History, Impacts and Regulation of Consumer Credit Winter, 2014 Mondays from 6:00 p.m. to 7:40 or 7:50 p.m. David Lander 314 345 4713 dal@greensfelder.com OFFICE HOURS: every couple of weeks from 5:00 to 5:50 p.m. Purpose of the Course: 1. Understanding how and why consumers borrow beyond their capacity to repay; 2. Understanding how and why lenders lend beyond the borrowers’ capacity to repay; 3. Deciding how to regulate consumer lending/borrowing against that backdrop Rules for the Course: Class Participation will count 25% of the grade; Missing three classes will reduce your grade by one level; Missing more than three classes will result in failure in the course; Excuses will only be considered if they affect three absences. Students who need accommodations because of a disability should contact the disability services coordinator for the School of Law, Shannon Stinebaugh Morse, Assistant Dean of Student Activities and Leadership. Dean Morse's office is in Room 1082 of Student Services suite and she can be reached by email at stinebsm@slu.edu or by phone 314977-2728. Confidentiality will be observed in all inquiries. Class 1 January 7, 2013 First Hours: Introduction: The Dilemma of Regulating Consumer Finance,Reducing the harm without reducing the benefits. Understanding the landscape: Second Hour: A Very Brief History of Consumer Credit in the United: Survey of Consumer Finances – Fed Three year study. Class 2: Credit Card Lending, Before and after the Crash; Class 3: Student Loans and Home Mortgages First Hour: Student Loans Second Hour: Home Mortgages: Part One Class 4: Home Mortgages: Part Two Class 5: Sub Prime Lending including Payday and Car Title Loans Predatory Lending Payday Car title Tax refund anticipation Other – housing –auto – credit cards Class 6: The Supply of dollars to lend and various surveys Class 7 : Understanding the micro and macro sociological, political and anthropological impacts of increased/decreased consumer debt/credit. Class 8: Understanding the micro and macro economic impacts of increased/decreased consumer debt/credit.: Class 9: Understanding consumer borrowing/lending from the behavioral economics or economic psychology points of view.; and intro to consumer finance issues; Who helps consumers in financial distress? Who trains those helpers? What are the goals? Class 10 Financial Distress Financial Literacy, Disclosure and Counseling of Consumers in Class 11 Price Controls Class 12 Prohibited Transactions and the Bureau Class 13 The ultimate consumer protection – the Bankruptcy Discharge Bankruptcy ; discharge of unsecured debt; treatment of secured debt . means test; chapter 13; nondischargability – student loans – credit cards Class 14 Consumer Credit around the World Exporting Consumer Credit around the world – or Not. Brazil, China, Canada HISTORY, IMPACTS AND REGULATION OF CONSUMER CREDIT- DEMAND AND SUPPLY Introduction to this book and this course 1. Understanding the landscape: The Dilemma of Regulating Consumer Finance; Reducing the harm without reducing the benefits. 2. A Very Brief History of Consumer Credit in the United States 3. Installment Debt and Auto Debt 4. Credit Cards 5. Student Loans 6. Debts Secured by the Borrower’s Home. 7. Sub Prime Loans 8. Surveys of Consumer Behavior, Finances and Sentiment 9. Sources of the Dollars that are lent 10. Economic Impacts of Consumer Finance – Micro and Macro 11. Sociological Impacts of Consumer Finance- Micro and Macro 12. Behavioral Economics 13. Introduction to Regulation of Consumer Finance and Financial Literacy Education, Disclosure Requirements and Distressed Debtor Counseling 14. . Price Control 15. Prohibitions 16. Bankruptcy – The Ultimate Consumer Regulation 17. Consumer Finance Around the World Required Reading: Course EBook (Years ago we used Credit Card Nation by Robert Manning but it became dated; then we used portions of Financing the American Dream by Calder, but it stops many years ago. Then two years ago we used Borrow by Louis Hyman which is excellent, but now we use these materials supplemented by the various readings. Most readings are short enough not to have a copyright problem; most longer readings consist of a cite to the web materials that are generally available to all for free. Please note that there are several longer readings which are long excerpts and may present copyright concerns. Introduction to the book and the course Every society struggles with its construct of rules regarding borrowing by and lending to consumers. As we will see if the door is open too widely there will likely be damaging consequences to consumers, to lenders and to the economy and society as a whole. If the door is not opened widely enough a different set of damaging consequences will likely occur. Many people think that one major cause of the crash of 2007 was that the door to consumer credit had been open too widely too long in the US. In the late 1990’s the regulators in South Korea decided to provide wide open credit card credit to borrowers without regard to credit history; the result was a short term boom for the economy and a short term happy buying sprees for many consumers; not long after the consumers became overwhelmed with debt and the lenders became overwhelmed with bad credit and the economy skidded to a halt because consumers shut down their buying. In Brazil in 2012 the government opened the door to auto financing in order to give a shot to the auto production and auto sales industries and shortly thereafter the economy and society suffered a reaction similar to that in Korea and the United States, although on a much smaller scale. If the door is open too narrowly in a country in which consumers wish to borrow then the economy will be less strong than it would otherwise be and the consumers will be unable to maintain a life style that they could afford. For example younger consumers might have to delay the purchase of a car or a house or a large appliance until later than necessary. Moreover, financial institutions will be less profitable and investors will receive lower returns on their investments. As we will see at the end of our study when we consider the consumer credit in various other countries, there are societies where consumers do not wish to borrow. Our focus will be ninety per cent on the US. In the last part of the course we will examine the various types of consumer credit regulations and the roles of lawyers but before we do that it is crucial to examine the history and impacts of consumer borrowing and consumer lending We begin with an overview of the course in order that can understand where each of the chapters fits into the overall scheme. We then proceed to a very brief history of consumer lending in the US; then to a look at several specific types of lending to understand how they developed and what they are; 1. installment lending such as car loans and furniture loans 2. credit card lending 3. student loans 4. home mortgages 5. subprime as a separate species, both tax refund antic, title loans payday and subprime types of car, home The author believes that we need to understand the impacts of more or less consumer lending and borrowing so we spend one class looking at the economic impact of consumer lending and borrowing, on individuals and their families as well as on the overall economy; then one class to look at the sociological impacts. We all know that some consumers make what turn out not to be wise decisions on borrowing; some borrow too much, some too little and some just right. We spend one class looking at how consumers make such decisions. All of this information forms our knowledge base as we consider how much and how little to regulate, and what types of regulation will do the most good and the least harm. Each type of regulation protects against certain vulnerabilities in the consumer or against certain harms in the financial offering. We will consider the role and efficacy of financial literacy education and disclosure information in combatting the unevenness of the relationship between borrower and lender and the lack of knowledge and information of some consumers. We next look at price controls, prohibiting certain financial products and finally we look at discharge of consumer debt in bankruptcy The last chapter provides a look at how consumers and lenders have acted and might act in various countries around the world including Canada, Brazil, South Africa, Indonesia, China, India, Turkey, Poland and Germany. We then consider what consumer regulatory regime might best fit each of those populations or cultures. Although our inquiry is mostly from the perspective of the borrower, it is necessary to understand the supply of funds to lend and the motives and techniques. To understand consumer borrowing in the 1990’s and early 2000’s it is essential to understand securitization and the pressure for higher returns. For that reason we will focus regularly on issues related to the supply of funds that the market is lending. Chapter 1 The Dilemma of Regulating Consumer Finance. Reducing the harm without reducing the benefits. Understanding the landscape: Welcome to your job as public policy maker in the office of the consumer credit regulator. Your test is to learn everything you need to know to determine the optimal regulatory scheme for consumer lending, then to decide how much and what kind of regulation is best. Your first assignment is to figure out what you need to know to decide how much and how to regulate consumer lending and consumer borrowing. These materials are intended to help you on your quest by providing you with: an understanding of how and why consumers borrow beyond their capacity to repay; an understanding how and why lenders lend beyond the borrowers’ capacity to repay; and a methodology for deciding how to regulate consumer lending/borrowing against that backdrop We begin by considering the opinions of four scholars of consumer borrowing behavior in the United States and who each have a different slant on the situation. opinion. As you read through the materials think about the following issues What do we need to know to decide how much and how to regulate consumer lending and consumer borrowing? To what extent does the regulation of consumer credit reduce the amount of credit or the availability of credit to selected populations? If so is that a reason for not regulating? Why do lenders lend? In his pioneering book Financing the American Dream, the author Lendol Calder asserts that there is something in the American character which pushes consumers to choose to borrow more than they can easily afford and then simply work harder to keep the house of cards from falling. He calls this a defining American value and hears American consumers happily singing “ I owe, I owe, it’s off to work I go. In her book, The Overspent American, Juliet Schor believes that American simply want to have luxuries so much that they overspend to purchase them. In our chapter on behavioral economics we will look more closely at the various theories behind the choices consumers make when they spend and borrow beyond the rational limits of what they can afford. Please consider these themes as you read an article that Ms. Warren wrote years ago. Mr. Wallace’s article was written when America was deciding whether to throw out the controls that had limited interest rates for a hundred years or more. There were many many pressures to take that action and his is the clearest explication of the value of keeping those limits. The Immoral Debtor 1995 or so Professor Elizabeth Warren Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA INTRODUCTION Every piece, of legislation is an answer, a solution, to a problem that Congress, has posed and then responded by changing some law. The answer may be right or wrong, too much or too little, but it is an answer nonetheless. The bankruptcy bill is no exception. On April 20,2005, when George W. Bush signed into law a bankruptcy bill that had been pending in Congress for eight years he declared that he was addressing “a problem.”2 Because the bill was written by credit industry lobbyists,3 shopped to their friends in Congress, and supported by tens of millions of dollars in lobbying and campaign contributions (including the president’s own single biggest contributor), it might easily be dismissed as just one more piece of highlyfocused, special interest legislation, an answer to nothing except payoff for big-dollar contributors. But that would be a mistake. The powerful financial industry that drove this bill defined a problem. Their supporters in Congress took up the call and agreed to make changes to the bankruptcy system that they claimed would answer that problem. The problem they described had substantial national resonance. It was plausible enough that it provided political cover for a large number of both Democrats and Republicans to support the bill. Despite the fact mat Senator Hatch’s own Utah constituents would be hit the hardest in the nation, he could tell a story that permitted him to support the bill. Despite the fact mat Senator Biden had overt presidential aspirations that he could advance only with the support of millions of middle class working people, he could tell a story that permitted him to support the bill. The list is long: traditional supporters of women faced down women’s groups; traditional supporters of minority groups faced down the Leadership Conference on Civil Rights; and traditional supporters of union workers, faced down union groups. Money may have been the unseen force, but money alone does not make it safe to vote contrary to the interests of constituents and supporters—unless there is a good cover story. In, the case of bankruptcy, many senators and representatives could ignore the groups they usually called on for help because they now had a powerful story to tell. They voted for the interests of credit card companies and subprime lenders, but they did so under the cloak of moral rectitude. The story is as simple as it is harsh: Middle class America is riddled with spendthrifts, irresponsible people consumed by appetites for goods they don’t need, people who think little of cost and who take their responsibilities to pay their debts lightly, people who file for bankruptcy rather than repay their lawful debts. The bankruptcy bill was more than a giveaway to the credit card companies; it was a public, moral judgment against those who go broke. The story isn’t about a few bad debtors. A few debtors could be snared by the existing version of 707(b). Indeed, if the problem were limited to a few people who stepped out of line, then the response would need to be sharply confined and pinpointed to the specific activities that signaled abuse. A story about a few bad debtors would not support the kind of wholesale reform that the credit industry wanted. Although the credit industry could be forced to admit from time to time that even their own inflated numbers about “can pay” bankruptcy filers were under 10 percent, the repeated language of both industry representatives and their political supporters was about irresponsibility, profligacy and immorality in vague, but powerful numbers. It was about untold numbers of people who routinely overspent with little care for the consequences. The bankruptcy bill was a way to strike back at the Immoral Debtors. It was an answer to the breakdown in the American culture that has produced record filings. By offering a harsh and punitive response, it attempts to meet immorality head-on, to fix the problem of irresponsibility and over-spending nationwide. The difficulty, of course, is that if the problem is misstated, then the solution is also misstated. If, in fact, families are filing for bankruptcy for reasons other than unrestrained profligacy, then a punitive solution may visit enormous pain on these families. Instead of being punished for their immorality, they may be punished for events beyond their control, for having relatives who had no money to bail them out in times of crises, or for plain old bad luck. Moreover, if the problem is misstated, then the statutory solution may have unanticipated effects that reverberate throughout the economy. The real problem goes unaddressed, while the proposed solution actually makes things worse. The Public Version of Why America Needs Bankruptcy Reform The story of American failure did not originate with the bankruptcy lobbyists. As American families have sunk deeper in debt, they have endured non-stop criticism from multiple quarters. To be sure, lobbyists and powerful politicians have set upon families in financial trouble, chiding them for their profligate ways. But economists and sociologists have added credibility to the story, describing families’ collective lust for goods they could easily forgo. The popular media echo the themes of irresponsibility. The accusations are sharp, the assertions are confident and unambiguous, and the tone of condemnation is unmistakable. Cornell University economist Robert Frank claims that America’s newfound “Luxury Fever” forces middle-class families “to finance their consumption increases largely by reduced savings and increased debt.” Documentary film maker John de Graaf and Duke Economics Professor Thomas Naylor explain in Affluenza: The All-Consuming Epidemic, “It’s as if we Americans, despite our intentions, suffer from some kind of Willpower Deficiency Syndrome, a breakdown in affluenza immunity.” They assert that Americans have a new character flaw—”the urge to splurge.” Economist Juliet Schor is often cited as documenting irresponsibility, as she explains that American families are buying “designer clothes, a microwave, restaurant meal, home and automobile air conditioning, and, of course, Michael Jordan’s ubiquitous athletic shoes, about which children and adults both display near-obsession. The popular press sounds the same notes. Newsweek ran a multi-page cover story about Americans drowning in debt. The reason for families’ distress? “Frivolous shopping is part of the problem: many debtors blame their woes squarely on Tommy, Ralph, Gucci, and Prada.” Money magazine laid blame on the family home. “A generation or so ago ... a basic, 800-square-foot, $8,000 Levittown box with a carport was heaven. ... By the 1980s, the dream had gone yupscale. Home had become a 6,000-square-foot contemporary on three acres or a gutted and rehabbed town-house in a gentrified ghetto.” The drumbeat shows no signs of letting up. Critics heap scorn on how Americans buy food, clothes, cars, shoes, appliances, and vacations.8 And what have Americans gotten for all their spending? Professor Schor cites “competitive spending” as a major, contributor to the deterioration of public goods” such as “education, social services, public safety, recreation, and culture.” Professor Frank sums it up: “The dogged pursuit for more’’ accounts for Americans’ “overload, debt, anxiety, and waste.” When it comes to money, Americans’ profligate spending has dug them into a hole from