. Gender. Gender of the principal operator self-reported to the NASS. 26 Analysis A variety of statistical analyses were used in this study. First, descriptive statistics were calculated using SPSS 19 to examine all variables and to provide information at the national level, including Alaska and Hawaii. Descriptive statistics were also calculated for all variables for each FRR, to provide data for comparison among each region. National level descriptive statistics were used to determine normality for further analysis. To determine normality of the data, skewness and kurtosis values as well as standard error were calculated using SPSS 19. Skewness varied greatly per variable, ranging from -0.412 to 49.279, suggesting non-normal distributions. Kurtosis values Farm Organization (NASS, 2009) Family or individual. Farms held in sole proprietorship, excluding partnership or corporation. Partnership. Partnership farms, including family partnerships, include both those registered under state law and those that are not. Corporation other than family held. Farms that reported to the NASS as corporation farms excluding family held corporations. Corporation family held. Farms classified as corporation farms that are held by families. Other. Other farms are classified as cooperative, estate or trust, institutional, or do not fall into the other farm organization categories. also suggested non-normal data, ranging from 3.051 to 2,522.140. The purpose of location quotients is to quantify the concentration of a certain commodity or other variable in a particular region in relation to the national average. Location quotients are used to provide a number that is comparable between counties and regions despite the variances in acres or number of farms. Location quotients were 27 calculated using Microsoft Excel 2010. LQs were calculated by dividing a county’s percent share of one variable (e.g. acres of corn) by its percent share of another variable (e.g. acres of farmland) considered to be a denominator. Location quotients were calculated for each county, and descriptive statistics were calculated for each Farm Resource Region based on location quotients, using SPSS 19. Areas with LQs higher than 1.25 were considered to have a high relative specialization in a certain commodity or high relative representation of farm and operator characteristics. Areas with LQs below 0.75 were considered to have a low relative specialization or low relative representation Government Payment Variables (NASS, 2009) Farms with commodity payments. The number of farms receiving federal payments excluding Conservation Reserve Program (CRP), Wetland Reserve Program (WRP), Farmable Wetland Program (FWP), Conservation Reserve Enhancement Program (CREP), Commodity Credit Corporation (CCC) loans, and state and local payments. Commodity payments. The dollar amount of federal payments received excluding payments from CRP, WRP, FWP, CREP, CCC loans, and state and local payments. Commodity payment dependence. Payment dependence is the ratio of commodity payments received to the net cash farm income of operation. It is a measure of dependence on commodity payments for operation and operator income. (Champion & Wein, 2008). LQs ranged from a minimum of 0 to a maximum of 1356.77 per county. Since the data violate the assumptions of normality, Kendall’s tau rank correlation coefficients were used for this study, as they do not assume normality. The Kendall’s tau ranks both variables in the correlation independently then calculates a correlation based on the number of concordant pairs and discordant pairs (Conover, 1980). The purpose of using the Kendall’s tau was to determine the strength of the relationship between independent variables and government payment variables on 28 the national level, including Alaska and Hawaii. Kendall’s tau correlations were also calculated comparing the county level location quotient of each independent variable to government payment variables, excluding Alaska and Hawaii. This was to test the strength of the relationship between independent variable location quotients and government payment variable location quotients. Finally, Kendall’s tau correlations were calculated comparing the county level location quotient of each independent variable to government payment variables by each Farm Resource Region, to determine which variables Farm Tenure (NASS, 2009) were the most salient in each region. Full owner. Principal operators who own all the land operated. Using ArcGIS10, choropleth maps were created to illustrate trends in variables across Part owner. Principal operators who both own and rent land operated. the country based on location quotients. Maps were created using the Albers equal-area conic Tenant. Principal operators who rent, lease, or work on shares all land operated. projection on a 1:19,822,089 scale. County and state lines were drawn using shapefiles available from ESRI. Map classes were created using low (below 0.75), normal (0.75-1.25), and high (over 1.25) location quotients. When a variable contained outliers based on interquartile range, these outliers were used to create map classes. Mild outliers, outliers only one interquartile range above the 75th or below the 25th percentile, and extreme outliers, outliers two or more interquartile ranges above or below, were broken into two separate classes for the maps. This resulted in some maps with only three classes, and some maps with seven classes. This method was chosen despite this inconsistency so outliers are always identified. 29 Commodity Variables (NASS, 2009) Barley for grain. Barley is covered under Direct Payments (DP), Counter Cyclical Payments (CCP), Marketing Assistance Loans (MAL), and Loan Deficiency Payments (LDP). Beans. Beans are defined as dry edible beans, excluding lima beans. Dry edible beans are covered under MALs and LDPs. Corn for grain. Corn is covered under DPs, CCPs, MALs, and LDPs. Upland cotton. Upland cotton is covered under DPs, CCPs, MALs, and LDPs. Total cropland. Total cropland includes all cropland harvested (including noncovered commodities), failed crops or abandoned cropland, cropland that was pastured or grazed, and idled cropland in 2007. Milk cows. Milk cows are covered under the Dairy program. Oats for grain. Oats are covered under DPs, CCPs, MALs, and LDPs. Peanuts for nuts. Peanuts are covered under DPs, CCPs, MALs, and LDPs. Rice. Rice is covered under DPs, CCPs, MALs, and LDPs. Sorghum for grain. Sorghum is covered under DPs, CCPs, MALs, and LDPs. Soybean for beans. Soybeans are covered under DPs, CCPs, MALs, and LDPs. Sugarbeets. Sugarbeets are covered under the Sugar program. Sugarcane. Sugarcane is covered under the Sugar program. Wheat for grain. Wheat is covered under DPs, CCPs, MALs, and LDPs. Choropleth maps were also created to illustrate the differences between the location quotients of the independent variables and the government payment variables. Since the variables discussed in this paper have strong positive correlations based on location quotients, it would be expected that the location quotients of government independent variables. These maps illustrate the counties where this is not the case. 30 Farm Typology (NASS, 2009) Small family farm limited resource. Sole proprietorship farms with market values of agricultural products sold less than $100,000 and total principal operator household income of less than $20,000. Small family farm retirement. Sole proprietorship farms with market values of agricultural products sold less than $250,000 and a principal operator who reports being retired Small family farm residential/lifestyle. Sole proprietorship farms with market values of agricultural products sold less than $250,000 and a principal operator who reports a primary occupation other than farming. Small family farm farming occupation lower sales. Sole proprietorship farms with market values of agricultural products sold less than $100,000 and a principal operator who reports farming as the primary occupation. Small family farm farming occupation higher sales. Sole proprietorship farms with market values of agricultural products sold between $100,000 and $249,999 and a principal operator who reports farming as the primary occupation. Large family farm. Sole proprietorship farms with market values of agricultural products sold between $250,000 and $499,999. Very large family farm. Sole proprietorship farms with market values of agricultural products sold more than $500,000. Nonfamily farm. Farms that do not fall into the family or individual organization, with no constraints on the market value of agricultural products sold. Counties with lower numbers (green) have much lower location quotients of independent variables than government payment variables, showing a concentration of government payment variables without a corresponding concentration of independent variables. For the purpose of this study these counties are called negative discordant counties since they payment variables increase relative to the increase in the location quotients of result in negative numbers. Counties with higher numbers (red) have much higher location quotients of independent variables than government payment variables, showing a 31 concentration of the independent variable without a corresponding concentration of government payment variables. These counties are called positive discordant counties since they result in positive numbers. The middle range counties (yellow) are counties with both location quotients within 0.50 of one another. These are called concordant counties for this paper. These counties fit the correlation closer than other counties. Chapter IV: Results The purposes of this study are to determine if commodity variables are the only variables closely related to government payment variables, and if payment distribution varies by Farm Resource Region. This study analyzed the data published in the 2007 U.S. Census of Agriculture. The only variables discussed in detail in this chapter are those variables that are strongly correlated to government payment variables. Based on the results, the hypothesis that only commodity variables are tied to government payment variables is rejected. Corn, soybean, wheat, and total cropland variables are all closely correlated to government payment variables. However, other variables were also correlated to commodity payments: three farm typologies, two farm tenures, one operator characteristic, and four economic variables. The hypothesis that payments are distributed equitably by Farm Resource Region was also rejected as the payment variables varied by region, and not always based on commodity variables. Appendix A contains Kendall’s tau correlations of all variables nationally to government payment variables based on raw county data and location quotients. Means and standard deviations of all variables, both nationally and by Farm Resource Region, 33 are located in Appendix B. Mean location quotients of all variables by Farm Resource Region are available in Appendix C. Salient Variables The results discussed in this paper are only those variables that have a strong Kendall’s tau correlation to government payment variables based on raw numbers (Appendix A). This was done to limit the number of variables discussed in this paper. Based on these correlations, there were 10 variables that were strongly (τ ≥0.5) correlated to the number of farms with government commodity payments: farming occupation, small family farming occupation higher sales farms, large family farms, very large family farms, part owner farms, tenant farms, corn farms, total cropland farms, soybean farms, and wheat farms. There were 12 variables that were strongly correlated to the amount of commodity payments received. Eight of these variables coincide with those correlated to the number of farms with payments: acres of large family farms, acres of very large family farms, acres of part owner farms, acres of tenant farms, acres of corn, acres of total cropland, acres of soybeans, and acres of wheat. Four of these variables are economic: market value of agricultural products sold, gross total income from farm related sources, farm production expenses, and net cash farm income of operation. Income dependence did not have a strong correlation to any independent variables (Appendix A). All in all, there are 14 separate independent variables correlated to government payment variables, some of which are correlated based on both the number of farms and the acres of farms. 34 National In 2007 the average U.S. county contained 716 farms classified as such by the NASS, with an average of 297,859 acres of land in farms. The average county accounted for $96,212,060 in market value of agricultural products sold for a gross income (excluding Farm Bill payments) of $3,392,874 per county. Total farm production expenses averaged $78,261,619, with an average net cash farm income (including Farm Bill payments) per county of $24,794,277 (Appendix B). Commodity payments, federal payments excluding conservation payments, averaged $2,196,715 per county. This money was received by an average of 223 farms per county, for a mean payment per farm for the average U.S. county of $9,838. The average income dependence, the ratio of government payments to net income, was 47 percent (Appendix B). This statistic varied greatly in range from 0 in some counties to 441.6 percent in one county. In total, there were 376 counties with a mean income dependence of over 100 percent. Seventy four of these counties are in the Southern Seaboard, followed by the Prairie Gateway at 65 and the Mississippi Portal at 54. The average U.S. county was comprised predominantly of full owner farms (494), followed by part owner (176), and then tenant (46) farms. However, part owner farms included more land in farms (166,612 acres) despite being far outnumbered by full owner farms (107,935 acres). So the average part owner farm is much larger than the average full owner farm. On average, almost half of the farms per county (322) had an operator whose primary occupation was farming (Appendix B). Small family residential farms (260) were the most populous farm typology in the average county, followed by small family retirement farms (148), small family limited 35 resource farms (100), and small family farming occupation lower sales farms (84). Very large family farms, small family farming occupation higher sales, nonfamily, and large family farms were the smallest farm typologies ranging from 33-28 farms per county. However, based on acreage, very large family farms, large family farms, and nonfamily farms had more acres than residential farms (Appendix B). In 2007 the average county had 547 farms reporting cropland for an average of 132,548 acres. Most farms, on average, reported producing corn (113), followed by soybeans (91), then wheat (52). Corn accounted for 31,151 acres per county, followed by soybeans and wheat (Appendix B). County Level Analysis One purpose of this research is to determine if commodity variables are the only variables that are strongly correlated to the commodity payment variables. The analysis at this level includes Kendall’s tau correlations of raw county data, Kendall’s tau correlations of county location quotients, mean location quotients per Farm Resource Region, and choropleth maps. Choropleth maps were created to illustrate trends at the county level. The first map for each variable was classified based on location quotients using below normal (<.75), normal, and above normal (>1.25) categories. In those instances where outliers were present in the data, based on quartiles, classes were added to include both mild and extreme outliers either low or high. Some maps use only the first three classes of data. However, some maps include up to 7 classes to identify these outliers. The second map for the independent variables was classed using negative discordant counties (<-0.50), positive discordant counties (>0.50), and relatively equal concordant counties. There are always three classes on these maps. 36 Government Payment Variables In 2007, the average U.S. county had 223 farms receiving government payments (Table 1) for a mean commodity payment received per county of $2,196,715 (Table 2). The average payment per farm was $9,838 (Table 2). Income dependence was at 47.1 percent nationally, meaning that government payments accounted for 47.1 percent of net income of farm operations as a county mean (Table 3). The Farm Resource Region with the highest mean number of farms per county receiving payments was the Heartland (Table 1), and the highest mean payment per county was in the Mississippi Portal (Table 2). On average the highest payment per farm was in the Fruitful Rim ($21,385) followed by the Mississippi Portal ($20,096). The lowest average payment per operation was in the Eastern Uplands at $3,410 (Table 2). The highest income dependence was in the Mississippi Portal at 378.4 percent, and the lowest was in the Northern Great Plains at 12.4 percent (Table 3). Farms with payments. Figure 2 was created using the location quotients of each county for the number of farms receiving government commodity payments. Based on the average location quotient for each Farm Resource Region, farms with commodity payments were above normal in the Northern Great Plains, Heartland, and Prairie Gateway. The LQs of the Eastern Uplands, Fruitful Rim, and Basin and Range were lower than normal (Table 1), meaning fewer farms received commodity payments than the national average. 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.925703 37 Figure 2. The location quotient of farms receiving commodity payments was highest on average in the Heartland, Northern Great Plains, and Prairie Gateway region. However, there are large pockets of above normal LQs in the Southern Seaboard and Mississippi Portal. 38 Table 1. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of farms with commodity payments by Farm Resource Region. Farms with Farms with Farms with Payments Ordinal Ordinal Payments Payments (No.) Rank Rank (%)a LQb Heartland 453.2 55.0 1 1.77 2 Northern 239.1 31.5 5 0.81 5 Crescent Northern 291.9 54.1 2 1.78 1 Great Plains Prairie 276.7 33.6 4 1.37 3 Gateway Eastern 129.1 16.6 7 0.47 9 Uplands Southern 97.2 18.8 6 0.73 6 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 110.0 12.3 9 0.49 8 Basin and 82.9 15.7 8 0.52 7 Range Mississippi 194.8 35.4 3 1.15 4 Portal National 223.3 31.2 a b Farms with Commodity Payments (number) / Farms (number). LQ of Farms with Commodity Payments (number) / Farms (number). Commodity payments. The average location quotient of commodity payments was above normal in the Mississippi Portal, Heartland, and Southern Seaboard, and below normal in the Basin and Range, Eastern Uplands, and Northern Great Plains (Table 2). There were mild and extreme high outliers in this data (Figure 3). The outliers are concentrated in the Mississippi Portal and Southern Seaboard with a few scattered in the Fruitful Rim. This holds consistently with the fact that these three regions had the highest mean commodity payments per operation (Table 2). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 3.299397 3.299398 - 4.790325 4.790326 - 11.999322 39 Figure 3. The location quotients of commodity payment dollars were highest in the Heartland, Southern Seaboard, and Mississippi Portal. Outliers were predominant in the Southern Seaboard and Mississippi Portal with a few outliers in parts of the Fruitful Rim. 40 Table 2. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of commodity payments by Farm Resource Region. Commodity Ordinal Ordinal Ave. per Commodity a b Payment LQ Farm ($) Payment ($) Rank Rank 3,526,080 7,780 7 1.94 2 Heartland Northern 1,328,181 5,555 8 1.15 4 Crescent Northern 3,403,486 11,660 4 0.68 7 Great Plains Prairie 3,036,438 10,974 6 0.89 6 Gateway Eastern 440,287 3,410 9 0.44 8 Uplands Southern 1,260,263 12,966 3 1.69 3 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 2,352,371 21,385 1 1.09 5 Basin and 929,331 11,210 5 0.30 9 Range Mississippi 3,914,677 20,096 2 2.43 1 Portal National 2,196,715 9,838 a b Commodity Payments ($) / Farms with Commodity Payments (number). LQ of Commodity Payments ($) / Land in Farms (acres). Income dependence. Income dependence averaged 47 percent nationally, with the highest dependence being in the Mississippi Portal (378.4 percent) followed by the Basin and Range (74.2 percent) (Table 3). The mean location quotients per region were highest in the Mississippi Portal, Prairie Gateway, and Heartland. They were below normal in the Eastern Uplands, Northern Crescent, Basin and Range, and Fruitful Rim. The map of county location quotients of income dependence (Figure 4) illustrates the high levels of income dependence in the Mississippi Portal with the high concentration of mild and extreme high outliers. However, other outliers are concentrated in the Southern Seaboard and Prairie Gateway. 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.524346 2.524347 - 3.668631 3.668632 - 14.331163 Figure 4. The location quotients of income dependence were highest in the Mississippi Portal, Heartland, and Prairie Gateway. There are extremely high outliers present in the Southern Seaboard even though the average county LQ is right at normal. 