Does the Quality of Electricity Matter? Evidence from Rural India Ujjayant Chakravorty † Martino Pelli‡ Beyza Ural Marchand§ April 2013 Preliminary, please do not cite Abstract This paper estimates the returns from increased access to electricity in rural India on household income. We examine the effect of connecting a household to the grid (the extensive margin) and the quality of electricity, in terms of daily hours of supply (the intensive margin). The analysis is based on two rounds of a representative panel of more than 10,000 households. We use the district-level variation in land elevation and the district-level density of transmission cables as instruments for the electrification status of the household. We find that a grid connection increases nonagricultural incomes of rural households by about 20-30 percent during the study period (1994-2005). However, a grid connection and a higher quality of electricity (in terms of fewer outages and more hours per day) increases non-agricultural incomes by about 85 percent in the same period. This is equivalent to an income growth of about 8 percent per year. Moreover, marginal returns from average daily hours of supply are highest at very low and very high levels of daily supply, not over a wide range in-between. JEL classification: O12, O18, Q48 Keywords: Electricity Supply, Quality, India, Energy and Development, Infrastructure † Department of Economics, Tufts University, 114A Braker Hall, 8 Upper Campus Rd., Medford, MA 02155-6722, USA. Email: Ujjayant.Chakravorty@tufts.edu ‡ Department of Economics and Alberta School of Business, University of Alberta, BUS 3-40E, Edmonton, AB, T6G 2R6, Canada. Email: Martino.Pelli@ualberta.ca § Department of Economics, University of Alberta, Tory 7-12, Edmonton, AB, T6G 2H4, Canada. Email: Beyza.Ural@ualberta.ca 1 1 Introduction In 2009, 288 million people – about a fourth of India’s population – had no access to electricity (World Energy Outlook 2011). In 2005, 364 million people did not have access, while another 300 million received intermittent supply (Balachandra, 2011). The massive grid failure of July 2012 affected 670 million individuals, almost 10 percent of the world’s population and made world headlines (New York Times, 2012). According to the World Bank, unreliable electricity supply has been a major obstacle to Indian economic development, limiting its comparative advantage in labor-intensive products (World Bank, 2010; Rud, 2012). Connecting all households to the grid and providing them assured electricity is likely to have a major impact on the Indian economy. The aim of this paper is to estimate the economic returns to rural households from a grid connection (the extensive margin) as well as from the quality of electricity supply (the intensive margin).1 We study the effect on rural household income that includes all income from wages and business income, except income from agricultural assets for which we have insufficient data.2 Rural electrification may affect incomes of households in several ways (Oda and Tsujita, 2011; Modi, 2005). It may free members of the household from domestic chores, or let them perform these tasks in the evening. The resulting increase in the labor supply may drive down wages, especially for females. Electrification may also increase the productivity of some activities. The productivity of agricultural labor may improve due to technologies such as sprinkler or drip irrigation, which is likely to have an upward effect on wages. Assured supply of electricity creates opportunities for entrepreneurial activities which can take place within the household, such as rice-milling and production of oil from oilseeds. Other ancillary industries, such as the repair and welding of agriculture implements such as ploughs and tractors, may now be possible. These activities are likely to increase farm incomes, which may result in a general increase in labor supply and wages. Finally, electrification could also affect labor supply by children. The need to collect different kinds of fuels, including animal and agricultural waste and fuelwood may diminish and therefore their labor supply to market activities may increase, or they may allocate their time to other pursuits such as education.The possibility of switching from biomass to electricity for cooking may improve indoor air quality and have a positive impact on health (Modi, 2005; Oda and Tsujita, 2011). There are many studies that qualitatively describe the Indian electricity sector (Balachandra, 2011; Khandker et al., 2010; Bhide and Monroy, 2011). Most papers identifying the effect of rural electrification using econometric techniques such as propensity score 1 2 We define “quality” in terms of average hours of daily electricity received by the household. 70 percent of India’s population lives in rural areas, the focus of our analysis. 2 matching, difference-in-difference or instrumental variables usually deal with countries other than India. Bensch et al. (2010) focus on the case of Rwanda, while Khandker et al. (2009a and 2009b) study Bangladesh and Vietnam, specifically rural electrification initiatives undertaken by the World Bank. Two recent papers focus on the extensive margin of electrification. Dinkelman (2012) studies the labor market effects of an electrification project in South Africa using an instrumental variable approach. Lipscomb et al. (2013) focus on the case of Brazil and, using instrumental variables, find a positive impact of electrification on various development indicators. The main contribution of our paper is the focus on the intensive margin of electricity, which has not been done previously. A variety of factors may lie behind the electrification of certain areas and the nonelectrification of others. Governments usually aim infrastructure investment to already growing areas. Other economic trends may affect the investment decision. For instance, a rich village is probably more likely to be electrified than a poor village. The likelihood of being connected to the grid may also depend on the proximity to a big city, or on the population density of the region. For all these reasons, disentangling the impact of infrastructure investments such as electricity on development outcomes has ben discussed extensively in the literature (Duflo and Pande, 2007; Roller and Waverman, 2001; Aschauer, 1989; Garcia-Mila and McGuire, 1992; Holtz-Eakin, 1993). We tackle this endogeneity issue regarding electrification using an instrumental variable approach. We use a set of two instruments. First, following Dinkelman (2012) we use the district-level variation in land elevation. This variable, measured as the standard deviation of the mean elevation strongly correlates with the cost of electrification. Setting up a transmission network on flat land is cheaper than installing it on undulating or hilly terrain. A high variability in land elevation implies a larger number of structures (e.g., poles) must be put in place in order to ensure that the cables do not sag and run too close to the terrain. There may be a trade-off between building a longer route for the grid with higher transmission losses and a shorter route (e.g., going over the top of a mountain) which is likely to be relatively expensive. A high degree of variability in land elevation is expected to decrease the probability of electrification. We construct another instrument which measures the variation in the density of transmission cables in each district from the national average. The data on transmission network is constructed by measuring the length of the transmission cables within each district using ArcGIS. The argument is straightforward. If a household is located in a district served by a higher density of transmission cables the probability of being connected to the network, and by receiving a better quality power supply, is higher than when it is located in a district with a lower cable density (Brown and Sedano, 2004). In addition, because transmission lines are connected to many power plants, a household in 3 a district with higher density of transmission cables are more likely to receive reliable, high quality power. The decisions regarding investments on a transmission network in India lie with the federal government, but not the state governments (Modi, 2005; Balachandra, 2011). Transmission lines are a major infrastructure investment and require a high voltage pole at their destination. The primary purpose of establishing transmission lines is to electrify urban and industrial areas (Brown and Sedano, 2004). Once the federal government decides to build a transmission line between two points, the planner’s problem is to find the shortest and the least costly route between these two points, and the objective of bringing electricity to remote villages is not considered during this stage.3 For this reason, the objective of rural electrification in India played little to no role on how the transmission lines were installed and located. In fact, the federal-level Indian legislation did not explicitly mention rural electrification until 2003 (Modi, 2005).4 On the other hand, elected state officials within the states have large incentives to improve rural electrification, but they only have the control of investments in distribution networks (Balachandra, 2011). While distribution networks are much less costly, they can only be be installed if there is a transmission line within a feasible radius. For these reasons, this paper uses the transmission network, rather than distribution network, as an instrument for the probability of electrification in rural areas. We find that a grid connection increases non-agricultural incomes of rural households by about 20-30 percent during the study period (1994-2005). However, higher quality of electricity (in terms of fewer outages and more hours per day) increases non-agricultural incomes by about 85 percent in the same period. This is equivalent to an income growth of about 8 percent per year. We find that assured electricity supply increases wage incomes, but surprisingly, reduces the income of small businesses or households engaged in petty trades. At the intensive margin, returns are highest at low and high daily hours of supply but not for a wide range in-between. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses electrification policy in India. Section 3 describes the data used in our analysis. Section 4 summarizes the descriptive statistics and presents stylized facts. Section 5 outlines the methodology used and presents results. Section 6 concludes the paper. 3 The per mile cost of setting up a new transmission network may range from several hundred thousand dollars to several million (Brown and Sedano, 2004). 4 In the federal planning budget, only about 10 percent of the electricity outlay is spent on distribution, the rest goes towards power generation and transmission. 