which they may never recover. Or so say the critics. The step from social critique to political action is short. The bankruptcy bill received widespread support in Congress, carefully couched in tones of moral condemnation for their spending binge. Senator Oren Hatch, R-UT, a senior spokesman of the United States Senate, points an unwaivering finger at families. He explains that millions of Americans are bankrupt or near-bankrupt because “they run up huge bills and then expect society to pay for them.” He is joined by federal Judge Edith Jones, once-rumored to be a potential Bush appointee to the Supreme Court. She asserts that “[b]ankruptcy is increasingly seen as a big ‘game,’ with the losers being those who live within their means, while the bankrupts pursue more interesting and carefree lives.” Judge Jones and her co-author Professor Todd Zywicki make the connection even clearer in explaining why bankruptcies are on the rise: “if debt ‘causes’ bankruptcy, it is only because overspending and an unwillingness to live within one’s means ‘causes’ debt. In short, one can simply re-characterize the ‘debt causes bankruptcy’ thesis as ‘overspending causes bankruptcy.’” In case anyone missed the point, they drive it home: “Bankruptcy is now too frequently a choice, fostered by irresponsible spending habits and an unwillingness to live up to commitments.” Professor Zywicki testified before Congress that: “We have ‘defined bankruptcy deviancy downward’ such that it has become a convenient financial planning tool rather than a decision freighted with moral and social significance.” He explained that the bankruptcy bill offered a way to correct that moral lapse, a tool to change the ways of the Immoral Debtor. The deep entanglement of the power of campaign contributions and advancing an ideological viewpoint was explored by Princeton political scientists Steven Nunez and Howard Rosenthal. They analyzed the intersection of ideology, campaign contributions, and voting in Congress, using the example of a credit industry supported amendment to the bankruptcy laws. Nunez and Rosenthal posit that support for the bankruptcy bill among Republicans was; largely a matter of ideology. Among Democrats, who might be less inclined to support the dominant view that human misfortune was largely a matter of just deserts, they identified enough vote buying through campaign contributions to conclude that “after controlling for ideology, we find that campaign contributions are significantly correlated with voting.” But even Nunez and Rosenthal saw the importance of keeping the public on board for any legislative change: “if public opinion tilts toward a view that it is necessary to discipline a minority of profligate, strategic debtors, then the industry bill should attract broad support . . . .” In other words, money counts, but the story counts too. The Family Balance Sheet The idea of the Immoral Debtor, the over-spender whose uncontrolled appetites impel him to run up debts that can easily be discharged in bankruptcy, gets a big boost from current economic data on the family. First, families have more to spend than a generation ago. Family income, adjusted for inflation, has taken a big jump in a single generation, the typical two-income family today earns nearly 75 percent more than their one-income parents earned a generation ago. But incomes haven’t risen because men are making more money. In fact, adjusted for inflation, the wages of fully-employed men have remained essentially flat. Instead, the rise in income can be attributed almost entirely to the decisions of millions of mothers to enter the workforce. Over the course of a few decades, the change has been nothing short of revolutionary. Mothers have entered the workforce in record numbers, doubling the number of earners in typical middle-class families from one to two. As recently as 1976 a married mother was more than twice as likely to stay home with her children as to work full-time. By 2000, those figures had almost reversed: The modern married mother is now nearly twice as likely to have a full-time job as to stay home. Mothers are going back to work much sooner after their children are born. A mother with a three month-old infant in 2001 was more likely to be working outside the home than was a 1960s woman with a five-year-old child. The transformation can be felt in other ways as well. In 1965 only 21 percent of working women were back at their jobs within 6 months of giving birth to their first child. Todays that figure is more than three times higher, topping 70 percent. In other words, families have more money to spend, but, they picked up that extra income by sending two people into the workforce. Without both parents pulling in paychecks, today’s family has no more to spend than they had a generation ago. They need both husband and wife at work to secure a place as middle-income earners. Even as family incomes have risen dramatically over the past generation, American families have decreased the amounts they put away. Family savings in the U.S. have decline markedly from the early 1970s to the early 2000s, with families putting away a shrinking fraction of their take-home pay. Families are spending an ever-larger fraction of what they earn. They spend now, saving less either for future purchases or as insurance against hard times. Increased income has not saved the family balance sheet for the median earning family. The reversal in spending patterns—spending more than they earn—has taken a terrible toll. Today there are five times more families filing bankruptcy than in the early 1980s. Home foreclosures have more than tripled in less than 25 years. Nearly half of the families with credit cards report that they have no money to make more than a minimum monthly payment on their outstanding credit card bills. One in every three families in the U.S. with an income above $35,000 reports owing medical bills that they cannot pay. Financial distress documented by these numbers hits hard in the middle class. It is homeowners—people who once saved money for a down payment, who showed that they had steady enough incomes to make monthly payments and who survived the most rigorous credit screen imposed in consumer financial markets—who lose their houses to foreclosure. It is people in the middle—not the richest or the poorest—who accumulate the most debt on their credit cards. It is middle class families seeking relief in the bankruptcy courts. These data compose a deeply disturbing picture. Tens of millions of American families—middle class people with decent educations and respectable occupations—are living on a financial cliff. Some will hang on, and others will plunge over as they deal with the anxiety of unplanned emergencies and unpaid bills. How They Spend If families are making more money than ever and in financial trouble, surely the critics are right: Over-consumption is rife in the land, and Immoral Debtors are running wild. But despite the steadfast assurances of the politicians, intuition and anecdotes are no substitute for hard data. The story of the Immoral Debtor is advanced as fact, but without any numbers. It might be worthwhile to look at some actual data on spending. And yet, when it is all added up, including the Tommy sweatshirts and Ray-Ban sunglasses, the average family of four today spends 21 percent less (inflation adjusted) on clothing than a similar family did in the early 1970s. How can this be? What the fingerwaggers have forgotten are the things families don’t spend money on anymore. No more rushing off to Stride Rite to buy two new pairs of sensible leather shoes for each child every three months (one for church and one for everyday) plus a pair of sneakers for play. Today’s toddlers often own nothing but a pair of $5 tennis shoes from Wal-Mart. Suits, ties, and pantyhose have been replaced by cotton trousers and knit tops, as “business casual” has swept the nation. New fabrics, new technology, and cheap labor have lowered prices. Discounters like Target and Marshall’s have popped up across the country, replacing full-price department stores of a generation ago. The differences add up. In 1973, Sunday dresses, wool jackets, and the other clothes for a family of four claimed nearly $750 more a year from the family budget than all the name-brand sneakers and hip T-shirts today’s families are buying. If Americans are not blowing their paychecks on clothes, then they must be overspending on food. Designer brands have hit the grocery shelves as well, with far more prepared foods, high-end ice creams, and exotic juices. Families even buy bottles of water, a purchase that would have shocked their grandparents. Besides, who cooks at home anymore? With Mom and Dad both tied up at work, Americans are eating out (or ordering in) more than ever before. The Immoral Debtor critics have it right, but only to a point. The average family of four spends more at restaurants than it used to, but it spends less at the grocery stores—a lot less. Families are saving big bucks by skipping the T-bone steaks, buying their cereal in bulk at Costco, and opting for generic paper towels and canned vegetables. Those savings more than compensate for all that restaurant eating—so much so that today’s family of four is actually spending 22 percent less on food (at-home and restaurant eating combined) than its counterpart of a generation ago. Outfitting the home? Affluenza authors rail against appliances “that were deemed luxuries as recently as 1970, but are now found in well over half of U.S. homes, and thought of by a majority of Americans as necessities: dishwashers, clothes dryers, central heating and air conditioning, color and cable TV.” These handy gadgets may have captured a new place in Americans’ hearts, but they aren’t taking up much space in our wallets. Manufacturing costs are down, and durability is up. When the microwave oven, dishwasher, and clothes dryer are combined with the refrigerator, washing machine, and stove, families are actually spending 44 percent less on major appliances today than they were a generation ago.51 Furniture may now be leather and super-sized, but spending has shrunk for it as well—a 30% decline in a single generation. What about cars? At first glance it would seem that the family car might just shatter the case against the Immoral Debtor. Cars now come jam-packed with automatic gizmos that no one had even dreamed of a generation ago. And cars cost more than ever. In the words of a Toyota salesman quoted in Affluenza, “People’s expectations are much higher. They want amenities—power steering, power brakes as standard, premium sound systems.”52 At last, a big-ticket item that that proves that Americans are indeed indulging themselves with lavish extravagances they can ill afford. Families are also buying safety devices that didn’t even exist in the, early 1970s. Every time I strap my new granddaughter into the car I am reminded of what I did when her mother Amelia was a baby. I tucked her in a wicker bassinet, which perched on the back seat of our Volkswagen Beetle. I was somewhat unusual—not because I failed to use so much as a seat belt to hold my seven-pound daughter in place—but because I opted not to hold her in my lap, where a simple fender bender would have transformed her into a freeflying projectile. By and large, families have spent prudently on their automobiles, or at least as prudently as they did a generation ago. And the money they are spending is paying off: The rate of child auto fatalities has declined steadily since the mid-1970s, thanks at least in part to safer cars and better car seats.58 For all the criticism hurled at car manufacturers (and car buyers), it is important to note that families drive stronger, safer cars that last a lot longer than they used to. That is not to say that middle-class families never flitter away any money. A generation ago no one had cable, big-screen televisions were a novelty reserved for the very rich, and DVD and TiVo were meaningless strings of letters. So how much more do families spend on “home entertainment,’’ premium channels included? They spend 23 percent more—an extra $170 annually. Computers add another $300 to the annual family budget.59 But even that increase looks a little different in the context of other spending. The extra money spent on cable, electronics, and computers is more than offset by families’ savings on major appliances and household furnishings alone. The same balancing act holds true in other areas. The average family spends more on airline travel than it did a generation ago, but it spends less on dry cleaning. More on telephone services, but less on tobacco. More on pets, but less on carpets.60 When the numbers are all added up, increases in one category are offset by decreases in another. In other words, there seems to be about as much frivolous spending today as there was a generation ago. Whether families are spending more than they should by some moral notion—consuming too much of the world’s resources or buying things they could easily live without—is not at issue here. These data give us no clue about the right amount of spending. But the, data give us a powerful look at why families are not going broke. Here the data are solid and on point: There is no evidence of any “epidemic” in overspending—certainly nothing that could explain a 255 percent increase in the foreclosure rate, a 430 percent increase in the bankruptcy rolls, and a 570 percent increase in credit card debt.61 A growing number of families are in terrible financial trouble, but no matter how many times the accusation is hurled, Prada and HBO are not the reasons. Where Did the Money Go? They have more money and they aren’t spending themselves into oblivion on designer water and DVDs, so how did middle-class families get into so much financial trouble? The answer starts, quite literally, at home. It would be possible to pile cliché on cliché about the home, but restraint forces me to settle for this observation: The home is the single most important purchase for the average middle-class family. To the overwhelming majority of Americans, home ownership stands out as the single most important component of “the good life.”62 Homes mark the lives of their children, setting out the parameters of their universe. The luck of location will determine whether there are computers in their classrooms, whether there are sidewalks for them to ride bikes on, and whether the front yard is a safe place to play. And a home will consume more of the family’s income than any other purchase— more than food, more than cars, more than health insurance, more than childcare. As anyone who has read the newspapers or purchased a home knows, it costs a lot more to buy a house than it used to. (Because the overwhelming majority of middle-class families are homeowners, this discussion focuses on the costs of owning, rather than renting.) What is easy to forget, however, is that today’s home prices, are not the product of some inevitable demographic force that has simply rolled its way across America. Quite the opposite. In the late 1980s, several commentators predicted a spectacular collapse in the housing market. Economists reasoned that the baby boomers were about to become empty nesters, so pressure on the housing market would undergo a sharp reversal. According to these experts, housing prices would reverse their forty-year upward trend and drop during the 1990s and 2000s—anywhere from 10 to 47 percent. The Immoral Debtor diehards are clearing their throats, eager to interrupt to explain why housing prices shot up despite expert predictions. If they cannot sustain their claim, that families are spending too much on frivolous purchases, these critics can simply adjust their chant to declare that Americans’ materialistic and shallow motivations have driven housing prices up. Money magazine captures this view: “A generation or so ago . . . a basic, 800-square-foot, $8,000 Levittown box with a carport was heaven. . . . By the 1980s, the dream had gone yupscale. Home had become a 6,000-square-foot contemporary on three acres or a gutted and rehabbed town-house in a gentrified ghetto.” Where did so many people get this impression? Perhaps from the much ballyhooed fact that the average size of a new home has increased by nearly 40 percent over the past generation (although it is still less than 2,200 square feet).67 But before the Immoral Debtor group declares victory, there are a few more details to consider. Those data tell us only where real estate developers are aiming new home construction, that they have decided that McMansions are more profitable than Levittowns. The wealthy may be living in spacious digs, but those new homes are not snapped up by middle-class families. The proportion of families living in older homes has increased by nearly 50 percent over the past generation, leaving a growing number of homeowners grappling with deteriorating roofs, peeling paint, and old wiring. Today, nearly six out of ten families own a home that is more than twenty-five years old, and nearly a quarter own a house that is more than fifty years old. 68 As millions of families sent a second earner into the workforce and pushed up total family income, one might expect that they would spend less on housing as a proportion of total income. Instead, just the opposite has occurred. A growing number of middle-class families now spend more on housing relative to family income. Over a generation, the average family increased the number of rooms in their homes by 7 percent, but their mortgage expenses took a leap of 69 percent at a time that other family expenditures fell. As food, clothing, home furnishings, and the like remained steady or fell, families across America were loading up on mortgages like never before to buy those homes. The impact of rising mortgage costs has been huge. The proportion of families who are “house-poor,” that is, who are spending more than 35 percent of their incomes on housing has quadrupled in a single generation.3 Today it takes two working people to support a mortgage in most metropolitan areas. For example, the average police officer could not afford the mortgage for a median priced home in two-thirds of the nation’s metropolitan areas on the officer’s income alone. The same is true for elementary school teachers. This phenomenon is not limited to high-cost cities such as New York and San Francisco. Without a working spouse the family of a police officer or teacher is priced out of a median home even in more modestly priced cities such as Nashville, Kansas City, and Charlotte. So what does all this have to do with educating middle-class children, most of whom have been lucky enough to avoid the worst failings of the public school system? The answer is simple—money. Failing schools impose an enormous cost on those children who are forced to attend them, but they also inflict an enormous cost on those who don’t. Even over-consumption critic Juliet Schor acknowledges