Greening the Saskatchewan Grid: Comparative Analysis of the Costs and Effectiveness of Three Policy Approaches to Lowering Greenhouse Gas Emissions in the Saskatchewan Electricity Sector Brett Dolter 1 Greening the Saskatchewan Grid 1. Introduction In recent years, the Saskatchewan electricity sector has registered the highest per capita electricity sector greenhouse gas emissions (GHGs) in Canada (See Figure 1). 20.0 Electricity GHG Emissions per capita (tonnes CO2e/person) 18.0 16.0 14.0 NL PEI 12.0 NS NB PQ 10.0 ON MB 8.0 SK AB 6.0 BC YT 4.0 NWT & NT 2.0 10 20 11 09 20 08 20 07 20 06 20 05 20 04 20 03 20 02 20 01 20 00 20 99 20 98 19 97 19 96 19 95 19 94 19 93 19 92 19 91 19 19 19 90 0.0 Year (Data source: Environment Canada NIR, 2013 for electricity GHG data; Statistics Canada, 2014 CANSIM table 051-0001 for population data; author’s calculations) Figure 1 – Canadian Per Capita GHG Emissions in the Electricity Sector Saskatchewan’s electricity is generated primarily by coal-fired power plants, natural gas turbines (including natural gas fired cogeneration facilities), hydroelectric dams and a small but growing number of wind farms (See Figure 2). Crown utility SaskPower owns 2 much of the generation fleet, but also purchases power from wind farms and natural gas fired cogeneration facilities operated by the potash and oil and gas pipeline industries. Electricity Generation (GWh '000s) 25 20 15 Other Imports Wind Hydro 10 Gas Coal 5 0 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Year (Data source: SaskPower, 2009 & SaskPower, 2013)) Figure 2 – Saskatchewan Electricity Generation by Fuel Type SaskPower has an opportunity to transform its electricity generation mix substantially as aging generation stations reach the end of their useful lives (SaskPower, 2011). Figure 3 displays Saskatchewan’s electricity generation capacity and the scheduled retirements that will lead that capacity to decrease in the coming years. 3 4500 4000 Installed Net Capacity (MW) 3500 3000 2500 Cogeneration Wind 2000 Hydro Natural Gas 1500 Coal 1000 500 48 46 44 42 40 38 36 34 32 30 28 26 50 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 22 20 18 16 24 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 14 0 Year (Data source: SaskPower, 2011) Figure 3 –Electricity Capacity in Saskatchewan and Scheduled Retirements Saskatchewan must also meet the increasing electricity needs of a growing population and a growing economy. Forecasts indicate that electricity demand in Saskatchewan will increase by approximately 15,000 Gigawatt-hours (GWh) by 2050 (SaskPower, 2013; SaskPower, 2011; author’s calculations). Peak demand will also increase by approximately 1400 Megawatts (MW) in the same period (SaskPower, 2013; SaskPower, 2011; author’s calculations). 4 In this paper I seek to identify the least cost path of meeting Saskatchewan’s future electricity generation needs in the short, medium, and long-term.1 I also work to understand the cost and effectiveness of three greenhouse gas emission reduction policy scenarios for Saskatchewan’s electricity sector. The scenarios are as follows: 1. Carbon Tax – A carbon tax is set at $15 per tonne carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2e) in the short-term, rising to $25/tonne CO2e in the medium term, and $35/tonne CO2e in the long-term. 2. Renewable Portfolio Standard - An increasing renewable portfolio standard is imposed on Saskatchewan’s electricity sector requiring 30% renewable electricity generation in the short-term, 40% renewable generation in the medium-term, and 50% renewable generation in the long-term. 3. Regulation – The Saskatchewan electricity sector must meet increasingly strict GHG regulations, achieving a 20% reduction below the short-term baseline business-as-usual (BAU) emissions in the short-term, a 50% reduction below BAU in the medium-term, and an 80% reduction below the short-term BAU in the long-term. To conduct this analysis I use a non-linear programming approach over three time steps. In each time step the objective is to minimize the cost of meeting Saskatchewan’s electricity needs. The three time steps allow for the growth of electricity demand and the phased retirement of existing electricity generation infrastructure. 1 The planning periods are approximations of SaskPower’s planning process (SaskPower, 2011). Short-term means approximately 3-5 years; medium-term 10-15 years; and long-term 25-30 years. 5 This paper proceeds as follows; in section two I discuss the linear programming and nonlinear programming approach to energy policy modeling and key examples of its use in electricity policy analysis. In section three I describe the model created for this exercise. Results and a discussion of my analysis are presented in section four. Section five concludes by clarifying the limitations of the current study and outlining next steps for the research. 