41 42 Table 3. The mean, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of income dependence by Farm Resource Region. Income Income Dependence Dependence (%)a Ordinal Rank LQb Ordinal Rank Heartland 21.1 5 1.35 3 Northern 12.9 8 0.52 8 Crescent Northern 12.4 9 1.16 4 Great Plains Prairie 33.6 4 1.37 2 Gateway Eastern 17.3 7 0.46 9 Uplands Southern 47.7 3 0.99 5 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 20.3 6 0.62 6 Basin and 74.2 2 0.53 7 Range Mississippi 378.4 1 2.36 1 Portal National 47.1 a b Commodity Payments ($) / Net Cash Income of Farm Operation ($). Location quotient of Commodity Payments ($) / Net Cash Income of Farm Operation ($). Even though the Southern Seaboard had a high concentration of outliers, it had a normal mean location quotient for income dependence (Table 3). Therefore, these outliers must have been offset by numerous low location quotients. This means there is a very large variation among income dependence in the Southern Seaboard. Economic Variables Economic variables include the market value of agricultural products sold, gross income of operation, production expenses, and net cash income of farm operation. Nationally, the average county had a market value of agricultural products sold of $96,212,060 (Table 4). Gross income averaged $3,392,874 (Table 5); production expenses averaged $78,261,619 (Table 6), and net income of operation per county 43 averaged $24,794,277(Table 7). The Fruitful Rim had the highest mean market value per county at $217,886,746 (Table 4) and the highest mean gross income ($6,000,168) (Table 5), production expenses ($174,821,354) (Table 6), and net income ($54,105,846) (Table 7). Market value appears to be so much larger than gross income because market value includes all goods removed for sale regardless of who received payment for the goods while gross income includes only the income of the operation. Net income is larger than gross income because net income includes Farm Bill payments even though gross income does not. Market value. Market value of agricultural products sold was strongly correlated to the commodity payment amount (τ = .529, p = .000) for raw data. However, this same correlation was only moderate (τ = .352, p = .000) when based on location quotients (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of market value of agricultural products sold, the Fruitful Rim was very high (3.49) followed by the Northern Crescent and the Southern Seaboard (Table 4). This trend holds true when looking at the county level location quotients (Figure 5). The Basin and Range and the Northern Great Plains were tied for the lowest mean location quotient, meaning that the agricultural products sold based on the acres of land used to produce them was below normal. Based on the mean market value per acre, the ordinal rank of the top three FRRs changes, but is otherwise similar to the ordinal rank based on location quotients (Table 4). Based on the correlation of the location quotients, the location quotient of commodity payments would be expected to increase as the location quotient of market 44 Table 4. The mean, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of market value by Farm Resource Region. Market Value Ave. per Ordinal Ordinal Market a b Value LQ Acre ($) ($) Rank Rank Heartland 132,582,011 517 4 1.53 4 Northern 78,855,418 617 2 2.34 2 Crescent Northern Great 106,170,464 118 8 0.44 8 Plains Prairie 114,977,404 207 7 0.69 7 Gateway Eastern 42,012,873 343 5 0.98 5 Uplands Southern 63,848,282 643 1 2.14 3 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 217,866,746 560 3 3.49 1 Basin and 40,669,223 75 9 0.44 8 Range Mississippi 56,067,297 315 6 0.92 6 Portal National 96,212,060 323 a Market Value of Agricultural Products Sold ($) / Land in Farms (acres). b Location quotient of Market Value of Agricultural Products Sold ($) / Land in Farms (acres). value increases moderately. The yellow counties on Figure 5 show those counties where the location quotients of the two variables vary by less than 0.50, and follow the correlation as expected (concordant counties). The red counties, concentrated in the Northern Crescent, Fruitful Rim, and the border between the Eastern Uplands and Southern Seaboard, show those counties where the location quotients of market value were larger than the location quotients of commodity payments (positive discordant counties). The green counties, concentrated in the Mississippi Portal, Southern Seaboard, and Heartland, show those counties where the location quotient of the commodity payments is larger than the location quotient of the market value (negative discordant counties). Since the correlation is only moderate between the location quotients of 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 3.049271 3.049272 - 4.395529 4.395530 - 283.348118 -6.861019 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 283.348118 45 Figure 5. The mean location quotient of market value of agricultural products sold was highest in the Fruitful Rim, Northern Crescent, and Southern Seaboard (left). The location quotients of commodity payments were larger than the location quotients of market value in the Mississippi Portal, Southern Seaboard, and Heartland (right). 46 market value and commodity payments, it is expected that not every county will fit the correlation. Gross income. Gross income from farm-related sources, as defined in this study, includes all sources of income related to agricultural production and services, as well as insurance and state and local payments, but does exclude Farm Bill payments. Gross income was strongly correlated to commodity payments (τ = .559, p = .000) based on raw data. Based on location quotients, the correlation was weaker (τ = .358, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of gross income, the Northern Crescent, Fruitful Rim, Southern Seaboard, and Heartland were all higher than expected (Table 5). This Table 5. The mean, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranking of gross income by Farm Resource Region. Gross Ave. per Ordinal Gross Ordinal Acre ($)a Income LQb Income ($) Rank Rank 4,754,547 19 2 1.79 4 Heartland 4.95 Northern 3,469,548 27 1 1 Crescent 0.67 Northern Great 5,459,966 6 8 7 Plains 0.66 Prairie 3,698,723 7 7 8 Gateway 1.03 Eastern 1,353,832 11 6 5 Uplands Southern 2.00 1,918,280 19 2 3 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 6,000,168 15 4 2.65 2 0.64 Basin and 2,071,345 4 9 9 Range 1.01 Mississippi 2,146,152 12 5 6 Portal National 3,392,874 11 a b Total Income from Farm Related Sources Gross ($) / Land in Farms (acres). Location quotient of Total Income from Farm Related Sources Gross ($) / Land in Farms (acres). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 3.118991 3.118992 - 4.404729 4.404730 - 321.746072 -6.322992 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 321.746072 47 Figure 6. The location quotients of gross income were highest in the Northern Crescent, followed by the Fruitful Rim and Southern Seaboard (left). The location quotients of commodity payments were much larger than the location quotients of the gross income in the Heartland and Mississippi Portal (right). 48 trend holds true when looking at the county level location quotients (Figure 6). Gross income location quotients were lowest on average in the Basin and Range, Prairie Gateway, and Northern Great Plains (Table 5). The mean gross income per acre was highest in the Northern Crescent ($27) and lowest in the Basin and Range ($4). The ordinal rank of Farm Resource Regions based on gross income per acre and location quotients were similar (Table 5). Based on the correlation of the location quotients, the location quotient of commodity payments would be moderately expected to increase as the location quotient of gross income increases. On Figure 6, the positive discordant counties are concentrated in the Northern Crescent, Fruitful Rim, and eastern Southern Seaboard and Eastern Uplands. The payment variables in these regions are more strongly correlated to another variable that is causing them to remain low despite the high gross income values. The negative discordant counties are concentrated in the Mississippi Portal and Heartland. In these regions the government payment variable is elevated by a more strongly correlated variable. Since the correlation is only moderate between the location quotients of gross income and commodity payments, it is expected that not every county will fit the correlation. Production expenses. Production expenses were strongly correlated to commodity payments based on raw data (τ = .513, p = .000) but only moderately correlated based on location quotients (τ = .315, p = .000) (Appendix A). Those farm resource regions with above normal location quotients of production expenses were the Fruitful Rim, Northern Crescent, Southern Seaboard, and Heartland. Production expenses location quotients were below 49 normal in the Northern Great Plains and Basin and Range (Table 6). This trend is visible on the county level map (Figure 7) with mild and extreme high outliers being concentrated in the regions with above normal location quotients. However, some outliers are scattered throughout the Prairie Gateway, Basin and Range, and Mississippi Portal. Based on the mean production expenses per acre the Southern Seaboard ($546) and the Northern Crescent ($499) were the highest while the Basin and Range was the lowest ($68). The ordinal ranks based on the mean production expenses per acre was similar to the ordinal ranks based on location quotients (Table 6). The location quotient of commodity payments would be expected to increase moderately as the location quotient of production expenses increases. On Figure 7, the Table 6. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of production expenses by Farm Resource Region. Ave. per Production Ordinal Acre ($)a Ordinal Production b Expenses LQ Expenses ($) Rank Rank Heartland 99,427,878 388 4 1.43 4 Northern 63,758,953 499 2 2.48 2 Crescent Northern 82,748,067 92 8 0.42 9 Great Plains Prairie 100,525,096 181 7 0.74 7 Gateway Eastern 36,701,522 299 5 1.11 5 Uplands Southern 54,219,584 546 1 2.29 3 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 174,821,354 450 3 2.53 1 Basin and 36,597,508 68 9 0.66 8 Range Mississippi 48,044,291 270 6 0.98 6 Portal National 78,261,619 263 a Total Farm Production Expenses ($) / Land in Farms (acres). b Location quotient of Total Farm Production Expenses ($) / Land in Farms (acres). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.992505 2.992506 - 4.260652 4.260653 - 55.971026 -6.612931 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 55.971026 50 Figure 7. The location quotients of production expenses were above normal in the Fruitful Rim, Northern Crescent, Southern Seaboard, and Heartland (left). The location quotients of commodity payments were greater than the location quotients of production expenses in the Heartland and Mississippi Portal (right). 51 positive discordant counties are concentrated in areas similar to those as market value and gross income. In these regions government payment variables are being kept low by another variable. The negative discordant counties are again concentrated in the Mississippi Portal and the Heartland as well as the Southern Seaboard. Here, again, the amount of commodity payments is elevated based on another more strongly correlated variable. Since the correlation is only moderate between the location quotients of production expenses and commodity payments, it is again expected that not every county will fit the correlation. Net income. Net cash income of farm operation is gross income of operation minus production expenses, including Farm Bill payments. Net income was strongly correlated to commodity payments based on raw data (τ = .555, p = .000) and moderately correlated based on location quotients (τ = .410, p = .000) (Appendix A). In Table 7, the Fruitful Rim, Northern Crescent, Heartland, and Southern Seaboard all had above normal net income. Location quotients of net income were below normal in the Northern Great Plains, Prairie Gateway, and Eastern Uplands (Table 7). This data is supported by the county level location quotient map (Figure 8). The ordinal rank based on the mean per acre net income by Farm Resource Region varies from the rank based on location quotients. The Heartland had the highest mean per acre net income at $165, while the lowest was in the Basin and Range at $17 (Table 7). The location quotient of commodity payments would be expected to increase moderately as the location quotient of net income increases. On Figure 8, the positive discordant counties appear to be fewer but still in a similar pattern to other economic 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 3.327114 3.327115 - 4.878050 4.878051 - 92.905794 -6.957226 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 92.905794 52 Figure 8. The location quotients of net income of operation were highest in the Fruitful Rim, Northern Crescent, and Heartland. Mild and extreme high outliers were scattered throughout the Southern Seaboard and Mississippi Portal (left). The location quotients of commodity payments were larger than the location quotients of net income in the Mississippi Portal (right). 53 Table 7. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of net income by Farm Resource Region. Net Income Ordinal Ordinal Ave. per Net Income a b Acre ($) LQ ($) Rank Rank 42,306,560 165 1 1.85 3 Heartland 2.10 Northern 20,445,220 160 2 2 Crescent 0.56 Northern Great 38 8 9 34,148,089 Plains 42 7 0.58 8 Prairie Gateway 23,655,736 0.73 Eastern 64 6 7 7,830,151 Uplands 1.77 Southern 13,936,245 140 3 4 Seaboard 139 4 2.51 1 Fruitful Rim 54,105,846 0.82 Basin and 8,964,660 17 9 6 Range 0.86 Mississippi 82 5 5 14,508,467 Portal 83 National 24,794,277 a b Net Cash Farm Income of Operation ($) / Land in Farms (acres). Location quotient of Net Cash Farm Income of Operation ($) / Land in Farms (acres). variable maps. Negative discordant counties are again concentrated in the Mississippi Portal but much less in the Heartland than other economic variables. Since the correlation is only moderate between the location quotients of production expenses and commodity payments, it is again expected that not every county will fit the correlation. Net income is perhaps a better indicator of trends since net income takes into account gross income and production expenses. However, one thing that is visible is that the Heartland and the Mississippi Portal have much larger county location quotients for commodity payments than for the economic variables. Another thing that is visible is that the Northern Crescent and the Pacific Coast region of the Fruitful Rim have much larger economic variable location quotients than commodity payment location quotients. 54 Occupation and Tenure Variables Occupation and tenure variables include the occupation of the principal operator of a farm operation as well as part owner and tenant farms and acres. Nationally, the average county had 45.1 percent of farms with a principal operator reporting farming as their primary occupation (Table 8). On average, 24.6 percent of operators were part owners (Table 9), for an average of 55.9 percent of acres operated (Table 10). Finally, an average of 6.4 percent of principal operators were tenant farmers (Table 11) for an average of 9.2 percent of acres operated (Table 12). The Northern Great Plains had the highest percentage of principal operators (55.8 percent) reporting farming as their primary occupation (Table 8). The Northern Great Plains also had the highest percentage of part owner farms at 35.7 (Table 9) and the highest percentage of acres in part owner farms (65.6 percent) (Table 10). The highest percentage of tenant farms (8.7 percent) was in the Northern Great Plains as well (Table 11). However, the highest percentage of tenant farm acres was in the Mississippi Portal at 19.9 (Table 12). Farming occupation. Farming occupation was strongly correlated to the number of farms with commodity payments (τ = .519, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was weak based on location quotients (τ = .297, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of farming occupation, the Northern Great Plains was the only region above normal. All other regions were at normal (Table 8). This trend is supported by the county level analysis (Figure 9). The ordinal rank of Farm Resource Regions based on mean percentage of farming occupation farms differs from the ordinal rank based on 55 location quotients. However, the Northern Great Plains comes in first again at 55.8 percent, followed distantly by the Heartland at 47.2 percent (Table 8). Table 8. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of farming occupation by Farm Resource Region. Farming Farming Farming Occupation Occupation Ordinal Occupation Ordinal (%)a LQb (No.) Rank Rank 388.3 47.2 2 1.06 2 Heartland 1.03 Northern 352.6 47.1 3 3 Crescent Northern 301.2 55.8 1 1.31 1 Great Plains Prairie 354.9 43.1 6 1.03 3 Gateway Eastern 317.3 40.8 8 0.90 9 Uplands Southern 218.4 42.3 7 0.96 7 Seaboard 416.3 46.4 4 1.01 6 Fruitful Rim Basin and 244.8 46.3 5 1.02 5 Range Mississippi 222.2 40.4 9 0.95 8 Portal 322.8 45.1 National a b Farming Occupation (number) / Farms (number). Location quotient of Farming Occupation (number) / Farms (number). The correlation of farming occupation and farms with payments based on location quotients is weak. Therefore, it is hard to expect to see patterns in Figure 9. However, this map has very visible patterns due to the small amount of concordant counties. Positive discordant counties, counties with a high location quotient of farming occupation without a corresponding concentration of farms with commodity payments, are focused in the Fruitful Rim and Basin and Range with some counties in the Eastern Uplands and Southern Seaboard. Negative discordant counties, counties with large location quotients of farms with government payments but not farming occupation, are concentrated in the 0.000000 - 0.322721 0.322722 - 0.595756 0.595757 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 1.425079 1.425080 - 1.688144 1.688145 - 2.219538 -1.771702 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 2.219538 56 Figure 9. The location quotients of farming occupation were above normal in the Northern Great Plains (left). The Farm Resource Regions with larger location quotients of farms with payments than of farming occupation are concentrated in the Northern Great Plains, Prairie Gateway, and Heartland (right). 57 Northern Great Plains, Prairie Gateway, and Heartland. It is expected that there would be few concordant counties, counties with small differences between location quotients, based on the weakness of the correlation. Part owner. Part owner farms were strongly correlated to the number of farms with commodity payments (τ = .593, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was moderate based on location quotients (τ = .464, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of part owner farms, the Northern Great Plains was the only region above normal. The Fruitful Rim was the only region below normal (Table 9). Table 9. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of part owner farms by Farm Resource Region. Part Part Part Owner Ordinal Ordinal Owner Owner a b (No.) Rank Rank (%) LQ Heartland 238.6 29.0 2 1.18 2 Northern 192.3 25.7 4 0.97 4 Crescent Northern Great 192.9 35.7 1 1.54 1 Plains Prairie Gateway 221.0 26.8 3 1.17 3 Eastern 177.2 22.8 6 0.92 7 Uplands Southern 120.3 23.3 5 0.93 6 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 137.4 15.3 9 0.70 9 Basin and 100.9 19.1 8 0.84 8 Range Mississippi 123.3 22.4 7 0.96 5 Portal National 176.1 24.6 a b Part Owner (number) / Farms (number). Location quotient of Part Owner (number) / Farms (number). 0.000000 - 0.338235 0.338236 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 1.639567 1.639568 - 2.905805 2.905806 - 4.057929 -2.186670 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 4.057929 58 Figure 10. The location quotients of part owner farms were above normal in the Northern Great Plains and below normal in the Fruitful Rim. There are a few outliers in the Heartland and Basin and Range regions (left). Counties that do not follow the correlation were concentrated in the Heartland, Eastern Uplands, and Southern Seaboard (right). 59 Again this is supported by the county level location quotient map (Figure 10). Based on the mean percentage of part owner farms per Farm Resource Region, the Northern Great Plains was highest at 35.7 and the Fruitful Rim was lowest at 15.3. The ordinal ranks of regions based mean percentages and location quotients were similar (Table 9). Since the correlation of part owner farms to farms with payments was moderate, it is expected that the location quotients of farms with payments increase when the location quotients of part owner farms increase. On Figure 10, positive discordant counties are concentrated in the Eastern Uplands and Southern Seaboard. In these regions independent variables other than part owner farms are keeping number of farms with payments low. Negative discordant counties are centralized in the Heartland. The number of farms with payments is more strongly correlated to other variables than part owner farms in the Heartland. The Prairie Gateway and the Mississippi Portal both have large amounts of counties on both ends of the spectrum. Part owner farm acres were strongly correlated to the amount of commodity payments (τ = .503, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was moderate based on location quotients (τ = .300, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of part owner farm acres, the Fruitful Rim was the only region below normal. All other regions were normal (Table 10). The Fruitful Rim is where most low outliers are concentrated, with the above normal counties being centralized in the Northern Great Plains and Heartland (Figure 11). The mean percentage of part owner farm acres per county was highest in the Northern Great Plains (65.6 percent) and Heartland (64.7 percent), and lowest in the Fruitful Rim at 41.4 percent (Table 10). The ordinal ranks, location quotients, mean percentages, and choropleth map are all very similar. 60 Since the correlation based on location quotients was only moderate, large numbers of discordant counties are expected on Figure 11. Positive discordant counties are concentrated in the Northern Great Plains, Eastern Uplands, and Prairie Gateway. In these counties, commodity payments are being kept lower based on other variables despite large part owner farm acres. Negative discordant counties are centralized in the Heartland, Mississippi Portal, and Southern Seaboard. In these regions, variables other than part owner farm acres are more strongly correlated to commodity payments and the location quotients of commodity payments are much higher than would be expected based on part owner farm acres. Table 10. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of part owner farm acres by Farm Resource Region. Part Owner Part Owner Ordinal Part Owner Ordinal a b Acres (%) Acres LQ Acres (ac) Rank Rank Heartland 165,869.1 64.7 2 1.17 2 Northern 76,091.5 59.5 3 0.96 4 Crescent Northern 588,565.5 65.6 1 1.22 1 Great Plains Prairie 312,936.6 56.2 4 1.05 3 Gateway Eastern 54,370.9 44.3 8 0.77 8 Uplands Southern 46,975.0 47.3 6 0.81 6 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 161,041.2 41.4 9 0.73 9 Basin and 273,073.0 50.5 5 0.85 5 Range Mississippi 79,104.2 44.5 7 0.78 7 Portal National 166,612.0 55.9 a Part Owner (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). b Location quotient of Part Owner (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). 0.000000 - 0.277475 0.277476 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 1.643890 1.643891 - 1.767829 -11.147299 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 1.489519 61 Figure 11. The location quotients of part owner farm acres were lowest in the Fruitful Rim. High outliers are concentrated in the Northern Great Plains, Heartland, and Prairie Gateway (left). The differences between the location quotients of part owner farm acres and commodity payments were greatest in the Northern Great Plains, Heartland, and Mississippi Portal (right). 62 Tenant farms. Tenant farms are those farms where the operator rents all the land that they operate from someone else. Tenant farms were strongly correlated to the number of farms receiving commodity payments based on raw data (τ = .521, p = .000). This same correlation was moderate based on location quotients (τ = .321, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of tenant farms, the Mississippi Portal, Northern Great Plains, Prairie Gateway, and Heartland regions were all above normal. The Eastern Uplands was the only region below normal (Table 11). The concentration of mild and extreme high outliers in these same above normal regions (Figure 12) supports the Table 11. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of tenant farms by Farm Resource Region. Tenant Tenant Tenant Owner Ordinal Ordinal Owner Owner a b (No.) Rank Rank (%) LQ Heartland 68.4 8.3 2 1.34 4 Northern 37.2 5.0 7 0.86 7 Crescent Northern 47.0 8.7 1 1.47 2 Great Plains Prairie 59.1 7.2 4 1.38 3 Gateway Eastern 29.0 3.7 9 0.61 9 Uplands Southern 25.4 4.9 8 0.85 8 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 60.8 6.8 5 1.16 5 Basin and 30.1 5.7 6 1.06 6 Range Mississippi 44.2 8.0 3 1.77 1 Portal National 45.7 6.4 a Tenant Owner (number) / Farms (number). b Location quotient of Tenant Owner (number) / Farms (number). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.286768 2.286769 - 3.150049 3.150050 - 15.825824 -1.745353 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 15.825824 63 Figure 12. The location quotients of tenant farms were highest in the Mississippi Portal and lowest in the Eastern upland (left). Positive discordant counties of tenant farms to farms with payments are concentrated in the Fruitful Rim and Mississippi Portal, and negative discordant counties are scattered in the Heartland and Northern Great Plains (right). 64 location quotient analysis. Based on the mean percentage of tenant farms in each region, the Northern Great Plains (8.7 percent) and the Heartland (8.3 percent) were the highest with the Eastern Uplands being the lowest (3.7 percent). The ordinal ranks based on mean percentage were different from those based on the location quotients of tenant farms (Table 11). The location quotient of farms with payments would be expected to increase moderately as the location quotient of tenant farms increases. On Figure 12, the positive discordant counties are concentrated in the Fruitful Rim, Mississippi Portal, and northeastern coast. In these regions government payment variables are being kept low by another variable. The negative discordant counties are concentrated in the Heartland, Northern Great Plains, and the western part of the Northern Crescent. Here the amount of commodity payments is elevated based on another more strongly correlated variable. These patterns are weaker than with some other variables, as would be expected with only a moderate correlation between tenant farms and farms with payments based on location quotients. Tenant farm acres were strongly correlated to commodity payment amounts (τ = .510, p = .000). This same correlation was weak based on location quotients (τ = .262, p = .000) (Appendix A). The Mississippi Portal was the only region with an above normal location quotient of tenant farm acres. Location quotients were below normal in the Eastern Uplands, Northern Crescent, and Southern Seaboard (Table 12). Outliers tended to be concentrated in the Mississippi Portal, supporting these results. However, there were outliers scattered throughout the Fruitful Rim, Prairie Gateway, and Heartland (Figure 13). The Mississippi Portal had the largest percentage of tenant farm 65 acres at 19.9 percent followed distantly by the Fruitful Rim at 12.7 percent. The Eastern Uplands were the lowest at 4.2 percent. The ordinal ranks based on mean percentages and location quotients were very similar (Table 12). Since the correlation of the location quotients of commodity payments to tenant farms is so weak, it is hard to expect a strong pattern on Figure 13. However, some patterns are very clear. Positive discordant counties are few but follow a pattern along the border of the Basin and Range region and the Northern Great Plains and Prairie Gateway. Negative discordant counties are concentrated in the Heartland, Mississippi Portal, Northern Crescent, and southern border of the Southern Seaboard. This means Table 12. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of tenant farm acres by Farm Resource Region. Tenant Tenant Tenant Owner Ordinal Ordinal Owner Owner a b Acres (ac) Rank Rank Acres (%) Acres LQ Heartland 25,118.9 9.8 4 1.05 4 Northern 6,644.1 5.2 8 0.57 8 Crescent Northern 69,635.5 7.8 5 0.90 5 Great Plains Prairie 55,035.6 9.9 3 1.13 2 Gateway Eastern 5,340.9 4.4 9 0.43 9 Uplands Southern 6,133.5 6.2 7 0.63 7 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 47,445.9 12.2 2 1.11 3 Basin and 40,499.0 7.5 6 0.83 6 Range Mississippi 35,385.4 19.9 1 1.96 1 Portal 27,415.8 9.2 National a b Tenant Owner (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). Location quotient of Tenant Owner (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 1.939658 1.939659 - 3.081907 3.081908 - 8.934124 -10.816690 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 8.428727 66 Figure 13. The location quotients of tenant farm acres were above normal only in the Mississippi Portal. Outliers are scattered throughout the Fruitful Rim, Prairie Gateway, and Heartland (left). The location quotients of farms with payments are larger than the location quotients of tenant farm acres in the Heartland, Mississippi Portal Northern Crescent, and Southern Seaboard (right). 67 that although location quotients of tenant farm acres are low, location quotients of commodity payments are high. Therefore, other variables are more strongly correlated to payments in these regions than tenant farm acres, as expected with a weak correlation. Typology Variables Typology variables group farms by similar characteristics based on sales, occupation, and farm organization. Typology variables, as discussed in these results, include small family farming occupation higher sales, large family, and very large family farms. The average U.S. county had 32.5 small family farming occupation higher sales farms (4.5 percent) (Table 13). Large family farms averaged 28.1 farms per county (3.9 percent) (Table 14) for a total of 45,559.9 acres (15.3 percent) (Table 15). Very large family farms averaged 32.9 farms per county (4.6 percent) (Table 16) for an average of 76,868.7 acres per county (25.8 percent) (Table 27). The Northern Great Plains had the highest percentage of small family farming occupation higher sales farms (11.2 percent) (Table 13). The Northern Great Plains had the highest percentage of large family farms at 8.9 percent (Table 14) and the highest percentage of large family farm acres at 19.7 (Table 15). The Northern Great Plains also had the highest percentage of very large family farms at 8.0 (Table 16). However, the largest percentage of very large family farm acres was in the Mississippi Portal at 39.5 percent (Table 17). Small family higher sales farms. Small family farming occupation higher sales farms are sole proprietorship farms with market values of agricultural products sold between $100,000 and $249,999 and principal operators who report farming as their primary occupation. Small family higher sales farms were strongly correlated to farms with payments (τ = .641, p = .000). This 68 correlation was also strong based on location quotients (τ = .540, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of small family farming occupation higher sales farms, the Northern Great Plains was very high (2.82) followed by the Heartland. The Eastern Uplands was the lowest (0.30) followed by the Southern Seaboard, Mississippi Portal, and Fruitful Rim (Table 13). This trend holds true when looking at the county level location quotients (Figure 14). The Eastern Uplands is visibly the lowest with all counties being in the below or normal categories on the map. Based on the mean percentage of small family farming occupation higher sales farms per county the Northern Great Plains were the highest at 11.2 percent followed by the Heartland at Table 13. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of small family higher sales farms by Farm Resource Region. Small Small Higher Ordinal Ordinal Higher Small b a Higher LQ (No.) Rank Rank (%) Heartland 60.6 7.4 2 1.60 2 Northern 49.0 6.5 3 1.12 4 Crescent Northern Great 60.7 11.2 1 2.82 1 Plains Prairie 32.6 4.0 4 1.21 3 Gateway Eastern 12.6 1.6 9 0.30 9 Uplands Southern 9.6 1.9 8 0.51 8 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 25.4 2.8 6 0.63 6 Basin and 18.8 3.6 5 1.00 5 Range Mississippi 12.6 2.3 7 0.56 7 Portal 32.5 4.5 National a b Small Family Farming Occupation Higher Sales (farms) / Farms (number). Location quotient of Small Family Farming Occupation Higher Sales (farms) / Farms (number). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.743190 2.743191 - 3.976291 3.976292 - 9.417600 -2.283287 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 8.047628 69 Figure 14. The location quotients of small family farming occupation higher sales farms were above normal in the Northern Great Plains and Heartland (left). Positive discordant counties of small family higher sales farms to farms with payments are centralized in the Northern Great Plains and negative discordant pairs are concentrated in the Mississippi Portal (right). 70 7.4 percent. The Eastern Uplands were the lowest at 1.6 percent (Table 13). All analyses are very similar. Based on the correlation of location quotients, the location quotient of farms with commodity payments would be expected to increase as the location quotient of small family farming occupation higher sales farms increase. Based on the strength of the correlation the large number of concordant counties on Figure 14 is expected. The positive discordant counties are centralized in the Northern Great Plains with some in the Basin and Range and Northern Crescent. The Northern Great Plains has very large location quotients of small family higher sales farms without a corresponding increase in the location quotients of farms with payments. Despite the strong correlation other variables are having a stronger influence. The negative discordant counties are concentrated in the Mississippi Portal. The Heartland has both positive and negative discordant counties, yet is ranked second highest based on both mean percent per county and location quotient. This means that although there are more negative discordant counties than positive, the positive discordant counties must be much larger in magnitude than the negative counties. Large family. Large family farms are sole proprietorship farms with market values of agricultural products sold between $250,000 and $499,999. Large family farms were strongly correlated to farms with commodity payments (τ = .631, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was also strong based on location quotients (τ = .551, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of large family farms, the Northern Great Plains was very high (2.44) followed by the Heartland as the only other region with 71 a location quotient above normal. The Eastern Uplands was the lowest (0.31) followed by the Southern Seaboard, and Fruitful Rim (Table 14). This trend holds true when looking at the county level location quotients (Figure 15), with some high outlying counties scattered in all regions but the Eastern Uplands. Based on the mean percentage of large family farms per county the Northern Great Plains was highest at 8.9 percent followed by the Heartland at 7.0 percent. The Eastern Uplands were lowest at 1.5 percent followed by the Southern Seaboard at 2.1 percent (Table 14). Based on the correlation of location quotients, the location quotient of farms with commodity payments is expected to increase as the location quotient of large family Table 14. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of large family farms by Farm Resource Region. Large Large Family Ordinal Ordinal Family Large b a Family LQ (No.) Rank Rank (%) Heartland 57.8 7.0 2 1.81 2 Northern 12.5 4.3 3 0.89 4 Crescent Northern Great 18.6 8.9 1 2.44 1 Plains Prairie 11.9 3.3 4 1.22 3 Gateway Eastern 7.1 1.5 9 0.31 9 Uplands Southern 11.0 2.1 8 0.60 7 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 24.8 2.8 5 0.65 7 Basin and 13.6 2.6 7 0.84 5 Range Mississippi 15.0 2.7 6 0.81 6 Portal 28.1 3.9 National a b Large Family (farms) / Farms (number). Location quotient of Large Family (farms) / Farms (number). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.837501 2.837502 - 4.130665 4.130666 - 5.576563 -2.283287 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 3.705381 72 Figure 15. The location quotients of large family farms were highest in the Northern Great Plains and Heartland, and lowest in the Eastern Uplands (left). Discordant counties of large family farms to farms with payments are scattered with patterns that barely fit Farm Resource Region boundaries (right). 73 farms increase. Based on the strength of the correlation, concordant pairs are expected to outnumber discordant pairs and patterns are expected to be hard to see (Figure 15). Positive discordant pairs are focused around the border of the Heartland and the Northern Great Plains. The negative discordant counties are scattered but predominant in the center of the Prairie Gateway and the eastern side of the Mississippi Portal. Large family farm acres were strongly correlated to commodity payments (τ = .527, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was only moderate based on location quotients (τ = .319, p = .000) (Appendix A). In table 15, the Northern Great Plains and Heartland were the only regions with above normal location quotients. The Table 15. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of large family farm acres by Farm Resource Region. Large Large Large Family Ordinal Ordinal Family Family a b Acres(ac) Rank Rank Acres (%) Acres LQ Heartland 49,197.9 19.2 2 1.36 2 Northern 18,493.9 14.5 3 0.82 5 Crescent Northern 176,845.9 19.7 1 1.47 1 Great Plains Prairie 76,761.2 13.8 4 1.03 3 Gateway Eastern 8,447.0 6.9 9 0.37 9 Uplands Southern 9,177.7 9.2 8 0.59 8 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 36,785.1 9.5 7 0.60 7 Basin and 72,665.1 13.4 5 0.86 4 Range Mississippi 19,174.9 10.8 6 0.66 6 Portal 45,559.9 15.3 National a b Large Family (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). Location quotient of Large Family (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 1.735495 1.735496 - 3.133540 3.133541 - 3.298801 -11.695110 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 3.219483 74 Figure 16. The location quotients of large family farm acres were highest in the Northern Great Plains and Heartland. Trends are hard to see based on the high amount of omitted counties (left). The differences between the location quotients of large family farm acres and commodity payments were greatest in the Heartland, Mississippi portal, and Northern Great Plains (right). 75 Eastern Uplands was the lowest (0.37) followed by the Southern Seaboard, and Fruitful Rim. This trend holds true in Figure 16 with most outliers being centralized in the Northern Great Plains and Heartland. The highest mean percentage of large family farm acres was in the Northern Great Plains at 19.7 percent and the Heartland at 19.2 percent. The Eastern Uplands was the lowest at 6.9 percent (Table 15). The location quotients of commodity payments are expected to increase as the location quotients of large family farm acres increase, but only somewhat based on the moderate correlation. It is hard to see patterns in Figure 16 based on the large amount of missing data, but some trends are visible. Positive discordant counties are centralized in the Northern Great Plains. Here the location quotients of large family farm acres are larger than the location quotients of commodity payments because another variable is influencing the commodity payments more strongly. This is understandable based on the strength of the correlation. Negative discordant counties are focused in the Heartland, Mississippi Portal, and along the southern edge of the Southern Seaboard. In these regions the location quotients of commodity payments outweigh the location quotients of large family farm acres, again due to the moderate strength of the correlation. Very large family. Very large family farms are sole proprietorship farms with market values of agricultural products sold over $500,000. Very large family farms were strongly correlated to farms with commodity payments (τ = .505, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was only moderate based on location quotients (τ = .429, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of very large family farms, the Northern Great Plains, Heartland, and Mississippi Portal were all above normal. The 76 Eastern Uplands, Basin and Range, and Northern Crescent were all below normal (Table 16). This trend holds true when looking at the county level location quotients (Figure 17). Based on the mean percentages of very large family farms by Farm Resource Region the Northern Great Plains was highest at 8.0 percent, followed by the Heartland at 6.9 percent. The Basin and Range and Eastern Uplands were lowest, tied at 2.2 percent each (Table 16). Table 16. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of very large family farms by Farm Resource Region. Very Large Very Large Very Large Ordinal Family LQb Ordinal Family Family(No.) Rank Rank (%)a Heartland 56.8 6.9 2 1.56 2 Northern 27.3 3.6 6 0.66 7 Crescent Northern 43.3 8.0 1 1.77 1 Great Plains Prairie 29.2 3.5 7 1.19 5 Gateway Eastern 17.0 2.2 8 0.40 9 Uplands Southern 27.1 5.3 3 1.20 4 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 45.3 5.0 5 0.98 6 Basin and 11.8 2.2 8 0.59 8 Range Mississippi 28.0 5.1 4 1.47 3 Portal 32.9 4.6 National a b Very Large Family (number) / Farms (number). Location quotient of Very Large Family (number) / Farms (number). The correlation of very large family farms and farms with payments based on location quotients is only moderate. Therefore, it is harder to expect to see patterns in Figure 17. Discordant counties, both positive and negative are more scattered and many 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.786678 2.786679 - 4.076460 4.076461 - 8.071464 -2.283287 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 7.064769 77 Figure 17. The location quotients of very large family farms were above normal in the Northern Great Plains, Heartland, and Mississippi Portal (left). The differences between the location quotients of very large family farms and farms with commodity payments were scattered with trends among Farm Resource Regions hard to discern (right). 78 regions have a fair share of both categories. There is a large section of positive discordant counties in the western part of the Southern Seaboard and Eastern Uplands. There are also large clusters of positive discordant counties on the Pacific Coast. Negative discordant counties tend to be in the Midwest and the eastern parts of the prairie states. However, trends by Farm Resource Region are hard to discern. Very large family farm acres were strongly correlated to commodity payments (τ = .607, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was only moderate based on location quotients (τ = .458, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of very large family farm acres in Table 17, the Heartland, Mississippi Portal Table 17. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of very large family farm acres by Farm Resource Region. Very Large Very Large Very Large Family Acres Ordinal Ordinal Family Family Rank Rank (ac) Acres (%)a Acres LQb Heartland 90,456.4 35.3 2 1.48 1 Northern 31,678.9 24.8 4 0.80 7 Crescent Northern 238,718.8 26.6 3 1.28 3 Great Plains Prairie 129,495.0 23.3 6 1.02 4 Gateway Eastern 12,431.1 10.1 9 0.31 9 Uplands Southern 21,023.3 21.2 7 0.83 6 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 95,439.2 24.6 5 0.96 5 Basin and 96,826.4 17.9 8 0.64 8 Range Mississippi 70,240.7 39.5 1 1.35 2 Portal 76,868.7 25.8 National a b Very Large Family (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). Location quotient of Very Large Family (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.577768 2.577769 - 3.533457 -10.176452 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 2.500010 79 Figure 18. The location quotients of very large family farm acres were above normal in the Mississippi Portal, Heartland, and Northern Great Plains (left). The differences between the location quotients of very large family farm acres and commodity payments were greatest in the Mississippi Portal, Heartland, and Northern Great Plains (right). 