the growing pressure on middle-class parents. For all that she criticizes America’s love affair with granite countertops and microwave ovens, she recognizes that parents’ motivations are not always so crass: Within the middle class, and even the upper middle class, many families experience an almost threatening pressure to keep up, both for themselves and their children. They are deeply concerned about the rigors of the global economy, and the need to have their children attend “good” schools. This means living in a community with relatively high housing costs.81 In other words, the only way to ensure that a beloved youngster gets a solid education is to spring for a three-bedroom Colonial within an hour-long commute to a job in the city. Newer, more isolated suburbs with restrictive zoning also promise a refuge from the random crimes that tarnish urban living. It may seem odd that families would devote more attention to personal safety—or the lack thereof—when the crime rate in the United States has fallen sharply over the past decade. But national statistics mask differences among communities, and disparities have grown over time. In many cities, the urban centers have grown more dangerous while outlying areas have gotten safer—further intensifying the pressure parents feel to squeeze into a suburban refuge. In Baltimore and Philadelphia, for example, the crime rate fell in the surrounding suburbs just as it increased in the center city. The disparities are greatest for the most frightening violent crimes. Today a person is ten times more likely to be murdered in center city Philadelphia than in its surrounding suburbs, and twelve times more likely to be killed in central Baltimore. The overall odds may remain low, but it is the comparative story that drives parents to distant suburbs. Perhaps the strongest evidence of parents’ Herculean efforts to buy homes where their children will be safe and go to good schools is the differential changes in housing prices. The federal government has not reported the data for the full thirty-year period examined here, but even in the confines of a fifteen year comparison, the relative increases in housing costs for parents and non-parents have been quite different. Wherever they started in 1989, housing prices grew for parents at a rate three times faster than for those who have no minor children at home. Families have been hit hard by more than mortgage costs. The rising cost of health care has taken a terrible bite out of the family budget. If we focus on only the healthy family—an unrealistic assumption, but one that makes the point even sharper—medical costs are up dramatically. For the families lucky enough to have an employer who contributes to their health insurance program, the costs of keeping a family covered have risen dramatically. In one generation, the out-of-pocket cost of employer-subsidized health insurance has jumped by about 90 percent. Of course, median earning families are not all spending this amount. Some are lucky enough to have employers who pick up the entire tab. For a growing number, however, the employer offers no assistance, and the family either buys on the open market or gives up on health insurance altogether. In recent years, the number of middle class families with no health insurance has grown precipitously. Adding It Up The Immoral Debtor story dominates any discussion of the financial condition of America’s families, but when all the plusses and minuses of changes in family spending are added up, a very different picture emerges. Families are spending less on ordinary consumption and more on the basics of being middle class. These data tell a story of middle class families clipping coupons and buying pasta in bulk, while they hemorrhage money to pay the bills for their mortgages, their health insurance, transportation, chlldcare and taxes. The changes in income and in expenses have transformed the family budget. A generation ago, the median family kept one parent at home and put one into the workforce. Today, the median family puts both parents to work, but their basic expenses have outrun even the addition of a second worker. Even with two people in the workforce, the new family budget still leaves families trailing their one-income parents from a generation ago. The new family budget is notable first for the sharp dissonance between earning and spending. The two-income family of the 2000s has less money to spend on every consumption good—food, clothing, appliances, furniture, life insurance, vacations, etc.— than the one income family of a generation ago. They now have two people at work, but less money for spending. But the new family budget is notable for another reason: It is far more deeply leveraged. A generation ago, the one-income family committed about 54 percent of its pay to the basics—housing, health insurance, transportation and taxes. In effect, the one-income family spent about half its income to make the nut—the basic expenses that do not vary if someone gets sick or loses a job. Today, the basic expenses consume 75 percent of the family’s combined income. Their nut—the amount that they must pay in good times and in bad—is-fixed at 75 percent of their income. With 75 percent of income earmarked for fixed expenses, today’s family has no margin for error. There is no leeway to cut back if one parent’s hours are cut or if the other gets laid off. There is no room in the budget if someone needs to take a few months off work to care for Grandma, or if a parent hurts his back and can’t work. The modern American family is walking on a high wire without a net; they pray there won’t be any wind. If all goes well, they will make it across safely, their children will grow up and finish college, and they will move on to retirement. But if anything—anything at all—goes wrong, then today’s two-income family is in big, big trouble. The expenses laid out here are averages, and plenty of families manage to pay less (or more). But the alternatives families have pursued in an effort to make ends meet bear some scrutiny. Consider childcare. Government statistics show that the average amount a family of four spends on after-school care is lower than the $4,350 cited above. The number reported here is calculated based on reports of families who pay for their childcare, but the government “average” includes children who have a grandmother or an older sibling who watches them for free. That is a great way for those, lucky families to save some money, but it doesn’t do a bit of good for the typical family that has to rely on paid childcare. For them, paying less money means getting less quality, such as an unlicensed neighbor who parks several children in front of her television or an overcrowded center with barely passable facilities. The cost of childcare is also on the march. From 2000 to 2003 alone, the cost of childcare increased 19%. There are other ways families could save money. Families could also cut their health insurance expenses. They could drop those costs to zero by following the model of millions of other middle-class families who simply live without health insurance and pray for the best. Or they could give up the house and move into an apartment in a marginal neighborhood. There are always options, but for families with children, these options signal that their middle-class lives are slipping away. Even if they are able to trim around the edges, families are faced with a sobering truth: Every one of those expensive items—mortgage, car payments, insurance, tuition—is a fixed cost. Families must pay them each and every month, through good times and bad times, no matter what. Unlike clothing or food, there is no way to cut back from one month to the next. Short of moving out of the house, withdrawing a child from preschool, or canceling the insurance policy altogether, the families are stuck. Fully 75 percent of their income is earmarked for recurrent monthly expenses. If all goes well, many families will squeak by. They will even get a breather in another five years or so, when their children are old enough to be left alone after school. But the spending hiatus will last for just a few years, until the older child heads off to college. At that point, the family’s budget will be squeezed harder than ever as they search for the money to cover room, board, and tuition for the local state university. If they are lucky, they will have set something aside during the intervening years, and they will find a way to put their kids through college. And when they hit their mid-to late fifties, these couples might begin to think about putting something away for their retirement (about thirty years later than a financial planner would recommend). And so go the lives of the families with “affluenza,” “the urge to splurge,” and other clever variation on rampant materialism. Lobbyists and politicians may cling to the idea that these families over consume, but they can do so only with a deliberate disregard for the data that tells a very different story. Over the past decade, returns to investors on credit card debt have outstripped every other form of lending—even after all the bad debt and bankruptcy losses are counted. A multibillion dollar wealth transfer has, in fact, taken place, but not the one the credit card industry claims has occurred. Families that have lost jobs, families that have no health insurance and families that have split apart following divorce or death of a spouse have paid billions to credit card companies and their investors. And just to clarify the classdriven point, it is worth noting that across the U.S., half of all families have not one dollar of savings put aside for their retirements and 73% of all families have not one dollar in the stock market. It is a fair assumption that paying dearly for consumer credit has not created a wealth transfer within the middle class, but rather a transfer from working families to upper income families. The credit industry has good reason to spend money to protect the income flow from debtors to shareholders. The Immoral Debtor story is good for the financial services industry and for a Congress that does their bidding. In the world of statutory regulation, reality matters less than the perception of reality. The Immoral Debtor story keeps would-be reformers at bay, and it blunts the criticism of the industry leveled by consumer groups and advocates for the elderly, for racial minorities and for women. After all, who wants to organize to defend deadbeats who are the cause of their own destruction? What Happens to the Families The story is powerful, but at some point reality asserts itself. Congress can cut off access to bankruptcy. Credit industry spokesmen can assert that the people in trouble are the profligate and irresponsible. But that won’t help families who have cut out lattes and who don’t go to the mall every weekend; they still can’t make their mortgage payments or find the money for health insurance. And it won’t help families avoid job losses, illnesses, accidents or family break ups. In other words, Congress can pass the laws, but if the laws have little to do with why families are in trouble, then people will still go broke. But those are complex changes, and change requires a consensus that something is wrong. So long as Americans can be persuaded that families in financial trouble have only themselves to blame, there will be no demand to change anything. One cost of the Immoral Debtor story is that it helped bring us a bankruptcy bill that will fall hard on good people. A second cost is that the story is one more roadblock to prevent getting on with the difficult business of making America once again safe for middle class families. Please also read the following excerpts from a 1976 article by George J. Wallace. THE USES OF USURY: LOW RATE CEILINGS REEXAMINEDt GEORGE J. WALLACE* The problem which is becoming acute is that the market as it is does not produce a distribution of income and power which satisfies the ideas of modern justice. Kenneth Arrow 1 INTRODUCTION Apparently spurred by the drafting and promulgation of the Uniform Consumer Credit Code2 and by decisions such as Wisconsin v. J. C. Penney Co.3 critics of low consumer credit rate ceilings have loudly and persistently called for their repeal.4 Not long ago the National Commission on Consumer Finance5 considerably strengthened that call by presenting empirical data tending to show that low ceilings bind more low income than high income individuals.6 The main argument made by the critics is that low ceilings, if effective, reduce the availability of consumer credit to those with low incomes. Reduced availability interferes with the freedom of those denied credit to buy what they want with discretionary income.7 Rate ceilings have also been charged with being ineffective, reducing competition and efficiency, and discouraging economic growth in the state that harbors them.8 Although there have been a few rumblings in response, the critics charges to date remain basically uncontested.9 My aim is to suggest that the critics' position, stripped of its free choice and efficiency verbiage, is extraordinarily narrow. Low rate ceilings, if properly used, are potentially effective and beneficial regulatory tools. Of course, like most regulatory tools, they also have their costs. But the critics-apparently influenced by the conviction that, as a normative matter, the theoretical free market shows the best way to structure debtor-creditor relationships-have focused only on the costs. This article attempts to readjust the uneven balance. Although those who ultimately set the guidelines for credit policy in a state or the nation must determine by their own values whether the costs outweigh the benefits, they cannot do so wisely when the relevant factors have been only half-way explored. Low ceilings are often opposed as governmental interference with the workings of a market pricing system. In part I, I approach the dispute over low ceilings as a distributive question and argue that there is no a priori reason to suppose that the market system's answer to distributive questions is more ethically justifiable than that provided by governmental intervention. In part II, I identify four advantages that appear to provide some ethical support for certain types of low ceilings advantages that at the least require careful consideration before a decision is made to adopt high ceilings. My primary purpose is to suggest the lack of balance in any analysis of rate ceiling policy that considers only efficiency and freedom to use credit. I therefore develop each of these advantages with sufficient clarity to underscore its relevance to the choice of high or low rate ceiling policy, but my purpose does not require that I examine each concern in sufficient depth to establish it against all adverse criticism. The first advantage of low ceilings, the protection of high risk consumers from the psychic and material hardship associated with default, suggests the desirability of a moderately low rate ceiling affecting all types of consumer credit. Because this type of regulation is of current interest in state and national legislatures, part III subjects such regulation to the full analysis suggested in part II. After exploring the ethical basis for low ceilings, I conclude that a substantial argument can be made in their favor, even though the available evidence on several crucial points is incomplete. Because the other advantages of low ceilings are of less current interest, the lengthy analysis they require can be saved for later articles. III. EVALUATING LOW RATE CEILINGS AS PROTECTION AGAINST EXCESSIVELY RISKY CREDIT Proposals for reform of economic institutions, such as the moderately low rate ceiling examined here, require evaluation in terms of the ethical values they promote or disrupt.74 That evaluation can best begin by examining two hypothetical credit systems, one with low, one with high ceilings, drawn so as to clarify the basic ethical position that underlies advocacy of low ceilings for protective purposes.75 Thereafter, several complications likely to be encountered in the real world will be considered.76 In all this, a certain degree of generality must be tolerated, particularly given the limits of the empirical information on the impact rate ceilings and other regulatory proposals might have.77 But the basic issues can at least be identified and the tentative prognosis made that across-the-board low rate ceilings hold considerable promise as ethically justifiable protective tools. A. The Hypothetical Credit Systems18 The two systems are in all respects the same except for rate ceilings. Both have a package of restrictions on creditor collection practices equivalent to those proposed by the National Commission on Consumer Finance.79 The costs of administering the regulation of consumer credit are likewise assumed to be the same. The first system, however, utilizes a-rate ceiling low enough to interfere significantly with the borrowing ability of high risk customers-perhaps a mean rate ceiling80 of twenty percent81 that would apply across the board to all consumer credit markets.82 The assumed effect of this ceiling is to restrict credit availability so as to save those denied it a substantial risk of psychic harm caused by the threat of occurrence of default and its aftermath. Under these assumptions, the reduction in borrowing ability necessarily produces an increase in protection. Because there are substantial restrictions on creditor collection practices, rate ceilings only serve as a specialized method of protection designed to protect the highest risk borrowers. The second system has a high ceiling like that recommended by the Uniform Consumer Credit Code,83 producing a mean rate ceiling of thirty-one percent.84 This system, then, offers an increase in borrowing ability to high risk debtors at the price of less protection, while other variables are held constant. The assumptions underlying these two alternatives have avoided several important questions about the impact ceilings will actually have in the real world. After briefly examining these questions, they can be set aside until we have explored the ethical basis for lowered ceilings. Then they will be treated at greater length. The first question is whether there is a strong relationship between lowered ceilings and reduced psychic harm resulting from default. Even though the connection between lowering ceilings and barring some high risk consumers from some credit is quite well established,85 we do not understand well the relation between rate . ceiling levels, default and psychic harm. Despite the time and money the National Commission on Consumer Finance spent, its staff did not seriously inquire into the psychic impact of default. 86 It did not do so presumably because of greater concern with the question of availability of credit a factor of overriding significance only if the problem is to be analyzed solely in terms of freedom of choice. 