2. Linear and Nonlinear Programming The linear and nonlinear programming approaches to energy policy analysis are both examples of constrained optimization (Chinneck, 2001). In the constrained optimization approach an objective function is specified that mathematically represents a desired goal. The linear or nonlinear program then works to optimize the objective function by changing the values of decision variables. In a linear program the decision variables affect the objective function in a linear fashion; decision variables cannot affect each other in a multiplicative way. In a nonlinear program the decision variables can affect each other multiplicatively. This introduces a degree of uncertainty into the analysis; the nonlinear program solver finds a local optimum, but there is no guarantee that this is a global optimum. The nonlinear program solver can be sensitive to the initial starting values of decision variables and finding a globally optimum solution may require changing these initial values. 6 In both linear and nonlinear programming the values of the decision variables (or other functions influenced by the values of the decision values) are constrained to meet certain conditions. (Chinneck, 2001) In this paper the objective function is a calculation of the annual operating costs of the Saskatchewan electricity sector (See Section 3). The goal of this exercise is to minimize these annual operating costs by changing the values of two decision variables; investment in electricity generation capital, and the hours that available electricity generation facilities operate within a year. These two decision variables affect each other in a multiplicative way so a nonlinear programming approach is required. Without constraints, the nonlinear program could minimize annual operating costs simply by setting the value of investment and hours to zero. Constraints are required to create a non-trivial solution. In this model there are constraints in each time step requiring the electricity system to supply a minimum level of electricity; constraints to ensure that adequate capacity is available to meet peak electricity demand; constraints to limit the feasible annual run-time of electricity generation facilities; and specialized constraints relevant to specific electricity generation options such as wind and hydro-electricity. Constraints are also used to specify the renewable portfolio standard policy and the GHG regulation policy. A full presentation of the constraints is included in Section 3. Constrained optimization is commonly used in energy policy analysis. The MARKALTIMES family of linear and nonlinear programming energy models have been developed 7 and refined over the past thirty years by the International Energy Agency (IEA) and associated researchers (Loulou, Goldstein and Noble, 2004). The MARKAL models offer a prescriptive method of optimizing the energy technologies that will meet the demand for energy using services (Jaccard, Loulou, et al., 2003; Loulou et al., 2004). MARKAL is “technologically explicit” (Jaccard, Loulou, et al., 2003: 149) in that it provides detailed cost and operating information about a range of technologies, including electricity generation technologies (Loulou et al., 2004). MARKAL has inspired other optimization modeling efforts. Henning & Trygg (2008) use the MODEST linear programming model, which they state is “similar to MARKAL” (p. 2338), to analyze demand side management potential in the Swedish electricity sector. Howell et al. (2011) have introduced an open-source optimization model for energy policy called OSeMOSYS. With OSeMOSYS Howell et al. (2011) endeavor to reduce the financial barriers to optimization modeling. In this essay I construct a nonlinear programming model in Microsoft Excel and use the built-in ‘Generalized Reduced Gradient’ algorithm in Solver to solve the model (Solver, 2014). This paper builds on other optimization studies of Canadian electricity and sustainability policy. Benitez et al. (2008) use a nonlinear mathematical optimization program to analyze the impact of increasing wind electricity penetration on the Alberta electricity grid. They find that a high penetration of wind electricity can lower GHGs in Alberta at a cost of between $41 – $56/tonne CO2e. The higher wind penetration will also require additional natural gas peaking plant capacity for times when wind energy is not available. 