80 and Northern Great Plains were above normal. The Eastern Uplands and Basin and Range regions were below normal. This trend holds true when looking at the county level location quotients (Figure 18), but again trends are hard to see because of the large number of counties with omitted data. The Mississippi Portal had the highest mean percentage of very large family farm acres at 39.5 percent, followed by the Heartland at 35.3 percent. The Eastern Uplands had the lowest mean percentage at 10.1 percent followed by the Basin and Range at 17.9 percent. The ordinal ranks of the Farm Resource Regions based on the location quotients and mean percentages are different from one another (Table 17). Based on the correlation of the location quotients, the location quotient of commodity payments would be moderately expected to increase as the location quotient of very large family farms acres increases. On Figure 18, the positive discordant counties are concentrated in the Northern Great Plains and the northern part of the Prairie Gateway. The payment variables in these regions are more strongly correlated to another variable that is causing them to remain low despite the high very large family farm acres. The negative discordant counties are concentrated in the Mississippi Portal and Heartland, and southern portion of the Southern Seaboard. In these regions the government payment variable is elevated by a more strongly correlated variable. Since the correlation is only moderate between the location quotients of very large family farm acres and commodity payments, it is expected that not every county will fit the correlation. 81 Commodity Variables Commodity variables include the number of farms growing corn, soybean, and wheat as well as the acres of these three commodities. Farms with cropland and total cropland acres are also included as salient variables in this paper. Nationally, an average of 15.8 percent of farms per county produced corn (Table 18) for a total of 10.5 percent of acres (Table 19). The mean number of farms producing soybeans per county was at 12.7 percent (Table 20) for a total of 7.7 percent of acres (Table 21). Wheat was produced on a mean of 7.3 percent of farms per county (Table 22), and 6.4 percent of acres per county (Table 23). Nationally, 76.4 percent of farms per county (Table 24) had cropland for only 44.5 percent of the acreages of land in farms (Table 25). The percentage of farms producing corn was highest in the Heartland at 41.3 percent (Table 18), as was the percentage (37.4 percent) of acres in corn production (Table 19). The percentage of farms producing soybean and the percentage of acres in soybean were highest in the Heartland at 37.8 percent (Table 20) and 27.7 percent (Table 21), respectively. The Northern Great Plains had the highest percentage (28.7 percent) of farms producing wheat (Table 22) and the highest percentage (11.9 percent) of acres in wheat (Table 23). Finally, the Heartland had the highest percentage of farms with total cropland at 86.6 percent (Table 24) and the highest percentage of acres in total farmland at 80.9 percent (Table 25). Corn. Corn farms were strongly correlated to farms with payments (τ = .613, p = .000). Corn farms were also strongly correlated based on location quotients (τ = .556, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of corn farms, the Heartland was 82 very high (2.61) with no other regions being above normal. The Basin and Range was the lowest followed by the Fruitful Rim, and Eastern Uplands (Table 18). This trend holds true when looking at the county level location quotients (Figure 19) where very few counties are above normal outside of the Heartland and its surrounding counties. Based on the mean percentage of farms per county producing corn, the Heartland was far above average at 41.3 percent, with the Northern Crescent following distantly at 24.0 percent. Corn producing farms were the lowest in the Basin and Range and Fruitful Rim at 1.0 and 1.7 percent, respectively. The ordinal ranks of Farm Resource Regions by location quotients and mean percentage were similar (Table 18). Table 18. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of corn farms by Farm Resource Region. Ordinal Ordinal Corn LQb Corn (No.) Corn (%)a Rank Rank Heartland 339.9 41.3 1 2.61 1 Northern 179.2 24.0 2 1.07 3 Crescent Northern Great 90.9 16.8 3 1.09 2 Plains Prairie Gateway 67.6 8.2 4 0.74 4 Eastern 35.3 4.5 7 0.27 7 Uplands Southern 36.7 7.1 6 0.57 5 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 15.2 1.7 8 0.15 8 Basin and 5.4 1.0 9 0.05 9 Range Mississippi 43.3 7.9 5 0.56 6 Portal 113.0 15.8 National a Corn (number) / Farms (number). b Location quotient of Corn (number) / Farms (number). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 3.045091 3.045092 - 4.587977 4.587978 - 4.986792 -2.474293 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 2.310940 83 Figure 19. The location quotients of corn farms were highest in the Heartland (left). The differences between the location quotients of corn farms and farms with commodity payments were greatest in the Heartland, Northern Great Plains, Prairie Gateway, and Mississippi Portal (right). 84 Based on the strength of the correlation, farms with payments location quotients were expected to increase as corn farms location quotients increase. The strength of the correlation is visible in Figure 19. The positive discordant counties are all clustered in and around the Heartland, exactly where the above normal location quotients were focused on Figure 19. In these counties, the location quotients of farms with payments are lower than expected based on the location quotients of corn farms. The negative discordant counties are in the Northern Great Plains, Prairie Gateway, and Mississippi Portal. Here, although the location quotients of corn farms are low, location quotients of farms with payments are higher, meaning that another variable is more important in these regions. Corn acres were strongly correlated to commodity payments (τ = .576, p = .000). This correlation was also strong based on location quotients (τ = .560, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of corn acres, the Heartland was very high (3.75), followed by the Northern Crescent as the only other region above normal. All other regions but the Mississippi Portal were below normal (Table 19). Figure 20 supports this trend, with some above normal counties in the Mississippi Portal, Prairie Gateway, and Southern Seaboard. Based on the mean percentage of corn acres in each county, the Heartland was again the highest at 37.4 percent followed by the Northern Crescent at 19.5 percent. The Basin and Range and Fruitful Rim were lowest at 0.1 and 1.1 percent, respectively. The ordinal ranks of Farm Resource Regions based on location quotients and mean percentages were very similar (Table 19). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 3.819450 3.819451 - 5.743412 5.743413 - 7.513393 -11.920037 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 4.714063 85 Figure 20. The location quotients of corn acres were highest in the Heartland and the Northern Crescent. All other regions except the Mississippi Portal were below normal (left). The differences between the location quotients of corn acres and commodity payments were greatest in the Heartland, Mississippi Portal, and Southern Seaboard (right). 86 Table 19. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of corn farm acres by Farm Resource Region. Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Grea t Plains Prairie Gatew ay Eastern Uplan ds Southern Seaboard Fruitful Rim Basin and Range Mississippi Portal Corn Acres (ac) 95,835.3 Corn Acres (%)a 37.4 Ordinal Rank 1 Corn Acres LQb 3.72 Ordinal Rank 1 24,903.1 19.5 2 1.35 2 37,582.5 4.2 6 0.62 6 31,773.2 3,208.4 5.7 2.6 5 7 0.73 0.23 4 7 6,661.3 6.7 4 0.70 5 4,110.9 1.1 8 0.14 8 563.9 0.1 9 0.01 9 17,381.1 9.8 3 0.81 3 31,151.4 10.5 National a b Corn (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). Location quotient of Corn (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). Based on the strength of the location quotient correlation, commodity payment location quotients were expected to increase as corn farm acres location quotients increase. Due to the large number of omitted data, some patterns may not be visible but some strong patterns do emerge (Figure 20). Positive discordant counties again are centralized in the Heartland and surrounding counties. Negative discordant counties are in the Mississippi Portal and Southern Seaboard. In these regions, despite the low location quotients of corn farm acres the location quotients of commodity payments are higher based on other variables. Soybeans. Soybean farms were strongly correlated to the number of farms receiving commodity payments based on raw data (τ = .574, p = .000). This same correlation was 87 strong based on location quotients (τ = .547, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of soybean farms, the Heartland was the highest (3.01). The Basin and Range, Fruitful Rim, and Eastern Uplands had the lowest location quotients of soybean farms (Table 20). The concentration of high outliers in the Heartland supports the location quotient analysis, with some outliers clustered in the surrounding regions as well as the Southern Seaboard and Mississippi Portal (Figure 21). The Heartland had the highest mean percentage of soybean farms per county at 37.8 percent, followed distantly by the Northern Crescent at 14.2 percent. The Basin and Range and Fruitful Rim had the lowest mean percentages at 0.0 and 0.3 percent, respectively (Table 20). Table 20. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of soybean farms by Farm Resource Region. Soybean Ordinal Ordinal Soybean Soybean a b (%) LQ (No.) Rank Rank 310.9 37.8 1 3.01 1 Heartland Northern 106.6 14.2 2 0.77 4 Crescent Northern Great 71.6 13.3 3 0.92 3 Plains 6.3 5 0.63 5 Prairie Gatewa y 52.0 1.9 7 0.12 7 Eastern Upland s 14.8 Southern 30.7 6.0 6 0.61 6 Seaboard 2.5 0.3 8 0.05 8 Fruitful Rim 0.0 9 0.00 9 Basin and Rang e 0.1 Mississippi 63.7 11.6 4 1.14 2 Portal 90.7 12.7 National a b Soybean (farms) / Farms (number). Location quotient of Soybean (farms) / Farms (number). Based on the strength of the correlation between the location quotients of soybean farms and farms with commodity payments, the location quotients of farms with commodity payments should increase as the location quotients of soybean farms increase. 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.961782 2.961783 - 4.442673 4.442674 - 6.453298 -2.597239 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 3.539824 88 Figure 21. The location quotients of soybean farms per county were highest in the Heartland followed distantly by the Mississippi Portal. There were some outliers scattered in the Southern Seaboard, Northern Great Plains, and Northern Crescent (left). Discordant counties based on soybean farms are located in the Heartland, Northern Great Plains, and Prairie Gateway 89 Positive discordant counties are concentrated in the Heartland, meaning that in this region the location quotients of soybean farms are higher than the location quotients of farms with commodity payments (Figure 21). More importantly, the negative discordant counties are located in the Northern Great Plains and Prairie Gateway. This means that in these regions the location quotients of farms with payments were higher than expected based on the location quotients of soybean farms. Soybean acres were strongly correlated to the amount of commodity payments (τ = .501, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was also strong based on location quotients (τ = .561, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of soybean acres, the Heartland was the highest (3.88) followed by the Mississippi Portal (2.19). The Basin and Range, Fruitful Rim, Eastern Uplands, and Prairie Gateway were all below normal (Table 21). Most high outliers were concentrated in the Heartland and Mississippi Portal (Figure 22), with some scattered along the edges of the Southern Seaboard, Northern Great Plains and Northern Crescent. Based on the mean percentage of soybean acres per county, the Heartland was again the highest at 27.7 percent followed by the Mississippi Portal at 21.2 percent. The Basin and Range and Fruitful Rim were again the lowest at 0.0 and 0.1 percent, respectively (Table 21). Based on the large number of omitted data in Figure 22, trends are hard to discern. However, positive discordant counties are clustered in the Heartland and surrounding counties. Negative discordant counties may be focused in the Northern Crescent, Southern Seaboard, and Prairie Gateway, but it is hard to be sure based on the large numbers of omitted data in these regions. 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 4.847404 4.847405 - 7.271106 7.271107 - 7.980652 -11.999322 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 5.627714 90 Figure 22. The location quotients of soybean acres were highest in the Heartland and Mississippi Portal. There were a few outliers in the Southern Seaboard, Northern Great Plains, and Northern Crescent (left). The differences between the location quotients of soybean acres and commodity payments were greatest in the Heartland (right). 91 Table 21. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of soybean farm acres by Farm Resource Region. Soybean Ordinal Ordinal Soybean Soybean a b Acres (%) Acres LQ (ac) Rank Rank Heartland 70,912.0 27.7 1 3.88 1 Northern 15,173.0 11.9 3 1.15 3 Crescent Northern Great 37,427.3 4.2 5 0.86 5 Plains Prairie 12,324.2 2.2 7 0.50 6 Gateway Eastern 3,073.9 2.5 6 0.27 7 Uplands Southern 7,349.5 7.4 4 1.11 4 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 417.1 0.1 8 0.06 8 Basin and 0.0 0.0 9 0.00 9 Range Mississippi 37,754.4 21.2 2 2.19 2 Portal 22,980.2 7.7 National a b Soybean (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). Location quotient of Soybean (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). Wheat. Wheat farms were strongly correlated to farms with commodity payments (τ = .554, p = .000) based on raw data. This was strongly correlated based on location quotients as well (τ = .553, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of wheat farms, the Northern Great Plains and Prairie Gateway were the only regions above normal (Table 22), supported by the county level map (Figure 23). The Eastern Uplands, Fruitful Rim, Basin and Range, and Southern Seaboard were all below normal (Table 22). Based on the mean percentage of wheat farms per county, the Northern Great Plains were the highest at 28.7 percent followed distantly by the Prairie Gateway at 14.5 percent. The Eastern Uplands and the Fruitful Rim were the lowest at 1.2 and 2.4 percent, respectively (Table 22). 92 Table 22. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of wheat farms by Farm Resource Region. Wheat Ordinal Ordinal Wheat LQb (No.) Wheat (%)a Rank Rank 66.8 8.1 3 1.16 3 Heartland Northern 53.0 7.1 4 0.71 5 Crescent Northern Great 154.7 28.7 1 3.93 1 Plains 119.7 14.5 2 2.80 2 Prairie Gateway 1.2 9 0.13 9 Eastern Upland s 9.1 Southern 16.6 3.2 7 0.62 6 Seaboard 21.6 2.4 8 0.36 8 Fruitful Rim 4.7 6 0.61 7 Basin and Rang e 24.6 Mississippi 28.4 5.2 5 0.90 4 Portal 52.2 7.3 National a b Wheat (number) / Farms (number). Location quotient of Wheat (number) / Farms (number). Since the correlation based on location quotients was strong the location quotients, the location quotient of farms with payments will increase as the location quotient of wheat farms increases. Positive discordant counties are centralized in the Northern Great Plains and the Prairie Gateway (Figure 23). This means that wheat farms were concentrated in these regions, but farms with payments were not. Negative discordant counties are centralized in the Heartland. This means that farms with payments were concentrated in this region but wheat farms were not, so another variable must have a stronger effect on the farms with payments in this region. 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.781679 2.781680 - 4.187196 4.187197 - 9.732654 -2.556991 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 7.135415 93 Figure 23. The location quotients of wheat farms were highest in the Northern Great Plains and Prairie Gateway (left). Discordant counties based on wheat farms were concentrated in the Northern Great Plains, Prairie Gateway, and Heartland (right). 94 Wheat acres were strongly correlated to commodity payments (τ = .504, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was weaker based on the location quotients for each county (τ = .297, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of wheat acres, the Northern Great Plains and Prairie Gateway were above normal. All other regions were below normal with the lowest location quotients in the Eastern Uplands, Northern Crescent, and Fruitful Rim (Table 23). This trend holds true when looking at the county level location quotients (Figure 24), but again trends are hard to see because of the large number of counties with omitted data. The mean percentage of wheat farm acres per county was highest in the Northern Great Plains (11.9 percent) and the Prairie Gateway (9.1 percent). The lowest mean percentages were in the Eastern Uplands (1.0 percent) and the Heartland and Northern Crescent at 2.9 percent each (Table 23). Table 23. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of wheat farm acres by Farm Resource Region. Wheat Ordinal Ordinal Wheat Wheat a b Acres (%) Acres LQ (ac) Rank Rank 7,306.5 2.9 7 0.52 6 Heartland Northern 3,735.1 2.9 7 0.38 8 Crescent Northern Grea t 11.9 1 2.38 1 106,356.1 Plains 9.1 2 1.70 2 Prairie Gatewa y 50,901.1 1.0 9 0.12 9 Eastern Uplan ds 1,219.3 Southern 3,282.5 3.3 5 0.62 4 Seaboard 12,117.4 3.1 6 0.40 7 Fruitful Rim 3.6 4 0.60 5 Basin and Ran ge 19,240.3 Mississippi 9,590.8 5.4 3 0.68 3 Portal 19,132.9 6.4 National a b Wheat (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). Location quotient of Wheat (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 1.839130 1.839131 - 2.752493 2.752494 - 8.180753 -11.999322 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 7.123477 95 Figure 24. The location quotients of wheat acres were highest in the Northern Great Plains and Prairie Gateway (left). Discordant pairs based on wheat farm acres were greatest in the Northern Great Plains, Prairie Gateway, Heartland, and Mississippi Portal (right). 96 Based on the weakness of the correlation between location quotients of wheat farm acres and commodity payments, trends on Figure 24 are not expected to be strong. Also, due to the large number of omitted data trends are not expected to be highly visible. The low number of concordant counties is expected based on the weakness of the correlation as well. Positive discordant counties are focused in the Northern Great Plains and Prairie Gateway, as expected based on the high location quotients of wheat farm acres in these regions. Negative discordant counties are concentrated in the Heartland, Northern Crescent, Mississippi Portal, and Southern Seaboard. The patterns are not as strong in the Northern Crescent and Southern Seaboard, again based on the large number of omitted data. These regions have high location quotients of commodity payments despite low location quotients of wheat farm acres because another variable is more strongly correlated to commodity payments in these regions. Total cropland. Finally, total cropland is all cropland harvested including non-covered commodities and idled cropland. Total cropland farms were strongly correlated to farms with commodity payments (τ = .543, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was moderate based on location quotients (τ = .472, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of total cropland farms, all regions were normal, ranging between 0.81 and 1.13 (Table 24). Although Figure 25 may appear to be full of high location quotients, these are all counties that fall within the normal location quotient range. There are below normal outliers in the Fruitful Rim, Basin and Range, and in 0.000000 - 0.364277 0.364278 - 0.619962 0.619963 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 1.305211 -1.664737 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 1.305211 97 Figure 25. The location quotients of total cropland farms were normal for all regions (left). The differences between the location quotients of total cropland farms and farms with commodity payments were greatest in the Northern Great Plains, Prairie Gateway, and Heartland (right). 98 Table 24. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of total cropland farms by Farm Resource Region. Cropland Ordinal Ordinal Cropland Cropland a b (%) LQ (No.) Rank Rank Heartland 713.3 86.6 1 1.13 1 Northern 637.1 85.2 2 1.09 2 Crescent Northern Great 453.2 84.0 3 1.08 3 Plains Prairie 577.4 70.1 6 0.95 5 Gateway Eastern 590.2 75.9 4 0.99 4 Uplands Southern 356.7 69.1 7 0.91 7 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 593.8 66.2 9 0.81 9 Basin and 352.8 66.7 8 0.85 8 Range Mississippi 392.8 71.4 5 0.93 6 Portal 547.4 76.4 National a b Total Cropland (number) / Farms (number). Location quotient of Total Cropland (number) / Farms (number). western Prairie Gateway and Northern Great Plains. There are very few counties that are above normal scattered throughout the Heartland and Mississippi Portal. Based on the mean percentage of farms with total cropland per county, the highest regions were the Heartland (86.6 percent), Northern Crescent (85.2 percent), and the Northern Great Plains (84.0 percent). The Fruitful Rim (66.2 percent), Basin and Range (66.7 percent), and the Southern Seaboard (69.1 percent) had the lowest mean percentages of farms with total cropland per county (Table 24). The location quotients of farms with payments were expected to increase as the location quotients of farms with total cropland increase based on the correlation. In Figure 25, the positive discordant counties were scattered but may be centralized in the 99 Eastern Uplands, Northern Crescent, and western parts of the Fruitful Rim. Negative discordant counties were concentrated in the Northern Great Plains, Prairie Gateway, and Heartland. In these regions, the location quotients of farms with payments were larger than the location quotients of farms with total cropland. Total cropland acres were strongly correlated to commodity payments (τ = .697, p = .000) based on raw data. This correlation was also strong based on location quotients (τ = .596, p = .000) (Appendix A). Based on the mean location quotients of total cropland acres, the Heartland, Northern Crescent, and Mississippi Portal are all above normal. The Basin and Range region is the only region with a below normal location quotient (Table 25). On the county level map (Figure 26), the Heartland, Northern Table 25. The means, mean location quotients, and ordinal ranks of total cropland farm acres by Farm Resource Region. Cropland Ordinal Ordinal Cropland Cropland Acres (%)a Acres LQb (ac) Rank Rank Heartland 207,227.4 80.9 1 1.77 1 Northern 85,057.2 66.5 2 1.31 2 Crescent Northern 381,285.7 42.5 4 1.10 4 Great Plains Prairie 211,425.6 38.0 6 0.95 5 Gateway Eastern 45,492.9 37.1 7 0.82 7 Uplands Southern 41,485.5 41.8 5 0.95 5 Seaboard Fruitful Rim 113,765.0 29.3 8 0.80 8 Basin and 90,990.8 16.8 9 0.49 9 Range Mississippi 115,932.2 65.2 3 1.29 3 Portal 132,547.9 44.5 National a b Total Cropland (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). Location quotient of Total Cropland (acres) / Land in Farms (acres). 0.000000 - 0.750000 0.750001 - 1.250000 1.250001 - 2.245204 -10.197265 - -0.510000 -0.509999 - 0.510000 0.510001 - 2.245204 100 Figure 26. The location quotients of total cropland acres were highest in the Heartland, Northern Crescent, and Mississippi Portal (left). Negative discordant counties are concentrated in the Mississippi Portal and Southern Seaboard with some in the Heartland (right). 101 Crescent, and Mississippi Portal are above normal. However, the Southern Seaboard, Prairie Gateway, and Fruitful Rim all have large numbers of counties with above normal location quotients as well. Based on the mean percentages of total cropland acres per county, the Heartland was again the highest at 80.9 percent, followed by the Northern Crescent (66.5 percent) and the Mississippi Portal (65.2 percent). The ordinal ranks of regions based on location quotients and mean percentages were very similar (Table 25). Based on the strength of the correlation between location quotients, commodity payments would be expected to increase as total cropland acres increase. Logically, this correlation would be very strong since the amount of commodity payments received is based on the acres of covered commodities produced. The low number of discordant counties in Figure 26 is evidence of the strength of this correlation. Positive discordant counties are sparse and highly scattered. Negative discordant counties are concentrated in the Mississippi Portal, with some in the Southern Seaboard and even fewer in the Heartland. In these counties, the location quotients of commodity payments are larger than expected based on the location quotients of total cropland acres, meaning that other variables are more strongly correlated to payments in these areas. The purpose of the county level analysis was to determine if commodity variables are the only variables that are strongly correlated to government payment variables. This hypothesis was rejected. Although corn, soybean, wheat, and total cropland were all strongly correlated to commodity payment variables, they were not the only variables with strong correlations. Although the correlation of the other variables does not mean they directly determine payment amounts, they do play a role in the participation in the commodity payment programs. 102 Farm Resource Regions The other purpose of this research is to determine if payments are distributed equitably by Farm Resource Region. Given that commodity payments are determined by the commodities produced, you would expect to see variations among Farm Resource Regions based on the commodities they produce and the amount of commodities produced. Following this logic, those regions with the highest government payment variables should have the highest commodity variables, and those regions with the lowest government payment variables should have the lowest commodity variables. However, not all commodities are created equal. In 2006, corn farms accounted for 46 percent of commodity payments, followed by upland cotton farms (23 percent), wheat farms (10 percent), rice farms (8 percent), and soybean farms (6 percent) (ERS, 2006). Therefore, regions specializing in corn, for example, would be expected to have higher location quotients of payment variables than regions specializing in barley, for example, even though barley is a covered commodity. Heartland. In 2007 the Heartland had the third highest mean number of farms per county (823.3) but the fifth highest mean land in farms (256,298.4 acres). Commodity payments went to an average of 453.2 farms per county for a mean county payment received of $3,526,080. Income dependence averaged 21.1 percent (Appendix B). The Heartland had the second highest location quotient of farms with commodity payments (Table 1), and the second highest location quotient of commodity payments (Table 2). The Heartland had strong correlations between farms with commodity payments and all salient variables except wheat (Table 26). Commodity payments were strongly 103 correlated to market value, net income, corn acres, and total cropland acres. The correlation to production expenses was also very high (Table 26). Based on the correlations of corn and soybean farms to farms with payments, it was expected that the Heartland would have a very high location quotient of farms with payments. Especially since corn and soybean farms accounted for 52 percent of government payments in 2006 (ERS, 2006). However, based on the fact that the only covered commodity strongly correlated to commodity payments was corn, the high location quotient of commodity payments is slightly unexpected. Table 26. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Heartland. Farms with Payments (No.) Kendall’s τ Commodity Payments ($) 0.575** Market Value ($) Farming Occupation (No.) 0.586** Gross Income ($) Small Family Higher (No.) 0.670** Production Expenses ($) Large Family (No.) 0.562** Net Income ($) Very Large Family (No.) 0.652** Large Family (ac.) Part Owner (No.) 0.520** Very Large Family (ac.) Tenant (No.) 0.732** Part Owner (ac.) Corn (No.) 0.739** Tenant (ac.) Soybean (No.) 0.075** Corn (ac.) Wheat (No.) 0.535** Soybean (ac.) Total Cropland (No.) Wheat (ac.) Total Cropland (ac.) *p < .05. **p < .01. Kendall’s τ 0.520** 0.343** 0.499** 0.506** 0.318** 0.422** 0.405** 0.428** 0.626** 0.437** -0.050 0.650** Northern Crescent The average county in the Northern Crescent had 748.2 farms and 127,980.2 acres of farmland. On average, 239.1 farms received government commodity payments for $1,328,181 per county. Income dependence averaged 12.9 percent for the Northern Crescent (Appendix B). The Northern Crescent had the fifth highest location quotient 104 farms with payments, which was on the lower end of the normal range (Table 1). The location quotient of commodity payments was on the higher end of the normal range and the fourth highest region (Table 2). Farms with commodity payments were strongly correlated to corn and soybean farms in the Northern Crescent (Table 27). Farming occupation and tenant farms have little to do with farms with commodity payments in the Northern Crescent. Commodity payments were strongly correlated to corn, soybean, and total cropland acres (Table 27). Although payments were strongly correlated to these commodity variables, the mean location quotients of these variables were all at or slightly above normal, hence the mean location quotients of farms with commodity payments and payments were as expected. Table 27. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Northern Crescent. Farms with Payments (No.) Kendall’s τ Commodity Payments ($) Kendall’s τ 0.075* 0.338** Farming Occupation (No.) Market Value ($) 0.441** Gross Income ($) 0.239** Small Family Higher (No.) ** 0.437 0.286** Large Family (No.) Production Expenses ($) 0.351** Net Income ($) 0.429** Very Large Family (No.) ** 0.485 0.483** Part Owner (No.) Large Family (ac.) 0.484** -0.103** Very Large Family (ac.) Tenant (No.) 0.637** Part Owner (ac.) 0.476** Corn (No.) ** 0.587 0.296** Soybean (No.) Tenant (ac.) 0.482** Corn (ac.) 0.591** Wheat (No.) ** 0.407 0.574** Total Cropland (No.) Soybean (ac.) 0.423** Wheat (ac.) 0.527** Total Cropland (ac.) *p < .05. **p < .01. Northern Great Plains. The average county in the Northern Great Plains had the third lowest number of farms (539.7) but the highest land in farms (896,661.4 acres). On average, over half of 105 the farms received commodity payments (291.9) for a county average of $3,403,486. Income dependence was the lowest among farm resource regions at 12.4 percent (Appendix B). The Northern Great Plains had the highest location quotient of farms with commodity payments (Table 1), but the third lowest location quotient of commodity payments (Table 2). This means that although many farms receive payments, the payment per acre is lower than would be expected because the average farm is so large. Table 28. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Northern Great Plains. Farms with Payments (No.) Kendall’s τ Commodity Payments ($) Kendall’s τ 0.324** Market Value ($) 0.587** Farming Occupation (No.) 0.272** Gross Income ($) 0.670** Small Family Higher (No.) ** 0.421 0.551** Large Family (No.) Production Expenses ($) 0.335** Net Income ($) 0.720** Very Large Family (No.) 0.026 0.414** Large Family (ac.) Part Owner (No.) ** 0.159 0.493** Tenant (No.) Very Large Family (ac.) 0.308** Part Owner (ac.) 0.031** Corn (No.) ** 0.213 0.035 Soybean (No.) Tenant (ac.) ** ** 0.564 0.463 Wheat (No.) Corn (ac.) 0.627** 0.415** Soybean (ac.) Total Cropland (No.) 0.535** Wheat (ac.) 0.805** Total Cropland (ac.) *p < .05. **p < .01. Farms with payments were strongly correlated to wheat farms in the Northern Great Plains (Table 28). Farms with payments depended little on tenant farms in the Northern Great Plains. Commodity payments were strongly correlated to market value, gross income, production expenses, net income, and soybean, wheat, and total cropland acres (Table 28). Part owner and tenant acres had little correlation to commodity payments in this region. The Northern Great Plains had the highest location quotient of farms with commodity payments, which was unexpected based on the fact that only wheat farms were strongly correlated to farms with commodity payments, and that wheat 106 farms only accounted for 10 percent of farms with payments in 2006 (ERS, 2006). On the other hand, the Northern Great Plains had the third highest location quotient of commodity payments, which was low based on the fact that soybean and wheat acres were both strongly correlated to commodity payments. However, since wheat and soybeans only accounted for 16 percent of payments in 2006 (ERS, 2006), this was not totally unexpected. Prairie Gateway. The Prairie Gateway had the second highest mean number of farms (824.1) and land in farms (556,704.1 acres) per county. One-third of the farms per county received government commodity payments (276.7) for a mean county receipt of $3,036,438. Income dependence was 33.6 percent (Appendix B). The Prairie Gateway had the third highest location quotient of farms with payments (Table 1). The location quotient of commodity payments was on the lower end of the normal range as the fourth lowest (Table 2). Table 29. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Prairie Gateway. Farms with Payments (No.) Kendall’s τ Commodity Payments ($) Kendall’s τ 0.518** Market Value ($) 0.458** Farming Occupation (No.) ** 0.668 0.476** Small Family Higher (No.) Gross Income ($) 0.641** Production Expenses ($) 0.386** Large Family (No.) ** 0.537 0.555** Very Large Family (No.) Net Income ($) 0.544** Large Family (ac.) 0.324** Part Owner (No.) 0.425** Very Large Family (ac.) 0.396** Tenant (No.) ** 0.433 0.301** Corn (No.) Part Owner (ac.) 0.459** Tenant (ac.) 0.212** Soybean (No.) ** 0.690 0.442** Wheat (No.) Corn (ac.) 0.672** Soybean (ac.) 0.361** Total Cropland (No.) 0.450** Wheat (ac.) 0.649** Total Cropland (ac.) *p < .05. **p < .01. 107 In the Prairie Gateway, farms with payments were strongly correlated to farming occupation, part owner farms, small family higher sales farms, large and very large family farms, wheat farms, and total cropland farms (Table 29). It was also strongly correlated to sorghum farms (τ = .546, p = .000). Hence, having the third highest location quotient of farms with payments not only relied on the salient variables, but also grain sorghum in the Prairie Gateway. Commodity payments were only strongly correlated to net income and total cropland acres (Table 29); therefore the lower location quotient of commodity payments was expected. Eastern Uplands. The Eastern Uplands had a mean of 777.8 farms and 122,617.1 acres in farmland per county. Only 129.1 farms per county received commodity payments on average for only $440,287, the lowest of all regions. Income dependence was 17.3 percent (Appendix B). Based on location quotients, the Eastern Uplands were at or below normal for all variables salient enough for inclusion in the results. In fact, the Eastern Uplands had the lowest location quotient of farms with payments (Table 1) and the second lowest location quotient of commodity payments (Table 2). Farms with payments were not strongly correlated to any salient variable in the Eastern Uplands, nor any other variable tested in this research (Table 30). Farming occupation, part owner farms, tenant farms, and very large family farms were not correlated to farms with payments. Therefore, the low mean location quotient of farms with payments was expected. However, commodity payments were strongly correlated to corn and soybean acres in the Eastern Uplands (Table 30). Tenant and part owner 108 farm acres were not correlated to commodity payments. This means that the farms that do receive payments in the Eastern Uplands receive them mostly for corn and soybeans. Table 30. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Eastern Uplands. Farms with Payments (No.) Kendall’s τ Commodity Payments ($) Kendall’s τ 0.076* 0.320** Farming Occupation (No.) Market Value ($) ** 0.380 0.286** Small Family Higher (No.) Gross Income ($) 0.245** Production Expenses ($) 0.310** Large Family (No.) ** 0.171 0.269** Very Large Family (No.) Net Income ($) 0.015 0.354** Part Owner (No.) Large Family (ac.) 0.048 0.329** Tenant (No.) Very Large Family (ac.) ** 0.400 0.040 Corn (No.) Part Owner (ac.) 0.433** Tenant (ac.) 0.132** Soybean (No.) ** 0.367 0.512** Wheat (No.) Corn (ac.) 0.232** Soybean (ac.) 0.584** Total Cropland (No.) 0.495** Wheat (ac.) 0.435** Total Cropland (ac.) *p < .05. **p < .01. Southern Seaboard. The average county in the Southern Seaboard had a mean of 516 farms and 99,326.5 acres in farmland, with both of these being the lowest of all regions. Only 97.2 of these farms received commodity payments for a county mean of $1,260,263 in payments. Income dependence in this region averaged 47.7 percent per county (Appendix B). The Southern Seaboard had the fourth lowest location quotient of farms with payments (Table 1), but the third highest location quotient of commodity payments (Table 2). In the Southern Seaboard, farms with payments were strongly correlated to corn, soybean, and total cropland farms (Table 31). However, farms with payments were also strongly correlated to upland cotton farms (τ = .556, p = .000) and peanut farms (τ = .524, p = .000). Therefore, the low location quotient of farms with payments was unexpected. 109 In the Southern Seaboard, commodity payments were not strongly correlated to any of the salient variables (Table 31). However, it was strongly correlated to both upland cotton acres (τ = .677, p = .000) and peanut acres (τ = .595, p = .000). The high location quotient of commodity payments was expected based on the strong correlation to upland cotton, since upland cotton accounted for 23 percent of payments in 2006 (ERS, 2006). Market value, production expenses, and net income had very little to do with commodity payments in the Southern Seaboard (Table 31). Table 31. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Southern Seaboard. Farms with Payments (No.) Kendall’s τ Commodity Payments ($) Kendall’s τ 0.215** Market Value ($) 0.079* Farming Occupation (No.) 0.448** Gross Income ($) 0.206** Small Family Higher (No.) ** 0.055 0.417 Large Family (No.) Production Expenses ($) 0.279** Net Income ($) 0.104** Very Large Family (No.) 0.218** Large Family (ac.) 0.423** Part Owner (No.) ** 0.294 0.405** Tenant (No.) Very Large Family (ac.) 0.579** Part Owner (ac.) 0.288** Corn (No.) ** 0.233** 0.555 Soybean (No.) Tenant (ac.) 0.574** Corn (ac.) 0.479** Wheat (No.) ** 0.377 0.458** Total Cropland (No.) Soybean (ac.) 0.454** Wheat (ac.) 0.499** Total Cropland (ac.) *p < .05. **p < .01. Fruitful Rim. The Fruitful Rim had the highest mean number of farms per county (897.3) but the fourth highest land in farms (388,738.6 acres). One-eighth of the farms in the average county received government payments (110) for $2,352,371 in payments. Income dependence was 20.3 percent (Appendix B). The Fruitful Rim had the second lowest 110 location quotient of farms with payments (Table 1). The Fruitful Rim had the fifth highest location quotient of commodity payments on the higher end of normal (Table 2). In the Fruitful Rim, farms with payments were not strongly correlated to the salient variables (Table 32). This means that the low location quotient of farms with payments was expected. Commodity payments were also not strongly correlated to any salient variables (Table 32). So, the fact that the Fruitful Rim had the fifth highest location quotient of commodity payments, which was on the higher end of the normal range, was unexpected. Although correlations to covered commodity acres were moderate, they were not as strong as they were in other Farm Resource Regions. Plus, the correlations to economic variables, farm typology acres, and farm tenure acres were all weak (Table 32). So the high location quotient of commodity payments was unexplainable by the variables covered in this research. Table 32. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Fruitful Rim. Farms with Payments (No.) Kendall’s τ Commodity Payments ($) Kendall’s τ 0.121** Market Value ($) 0.169** Farming Occupation (No.) ** 0.349 0.220** Small Family Higher (No.) Gross Income ($) 0.295** Production Expenses ($) 0.186** Large Family (No.) 0.232** Net Income ($) 0.197** Very Large Family (No.) ** 0.431 0.154** Part Owner (No.) Large Family (ac.) 0.162** Very Large Family (ac.) 0.296** Tenant (No.) ** 0.347 0.152** Corn (No.) Part Owner (ac.) 0.206** Tenant (ac.) 0.095* Soybean (No.) 0.490** Corn (ac.) 0.415** Wheat (No.) ** 0.287 0.327** Total Cropland (No.) Soybean (ac.) 0.384** Wheat (ac.) 0.488** Total Cropland (ac.) *p < .05. **p < .01. 111 Basin and Range. The average county in the Basin and Range region had the second lowest number of farms (528.8) yet the third highest land in farms (541,200.3 acres). The mean county had the lowest number of farms receiving commodity payments (82.9) and the second lowest commodity payments ($929,331). Income dependence was the second highest at 74.2 percent (Appendix B). The Basin and Range had the third lowest location quotient of farms with payments (Table 1) and the lowest location quotient of commodity payments (Table 2). Table 33. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Basin and Range. Farms with Payments (No.) Kendall’s τ Commodity Payments ($) Kendall’s τ 0.232** Market Value ($) 0.496** Farming Occupation (No.) 0.364** Gross Income ($) 0.430** Small Family Higher (No.) ** 0.414 0.417** Large Family (No.) Production Expenses ($) 0.452** 0.425** Net Income ($) Very Large Family (No.) 0.338** Large Family (ac.) 0.250** Part Owner (No.) ** 0.224 0.371** Tenant (No.) Very Large Family (ac.) 0.181** Part Owner (ac.) 0.207** Corn (No.) ** 0.124 0.190* Soybean (No.) Tenant (ac.) 0.598** Corn (ac.) 0.258** Wheat (No.) 0.409** Soybean (ac.) Total Cropland (No.) 0.582** Wheat (ac.) 0.545** Total Cropland (ac.) *p < .05. **p < .01. - Not calculable. Farms with commodity payments were strongly correlated to wheat farms in the Basin and Range (Table 33). Farms with payments were also strongly correlated to barley farms (τ = .559, p = .000). Corn and soybean farms had weak correlations to farms with commodity payments in the Basin and Range. Commodity payments were strongly correlated to wheat and total cropland acres (Table 33). Commodity payments 112 were also strongly correlated to barley acres (τ = .545, p = .000). Commodity payments were moderately correlated to all economic variables in the Basin and Range. The fact that the Basin and Range had the lowest location quotient of commodity payments was unexpected. The Fruitful Rim did not have a strong correlation of commodity payments to any covered commodities (Table 32), nor did the Prairie Gateway (Table 29). Therefore, the Basin and Range was expected to have a higher location quotient of commodity payments than these regions. Mississippi Portal. The average county in the Mississippi Portal ranked sixth in the number of farms (550.3) and land in farms (177,725.3 acres). On average, 194.8 farms per county received $3,914,677 in commodity payments, the highest mean county receipt of all regions. Income dependence was the highest of all FRRs at 378.4 percent (Appendix B). The Mississippi Portal had the fourth highest location quotient of farms with payments (Table 1) and the highest location quotient of commodity payments (Table 2). Table 34. Kendall’s tau correlations of location quotients in the Mississippi Portal. Farms with Payments (No.) Kendall’s τ Commodity Payments ($) Kendall’s τ 0.188** Market Value ($) 0.336** Farming Occupation (No.) ** 0.455 0.258** Small Family Higher (No.) Gross Income ($) 0.503** Production Expenses ($) 0.351** Large Family (No.) ** 0.309** 0.385 Very Large Family (No.) Net Income ($) 0.118* 0.405** Part Owner (No.) Large Family (ac.) 0.298** Very Large Family (ac.) 0.597** Tenant (No.) ** 0.568 0.259** Corn (No.) Part Owner (ac.) 0.647** Tenant (ac.) 0.506** Soybean (No.) ** 0.580 0.449** Wheat (No.) Corn (ac.) 0.517** 0.497** Soybean (ac.) Total Cropland (No.) 0.491** Wheat (ac.) 0.581** Total Cropland (ac.) *p < .05. **p < .01. 