4 2 Background Electricity supply in India is inefficient at all stages of production, transmission and distribution (Modi, 2005). At subsidized prices, supply lags demand, especially during peak periods, leading to frequent outages and voltage fluctuations. In 2007, average per capita consumption was 543 kWh, lower than Sub-Saharan Africa (578 kWh) while the average for OECD countries was 8,477 kWh. Average per capita consumption in India is about a fourth of Chinese consumption (2,346 kWh).5 These low figures are partly because India is home to a third of the world’s population that is not connected to any electric grid. Cost recovery is low and has actually declined over time (69 percent in 200102). These low rates are mainly due to losses during transmission and distribution, which rose from 25% in 1997-98 (Modi, 2005) to 38.86% in 2000-01 (Oda and Tsujita, 2011), while the average for neighboring countries is about 10%. Estimates suggest that only 55% of the power supplied is billed and only 41% is paid for (Modi, 2005). Infrastructure theft has led to further declines in coverage (Balachandra, 2011). Figure B.1 and Figure B.2 plot the transmission network with the rail and road networks, respectively. Note that both rail and road networks have a national coverage while the electricity transmission network is quite unevenly distributed, with higher coverage in the northern industrial states. Large parts of the country have no transmission lines hence no electricity. Regions with poor transmission network include eastern Karnataka, western Andhra Pradesh, Jammu & Kashmir, Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Aizawl, Imphal, Nagaland, Gujarat (outside of the Ahmedabad metro region), western Rajasthan and eastern Madhya Pradesh. However, there has been significant improvement in average consumption and production of electricity. The generation capacity grew from 1,362 MW in 1947 to nearly 74,699 MW in 1991. Over the same period, per capita consumption increased from 15.55 kWh to 252.7 kWh (Modi, 2005). Currently, capacity exceeds 170 GW. According to Brown and Sedano (2004), the cost of setting up a transmission network ranges from several hundred thousand dollars, if there are no geographical obstacles such as hills or mountains, to over a million dollars per km. Figure 1 shows the main components of an electricity network. The transmission network carries electricity from production sites to high demand locations. This network is characterized by a high voltage (High-Voltage Direct-Current of 765, 500, 345 and 230 kV), as this reduces transport losses. Because of the high voltage, it is not possible to directly connect a house or a firm to the line, and a step-down transformer must be installed to decrease the voltage and then channel power through a subtransmission network, which is characterized by lower voltage, usually 69, 115 or 138 kV. At the end of the sub-transmission network 5 International Energy Agency, 2009. 5 there is another electrical substation which moves electricity into the distribution network. This last section of the grid is characterized by lower voltages (less than 50 kV) and travels very short distances, between 50 and 100 km. The electricity transported by the distribution network is at a voltage that can be consumed by the retail consumer. Figure 1: Schematic of the Power Grid Source: United States Department of Energy. Setting up new segments of the transmission network is costly and differs from the investment in the distribution network. The cost depends on its length, but also on other factors related to the landscape it must traverse. For example, installing cables over rolling hills is costlier than over flat land because the line will need a higher number of supporting structures. If the line has to bypass a mountain, the cost is likely to increase, as more structures are needed. Because of the high cost of setting up a transmission network, and because it is mainly used to transfer electricity to high demand centers, its route does not serve retail customers between the two points (Brown and Sedano, 2004). The engineer’s problem at this stage is to find the route that is shortest and the most cost effective. Once the transmission cables are installed, the state government can withdraw power through a step down transformer and building a new distribution network. In our data sample, over 80% of the households live in villages with populations less than 5,000 and out of these, 24% live in villages with less than 1,000 inhabitants. These small villages are not likely to have any impact on the location of transmission lines, an observation critical to our identification strategy. 6 We differentiate between connecting to the power grid (the extensive margin) and the quality of power supply (a measure of outages and average daily hours of supply which are generally correlated - the intensive margin). 6 The density of transmission lines thus determines the quality of power supply, as well as the probability of being connected to a grid. A household situated in a district characterized by a high density of transmission cables is more likely to be connected to the grid, and conditional on being connected, it is more likely to receive higher quality power. 3 Data and Stylized Facts The panel contains two survey waves conducted in 1994 and 2005. The first wave is part of the Human Development Profile of India (HDPI) and covers 33,230 rural households. A share of these households was then re-interviewed for the India Human Development Survey (IHDS) in 2005, which covered 41,554 rural and urban households. The households to be re-visited in 2005 were chosen by first randomly ranking villages, and then fulfilling a variety of conditions needed for the survey to be representative by starting in the first village and then moving down the list of villages. The survey is thus representative at the village level, but not necessarily at larger geographical units such as a district. The final data consists of a representative panel comprising 12,958 rural households which were interviewed both in 1994 and 2005. Households are asked whether or not they receive electricity, and if they do, information is obtained regarding the intensive margin of the electricity supply. While the definition of power quality varies across rounds, we carry out various robustness tests to ensure that the impact of power quality is correctly identified. The panel also contains a wide variety of information at the individual, household and village level. Our main variables are constructed as follows. House is a dummy variable which takes a value of 1 if the household owns the house in which the family is currently living. Children, Teen and Adult represent the percentage composition of the household in terms of children (between 0 and 14 years old), teens (between 15 and 21 years old) and adults (older than 22 years old), respectively. Size represents the total number of individuals in the household. Livestock is a dummy variable which takes the value 1 if the household owns farm animals. Hindu is a dummy variable taking a value of 1 if it is a Hindu household and 0 if it belongs to another religious denomination. Finally, the occupation of the household head is constructed by grouping occupational categories under broader classes to achieve concordance between the two rounds of the survey.7 6 We use the term "quality" of power rather than "reliability" which in engineering literature has a precise meaning relating to interruptions in power supply. This will become clearer when we discuss the data. 7 The complete list of occupations for each round is presented in table A.1. 7 These categories are Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill, indicating whether the head of the household is affiliated with agricultural, low skill non-agriculture or high skill non-agriculture occupations, respectively. The control group, Other, covers students, unemployed individuals, and individuals engaged in home-based activities. Finally, household income is measured as non-agricultural income in per-adult equivalent terms. It is computed by using the OECD definition of equivalence scale, which is given by 1 + 0.7(NAdults − 1) + 0.5NChildren (OECD, 1982). This expression gives us the number of adult equivalent members of the household. There is some discrepancy in variable definitions between the two surveys. For example, the questionnaire used in 2005 was much more detailed on agricultural income than the one used in 1994. The latter questionnaire also contains questions about losses, while in the former, agricultural income was not allowed to be negative. Therefore, for the sake of our analysis, data on agricultural income could not be included in household total income. Table 1 presents the household characteristics considered in this paper. Per adult equivalent income increased significantly over the period studied, and so did its volatility. On average, there were 6.6 individuals per household, while this number was reduced to 5.5 by 2004. About one third of the individuals within households were children, 14 percent were teenagers and slightly more than half of the household population were adults. The share of adults has increased over time, and the share of children as well as teenagers has decreased. Approximately 85 percent of the households in the sample are Hindus. With respect to asset ownership, almost the entire sample owned the dwelling they were living in. In 1994, 70 percent of the sample owned livestock while this number increased to 85 percent in 2005. The proportion of household heads employed in a skilled occupation is very low, but increased significantly between 1994 and 2005, going from 0.3% to 1.91%. Household heads dedicated to low skilled occupations remained around 30%, while those working in agriculture diminished significantly from 56% to 30%. Many factors may explain this shift: e.g., some of them may have just stopped working and retired. 3.1 Household Electrification Table 2 reports household grid connection rates for the 18 states surveyed in this study. The majority of the states surveyed exhibit an increase in connection rates.8 The table shows that the better-off states, such as Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu and Kerala are also those doing better in terms of grid connections. Poorer states, such as Bihar, Orissa and 8 Assam shows a 100% connection rate, but because of random sampling, only three households from Assam were interviewed. 