87 Although Professors Caplovitz and Jacobs have given us evidence of significant psychic impact associated with default, the evidence is not related to particular rate ceiling levels.88 If we can assume that the psychic harm they document occurs with regularity in most defaults, credit with a high risk of default should carry a high risk of psychic harm. But we still do not know enough to judge at what risk level that harm reduces to acceptable proportions. The analysis in this part can therefore only suggest that lowered rate ceilings are likely to have merit; it cannot determine with precision that they do. Second, whether a lowered ceiling will be completely effective in removing high risk credit without seriously interfering with socially acceptable credit must be determined.89 A lowered ceiling will certainly exclude from the market some of the highest risk credit. But there may still be "leakage" in retail markets, for example, unless rather extensive regulation is combined with the lowered ceiling.90 Lowered ceilings may also restrict socially acceptable credit unless the market works with absolute perfection.91 The third question is whether there will be a seriously adverse impact on the competitive structure of the credit industry in the low ceiling system. Lowered ceilings will certainly interfere with pricing in the market for credit, and they may ultimately drive out all but the most efficient operators,92 thereby reducing the potential for competition. High ceilings might not have this disadvantage. Fourth, there may be some alternative regulatory program which could provide similar protection yet not carry the disadvantages of the low ceiling system. Because a quite different ethical question would be posed if protection similar to that produced by a low ceiling were obtainable without high cost in freedom to borrow or in efficiency, the availability of such an alternative must be explored .. Finally, we know practically nothing about the net transaction costs produced by credit rate regulation.93 A lowered rate ceiling might r quire extensive enforcement, particularly if an illegal loan market began to develop. Furthermore, an attempt to restrict the ability of retailers to cover some of their credit extension costs by raising the prices of goods sold would increase enforcement costs.94 On the other hand, regulatory costs could just as well turn out to be higher under the second hypothetical system because the greater volume of high risk credit associated with higher ceilings could result in greater default collection. And there might be greater resort to bankruptcy and welfare than in the lower risk system. Each of these questions raises an important difficulty with lowering rate ceilings for protective purposes. The issue that must first be settled, however, is whether there is some ethical justification for such ceilings. B. The Ethical Position Favoring Low Ceilings The controversy whether protection justifies restrictions on borrowing ability and freedom of action caused by low rate ceilings revolves around a classic ethical question. To what extent is it proper to limit an individual's freedom of action in order to protect that individual? A universally acceptable resolution has never emerged,95 and I do not suggest that I have found one. Nonetheless, an examination of the precise effect lowered ceilings would have on freedom of action will reveal a degree of infringement to which only the most extreme libertarians could object. 1. The Purpose of Low Ceilings Reexamined and Refined I have already urged that a lowered ceiling can be used to improve a society's overall distribution of benefits and burdens among its members.97 At this point, it is necessary to specify the distributive improvement that might be achieved. The protection from a high risk of default afforded by a lowered ceiling is not expected to transfer wealth in the same direct way as a welfare payment.98 A lowered ceiling, by protecting the debtor family from a threat to stability and psychic harm,99 should, however, help maintain a minimum standard of existence sufficient to preserve the dignity of the individual. Proposals for various minimum standards are usually justified as a means to promote equality and to satisfy the basic conditions for assuring the citizen the ability to exercise and enjoy freedom. The low ceiling system hypothesized can therefore be viewed as an attempt to equalize in part the distribution of such important social goods as family stability and the ability to enjoy and exercise freedom.100 Of course, the contribution a low ceiling system would make toward securing these goods is only a partial one, but it may nonetheless be an important complement to other programs with the same objectives. 2. The Apparent Infringement on Freedom I: Who Is Hurt by Low Ceilings? Lowered ceilings would limit credit to three identifiable classes of borrowers, and only the third class could rationally complain that its freedom of action was being impaired. The first class consists of those who would not use high risk credit if they fully understood the extent and seriousness of the risk involved. The evidence indicates that consumers understand little about the terms and conditions of the credit they purchase.101 On the other hand, they probably do understand that if they fail to repay, serious consequences will follow. But a large group of high risk debtors may well fail to comprehend their own degree of risk. No one tells them, as they might, "Eight out of fifty of your class will have serious trouble repaying; two or three out of one hundred of your class will default and be subjected to repossession." 102 A National Commission study provides some evidence that the size of this group of unaware borrowers may be substantial and that the members of this group may not object to the elimination of high risk credit. Of those who were denied high risk credit by a legislative change in Maine's small loan laws, thirty-six percent indicated that they were pleased to be rid of the "burden" of the finance company, and another twenty-seven percent "felt about the same" without credit as with it.103 A second class of those who would be affected by lowered ceilings is composed of those people who are simply not competent to run their own affairs. Although I suspect this class to be rather small, few would object to protecting those who fall within its bounds. 104 Those who have advocated high rate ceilings have usually argued that the creditor has a strong self-interest in identifying members of this class of borrowers and refusing to extend them credit.105 Outside of certain peculiar submarkets,106 this incentive no doubt exists and is quite strong. But the problem is that a creditor's ability to distinguish members of this class is limited by the cost of obtaining the necessary information and by the difficulty of ever knowing fully the subjective motivations, intelligence and fortune of another person. In fact, there may be more than a few members of this class who are not filtered out by creditors.107 They might be protected by a lowered ceiling. The disadvantage of the lowered ceiling is to the third class: those who are intelligent enough to handle their own affairs and willing after intelligent consideration to run the risk of high cost, high default credit, but who cannot in fact obtain credit from an alternative low risk source.108 To this class of borrowers the interference with the ability to arrange their own lives is not so insignificant as to be fairly ignored. Use of credit to purchase durable goods may sometimes produce a net savings to the consumer.109 Moreover, consumption behavior is a frequently practiced form of individual expression in this society. By purchasing certain goods on credit, an individual may hope to enjoy a more satisfying mixture of amenities and necessities than he could otherwise acquire. The critics have always denounced low ceilings because of the kind of interference with freedom which would fall on the third class. As the critics have framed the problem, low ceilings are undesirable because they obstruct personal liberty (in choice of lifestyle) for an improper purpose, paternalistic intervention.11° This argument focuses on the interests of the third class rather than of the first and second classes, and it has therefore misstated the issue. In fact, the ethical question is whether, despite the protection provided the first two classes at no real loss in liberty, the infringement of the personal liberty of the third class is so unacceptable as to require that lowered ceilings not be used as a tool of social policy. The argument in response may begin from an ethical premise quite similar to the one underlying the critics' position. Although the state ought not to limit personal liberty solely for a paternalistic purpose, it properly may infringe on it in order to help and protect others.111 This statement of the relation of the individual to the state is a familiar feature of utilitarian philosophy, 112 and lowered ceilings are consistent with it. Their use for protection would not be for a paternalistic purpose. They are designed to protect the first and second classes whose liberty is not decreased by the protection, although at the expense of the third class.113 Alternatively, one may begin from the premise that some infringement on personal liberty by the state is acceptable when the infringement is slight, affects economic rather than political rights, and improves the distribution of benefits in the society. If we accept this position, as many others have, 114 the question becomes whether the infringement caused by lowered ceilings can fairly be called minor. There are several reasons why it can be. First, although low ceilings limit somewhat the ability to buy major durable goods on credit, the alternative ways of spending the money involved might be thought adequate to compensate for the loss. The payments that would have gone to repay the debt with interest could be spent on lower priced items or saved. Although some advantageous opportunities for example, the possibility that a washing machine bought on credit would result in net savings to a large family will no doubt be lost, the alternatives will be adequate in most cases, such as when use of public transportation would be cheaper than driving a private car purchased on credit. Second, lowered ceilings do not interfere with the restricted individual's ability to express himself through a wide range of purchase behavior on a cash basis. Third, if credit were not available, equally valued new outlets for expression other than purchase behavior might emerge as substitutes. And, finally, the shape our consumption desires take appears to be influenced to some degree by social pressures, and particularly by the cumulative effect of massive advertising.115 The resulting purchase behavior is therefore an amalgam of individual preference and social conformism.116 As a result, restrictions on purchase behavior are not wholly restrictions on individual freedom of choice. The foregoing analysis demonstrates that the interference with individual liberty occasioned by lowered ceilings will not be nearly as burdensome as some have thought. In addition, it is clear that our society already tolerates numerous forms of protective legislation that interfere significantly with an individual's ability to spend wealth in precisely the way he wants. The Consumer Product Safety Commission, for example, has the power to ban unsafe products• from the market, even though some who realize they are unsafe may want to buy them.117 Thus, I am not persuaded that low ceilings must be rejected out of hand simply because they would somewhat compromise the value of individual liberty. The conclusion does not directly follow, however, that such ceilings are justifiable. At most, low ceilings for the protective purposes I am advocating would be set so as to restrict borrowing by only a small portion of the population. The dominant society would still be able to use credit freely. The exclusion of the poorest members of society from the dominant culture might therefore be exacerbated. For the third class of borrowers, those who want to use risky credit, the restriction on freedom to borrow caused by low ceilings is actually a decrease in the ability to participate in the dominant culture. Although the lack of empirical evidence prevents accurately assessing how serious this widening of the gulf between rich and poor would be, the potential for harm is great enough to demand that the widening be seriously examined. 3. The Apparent Infringement on Freedom II: Inequality The unavoidable conclusion from what has. gone before is that any infringement on freedom of action caused by low ceilings involves a question more of unequal economic treatment for the disadvantaged than of a significant infringement on liberty. Insofar as the critics have based their attack on the argument that low ceilings interfere with freedom, they may be fairly charged with mislabeling the basic issue. Low ceilings can be justified as an attempt to promote equality by preserving the basic dignity of the debtor and the debtor family. Conversely, high ceilings arguably permit high risk debtors to share in some degree the consumption opportunities of the more fortunate—although, of course, at higher interest costs. Two mutually exclusive schemes of social organization, the low and the high ceiling systems hypothesized, both seek to justify themselves as methods for promoting equality. The type of equality that each seeks to promote, however, is different. Low ceilings promote equality by seeking to avoid catastrophes that would destroy stability, self-esteem and family life. The focus is on conserving the little property and security held by high risk debtors, most of whom presumably fall in the lower ranks of wealth. High ceilings promote equality by expanding the opportunities of the same group, at the attendant cost of increasing the risks, and potentially the rewards, of that group. The basic issue in the controversy over low ceilings, then, is the ethical problem of determining which type of equality should be given priority. 4. The Priority of Protection A strict utilitarian would resolve the priority problem just posed in favor of the alternative that produced the greatest good for the greatest number.118 So analyzed, the decision might be thought best resolved by a surrogate for majority vote of the borrowers involved.119 The relevant empirical question would then be whether the first and second classes described above were greater in number, or perhaps in intensity of opinion, than those in the third class, the group most disadvantaged by low ceilings. There is a pragmatic objection, however, that may be raised to basing resolution of this problem on strict utilitarian grounds. The utilitarian test for priority raises difficult, and possibly unresolvable, questions. How can we determine the greatest good in a conflict of this nature when the answer immediately turns empirical and fades into interpersonal comparisonsutility, as it must? How can we decide satisfactorily whether the first and second classes are numerically larger than the third; whether the feelings on the question held by the first and second classes are stronger than those of the third? The only satisfactory answer may be that we cannot avoid such questions.120 But if the manifest defects of the market as a device for resolving such questions lead us to reject its verdict, as I have argued we must, l21 then informed intuition and belief seem to be the substitute with which we must be content. As I argue below, the lowered ceiling position has, on the present state of the evidence, as much intuitive appeal in utilitarian terms as does that of its critics.122 Another approach to wealth distribution questions, recently urged by Rawls in a special form, suggests that some of these difficulties with utilitarianism can be avoided.123 If the criterion of choice between conflicting policies should be, as Rawls suggests, to select whichever program favors the least advantaged group of society, the controlling question is apparently narrower than that involved in a strict utilitarian judgment. Arguably, the least advantaged groups affected by low ceilings are the first and second classes, while the third class is by comparison the most advantaged. The first class, composed of those who now use high risk credit but would not if they understood the degree of risk they run, seems easily viewed as less competent and less secure than the members of the third class, composed of those who would willingly take on the risk of default in light of the potential rewards. The few studies made of the relation between personality and attitude toward risk-taking support this view. 124 The fact that the second class seems clearly more disadvantaged than the third adds additional support to this justification for low rate ceilings. Yet this approach, particularly in the concrete application here, has its difficulties. The principle itself, if applied without limitation, would lead to a complete equalization of wealth. 