113 Farms with payments were strongly correlated to large family farms, corn farms, soybean farms, and wheat farms (Table 34). Upland cotton farms (τ = .562, p = .000) and sorghum farms (τ = .506, p = .000) were also strongly correlated to farms with payments. Therefore, the location quotient of farms with payments was expected to be higher based on the correlation to these covered commodities. Especially since farms specializing in upland cotton, corn, soybean, and wheat accounted for 85 percent of payments in 2006 (ERS, 2006). Farming occupation and part owner farms had weak correlations in the Mississippi Portal (Table 34). Commodity payments were strongly correlated to tenant acres, very large family farm acres, soybean acres, and cropland acres (Table 34). They were also strongly correlated to upland cotton acres (τ = .636, p = .000), rice acres (τ = .548, p = .000), and sorghum acres (τ = .541, p = .000). The fact that the Mississippi Portal had the highest location quotient of commodity payments is expected based on the fact that soybean, upland cotton, and rice acres accounted for 37 percent of payments in 2006 (ERS, 2006). Therefore, the variation in the distribution of payments by Farm Resource Region was based somewhat on commodity production. However, it did not exactly follow the expected pattern. For example, despite the fact that the Basin and Range had stronger correlations to covered commodities than the Fruitful Rim and Prairie Gateway did, it had a lower location quotient of commodity payments than these Farm Resource Regions. Also, the Mississippi Portal had the fourth highest location quotients of farms with payments despite the fact that there were more strong correlations between covered commodities and farms with payments than in any other region. Also, the Fruitful Rim had the fifth highest location quotient of commodity payments despite the fact that it did 114 not have a strong correlation to any covered commodities. The hypothesis that government payments are distributed equitably between Farm Resource Regions based on commodities was rejected. Variation in the number of farms with payments and commodity payments also varied by variables other than commodities. For example, the Northern Great Plains, the region with the highest location quotient of farms with payments, was not strongly correlated to any variables other than wheat. However, the Heartland (Table 26), the Prairie Gateway (Table 29), and the Mississippi Portal (Table 34) all had strong correlations with one or more salient variables other than commodities. These are the top four highest location quotients of farms with payments. The Heartland and the Prairie Gateway were both strongly correlated to farming occupation, small family higher sales farms, large family farms, very large family farms, and part owner farms. The five regions with the lowest location quotients of farms with payments did not have strong correlations to any non-commodity salient variables. Therefore, this hypothesis was rejected, as well, based on the fact that salient variables other than commodities were also correlated to government payment distribution. Chapter V: Discussion and Conclusion The hypotheses for this study were that only those variables related to the commodities covered under the Farm Bill would be correlated to government payment variables, and that payments were made equitably by Farm Resource Region. These hypotheses were rejected. Not only were commodity payment variables correlated to government payment variables, but some farm tenure, farm typology, occupation, and economic variables were as well. Not only are they also strongly correlated, but they may be more strongly correlated than the commodity variables themselves. Large disparity was also evident between Farm Resource Regions, although this disparity was not always based on commodity production. Contrary to the hypothesis, not all commodity variables were correlated to government payments. Based on Kendall’s correlations and county level location quotient maps, corn farms, corn acres, soybean farms, soybean acres, and wheat farms were the strongest commodity variables tied to commodity payments. However, the location quotients of market value, gross income, production expenses, net income, tenant farms, small family higher sales farms, large family farms, and very large family 116 farms and acres were also strongly correlated to the location quotients of government payment variables. The salient economic variables (market value, gross income, production expenses, and net income) might be expected to be strongly correlated to commodity payments because income might be dependent on government payments. However, the only variable that directly included commodity payments was net income, and net income also included all other payments made under the Farm Bill. So the correlation between net income and commodity payments might be inherent. Ignoring this variable, however, the other three economic variables did not include commodity payments and were still strongly correlated to commodity payments. Based on the analyses, even excluding net income, three economic variables were still strongly correlated to commodity payments. This showed that counties with high market values, gross incomes, and production expenses all received higher commodity payments. Although these economic variables did not directly cause commodity payments, i.e. market value was not included in the calculation of Direct Payments, there was a strong correlation suggesting that farms with higher economic variables did get higher commodity payments. Also, very large family farm acres were strongly correlated to commodity payments, suggesting that, although this variable was not included in the calculation of payment dollars, counties with high numbers of very large family farm acres got higher payments. Corn acres and soybean acres were also strongly correlated to the commodity payments. Counties with higher acres of corn and soybeans received higher commodity payments. The difference, however, was that corn and soybean acres were included in 117 the calculation of payments. This meant that corn and soybean acres were directly correlated to the amount of payments received, and this correlation was founded. The shocking part was that, although corn and soybean acres were included in the calculation, these correlations were not much stronger than the correlations of commodity payments to market value, gross income, production expenses, and very large family farm acres. Based on the analyses, as well, tenant farms, small family higher sales farms, large family farms, and very large family farms were strongly correlated to farms with payments. Although these variables were not included in the calculation of commodity payments the correlation was still strong. This showed that counties with high numbers of these types of farms have a higher number of farms with commodity payments. Again, corn farms, soybean farms, and wheat farms were all strongly correlated to the farms with payments, as expected since commodity payments were calculated based on commodities produced. Again, however, these correlations were not much stronger than the correlations based on tenure and farm typology variables. The regions with the highest location quotients of farms with payments per county were the Heartland and the Northern Great Plains. As far as farms with payments are concerned, the strongest correlations by Farm Resource Regions in the Heartland were corn and soybean farms, and wheat farms in the Northern Great Plains. The regions with the lowest location quotients of farms with payments were the Eastern Uplands, Basin and Range, and Fruitful Rim. These regions were expected to be the lowest since they had the weakest correlations of farms with payments to covered commodity farms. Farms with commodity payments are dependent on commodity variables. 118 The regions with the highest location quotients of commodity payments per county were the Mississippi Portal, Heartland, and Southern Seaboard. The strongest correlations to covered commodities in the Mississippi Portal were to soybean acres, as well as upland cotton, rice, and sorghum acres. Corn acres were strongly correlated to farms with payments in the Heartland. Commodity payments in the Southern Seaboard were strongly correlated to upland cotton and peanut acres, and were not strongly correlated to acres of corn, soybeans, or wheat as would be expected since these covered commodities were found to be the most salient for the nation. The regions with the lowest location quotients of commodity payments were the Basin and Range and the Eastern Uplands. In the Basin and Range, commodity payments were strongly correlated to wheat and barley acres, which was unexpected since it had the lowest location quotient of commodity payments. Also, the Eastern Uplands had strong correlations between commodity payments and corn and soybean acres. This is unexpected as well due to the low location quotient of commodity payments. Therefore, commodity variables do not seem to be as salient as other variables when it comes to the amount of commodity payments farms receive, which is contrary to the hypotheses. This can be broken down even further and analyzed on the county level basis. For example, Johnson County, Tennessee, is in the Eastern Uplands. Its location quotients of farms with commodity payments, commodity payments, and income dependence were all well below normal. Its location quotients for all other salient variables discussed in this paper were at or below normal. Queen Anne’s County, Maryland, is in the Southern Seaboard. Its location quotients for farms with commodity payments and commodity 119 payment dollars are both above normal. Location quotients for all salient variables were at or above normal. However, some counties do not fit the pattern, which is evident by looking at the county level maps. Some counties have low government payment variables despite high location quotients of other salient variables, and vice-versa. For example, Appling County, Georgia, is in the Fruitful Rim. Location quotients for government payment variables were well above normal, with commodity payment dollars at a 6.00 LQ. Location quotients for corn, soybean, and wheat variables were all below normal. Economic variable location quotients were above normal, as were very large farms, and total cropland acres. Based on all of these analyses, the hypothesis was rejected. Relation to Previous Studies Monke (2004) pointed out that about 60 percent of acres enrolled in Farm Bill programs are rented. That trend is supported by this study. Part owner and tenant farms, farms with acres under operation that are rented, are strongly correlated to government commodity payments. Based on the correlations, part owner farms and acres are more strongly related to payment variables than tenant farms and acres. However, based on the regional analysis, tenant farms are more strongly related than part owner farms. Despite this discrepancy, this is still strong support of the previous studies that relate land rental to Farm Bill program participation. This is not to say that there is an incentive to rent, but that renters are more likely to participate in commodity programs. This is due to the fact that rental prices are inflated by program payments (Burfisher & Hopkins, 2003). Westcott & Young (2000) found that large farms, by sales class, receive higher government payments. Hoppe & MacDonald (2001) stated that roughly half of all 120 government payments went to large family, very large family, and nonfamily farms. By contrast nonfamily farms were not found to be salient in this study. However, large family farms, very large family farms, and very large family farm acres were strongly correlated to commodity payments in this study based on correlations and location quotient maps, as well. In addition, small family farming occupation higher sales farms were also strongly related to commodity payments. This same study by Westcott & Young (2000) found that large farms not only earn more income, but also receive higher government payments. Four economic variables were closely related to commodity payments. The correlations were all strong when based on raw data, but only moderate when based on county level location quotients. However, the correlation appears to be strong based on the regional analysis. This study supports the Westcott & Young (2000) study. Based on the 2007 Census, farm size and the number of farms seemed to remain relatively stable since the Goodwin (2000) study. However, agricultural production grew more concentrated. In 2007 only 32,886 farms, or 1.5 percent of farms, accounted for 50 percent of the market value of agricultural products sold in the U.S., down by roughly 31,000 farms from the Goodwin (2000) study. The number of farms receiving government payments remained stable at 38 percent of farms in 2007, compared to 36 percent in 1997. Commodity payment dependence has increased, however. In 2000, 40 percent of net farm income on average came from government payments, including conservation payments. In 2007, an average of 47 percent of net income came from commodity payments alone, excluding conservation payments. This could be due to variations in 121 income per year, but could also indicate a growing dependence among farmers on Farm Bill subsidies, especially since less money was paid to farmers for conservation and commodity programs in 2007 than in 2000. Based on the calculations used in this study in contrast to the calculations used in the study by Eathington & Swenson (2001), these numbers are not strictly comparable. However, trends are noticeable between these two studies. In 1997, more than 37 percent of all farms that received government payments (both commodity and conservation) were in the Heartland (Eathington & Swenson, 2001). This study found that the Heartland had the highest average of farms receiving commodity payments in 2007. According to the 2001 study, the Northern Great Plains had the highest mean percentage of farms receiving government payments, and the Eastern Uplands had the lowest percentage. Although this study looked only at commodity payments, the Heartland and Northern Great Plains had the highest mean percentages per county, and the Basin and Range and Eastern Uplands had the lowest mean percentages per county. The Fruitful Rim had the highest mean amount of Farm Bill payments in 1997, while the Eastern Uplands had the lowest (Eathington & Swenson, 2001). In 2007, by contrast, the average county in the Mississippi Portal had the highest mean commodity payment, while the Fruitful Rim came in fifth. The Eastern Uplands, however, still had the lowest mean commodity payments in 2007. The Mississippi Portal had the highest ratio of government payments to income in 1997 (Eathington & Swenson, 2001) as well as the highest in 2007. Based on economic variables, the Eathington & Swenson (2001) study found that the Eastern Uplands had the lowest mean market value of agricultural products sold, 122 while the Fruitful Rim had the highest. In 2007, based on the mean market value of agricultural products sold by county, the Fruitful Rim was still the highest. The Eastern Uplands had the second lowest mean market value of agricultural products sold, following the Basin and Range region. Broader Implications of the Farm Bill Many people currently support the elimination or reduction of the Farm Bill to curb government spending (Nixon, 2012). Commodity program payments alone totaled $13.164 billion in 2002, reaching a high of $16.903 billion in 2006 and a low of $5.663 billion in 2008. Total spending for Farm Bill programs, including conservation, commodities, crop insurance, and exports reached a high of $23.926 billion in 2006 (Monke & Johnson, 2010). Therefore, Farm Bill programs are on the table for cuts when it comes to government spending appropriations (Imhoff, 2012b). The Farm Bill is not only on the table for cuts due to government spending concerns but also concerns about rising health care costs due to obesity, dwindling water resources, environmental concerns, and local food movements (Imhoff, 2012b). If the Farm Bill Commodity title were to be eliminated or reduced, environmental quality would increase (Plantinga, 1996), government spending would decrease (Lingard, 2001), trade and production distortions would decrease (Mayrand et al., 2003), and food prices would increase (Fairchild, 2012). The subsidies that would be the best to reduce for the environment are those most directly tied to production and thereby encourage expanding acreage and yield, such as DPs. Lowering or cutting these subsidies would lead to less intensive land use (Lingard, 2001) and reduce incentives to keep marginal land in production (Plantinga, 1996). 123 Reducing the highly erodible land in production would decrease soil erosion, sedimentation, and agro-chemical runoff (Plantinga, 1996). Cutting these programs could mean that funding for land retirement programs will longer be necessary, as farmers will no longer be cultivating marginal land (Plantinga, 1996). It would also lead to reduced agro-chemical input (Lingard, 2001). One example would be New Zealand. Subsidies here were reduced to almost no support from 1984 to 1987. Land prices fell by 60 percent as the added inflation in land prices from subsidies crashed. Agro-chemical use, specifically fertilizer use, fell by 50 percent. By 1995, land prices had recovered to 80 percent of the 1984 land prices (Lingard, 2001). The results in New Zealand were mixed, but the agricultural economy recovered (Mayrand et al., 2003). Cutting those programs that encourage increased acreages and yields are the best programs to cut for the environment. However, there are less direct environmental benefits of cutting these programs as well as government spending benefits. Agriculture is a major source of pollution and other environmental problems that the farmer is not responsible for mitigating. Therefore, the price of mitigating these problems is neither included in the cost of the commodity produced, nor the true cost of consumption (Mayrand et al., 2003). The consumer does not directly pay for the environmental price at the grocery store. However, we as taxpayers pay to subsidize the cost of producing the commodity before we buy it and pay to regulate and clean-up the environmental effects of its production. For example, the Clean Water Act (CWA) created more stringent regulations for livestock producers. Money from the Farm Bill, in the form of Environmental Quality Incentives Program payments, can be used by the producer to meet the new regulations imposed by the CWA (Mayrand et al., 2003). This can result in 124 up to $300,000 per operation owner in Farm Bill conservation dollars being spent on meeting regulations (Imhoff, 2012b). Therefore, government spending would be reduced by removing the subsidies paid to produce the commodity and the environmental regulations and programs created to deal with the problems associated with intensive agriculture (Lingard, 2001). Reducing subsidies that are coupled with production would help both the environment and world trade. Cutting these subsidies would precipitate a shift from high intensity agricultural countries to low intensity countries. These high intensity countries are bigger users of agro-chemicals, thereby reducing pollution. The lower intensity countries are less developed nations, and this shift would increase economic activity for these countries (Mayrand et al., 2003). Fewer subsidies in the developed nations would lead to less trade distortion as fewer cheap subsidized commodities flood world markets (Mayrand et al., 2003). Thereby, world prices would increase (Borders & Burnett, 2006). The International Monetary Fund estimates that ending subsidies in more developed countries would raise global welfare by $100 billion (Borders & Burnett, 2006). Ending U.S. cotton support could help stabilize the economies in sub-Saharan Africa. Burkina Faso could get an extra $28 million in export revenue, Benin could see an increase of $33 million, and Mali stands to gain the most at $43 million in export revenue (Borders & Burnett, 2006). The increase in economies and global welfare would lead to a decreased need for international food aid programs (Borders & Burnett, 2006), saving governments money, and decreasing the need of subsidies to create surpluses of commodities. Once income and economic development reach certain levels in less developed nations, it has been 125 shown that these countries spend more money on