8 Table 1: Household Characteristics Variable Income per Adult Equvalent Household Size Share of Children Share of Teenager Share of Adults Hindu Home Ownership Livestock Ownership Occupation: Agriculture Occupation: Low Skill Occupation: High Skill Mean 6.472.4 6.577 0.341 0.146 0.513 0.854 0.968 0.704 0.564 0.344 0.003 1994 Std. Dev. 7,639.8 3.322 0.21 0.166 0.187 0.353 0.175 0.456 0.496 0.475 0.056 Mean 8,722.5 5.546 0.3 0.136 0.564 0.848 0.98 0.845 0.299 0.276 0.019 2005 Std. Dev. 10,895.0 2.759 0.222 0.173 0.216 0.359 0.139 0.361 0.458 0.447 0.137 Obs. 9791 9791 9791 9791 9791 9791 9791 9791 9782 9782 9782 Notes: The table reports descriptive statistics of the household controls used in the estimation. The following variables are dummies: Hindu, Home and Livestock. Child, Teen and Adult represent percentages and finally Occupation Head Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill represent the percentage of household heads employed in the different occupation groups, which are described in Table (A.1). Uttar Pradesh are under-performing.9 Figure 2 provides an illustration of the districtlevel electrification rate in 2005, which shows that for almost half of the districts in our sample, the electrification rate is less that 57 percent, with a high level of variation across districts. The quality of power supply at the household level is constructed as follows. The 1994 wave asked if the household’s power supply was continuous, if the household experienced on average one or two or more than two power outages per week. The electricity supply is characterized as high quality if the household reported no power outages. We assume this threshold for high quality to be 18 hours per day.10 The 2005 wave asked how many hours of electricity per day does the household receive on average. The quality of power supply variable is then defined as a variable that takes the value of zero when the household is not connected to the grid, 0.5 when it is connected but receives a low quality power supply, and 1 when it is connected and receives high quality power supply. As shown in Table 2 the quality of supply improved by almost 80% between 1994 and 2005. Quality increased across the board, and the numbers show a certain degree of correlation between the increase in grid connections and quality. 9 This relationship between income and electrification rates is clearer at the state level. Figure B.3 shows that there is a strong and positive correlation between state-level income and electrification rates in 2005. The same relationship holds for 1994, not presented here for brevity. 10 Different values of the threshold – 16 and 20 hours – were used in robustness checks, and the results hold over a large set of thresholds. 9 Table 2: Household Electrification Rate by State (%) Electrification 1994 2005 Change Quality of Supply 1994 2005 Change Andhra Pradesh Assam Bihar Chhattisgarh Gujarat Haryana Himachal Pradesh Jharkhand Kerala Maharashtra Madhya Pradesh Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh Uttarakhand West Bengal 54 0 10 36 71 82 91 20 76 67 62 17 77 49 66 19 33 13 86 0 21 68 87 90 97 64 89 78 71 34 95 54 88 39 66 36 32 0 11 32 16 8 6 44 13 11 9 17 18 5 22 20 33 23 31 0 7 27 44 45 69 17 44 40 41 21 45 36 50 19 19 15 78 0 27 57 80 60 99 71 96 80 45 94 64 49 98 50 61 86 47 0 20 30 36 15 30 54 52 40 4 73 19 13 48 31 42 71 India 53 69 16 39 71 32 Notes: The table reports the percentage of households that reported a grid connection in 1994 and 2005. 3.2 Infrastructure: The Transmission Network In order to construct the variable for the length of the transmission cables within each district, we use maps of the Indian transmission network published by the Indian Ministry of Power. We then superimpose these maps on the map of Indian districts from Census 2001 (Government of India, 2001) using ArcGIS. Next, transmission cables are split along the borders of the districts in order to measure their exact length within each district. The density of the transmission network is then computed by taking the total length of all the transmission line segments for each district, and dividing it by the district surface area. The deviation of this measure from the national average is defined as the normalized transmission cable density. Figure 3 shows the map of this cable density measure for 2005.11 The shades of green represent values below the national average, while warmer shades show above average densities. If a household is located in a district characterized by a positive density, then the probability that the household is connected to the grid, and receive high quality electricity is higher (Brown and Sedano, 2004), while the opposite is true for negative values. Table 3 shows the number of households with and without connection in the two 11 The map for 1994 is presented in Figure B.4 10 Figure 2: Electrification rate in the survey districts in 2005. Note: Source is ESRI ArcGIS World package and geocommons. Districts left white are not part of the survey sample. periods. Those with electricity are divided into two groups - higher or lower than a daily average of 18 hours of supply. During the study period, the number of households connected to the grid increased from 52.9% initially to 68.7%. Table 3 also shows the variation in real income per adult equivalent between 1994 and 2005. Households experiencing the highest increase in income per adult equivalent are those who got connected to the grid within that time period. This data suggests a strong positive effect of electrification on income.12 The number of households with low quality power decreased by 21.6%, while those with good supply more than doubled. The status of a small number of households regressed, either from good to poor power supply, from poor to no grid connection and also from a good to no connection. The last may have occurred because of theft of cables and other infrastructure, which is common in India (Balachandra, 2011). Both being connected to the grid and receiving more hours of supply have a positive effect on household income (see Table 3, Figures B.3). Table 3 shows (top row) that 12 Approximately three quarters of the households report data on the hours of electricity they received. The full sample is used in the analysis wherever possible. 11 Figure 3: Density of transmission cables per km2 by district, 2005 Note: Source is ESRI ArcGIS World package and geocommons. The cable density is normalized as a deviation from the national mean. moving from no connection in 1994 to a connection in 2005, without regard to the quality of power supply, leads to an increase in household income of about 3%. This number is statistically significant at the 1% level. Moving from a low to a high quality power supply (second row) generates an increase in income of 3.6 %, which is also statistically significant at the 1% level. These preliminary figures seem to suggest that both connecting to the grid and improving the quality of supply are important factors. Table 4 summarizes information on the density of transmission cables by state. Between the years we study, the transmission network expanded by about 23% (more than 7,000 kms). However, there is considerable heterogeneity within states - West Bengal saw a decline of 3.3% while the network size in Gujarat increased by 96.7%. The states which saw their network size increase – Gujarat, Maharashtra, Punjab, Rajasthan and Uttar Pradesh – also experienced large gains in mean household income. 12 Table 3: Household Electrification and Quality of Supply Not Connected 2005 Connected, Low Quality Supply Connected, High Quality Supply Total 2,447 1.9∗∗∗ 1,188 2.8∗∗∗ 978 3.4∗∗∗ 4,613 Connected, Low Quality Supply Number of Households Change in Income (%) 532 0.09 1,762 2.1∗∗∗ 1,848 3.6∗∗∗ 4,142 Connected, High Quality Supply Number of Households Change in Income (%) 83 2.3 299 2.1∗∗ 653 4.6∗∗∗ 1,035 3,062 3,249 3,479 9,790 1994 Not Connected Number of Households Change in Income (%) Total Number of Households Notes: The table reports the absolute number of households moving from one state to the other between 1994 and 2005 and the variation in the household total income, not including income from agriculture. Asterisks report statistics for a test of two means between 1994 income and 2005 income. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. High Quality Supply is defined as more than 18 hours of electricity per day on average in 2005; in 1994, households were asked whether or not electricity supply was "reliable." 3.3 Geography: The Land Elevation The district level variation in land elevation is computed from Global Land Cover Facility data (USGS, 2004), which provides maps of global land elevation at 90 meters resolution. Each district is divided into grids of 90 by 90 meters, and the grid elevation with respect to sea-level is known. Using ArcGIS, we compute the mean, standard error and range of elevation for each district. While the range gives us the difference between the lowest and highest points in a district, the standard deviation gives us the variation in the terrain. For instance, rolling hills will generate a higher variation than a gentle upward slope. A larger variation implies a higher cost of electrification. Table 5 reports mean land elevation by state. Figure 4 shows the district-level variation in land elevation. The northern states closer to the Himalayas, such as Himachal Pradesh and Uttarakhand, report the highest mean elevation and a bigger range. These regions also exhibit large variation in elevation. Within the states with high variation in land elevation, there are relatively poor states such as Assam, and richer states like Kerala. The coastal districts are dropped as their measurement is not precise: the map used assigns extreme values to the pixels close to the coast. This corresponds to dropping 8 of the 157 districts sampled. 13 14 32,432.0 2,057.2 465.5 1,635.1 368.6 1,118.5 736.9 281.7 1,320.0 1,368.0 2,337.9 2,359.0 3,568.6 1,018.0 1,076.2 3,041.5 5,326.9 323.2 807.4 0.0101 0.0074 0.0055 0.0169 0.0027 0.0060 0.0167 0.0051 0.0160 0.0362 0.0076 0.0076 0.0224 0.0202 0.0032 0.0233 0.0220 0.0060 0.0091 28,710.6 24,192.8 33,245.5 25,179.1 18,060.5 23,179.1 36,755.6 33,296.9 39,286.0 30,393.1 25,364.8 17,754.8 19,556.5 38,883.9 30,476.7 30,620.9 28,370.0 22,342.3 26,830.0 157,031.0 253,971.0 39,779.3 2,281.9 465.3 1,644.6 383.6 2,186.9 978.3 292.6 1,326.7 1,566.0 3,100.4 2,965.8 3,621.0 1,673.0 2,132.1 3,422.0 6,798.5 323.1 785.6 Total length 0.0163 0.0258 0.0124 0.0082 0.0055 0.0170 0.0028 0.0118 0.0222 0.0053 0.0161 0.0414 0.0101 0.0096 0.0227 0.0332 0.0062 0.0262 0.0280 0.0060 0.0088 Length/km2 Real mean income Length/km2 22,564.0 27,215.3 10,921.8 24,842.4 16,857.7 22,626.3 52,558.4 51,985.8 45,039.8 54,139.0 28.537.8 18.673.2 19,977.2 55,157.2 34,403.1 28,513.2 35,848.6 29,570.4 28,439.0 Real mean income 9,640,821.0 9,826,675.0 3,195,023.0 276,472.5 84,841.0 96,875.8 137,771.5 185,460.2 44,017.4 54,997.7 82,330.5 37,824.5 307,545.2 308,997.3 159,348.7 50,330.2 341,790.7 130,586.9 242,618.2 53,833.8 88,992.4 Total surface 157 11 1 8 7 10 11 8 4 4 16 18 11 8 12 8 9 3 8 # of district surveyed Notes: Real mean income is calculated using the households included in the sample. For example only three households are interviewed in Assam, causing significant variation in mean income. 1 Yang (2006). 2 Brown and Sedano (2004) China (2000)1 US (2002)2 India Andhra Pradesh Assam Bihar Chhattisgarh Gujarat Haryana Himachal Pradesh Jharkhand Kerala Maharashtra Madhya Pradesh Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh Uttarakhand West Bengal Total length 2005 1994 Table 4: The density of transmission cables Figure 4: District level variation in land elevation Note: Source is Global Land Cover Facility (USGS, 2004). Darker red indicate a higher degree of variability in district-level land elevation. The measure is not computed for coastal districts (white). Elevation for these districts cannot be accurately measured. 