8 Lin, Huang et al., (2010) developed a MARKAL-based energy systems planning optimization model to analyze GHG reduction policy in Saskatchewan. The Saskatchewan model includes the electricity sector and other energy sectors such as oil and gas extraction and coal mining. Lin, Huang et al. (2010) determine that the electricity sector would be the least-cost sector in which to reduce Saskatchewan’s GHGs. 3.0 Model Description The model used in this essay is much simpler than other models in the literature. Figure 4 presents the MARKAL model structure. The electricity sector is a small part of this model. It depends upon the resource and processes sectors for inputs, and meets demands for end-use energy services. In MARKAL, these demands respond to changes in energy prices (Loulou et al., 2004). (Seebregts et al., 2001; modified by the author) Figure 4 – MARKAL Model Structure 9 The model used in this paper simplifies the MARKAL structure substantially by assuming that demand for electricity is constant and that inputs such as coal and natural gas are available in unlimited quantities and at constant prices. Figure 5 presents the simplified model structure used in this analysis. Electricity Generation Fuel Electricity Demand Figure 5 – Model Structure for this Analysis 3.1 Scenarios and Time Steps The simplified model is used to analyze four scenarios: business-as-usual (BAU); as well as the three sustainability policy scenarios outlined in section 1: carbon taxation, renewable portfolio standard, and GHG regulation (See Table 1 below). For each scenario the least cost investment and operations strategies are calculated for three time periods, which coincide with SaskPower’s (2011) short-, medium-, and longterm planning horizons. Electricity demand and peak electricity generation requirements grow throughout the three time steps as summarized in Table 1 below. 10 Short Medium Long System Requirements Policy Scenarios Electricity Peak Carbon Tax Renewable GHG Regulation Demand Demand ($/tonne Portfolio (% below Short(GWh) (MW) CO2e) Standard term BAU) 25,000 4000 $15 30% 20% 30,000 4600 $25 40% 50% 35,000 5400 $35 50% 80% Table 1 – Model System Requirements and Scenarios The detailed retirement schedule presented in Figure 3 is simplified to align with the three time steps in this analysis (See Figure 4). Retirements within each planning period are subtracted from capital capacity at the beginning of each time step. 3500 Generation Capacity (MW) 3000 2500 2000 Wind Hydro 1500 Gas Coal 1000 500 0 Now Short Medium Long Planning Horizon Time Steps (Data source: SaskPower, 2011; author’s calculations) Figure 6 – Simplified Schedule of Retirements 11 Investment decisions made in a previous period lead to carry-over electricity generation capacity in future periods. The stock of electricity generation capacity at the beginning of each period is thus equal to: πΈπ. 1 ππ‘πππ!" = ππ‘πππ!(!!!) + πΌππ£ππ π‘ππππ‘!(!!!) − π ππ‘πππππππ‘!(!) Where subscript k refers to the type of electricity generation technology, t refers to the current time period, t-1 refers to the previous time period, and all units are in megawatts (MW). The capital stock thus provides a memory of previous investments in each electricity generation technology. A further simplification involves optimizing the investment and operation strategy within each time step. This approach does not seek an inter-temporal optimization where decisions made in earlier stages are optimal for later stages. Instead the model optimizes the objective function within each time step, which can lead to sub-optimal capital residuals in future time steps. This approach bears some resemblance to the ‘bounded rationality’ approach of simulation models like CIMS (Jaccard, Loulou, et al., 2003). 3.2 Objective Function Drawing from the MARKAL model described by Loulou (2004: 42) the objective function in the Saskatchewan Electricity Model (SEM) is presented in Equation 2. 12 πΈπ. 2 π΄πππ’ππππππππ‘ππππΆππ π‘π = πΌππ£ππ π‘ππππ‘! ∗ π΄πππ’ππππ§πππΆπππΆππ π‘! + πΆππππ‘ππππ‘πππ! ! ∗ πΉππ₯πππ&π! + πΈππππ‘πππππ‘π¦! ∗ (πππππππππ&π! + πΉπ’πππΆππ π‘! ) + πΊπ»πΊπ ! ∗ πΆπππππ πππ₯ Where, πΌππ£ππ π‘ππππ‘! = new investment in a generation technology k ($), π΄πππ’ππππ§πππΆπππΆππ π‘! = the annualized cost of capital for technology k ($), πΆππππ‘ππππ‘πππ! = total capital stock including existing and new investment for each technology k (Megawatts - MW), πΉππ₯πππ&π! = annual fixed operation and maintenance (O&M) costs of capital for each technology k ($/MW), πΈππππ‘πππππ‘π¦! = annual electricity generated in the present time-step by technology k (Megawatt-hours – MWh), πππππππππ&π! = annual variable operating and maintenance costs for each technology k ($/MWh), πΉπ’πππΆππ π‘! = fuel cost for technology k ($/MWh), πΊπ»πΊπ ! = total GHGs in time period t (tonnes CO2e), πΆπππππ πππ₯ = a tax placed on GHG emissions ($/tonne); this was set to zero in all but the escalating carbon tax policy scenarios where it escalated from $15/tonne CO2e in the short-term, to $25/tonne CO2e (medium-term), and $35/tonne CO2e (long-term). Splitting the annual costs of the electricity system into four different cost types allows flexibility in the model. It is possible, for example, for an optimum solution to involve 13 purchasing low-cost natural gas single-cycle peaking turbines to meet the peak demand requirement constraint (see below) but for these turbines to also run for zero hours and provide zero electricity due to their high variable O&M and fuel costs. 