Acta Polytechnica Hungarica Vol. 8, No. 3, 2011 A Dynamic Model of a Small Open Economy Under Flexible Exchange Rates Petra Medveďová Department of Quantitative Methods and Information Systems Faculty of Economics Matej Bel University Tajovského 10, 975 90 Banská Bystrica, Slovakia petra.medvedova@umb.sk Abstract: In the paper a three dimensional dynamic model of a small open economy, describing the development of net real national income, real physical capital stock and the expected exchange rate of the near future, which was introduced by T. Asada in [1], is analysed under flexible exchange rates. We study the question of the existence of business cycles. Sufficient conditions for the existence of a pair of purely imaginary eigenvalues with the third one negative in the linear approximation matrix of the model are found. For the existence of business cycles and their properties the structure of the bifurcation equation of the model is very important. Formulae for the calculation of the bifurcation coefficients in the bifurcation equation of the model are derived. Theorem on the existence of business cycles in a small neighbourhood of the equilibrium point is presented. Keywords: dynamical model; matrix of linear approximation; eigenvalues; bifurcation equation; business cycle 1 Introduction Toichiro Asada formulated in [1] a Kaldorian business cycle model in a small open economy. He studied both the system of fixed exchange rates and that of flexible exchange rates with the possibility of capital mobility. In this article we investigate Asada’s model which was introduced in [1] under flexible exchange rates. In this case Asada’s model has the form Y = α (C + I + G + J − Y ), α > 0, K = I , π e (1) ( = γ π −π e ), γ > 0, where – 13 – P. Medved’ová A Dynamic Model of a Small Open Economy Under Flexible Exchange Rates C = c(Y − T ) + C0 ,0 < c < 1, C0 > 0, T = τY − T0 ,0 < τ < 1, T0 > 0, I = I (Y , K , r ), I Y = ∂I ∂Y > 0, I K = ∂I ∂K < 0, I r = M ∂L ∂L = L (Y , r ), LY = > 0, Lr = < 0, p ∂Y ∂r ∂I ∂r < 0, (2) ∂J ∂J < 0, J π = > 0, ∂Y ∂π e ⎛ π −π ⎞ ⎟, β > 0, Q = β ⎜⎜ r − r f − π ⎟⎠ ⎝ J = J (Y , π ), J Y = A = J + Q, A = 0, M = constant, (M = 0). The meanings of the symbols in (1) and (2) are as follows: Y - net real national income, C - real private consumption expenditure, I - net real private investment expenditure on physical capital, G - real government expenditure (fixed), T - real income tax, K - real physical capital stock, M - nominal money stock, p - price level, r - nominal rate of interest of domestic country, e r f - nominal rate of interest of foreign country, π - exchange rate, π - expected exchange rate of near future, J - balance of current account (net export) in real terms, Q - balance of capital account in real terms, A - total balance of α - adjustment speed in goods market, β - degree of capital mobility, α , β , γ - positive parameters, and the meanings of other dY dK e dπ e , K= , π = symbols are as follows, Y = , t - time. dt dt dt payments in real terms, In the whole paper we assume as well as Asada in [1] a fixed-price