125 Rawls therefore surrounds its application with several significant restrictions, but they are unfortunately so abstract as to make the application of his analysis here at least as difficult as a strict utilitarian examination of the problem}26 Moreover, the approach here requires a determination of which class is the least advantaged. Deciding that question solely on the attitude of a class toward risk is arguably far too narrow a focus, although it may be the best solution available.127 The role of informed intuition about the state of the real world is thus just as important to this analysis as it is to a strict .utilitarian analysis. Despite these difficulties, the principle that society should generally favor the least advantaged in making a wealth distribution choice has strong appeal. The choice between a low ceiling and a high one is a choice between hurting the first and second classes on the one hand or the third class on the other. The first two classes seem the most deserving, unless either they are very small in comparison to the third or the protection from psychic harm provided by lowered ceilings is insignificant. To be sure, the basic ethical argument underlying this position may be viewed as only a special application of utilitarianism in which the greatest good is thought to be found by identifying the least advantaged class and designing social programs that are most likely to aid it. 128 But regardless of -;whether the argument draws its greatest ethical force from utilitarianism or some version of Rawls' contractarianism, it plainly, offers an ethically supportable ground for advocating low ceilings, absent countervailing considerations. Such considerations, however, must be thoroughly examined before any conclusions• can be reached. Third, an alternative program that would provide equivalent, or nearly equivalent, protection at less cost in anticompetitive effects, administrative costs, or other relevant factors wo4ld clearly be preferable. Although efficiency may be subordinate to ethical concerns when determining the proper course for distributive policy, the choice of the method used for accomplishing the social objectives must be directed by cost minimizing considerations.160 IV. CONCLUSION Recently, there has been much criticism and little defense of low consumer credit rate ceilings. The result has been an unbalanced view of the issues involved. An overview of the potential of lowered ceilings suggests several uses that appear to deserve thorough consideration before a state or the nation elects a high ceiling policy. Furthermore, close examination of one use-protecting high risk debtors from the psychic harm associated with default-suggests that a moderately low ceiling applied to all forms of consumer credit provides a significant improvement in the distribution of benefits within society. There will, of course, be those who disagree. When considerations of social policy turn on the degree of psychic harm which one or another class must bear, empirical evidence can only help uncover the right decision, it cannot identify it with certainty. A conclusion in favor of a particular alternative must instead turn on the exercise of careful judgment, informed by the available evidence and shaped by the relevant ethical considerations. My •purpose has been to show those who set rate ceiling policy that a reasonable judgment can be made to use lowered ceilings for protective purposes. A fair evaluation of the empirical evidence and relevant ethical considerations supports, on balance, lowered ceilings instead of the high ceiling alternative generally proposed.184 Of course, those who assess differently the real world-the workings of the credit industry, the motivations of credit users and the effectiveness of government regulation-will dispute this conclusion. The available empirical evidence certainly does not preclude differences on this basis, and I would prefer more evidence correlating default harm with high risk credit before advocating wide adoption of lowered ceilings.185 But in my judgment the most reasonable conclusion is that the psychic harm caused by default will have great impact on high risk debtors if they do borrow and default, while losing the benefits of credit and suffering pain and embarrassment when it is denied will have a relatively slight effect. Differing interpretations of the evidence should not be exaggerated, however. The disagreement over rate ceiling policy arises from a basic difference as to the ethical considerations which should be brought to bear on the decision. In this respect, the argument for lowered ceilings appears to rest on stronger grounds than that advanced by its critics. The ethical justification for lowered ceilings begins from the premise that any program designed to improve the distribution of benefits and burdens in the society must at a minimum favor those who are the least advantaged. Lowered ceilings appear to satisfy this criterion. They will protect two classes of debtors, both of which now use high risk credit but are unaware of the risks they run when they do so, at the expense of a third class which seems likely to be better off than the others. 186 In contrast, the ethical position of those who oppose lowered ceilings remains obscure. On the surface the critics argue that low ceilings will intolerably impair individual liberty and must therefore be rejected. Yet close analysis demonstrates little, if any, impairment of the liberty of the two classes of debtors who are to be protected. Although the freedom of the third class to use credit is in fact impaired, any program to improve distribution will probably encroach somewhat on the freedom of others to do what they want. Few will disagree that some limited encroachment on freedom is acceptable if a significant improvement in distribution results. Some critics have also premised their position on a version of utilitarianism. They argue that high ceilings will maximize the sum of social satisfaction, but they fail to inquire whether those less well off at the start are those who end with the greatest improvement.187 A high ceiling program would favor the third class of debtors-those who are aware of the risks of high risk credit and want to use it-all the expense of the first two classes. It is difficult to see how social conditions are improved when the effect of a program is to worsen the lot of the least advantaged classes affected. If the critics have an ethical justification for high ceilings which rests on a different foundation, they have failed to explain it. . Reformers have tended to decide questions of social organization involving the marketplace by an easy reliance upon the standard wisdom that an unregulated market, on balance, will produce the best result. Thus, they first suggest solving a social problem in the marketplace by increasing the conformance of the real market to the intellectual model of the unregulated market. Yet defining the best social organization is an ethical question, and the ethical underpinnings of the results of the unregulated market seem increasingly out of tune with the ethical views of the dominant culture. When the market exposes individuals to risk of severe physical or psychic harm, ethical concerns will likely reject reliance on the unregulated market. The Consumer Product Safety Commission's authority to ban unsafe products is one demonstration of this rejection.188 Therefore, it is no surprise that a close examination of the consumer credit system leads in a similar direction. Rate ceilings will be, in effect, a ban on unsafe credit. What should surprise is the failure to notice the similarity between banning unsafe products and banning unsafe credit. But the model of the unregulated market seems to hold an almost magic fascination; unfortunately, the magic tends to bewitch rather than clarify. Although economic analysis helps identify a reform program's cost and benefits, it also tends to obscure the relevant ethical questions. The only antidote is to inquire continually whether the market will reach an ethically justifiable result. When that question is asked about consumer credit, the answer suggests lowered rate ceilings, inconsistent though they may be with the very essence of an unregulated market. Edit Elizabeth’s piece Add Something by Julia Schorr Chapter 2 A VERY BRIEF HISTORY OF CONSUMER CREDIT IN THE US This chapter provides a brief history of consumer credit in the United States up until 1978.Prior to the crash there were extremely limited sources of information on this topic. Perhaps the best is Lendol Calder’s “Financing the American Dream.” Louis Hyman’s “Borrow, the American Way of Debt” is an excellent example of the more recent work in this area and is particularly useful because it focuses on the history of the supply of dollars to lend as well as the borrowers. Later individual chapters on credit cards, home mortgages and subprime will fill out the story of their history and will carry the story to the present time. 1880 – 1930 Although the history of consumer credit goes back further, we begin in the nineteenth century. The largest early credit program of all was the homestead movement wherein the family “bought” the land and was required to do work on the land within a fixed time to keep it. Financial institutions and certain wealthy individuals were also willing to finance the purchase of farm land. Closely related was the growth of farm equipment lending. This was most often provided by the seller or manufacturer of the equipment and was an example of “useful,” or healthy borrowing. A similar example is the credit extended by the Singer Sewing Machine Company. The early sewing machines were manufactured for industrial use and were too large and expensive for individual consumers. Singer and others soon realized they had a bonanza if they could make smaller units and find a way for consumers to “afford” them. This caught on and became extremely profitable when Singer found a way to provide a credit or financing vehicle. Once again, this was an example of credit about which the borrower could be proud. On the other extreme were the loan sharks who were always there and always ready to finance the consumer need for ready cash. As we move forward into the twentieth century more and more merchants of various types sell items on credit or keep an account for the consumer in order to retain their business. At the beginning of the twentieth century, as more immigrants arrive in the United States, and as cities continue to grow, several different types of borrowing/lending trends intensify. The accounts being kept at merchants grow and add a credit price to a “cash price; eventually this will become the “time price differential” but at this early stage it is simply a way for the merchant to keep the customer and realize a profit for the credit sale. In addition there grew up in poorer sections of urban areas stores that sold only on credit and that employed route men both as salesmen and as collectors. A second major development is the short term balloon method of financing a home purchase. The demand for home mortgage financing grows but the provider of the financing wants to keep their commitment short term. One way of doing this is to make a series of three to five year loans at a fixed interest rate. Both parties assume that the loans can be refinanced at the “going” interest rate at the end of the term and the system works well so long as there is not significant change in the market or economy or interest rates which makes the refinance problematic or impossible. The explosive growth of these short term balloon mortgages was a major factor leading up to the depression of the late 1920’s. When Henry Ford and others started the manufacture and sale of automobiles in the United States in the early part of the twentieth century their initial sales were for cash to wealthy consumers or businesses. Just as in the case of the sewing machine, manufacturers they soon realized that if prices could be reduced and if financing could be made available the potential market for their product would expand enormously. Prices came down as some used cars became a factor in the market and as the assembly line became more efficient. Those developments brought in more buyers but the number of cash buyers even at those reduced prices was severely limited. It became clear to both General Motors and to Ford Motors that auto financing was the key. Because Henry Ford was opposed to buying on credit Ford Motors went very slowly down this route. General Motors had no such reservations and created a financing arm and increased its market share and the its potential customer base extraordinarily and auto finance followed farm equipment finance and sewing machine finance. Neither of these developments satisfied the need of the consumer who wanted some cash to live or to finance something other than a house or a car or a sewing machine or a tractor or something that a merchant would sell “on account.” Credit for consumables was hard to come for the person who did not wish to deal with a loan shark. In a reverse of the installment sale these folks increasingly turned to the pawn shop where they could bring something they already owned, receive a small loan and perhaps buy the item back at a higher price when they had the wherewithal. Pawn shops grew rapidly in number and in importance. In the early part of the twentieth century a number of businesses within the American mercantile mainstream began to try to meet this need for cash. Initially there was moral resistance to this growth; then a number of non-profits organization that purported to be a friend and counselor to the potential borrower entered the foray and advocated for laws that restricted cash lending to well-meaning non-profits. As this development began to be problematic an important report was issued by ERA Seligman that seemed to give the society stamp of approval to the small loan industry. This marked the rebirth of that industry which was shortly followed by legislation allowing them to operate profitably and attract capital. 1930 – 1950 A widespread credit market emerged in the 1920s. The players in the market were large manufacturers, who allowed their customers to pay for goods in installments. This practice was pioneered by the General Motors Acceptance Corporation in 1919, and other manufacturers followed. These programs required a down payment followed by monthly payments for a prearranged time period. Customers were approved for the programs on the basis of their meeting minimum income requirements rather than their personal reputations. Pawns shops continued to thrive in the post war period and various types of small loans have come and gone and come again, this time in the guise of payday loans. The onslaughts of the Depression and World War II stopped the growing flow of consumer credit on its heels. The housing finance arena which looms so large over all other types of consumer credit changed rapidly. Refinancing the short term balloon loans became impossible; that coupled with the millions of home buyers who lost their jobs and became unable to make their monthly payments swelled the number of foreclosures into a true crisis on both a human and economic basis. The government tried a number of programs to halt the foreclosures and provide the refinancing or finance home purchases. Some of these marked the intensification of government involvement in the financing of single family homes that continues today. As the Depression gave way to World War II the government became concerned about inflation, the factories turned from automobiles and consumer appliances to war munitions and the need for consumer credit decreased. The end of the War changed that in many many ways. Returning white male veterans more often moved from the cities to the suburbs; department stores grew in importance and competed for buyer loyalty. Pent up demand for automobiles, consumer appliances and furniture was extraordinary and so the consumer credit tapper was ready to be turned back on and expanded significantly. Historically the dollars that were lent to consumers came from several sources. One memorable example was the bank accounts in the Bailey Building and Loan in Bedford Falls. Individual put their money in savings accounts and the financial institutions lent that money out to folks to buy their homes. Small loan companies fond their dollars either from the owners’ capital investments or from their own borrowing at rates lower than they charged to their borrowers. The government involvement in the home financing arena led to a new source, investments by third parties that were seeking a high return. This could come in the way of stock purchases in the lender or in the development of special purpose entities that purchased the loans from the original lenders. As we will see in the chapter on “where does the money come from: form the Building and Loan to Securitization, the shift in ownership of the loan and the concomitant shift in risk will have important implications. Government financing of homes in the suburbs created heft liabilities for the returning veterans and their spouses; most government sponsored and non-government lending sources provided a long term fixed rate mortgage which became the bedrock of U S financing until late in the twentieth century. As we now know, the shift back to short term balloon loans will have dire consequences during the next crash; indeed it will be a significant cause of that crash. This financing will also be done in a manner which is racially discriminatory since most of these suburbs will not allow a family of color to own a home within its borders. The growth of the department stores during this period and their fierce competition for customer loyalty led to their issuing and urging customers to use their branded credit card. As we will investigate in the chapter on credit cards non store cards took control of this market for thirty or more years, but recently this same store loyalty thirst has reasserted itself. In the middle of the twentieth century, certain companies offered credit cards, similar to modern credit cards. The first was the Diners Club card in 1949, followed by bank cards in the 1950s. The cards entered into widespread use in the 1960s. The concept of the credit card removed the responsibility of credit verification from the seller. Instead, the issuing agency allows the consumer a certain limit that it believes he can and will pay back. This kind of credit is called revolving credit, as opposed to the installment credit that manufacturers and retailers offered. That chapter will explain in greater detail exactly how, during the late 1960’s and the 1970’s the Visa and Mastercard systems became established and developed a strong hold on the consumer borrowing world. Return to the Payday Lending in America featured collection. A hundred years ago, when a mass market for consumer credit did not yet exist, underground purveyors of consumer credit began to emerge, and a variety of problems ensued. “Salary lenders” offered one-week loans at annual percentage rates (APRs) of 120 percent to 500 percent, which are similar to those charged by payday lenders today.[i] To induce repayment, these illegal lenders used wage garnishment, public embarrassment or “bawling out,” extortion and, especially, the threat of job loss.[ii] State policy makers undertook an effort to suppress salary lending while also seeking to facilitate the expansion of consumer credit from licensed lenders. One key change was a targeted exception to the traditional usury interest rate cap for small loans (all original colonies and states capped interest rates in the range of 6 percent per year).[iii] The 1916 publication of the first Uniform Small Loan Law permitted up to 3.5 percent monthly interest on loans of $300 or less. Two-thirds of states adopted some version of this law, authorizing annualized interest rates from 18 to 42 percent, depending on the state.[iv] Subsequently, a market for installment lenders and personal finance companies developed to serve consumer demand for small-dollar credit. By the middle of the 20th century, a mass-market consumer financial industry was emerging. Consumers were gaining access to a wide range of credit products, including mortgages to purchase homes and credit cards to purchase goods and smooth household consumption. State laws started to become inadequate to regulate national lenders. A series of federal banking-law developments in the 1970s and 1980s eased regulations on federally insured depositories, mortgage lenders, credit card lenders, and other financial companies, giving them broad rights to disregard state usury interest laws.