3.3 Available Technologies Table 2 summarizes the technologies available in this model and their associated costs. All values are in 2013 Canadian dollars ($CDN). Coal CCS stands for coal with carbon capture and storage. Natural gas CC refers to combined-cycle natural gas turbines. Natural gas SC refers to single-cycle natural gas turbines that are most often used in peaking applications. Solar refers to solar photovoltaic technology. The electricity costs in $/kilowatt-hour (kwh) are calculated by assuming that a 1 MW installation operates at the capacity factor indicated in Table 2 for an entire year; the total annualized cost of operating the system is then divided by the total amount of electricity generated. GHG intensity figures are derived from SaskPower (2013) with modifications based on Delucchi & Jacobson (2011). Please see Appendix A for further details on how the costs in Table 2 were derived. Technology Coal Coal CCS Natural gas CC Natural gas SC Hydro Wind Solar Annualized Fixed O&M Capital ($/MW) ($/kW/year) $ 202,950 $ 33.69 $ 344,758 $ 56.44 $ 93,487 $ 14.32 $ 59,650 $ 8.10 $ 221,095 $ 16.68 $ 189,637 $ 37.08 $ 595,437 $ 14.29 Variable O&M ($/MWh) $ 5.63 $ 5.38 $ 2.45 $ 11.93 $ 2.94 $ $ - Fuel Cost Capacity ($/MWh) factor 15.61 74% 18.04 74% 26.76 42% 45.50 38% $ 65% $ 38% $ 21% GHG Intensity $/kwh (g CO2e/kwh) 0.058 1.35 0.085 0.2025 0.059 0.45 0.078 0.735 0.045 0 0.068 0 0.331 0 Table 2 - Electricity Generation Options 14 3.4 Constraints on the Objective Function To motivate a non-trivial solution to the model constraints must be introduced into the nonlinear program. Constraints common to each scenario are as follows: 1. πππ‘ππ πΊππππππ‘ππ πΈππππ‘πππππ‘π¦! πΊπβ ≥ π πππ’ππππ πΈππππ‘πππππ‘π¦! (πΊπβ) 2. πππππππ πΆππππππ‘π¦! (ππ) ≥ ππππ π·πππππ π πππ’πππππππ‘! (ππ) 3. ππππππ‘πππ π»ππ’ππ ! ≤ πΆππππππ‘π¦πΉπππ‘ππ! % ∗ 8760 (βππ ) ∗ πΆππππππ‘π¦ (ππ) 4. π»π¦πππ πΆππππππ‘π¦ (ππ) ≤ 1000 ππ 5. ππππ πΈππππ‘πππππ‘π¦ πΊπβ ≤ 20% ∗ πππ‘ππ πΊππππππ‘ππ πΈππππ‘πππππ‘π¦ (πΊπβ) The first constraint requires the total electricity generated in the program to equal or exceed the required electricity in terms of GWh. The required electricity increases with each time step, beginning at 25,000 GWh in the short-term, then increasing to 30,000 GWh in the medium-term and 35,000 GWh in the long-term. In the second constraint peaking capacity refers to the total installed capacity of generating technologies that can be made available on demand. This includes coal, coal with carbon capture and storage (CCS), natural gas combined cycle, natural gas single cycle (peaking) plants, and hydroelectricity. It does not include intermittent generation technologies such as wind and solar. Peaking capacity must be large enough to meet the required peak demand. This peak demand begins at 4000 MW in the short-term, increasing to 4600 MW in the medium-term and 5400 MW in the long-term. Often this 15 constraint was not binding in the policy scenarios as historic assets with low run times provided peak capacity. The third constraint is a means of converting the stock of electricity generation capital measured in MW into a flow of electricity generation measured in Megawatt-hours (MWh). The number 8760 represents the number of hours in a year. Technologies are not able to run for all 8760 hours in a year and are limited by technology specific capacity factors. The third constraint is also the reason that a nonlinear approach to optimization is required. As outlined in Equation 1 above, available electricity generation capacity is a function of inherited capital and new investments. New investment in capacity is one of the decision variables for which the program must solve. The number of hours that available electricity generation capacity will run is also a decision variable. This means that two decision variables are affecting the program in a multiplicative fashion. The fourth constraint reflects limited hydroelectric potential in Saskatchewan. SaskPower (2011) notes that hydroelectric potential is located in northern Saskatchewan, far from large markets, and is limited in quantity. I allow an additional 350 MW of hydroelectric capacity to be built above and beyond the existing 650 MW for a total of 1000 MW. The fifth constraint imposes a restriction on the amount of wind-generated electricity that can be used on the grid. Wind is low-cost and the resource is plentiful in Saskatchewan, 16 but this analysis assumes that the intermittency of the wind electricity resource leads system planners to allow a maximum of 20% of generated electricity to come from wind. To encourage realism in the model I constrained new investment in coal to zero. This is because Saskatchewan is not contemplating new coal facilities unless they are equipped with carbon capture and storage. 