healthcare and environmental protection (Borders & Burnett, 2006). Therefore, the governments of more developed countries would need to spend less money not only on food aid programs but also international healthcare and environmental programs. If the Farm Bill were to be eliminated or reduced, the face of farm production might change. One major impact of the Farm Bill is the reduced price of processed foods and meat. If the Commodity title of the Farm Bill were to be eliminated or greatly reduced, prices of meat and processed foods would increase greatly. The new prices would more closely resemble the prices of organic or GMO free products currently. Many farmers might switch to growing commodities that would gain them the most income. In most cases, this would mean a switch to whole foods production. Fruits and vegetables would increase in production, thereby reducing their prices to consumers. Prices of other foods, such as meat and processed foods derived from flours and crop byproducts, would increase. Milk could double in price (Fairchild, 2012). This would impact not only the income of farm families, but also the spending habits and food security of most Americans. Since price control was the original point of the Farm Bill, we might end up back in the same situation that initiated the Agricultural Act of 1933 to begin with. Eliminating the Farm Bill is not the answer as this would cause a drastic change in the American economy. A gradual shift in the Farm Bill is needed to cover shifts in food choices and the economy. Many Americans are shifting to local, organic, and GMO free foods, but often cost is a major inhibitor to this shift in diet. A Farm Bill that begins to support whole foods, such as fruits and vegetables, as well as organic and GMO free 126 foods would help ameliorate the problem of cost associated with healthier food choices. This same legislation needs to begin scaling back on the commodity payments as they currently are to help encourage this shift in the farmers without collapsing the farm economy. Payments could be made on an income-support or risk reduction method as suggested by previous researchers (Gunderson et al., 2000; Lamb, 2003). These programs would not provide an incentive to increase acreage or yield, and therefore decrease environmental problems, but would still mitigate the financial risks inherent in farming (Lingard, 2001). Lamb (2003) suggests a cut to commodity programs in favor of a shift to supply and demand. The solution to cutting program payments is to offer a ‘buyout” program. In the 1980s the government provided payments to dairy farmers who sold their entire herd without keeping their herd in production elsewhere, i.e., export or slaughter. These producers could not be involved in dairy production for five years following their buyout, effectively reducing the surplus of dairy products and stabilizing dairy prices (Lamb, 2003). This buyout solution would allow farmers to exit production with government assistance, thereby reducing surpluses and allowing market forces to set commodity prices. Farmers who stay in production, generally the more industrialized farms, will be able to continue without further government assistance (Lamb, 2003). Gunderson et al. (2000) provided four approaches to government payments that could replace commodity payments and crop insurance. The first method was to pay farm operators the difference between their household income and the median nonfarm household income in their Farm Resource Region. This would result in payments only to those farmers with below median household income and would focus money into small 127 family farm typologies and away from large and non-family farms. The second method was to pay farm operators the difference between their household income and 185 percent of the poverty level across the nation. This would result in establishing a minimum farm household income for the entire U.S., without differentiating among Farm Resource Regions. The third scenario was to pay farm households the difference between their household income and the median household expenditures in their region. If household expenditures in a Farm Resource Region are higher on average than a farmer’s income, that farmer would receive a payment for the difference. Finally, the fourth scenario is to ensure a farm household income equal to the average nonfarm selfemployed hourly wage by Farm Resource Region. Therefore, if farm income was below a set level based on hourly wages, these farmers would be compensated for time up to the average hourly wage for self-employed nonfarm workers (Gunderson et al., 2000). All of these scenarios would result in a decline in payments to large family farms, very large family farms, and nonfamily farms. The fourth scenario would overlook limited resource and residential farms compared to the other three scenarios. All four scenarios would change the distribution of government payments based on Farm Resource Regions. For example, in 1997, based on these four scenarios, payments would have been made to an average of 37 percent of farms in the Heartland, ranging from 21 to 62 percent. Payments in the Basin and Range would have been made to an average of 43 percent of farms, ranging from 22 to 75 percent, based on the scenario. In fact, payments in 2007 ranged from 12 percent of producers in the Fruitful Rim to 55 percent of producers in the Heartland (Table 1). These four different payment scenarios, on average, close this gap between regions from 37 percent in the Fruitful Rim to 53 percent 128 in the Southern Seaboard (Gunderson et al., 2000). Not only would this solve the environmental problems and world trade problems provided, but would also solve the inequitable distribution of payments by Farm Resource Region. Future Research By using data from the upcoming 2012 Census of Agriculture, a comparative analysis of the same study based on two Farm Bills would be possible. The data in the 2012 Census would cover payments made under the Food, Conservation, and Energy Act of 2008. This would enable the researcher to compare the efficacy of changes made in Bill over time. The new Farm Bill, due out in 2013, will be covered under the 2017 Census of Agriculture. Including this Census in the study would allow the analysis of changes over three Farm Bills, spanning eleven years of government payments. Future research would be needed to determine the effects of eliminating commodity payments as they currently stand. What effects would the elimination of these payments have on not only farm economies, but also on the economies of related industries, such as livestock producers, processed food manufacturers, and agro-chemical and seed suppliers? Would new economies emerge, such as heirloom seed companies and organic fertilizer suppliers? Future research could also include the effects of consumers on the Farm Bill program development over the years. Have the changes in shopping and cooking habits of Americans driven changes in the Farm Bill? Would a larger shift to organic, GMOfree, whole food diets create a change in subsidies toward smaller, niche market farms that specialize in producing these products? Does the demand for cheap food from fast 129 food establishments drive the need to produce meat and commodities more cheaply and reinforce the need for subsidies? Future research could also include an analysis of public opinion in changes to the legislation that would impact market prices of food. For example, would people be willing to pay more per gallon of milk or box of snack cakes in order to cut federal spending. Although the bulk of the changes that occur to the Farm Bill are encouraged by the agricultural and agro-business lobbyists, pressure from constituents, if they support eliminating Farm Bill programs, could create drastic changes to the Farm Bill. Nothing is more important to a legislator looking to get reelected than the majority opinion of their constituents. Future research should also examine the environmental impacts of eliminating those subsidies that encourage agricultural intensification. Modeling the impacts of agricultural intensification on the environment has been successful before. These models can be used to look at the impacts of eliminating different kinds of subsidies and the impacts of eliminating subsidies all together in favor of income support payments like those suggested by Gunderson et al. (2000). References Agricultural Act of 1956 (AA). Public Law 84-540. May 28, 1956. Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1935 (AAA). Public Law 73-10. May 2, 1933. Barnard, C. Nehring, R., Ryan, J., & Collender, R. 2001. Higher cropland values from farm program payments: Who gains?. Agricultural Outlook No. AGO-286, Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington DC. Borders, M. & Burnett, H. (2006, March). Farm subsidies: Devastating the world’s poor and the environment (Brief Analysis No. 547). Dallas, TX: National Center for Policy Analysis. Burfisher, M. & Hopkins, J. (Eds). (2003). Decoupled payments: Household income transfers in contemporary U.S. agriculture. Agricultural Economics Report No. AER-822, Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington, DC. Cain, Z., & Lovejoy, S. (2004). History and outlook for the farm bill conservation programs. Choices, 19(4), 37-42. Champion, R., & Wein, A. (2008). ShakeOut scenario appendix I: Characterizing a regional economy – Bureau of labor statistics location quotients for industrial sectors on southern California. In Jones, L., et al., The shakeout scenario. U.S. Geological Survey Open-File Report 2008-1150, USGS, Reston, VA. Chite, R. (2008). Farm bill budget and costs: 2002 vs. 2007. Report for Congress No. RS22694, U.S. Congressional Research Service, Washington, DC. Conover, W. (1980). Practical non-parametric statistics (2nd ed.) New York, NY: John Wiley and Sons. 131 Eathington, L and Swenson, D. (2001). Profiles: Government farm payments and other government transfer payments in the United States. Ames, Iowa: Iowa State University, Department of Economics. Economic Research Service (2000). Farm resource regions. Agricultural Information Bulletin No. 760, Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington, DC. Economic Research Service (2006). Farm business and household survey data. Retrieved from http://www.ers.usda.gov/data/arms/FarmOverview.htm. Economic Research Service (2012a). Commodity costs & returns. Retrieved October 1, 2012, from http://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/commodity-costs-andreturns.aspx Economic Research Service (2012b). Corn. Retrieved October 1, 2012, from http://www.ers.usda.gov/topics/crops/corn.aspx Economic Research Service (2012c). Soybeans & oil crops. Retrieved October 1, 2012, from http://www.ers.usda.gov/topics/crops/soybeans-oil-crops.aspx Fairchild, C. (2012, October). Milk prices could double in January if farm bill is not extended. The Huffington Post. Retrieved October 3, 2012, from http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2012/10/02/milk-prices-farmbill_n_1933217.html Farm Security and Rural Investment Act of 2002 (FSRIA). Public Law 107-171. May 13, 2002. Federal Agricultural Improvement and Reform Act of 1996 (FAIRA). Public Law 104127. April 4, 1996. Flinchbaugh, B., & Knutson, R. (2004). The agricultural policy outlook: Looking back focuses on the road ahead. Choices, 19(4), 27-29. Food Security Act of 1985 (FSA). Public Law 99-198. December 23, 1985. Fresh fruit, hold the insulin. (2012, April 17). Scientific American, 306, 12. Gardner, B. (1992). Changing economic perspectives on the farm problem. Journal of Economic Literature, 30, 62-101. Goodwin, B. (2000). Instability and risk in U.S. agriculture. Journal of Agribusiness, 18(1), 71-89. 132 Gunderson, C, M. Morehart, L. Whitener, L. Ghelfi, J. Johnson, K. Kassel, B. Kuhn, A. Mishra, S. Offutt, & L. Tiehen. (2000). A safety net for farm households. Agricultural Economic Report, No. AER-788, Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington, DC. Hoppe, R., & MacDonald, J. (2001). America’s diverse family farms: Assorted sizes, types, and situations. Agricultural Information Bulletin No. AIB-769, Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington, DC. Imhoff, D. (2012a). Overhauling the Farm Bill: Planting for the future with perennials. The Atlantic. Retrieved November 5, 2012 from http://www.theatlantic.com/health/archive/2012/03/overhauling-the-farm-billplanting-for-the-future-with-perennials/254423/ Imhoff, D. (2012b). Overhauling the Farm Bill: Political wedge issues slowing reform. The Atlantic. Retrieved November 5, 2012 from http://www.theatlantic.com/health/archive/2012/03/overhauling-the-farm-billpolitical-wedge-issues-slowing-reform/254421/ Imhoff, D. (2012c). Overhauling the Farm Bill: The real beneficiaries of subsidies. The Atlantic. Retrieved November 2, 2012 from http://www.theatlantic.com/health/archive/2012/03/overhauling-the-farm-bill-thereal-beneficiaries-of-subsidies/254422/ Lamb, R. (2003). The new farm economy. Regulation, 26(4), 10-15. Lingard, J. (2001). Agricultural subsidies and environmental change. In T. Munn (Ed.), Encyclopedia of Global Environmental Change (pp. 168-171). New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons. Mayrand, K., S. Dionne, M. Paquin, & I. Pageot-LeBel. (2003). The economic and environmental impacts of agricultural subsidies: An assessment of the 2002 U.S. farm bill & Doha round. Unisefera, Quebec: Canada. Monke, J. (2004). Farm commodity payments: Direct payments, counter-cyclical payments, and marketing loans. Report for Congress No. RS21779, U.S. Congressional Research Service, Washington DC. Monke, J & Johnson, R. (2010). Actual Farm Bill spending and cost estimates. Report for Congress No. R41195, U.S. Congressional Research Service, Washington, DC. 133 Mishra, A., El-Osta, H., Morehart, M., Johnson, J., & Hopkins, J. (2002). Income, wealth, and the economic well-being of farm households. Agricultural Economics Report No. AER-812, Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington, DC. National Agricultural Statistics Service (2009). 2007 Census of agriculture. Retrieved from http://www.nass.usda.gov/Census_of_Agriculture/index.asp Nixon, R. (2012, July 12). Split among House Republicans over how deeply to cut may delay Farm Bill. The New York Times, p. A13. Plantinga, A. (1996). The effect of agricultural policies on land use and environmental quality. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 78, 1082-1091. Pollan, M. (2007). You are what you grow. The New York Times Magazine. Retrieved August 20, 2012 from http://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/22/magazine/22 wwlnlede.t.html Pollan, M. (2008). How to feed the world. Newsweek. Retrieved August 20, 2012, from http://michaelpollan.com/articles-archive/how-to-feed-the-world Soil Conservation Act of 1935 (SCA). Public Law 74-76. April 27, 1935. Soil Conservation and Domestic Allotment Act of 1936 (SCDAA). Public Law 74-461. March 1, 1936. Westcott, P., & Young, C. (2000). U.S. farm bill program benefits: links to planting decisions and agricultural markets. Agricultural Outlook No. AGO-275, Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington, DC. Appendix A Kendall’s Tau Correlations of Independent to Government Payment Variables 135 Kendall’s Tau Correlations of Independent to Government Payment Variables Raw Data Location Quotient Payment (farms) Payment ($) Income Dependence Payment (farms) Payment ($) Income Dependence Farms .460** .217** -.049** Land in Farms .448** .466** .106** Market Value .507** .529** -.212** .106** .352** .052** Total Income .528** .559** -.031* .075** .358** -.069** Production Expenses Net Income .496** .513** -.188** .025* .315** -.009 .501** .555** -.259** .208** .410** .118** Farming Occupation Other Occupation .519** .302** -.083** .297** .175** .133** .382** .136** -.019 -.293** -.171** -.130** Worked Off Farm Any Worked Off Farm 200+ American Indian/ Alaskan Native Asian .412** .169** -.046** -.351** -.208** -.245** .413** .165** -.050** -.193** -.085** -.120** -.036* -.050** -.011 -.197** -.199** -.088** -.095** -.053** -.142** -.197** -.063** -.131** Black/ African American Multi-Race -.162** -.076** .094** -.068** .021 .009 .050** -.041** .026 -.181** -.194** -.010** White .469** .219** -.055** .240** .090** .057** Spanish, Hispanic, or Latino Origin Female -.030* -.022 -.012 -.243** -.178** -.120** .246** .067** -.045** -.348** -.174** -.220** Male .488** .237** -.045** .351** .178** .224** Family or Individual (farms) Family or Individual (acres) .440** .187** -.047** -.187** -.166** -.115** .469** .447** .106** -.111** -.169** -.112** 136 Kendall’s Tau Correlations of Independent to Government Payment Variables Raw Data Location Quotient Payment (farms) .499** Payment ($) .347** Income Dependence .004 .374** .476** .139** .139** .173** .174** .181** .169** -.109** .004 .086** .004 .242** .271** -.097** .019 .148** .032* .333** .329** -.123** .109** .168** .045** .300** .391** -.003 .109** .121** .032* .377** .321** .003 .157** .053** .114** .284 .312** .055** .025** -.011 .056** Limited Resource (farms) Limited Resource (acres) Retirement (farms) Retirement (acres) .244** -.001 -.025* -.364** -.266** -.254** .194** .028* .096** -.402** -.313** -.297** .289** .058** .004 -.342** -.215** -.164** .237** .110** .146** -.424** -.291** -.260** Residential/Lifest yle (farms) Residential/Lifest yle (acres) Lower Sales (farms) Lower Sales (acres) Higher Sales (farms) Higher Sales (acres) Large Family (farms) .377** .126** -.024 -.250** -.141** -.119** .328** .193** .138** -.412** -.290** -.273** .434** .211** -.038** .024* -.067** -.064** .298** .219** .110** -.302** -.361** -.261** .641** .550** -.049** .540** .309** .310** .439** .427** .078** .369** .125** .208** .631** .602** -.086** .551** .377** .350** Partnership (farms) Partnership (acres) Corporation Other (farms) Corporation Other (acres) Corporations Family (farms) Corporations Family (acres) Other (farms) Other (acres) Payment (farms) .224** Payment ($) .144** Income Dependence .181** 137 Kendall’s Tau Correlations of Independent to Government Payment Variables Raw Data Location Quotient Payment (farms) .476** Payment ($) .527** Income Dependence .086** .505** .559** -.182** .429** .386** .322** .455** .607** .043** .452** .458** .361** .417** .365** -.071** .142** .131** .079** .208** .320** .059** -.065** -.040** -.051** Full Owner (farms) Full Owner (acres) Part Owner (farms) Part Owner (acres) Tenant (farms) .355** .116** -.049** -.475** -.245** -.287** .274** .228** .094** -.485** -.347** -.329** .593** .352** -.031* .464** .207** .272** .484** .503** .082** .466** .300** .291** .521** .482** .010 .321** .248** .234** Tenant (acres) .368** .510** .106** .253** .262** .217** Barley(farms) Barley (acres) .207** .204** .145** .156** -.062** -.059** .146** .142** .025* .028 .017 .014 Barley (bushels) .205** .157** -.060** Beans (farms) .125** .158** -.056** .089** -.011 .032** Beans (acres) .142** .166** -.046** .108** .014 .035** Beans (cwt) .142** .166** -.048** Corn (farms) .613** .460** -.003 .556** .498** .346** Corn (acres) .611** .576** .008 .498** .560** .350** Corn (bushels) .607** .576** -.003 ** ** .297** .118** .251** .316** Large Family (acres) Very Large Family (farms) Very Large Family (acres) Nonfamily (farms) Nonfamily (acres) Upland cotton (farms) .053 .222 Payment (farms) .519** Payment ($) .319** Income Dependence .336** 138 Kendall’s Tau Correlations of Independent to Government Payment Variables Raw Data Location Quotient Payment (farms) Payment ($) Income Dependence Payment (farms) Payment ($) Income Dependence Upland cotton (acres) Upland cotton (bales) Oats .071** .264** .321** .143** .313** .353** .070** .265** .319** .429** .318** -.006 .336** .211** .186** Oats (acres) .427** .353** .031* .298** .233** .182** Oats (bushels) .438** .367** .016 Peanuts -.007 .110** .198** .055** .120** .201** Peanuts (acres) .019 .136** .195** .083** .237** .214** Peanuts (pounds) .019 .137** .198** Rice .036* .168** .133** .040** .170** .165** Rice (acres) .053** .180** .129** .055** .174** .168** Rice (cwt) .054** .182** .132** Sorghum (farms) .265** .311** .189** .292** .192** .337** Sorghum (acres) .269** .341** .217** .298** .204** .358** Sorghum (bushels) Soybeans (farms) .272** .343** .215** .574** .453** .042** .547** .545** .376** Soybeans (acres) .561** .501** .064** .488** .561** .380** Soybeans (bushels) Sugarbeets (farms) Sugarbeets (acres) .566** .505** .052** .137** .136** -.044** .107** .022 .033** .123** .127** -.050** .094** .016 .028* Sugarbeets (tons) Sugarcane (farms) .123** -.048** .127** .009 -.050** -.022 -.061** .025* -.023 Sugarcane (acres) -.028 .027 .003 -.030* .036** .003 Sugarcane (tons) -.028 .027 .003 139 Kendall’s Tau Correlations of Independent to Government Payment Variables Raw Data Payment (farms) .554** .448** .454** .543** Payment ($) .519** .504** .516** .278** Location Quotient Income Dependence .127** .164** .144** -.047** Payment (farms) .553** .463** Wheat (farms) Wheat (acres) Wheat (bushels) Total cropland .472** (farms) Commodity .639** .195** .484** Payments Income .100** .195** .553** Dependence Note. Blank cells were not calculable based on location quotients. *p < .05. **p < .01. Payment ($) .317** .297** Income Dependence .426** .395** .318** .234** - .498** .498** - Appendix B Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region 141 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Farms No. Land in Farms ac. Market Value $ Total Income $ Total Expenses $ Net Income $ Farming Occupation No. Other Occupation No. Worked Off Farm Any No. Worked Off Farm 200+ No. No. Female Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Great Plains Prairie Gateway Eastern Uplands M 823.3 748.2 539.7 824.1 777.8 SD 350.2 579.9 385.1 620.1 504.8 M 256,298.4 127,890.2 896,661.4 556,704.1 122,617.1 SD 118,333.3 112,361.5 566,449.4 340,518.2 105,700.0 M 132,582,011 78,855,418 106,170,464 114,997,404 42,012,873 SD 107,244,612 97,830,055 131,692,033 156,405,561 66,031,168 M 4,754,547 3,469,548 5,459,966 3,698,723 1,353,832 SD 3,292,904 3,533,330 4,638,124 3,133,097 2,260,960 M 99,427,878 63,758,953 82,748,067 100,525,096 36,701,522 SD 82,438,058 75,066,837 115,952,090 13,809,557 53,060,290 M 42,306,560 20,445,220 34,148,089 23,655,736 7,830,151 SD 33,078,859 28,242,901 27,647,556 25,043,290 15,159,893 M 388.3 352.6 301.2 354.9 317.3 SD 170.4 304.2 174.4 225.7 212.0 M 435.0 395.6 238.5 469.2 460.4 SD 212.0 291.4 227.1 404.9 298.6 M 524.1 476.6 306.0 541.9 516.2 SD 236.1 358.5 260.7 455.1 335.1 M 332.2 299.6 178.2 328.4 330.8 SD 157.0 228.7 157.1 270.2 218.2 M 82.0 113.4 64.8 113.5 95.7 SD 43.9 74.7 62.1 94.0 66.1 142 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Farms No. Land in Farms ac. Market Value $ Total Income $ Total Expenses $ Net Income $ Farming Occupation Other Occupation No. No. Worked Off Farm Any No. Worked Off Farm 200+ No. No. Female Southern Seaboard Fruitful Rim Basin and Range Mississippi Portal National M 516.0 897.3 528.8 550.3 716.1 SD 413.9 961.2 535.4 337.5 564.4 M 99,326.5 388,738.6 541,200.3 177,725.3 297,859.0 SD 78,958.6 604,224.3 564,334.0 101,046.9 378,188.7 M 63,848,282 217,866,746 40,669,223 56,067,297 96,212,060 SD 107,637,607 472,200,809 55,355,182 53,664,342 181,462,549 M 1,918,280 6,000,168 2,071,345 2,146,152 3,392,874 SD 1,909,461 10,169,840 2,328,065 1,735,259 4,434,705 M 54,219,584 174,821,354 36,597,508 48,044,291 78,261,619 SD 82,804,596 366,348,125 45,979,386 42,805,406 143,314,856 M 13,936,245 54,105,846 8,964,660 14,508,467 24,794,277 SD 26,880,197 119,676,956 14,426,338 16,805,152 45,988,508 M 218.4 416.3 244.8 222.2 322.8 SD 173.8 473.7 289.9 130.9 263.1 M 297.6 480.9 284.0 328.2 393.3 SD 248.7 510.0 275.3 220.6 321.9 M 333.8 602.4 349.6 349.9 463.5 SD 281.1 656.1 334.2 224.8 382.6 M 204.0 347.8 197.8 214.3 284.6 SD 166.7 372.4 192.7 141.6 231.1 M 76.7 168.3 103.2 73.1 99.5 SD 65.1 208.2 198.9 51.0 106.6 143 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region No. Male American Indian or Alaskan Native No. No. Asian Black or African American No. No. Mutli-Race No. White Spanish, Hispanic, or Latino No. Family or Individual No. ac. Partnership No. ac. Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Great Plains Prairie Gateway Eastern Uplands M 741.3 634.8 474.9 710.6 682.1 SD 318.7 523.3 329.8 535.0 443.2 M 2.0 3.4 17.9 13.0 19.8 SD 2.9 3.5 44.0 25.0 55.3 M 1.6 2.8 1.6 2.8 4.3 SD 3.1 4.1 3.3 2.8 9.8 M 3.9 4.6 3.3 20.0 14.4 SD 8.7 10.8 4.5 37.0 21.8 M 2.6 2.7 2.8 7.9 8.8 SD 3.2 2.8 3.3 9.3 13.1 M 818.0 746.1 525.0 798.3 747.0 SD 348.2 575.2 381.4 592.3 477.4 M 3.6 5.5 4.6 36.0 5.8 SD 3.4 7.4 12.9 80.7 5.0 M 705.8 649.4 446.7 713.2 710.9 SD 307.7 517.0 319.9 575.6 464.0 M 195,543.7 102,873.8 612,268.9 379,708.9 105,705.6 SD 90,351.5 84,433.2 324,013.0 194,901.0 82,384.2 M 65.7 56.0 50.4 69.4 48.8 SD 30.7 45.8 41.2 40.9 35.8 M 36,732.4 21,197.5 143,894.0 108,594.4 15,178.0 SD 21,819.9 21,043.4 110,128.1 101,018.2 17,607.0 144 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region No. Male American Indian or Alaskan Native No. No. Asian Black or African American No. No. Mutli-Race No. White Spanish, Hispanic, or Latino No. Family or Individual No. ac. Partnership No. ac. Southern Seaboard Fruitful Rim Basin and Range Mississippi Portal National M 439.3 729.0 425.6 477.2 616.6 SD 356.7 785.0 382.9 291.7 481.9 M 5.9 29.3 67.8 3.2 15.5 SD 19.7 192.4 381.2 3.9 123.8 M 3.0 26.0 3.6 1.6 7.2 SD 3.9 73.3 6.5 2.7 49.5 M 28.8 17.6 2.3 37.6 18.7 SD 35.7 31.7 3.7 45.6 32.0 M 3.5 7.1 3.6 2.5 5.1 SD 4.9 8.2 4.6 3.0 11.4 M 478.0 836.5 469.6 503.1 687.6 SD 391.1 889.8 414.7 328.7 533.6 M 8.1 96.6 34.2 5.5 21.0 SD 13.8 203.8 96.4 5.2 80.7 M 455.1 740.9 442.4 466.0 619.1 SD 377.1 792.5 490.0 308.5 498.0 M 82,575.3 177,200.5 239,523.5 108,428.5 201,617.2 SD 65,674.9 188,203.1 240,116.4 52,323.3 201,980.4 M 37.0 79.0 44.3 57.6 56.6 SD 28.4 106.0 34.1 35.9 49.0 M 16,314.4 86,635.8 100,679.5 56,373.9 54,641.9 SD 15,394.0 128,270.4 127,723.0 60,147.9 82,099.9 145 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Great Plains Prairie Gateway Eastern Uplands 3.3 3.7 1.8 2.7 1.7 3.3 4.1 2.5 2.7 2.4 M 1,280.5 996.6 2,984.5 2,415.0 305.3 SD 1,965.3 1,633.7 9,032.0 4,961.3 1,088.6 M 34.8 31.6 31.0 24.8 11.9 SD 24.3 26.6 37.1 17.6 12.3 M 27,547.8 13,989.9 153,854.5 57,807.0 5,876.3 SD 20,905.7 15,505.2 191,061.8 87,556.5 8,339.1 M 13.7 7.5 9.8 14.0 4.5 SD 10.0 7.7 9.4 10.2 6.0 M 3,100.3 1,834.0 25,400.7 9,250.1 1,302.3 SD 2,862.8 2,243.1 42,327.3 13,153.9 2,578.9 M 84.4 113.3 55.5 105.5 136.9 SD 52.0 78.9 43.7 97.5 88.5 M 8,212.0 10,458.2 25,733.2 25,121.5 14,588.4 SD 7,691.4 8,896.0 18,418.1 20,612.1 9,200.9 M 141.6 134.6 79.3 186.2 183.9 SD 75.9 94.2 66.4 176.4 119.1 M 19,745.3 14,992.3 48,896.9 60,588.7 27,159.8 SD 13,731.2 10,859.8 36,276.7 41,277.1 19,176.9 M 293.6 266.9 152.4 311.8 313.4 SD 148.3 205.8 161.1 290.9 209.3 Corporation No. M Other than SD Family Held ac. Corporation No. Family Held ac. Other No. ac. Small Family Limited Resource No. ac. Small Family Retirement No. ac. Residential/ Lifestyle No. 146 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Southern Seaboard Fruitful Rim Basin and Range Mississippi Portal National 2.4 8.6 3.2 2.9 3.3 3.1 13.2 3.9 2.9 5.5 M 784.9 10,514.9 7,463.2 2,082.7 2,701.3 SD 1,840.0 31,852.9 18,543.0 3,079.9 12,233.1 M 17.4 55.4 29.1 19.9 27.9 SD 15.6 70.5 28.5 15.9 32.5 M 9,428.7 60,910.3 107,571.5 16,681.4 40,025.4 SD 9,940.7 99,880.7 141,696.1 17,085.9 84,648.5 M 4.1 13.3 9.8 3.9 9.1 SD 4.5 19.7 8.9 4.7 10.6 M 1,481.1 74,363.4 66,194.3 1,802.8 15,971.7 SD 3,064.2 516,170.0 223,094.7 3,770.3 182,978.3 M 78.7 126.1 97.0 84.2 100.3 SD 65.8 152.7 204.8 60.9 100.5 M 8,144.7 14,496.5 20,953.1 9,138.7 13,953.8 SD 7,087.5 23,910.6 22,892.9 6,038.4 15,576.2 M 128.2 192.8 108.8 126.2 148.1 SD 114.3 209.4 107.7 89.1 129.9 M 19,770.1 31,109.1 38,173.0 21,950.1 29,378.9 SD 18,749.5 37,458.3 36,788.4 15,247.6 29,816.2 M 190.7 310.5 182.6 208.3 260.4 SD 168.8 331.1 178.7 144.8 221.4 Corporation No. M Other than SD Family Held ac. Corporation No. Family Held ac. Other No. ac. Small Family Limited Resource No. ac. Small Family Retirement No. ac. Small Family Residential/ Lifestyle No. 147 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Small ac. Family Residential/ Lifestyle No. Small Family Lower Sales Small Family Higher Sales ac. No. ac. Large Family No. ac. Very Large Family No. ac. Nonfamily No. ac. Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Great Plains Prairie Gateway Eastern Uplands M 31,357.3 22,414.7 65,029.3 81,390.5 34,564.8 SD 18,392.3 18,033.0 47,990.3 50,444.8 24,121.0 M 91.7 97.5 78.0 96.6 86.0 SD 43.6 79.2 53.4 67.4 59.6 M 15,823.2 12,868.3 89,536.1 64,464.8 17,439.5 SD 10,786.5 10,492.8 77,789.9 57,089.0 14,681.8 M 60.6 49.0 60.7 32.6 12.6 SD 42.5 86.6 31.9 24.2 16.1 M 30,187.9 15,945.1 166,940.5 66,111.9 8,759.2 SD 19,444.0 18,157.7 138,998.3 55,860.6 10,245.2 M 57.8 32.4 48.0 27.1 11.5 SD 42.8 42.7 31.0 22.5 17.4 M 49,197.9 18,493.9 176,845.9 76,761.2 8,447.0 SD 31,298.5 19,975.3 122,953.6 54,967.6 12,096.0 M 56.8 27.3 43.3 29.2 17.0 SD 45.2 35.9 39.1 28.4 32.5 M 90,456.4 31,678.9 238,718.8 129,495.0 12,431.1 SD 58,967.3 37,796.3 171,026.3 113,475.6 22,942.7 M 36.9 27.3 22.5 35.2 16.6 SD 21.3 22.1 24.0 18.5 14.3 M 16,424.4 9,181.9 88,813.4 68,412.9 7,750.2 SD 11,155.6 8,313.9 125,030.7 112,196.3 15,978.9 148 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Small ac. Family Residential/ Lifestyle No. Small Family Lower Sales Small Family Higher Sales ac. No. ac. Large Family No. ac. Very Large Family No. ac. Nonfamily No. ac. Southern Seaboard Fruitful Rim Basin and Range Mississippi Portal National M 23,023.1 43,399.7 50,222.1 29,239.7 39,792.1 SD 22,112.9 58,233.4 49,361.0 18,705.4 39,616.8 M 53.2 110.9 68.7 56.0 84.1 SD 44.0 121.6 78.1 38.7 70.5 M 9,855.7 35,457.8 53,165.0 11,651.0 29,186.6 SD 9,988.1 58,380.6 66,383.1 7,348.7 44,728.9 M 9.6 25.4 18.8 12.6 32.5 SD 10.5 38.6 20.8 11.9 45.8 M 7,780.0 31,259.3 70,632.4 10,361.2 38,133.7 SD 7,813.1 52,181.9 95,353.1 7,449.2 65,288.2 M 11.0 24.8 13.6 15.0 28.1 SD 14.5 40.8 16.4 13.8 35.1 M 9,177.7 36,785.1 72,665.1 19,174.9 45,559.9 SD 9,028.7 54,081.4 97,842.1 15,725.6 65,986.7 M 27.1 45.3 11.8 28.0 32.9 SD 47.1 86.0 16.9 29.9 46.3 M 21,023.3 95,439.2 96,826.4 70,240.7 76,868.7 SD 24,157.4 147,839.1 133,411.6 71,006.7 105,730.6 M 17.5 61.3 27.5 20.2 29.6 SD 14.5 90.9 23.4 13.7 35.7 M 9,072.4 126,168.6 147,925.7 19,894.0 42,841.6 SD 9,908.2 487,854.1 225,625.5 23,792.8 170,747.8 149 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Full Owner No. ac. Part Owner No. ac. Tenant No. ac. Barley No. ac. bu. Dry Edible Beans No. ac. Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Great Plains Prairie Gateway Eastern Uplands M 516.3 518.7 299.8 544.0 571.9 SD 252.4 390.7 273.7 472.7 372.9 M 66,638.3 50,269.1 238,460.5 188,661.3 66,432.3 SD 39,934.0 42,681.9 188,827.0 142,406.9 46,576.8 M 238.6 192.3 192.9 221.0 177.2 SD 113.6 159.5 104.4 142.6 122.2 M 165,869.1 76,091.5 588,565.5 312,936.6 54,370.9 SD 84,179.1 69,769.1 366,776.3 201,371.2 55,336.9 M 68.4 37.2 47.0 59.1 29.0 SD 44.1 58.3 34.6 32.9 22.0 M 25,118.9 6,644.1 69,635.5 55,035.6 5,340.9 SD 21,088.7 8,694.7 56,327.2 52,255.3 13,748.4 M 1.2 11.0 39.4 0.6 1.2 SD 3.6 32.0 56.8 1.5 5.1 M 40.0 362.6 13,273.1 44.3 22.9 SD 200.7 1,139.3 21,992.8 197.1 115.2 M 2,013.8 22,953.5 670,367.1 2,487.7 1,414.1 SD 10,457.9 77,985.4 1,166,759.3 11,545.1 8,418.3 M 0.3 3.6 14.5 0.7 0.0 SD 2.3 24.5 36.5 3.5 0.2 M 56.7 666.6 5,672.2 124.0 0.0 SD 576.2 4,585.8 15,314.8 882.8 0.2 150 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Full Owner No. ac. Part Owner No. ac. Tenant No. ac. Barley No. ac. bu. Dry Edible Beans No. ac. Southern Seaboard Fruitful Rim Basin and Range Mississippi Portal National M 370.3 699.1 397.8 382.8 494.3 SD 300.9 798.0 463.6 264.5 431.9 M 50,487.8 178,608.6 243,803.1 63,252.3 107,934.9 SD 40,436.0 338,998.8 250,920.4 37,459.7 156,483.4 M 120.3 137.4 100.9 123.3 176.1 SD 104.5 134.6 89.4 75.8 131.6 M 46,975.0 161,041.2 273,073.0 79,104.2 166,612.0 SD 39,685.9 216,546.4 314,224.3 55,230.3 213,647.8 M 25.4 60.8 30.1 44.2 45.7 SD 22.5 74.5 29.5 32.1 48.3 M 6,133.5 47,445.9 40,499.0 35,385.4 27,415.8 SD 7,569.7 76,662.1 52,896.4 44,629.8 44,878.0 M 2.5 8.6 15.9 0.0 6.5 SD 8.6 26.7 34.8 0.3 24.0 M 186.1 2,429.0 3,550.0 2.2 1,326.8 SD 865.5 8,771.2 924.6 28.7 7,189.0 M 13,549.4 188,547.5 240,495.9 100.7 78,424.8 SD 67,468.9 711,780.2 686,787.2 1,289.6 430,585.4 M 0.0 3.5 3.5 0.0 2.2 SD 0.2 17.0 11.5 0.0 18.5 M 0.0 445.3 675.0 0.0 519.5 SD 0.5 1,810.1 3,365.6 0.0 4,507.2 151 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Dry Edible Beans cwt. Corn No. ac. bu. Upland Cotton No. ac. bale Oats No. ac. bu. Peanuts No. Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Great Plains Prairie Gateway Eastern Uplands M 1,039.2 11,132.4 96,266.6 2,927.5 0.2 SD 10,483.8 80,653.3 259,389.3 20,791.9 3.9 M 339.9 179.2 90.9 67.6 35.3 SD 213.8 253.97. 106.8 97.2 60.1 M 95,835.3 24,903.1 37,582.5 31,773.2 3,208.4 SD 69,958.9 35,782.7 53,303.7 49,861.0 5,965.9 M 15,118,341 3,208,367 4,590,762 4,752,085 367,133 SD 12,553,742 5,054,506 7,045,153 8,263,123 708,809 M 0.9 0.0 0.0 17.2 0.9 SD 11.3 0.0 0.0 49.0 6.1 M 696.2 0.0 0.0 11,228.4 457.0 SD 8,493.0 0.0 0.0 37,653.8 3,424.7 M 1,329.7 0.0 0.0 19,932.8 472.3 SD 15,808.7 0.0 0.0 66,875.0 3,493.4 M 17.1 46.1 26.2 5.9 7.3 SD 30.8 69.5 29.0 9.0 33.1 M 501.5 1,174.8 2,623.4 414.3 132.9 SD 1,068.9 2,195.8 3,290.4 812.2 603.5 M 33,507.3 70,981.6 154,897.2 16,808.2 7,250.0 SD 65,233.6 145,312.5 199,657.3 33,332.1 35,448.8 M 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.2 0.0 SD 0.0 0.0 0.0 12.7 0.2 152 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Dry Edible Beans cwt. Corn No. ac. bu. Upland Cotton No. ac. bale Oats No. ac. bu. Peanuts No. Southern Seaboard Fruitful Rim Basin and Range Mississippi Portal National M 0.8 10,119.6 9,134.5 0.0 9,061.4 SD 16.4 43,567.7 44,839.6 0.0 78,097.6 M 36.7 15.2 5.4 43.3 113.0 SD 56.5 30.9 18.5 51.8 183.2 M 6,661.3 4,110.9 563.9 17,381.1 31,151.4 SD 11,462.9 10,231.1 1,952.1 23,638.1 53,118.3 M 701,650 590,260 99,364 2,561,041 4,657,411 SD 1,229,096 1,478,219 352,208 3,714,366 8,772,861 M 10.6 8.6 0.1 19.1 5.9 SD 22.2 25.1 1.3 28.5 23.6 M 4,674.8 3,856.8 1.5 15,381.0 3,304.4 SD 9,375.7 14,123.8 21.2 26,901.8 16,397.0 M 7,080.6 7,781.9 3.5 29,831.0 5,842.4 SD 15,210.7 30,467.1 48.9 54,404.3 30,084.8 M 3.7 3.5 4.8 0.9 13.8 SD 6.2 7.4 7.6 3.2 35.4 M 176.1 254.1 292.6 42.2 575.0 SD 403.2 703.4 695.1 213.8 1,507.6 M 9,375.8 19,905.5 18,525.1 3,856.8 34,379.1 SD 23,224.9 66,746.8 41,108.9 20,147.5 94,519.7 M 9.2 3.0 0.0 0.5 2.0 SD 22.5 11.1 0.0 1.7 11.0 153 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Peanuts ac. lbs. Rice No. ac. cwt. Sorghum No. ac. bu. Soybeans No. ac. bu. Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Great Plains Prairie Gateway Eastern Uplands M 0.0 0.0 0.0 534.1 0.4 SD 0.0 0.0 0.0 3,697.4 7.8 M 0.0 0.0 0.0 1,931,461.0 1,312.9 SD 0.0 0.0 0.0 14,250,520 26,388.4 M 0.8 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.1 SD 8.9 0.0 0.0 3.7 1.1 M 323.5 0.0 0.0 70.3 28.6 SD 3,615.1 0.0 0.0 1,329.2 307.5 M 22,164.8 0.0 0.0 4,446.2 1,754.4 SD 248,475.0 0.0 0.0 84,648.5 20,919.1 M 4.2 0.5 2.4 47.4 0.8 SD 11.2 1.3 10.0 65.1 3.2 M 480.2 10.1 810.8 12,755.9 80.6 SD 1,348.2 55.2 3,777.6 16,450.0 399.0 M 42,086.6 524.4 47,840.9 889,048.9 5,743.9 SD 120,803.9 3,479.7 231,829.2 1,247,380.4 30,213.9 M 310.9 106.6 71.6 52.0 14.8 SD 183.0 158.0 119.2 100.4 28.8 M 70,912.0 15,173.0 37,427.3 12,324.2 3,073.9 SD 42,160.3 23,483.7 67,890.0 22,514.4 6,762.0 609,422.9 1,347,236.9 467,877.1 86,045.2 1,007,823.8 2,386,952.9 928,607.7 200,831.2 M 3,125,342.7 SD 2,108,203.6 154 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Peanuts Rice Sorghum Soybeans 155 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Sugarbeets No. ac. ton Sugarcane No. ac. ton Wheat No. ac. bu. Total Cropland No. ac. Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Great Plains Prairie Gateway Eastern Uplands M 0.7 2.2 9.5 0.1 0.0 SD 7.4 16.1 30.2 1.3 0.0 M 230.9 499.8 3,645.5 31.8 0.0 SD 2,744.4 3,810.0 12,909.1 334.8 0.0 M 5,211.6 12,240.9 85,269.8 796.9 0.0 SD 61,116.1 95,869.7 305,906.1 8,950.1 0.0 M 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 SD 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 M 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 SD 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 M 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 SD 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 M 66.8 53.0 154.7 119.7 9.1 SD 83.2 90.3 116.8 121.7 20.4 M 7,306.5 3,735.1 106,356.1 50,901.1 1,219.3 SD 11,492.7 6,734.7 98,100.2 57,237.8 3,894.7 M 364,296.0 230,977.8 3,805,778.3 1,666,559.1 40,789.7 SD 542,708.0 469,045.4 3,578,710.4 2,041,540.5 119,073.9 M 713.3 637.1 453.2 577.4 590.2 SD 304.8 508.9 306.8 393.8 381.4 M 207,227.4 85,057.2 381,285.7 211,425.6 45,492.9 SD 109,968.7 87,140.2 256,206.7 149,657.8 36,568.5 156 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Sugarbeets No. ac. ton Sugarcane No. ac. ton Wheat No. ac. bu. Total Cropland No. ac. Southern Seaboard Fruitful Rim Basin and Range Mississippi Portal National M 0.0 2.4 1.6 0.0 1.3 SD 0.0 11.0 8.1 0.0 10.9 M 0.0 756.9 313.6 0.0 407.0 SD 0.0 4,046.9 1,581.0 0.0 3,869.8 M 0.0 26,258.1 7,766.3 0.0 10,368.7 SD 0.0 139,888.0 39,147.3 0.0 97,047.6 M 0.0 0.8 0.0 2.8 0.2 SD 0.0 5.6 0.0 9.7 2.9 M 0.0 1,542.0 0.0 2,457.2 268.0 SD 0.0 18,303.9 0.0 8,609.2 5,816.6 M 0.0 56,981.4 0.0 85,372.4 9,612.3 SD 0.0 688,855.5 0.0 302,014.9 217,055.2 M 16.6 21.6 24.6 28.4 52.2 SD 26.3 47.4 58.4 38.5 86.8 M 3,282.5 12,117.4 19,240.3 9,590.8 19,132.9 SD 5,375.9 39,231.3 50,537.0 13,847.1 46,639.9 M 149,674.5 792,159.7 971,729.5 439,541.6 751,804.4 SD 256,018.7 618,728.0 1,842,768.5 M 356.7 593.8 352.8 392.8 547.4 SD 283.8 746.4 348.1 247.0 437.0 M 41,485.5 113,765.0 90,990.8 115,932.2 132,547.9 SD 35,782.2 162,519.6 125,671.8 98,657.7 149,407.8 2,291,997.5 3,006,848.0 157 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Milk Cows No. ac. Farms with No. Commodity Payments Commodity Payments $ Income % Dependence Heartland Northern Crescent Northern Great Plains Prairie Gateway Eastern Uplands M 21.5 87.3 8.0 6.6 18.8 SD 37.6 148.7 11.7 9.3 33.9 M 2,109.4 8,351.7 1,497.7 2,801.9 1,129.1 SD 3,853.9 12,197.1 6,610.7 10,084.3 2,045.6 M 453.2 239.1 291.9 276.7 129.1 SD 220.2 272.3 175.9 176.8 130.7 M 3,526,080 1,328,181 3,403,486 3,036,438 440,287 SD 2,318,028 1,443,872 2,460,797 2,912,230 712,447 M 21.1 12.9 12.4 33.6 17.3 SD 190.6 36.8 15.0 76.8 35.3 Means and Standard Deviations of Variables by Farm Resource Region Milk Cows No. ac. Farms with No. Commodity Payments Commodity Payments $ Income % Dependence Southern Seaboard Fruitful Rim Basin and Range Mississippi Portal National M 5.5 16.8 7.8 3.9 22.7 SD 14.0 36.5 12.5 13.4 65.8 M 821.8 14,215.9 1,470.0 300.7 3,795.1 SD 2,654.5 46,897.5 4,016.1 1,377.4 15,888.4 M 97.2 110.0 82.9 194.8 223.3 SD 86.9 129.0 109.2 150.8 218.3 M 1,260,263 2,352,371 929,331 3,914,677 2,196,715 SD 1,733,375 4,396,800 1,538,519 4,338,473 2,742,667 M 47.7 20.3 74.2 378.4 47.1 SD 213.3 55.6 543.4 3,616.4 864.4 Appendix C Location Quotients by Farm Resource Region 159 Location Quotients by Farm Resource Region Farming Occupation Other Occupation Worked Off Farm Any Worked Off Farm 200+ American Indian/ Alaskan Native Asian Black/ African American Multi-Race White Spanish, Hispanic, or Latino Origin Female Male Family or Individual (farms) Family or Individual (acres) Partnership (farms) Partnership (acres) Corporation Other (farms) Corporation Other (acres) H NC NGP PG EU SS FR BR MP 1.06 1.03 1.31 1.03 .90 .96 1.01 1.03 .95 .95 .97 .75 .96 1.08 1.04 .99 .97 1.04 .98 1.00 .85 .97 1.03 .99 1.03 1.02 .96 1.00 1.01 .80 .96 1.07 .99 .97 .94 .95 .15 .48 .58 1.50 2.53 .53 .80 .66 1.15 1.05 .66 1.75 1.47 4.90 3.58 1.57 36 .89 .36 .60 1.03 .70 .79 1.03 .44 .96 1.01 1.70 1.45 1.02 1.48 1.81 1.01 5.92 1.04 .96 3.20 1.47 .98 .67 1.20 .98 9.23 .78 .94 .18 .73 1.04 .31 1.26 .95 .26 .83 1.03 1.65 1.01 1.00 .29 .90 1.02 .52 1.12 .98 3.91 1.29 .95 2.61 1.25 .95 .49 .92 1.01 .99 .98 .95 .97 1.06 1.00 .95 .92 .94 1.36 1.32 1.25 1.32 1.58 1.40 1.07 .93 1.26 1.03 .93 1.19 1.23 .77 .98 1.13 1.29 1.50 .84 .82 .91 1.04 .62 .89 1.09 1.06 1.46 .90 1.44 .80 .90 .51 1.18 1.96 1.66 1.48 .45 .82 .88 .59 .25 .43 1.59 2.81 .32 160 Location Quotients by Farm Resource Region Corporation Family (farms) Corporation Family (acres) Other Farms (farms) Other Farms (acres) Limited Resource (farms) Limited Resource (acres) Retirement (farms) Retirement (acres) Residential/ Lifestyle (farms) Residential/ Lifestyle (acres) Lower Sales (farms) Lower Sales (acres) Higher Sales (farms) Higher Sales (acres) Large Family (farms) Large Family (acres) H NC NGP PG EU SS FR BR MP 1.15 1.35 1.60 1.05 .40 1.08 1.67 1.71 1.35 .88 .92 1.21 .77 .32 .80 1.38 1.48 .85 1.30 1.44 1.41 1.68 .42 .70 1.24 1.77 .60 .45 .82 .88 .59 .25 .43 1.59 2.81 .32 .73 1.13 .74 .84 1.31 1.08 1.02 1.11 1.05 .83 2.07 .70 1.10 2.99 1.95 1.29 1.16 1.49 .84 .91 .66 1.00 1.17 1.19 1.06 .98 1.05 .93 1.42 .59 1.22 2.47 2.16 1.38 .97 1.59 .97 .96 .71 .94 1.10 .98 .96 .94 .98 1.03 1.50 .60 1.22 2.30 1.79 1.29 1.01 1.52 .95 1.16 1.29 1.04 .93 .90 1.07 1.08 .88 .68 1.17 .98 1.19 1.42 1.05 1.07 1.08 .77 1.60 1.12 2.82 1.21 .30 .51 .63 1.00 .56 .99 .88 1.56 1.03 .46 .59 .61 1.00 .47 1.81 .89 2.44 1.22 .31 .60 .65 .84 .81 1.36 .82 1.47 1.03 .37 .59 .60 .86 .66 161 H Very Large (farms) Very Large (acres) Nonfamily (farms) Nonfamily (acres) Full Owner (farms) Full Owner (acres) Part Owner (farms) Part Owner (acres) Tenant (farms) Tenant (acres) Barley (farms) Barley (acres) Beans (farms) Beans (acres) Corn (farms) Corn (acres) Upland cotton (farms) Upland cotton (acres) Oats (farms) Oats (acres) Peanuts (farms) Location Quotients by Farm Resource Region NC NGP PG EU SS FR BR MP 1.56 .66 1.77 1.19 .40 1.20 .98 .59 1.47 1.48 .80 1.28 1.02 .31 .83 .96 .64 1.35 1.11 1.18 1.08 1.34 .53 .94 1.56 1.55 1.18 .50 .64 .68 .81 .38 .67 1.57 1.89 .82 .90 1.02 .76 .90 1.06 1.04 1.09 1.05 .94 .80 1.24 .76 .96 1.57 1.50 1.47 1.35 1.15 1.18 .97 1.54 1.17 .92 .93 .70 .84 .96 1.17 .96 1.22 1.05 .77 .81 .73 .85 .78 1.34 .86 1.47 1.38 .61 .85 1.16 1.06 1.77 1.05 .57 .90 1.13 .43 .63 1.11 .83 1.96 .13 1.28 7.43 .13 .16 .61 1.51 3.17 .00 .03 .58 4.27 .02 .05 .50 2.11 1.86 .00 .11 1.35 8.03 .51 .01 .01 1.13 1.71 0 .08 1.73 5.28 .12 .00 .00 .63 1.01 0 2.61 3.72 1.07 1.35 1.09 .62 .74 .73 .27 .23 .57 .70 .15 .14 .05 .01 .56 .81 .29 0 0 3.68 .11 3.62 1.48 .09 5.59 .19 .92 1.06 0 2.60 4.59 0 2.62 2.41 1.94 .39 .52 .24 .40 .61 3.61 .42 .99 1.18 .21 .56 .00 .48 .51 6.23 .08 .14 0 0 0 1.32 .01 9.62 2.04 0 .41 162 H Peanuts (acres) Rice (farms) Sorghum (acres) Soybeans (farms) Soybeans (acres) Sugarbeets (farms) Sugarbeets (acres) Sugarcane (farms) Sugarcane (acres) Wheat (farms) Wheat (acres) Total cropland (farms) Total cropland (acres) Milk cows (farms) Market Value Total Income Expenses Net Income Farms with Commodity Payments Commodity Payments Income Dependence Location Quotients by Farm Resource Region NC NGP PG EU SS FR BR MP 0 .58 0 0 0 0 .69 .04 .00 .10 11.13 .03 4.80 1.86 0 .03 .16 18.23 .26 .01 .15 3.40 .06 .24 1.25 .00 2.20 3.01 .77 .92 .63 .12 .61 .05 .00 1.14 3.88 1.15 .86 .50 .27 1.11 .06 0 2.19 .62 .99 6.52 .15 0 0 1.83 1.52 0 .43 1.09 3.69 .03 0 0 .93 .11 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 3.25 0 42.96 0 0 0 0 0 0 3.35 0 34.95 1.16 .52 .71 .38 3.93 2.38 2.80 1.70 .13 .12 .62 .62 .36 .40 .61 .60 .90 .68 1.13 1.09 1.08 .95 .99 .91 .81 .85 .93 1.77 1.31 1.10 .95 .82 .95 .80 .49 1.29 .68 1.53 1.79 1.43 1.85 2.77 2.34 4.95 2.48 2.10 .44 .44 .67 .42 .56 .25 .69 .66 .74 .58 .67 .98 1.03 1.11 .73 .31 2.14 2.00 2.29 1.77 .51 3.49 2.65 2.53 2.51 .46 .44 .64 .66 .82 .15 .92 1.01 .98 .86 1.77 .81 1.78 1.37 .47 .73 .49 .52 1.15 1.94 1.15 .68 .89 .44 1.69 1.09 .30 2.43 1.35 .52 1.16 1.37 .46 .99 .62 .53 2.36