economy, so that p is exogenously given and normalized to the value 1. Asada assumed that ( ) the equilibrium on the money market M = L Y , r is always preserved, which enables using the Implicit-function theorem to express interest rate r as the function of Y , so – 14 – Acta Polytechnica Hungarica r = r (Y ), rY = Vol. 8, No. 3, 2011 ∂r > 0. ∂Y ⎡ π e −π ⎤ A = J (Y , π ) + β ⎢r (Y ) − rf − = 0 with respect π ⎥⎦ ⎣ Solving equation to π , we have π = π (Y , π e ), π Y = ∂π − J Y − βrY ∂π β = , ππe = = > 0. e e βπ βπ e ∂Y ∂π Jπ + 2 Jπ π + π π Further we suppose that r f is also given exogenously because of the assumption of a small open economy. Under these assumptions, taking into account (2) and the explicit expression for r , the model (1) takes the form [ ( ( )) ] Y = α c (1 − τ )Y + cT0 + C 0 + G + I (Y , K , r (Y )) + J Y , π Y , π e − Y K = I (Y , K , r (Y )) (3) π e = γ [π (Y , π e ) − π e ]. In the whole paper we suppose that: (i) the model ( (3) E = Y , K ,π e∗ ), Y has a unique > 0, K > 0, π triple of positive parameters (α , β , γ ) . ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ e∗ equilibrium point > 0, to an arbitrary (ii) 0 < IY + I r rY < 1 − c(1 − τ ) − J Y at the equilibrium point. (iii) π π − 1 < 0 at the equilibrium point. (iv) The functions in the model (3) have the following properties: the function I is linear in the variable K and r . The function π is e linear in the variable π . The function J is nonlinear in the variable π . In the variable Y the functions I , J , r , π are nonlinear, and have continuous partial derivatives with respect to Y up to the sixth order in a small neighbourhood of the equilibrium point. e In [1] Asada found sufficient conditions for local stability and instability of the equilibrium point. He studied how changes of the parameter β affect the dynamic characteristics of the model. – 15 – P. Medved’ová A Dynamic Model of a Small Open Economy Under Flexible Exchange Rates We analyse the question of the existence of business cycles analytically. Stable business cycles can arise only in the case when the linear approximation matrix of the model (3) has at the equilibrium point a pair of purely imaginary eigenvalues with the third one negative. In Section 2, Theorem 1 gives sufficient conditions for the existence of a pair of purely imaginary eigenvalues with the third one negative. The bifurcation equation of the model (3) is very important for the existence of business cycles. In Section 3, Theorem 2 gives the formulae for the calculation of the bifurcation coefficients in the bifurcation equation. Theorem 3 speaks about the existence of business cycles in a small neighbourhood of the equilibrium point. Such an analytical approach was applied to study similar models in [6], [7], [8], [9], [10]. 