6. πΆπππ πππ£ππ π‘ππππ‘ ππ ≤ 0 Constraints specific to the policy scenarios were also added when applicable: 7. π ππππ€ππππ πΈππππ‘πππππ‘π¦ πΊπβ ≥ π% ∗ πΊππππππ‘ππ πΈππππ‘πππππ‘π¦ (πΊπβ) 8. πΊπ»πΊπ ππ‘ ≤ π% ∗ πβπππ‘π‘πππ π΅π΄π πΊπ»πΊπ (ππ‘) The seventh constraint was used in the renewable portfolio standard analysis. It required that the sum of electricity generated by hydroelectric, wind, and solar equaled or exceeded a certain percentage of the total electricity generated. This percentage was set at 30% in the short-term, 40% in the medium-term, and 50% in the long-run. The eighth constraint was used in the GHG regulation scenarios. It required total GHGs to be restricted to a certain percentage of business-as-usual GHG emissions in the shortrun, which totaled 14.2 Mt CO2e. The percentage was 80% of BAU emissions in the short-term, 50% of BAU emissions in the medium-term, and 20% of BAU emissions in the long-term. 17 4.0 Results The four scenarios result in different least-cost investment pathways. In the business-asusual (BAU) scenario, hydroelectric electricity production is maximized at 1000 MW capacity throughout all three time steps. Combined cycle natural gas turbines fill in the gap as coal plants are retired and demand increases (See Figure 7). Business as Usual 40,000 Generation Capacity (MW) 35,000 30,000 Imports 25,000 Solar Wind 20,000 Hydro Natural gas SC 15,000 Natural gas CC 10,000 Coal CCS Coal 5,000 2014 Short Medium Long Planning Horizon Time Steps Figure 7 – Business-As-Usual Electricity Generation 18 Escalating Carbon Tax 40,000 Generation Capacity (MW) 35,000 30,000 Imports 25,000 Solar Wind 20,000 Hydro Natural gas SC 15,000 Natural gas CC 10,000 Coal CCS Coal 5,000 2014 Short Medium Long Planning Horizon Time Steps Figure 8 – Escalating Carbon Tax In the carbon tax scenario, the $15/tonne CO2e tax is not high enough in the short-term to encourage investment to deviate from the BAU scenario. In the medium-term, when the tax reaches $25/tonne CO2e, the tax does motivate a change in investment strategy and investments are made in wind turbines (See Figure 8). Investments in wind are expanded in the long-term to maintain wind electricity production at the maximum allowable level (i.e. 20% of total generation). 19 Renewable Portfolio Standard 40,000 Generation Capacity (MW) 35,000 30,000 Imports 25,000 Solar Wind 20,000 Hydro Natural gas SC 15,000 Natural gas CC 10,000 Coal CCS Coal 5,000 2014 Short Medium Long Planning Horizon Time Steps Figure 9 – Renewable Portfolio Standard The renewable portfolio standard offers another distinct investment pathway (Figure 9). Some investments are made in wind even in the short-term to meet the 30% renewable generation requirement. In the long-term the 1000 MW capacity constraint on hydroelectric electricity and the limitation on wind comprising more than 20% of electricity generation means that substantial investment is required in solar photovoltaics.2 The high cost of solar photovoltaics substantially increases operating costs in the final time step of the renewables scenario. Large cost reductions could be obtained were the binding constraints on hydroelectric capacity and wind generation loosened. 2 Whether this should be allowed in the model is debatable; the intermittent nature of solar may also lead to maximum penetration rates being established. An additional constraint may be necessary in future iterations of the model. 20 GHG Regulation 40,000 Generation Capacity (MW) 35,000 30,000 Imports 25,000 Solar Wind 20,000 Hydro Natural gas SC 15,000 Natural gas CC 10,000 Coal CCS Coal 5,000 2014 Short Medium Long Planning Horizon Time Steps Figure 10 – GHG Regulation GHG regulation is the only scenario in which coal with carbon capture and storage (Coal CCS) plays a role. Coal CCS is an expensive technology, but is allowed to contribute to peak demand capacity in the SEM; something that wind and solar cannot do. Coal CCS also has the lowest GHG-intensity of all of the peak-demand-eligible generation options. The hazard of choosing an optimal investment strategy within each time period, rather than across time periods, is illustrated in this scenario. Despite there being 3538 MW of natural gas combined cycle capacity available in the long-term time step, this capital is made to sit idle in order to meet the restrictive 80% below BAU GHG regulation. An inter-temporal optimization would have allowed for greater foresight and a different investment strategy in the short-term and medium-term. This also points to the importance of long-term and consistent policy signals; the bounded rationality present in 21 SEM may be a useful approximation of the current climate policy context in Saskatchewan and Canada where long-term policy guidance on GHG reductions is absent. Short Medium Long $ $ $ Net Operating Costs (2013 $Millions) BAU