[v] As this deregulation proceeded, some state legislatures sought to act in kind for state-based lenders by authorizing deferred presentment transactions (loans made against a post-dated check) and triple-digit APRs.[vi] These developments set the stage for state-licensed payday lending stores to flourish. From the early 1990s through the first part of the 21st century, the payday lending industry grew exponentially.[vii] Today, the landscape for small-dollar credit is changing and several federally chartered banks, most of which have not previously offered these loans, have expanded their roles by offering “deposit advance” loans. These bank products share many characteristics of conventional payday loans, including triple-digit APRs and lump-sum repayment due on the borrower’s next payday. Further, a growing number of companies are providing loans online. These lenders pose challenges for state regulators, as national banks are typically exempt from state lending laws and online providers, who tend to incorporate offshore, on tribal land, or in states without usury caps, often evade state authority.[viii] Though federal law remains mostly silent about payday lending, this situation is changing. The Talent Amendment to the 2007 defense authorization bill sought to protect military families from payday lending. This federal law enacted a first-of-its-kind, 36 percent interest rate limit on payday loans provided to military service members and their immediate relatives. Moreover, the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protect Act of 2010 created the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) and provided the new agency with the authority to regulate payday loans generally.[ix] Until the late nineteenth century, credit markets were limited to the local sphere. In 1800, more than 90 percent of Americans lived in rural communities. Shopkeepers knew the residents of their towns: they knew who could repay debts and who could not. On the basis of their personal knowledge, they sometimes chose to issue credit to reliable customers. Industrialization and Urbanization The system of credit advanced by local retailers grew weaker throughout the nineteenth century. The causes were twofold. First, industrialization gave rise to large companies that eclipsed local shopkeepers. The owners of these companies did not know the communities in which they operated, so they could no longer base credit on reputation. Second, the small rural communities gradually consolidated into cities. Urbanization meant that each store had a much larger clientele, so keeping track of customers and their debts became more difficult. The modern credit market depends on scoring methods that have been devised by credit reporting agencies to quantify each individual's reliability. These scores limit the access that people have to the credit market: loans and credit card approvals are based in large part on the credit agencies' reports. The agencies began with the founding of the Retail Credit Company (now Equifax) in 1899. Its founders realized that business owners had little time to keep track of their customers. Moreover, each business took a risk on each new customer. Businesses were willing to pay for a directory of consumers that rated their trustworthiness. The company began locally and expanded. Today, four major agencies operate in the United States: Equifax, Experian, TransUnion and Innovis. Notes and Questions: Question #1 Thinks about the “sources of the money that is lent and borrowed. Who supplies those dollars (the “product” being “sold”)? Who actually make the loan or credit extension? What is each of those parties looking for? Consider the role that each of these “providers” of borrowing dollars has played over history. Family Loan shark Retailer/clothing Retailer/furniture Retailer/ peddler Pawn shop Charity Car sales or credit Builder and Loan Associations US Government BANKER Question # 2 Think about the following factors as limiting or expanding factors regarding the amount and ease of borrowing/lending. Law usury rules or not; Difference between cash sales and credit sales; Cultural climate; Moral climate etc Economic climate; Repayment potential Purchasing climate Other QUESTION #3 What did people need / want to buy that they may not have had cash for and were they credit worthy? Why did consumption increase so sharply after WW? Consider the effect of post WW2 suburbanization on consumer credit; What role did department stores and their willingness or unwillingness to provide credit have? Chapter 3 Auto and Installment Debt FROM BORROW BY LOUIS HYMAN CHAPTER TWO EVERYBODY PAID CASH FOR THE MODEL T (1908-1929) The second most expensive purchase most of us ever make is a car, and when Americans think of cars, we think of Henry Ford. Though fewer of us today drive Fords than Hondas, Henry Ford's name is forever linked to the automobile. Yet the auto loan, which makes buying cars possible, has nothing to do with Henry Ford, despite being invented at just about the same time as his car company, Ford Motor Company. Indeed, Henry Ford fought tooth and nail not to sell his cars through installment credit and in the process nearly destroyed his company. Where did auto loans come from, if not from the father of the car? And why did he resist helping his customers buy his cars? Before 1919, nearly all cars, including the Model T, were sold for cash. As one General Motors executive remarked, the car had "given us all something worth working for."1 It was the ultimate luxury good, giving purpose to the savings of millions of Americans. The best-selling car in the United States and the world was the Model T from Henry Ford, whose innovative production techniques transformed the car from a hobbyist curio into a mass-market love affair. Before Henry Ford, the automobile languished as a hobbyist's gadget, a rich man's plaything. Usually the Germans Karl Benz and Gottlieb Daimler are credited with its invention in 1885, and by the 1890s many varieties of car proliferated in Europe. In the United States alone there were around 2,500 automobile companies. But none of these start-ups managed to transform cars into a mass-consumption item. Hand-tooled and built one by one, they were expensive oddities. A few guys got together and made cars piece by piece. The parts were never interchangeable. Each one required a great deal of skill to produce, and the prices of the cars were unbelievable. In the United States the story was largely the same as in Europe. In the 1890s, there were already about thirty companies building cars. By 1909, the low-volume, high-price model of automobile production was standard for the nearly three hundred American automobile companies. All except for one: Ford Motor Company. The introduction of the Model T in 1908 changed U.S. industry forever. But the Model T was not the first car Ford worked on. The company had started in 1903. What happened in those first five years? Models A, B, C, F, K, N, R, and S all came and went as Ford struggled to find the right car for the American market. He aimed for a car that would suit not only a high-end novelty audience but a mass market as well. He wrote in 1906 that "the greatest need today is a light low-priced car with an up-to-date engine of ample horsepower, and built of the very best material."2 Ford sold the initial Model Ts for $850 but by 1924 dropped the price to only $290, which is amazing considering the rising inflation of the period. Quality was key, but so was price. How to reconcile the two? Ford dropped the production time of a Model T from twelve and half hours in 1908 to less than thirty minutes by 1914. The car stayed the same while the machines used to produce the cars constantly improved. In 1915, Ford Motor Company celebrated its millionth sale. Ford always thought of himself as a mechanic first and a businessman last. While "business men believed that you could do anything by 'financing' it," Ford "determined absolutely that [he] never would... join a company in which finance came before the work or in which bankers or financiers had a part."5 Ford, more than anything else, was a builder of cars, He liked to know how they worked. He liked to improve them. Selling cars was great, but that was secondary to building a quality machine. Once you had a great machine, he would say, the only thing left to decide was its price,48 Though Ford remained in the hands of the original mechanics who built cars, by 1920 GM, through a series of corporate intrigues, had passed into the control of the Du Font Corporation, famed for its ability to organize finance as well as production. So on the one hand there was Ford Motor Company, headed by one man, who believed in nothing but production, and on the other hand there was a vast corporation, drawing on the organizational resources of many different men and predicated entirely on profit. For the auto industry to continue the breakneck growth of the 1910s, new ways to sell cars would have to be found. Though Henry Ford saw finance as antithetical to production, General Motors saw salvation in finance. Then, as now, most Americans bought their cars in the summer. Yet for factories to be run profitably, they had to be run 24/7, even in the winter. Who would pay for the storage of all the excess production? Once production began to seriously outpace seasonal demand, GM hit upon a clever idea. GM would finance dealers' purchases of cars from the factory. Then the automaker wouldn't have to deal with the excess inventory, and dealers would have stock on hand for any potential customers. If you think the dealers got the raw end of the deal, you would be right. They had to pay for cars that could not be sold until the summer, while GM got the interest on the financing, plus the profitable operation of the factory. But a dealer had little choice in the matter, since GM could easily stop selling its cars and simply find another dealership that was willing to play ball. One of Du Font's vice presidents, a finance expert named John Raskob, set up a new subsidiary corporation to handle this new financing plan, General Motors Acceptance Corporation (GMAC). Though originally created to handle wholesale dealership financing, GMAC eventually realized that consumers had financing problems of their own. Though dealers were loath to go into debt to deal with GM's excess inventory problem, consumers clamored to borrow. In the first few years of the 1920s, small finance companies across the country recognized the opportunity and began to offer consumers the option to borrow against their rising wages. Recognizing the possibilities to be found, in lending to consumers, GMAC expanded beyond just lending to dealers. Still, by 1924, GMAC provided about 5 percent of the total annual profit for GM and its subsidiary companies. Whereas the General Motors Annual Report for 1919 describes the primary purpose of GMAC as "to assist dealers in financing their purchase of General Motors' products," by 1927, the GMAC annual report describes "providing] credit to the consumer of goods as its most important func¬tion."11 Though we might think of GM's shift to financing as a relatively recent phenomenon, its long road from a manufacturing company to a finance company began nearly at its outset. By 1927, GMAC's annual gross revenues totaled more than $40 million, and its assets totaled more than $300 million. In 1926, GMAC connected high finance with consumer finance for the first time. To maintain its growth, GMAC issued its first 6 percent bond in February 1926. The investment bank J.P. Morgan sold the bonds, raising $50 million in cash.12 Begun only seven years earlier, GMAC had assets of $275 million, or 30 percent of General Motors proper.13 The successful 1926 bond issue was followed in 1927 by another $50 million sale, giving GMAC the capital it needed to grow.14 Ford, in contrast, relied on its own pro fits—called retained earnings—to fund its growth. In 1926, it dispersed 62 percent of profits to stockholders and reinvested an ample $64 million in its operations. Automobile companies, in particular, did not tend to rely on loans. Car companies tended to fund only 2.3 percent of their capital from bond issues, compared to 9 percent in other industries. Yet even among that relatively debt-free industry, Ford stood out, with only 0.02 percent—$145,000-—of its capital backed by bonds.15 Finance enabled GMAC to expand, which in turn allowed GM to expand. Raskob imagined consumer credit as an alternative to socialism, since credit might make possible "the dream haven of plenty for everybody and fair shake for all, which the socialists have pointed out to mankind. But our route will be by the capitalist road of upbuilding rather than by the socialistic road of tearing down."16 Financing also made money: by the late 1920s, auto sales faltered, but the number of cars financed by GMAC grew from 646,000 in 1926 to 824,190 in 1927. In 1927, GMAC financed slightly over one million GM cars. Henry Ford, meanwhile, fought back against putting Americans in debt. As GM became the leading American car company in 1927, Ford groused, "1 sometimes wonder if we have not lost our buying sense and fallen entirely under the spell of salesmanship. The American of a generation ago was a shrewd buyer. He knew values in the terms of utility and dollars. But nowadays the American people seem to listen 1920s, GM had become the dominant auto manufacturer in America and Ford struggled to keep up as it rapidly lost profits and market share. By that point the Model T was nearly twenty years old, and its low-price design had never changed. It had no roof. It had no shock absorbers, no electric starter, no battery-powered ignition. It came in. any color you liked, as long as that color was black. Americans were now willing to pay more to get a car with a color—and a roof. And they were willing to borrow to do so. Within, ten years of World War I, installment sales of automobiles rose to 60 percent of total car sales—from zero. Ford resisted consumer choice and consumer finance at every turn. By the late 1920s, nearly all goods could be had on the installment plan. Cars and radios could be bought on time, and so too could vacuum cleaners, phonographs, washing machines, cabinets, clothes, and nearly anything else. Conservatives worried that all this borrowing—implicitly a lack of saving—reflected a failure of the American character. Republican senator James Couzens of Michigan, an early investor in Ford Motor Company and lifelong friend of Henry Ford, was an outspoken critic of installment credit. The "growing evil" of installment credit, he said, "results in weakening of character and neglect of the more substantial things of life."25 Budgeting to spend instead of budgeting to save, Couzens thought, undermined, the purpose of budgets. Echoing today's denunciations, he could "say from [his] personal knowledge that the education of children, their physical well-being generally, even the care of their teeth are being neglected to enable families to purchase on installments many luxuries [sic]." "If this is sound," he said, "then let the orgy proceed." It did. Retailers and manufacturers, ignoring politics in favor of profits, learned to lend, creating finance companies not just for automobiles but for everything, linking consumers' desire with banks' capital. One of the main justifications for all this lending was, of course, the character of the people who borrowed. Early-twentieth-century "Credit men" evaluated borrowers by what they called the four Cs: "character, capacity, capital, [and] collateral," of which character, it was claimed, was the basic rock foundation of the four big Cs.26 If borrowing required character and. the act of borrowing itself eroded character, then all those credit men were in quite a fix. Luckily it was not just character but the other Cs that mattered as well. More important than character was the stability of income. Even the Saturday Evening Post could explain, in 1928, that a car loan "cannot be sold with safety to a man with even a large income if he has no stability and no character."27 While character, depending on what one thinks, is within our control, stability often is not. Couzens's "warning against the continuance of practices which everyone who has had any experience at all knows to be unsound, unwise, and dangerous" went happily ignored as long as the economy chugged stably along. Those who grumbled, like the economist C. Reinhold Noyes writing in the Yale Review, about "financing prosperity on tomorrow's income" and the inevitability of the business cycle were unheeded.28 Noyes held "the motor industry to be the storm centre of the next period of depression, and it will be entirely to blame" for infusing installment credit so thoroughly into the economy. The Depression, which he correctly predicted in 1927 to be "two or three years" away, would be "automatic and inevitable" as it was the result of "retribution for economic sin,"29 The "various bubbles" of cars and houses would burst and. drag down the economy. Noyes, like all bellyachers, was blissfully ignored. The celebrated economic pundits pronounced the late 1920s as a New Era forever free of recession. Expansion, made possible by the electrical age and enabled through credit, would continue forever. Another Yale economist, Irving Fisher—much more famous1 than Noyes for his optimism—pronounced in 1929 that stocks, in this new economy, would never fall again. And then, three days later the world—including Yale-watched slack-jawed as the stock market crashed. CHAPTER 4 CREDIT CARDS GOALS FOR THIS CHAPTER To understand how the credit card developed in the US To understand its explosive growth in the 1980 – 2000 period To understand its development from 2000 – 2012 To predict the future To understand where the credit card fits in with other payment vehicles and consumer credit vehicles In 2010 The BBC produced a series with the lofty title “The History of the World in 100 Objects.” The modern day credit card is and deserves to be one of those 100 objects. When this course was first taught in the late 1990’s the story of consumer credit seemed to be the story of American Love Affair with the Credit Card. This was true even though total credit card debt is just a small fraction of mortgage debt and has even been eclipsed by educational debt. It remains vitally important today, but its importance economically, and anthropologically in the years from 1988 to 2000 cannot be overstated. Before we begin with a quick look at the history of the credit card it is interesting to note that in Canada and various other countries around the globe the debit card and the credit card arrived simultaneously and a great many consumers preferred the debit card. No borrowing (except for charges for overdraft protection) !!! Yet in the United States the credit card was deeply ensconced in the wallet and the brain and the soul of the American consumer before the debit card arrived. Timing may