2 The Analysis of the Model (3) Consider an isolated equilibrium poin E ∗ π e > 0, ∗ ( ∗ ) = Y ∗ , K ∗ , π e , Y ∗ > 0, K ∗ > 0, of the model (3). After the transformation ∗ Y1 = Y − Y ∗ , K1 = K − K ∗ , π 1e = π e − π e , the equilibrium point E the model (3) becomes [ ( ∗ ( ) = Y ∗ , K ∗ , π e goes into the origin E1∗ = (0,0,0), and ∗ ) ( ( )) Y1 = α c (1 − τ ) Y1 + Y ∗ + I Y1 + Y ∗ , K1 + K ∗ , r Y1 + Y ∗ + cT0 + ( ( ∗ )) ( + C0 + G + J Y1 + Y ∗ , π Y1 + Y ∗ , π 1e + π e − Y1 + Y ∗ ( ( K 1 = I Y1 + Y ∗ , K1 + K ∗ , r Y1 + Y ∗ [( ∗ )( )) ∗ )] )] (4) π1e = γ π Y1 + Y ∗ , π 1e + π e − π 1e + π e . Performing the Taylor expansion of the functions on the right-hand side of this system at the equilibrium point E1 = (0,0,0 ) the model (4) obtains the form ∗ Y1 = α [c(1 − τ )Y1 + I Y Y1 + I K K1 + I r rY Y1 + J Y Y1 + ~ + J π π Y Y1 + J π π π e π 1e − Y1 + Y1 ] ~ K 1 = I Y Y1 + I K K 1 + I r rY Y1 + K 1 (5) – 16 – Acta Polytechnica Hungarica Vol. 8, No. 3, 2011 π1e = γ [π Y Y1 + π π π 1e − π 1e ] + π~1e , e where ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ∂I E ∗ ∂I E ∗ ∂I E ∗ ∂r E ∗ ∂J E ∗ , IK = , Ir = , rY = , JY = , ∂Y ∂r ∂Y ∂Y ∂K ∂J E ∗ ∂π E ∗ ∂π E ∗ ~ ~ Jπ = , πY = , ππe = , and the functions Y1 , K 1 , π~1e e ∂π ∂Y ∂π IY = ( ) are nonlinear parts of the Taylor expansion. The linear approximation matrix following form A = A(α , β , γ ) of the system (5) has the ⎛ α [c(1 − τ ) + I Y + I rrY + J Y + J π π Y − 1] αI K ⎜ A=⎜ I Y + I r rY IK ⎜ γπ Y 0 ⎝ The characteristic equation of 3 αJ π π π ⎞ ⎟ ⎟. − 1 ⎟⎠ e 0 γ (π π e ) (6) A(α , β , γ ) is given by 2 λ + b1λ + b2 λ + b3 = 0, (7) where b1 = − trace A(α , β , γ ) = = −{α [c (1 − τ ) + I Y + I r rY + J Y + J π π Y − 1] + I K + γ (π π e − 1)} b2 = sum of all principal second – order minors of A(α , β , γ ) = ( ) = αI K [c(1 − τ ) + J Y + J π π Y − 1] + γI K π π e − 1 + { ( ) + αγ [c (1 − τ ) + I Y + I r rY + J Y − 1] π π e − 1 − J π π Y } b3 = − det A(α , β , γ ) = = −αγ I K {(π πe ) } − 1 [c (1 − τ ) + J Y − 1] − J π π Y . As we are interested in the existence and stability of limit cycles we need to find such values of parameters α , β , γ at which the equation (7) has a pair of purely imaginary eigenvalues and the third one is negative. We will call such values of parameters α , β , γ the critical values of the model (3). We denote these critical values by α0 , β0 , γ 0. The mentioned types of eigenvalues are ensured by the Liu’s conditions [5]. – 17 – P. Medved’ová A Dynamic Model of a Small Open Economy Under Flexible Exchange Rates b1 > 0, b3 > 0, b1b2 − b3 = 0. (8) For an arbitrary α exists γ such that the first inequality is satisfied under the condition (iii). The second inequality is satisfied under the condition (π πe − 1)[c(1 − τ ) + J Y − 1] > J π π Y . This condition is satisfied when β is sufficiently small. The equation b1b2 − b3 = 0 gives {α [c(1 − τ ) + I + I r + J + J π − 1] + I + γ (π − 1)}. .{γI (π − 1) + αI [c(1 − τ ) + J + J π − 1] + + αγ [(c (1 − τ ) + I + I r + J − 1)(π − 1) − J π ]}− Y K r Y πe π Y K Y Y r Y Y Y πe K π Y π πe Y − αγI K {(π π e − 1)[c(1 − τ ) + J Y − 1] − J π π Y } = 0. π Y < 0 and for π Y = 0. The = 0 is satisfied under the condition π Y > 0. This inequality Asada indicated in [1] that b1b2 − b3 > 0 for equation b1b2 − b3 is satisfied if The β< equation − JY . rY b1b2 − b3 = 0 can be expressed in the f 1 (α , β )γ + f 2 (α , β )γ + f 