Carbon Tax Renewables 868 $ 868 $ 879 1,015 $ 1,066 $ 1,105 1,181 $ 1,040 $ 2,259 Regulation $ 947 $ 1,111 $ 3,809 Table 3 – Net Operating Costs by Scenario and Time Step Table 3 presents the net operating costs of each scenario and time step. Regulation is clearly the most expensive scenario, followed by the renewable portfolio standard. Interestingly, the carbon tax scenario has a lower net cost in the long-term than BAU. This is because the net cost of the carbon tax scenario involves the total operating cost including carbon tax payments minus the carbon tax payments. It is assumed that these carbon tax payments are collected without cost from the utility and redistributed as spending for public priorities or as lump-sum payment to Saskatchewan citizens. The carbon tax provides an incentive for GHG reduction but, due to the redistribution of the tax revenue, it is the gentlest scenario in terms of net operating cost. 4.1 Greenhouse Gas Emission Scenarios The effectiveness of the sustainability policies is evaluated using greenhouse gas emissions totals. Though this is a narrow conception of sustainability, and misses important impacts on land, water, air, and ecosystems, it does offer an important test of the sustainability policy scenarios. 22 Greenhouse Gas Emissions Scenarios Greenhouse Gas Emissions (Mt CO2e) 18 16 14 12 10 BAU Carbon Tax 8 Renewables 6 Regulation 4 2 0 Present Short Medium Planning Horizon Time Steps Long Figure 11 – Greenhouse Gas Emissions Figure 11 presents the GHG emissions resulting from all four scenarios. Even without policy action, GHGs are set to fall as coal plants are retired and replaced by natural gas facilities. The carbon tax scenario leads to reductions in GHGs relative to BAU, but has the least impact of the three sustainability scenarios. Higher carbon taxes would be required to make additional GHG reductions. The renewable portfolio standard policy leads to reductions similar to the carbon tax scenario in the short- and medium-term. A substantial decrease is then made in the longterm when 50% of electricity must be generated by renewable sources. Most surprising might be that the renewable scenario only manages to reduce GHGs by 50% from the 2014 starting point. This is because no restrictions were placed on the other 50% of 23 electricity generation. This result highlights the importance of a well-rounded GHG reduction policy; renewable portfolio standards alone risk the continuation of GHGintensive electricity generation outside of the renewable portfolio. GHG regulation offers the greatest reductions in GHG emissions. This is of course a fait accompli of the nonlinear optimization program; GHG emissions were constrained in the optimization routine. It highlights, however, that substantial GHG emissions reductions are possible when GHG reduction is made to be an important (and binding) objective. The cost of GHG reduction in each scenario can be calculated by dividing the incremental net operating cost relative to BAU by the GHG reductions relative to BAU. Table 4 presents the results. Note again that the cost of GHG mitigation in the final period of the carbon tax scenario is negative reflecting the lower net operating cost of that scenario relative to BAU. Also note the influence of solar photovoltaics in the final step of the Renewables and Regulation scenarios. GHG mitigation costs take a substantial jump when solar is used to replace natural gas generation. Short Medium Long GHG Reduction Cost ($/tonne CO2e) BAU Carbon Tax Renewables $ 21 $ 21 $ 36 $ (46) $ 206 Regulation $ 28 $ 15 $ 256 Table 4 – GHG Mitigation Costs by Scenario and Time Step 24 5.0 Limitations and Next Steps Optimization models have inherent limitations. One of these is that they will always choose the lowest cost generation option, but this can lead to “penny-switching” where large swings in investment and operation occur (Jaccard, Loulou et al., 2003: 153). In a future SEM model I can work to mitigate penny-switching by imposing market share constraints on each technology (Jaccard, Loulou et al., 2003). Future versions of SEM can also explore the possibility of inter-temporal optimization. This would model decision-making as if SaskPower had perfect foresight and would avoid the type of idle capital seen in the final time step of the GHG Regulation scenario. In this model, the technology costs were fixed across time. This is unrealistic. It is very likely that costs will change over time. Solar in particular is expected to decrease in cost over the coming decades (Delucchi & Jacobson, 2011). Future models can incorporate changing costs to generation technologies, perhaps in a ‘learning-by-doing’ format. It would also be interesting to explore the addition of technologies such as renewable energy storage that could allow wind to play a larger, unconstrained role in the electricity system. This analysis could be enhanced by a sensitivity analysis. Factors that should be considered in this sensitivity analysis include: the discount rate, the cost of natural gas, and cost decreases for renewables. 