4 Empirical Approach and Results We deal with the endogenous probability of electrification and quality of supply by using an instrumental variable approach, following the seminal work of Angrist and Imbens.13 The endogeneity of electrification applies to both the probability of receiving electricity, and the quality of electricity supply. We use two different instruments. First, following Dinkelman (2012), the connection to the grid is instrumented using the district level variation in land elevation. As the variation increases, mean gradient within the district is higher and therefore it is more costly to set up distribution lines. Second, the quality of power supply is instrumented with the density of transmission cables within the district relative to the average over all districts. Proximity to the transmission network implies a closer connection to the source of electricity and therefore a higher probability of receiving good power supply. 13 See, for example, Angrist (1990), Angrist and Imbens (1994) and Angrist (1998). 15 Table 5: Average Land Elevation (meters) Andhra Pradesh Assam Bihar Chhattisgarh Gujarat Haryana Himachal Pradesh Jharkhand Kerala Maharashtra Madhya Pradesh Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh Uttarakhand West Bengal Range Mean St. Dev. 1,145.7 1,711.7 660.2 1,122.0 973.8 1,146.7 5,691.2 1,099.1 2,278.7 1,233.5 1,023.2 1,356.1 634.6 1,428.3 2,318.0 695.9 6,612.9 3,197.7 349. 113.7 69.0 388.7 136.9 231.6 1,914.1 291.0 469.6 415.5 378.0 279.1 220.8 279.1 322.6 134.1 1,694.9 109.4 96.6 69.5 23.0 106.8 65.5 22.7 625.3 86.7 321.2 82.0 71.8 127.1 20.6 59.4 195.0 13.4 749.1 73.6 Notes: Coastal districts are not included because elevation cannot be accurately measured. The main specification includes the village and year fixed effects to account for variation across villages in terms of their proximity to cities, industrial regions and other village-level characteristics such as land quality, other infrastructure including roads and railways that may affect income levels and may be time-varying. These controls also account for any changes in electricity prices that may affect incentives to connect to the grid. We also estimate the main specification by excluding villages that are near a main city, and excluding villages that are located within a district with high share of industrial output. At the household level, the investment necessary for connection to the grid may be better justified for those with significant land endowments, or those engaged in some home-based economic activity. Households that can invest in electrical appliances may find it worthwhile to connect to the grid. Even for households connecting to the grid illegally, the initial connection may require some expenditure in the form of a deposit to cover fixed costs for cables and other equipment, that may rule out poorer households. We present our results with a full set of household controls for factors that relate to the general well-being of the household, including assets, occupation and household composition. Let Y denote household income and X be a vector of household-level controls. Define T to be the treatment variable, which represents one of the two electrification variables: the extensive margin variable which is an indicator of whether the household receives 16 electricity, and the intensive margin variable, which represents the quality of power supply received by the household. Let Z be the district-level instrument. Our specification takes the following form: Yit = α + δt + δv + β T̂it + Xγ + εit (1) Tit = ϕ + δt + δv + ηZit + Xζ + uit (2) where subscripts i, t and v denote household, time and village level variables, respectively. Thus, δt and δv represent time and village fixed effects and ε and u are error terms. The coefficient of interest is β. The first stage, regression (2) is modeled with a probit specification when T is the indicator for receiving electricity, and linear specification when T represents quality of power supply. All standard errors are clustered at the village level to account for within-village correlation. Table 6 presents first stage regressions to assess the relationship between transmission cable density and electrification and quality of power supply in villages. The model is estimated using various combinations of demographic controls, including household size, share of children, teen and adult members within the household, asset controls including livestock and home ownership, and occupational controls indicating whether the household head works in agricultural, low skill or high skill occupations. The results suggest that cable density has a positive and robust impact on electrification in these remote villages. The coefficient is robust at 1.9 percent across all specifications, implying that a one unit increase in the density of transmission lines increases electrification by 1.9 percentage points. The results also show that quality of electricity increases with transmission cable density, with one unit increase in cable density increases the quality index by 2.0 percentage points.14 4.1 Extensive Margin: Connecting to the Grid and Household Income The impact of electrification on household income is presented in Table 7. The model is presented with OLS and IV specifications, the latter using the density of transmission cables as instrument for electrification. As before, standard errors are clustered at the village level. Time and village fixed effects are included in all specifications to account for time-invariant characteristics of villages, as well as changes over time that are common to all villages. The OLS results without household controls presented in Column (1) indicates that 14 Note that the number of observations declines in a panel due to missing information on power quality. In order to deal with this issue, we also run the latter specification using a village-level quality index, which is allocated to every household living in the same village. The coefficient is robust to this change. 17 Table 6: First stage regression on grid connection and quality index instrument: cable density Dependent variable: Grid connection (1) Cable density (2) (3) Quality of Supply (4) (5) (6) 0.019∗∗∗ 0.018∗∗∗ 0.018∗∗∗ 0.019∗∗∗ 0.019∗∗∗ (0.007) (0.006) (0.006) (0.007) (0.006) Size Children Hindu (7) (8) (9) 0.021∗∗ 0.020∗∗ 0.020∗∗ 0.021∗∗ (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (10) 0.020∗∗ (0.008) 0.021∗∗∗ 0.020∗∗∗ (0.001) (0.001) 0.019∗∗∗ (0.001) 0.007∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ (0.001) (0.001) 0.007∗∗∗ (0.001) −0.158∗∗∗−0.154∗∗∗ (0.017) (0.017) −0.139∗∗∗ (0.017) −0.098∗∗∗−0.094∗∗∗ (0.014) (0.014) −0.093∗∗∗ (0.014) 0.024 (0.018) 0.023 (0.018) 0.024 (0.018) 0.039 (0.027) 0.005 (0.015) 0.020 (0.028) Livestock 0.040∗∗∗ 0.068∗∗∗ 0.046∗∗∗ (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) 0.037∗∗∗ 0.048∗∗∗ (0.009) (0.009) Agriculture −0.112∗∗∗−0.093∗∗∗ (0.010) (0.010) −0.028∗∗∗ (0.008) Low Skill −0.058∗∗∗−0.031∗∗∗ (0.010) (0.010) −0.010 (0.007) 0.002 (0.008) 0.035 (0.022) 0.042∗ (0.022) High Skill 0.102 (0.029) 0.013 (0.018) 0.004 (0.015) Home ∗∗∗ 0.023 (0.027) 0.004 (0.015) ∗∗∗ 0.116 (0.029) 0.022 (0.018) 0.015 (0.018) 0.040∗∗∗ (0.009) −0.020∗∗ (0.008) Year F.E. Village F.E. yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes Observations 19,570 19,570 19,570 19,489 19,489 14,362 14,362 14,362 14,310 14,310 Notes: All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the village level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Instrument is the district deviation from the national density of transmission cables per squared kilometer. Hindu, Home and Livestock are dummy variables. Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill are occupations estimated with respect to a benchmark corresponding to any kind of home-based activity, including students and unemployed. receiving electricity is associated with 18 percent higher household income. The estimate is generally robust to the inclusion of household controls for demographic characteristics, asset ownership and occupations, and various combinations of these controls. Instrumentation of electricity with cable density increases the impact several fold to 180 percent, implying that receiving electricity almost triples the non-agricultural household income, and the estimate is largely robust to the inclusion of various household controls. Returns to electrification show a large increase after instrumentation. A potential explanation relates to the type of infrastructure reflected in the coefficients. The IV estimates reflect the impact of the transmission network, while the OLS estimates reflect both distribution and transmission networks. The smaller OLS estimates may thus be associated with the efforts of state governments to provide power to poorer areas. The transmission network, on the other hand, substantially improves the household’s probability of receiving electricity, but it does not reflect the potential downward bias arising from state policies. The coefficients of other control variables have the expected signs. Per-adult equivalent household income is negatively associated with household size, with each additional 18 individuals reducing income by 3 to 6 percent. The demographic controls are insignificant, which is most likely due to the demographic correction in the dependent variable.The coefficient on livestock ownership is negative, indicating that the household is less likely to receive income from non-agricultural activities if it owns livestock. Home ownership has insignificant impact as almost the entire sample are home owners, and the real estate rental market is likely to be very small or nonexistent in these small villages. The household income is about 41 percent and 125 percent higher than the control group if the household head was in low-skill and high-skill non-agricultural occupations, respectively. Agriculture is associated with a 12 percent lower non-agricultural income. The low magnitude of this estimate indicates that households tend to have both agricultural and non-agricultural incomes and do not necessarily specialize in one type of activity. These controls for household characteristics are expected to capture differences among households that may determine whether or not they receive electricity. However, unobserved household characteristics may still determine both income and electrification, leading to biased estimates. In Columns (11) and (12), we control for household fixed effects to account for these unobserved characteristics. The coefficient on electrification in the OLS specification has declined to 0.06 percent, while the IV specification is generally robust at 1.83, both statistically significant at the 5 percent level. The above exercise is repeated using the variation in land elevation as an instrument for electrification. The results are presented in Table 8. The magnitudes for the impact of electrification are quantitatively similar to the previous results. The OLS specification varies between 0.18 and 0.23, while the IV specification varies between 1.4 and 1.5. The discrepancy may be due to the fact that 8 coastal districts are dropped from the analysis as the variation in land elevation could not be measured for these districts. The model is also estimated by excluding households that live in districts that are relatively urbanized. The incomes in these districts may be growing faster than others for reasons that are not related to electricity, but they may be receiving electricity due to their proximity to cities. This is done by excluding the ten largest cities, and the districts in which they are located, as well as their neighbouring districts. The 10 biggest cities in India in decreasing order of importance, are: Mumbai, Delhi, Bangalore, Hyderabad, Ahmedabad, Chennai, Kolkata, Surat, Pune, and Jaipur.15 The results suggest that the coefficients of interest, on the Grid connection have roughly the same magnitude and the same statistical significance as in the whole sample estimation.16 15 This results in elimination of the following districts from the sample: Maharashtra: the districts of Dhule, Pune, Ahmednagar, Solapur and Satara; Haryana: the districts of Sonipat, Gurgaon and Faridabad; Karnataka: the district of Bangalore rural, Tumkuru and Kolar; Tamil Nadu: the districts of Dharmapuri and Kancheepuram; Andhra Pradesh: the district of Medak; Gujarat: the districts of Ahmedabad, Kheda, Gandhinagar and Bharuch; Rajasthan: the districts of Sikar, Alwar, and Sawai Madhopur; and finally West Bengal, the districts of South 24 Parganas and North 24 Parganas. 