3 (α , β ) = 0, 2 where f1 (α , β ) = J π2π 2 [I K − α (J Y − R ) − αβ rY ] f 2 (α , β ) = α 2 β 2TJ π πrY + α 2 β J π π ( J Y − R )(T − J π πrY ) − − α 2 J π2π 2 (R − J Y ) − 2αβ I K J π πT + 2αI K J π2π 2 (J Y − R ) − 2 − βI K2 J π π − I K2 J π2π 2 f 3 (α , β ) = α 2 β 2 I K TU + α 2 βI K J π π [T (P − J Y ) + U (R − J Y )] + + α 2 I K J π2π 2 (R − J Y )(P − J Y ) + αβ 2 I K2 U + + αβ I K2 J π π (P − J Y + U ) + αI K2 J π2π 2 (P − J Y ) where – 18 – form Acta Polytechnica Hungarica Vol. 8, No. 3, 2011 P = c(1 − τ ) + J Y − 1 < 0, R = P + IY + I r rY < 0, T = R − J π πrY < 0, U = P − Jπ πrY < 0. We see that for an arbitrary γ exists α̂ such that f1 (αˆ ,0) = 0, αˆ > 0. Put F (α , β , γ ) = f 1 (α , β ) + f 2 (α , β ) Instead of γ introduce ϑ = 1 γ 1 γ + f 3 (α , β ) 1 γ2 and consider an equation = 0. Φ(α , β ,ϑ ) = 0 when f1 (α , β ), ϑ =0 ⎧ Φ(α , β ,ϑ ) = ⎨ 2 ⎩ f1 (α , β ) + f 2 (α , β )ϑ + f 3 (α , β )ϑ , ϑ ≠ 0. We see that Φ(α , β ,ϑ ) = 0 is equivalent to F (α , β , γ ) = 0. Analyze Φ(α , β ,ϑ ) = 0. It holds: 1. Φ(αˆ , β = 0,ϑ = 0) = 0 2. ∂Φ(αˆ , β = 0,ϑ = 0) = − J π2π 2 (J Y − R ) ≠ 0. ∂α α = f (β ,ϑ ) in a small αˆ = f (0,0) and that By the implicit function theorem there exists a function neighbourhood of Φ( f (β ,ϑ ), β ,ϑ ) = 0. (β = 0,ϑ = 0) γ and sufficiently small β 0 of parameter β there exists value α 0 of parameter α such that the triple is (α 0 , β 0 , γ 0 ) the critical triple of the model (3). The following theorem gives We see that for a sufficiently large γ0 such of parameter sufficient conditions for the existence of a critical triple of the model (3). – 19 – P. Medved’ová A Dynamic Model of a Small Open Economy Under Flexible Exchange Rates Theorem 1. Let the condition π π − 1 < 0 is satisfied. If parameter β < e is sufficiently small and parameter γ is sufficiently large, then there exists a (α 0 , β 0 , γ 0 ) of model (5). critical triple 3 − JY rY Existence of Limit Cycles and their Stability According to the assumption (iv) the model (5) can be itemized in the form { } Y1 = α [I Y + I r rY − (1 − c(1 − τ ) − J Y ) + J π π Y ]Y1 + I K K1 + J π π π e π 1e + ( ) ( ) ( ) 2 1 1 1 + α I Y(2 ) + J Y(2 ) Y12 + αJ π(2e ) π 1e + α I Y(3) + J Y3 Y13 + 2 2 6 ( ) ( ) ( ) ( 3 4 1 1 1 + αJ π(3e) π 1e + α IY(4 ) + J Y(4 ) Y14 + αJ π(4e ) π 1e + O5 Y1 , π 1e 6 24 24 ) 1 1 1 (4 ) 4 K 1 = (I Y + I r rY )Y1 + I K K1 + I Y(2 )Y12 + I Y(3)Y13 + I Y Y1 + 2 6 24 + O5 (Y1 ) (9) π1e = γπ Y Y1 + γ (π π − 1)π 1e + γπ Y(2 )Y12 + γπ Y(3)Y13 + 1 2 e 1 6 1 γπ Y(4 )Y14 + 24 + O5 (Y1 ), where I Y(2 ) = ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ∗ ∗ ∗ 3 4 2 ∂2I E∗ (3 ) ∂ I E (4 ) ∂ I E (2 ) ∂ J E , I = , I = , J = , Y Y Y ∂Y 2 ∂Y 3 ∂Y 4 ∂Y 2 ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ∂ J (E ) ( ) ∂ π (E ) ( ) ∂ π (E ) ( ) ∂ π (E ) J( ) = ,π = ,π = ,π = . ∂Y ∂Y ∂Y ∂ (π ) J Y(3) = 4 π e 4 ∗ ∗ ∗ 2 3 ∂3 J E∗ (4 ) ∂ J E (2 ) ∂ J E (3 ) ∂ J E J J , J = , , , = = e e Y 2 3 π π ∂Y 3 ∂Y 4 ∂ πe ∂ πe 4 ∗ e 4 2 Y ∗ 2 2 3 Y – 20 – ∗ 3 3 4 Y ∗ 4 4 Acta Polytechnica Hungarica Vol. 8, No. 3, 2011 Consider a critical triple (α 0 , β 0 , γ 0 ) of