25 Future work will involve adding macroeconomic feedback into the model so that forecasts of electricity demand are not exogenous and instead interact with electricity prices to reach an equilibrium between supply and demand. 26 References Bank of Canada. (2014). Monthly Exchange Rates. Available on-line at: http://www.bankofcanada.ca/rates/exchange/monthly-average-lookup/. Last accessed April 15, 2014. Benitez, Liliana, Pablo Benitez, G. Cornelis van Kooten. (2008). “The economics of wind power with energy storage.” Energy Economics. 30, pp. 1973-1989. Chinneck, John. (2001). Practical Optimization: a Gentle Introduction. Available on-line at: http://www.sce.carleton.ca/faculty/chinneck/po.html. Delucchi, Mark and Mark Jacobson. (2011). “Providing all global energy with wind, water, and solar power, Part II: Reliability, system and transmission costs, and policies.” Energy Policy. 39, pp. 1170-1190. Energy Information Administration (EIA). (2013a). Assumptions to the Annual Energy Outlook 2013. U.S. Department of Energy: Washington, DC. Energy Information Administration (EIA). (2013b). Updated Capital Cost Estimates for Utility Scale Electricity. U.S. Department of Energy: Washington, DC. Energy Information Administration (EIA). (2012). Annual Energy Review 2012. U.S. Department of Energy: Washington, DC. 27 Environment Canada. (2013). National Inventory Report 1990-2011: Greenhouse Gas Sources and Sinks in Canada. The Canadian Government’s Submission to the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change. Ottawa, ON: Minister of the Environment. Farret, Felix A., M. Godoy Simoes. (2006). Integration of Alternative Sources of Energy. Wiley Publishing: Hoboken, New Jersey. Henning, Dag and Louise Trygg. (2008). “Reduction of electricity use in Swedish industry and its impact on national power supply and European CO2 emissions.” Energy Policy. 36, pp. 2330-2350. Howells, Mark, Holger Rogner, Neil Strachan, Charles Heaps, Hillard Huntington, Socrates Kypreos, Alison Hughes, Semida Silveira, Joe DeCarolis, Morgan Bazillian, and Alexandar Roehrl. (2011). “OSeMOSYS: The Open Source Energy Modeling System An Introduction to its ethos, structure and development.” Energy Policy. 39, pp. 5850-5870. Jaccard, Mark, Richard Loulou, Amit Kanudia, John Nyboer, Alison Bailie, Maryse Labriet. (2003). “Methodological contrasts in costing greenhouse gas abatement policies: Optimization and simulation modeling of micro-economic effects in Canada.” European Journal of Operational Research. 145, pp. 148-164. 28 Lin, Q.G., G.H. Huang, B. Bass, and Y.F. Huang. (2010). “The Optimization of Energy Systems under Changing Policies of Greenhouse-gas Emission Control – A Study for the Province of Saskatchewan.” Energy Sources. 32, pp. 1587-1602. Loulou, Richard, Gary Goldstein, and Ken Noble. (2004). Documentation for the MARKAL Family of Models. Energy Technology Systems Analysis Program. National Energy Board (NEB). (2013). Canada’s Energy Future 2013: Energy Supply and Demand Projections to 2035. Ottawa, ON: National Energy Board. SaskPower. (2013). SaskPower Annual Report 2012. Regina, SK: SaskPower. Available on-line at: http://www.saskpower.com/wpcontent/uploads/2012_saskpower_annual_report.pdf, Last accessed February 11, 2014. SaskPower. (2011). SaskPower’s Electricity and Conservation Strategy for Meeting Saskatchewan’s Needs. Regina, SK: SaskPower. SaskPower. (2009). SaskPower Annual Report 2008. Regina, SK: SaskPower. Seebregts Ad J., Gary A. Goldstein, Koen Smekens. (2002). “Energy/Environmental Modeling with the MARKAL Family of Models.” Eds. P. Chamoni, R. Leisten, A. Martin, J. Minnemann, H. Stadtler. Operations research proceedings 2001: Selected 29 papers of the International Conference on Operations, Duisburg, September 3-5, 2001. pp. 75-82. Solver. (2014). Frontline Solvers website for the Excel Solver. Available on-line at: http://www.solver.com. Last accessed April 17, 2014. Statistics Canada. (2014). Statistics Canada CANSIM Database. Ottawa, ON: Government of Canada. Available on-line at: http://www5.statcan.gc.ca/cansim/homeaccueil?lang=eng&p2=50&HPA. Statistics Canada. (2014). All-Items Consumer Price Index (CPI) – CANSIM Table 3260021. Available online at: http://www5.statcan.gc.ca/cansim/a05. Last accessed April 15, 2014. 