16 These results are presented in Table A.5. The same model is estimated using the land gradient 19 20 19,570 yes yes no 8.23 8.58 19,570 yes yes no 0.180∗∗∗ 1.807∗∗ (0.023) (0.793) (2) (1) −0.082 (0.064) −0.049 (0.044) 19,570 yes yes no 8.17 8.36 19,570 yes yes no −0.016 (0.045) 0.023 (0.033) −0.021 (0.045) 19,570 yes yes no 8.06 8.24 19,570 yes yes no −0.156∗∗∗−0.224∗∗∗ (0.019) (0.041) −0.417∗∗∗−0.156 (0.036) (0.142) −0.403∗∗∗−0.153 (0.036) (0.143) 0.017 (0.033) −0.033∗∗∗−0.067∗∗∗ (0.003) (0.018) (6) IVC −0.037∗∗∗−0.070∗∗∗ (0.003) (0.018) (5) OLS 0.213∗∗∗ 1.900∗∗ (0.023) (0.868) (4) IVC 0.207∗∗∗ 1.788∗∗ (0.023) (0.855) (3) OLS (8) IVC 19,489 8.71 9.26 19,489 19,489 yes yes no 8.72 9.09 19,489 yes yes no 1.246∗∗∗ 1.057∗∗∗ (0.069) (0.120) 1.259∗∗∗ 1.084∗∗∗ (0.072) (0.112) yes yes no 0.428∗∗∗ 0.479∗∗∗ (0.023) (0.036) 0.414∗∗∗ 0.513∗∗∗ (0.023) (0.052) yes yes no −0.101∗∗∗ 0.051 (0.024) (0.081) −0.036 (0.064) −0.013 (0.043) −0.115∗∗∗ 0.077 (0.024) (0.092) 0.001 (0.043) 0.026 (0.029) −0.501∗∗∗−0.271∗∗ (0.034) (0.125) −0.026∗∗∗−0.057∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.017) −0.107∗∗∗−0.182∗∗∗ (0.019) (0.043) −0.065 (0.070) (10) IVC 0.178∗∗∗ 1.819∗∗ (0.022) (0.831) (9) OLS −0.139∗∗∗−0.258∗∗∗ (0.019) (0.058) 0.001 (0.044) 0.165∗∗∗ 1.890∗∗ (0.022) (0.796) (7) OLS 1.872∗∗ (0.881) (12) IVC −0.057 (0.039) −0.089∗∗ (0.043) 0.123 (0.088) 0.043 (0.092) 19,489 yes no yes 7.73 8.19 19,489 yes no yes 0.769∗∗∗ 0.830∗∗∗ (0.082) (0.104) 0.320∗∗∗ 0.294∗∗∗ (0.030) (0.039) −0.052∗ (0.030) −0.034 (0.026) 0.081 (0.054) 0.107 (0.070) −0.422∗∗∗ −0.214∗ (0.043) (0.115) −0.026∗∗∗ −0.044∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.011) 0.061∗∗ (0.029) (11) OLS Notes: All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the village level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income represents total household income excluding agriculture expressed in per adult equivalent terms. Grid connection is instrumented using the district deviation from the national density of transmission cables per squared kilometer. Hindu, Home and Livestock are dummy variables. Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill are occupations estimated with respect to a benchmark corresponding to any kind of home based activities, including students and unemployed. F-stat first stage K-P F-stat (weak ident) Observations Year F.E. Village F.E. Household F.E. High Skill Low Skill Agriculture Livestock Home Hindu Children Size Grid connection IVC OLS Dependent variable: Log of income per adult equivalent Table 7: Effect of a grid connection on income instrument: density of transmission cables 21 17,282 Observations 17,282 282.34 0.000 17,282 yes yes 321.72 0.000 17,282 yes yes 0.020 (0.035) −0.038 (0.047) −0.038 (0.048) 17,282 yes yes 322.27 0.000 17,282 yes yes −0.147∗∗∗−0.140∗∗∗ (0.020) (0.019) 0.026 (0.035) 0.028 (0.036) (8) IVL 17,207 17,207 293.38 0.000 17,207 yes yes 1.227∗∗∗ (0.072) 1.241∗∗∗ 1.212∗∗∗ (0.075) (0.071) yes yes 0.424∗∗∗ (0.024) 0.394∗∗∗ 0.369∗∗∗ (0.025) (0.024) yes yes −0.111∗∗∗ (0.025) −0.136∗∗∗−0.158∗∗∗ (0.026) (0.025) 0.018 (0.047) −0.096∗∗∗ (0.019) 0.020 (0.048) 0.030 (0.033) −2.095 (1.419) −0.023∗∗∗ (0.004) 0.189∗∗∗ (0.023) (9) OLS −0.134∗∗∗−0.131∗∗∗ (0.019) (0.019) 0.024 (0.049) 0.176∗∗∗ 1.400∗∗∗ (0.023) (0.061) (7) OLS 317.55 0.000 17,207 yes yes 1.192∗∗∗ (0.068) 0.395∗∗∗ (0.023) −0.134∗∗∗ (0.024) −0.092∗∗∗ (0.018) 0.016 (0.047) 0.030 (0.032) −2.120∗ (1.261) −0.024∗∗∗ (0.004) 1.411∗∗∗ (0.057) (10) IVL Notes: All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the village level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income represents total household income excluding agriculture expressed in per adult equivalent terms. Grid connection is instrumented using the district-level variation (standard deviation) in land elevation. The first stage is modelled in a non-linear way using a probit estimation. Hindu, Home and Livestock are dummy variables. Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill are occupations estimated with respect to a benchmark corresponding to any kind of home based activities, including students and unemployed. Wald chi2 first stage Wald p-value yes yes Year F.E. Village F.E. High Skill Low Skill Agriculture Livestock Home yes yes 0.021 (0.036) Hindu −1.711 (1.435) −1.622 (1.580) −1.641 (1.445) −1.547 (1.586) Size Grid connection Children (6) IVL −0.031∗∗∗−0.032∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.004) (5) OLS −0.034∗∗∗−0.035∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.004) (4) IVL 0.225∗∗∗ 1.493∗∗∗ (0.024) (0.060) (3) OLS 0.219∗∗∗ 1.491∗∗∗ (0.024) (0.060) (2) (1) 0.192∗∗∗ 1.457∗∗∗ (0.024) (0.065) IVL OLS Dependent variable: Log of income per adult equivalent Table 8: Effect of a grid connection on income instrument: district level variation in land elevation Given that electrification rates increased by 16 percentage points between 1994 and 2005, these results imply that non-agricultural household incomes increased by 22 to 29 percent over this 11-year period as a result of increased access to electricity ((1.4)(0.16) to (1.89)(0.16)). A household moving from no electricity to having grid access, experiences an annual increase in income of 2.5%. However, this result only shows the impact of moving from no electricity to some connection, with no assumption on the quality of electricity supply. 4.2 Intensive Margin: Quality of Electricity Supply Table 9 shows the impact of mean quality of electricity supply on income. The results for OLS and IV estimations are reported, with transmission cable density as instrument. In an alternative specification, both the land elevation and transmission cable density were used as instruments. In all specifications standard errors are robust and clustered at the village level, and all specifications contain village and year fixed effects. Columns (1) to (3) include only household composition controls, and columns (4) to (6) include all household-level controls. The IV estimation results show cable density as the single IV (in columns 2 and 5) and results for both IVs are reported in columns 3 and 6. Columns (7) and (8) report results for OLS and single IV using household fixed effects instead of village fixed effects. The coefficient on column (5), implies that the income of an household whose quality of supply increases from 0 to 1 goes up by a factor of 2.6. The results suggest that OLS significantly underestimates the impact of electrification, implying that households who received an improved quality of electricity supply between 1994 and 2005 are living in under-performing areas with slower growth and economic improvement rates. This phenomenon is observed also in Dinkelman (2012) and in Lipscomb et al. (2013). From Table 2, we know that the quality of supply improved by 32 percentage points on average across the country between 1994 and 2005. These numbers imply that household non-agricultural incomes increased by roughly 85% percent over this 11-year period as a result of increased quality of power supply (2.649)(0.32). This suggests that the annual improvement attributable to improvements in quality of power supply is roughly 7.8%. The data on the quality of power supply has some missing values at the household level, which can lead to biased estimates if non-reporting households have common characteristics correlated with income or electrification. To check if this is affecting our results, the same model is also estimated using an aggregated quality measure at the village level and attributing the average quality to all households living in the village. The magnitude and the significance of coefficients are almost identical to the main results, instrument, but not presented for brevity. 22 implying that the missing data does not pose a problem in identifying the coefficient.17 Table 9: Effect of quality of electricity supply at the household level on household income Dependent variable: Log of income per adult equivalent Quality OLS IVC IVC+L OLS IVC IVC+L OLS IVC (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) 0.185∗∗∗ 2.733∗ (0.037) (1.471) 2.751∗ (1.429) 0.163∗∗∗ 2.649∗ (0.036) (1.437) 2.615∗ (1.376) 0.130∗∗∗ (0.047) 2.642∗ (1.423) Size −0.035∗∗∗−0.055∗∗∗ −0.055∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.013) (0.013) −0.023∗∗∗−0.041∗∗∗ −0.041∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.012) (0.012) −0.023∗∗∗ (0.005) −0.035∗∗∗ (0.011) Children −0.461∗∗∗−0.197 (0.042) (0.164) −0.561∗∗∗−0.316∗∗ −0.319∗∗ (0.041) (0.154) (0.148) −0.440∗∗∗ (0.052) −0.207 (0.152) Hindu 0.064 (0.048) 0.037 (0.055) −0.196 (0.160) 0.037 (0.055) Home 0.058 (0.042) 0.037 (0.049) 0.037 (0.048) 0.200∗ (0.103) 0.300∗∗ (0.135) 0.054 (0.058) 0.002 (0.074) 0.003 (0.073) 0.167∗∗ (0.071) 0.070 (0.115) Livestock −0.115∗∗∗−0.213∗∗∗ −0.212∗∗∗ (0.022) (0.063) (0.061) −0.037 (0.032) −0.136∗ (0.070) Agriculture −0.140∗∗∗−0.087∗ (0.029) (0.048) −0.086∗∗ (0.036) −0.145∗∗ (0.058) −0.088∗ (0.047) Low Skill 0.421∗∗∗ 0.414∗∗∗ 0.414∗∗∗ (0.028) (0.033) (0.033) 0.298∗∗∗ (0.035) 0.207∗∗∗ (0.067) High Skill 1.263∗∗∗ 1.142∗∗∗ 1.143∗∗∗ (0.074) (0.116) (0.114) 0.816∗∗∗ (0.090) 0.861∗∗∗ (0.131) Year F.E. Village F.E. Household F.E. Observations F-stat first stage K-P F-stat (weak ident) yes yes no yes yes no yes yes no yes yes no yes yes no yes yes no yes no yes yes no yes 12,652 12,652 12,652 12,605 12,605 12,605 12,605 12,605 4.90 5.19 5.71 2.92 5.07 5.4 5.96 3.07 5.02 5.61 Notes: All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the village level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income represents total household income excluding agriculture expressed in per adult equivalent terms. Instruments used are density of transmission cables (IVC ) and both the cable density and variation in land elevation (IVC+L ). Hindu, Home and Livestock are dummy variables. Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill are occupations estimated with respect to a benchmark corresponding to any kind of home based activities, including students and unemployed. The Quality takes value 0 for no electricity, 1 for high quality electricity supply and 0.5 for low quality electricity supply. The threshold for high quality power supply in 2005 is fixed at an average of 18 hours of power per day. In order to better understand the functional relationship between power quality and household income, we run a kernel-weighted local regression of household income on the predicted average quality of electricity received by the household obtained from the first stage. The results, presented in Figure 5, show that there is a linear and monotonic relationship, with high income households receiving higher quality of electricity, where the quality is measured by the number of hours of electricity received per day. Starting from no grid connection, the first five hours of electricity exhibit high marginal returns. Even if electrification is provided only for a few hours a day, the initial access to electricity is associated with higher incomes. Between 5 and 20 hours per day, incomes roughly stay 17 The results are presented in Table A.2 23 constant, but increase again beyond 20 hours of supply. That is, at very high levels of quality, marginal returns are high. Figure 5: Household income as a function of daily electricity supply, 2005 9.5 10 ln(income) Log of income 10.5 11 ln(income) 11 10.5 9.5 0 1 5 10 15 20 25 Predicted kernel 0 = epanechnikov, hours degree = 0, bandwidth = 1.27, pwidth = 1.91 0 5 10 15 Predicted hours kernel = epanechnikov, degree = 0, bandwidth = 1.27, pwidth = 1.91 Predicted hours 20 25 Note: Kernel weighted polynomial regression with 95% confidence band. This implies that the impact of electrification on households cannot be considered independently of the intensive margin. While the initial connection is important in the sense that it induces reallocation of labor and capital within the household, the same magnitude of impact can be observed at the other end of the scale. Starting from a grid connection, the impact of moving from low quality to high quality electricity can be as large as the initial connection. This highlights the importance of providing a high quality supply of power, as the potential benefits of electricity are not completely realized by just providing a grid connection and low quality power. The slope of the smoothed curve seems to change at about 20 hours per day. Recall our choice of 18 hours a day as the threshold for high quality. In order to assess whether or not these results are robust to this choice, the main model is estimated with 16 and 20 hours as thresholds for high quality power supply. Reducing the threshold to 16 hours per day does not affect the results. However, increasing the threshold to 20 hours 24 increases the magnitudes of the coefficient to 3.4, indicating that the impact of quality is not constant across the quality spectrum. The quality of power supply may be higher in relatively urbanized areas due to a higher number of power plants or higher investments in power transmission. We reestimate the model by excluding the districts with ten largest cities as well as their neighboring districts, as in section 4.1. The results suggest that the coefficients of interest, on Quality generally have the same magnitude and the same statistical significance as in the whole sample estimation.18 4.3 District Level Analysis The above analysis identifies the impact of electrification at the household level controlling for village effects and household characteristics. This specification can potentially yield biased results if there are unobserved factors that drive both electrification outcomes and household income. For this reason, the model is also estimated by aggregating the outcomes to the district level using sampling weights.19 The variables for electrification outcomes are (i) grid connection rate and (ii) average quality of power within the district. This model is estimated using district fixed effects to account for time-invariant factors across districts, and year fixed effects to account for changes that are common to all districts. The results are presented in Table 10. The OLS specification yields insignificant results although the magnitude is similar to those reported earlier. The instrumentation of electrification with density of transmission cables yields significant and higher coefficients. Overall, the results are not altered by aggregating the data to the district level. Higher electrification rates and higher quality of power supply within districts increases the households’ non-agricultural income. It is possible that districts in relatively urbanized and industrial areas receive better electricity, and exhibit higher income growth due to their proximity to large cities where most economic activity takes place. As before, the model is also estimated by excluding urban centers, specifically districts containing the 10 largest cities and their neighboring districts. The results presented in Table 11 show that the results are robust to this change. This is likely due to the fact that the villages in our sample are located in remote areas with limited access to urban centers. 18 19 These results are presented in Table A.6 This can not be done at the village level as the location of villages is unknown. 25 Table 10: District level effects on income instrument: density of transmission cables Dependent variable: Log of district-level mean household income Grid connection Share of district electrification Quality OLS IVC OLS IVc (1) (2) (3) (4) 0.225 (0.193) 1.567∗∗ (0.613) District-level quality 0.147 (0.178) 2.219∗ (1.331) Year F.E. District F.E. yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes Observations 314 314 314 314 F-stat first stage K-P F-stat (weak ident) 8.443 6.632 5.416 3.547 Notes:All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are robust. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income represents the district-level average of total household income excluding agriculture expressed in per adult equivalent terms. The Share of district electrification and the District-level quality are instrumented using the density of cables. Table 11: District level analysis (excluding urban centers) instrument: density of transmission cables Dependent variable: Log of district-level mean household income Grid connection Share of district electrification Quality OLS IVC OLS IVc (1) (2) (3) (4) 0.276 (0.203) 1.868∗∗∗ (0.718) District-level quality 0.263 (0.190) Year F.E. District F.E. yes yes Observations 276 F-stat first stage K-P F-stat (weak ident) yes yes yes yes 276 276 6.573 4.982 2.341∗ (1.401) yes yes 276 4.968 3.206 Notes:All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are robust. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income represents the district-level average of total household income excluding agriculture expressed in per adult equivalent terms. The Share of district electrification and the District-level quality are instrumented using the density of cables. 26 5 Potential Channels How does electrification increase non-agricultural income? While data restrictions do not allow for a detailed analysis of potential channels, it is possible to provide some insight by decomposing income into two components: (i) wage income that includes the formal and informal sectors, and (ii) business income, which includes family business, petty trades and other home-based activities. Increased productivity in agricultural production due to better access to electricity is likely to increase labor demand and wages. This can yield differential effects in wages if the labor mobility across sectors is imperfect, which may be the case if individuals in agriculture have little or no training in business, for example. An important issue in studying these channels is that the selection into wage or business activities is not likely to be random. It can be driven by factors such as land ownership, demographic structure within the household, or current occupation. In addition, the data consists of many households who do not report both types of incomes. The model is therefore estimated using a Tobit specification, which implies the existence of a latent variable Yit∗ , so that the income we observe, Yit , is given by ( Yit = Yit∗ 0 if Yit∗ > 0 if Yit∗ ≤ 0 (3) We use the transmission cable density and variation in land elevation as instruments for electrification.20 The results are presented in Table 12. The estimated coefficient represents the effect of electrification on the latent variable, and so it incorporates the mechanisms that cause households to move in and out of these activities. These results suggest that receiving electricity leads to an increase in wage incomes but also a significant reduction in business incomes. This duality can be explained by a model with immobile labor, and perfect mobility of other factors of production. A disproportional increase in agricultural productivity would move factors of production into agriculture, increasing wages but reducing the returns to business activities. Alternatively, individuals may be allocating more labor hours toward wage activities, and not in the ownership of businesses. In this case, mobility of labor would equalize wages across activities, but would have differential effects on earnings through changes in labor supply. In both scenarios, the earnings through wages will increase but earnings through business income may decrease. Similar results hold for the quality of power supply. The higher quality of power supply within village increases wage income, but again reduces business income. Again, 20 OLS results and the estimation with only the variation in land elevation instrument yields similar results, but are not presented here. 27 the mechanisms driving this result may work through wages or labor supply, which we are unable to identify due to lack of better data. Table 12: Effect of grid connection and quality of electricity supply on wages and business income Dependent variable: Log of income per adult equivalent Effect of grid connection Wage and salary income Grid connection Effect of quality of supply Business income Wage and salary income Business income IVC IVC+L IVC IVC+L IVC IVC+L IVC IVC+L (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) −8.342∗ (4.630) −6.094 (4.075) 1.539∗∗∗ 1.578∗∗∗ (0.573) (0.536) 1.697∗∗∗ 1.697∗∗∗ (0.497) (0.497) Village level Quality −9.195∗∗ (4.634) −9.195∗∗ (4.634) −0.013 (0.011) −0.014 (0.011) 0.248∗∗∗ 0.205∗∗ (0.094) (0.083) 0.016∗∗∗ 0.016∗∗∗ (0.002) (0.002) 0.090∗∗∗ (0.021) 0.090∗∗∗ (0.021) Children 0.010 (0.089) 0.016 (0.085) −2.089∗∗∗ −1.773∗∗∗ (0.732) (0.654) −0.194∗∗∗ −0.194∗∗∗ (0.031) (0.031) −0.976∗∗∗ (0.291) −0.976∗∗∗ (0.291) Hindu 0.019 (0.036) 0.018 (0.036) −0.438 (0.282) −0.491∗ (0.267) −0.639∗∗∗ (0.238) −0.639∗∗∗ (0.238) Home −0.089 (0.054) −0.090∗ (0.055) 0.887∗ (0.455) 0.819∗ (0.432) Livestock −0.211∗∗∗ −0.213∗∗∗ (0.033) (0.032) 0.757∗∗∗ 0.657∗∗∗ (0.271) (0.247) Agriculture 1.008∗∗∗ 1.011∗∗∗ (0.057) (0.054) Low Skill High Skill Size 0.058∗∗ (0.026) −0.032 (0.040) 0.058∗∗ (0.026) −0.032 (0.040) 0.606 (0.394) 0.606 (0.394) −0.168∗∗∗ −0.168∗∗∗ (0.018) (0.018) 0.517∗∗∗ (0.172) 0.517∗∗∗ (0.172) −7.047∗∗∗ −6.842∗∗∗ (0.680) (0.627) 0.868∗∗∗ 0.868∗∗∗ (0.019) (0.019) −6.304∗∗∗ (0.455) −6.304∗∗∗ (0.455) 1.085∗∗∗ 1.086∗∗∗ (0.030) (0.030) −4.253∗∗∗ −4.185∗∗∗ (0.375) (0.354) 1.034∗∗∗ 1.034∗∗∗ (0.020) (0.020) −3.990∗∗∗ (0.308) −3.990∗∗∗ (0.308) 0.954∗∗∗ 0.949∗∗∗ (0.099) (0.097) −1.131 (0.774) 1.123∗∗∗ 1.123∗∗∗ (0.056) (0.056) −2.059∗∗∗ (0.503) −2.059∗∗∗ (0.503) −1.399∗∗ (0.712) Year F.E. Village F.E. yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes Observations 17,217 17,217 17,217 17,217 17,217 17,217 17,217 17,217 Wald chi2 first stage Wald p-value 15.61 0.000 19.03 0.000 5.36 0.021 3.65 0.056 13.47 0.000 13.47 0.000 4.71 0.029 4.71 0.029 Notes: All estimations are tobit IV specifications, performed using the two steps methodology. All specifications contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are robust. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income corresponds to the total household income coming respectively from wage and salary activities or business activities and is computed in per adult equivalent terms. Electrification and the quality are instrumented using the density of transmission cables (IVC ) and a combination of the normalized density of transmission cables and the district level variation in land elevation (IVC+L ). Hindu, Home and Livestock are dummy variables. Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill are occupations estimated with respect to a benchmark corresponding to any kind of home based activities, including students and unemployed. The Village level quality takes value 0 for no electricity, 1 for high quality electricity supply and 0.5 for low quality electricity supply. 6 Concluding Remarks Previous studies of the effect of electrification have focused on the extensive margin. In this paper we examine the effect of a grid connection as well as the quality of power supply on household income in India. We use a nationally representative dataset to show that the quality of electricity supply may be as important as connecting to the grid. A 28 grid connection increases non-agricultural incomes of rural households by about 20-30 percent during the study period (1994-2005). However, higher quality of electricity (in terms of fewer outages and more hours per day) increased non-ag incomes by about 85 percent in the study period. This is equivalent to an income growth of about 8 percent per year. The result show that returns from electricity are high for the first few hours of supply, and when the supply is close to the maximum 24 hours. On the other hand, when average power supply is within a large middle band (5-20 hours a day), returns to household income are relatively flat. From a policy point of view, this suggests that while a grid connection brings high benefits at low levels of quality, further increases in supply bring no increased benefits unless the supply is of very high quality. Our results suggest that policies that aim to provide reliable electricity to households may bring about significant economic benefits. These estimates can be used to perform benefit-cost analysis for infrastructure improvements both at the extensive and intensive margins. References [1] The OECD List of Social Indicators. OECD, Paris, 1982. [2] World Energy Assessment: Energy and the Challenge of Sustainability. United Nations Development Program (UNDP), New York, 2000. [3] World Energy Outlook 2011. International Energy Agency, 2011. [4] J.D. Angrist. Lifetime Earnings and the Vietnam Era Draft Lottery: Evidence from Social Security Administrative Records. American Economic Review, 80(3):313–36, June 1990. [5] J.D. Angrist. Estimating the Labor Market Impact of Voluntary Military Service Using Social Security Data on Military Applicants. Econometrica, 66(2):249–288, March 1998. [6] D.A. Aschauer. Is Public Expenditure Productive? 23(2):177–200, March 1989. Journal of Monetary Economics, [7] P. Balachandra. Dynamics of Rural Energy Access in India: An Assessment. Energy, 36(9):5556 – 5567, 2011. [8] G. Bensch, J. Kluve, and J. Peters. Rural Electrification in Rwanda - An Impact Assessment Using Matching Techniques. Ruhr Ecnomic Papers 231, RUHR, December 2010. [9] A. Bhide and C. Rodriguez Monroy. Energy Poverty: A Special Focus on Energy Poverty in India and Renewable Energy Technologies. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 15(2):1057 – 1066, 2011. 29 [10] M.H. Brown and R.P. Sedano. Electricity Transmission, A Primer. National Council on Electricity Policy, June 2004. [11] Taryn Dinkelman. The Effects of Rural Electrification on Employment: New Evidence from South Africa. American Economic Review, 101(7):3078–3108, December 2011. [12] E. Duflo and R. Pande. Dams. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2):601–646, 05 2007. [13] T. Garcia-Mila and T.J. McGuire. The Contribution of Publicly Provided Inputs to States’ Economies. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 22(2):229–41, June 1992. [14] D. Holtz-Eakin. State-Specific Estimates of State and Local Government Capital. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 23(2):185–209, April 1993. [15] G.W. Imbens and J.D. Angrist. Identification and Estimation of Local Average Treatment Effects. Econometrica, 62(2):467–75, March 1994. [16] S.R. Khandker, D.F. Barnes, and H.A. Samad. Welfare Implications of Rural Electrification, A Case Study for Bangladesh. Policy Research Working Paper 4859, World Bank, March 2009a. [17] S.R. Khandker, D.F. Barnes, and H.A. Samad. Energy Poverty in Rural and Urban India. are the Energy Poor also Income Poor? Policy Research Working Paper 5463, World Bank, November 2010. [18] S.R. Khandker, D.F. Barnes, H.A. Samad, and N.H. Minh. Welfare Implications of Rural Electrification, Evidence from Vietnam. Policy Research Working Paper 5057, World Bank, September 2009b. [19] M. Lipscomb, A.M. Mobarak, and T. Barham. Development Effects of Electrification: Evidence from the Geologic Placement of Hydropower Plants in Brazil. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, April 2013. [20] V. Modi. Improving Electricity Services in Rural India. Working Paper 30, Center on Globalization and Sustainable Development, The Earth Institute at Columbia University, December 2005. [21] H. Oda and Y. Tsujita. The Determinants of Rural Electrification: The Case of Bihar, India. Energy Policy, 39(6):3086–3095, June 2011. [22] Directorate of Census Office of the Registrar General, editor. Census of India 2001. Government of India, New Delhi, India, 2001. [23] L.-H. Roller and L. Waverman. Telecommunications Infrastructure and Economic Development: A Simultaneous Approach. American Economic Review, 91(4):909–923, September 2001. 30 [24] J.P. Rud. Electricity Provision and Industrial Development: Evidence from India. Journal of Development Economics, 97(2):352 – 367, 2012. [25] USGS. Global Land Cover Facility (SRTM). In Shuttle Radar Topography Mission. Global Land Cover Facility, University of Maryland, 2004. [26] H. Yang. Overview of the Chinese Electricity Industry and its Current Uses. Working Paper 0617, CWPE, February 2006. 31 A Appendix Tables Table A.1: Occupational Categories # 1 New Group agriculture 2 low skill 1994 Group cultivation, allied agricultural activities, agricultural wage labor, cattle tending artisan/independent work, petty shop/other small business, organized business/trade, domestic servant, salaried employment/pension, nonagricultural wage labor, 3 high skill qualified profession/not classified 4 other own household work, student, family work, child (<15), living on income from rent, int, div, unemployed, any other, not willing to work, not specified 32 2005 Group farm manager, cultivator, other farmers, ag labor, plantation lab, other farm money lenders, house keepers, maids, sweepers, launderers, elected officials, govt officials, clerical supe, village officials, clerical nec, typist, book-keepers, computing op, transp/commun supe, transp conductors, mail distributor, telephone op, shopkeepers, manuf agents, technical sales, sales, shop, FIRE sales, salesa, nec, hotel/restaurant, cooks/waiters, police, service nec, barbers, tanners, tailors, electrical, plumbers/welders, jewellery, shoe makers, carpenters, stone cutters, construction, forestry, hunters, fishermen, miners, metal workers, wood/paper, chemical, textile, foods, tobacco, machine tool op, assemblers, cinema op, potters, rubber/plastic, paper, printing, painters, production nec, boilermen, loaders, drivers, labour nec physical sci tech, engineers, eng tech, air/ship officer, life sciantists, life science tech, physicians, nursing, other scientific, statisticians, economists, accountants, social scientists, lawyers, teachers, journalists, mgr whsl/retail, mgr finance, mgr manf, mgr transp/commun, mgr service, managerial nec n/a Table A.2: Effect of quality of electricity supply – Village Level Dependent variable: Log of income per adult equivalent Village level quality OLS IVC IVC+L OLS IVC IVC+L OLS IVC (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) 0.229∗∗∗ 1.965∗ (0.084) (1.123) 1.966∗ (1.123) 0.232∗∗∗ 2.065∗ (0.084) (1.121) 2.066∗ (1.121) 0.235∗∗∗ (0.082) 2.062∗ (1.111) Size −0.032∗∗∗−0.033∗∗∗ −0.033∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) −0.022∗∗∗−0.023∗∗∗ −0.023∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) −0.025∗∗∗ (0.005) −0.026∗∗∗ (0.005) Children −0.461∗∗∗−0.446∗∗∗ −0.446∗∗∗ (0.037) (0.039) (0.039) −0.551∗∗∗−0.536∗∗∗ −0.536∗∗∗ (0.035) (0.037) (0.037) −0.460∗∗∗ (0.045) −0.436∗∗∗ (0.051) Hindu 0.032 (0.037) 0.033 (0.036) 0.033 (0.036) Home 0.040 (0.034) 0.043 (0.033) 0.043 (0.033) 0.171∗∗ (0.076) 0.178∗∗ (0.075) 0.025 (0.048) 0.039 (0.058) 0.039 (0.058) 0.122∗∗ (0.059) 0.149 (0.093) Livestock −0.099∗∗∗−0.127∗∗∗ −0.127∗∗∗ (0.019) (0.026) (0.026) −0.044∗ (0.026) −0.096∗∗ (0.043) Agriculture −0.140∗∗∗−0.142∗∗∗ −0.142∗∗∗ (0.026) (0.029) (0.029) −0.073∗∗ (0.032) −0.073∗ (0.038) Low Skill 0.404∗∗∗ 0.399∗∗∗ 0.399∗∗∗ (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) 0.305∗∗∗ (0.032) 0.297∗∗∗ (0.034) High Skill 1.247∗∗∗ 1.230∗∗∗ 1.230∗∗∗ (0.073) (0.075) (0.075) 0.755∗∗∗ (0.085) 0.726∗∗∗ (0.094) Year F.E. Village F.E. Household F.E. Observations F-stat first stage K-P F-stat (weak ident) yes yes no yes yes no yes yes no yes yes no yes yes no yes yes no yes no yes yes no yes 17,302 17,302 17,302 17,226 17,226 17,226 17,226 17,226 6.53 6.96 7.21 3.88 6.54 6.99 8.63 4.66 6.54 7.25 Notes: All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the village level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income represents total household income excluding agriculture expressed in per adult equivalent terms. Instruments used are density of transmission cables (IVC ) and both the cable density and variation in land elevation (IVC+L ). Hindu, Home and Livestock are dummy variables. Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill are occupations estimated with respect to a benchmark corresponding to any kind of home based activities, including students and unemployed. The Village level quality takes value 0 for no electricity, 1 for high quality electricity supply and 0.5 for low quality electricity supply. The threshold for high quality power supply in 2005 is fixed at an average of 18 hours of power per day. 33 Table A.3: Effect of quality of electricity supply - 16 hour threshold Dependent variable: Log of income per adult equivalent Quality OLS IVC IVC+L OLS IVC IVC+L (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) 0.176∗∗∗ 2.636∗ (0.036) (1.384) 2.635∗ (1.381) 0.151∗∗∗ 2.538∗ (0.035) (1.351) 2.535∗ (1.346) Size −0.032∗∗∗−0.053∗∗∗ −0.053∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.013) (0.013) −0.020∗∗∗−0.039∗∗∗ −0.038∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.012) (0.012) Children −1.699 (1.479) −0.413 (1.317) −0.414 (1.316) −2.206∗ (1.318) −0.994 (1.172) −0.995 (1.170) 0.055 (0.047) 0.022 (0.055) 0.022 (0.055) 0.047 (0.042) 0.019 (0.049) 0.019 (0.049) 0.058 (0.058) 0.021 (0.070) 0.021 (0.070) Hindu Home Livestock −0.109∗∗∗−0.197∗∗∗ −0.197∗∗∗ (0.022) (0.057) (0.057) Agriculture −0.129∗∗∗−0.078∗ (0.029) (0.047) −0.078∗ (0.047) Low Skill 0.436∗∗∗ 0.427∗∗∗ 0.427∗∗∗ (0.028) (0.033) (0.033) High Skill 1.253∗∗∗ 1.115∗∗∗ 1.115∗∗∗ (0.074) (0.119) (0.119) Year F.E. Village F.E. yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes Observations 12,632 12,632 12,632 12,585 12,585 12,585 5.28 5.75 2.68 2.92 5.53 6.01 2.82 3.07 F-stat first stage K-P F-stat (weak ident) Notes: The threshold for high quality of supply in 2005 is fixed at an average of 16 hours of power per day. All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the village level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income corresponds to the total household income excluding income coming from agricultural activities and is computed in per adult equivalent terms. The Quality is instrumented using the district deviation from the normalized density of transmission cables (IVC ) and with the density of transmission cables and the district-level variation in land elevation (IVC+L ). Hindu, Home and Livestock are dummy variables. Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill are occupations estimated with respect to a benchmark corresponding to any kind of home based activities, including students and unemployed. The Quality takes value 0 for no electricity, 1 for high quality electricity supply and 0.5 for low quality electricity supply. 34 Table A.4: Effect of quality of electricity supply - 20 hour threshold Dependent variable: Log of income per adult equivalent Quality OLS IVC IVC+L OLS IVC IVC+L (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) 0.233∗∗∗ 3.478∗ (0.038) (2.055) 3.379∗ (1.981) 0.201∗∗∗ 3.399∗ (0.036) (2.051) 3.350∗ (1.988) Size −0.032∗∗∗−0.059∗∗∗ −0.058∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.018) (0.018) −0.020∗∗∗−0.045∗∗ −0.045∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.017) (0.017) Children −1.688 (1.439) −0.187 (1.091) −0.233 (1.068) −2.201∗ (1.287) −0.721 (1.061) −0.744 (1.036) 0.056 (0.047) 0.027 (0.059) 0.028 (0.058) 0.049 (0.041) 0.025 (0.055) 0.026 (0.054) 0.054 (0.058) 0.033 (0.076) 0.034 (0.075) Hindu Home Livestock −0.114∗∗∗−0.244∗∗∗ −0.242∗∗∗ (0.022) (0.088) (0.086) Agriculture −0.127∗∗∗−0.107∗∗∗ −0.107∗∗∗ (0.029) (0.040) (0.040) Low Skill 0.437∗∗∗ 0.386∗∗∗ 0.387∗∗∗ (0.028) (0.046) (0.045) High Skill 1.251∗∗∗ 0.991∗∗∗ 0.995∗∗∗ (0.074) (0.200) (0.196) Year F.E. Village F.E. yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes Observations 12,632 12,632 12,632 12,585 12,585 12,585 3.36 3.72 1.78 1.98 3.43 3.80 1.85 2.07 F-stat first stage K-P F-stat (weak ident) Notes: The threshold for high quality of supply in 2005 is fixed at an average of 20 hours of power per day. All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the village level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income corresponds to the total household income excluding income coming from agricultural activities and is computed in per adult equivalent terms. The Quality is instrumented using the district deviation from the normalized density of transmission cables (IVC ) and with the density of transmission cables and the district-level variation in land elevation (IVC+L ). Hindu, Home and Livestock are dummy variables. Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill are occupations estimated with respect to a benchmark corresponding to any kind of home based activities, including students and unemployed. The Quality takes value 0 for no electricity, 1 for high quality electricity supply and 0.5 for low quality electricity supply. 35 36 17,038 yes yes no 6.62 6.91 17,038 yes yes no 0.176∗∗∗ 1.990∗∗ (0.025) (0.862) (2) (1) −0.054 (0.075) −0.023 (0.050) 17,038 yes yes no 6.76 6.94 17,038 yes yes no −0.031 (0.049) 0.024 (0.032) −0.034 (0.048) 17,038 yes yes no 6.60 6.77 17,038 yes yes no −0.146∗∗∗−0.234∗∗∗ (0.021) (0.049) −0.417∗∗∗−0.118 (0.038) (0.160) −0.405∗∗∗−0.119 (0.038) (0.160) 0.019 (0.032) −0.035∗∗∗−0.072∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.019) (6) IVC −0.038∗∗∗−0.075∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.020) (5) OLS 0.210∗∗∗ 2.082∗∗ (0.025) (0.933) (4) IVC 0.204∗∗∗ 1.946∗∗ (0.025) (0.910) (3) OLS (8) IVC 16,965 7.01 7.45 16,965 16,965 yes yes no 7.21 7.53 16,965 yes yes no 1.227∗∗∗ 0.979∗∗∗ (0.074) (0.144) 1.239∗∗∗ 1.003∗∗∗ (0.077) (0.135) yes yes no 0.429∗∗∗ 0.490∗∗∗ (0.024) (0.041) 0.413∗∗∗ 0.533∗∗∗ (0.025) (0.061) yes yes no −0.090∗∗∗ 0.071 (0.026) (0.084) −0.011 (0.075) −0.031 (0.048) −0.107∗∗∗ 0.101 (0.027) (0.098) 0.024 (0.049) 0.025 (0.029) −0.505∗∗∗−0.239∗ (0.036) (0.142) −0.027∗∗∗−0.062∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.018) −0.099∗∗∗−0.195∗∗∗ (0.020) (0.051) −0.051 (0.083) (10) IVC 0.178∗∗∗ 2.016∗∗ (0.024) (0.904) (9) OLS −0.131∗∗∗−0.276∗∗∗ (0.020) (0.069) 0.020 (0.050) 0.165∗∗∗ 2.108∗∗ (0.024) (0.883) (7) OLS 2.088∗∗ (0.983) (12) IVC −0.066 (0.043) 16,965 yes no yes 6.17 6.55 16,965 yes no yes 0.721∗∗∗ 0.766∗∗∗ (0.086) (0.112) 0.316∗∗∗ 0.292∗∗∗ (0.031) (0.042) −0.062∗ (0.032) −0.107∗ (0.055) 0.125 (0.105) 0.097∗ (0.059) −0.027 (0.028) −0.007 (0.109) 0.107 (0.075) −0.428∗∗∗ −0.195 (0.045) (0.129) −0.026∗∗∗ −0.045∗∗∗ (0.005) (0.012) 0.061∗∗ (0.030) (11) OLS Notes: All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the village level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income represents total household income excluding agriculture expressed in per adult equivalent terms. Electrification is instrumented using the district deviation from the national density of transmission cables per squared kilometer. Hindu, Home and Livestock are dummy variables. Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill are occupations estimated with respect to a benchmark corresponding to any kind of home based activities, including students and unemployed. F-stat first stage K-P F-stat (weak ident) Observations Year F.E. Village F.E. Household F.E. High Skill Low Skill Agriculture Livestock Home Hindu Children Size Grid connection IVC OLS Dependent variable: Log of income per adult equivalent Table A.5: Effect of a grid connection on income (excluding urban centers) instrument: density of transmission cables Table A.6: Effect of quality of electricity supply at the household-level on household income (excluding urban centers) Dependent variable: Log of income per adult equivalent Quality Size Children Hindu OLS IVC IVC+L OLS IVC IVC+L OLS IVC (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) 0.188∗∗∗ 2.573∗ 2.567∗ (0.039) (1.376) (1.374) −0.036∗∗∗−0.057∗∗∗ −0.057∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.014) (0.014) −0.454∗∗∗−0.195 −0.196 (0.044) (0.165) (0.165) 0.084∗ 0.068 0.068 (0.045) (0.051) (0.051) 0.162∗∗∗ 2.536∗ 2.524∗ (0.037) (1.374) (1.369) −0.024∗∗∗−0.043∗∗∗ −0.043∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.013) (0.013) −0.561∗∗∗−0.313∗∗ −0.315∗∗ (0.043) (0.159) (0.158) 0.073∗ 0.061 0.061 (0.040) (0.047) (0.047) 0.085 0.063 0.063 (0.065) (0.076) (0.076) −0.111∗∗∗−0.221∗∗∗ −0.221∗∗∗ (0.024) (0.070) (0.069) −0.126∗∗∗−0.080∗ −0.081∗ (0.032) (0.048) (0.048) 0.420∗∗∗ 0.406∗∗∗ 0.406∗∗∗ (0.031) (0.036) (0.036) 1.239∗∗∗ 1.079∗∗∗ 1.080∗∗∗ (0.080) (0.134) (0.133) yes yes yes yes yes yes no no no Home Livestock Agriculture Low Skill High Skill Year F.E. Village F.E. Household F.E. Observations F-stat first stage K-P F-stat (weak ident) yes yes no yes yes no yes yes no 10,850 10,850 10,850 4.735 5.045 4.735 2.523 10,809 10,809 10,809 4.905 5.266 4.915 2.638 0.148∗∗∗ (0.049) −0.024∗∗∗ (0.005) −0.423∗∗∗ (0.056) 0.184 (0.115) 0.207∗∗∗ (0.077) −0.043 (0.035) −0.091∗∗ (0.039) 0.293∗∗∗ (0.038) 0.755∗∗∗ (0.095) yes no yes 10,809 2.499∗ (1.333) −0.036∗∗∗ (0.011) −0.202 (0.150) 0.270∗ (0.139) 0.130 (0.122) −0.170∗∗ (0.084) −0.150∗∗ (0.059) 0.196∗∗∗ (0.072) 0.745∗∗∗ (0.132) yes no yes 10,809 4.906 5.533 Notes: All estimations contain a constant. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the village level. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Income represents total household income excluding agriculture expressed in per adult equivalent terms. Instruments used are density of transmission cables (IVC ) and both the cable density and variation in land elevation (IVC+L ). Hindu, Home and Livestock are dummy variables. Agriculture, Low Skill and High Skill are occupations estimated with respect to a benchmark corresponding to any kind of home based activities, including students and unemployed. The Quality takes value 0 for no electricity, 1 for high quality electricity supply and 0.5 for low quality electricity supply. The threshold for high quality power supply in 2005 is fixed at an average of 18 hours of power per day. 37 B Appendix Figures Figure B.1: Indian transmission and rail networks Source: ESRI ArcGIS World package and geocommons. 38 Figure B.2: Indian transmission and road networks Source: ESRI ArcGIS World package and geocommons. 39 Figure B.3: Household Electrification Rate vs Mean Income by State, 2005 1 Andhra Bihar Gujarat Haryana Himachal Kerala Maharashtra, Madhya Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Uttar West Assam Jharkhand .Uttarakhand 0 Chhattisgarh S 1 .8 .6 .4 .2 8.6 8.8 9 9.2 9.4 9.6 State 2tate .2 Bengal Pradesh Nadu Pradesh percentage mean Pradesh Pradesh Goa income of electrified households State percentage of electrified households .2 .4 .6 .8 Himachal Pradesh Punjab Tamil Nadu Andhra Pradesh Gujarat Haryana Kerala Maharashtra, Goa Madhya Pradesh Chhattisgarh Uttarakhand Jharkhand Rajasthan Uttar Pradesh West Bengal Orissa 0 Bihar Assam 8.6 8.8 9 9.2 State mean income 9.4 9.6 1 Andhra Bihar Gujarat Haryana Himachal Kerala Maharashtra, Madhya Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Uttar West Assam Jharkhand .Uttarakhand 0 Chhattisgarh S 1 .8 .6 .4 .2 8.6 8.8 9 9.2 9.4 9.6 State 2tate .2 Bengal Pradesh Nadu Pradesh mean Pradesh Pradesh Goa power quality income Himachal Pradesh Kerala State mean power quality .4 .6 .8 Tamil Nadu Gujarat Andhra Pradesh Maharashtra, Goa Punjab Haryana Jharkhand Chhattisgarh Uttarakhand Madhya Pradesh Orissa .2 West Bengal Rajasthan Uttar Pradesh 0 Bihar Assam 8.6 8.8 9 9.2 State mean income Note: A linear fit to the scatter plot is shown. 40 9.4 9.6