the model (3). Let us investigate the Y1 , K1 and π 1e around the equilibrium E1∗ = (0,0,0) with respect to the parameter α ,α ∈ (α 0 − ε ,α 0 + ε ), ε > 0, and the fixed parameters β = β0 , γ = γ 0. behavior of After the shifting α0 into the origin by relation α1 = α − α 0 , the model (9) becomes Y1 = α 0 [I Y + I r rY − (1 − c (1 − τ ) − J Y ) + J π π Y ]Y1 + α 0 I K K1 + + α 0 J π π π e π 1e + [IY + I r rY − (1 − c(1 − τ ) − J Y ) + J π π Y ]Y1α1 + ( ) ( ) 2 1 1 + I K K1α1 + J π π π e π 1eα1 + α 0 I Y(2 ) + J Y(2 ) Y12 + α 0 J π(2e ) π 1e + 2 2 + ( ) ( ) ( ) 2 1 (2 ) 1 1 I Y + J Y(2 ) Y12α1 + J π(2e ) π 1e α1 + α 0 I Y(3 ) + J Y(3 ) Y13 + 2 2 6 ( ) ( ) ( ) 3 3 1 1 1 + α 0 J π(3e ) π 1e + I Y(3 ) + J Y(3 ) Y13α1 + J π(3e ) π 1e α1 + 6 6 6 + ( ) ( ) ( 4 1 1 α 0 I Y(4 ) + J Y(4 ) Y14 + α 0 J π(4e ) π 1e + O5 Y1 , π 1e , α1 24 24 (10) ) 1 1 1 (4 ) 4 K 1 = (I Y + I r rY )Y1 + I K K1 + I Y(2 )Y12 + I Y(3 )Y13 + I Y Y1 + O5 (Y1 ) 2 6 24 π1e = γ 0π YY1 + γ 0 (π π − 1)π 1e + γ 0π Y(2 )Y12 + γ 0π Y(3)Y13 + e 1 2 1 6 1 γ 0π Y(4 )Y14 + 24 + O5 (Y1 ). Denote the eigenvalues of (6) as λ1 = ξ (α , β , γ ) + iω (α , β , γ ), λ2 = ξ (α , β , γ ) − iω (α , β , γ ), λ3 = λ3 (α , β , γ ) and let λ1 = iω0 , λ2 = −iω 0 , ω0 = ω (α 0 , β 0 , γ 0 ), λ30 = λ3 (α 0 , β 0 , γ 0 ). Express the model (10) in the form ~ x = A(α 0 , β 0 , γ 0 )x + Y(x,α1 ), – 21 – P. Medved’ová A Dynamic Model of a Small Open Economy Under Flexible Exchange Rates where ~ ⎛Y ⎞ ⎛ Y1 ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ~ ⎜ ~1 ⎟ x = ⎜ K1 ⎟, Y = ⎜ Y2 ⎟. ⎜⎜ ~ ⎟⎟ ⎜π e ⎟ ⎝ 1⎠ ⎝ Y3 ⎠ ( ) Consider a matrix M = mij , i, j = 1,2,3, which transfers the matrix ( ) A(α 0 , β 0 , γ 0 ) into its Jordan form J, and its inverse matrix M −1 = mij−1 . ⎛ Y2 ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ By the transformation x = My , y = ⎜ K 2 ⎟ we obtain ⎜π e ⎟ ⎝ 2⎠ y = Jy + F(y,α1 ), (11) Where ⎛ iω 0 ⎜ J =⎜ 0 ⎜ 0 ⎝ 0 ⎞ ⎟ − iω0 0 ⎟, λ30 ⎟⎠ 0 −1 ~ −1 ~ −1 ~ ⎛ F1 (y,α1 ) ⎞ ⎛⎜ m11 Y1 + m12 Y2 + m13 Y3 ⎞⎟ ⎜ ⎟ −1 ~ −1 ~ −1 ~ F(y,α1 ) = ⎜ F2 (y,α1 )⎟ = ⎜ m21 Y1 + m22 Y2 + m23 Y3 ⎟, ⎜ F (y,α )⎟ ⎜⎜ m −1Y~ + m −1Y~ + m −1Y~ ⎟⎟ 32 2 33 3 ⎠ 1 ⎠ ⎝ 3 ⎝ 31 1 0 K 2 = Y2 , F2 = F1, and F3 is real function (the symbol "−" means complex conjugate expression). Theorem 2. There exists a polynomial transformation Y2 = Y3 + h1 (Y3 , K 3 ,α 1 ) K 2 = K 3 + h2 (Y3 , K 3 ,α 1 ) (12) π 2e = π 3e + h3 (Y3 , K 3 ,α 1 ) , where h j (Y3 , K 3 , α 1 ), j = 1,2,3, are nonlinear polynomials with constant coefficients of the kind – 22 – Acta Polytechnica Hungarica h j (Y3 , K 3 ,α 1 ) = Vol. 8, No. 3, 2011 4 − 2 m3 ∑ h( { m1 , m2 , m3 ) m1 j 3 m1 + m2 + m3 ≥ 2 , m3∈ 0 ,1} which transforms the model ( Y2 = iω0Y2 + F1 Y2 , K 2 , π 2e ,α 1 Y K 3m2 α 1m3 , j = 1,2,3, h2 = h1 , ) ( K 2 = −iω0 K 2 + F2 Y2 , K 2 , π 2e , α1 ) (11) π 2e = λ30π 2e + F3 (Y2 , K 2 , π 2e , α1 ) into its partial normal form on a center manifold ( ) ( Y3 = iω 0Y3 + δ 1Y3α 1 + δ 2Y32 K 3 + U D Y3 , K 3 , π 3e , α 1 + U ∗ Y3 , K 3 , π 3e , α 1 K 3 = −iω 0 K 3 + δ 1 K 3α 1 + δ 2Y3 K 32 + U D Y3 , K 3 , π 3e ,α 1 + ( + U ∗ Y3 , K 3 , π 3e ,α 1 ( ) ) ) (13) π 3e = λ30π 3e + V D (Y3 , K 3 , π 3e , α 1 ) + V ∗ (Y3 , K 3 , π 3e , α 1 ), where U (Y3 , K 3 ,0, α 1 ) = V (Y3 , K 3 ,0, α 1 ) = 0, D D ( ( αY, ) ( α ) U~(Y , K ,π ,α ), ~ ,α ) = ( α ) V (Y , K , π ,α ), 5 U ∗ α1 Y3 , α1 K 3 , α1 π 3e ,α1 = V∗ 1 3 α1 K 3 , α1 π 3e 1 3 5 1 1 3 e 3 3 3 e 3 1 1 ~ ~ and U ,V are continuous functions. The resonant coefficients δ 1 and formulae δ2 in the model (13) are determined by the δ1 = m11−1 {[I Y + I r rY + c(1 − τ ) − 1 + J Y + J π π Y ]m11 + I k m21 + J π π π m31 } e δ 2 = m11−1 ⎢ α 0 (I Y(3) + J Y(3) )m112 m12 + α 0 J π(3)m312 m32 + ⎡1 ⎣2 1 2 e ] + α 0 (I Y(2 ) + J Y(2 ) )A + α 0 J π(2e ) B + ⎡1 ⎤ ⎡1 ⎤ + m12−1 ⎢ I Y(3 )m112 m12 + I Y(2 ) A⎥ + m13−1 ⎢ γ 0π Y(3 )m112 m12 + γ 0π Y(2 ) A⎥, ⎣2 ⎦ ⎣2 ⎦ where – 23 – P. Medved’ová A Dynamic Model of a Small Open Economy Under Flexible Exchange Rates (Cm 1 h1(1,1, 0 ) = − −1 11 iω 0 + Dm12−1 + Em13−1 ( h1(2, 0, 0 ) = 1 Fm11−1 + Gm12−1 + Hm13−1 2iω 0 h2(1,1, 0 ) = 1 iω 0 h2(2, 0, 0 ) = −1 21 −1 −1 + Dm22 + Em23 ) ) ( 1 −1 −1 −1 Fm21 + Gm22 + Hm23 6iω 0 h3(1,1, 0 ) = − h3(2, 0, 0 ) = (Cm 1 λ30 (Cm −1 31 1 ) ) −1 −1 ) + Dm32 + Em33 2(2iω 0 − λ30 (Fm ) −1 31 ) −1 −1 + Gm32 + Hm33 , and ( ) ( ) A = m112 h1(1,1,0 ) + m122 h2(2, 0,0 ) + m11m12 h2(1,1, 0 ) + h1(2,0, 0 ) + + m11m13 h3(1,1, 0 ) + m12 m13 h3(2, 0, 0 ) 2 (1,1, 0 ) 2 (2, 0, 0 ) B = m31 h1 + m32 h2 + m31m32 h2(1,1, 0 ) + h1(2 , 0 , 0 ) + + m31 m33 h3(1,1, 0 ) + m32 m33 h3(2 , 0 , 0 ) C = m11m12α 0 (I Y(2 ) + J Y(2 ) ) + m31m32α 0 J π(2e ) D = m11m12 I Y(2 ) E = m11m12γ 0π Y(2 ) ( ) 2 F = m112 α 0 I Y(2 ) + J Y(2 ) + m31 α 0 J π(2e ) G = m112 I Y(2 ) H = m112 γ 0π Y(2 ) , while all partial derivatives are Y1 = K1 = π = 0,α 1 = 0. e 1 – 24 – calculated at the values Acta Polytechnica Hungarica Vol. 8, No. 3, 2011 Proof. The unknown terms h (jm1 ,m2 ,m3 ) , j = 1,2,3 and the resonant terms δ1 , δ 2 can be found by the standard procedure which is described for the example in [2]. As the whole process of finding them is rather elaborate, we do not present it here. iϕ In polar coordinates Y3 = re , K 3 = re ( ) ( − iϕ the model (13) can be written as ) ( ) r = r ar 2 + bα 1 + R D r , ϕ , π 3e , α 1 + R ∗ r , ϕ , π 3e , α 1 1 ϕ = ω 0 + cα 1 + dr 2 + Φ D r ,ϕ , π 3e ,α 1 + Φ ∗ r ,ϕ , π 3e ,α 1 r [ ( ) ( )] (14) π 3e = λ30π 3e + W D (r ,ϕ , π 3e ,α 1 ) + W ∗ (r ,ϕ , π 3e ,α 1 ), where a = Re δ 2 , b = Re δ1 . The equation ar 2 + bα1 = 0 (15) is the bifurcation equation of the model (14). It determines the behaviour of solutions in a neigbourhood of the equilibrium point of the model (5). Utilizing the results from the bifurcation theory [3], [11] we can formulate the following theorem. Theorem 3. Let the coefficients a, b in the bifurcation equation (15) exist. a < 0 then there exists a stable limit cycle for every small enough α1 > 0, if b is positive and for every small enough α1 < 0, if b is 1) If negative. a>0 α1 < 0, 2) If then there exists an unstable limit cycle for every small enough if b is positive and for every small enough α1 > 0, if b is negative. Conclusions The main contributions of this