30 Appendix A – Calculating the Cost of Electricity Generation There are four categories of cost associated with electricity generation: capital, fixed operations and maintenance (O&M), variable O&M, and fuel. Capital refers to the cost of building a generation facility, including feasibility and engineering studies, site preparation, building structures, boilers, turbines, and electrical connection to the grid (EIA, 2013b). Fixed O&M are annual costs incurred at a facility independent of the level of electricity generation. Fixed O&M costs include expenditures such as staffing, administrative expenses, grounds maintenance, pump maintenance, and equipment such as tools and safety supplies (EIA, 2013b). Variable O&M costs are annual expenditures that depend on the amount of electricity generated at a facility. They include expenditures on water, wastewater disposal, catalysts, lubricants, and other “consumable materials and supplies” (EIA, 2013b: 2-9). Fuel costs are annual expenditures on coal and natural gas for fossil-fuel plants. The cost of electricity generation for each technology is derived largely from Delucchi & Jacobson (2011) with some information from Benitez et al. (2008) and EIA (2013b) (See Table A1). 31 Source Delucchi & Jacobson Coal (2011) A.1a Delucchi & Jacobson Coal CCS (2011) A.1a Natural gas Delucchi & Jacobson combined cycle (2011) A.1a Delucchi & Jacobson (2011) A.1a & Benitez Natural gas single et al. (2008) & EIA cycle (peaking) (2013) Delucchi & Jacobson Hydropower (2011) A.1a Delucchi & Jacobson Wind onshore (2011) A.1a Delucchi & Jacobson (2011) A.1a Solar PV Dollars Capital cost ($/kW) Size (mW) Fixed O&M ($/kW/year) Variable O&M ($/mWh) Capacity factor Fuel efficiency (%) 2007 $USD 1 2058 27.53 4.6 74% 37% 2007 $USD 1 3496 46.12 4.4 74% 32% 2007 $USD 1 948 11.7 2 42% 51% 2011 $USD 1 632 6.92 10.19 38% 30% 2007 $USD 1 2242 13.63 2.4 65% 2007 $USD 1 1923 30.3 0 38% 2007 $USD 1 6038 11.68 0 21% Table A1 – Source Data for Electricity Generation Costs Costs are inflated to 2013 dollars using the All-Item Consumer Price Index (CPI) (Statistics Canada, 2014). Costs are converted from $USD to $CDN using the average US-CDN exchange rate for March, 2014, which was .90 $USD for 1 $CDN (Bank of Canada, 2014). The results in 2013 $CDN are presented in Table A2 – Electricity Generation Costs in Canada. Source Delucchi & Jacobson Coal (2011) A.1a Delucchi & Jacobson Coal CCS (2011) A.1a Natural gas Delucchi & Jacobson combined cycle (2011) A.1a Delucchi & Jacobson Natural gas single (2011) A.1a & Benitez et cycle (peaking) al. (2008) & EIA (2013) Delucchi & Jacobson Hydropower (2011) A.1a Delucchi & Jacobson Wind onshore (2011) A.1a Delucchi & Jacobson (2011) A.1a Solar PV Dollars Size (mW) Capital cost ($/kW) Fixed O&M ($/kW/year) Variable O&M ($/mWh) Capacity factor Fuel efficiency (%) 2013 $CDN 1 2518 33.69 5.6 74% 37% 2013 $CDN 1 4278 56.44 5.4 74% 32% 2013 $CDN 1 1160 14.32 2.4 42% 51% 2013 $CDN 1 740 8.10 11.9 38% 30% 2013 $CDN 1 2744 16.68 2.9 65% 2013 $CDN 1 2353 37.08 0.0 38% 2013 $CDN 1 7389 14.29 0.0 21% Table A2 – Electricity Generation Costs in 2013 $CDN 32 In this paper the linear program is set to minimize the annual operating cost of the Saskatchewan electricity system; the key word in this sentence is annual. While fixed O&M, variable O&M, and fuel costs are annual, capital is a one-time expenditure that occurs at the start of a facility’s life. Capital costs are annualized using the following formula from Loulou (2004: footnote 21 on page 42): !"#$ (1 + π)!! π΄πππ’ππππ§ππ πΆππππ‘ππ πΆππ π‘ = πΆππππ‘ππ πΆππ π‘/ !!! Where j equals year, and r equals the discount rate. For this paper I have used Delucchi & Jacobson’s (2011) approach of calculating annual capital cost using a lifetime of 30 years for each technology and a discount rate of 7%. To calculate the annual cost of fuel I assume that fossil fuel energy is being converted to electricity at the fuel efficiency factor indicated in Tables A1 and A2. I also assume that fossil fuel prices are $22.00/short ton for lignite coal3 and $4/MMBTU for natural gas4. Table A3 summarizes the fuel costs for coal and natural gas generation facilities. 3 SaskPower predominantly uses locally mined lignite coal in their coal generation stations. The price of lignite coal from the EIA is $18.76/short ton in 2010 $USD (EIA, 2012: 215). Converting to 2013 $CDN the price is approximately $22.00/short ton. 4 The price of natural gas is taken from the low-price scenario in NEB (2013). 33 Fuel Required Efficiency BTU/kWh Required BTU Content fuel (%) conversion BTU/kWh of Fuel Unit (Q/kWh) 37% 3412 9,222 13,000,000 /short ton 0.00071 32% 3412 10,663 13,000,000 /short ton 0.00082 Coal Coal CCS Natural gas combined cycle 51% 3412 6,690 1,000,000 /MMBTU Natural gas single cycle (peaking) 30% 3412 11,374 1,000,000 /MMBTU BTU$content$of$lignite$coal$is$6500$btu/lb$(Farret$&$Simoes,$2006) MMBTU$=$million$British$thermal$units Fuel Price Fuel Cost ($) Unit ($/MWh) $22.00 /short ton 15.61 $22.00 /short ton 18.04 0.00669 $4.00 /MMBTU 26.76 0.01137 $4.00 /MMBTU 45.50 Table A3 – Fuel Cost Calculation and Assumptions Table A3 presents the annualized capital costs along with the variable costs that occur when each facility-type is operating at the capacity factor indicated in Tables A1 and A2. 34