paper are the results in Theorem 1and in Theorem 2. Theorem 1 gives sufficient conditions for the existence of a critical triple of the model (3). Theorem 2 gives the formulae for the calculation of the first two resonant coefficients of the model. These theorems are important for the investigation of the existence of limit cycles which are interpreted as business cycles in economics. We intend to show an application of both the model of flexible exchange rates and the model of fixed exchange rates on selected countries. Acknowledgement The work was supported by the Slovak grant agency VEGA No. 1/0828/10. – 25 – P. Medved’ová A Dynamic Model of a Small Open Economy Under Flexible Exchange Rates References [1] Asada, T.: Kaldorian Dynamics in an Open Economy, Journal of Economics No. 3, Springer-Verlag, Printed in Austria, pp. 239-269, 1995 [2] Bibikov, Yu. N.: Local Theory of Nonlinear Analytic Ordinary Differential Equations, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 1979 [3] Bibikov, Yu. N.: Multi-frequency non-linear oscillations and their bifurcations, The Publishing House of the Saint Petersburg University, Saint Petersburg, 1991 [4] Gandolfo, G.: Economic Dynamics, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 1997 [5] Liu, W. M.: Criterion of Hopf Bifurcations without using Eigenvalues, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 182, pp. 250-256, 1994 [6] Makovínyiová, K.: Existence of an Equilibrium and Business Cycles in the Economy Model, in Proceedings of 10th International Scientific Conference Applications of Mathematics and Statistics in Economy, Poprad, Slovakia, August 30-31, 2007, pp. 145-153 [7] Makovínyiová, K., Zimka, R.: On the existence of Hopf bifurcation in an open economy model, Minisymposia and contributed talks, Comenius University Press, Bratislava, Slovakia, pp. 229-236, 2007 [8] Makovínyiová, K., Zimka, R.: On the necessary condition for the bifurcation of a torus in a macroeconomic model, in Proceedings of 12th International Scientific Conference Applications of Mathematics and Statistics in Economy, Uherské Hradiště, Czech Republic, August 26-28, 2009, pp. 269-278 [9] Maličký, P., Zimka, R.: On the existence of business cycles in Asada’s two-regional model, Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications, Volume 11, Issue 4, pp. 2787-2795, 2010 [10] Medveďová, P.: Dynamic Model of a Small Open Economy Under Fixed Exchange Rates, in Proceedings of 12th International Scientific Conference Applications of Mathematics and Statistics in Economy, Uherské Hradiště, Czech Republic, August 26-28, 2009, pp. 305-313 [11] Wiggins, S.: Introduction to Applied Nonlinear Dynamical Systems and Chaos, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 1990 [12] Maličký, P., Zimka, R.: Can Business Cycles Arise in a Two-Regional Model with Fixed Exchange Rates?, Tatra Mountains Mathematical Publications 43 (2009), ISSN 1210-3195, pp. 123-135 [13] L’ubica Lesáková: Innovations in Small and Medium Enterprises in Slovakia, in Acta Polytechnica Hungarica, Vol. 6, No. 3, 2009, pp. 23-34 – 26 –