not have been “everything” but it was at least almost everything. There are some who believe the difference in profitability between the debit card and the credit card provided the rationale for the timing that occurred. QUESTION #1 ; In what ways is credit card debt different from other types of consumer debt such as purchase money mortgage debt, auto debt and educational debt? Part of the reason is that it is so directly tied to purchasing. It is so tempting and with no delay a consumer can decide to purchase something they may or may not be able to afford and buy it now with no scrutiny and perhaps without even much thought or consideration. It is so tempting It is so important to the growth of American consumer spending. To start with some numbers to give a quick sense of the growth. ( in Billions) 1980 1984 1990 1994 2004 $54 Billion 79 214 313 753 and then look at the ancient history of the credit card in the United States. Commentators disagree on the beginning of credit card debt; the primary source of information is by Professor Mandel but Borrow by Louis Hyman has a good section as well. The story is fairly simple though it has its fits and starts. STAGE ONE 1950 - 1980 It starts on at least two separate tracks, the growth of single source cards from department stores and the oil companies and the growth of Diners Club, travel and entertainment cards which could be used more broadly. There were two primary challenges for the growth of the business. First and more simple was the technology; second was the “chicken and egg” problem of needing customers to use the card before retailers became interested and needing retailers before customers became interested Diners Club, one of the first of these “universal” cards began to be issued in the early 1950’s and persevered past these problems. It was used mostly by salesmen who were traveling into their territory. It is often called the pioneer of the use of a third party to act as a go between for the salesman and the restaurant or hotel. Once it began to thrive, American Express and Carte Blanch followed its lead. Most of these early cards were “convenience” cards and not “credit” cards and they required full payment upon full payment upon receipt of the bill. . Bank of America dove in on the west coast in the 1950’s and invited great numbers of largely undifferentiated consumers to sign up. The costs of the effort were considerable, the results although disappointing were large enough to show the lack of credit standards and various other problems when both billing errors and delinquencies mounted. . Bank of America persevered in its own right as an issuer and extender of credit and expanded to provide the infrastructure under which other banks might issue credit cards affiliated with the BankAmericard system. Eventually those other banks resented paying a competitor and the VISA system was created In order to compete with BankAmericard/VISA other banks joined together to in various associations in what became the InterBank Card, the Mastercharge and then the MasterCard system. There was a popular negative reaction to the unsolicited mailings which had swelled the ranks of the card holders and Congress passed a series of bills intended to regulate the fast growing industry. American Express passed Diners Club and Carte Blanch by and continued to grow. These travel and expense cards as they were called charged a monthly fee, catered to high income card holders and were reasonably profitable. On the other hand, the startup costs combined with higher delinquencies than the T and E cards presented challenges to the profitability of the bank cards. This was exacerbated as the large retailers refused to honor bank cards. Competitive factors kept the banks from charging monthly or annual fees and state law usury rates kept them from charging meaningful interest rates. As a partial antidote the banks tried innovative ways of becoming more profitable. This was the state of bank credit cards in 1980 as interest rates started to soar and bank cards were about to enter stage two of their development and growth. JC Penneys, which had led the resistance to the honoring of bank cards surprised everyone when they changed course and began to accept the cards. This opened the floodgates and they were followed by most of the other large department stores that had previously held out. Lewis Mandell was one of the early scholars of the credit card. The following excerpt from the Introduction to his work entitled: The Credit Card Industry: A History is helpful. STAGE TWO 1980 – 1990. This stage was marked by an extraordinary increase in the number of consumer borrowers with excellent credit scores and the amount each borrowed. The competition for market share was extreme and billions of preapproved applications were sent in the mail. Just as with the current markets for cell phones or computers in Asia, the profit potential in selling credit this way to Americans seemed unlimited and without parallel in the financial services industry. The 1980’s witnessed a sea change in the profitability of credit card operations. Technology and the beginnings of securitization helped but higher interest rates charged to an increasing number of the same kinds of card holders were the jet fuel on this sea change. STAGE THREE 1990 – 2000 Beginning in about 1990 a number of additional factors combined to allow the financial institutions to reach out far beyond its historical customer base to consumer borrowers with lower credit scores and to impose fees and penalties of all kinds that would stretch profitability beyond belief. For a fascinating article in which the FDIC asked all the right questions but came up with all the wrong answers please read carefully this article. http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/fyi/2003/091703fyi.html STAGE FOUR 2000 – 2007 By 2000, the potential of new customers had become more limited and the companies were working hard to take customers from one another. The concentration among the issuer-lenders had intensified and the top six now had a majority of the market. This allowed them to begin to charge greater fees for the use of the cards. The run up in real estate values combined with very low interest rates and certain tax advantages combined to empower a serous rival, the home equity line of credit. If a consumer was a homeowner then she could likely borrow against the recent increase in the value of her house at a lower interest rate and with an IRS subsidy on the payment of that interest. We will study this development in greater detail in the chapter on home mortgages, but suffice to say that consumer borrowing shifted away from credit cards to home equity lines of credit. In many cases the consumer paid down her credit card balance with the proceeds of the home equity loan or line of credit, but in some cases they built them right back up. Growth rates for credit card debts were smaller, partly because of home equity lending and partly because the base was so much higher than it had been twenty years before. The Mechanics of Payment Card Transactions The distinctions between ATM cards, charge cards, credit cards, and debit cards are largely invisible to the ordinary user. Still, those differences are critical to informed policymakers. To set the stage, this chapter discusses the mechanics of credit and debit card transactions, providing basic information on the economics of payment cards, primarily from the perspective of the merchant. The Credit Card Transaction Most credit card transactions involve four participants: a purchaser that pays with a credit card, an issuer that issues the credit card, a merchant that sells goods or services, and an acquirer that collects payment for the merchant. The acquirer is so named because it "acquires" the transaction from the merchant and then processes it to obtain payment from the issuer. In American Express and Discover transactions, the same entity that issues the card also acquires the transaction. That arrangement is called a three-party or closed-loop system. Although the purchaser, issuer, merchant, and acquirer are the nominal parties to the transaction, the network under which the card has been issued (usually Visa or MasterCard) is also involved. The networks (associations of member banks that issue Visa or MasterCard branded cards) provide information and transaction-processing services with respect to the transaction between the acquirer and the issuer. For example, when an acquirer has transactions involving Visa-branded cards, it will use VisaNet to communicate with the issuer of the card to obtain authorization and payment for the transaction. Perhaps more importantly, Visa and MasterCard (and the other network providers) establish and enforce rules and standards surrounding the use of cards carrying their brands that govern the contract between the acquirer and the issuer. Instead of negotiating a separate agreement with each issuer, each acquirer simply joins the relevant network and agrees to comply with the network rules for all transactions on that network. For example the network rules specify for all entities in the network the fees that the issuer will deduct from each transaction when it forwards payment to the acquirer. Although the network rules are central to the operation of the system, they are proprietary documents, owned by the networks, and thus not readily available. The key to any credit card transaction is the relationship between the cardholder and the card issuer. The typical relationship is familiar. The issuer commits to pay for purchases made with the card, in return for the cardholder's promise to reimburse the issuer over time. That relationship is the opposite of the common checking relationship, where the customer normally must deposit funds before the bank will pay checks. The buy-first, pay-later aspect of most credit-card relationships alters the underlying economics of the system. Banks that provide checking accounts can earn profits by investing the funds that customers have placed in their accounts. A credit card issuer does not have that option, because most cardholders do not deposit funds before they make purchases on their cards. Indeed, at least in the United States, the cardholder often does not even have a depositary relation with the card issuer. Traditionally and predominantly, the profit for the typical card issuer comes from the interest that the issuer earns on the balances its cardholders carry on their cards from month to month. The business models have become more diverse in recent years. Some major full-service issuers like Bank of America, Wells Fargo and JP Morgan Chase, for example, use relationships to create synergies among a broad portfolio of products. The centrality of this strategy is epitomized by Wells Fargo's annual report, the theme of which is its corporate commitment to have seven of its products in the hands of each of its customers. For these issuers, the profit conies from creating switching costs so that the banks can charge higher fee levels without losing customers to competitors. A second group of issuers, banks such as MBNA, Providian and Capital One, focus on cards as individual profit centers. Those issuers often are called monolines, because they typically do not offer depositary accounts or other traditional consumer banking products. Monolines rely for a large part of their income on interest and fees. Even among those issuers, though, there is a considerable amount of specialization. MBNA, for example, uses sophisticated data mining to profit in a market niche for loyalty cards, attractive to upper middle class card users. Those cards and other premium-brand loyalty cards typically carry a substantial annual fee. By contrast, Providian and Capital One traditionally have emphasized cardholders of considerably lower credit quality. Still other issuers focus entirely on highly risky subprime cardholders. As a matter of industry structure, the monolines are important because they give each potential cardholder multiple issuers from which to select credit cards. This is not true in other countries. For example, in England and in France, the majority of cards are issued by banks that hold deposit accounts for the cardholders. It is fair to say that the card industry in those countries has not shown as rapid a pace of product innovation or as aggressive a competition on price as the United States card industry. That structure has been in considerable flux. In 2005, large mainstream financial institutions acquired several of the prominent monolines. Although the ultimate competitive implications of those mergers are difficult to assess, it seems clear that one of the dominating motivations was the need of monoline issuers to lower the cost of their funds. It is clear from the annual reports of the acquired entities that these acquisitions would increase the profitability of the monolines even if the acquiring entities made no changes in business operations and were unable to create any synergies with their existing customer bases. To give a sense for the overall revenue structure of the industry, as it currently exists, Figure 2.2 displays the sources of the $100 billion in 2004 revenues for United States bank card issuers. American Household Credit Card Debt Statistics: 2013 The average US household credit card debt stands at $15,325, the result of a small number of deeply indebted households forcing up the numbers. Based on an analysis of Federal Reserve statistics and other government data, the average household owes $7,149 on their cards; looking only at indebted households, the average outstanding balance rises to $15,325. Here are statistics, trends, studies and methodology behind the average U.S. household debt. Current as of July 2013 U.S. household consumer debt profile: • Average credit card debt: $15,325 • Average mortgage debt: $147,924 • Average student loan debt: $32,041 In total, American consumers owe: • $11.16 trillion in debt o A decrease of 1.6% from last year • $856.5 billion in credit card debt • $7.86 trillion in mortgages • $999.3 billion in student loans • An increase of 6.1% from last year Deep dive: credit card debt Credit card debt is the third largest source of household indebtedness. Only the mortgage and student loan debt markets are larger. Here are the latest credit card debt statistics from the Federal Reserve: Total Credit Card Debt Average Household Credit Card Debt Average Indebted Household Debt . Between 2006 and 2008, credit card debt rose steadily and reached its height in January 2009, six months into the financial crisis, as unemployment soared and defaults began in earnest. From there, average debt loads took a sharply downward trajectory and dipped below 2006 levels in mid-2010. 2011, however, saw the decline in average debt become a plateau, and debt levels have since then hovered around $15,600. There is a broad consensus on why indebtedness rose during the boom years: low interest rates and easy access to credit brought Americans to take on record levels of debt. However, the data still leaves two questions: • Why did indebtedness decline in 2009 and 2010? • Why has indebtedness plateaued since then? Why did indebtedness fall in 2009 and 2012? Ideally, debt levels would have fallen because newly frugal Americans paid off their credit card balances. However, a number of not-so-pleasant factors contributed to the decline. In 2010, credit card companies wrote off seriously delinquent debts in earnest, lowering the total amount of revolving credit card debt. The charge-off rate – the percentage of dollars owed that issuers have written off as uncollectable – rose to 10.9% in the second quarter of 2010. This represented an increase of over 300% from the first quarter of 2006, when the charge-off rate was only 3.1%. Charge-offs account for a significant portion of the debt reduction. The graph says it all: between the fourth quarter of 2009 and the fourth quarter of 2010, average household debt fell by $2,722. The speed with which average debt fell indicates that loans were written off, rather than paid off. As a result of those losses, spooked credit card companies tightened their purse strings. Stricter lending standards also contributed to a fall in total credit card debt. Those two factors – fewer loans, made to more creditworthy consumers – are troubling, as they speak to a one-off correction rather than an improvement in underlying factors such as increased income or fiscal prudence. Why did indebtedness plateau in 2011? As the economy limps forward, credit card companies increasingly loosen their lending standards. Confident that consumers will be able to pay off their debts, the issuers allow more people to borrow more money. NerdWallet expects household indebtedness to resume an upward trend in the coming years as creditors become more lenient. Methodology Household indebtedness estimates can only be considered reliable when three sets of data were released at approximately the same time: • The U.S. Census, taken by the federal government every 10 years, tells us how many American households there are; • The Aggregate Revolving Consumer Debt Survey, taken monthly by the Federal Reserve, tells us how much debt is outstanding, in total; and • The Survey of Consumer Finances, taken by the Federal Reserve every 3-5 years, tells us the percentage of families with credit card debt. The last date at which this occurred was March 31st, 2010. To estimate consumer debt in June of 2012, we extrapolated from the following data sets: • The 2010 U.S. Census (2 years out of date) • The 2009 Survey of Consumer Finances (3 years out of date) We also use the Aggregate Revolving Consumer Debt survey, which is current. Mortgage, student loan and auto loan data come from the New York Federal Reserve’s Household Credit Report. Notes about 2012 data: NerdWallet used a straight-line extrapolation to estimate the number of household units each month, based on census estimates from 2005 as well as official census data from 2010. The percentage of credit card approval rates is updated every few years by the Federal Reserve, and was last published in March 2011 covering a survey period from 2007 to 2009. NerdWallet’s monthly estimates of this figure are based on internal data of credit card approval rates. Average U.S. household credit card debt by quarter, 2006-2012 Quarter Average debt/household Average debt/ indebted household 1Q2006 $7,826 $16,373 2Q2006 $7,926 $16,582 3Q2006 $8,008 $16,752 4Q2006 $8,123 $16,994 1Q2007 $8,237 $17,232 2Q2007 $8,367 $17,505 3Q2007 $8,543 $17,873 4Q2007 $8,740 $18,285 1Q2008 $8,329 $17,425 2Q2008 $8,416 $17,607 3Q2008 $8,440 $17,759 4Q2008 $8,341 $17,874 1Q2009 $8,186 $17,871 2Q2009 $7,963 $17,718 3Q2009 $7,750 $17,582 4Q2009 $7,516 $17,356 1Q2010 $7,281 $16,633 2Q2010 $7,101 $15,910 3Q2010 $6,939 $15,250 4Q2010 $6,816 $14,702 1Q2011 $6,746 $14,461 2Q2011 $6,730 $14,427 3Q2011 $6,708 $14,380 4Q2011 $6,753 $14,476 1Q2012 $6,754 $14,479 2Q2012 $7,224 $15,485 3Q2012 $7,160 $15,348 4Q2012 $7,168 $15,366 Average U.S. household credit card debt by year, 2006-2012 Year Average debt/household Average debt/ indebted household 2006 $7,971 $16,675 2007 $8,472 $17,724 2008 $8,382 $17,666 2009 $7,854 $17,632 2010 $7,034 $15,624 2011 $6,734 $14,436 2012 $7,172 $15,374 Credit Performance Loan Charge-Offs The charge-off statistics released by the Federal Reserve Board are calculated from data available in the Report of Condition and Income (Call Report), filed each quarter by all commercial banks. Charge-off rates for any category of loan are defined as the flow of a bank's net charge-offs (gross charge-offs minus recoveries) during a quarter divided by the average level of its loans outstanding over that quarter. Data for each calendar quarter become available approximately 60 days after the end of the quarter. Access at: http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/chargeoff/ Loan Charge-Offs 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Q3.12 Q4.12 Charge-Off Rate1 (SAAR, %) Consumer Loans 2.01 2.50 3.53 5.49 5.88 3.62 2.47 2.50 Credit Cards 3.54 4.00 5.52 9.40 9.34 5.68 3.86 4.06 Residential Real Estate Loans2 0.10 0.26 1.28 2.36 2.12 1.58 1.74 1.08 Net Charge-Offs3 (NSA, $ Mil) Consumer Loans $16,314 $21,987 $34,190 $52,961 $74,345 $43,010 $7,305 $7,558 Credit Cards $11,007 $13,339 $19,950 $34,883 $61,886 $35,017 $5,788 $5,906 Residential Real Estate Loans2 $1,835 $5,036 $25,513 $49,540 $44,273 $32,155 $9,058 $5,669 Source: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council. FRB Call Report. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Notes: SAAR = seasonally adjusted annual rate, NSA = not seasonally adjusted 1 Charge-off rate is the flow of a bank's net charge-offs (gross charge-offs minus recoveries) during a quarter divided by the average level of its loan outstanding over that quarter multiplied by 400 to express the ratio as an annual percentage rate. Charged-off loans are reported on schedule RI-B and the average levels of loans on schedule RC-K. 2 Residential real estate loans include loans secured by one- to four-family properties, including home equity lines of credit. 3 Charge-offs are the value of loans and leases removed from the books and charged against loss reserves. Credit Card Charge-Offs: Managed Assets Basis* This chart is derived from data available in the Report of Condition and Income (Call Report), filed each quarter by all commercial banks. The charge-off rate is calculated by dividing the sum of on- and off-balance-sheet credit card net charge-offs (gross chargeoffs minus recoveries) during a quarter by the on- and off-balance-sheet total amount outstanding for the end of the previous quarter. *The charge-off rate presented here may vary slightly from measures reported by the Board because the Board’s charge-off rate is calculated on the basis of average quarterly credit card assets. (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/chargeoff/) Source: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council. FRB Call Report. Note: The on-balance-sheet net charge-offs calculation comes from the aggregation of variables RIADB514 (gross charge-offs) and RIADB515 (recoveries) from the Call Report. The total amount outstanding for on-balance-sheet assets comes from the aggregation of variable RCFDB538 from the Call Report. For off-balance-sheet assets, the calculation of net charge-offs comes from the aggregation of variables RIADB749 (gross charge-offs) and RIADB756 (recoveries) from the Call Report. The total amount outstanding for off-balance-sheet assets comes from the aggregation of variable RCFDB707 from the Call Report. The bars depict on- and off-balance-sheet charge-offs in the quarter in which they occurred. The charge-off rate is the ratio of net charge-offs realized in the quarter divided by the sum of on- and off-balance-sheet credit card assets from the end of the previous quarter. Loan Delinquencies The delinquency statistics presented on the Federal Reserve Board's website are calculated from data available in the Report of Condition and Income (Call Report), filed each quarter by all commercial banks. The delinquency rate for any loan category is the ratio of the dollar amount of a bank's delinquent loans in that category to the dollar amount of total loans outstanding in that category. Data for each calendar quarter become available approximately 60 days after the end of the quarter. Access at: http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/chargeoff/ Loan Delinquencies 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Q3.12 Q4.12 Delinquency Rate1 (SAAR, %) Consumer Loans 2.90 3.13 3.76 4.70 4.15 3.23 2.77 2.62 Credit Cards 4.01 4.25 5.03 6.53 4.90 3.54 2.82 2.73 Residential Real Estate Loans2 1.73 2.54 4.99 9.14 10.84 10.41 10.60 10.07 Delinquencies3 (NSA, EOP, $ Mil) Consumer Loans $26,104 $33,737 $44,007 $46,140 $46,064 $38,573 $33,554 $33,684 Credit Cards $13,738 $17,376 $22,935 $24,368 $27,489 $20,950 $17,295 $17,563 Residential Real Estate Loans2 $39,925 $65,942 $145,024 $232,739 $220,389 $217,754 $221,307 $215,039 Source: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council. FRB Call Report. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Notes: NSA = not seasonally adjusted, EOP = end of period 1 "Delinquency Rate" is delinquent loan/lease as a percent of end-of-period loan/lease balance 2 Residential real estate loans include loans secured by one- to four-family properties, including home equity lines of credit. 3 Delinquent loans include those past due 30 days or more and still accruing interest, as well as those on nonaccrual status. Credit Standards and the Demand for Credit The data used to describe banks’ credit standards and demand for consumer loans come from two questions asked by the Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey (SLOOS). This survey covers approximately 60 large domestic banks and 24 U.S. branches and agencies of foreign banks. The Federal Reserve generally conducts the survey quarterly, timing it so that results are available for the January/February, April/May, August, and October/November meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee. Questions cover changes in the standards and terms of the banks' lending and the state of business and household demand for loans, or occasionally specific topics of current interest. Access at: http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/snloansurvey/ Note: The height of the line in the above graph is the net percentage of banks tightening credit standards for new credit card applicants. Note: The height of the line in the above graph is the net percentage of banks with strengthening demand for consumer loans. Debit Cards The data used to describe debit cards come from the 2007 and 2010 Federal Reserve Payments Studies and The Nilson Report, a twice-monthly newsletter based in Carpinteria, California. The Federal Reserve Payments Study is a triennial survey of the payments industry first conducted in 2001. These studies are part of a Federal Reserve System effort to track noncash payments in the United States, and they reflect the efforts of hundreds of organizations across the country. Nilson kindly permits some of its data to be included in tabulations that appear in the U.S. Census Bureau’s Statistical Abstract of the U.S. We include data from the 2009 edition here. More recent data should be obtained directly from Nilson. Access at: • The 2010 Federal Reserve Payments Study Return on Assets at Large U.S. Credit Card Banks (%) Year Return 2001 3.24 2002 3.28 2003 3.66 2004 3.55 2005 2.85 2006 3.34 2007 2.75 2008 1.43 2009 -3.01 2010 2.36 2011 5.25 Note: Credit card banks are commercial banks with average managed assets (loans to individuals, including securitizations) greater than or equal to $200 million with a minimum 50 percent of assets in consumer lending and 90 percent of consumer lending in the form of revolving credit. Profitability of credit card banks is measured as net pretax income as a percentage of average quarterly outstanding balances. Source: Report of Condition and Income (Call Report) Consumer Borrowing Falls as Less Is Put on Credit Cards By THE ASSOCIATED PRESS Published: September 10, 2012 WASHINGTON (AP) — Americans cut back on their credit card use in July for a second consecutive month, suggesting that many remain cautious in the face of high unemployment and slow growth. The New York Times Total consumer borrowing dipped $3.3 billion in July from June, to a seasonally adjusted $2.705 trillion, the Federal Reserve reported Monday. The drop in credit card debt offset a small rise in a measure of auto and student loans. The Fed also said Americans had borrowed much more than previously estimated after it revised consumer borrowing data back to December 2010. June’s figure was increased to $2.708 trillion, or $130 billion more than initially thought. That is also well above prerecession levels. Consumer debt declined even though Americans increased their spending in July by the most in five months, according to government data released last week. Consumers have been using credit cards much less since the 2008 financial crisis. Four years ago, Americans had $1.03 trillion in credit card debt, a record high. In July, it was $850.7 billion, 17 percent lower. During that same time, student loan debt has increased sharply. The category that includes auto and student loans, along with other loans for items like boats, has jumped to $1.85 trillion from $1.56 trillion in July 2008. The weak job market is putting more pressure on the Federal Reserve to provide more help to the anemic economy. The Fed’s policy makers will meet Wednesday and Thursday to consider whether to take further action at this time. The economy is growing too slowly to bolster business and consumer confidence and spur sustained gains in spending and hiring. Overall economic growth slowed to an annual rate of just 1.7 percent in the April-June quarter and analysts do not expect much of a pickup for the rest of the year. Over all, Americans have been steadily paring debt since the financial crisis. Household debt, including mortgages and home equity lines of credit, has declined for 16 straight quarters to $12.9 trillion in March, according to a separate Fed survey on consumer finances. That is down from $13.8 trillion in March 2008. is largely due to defaults rather than repayment Debit card usage • THE AVERAGE DEBIT CARD HOLDER SPENT $8,326 ON THE DEBIT CARD IN 2011, UP FROM $7,781 IN 2010.38 • ACTIVE DEBIT CARD USERS PERFORMED AN AVERAGE OF 18.3 PURCHASES A MONTH WITH THEIR DEBIT CARDS IN 2011 COMPARED WITH 16.3 A MONTH IN 2010.38 • THE AVERAGE PRICE ON A DEBIT TRANSACTION IN 2011 WAS $38. THE MEDIAN PRICE ON A DEBIT TRANSACTION IN 2011 WAS $19. MORE THAN 30 PERCENT OF DEBIT TRANSACTIONS IN 2011 WERE LESS THAN $10.38 • 63 PERCENT OF DEBIT CARD HOLDERS SURVEYED IN 2011 SAID THEY USED THEIR DEBIT CARDS MOST OFTEN TO PAY FOR GROCERIES, COMPARED WITH 19 PERCENT WHO SAID CREDIT CARDS AND 13 PERCENT WHO SAID CASH.37 • 50 PERCENT OF DEBIT CARD HOLDERS SURVEYED IN 2011 SAID THEY USED THEIR DEBIT CARDS MOST OFTEN TO PAY FOR GASOLINE, COMPARED TO 25 PERCENT WHO SAID CREDIT CARDS AND 13 PERCENT WHO SAID CASH.37 • 50 PERCENT OF DEBIT CARD HOLDERS SURVEYED IN 2011 SAID THEY USED THEIR DEBIT CARDS MOST OFTEN TO PAY AT DISCOUNT STORES, COMPARED WITH 17 PERCENT WHO SAID CREDIT CARDS AND 23 PERCENT WHO SAID CASH.37 • 47 PERCENT OF DEBIT CARD HOLDERS SURVEYED IN 2011 SAID THEY USED THEIR DEBIT CARDS MOST OFTEN TO PAY AT DEPARTMENT STORES, COMPARED WITH 25 PERCENT WHO SAID CREDIT CARDS AND 8 PERCENT WHO SAID CASH.37 • 46 PERCENT OF DEBIT CARD HOLDERS SURVEYED IN 2011 SAID THEY USED THEIR DEBIT CARDS MOST OFTEN WHEN ONLINE SHOPPING, COMPARED WITH 40 PERCENT WHO SAID CREDIT CARDS AND 2 PERCENT WHO SAID CASH.37 • 46 PERCENT OF DEBIT CARD HOLDERS FSURVEYED IN 2011SAID THEY USED THEIR DEBIT CARDS MOST OFTEN WHEN DINING IN RESTAURANTS, COMPARED WITH 26 PERCENT WHO SAID CREDIT CARDS AND 21 PERCENT WHO SAID CASH.37 • 38 PERCENT OF DEBIT CARD HOLDERS SURVEYED IN 2011SAID THEY USED THEIR DEBIT CARDS MOST OFTEN WHEN SHOPPING AT CONVENIENCE STORES, COMPARED WITH 11 PERCENT WHO SAID CREDIT CARDS AND 38 PERCENT WHO SAID CASH.37 • 36 PERCENT OF DEBIT CARD HOLDERS SURVEYED IN 2011 SAID THEY USED THEIR DEBIT CARDS MOST OFTEN WHEN DINING AT FAST FOOD RESTAURANTS, COMPARED WITH 11 PERCENT WHO SAID CREDIT CARDS AND 46 PERCENT WHO SAID CASH.37 • DEBIT CARD PAYMENTS ACCOUNTED FOR 43 PERCENT OF 110 BILLION TRANSACTIONS IN 2011, UP FROM 19.4 PERCENT IN 2003.40 • HALF OF ALL NONCASH PAYMENTS FOR FUEL IN 2012 WERE MADE WITH DEBIT CARDS.41 • AMONG HOUSEHOLDS WITH INCOME OF LESS THAN $50,000, DEBIT CARDS ACCOUNTED FOR TWICE AS MANY GAS STATION TRANSACTIONS AS CREDIT CARDS IN 2012.41 Read more: http://www.creditcards.com/credit-card-news/credit-card-industry-factspersonal-debt-statistics-1276.php#ixzz2nICq1KSv Follow us: @CreditCardsCom on Twitter | CreditCards.com on Facebook Compare credit cards here - CreditCards.com Credit card usage •Nearly half of low- and middle-income households carried debt from out of pocket medical expenses on their credit cards in 2012. The average amount of medical credit card debt was $1,678.19 •Proportion of parents who used credit cards to pay for their kids’ college bills as of 2012: Approximately 4 percent, borrowing on average $4,911.11 •Proportion of college students borrowing from credit cards to pay for college as of 2012: 3 percent. Average amount in college costs financed on those credit cards as of 2012: $2,169.11 •Low- and middle-income households that used credit cards to pay for basic living expenses such as rent or mortgage, groceries or utilities, in the 12 months prior to March 2012 because they did not have enough money in their checking or savings accounts: 40 percent.19 •Credit card holders with two to three credit cards who actually use two to three each month, as of 2012: 49 percent. Credit card holders with four or more credit cards who only use two to three each month, as of 2012: 68 percent.33 •Credit card users surveyed in 2012 who used their cards to buy: Clothing: 67 percent Gas: 64 percent Food: 64 percent Travel: 62 percent.33 •Among credit card holders surveyed in 2012, those age 50 and up were more likely than those age 18 to 49 to use their credit card for travel (68 percent versus 55 percent ), clothing (72 percent versus 62 percent), home maintenance (39 percent versus 28 percent) and car maintenance (54 percent versus 40 percent).33 •63 percent of debit card holders surveyed in 2011 said they used their debit cards most often to pay for groceries, compared with 19 percent who said credit cards and 13 percent who said cash.37 •50 percent of debit card holders surveyed in 2011 said they used their debit cards most often to pay for gasoline, compared to 25 percent who said credit cards and 13 percent who said cash.37 •50 percent of debit card holders surveyed in 2011 said they used their debit cards most often to pay at discount stores, compared with 17 percent who said credit cards and 23 percent who said cash.37 •47 percent of debit card holders surveyed in 2011 said they used their debit cards most often to pay at department stores, compared with 25 percent who said credit cards and 8 percent who said cash.37 •46 percent of debit card holders surveyed in 2011 said they used their debit cards most often when online shopping, compared with 40 percent who said credit cards and 2 percent who said cash.37 •46 percent of debit card holders surveyed in 2011 said they used their debit cards most often when dining in restaurants, compared with 26 percent who said credit cards and 21 percent who said cash.37 •38 percent of debit card holders surveyed in 2011 said they used their debit cards most often when shopping at convenience stores, compared with 11 percent who said credit cards and 38 percent who said cash.37 •36 percent of debit card holders surveyed in 2011 said they used their debit cards most often when dining at fast food restaurants, compared with 11 percent who said credit cards and 46 percent who said cash.37 Read more: http://www.creditcards.com/credit-card-news/credit-card-industry-factspersonal-debt-statistics-1276.php#ixzz2nICxeQWh Follow us: @CreditCardsCom on Twitter | CreditCards.com on Facebook Compare credit cards here - CreditCards.com Debit Cards End 20-Year Trend Of Gaining Share Against Credit Cards According to The Nilson Report November 11, 2013 03:44 PM Eastern Standard Time CARPINTERIA, Calif.--(BUSINESS WIRE)--The more than 20-year trend that had debit card purchase volume and purchase transactions gaining share versus credit cards ended in 2012, according to The Nilson Report, a leading payment industry newsletter. In a feature projecting results for U.S. payment cards through 2017, it reported that spending for goods and services on general purpose and private label consumer and commercial credit, debit, and prepaid cards reached $4.633 trillion in 2012, and is projected to reach $7.285 trillion by 2017. “There is a finite amount of money in deposit accounts owned by consumers” Credit cards accounted for 52.82% of spending in 2012 compared to 47.18% for debit cards. In 2011 credit cards accounted for 52.63% and debit cards accounted for 47.37% of $4.301 trillion in purchase volume. In 2017, 54.72% is projected to be generated from credit cards and 45.28% from debit cards. “There is a finite amount of money in deposit accounts owned by consumers,” said David Robertson, Publisher of The Nilson Report. “Credit cards are different. Because they can borrow money and pay it back over time, they can spend more on credit than they have in their own accounts.” Visa debit cards’ market share of 23.83% was highest when comparing purchase volume for all product types in 2012. Visa credit cards ranked second with 21.18%, followed by American Express credit cards (12.70%), MasterCard credit cards (11.53%), and MasterCard debit cards (9.67%). Visa credit card purchase volume is projected to have a greater share in 2017 at 23.65% than Visa debit cards at 22.98%. American Express’s share is projected to grow to 13.36%. MasterCard’s credit card share is expected to fall to 10.82%, and its debit card share is expected to fall to 9.40%. About The Nilson Report The Nilson Report is a highly respected source of global news and analysis of the card and mobile payment industries. The subscription newsletter provides in-depth rankings and statistics on the current status of the industry, as well as company, personnel, and product updates. David Robertson, Publisher of The Nilson Report, and a recognized expert in the field, is a frequent speaker at industry conferences, and is regularly quoted in publications worldwide. Over 18,000 readers in 90 countries value The Nilson Report to track industry trends and market information. Contacts The Nilson Report Lori Fulmer, 805-684-8800 lfulmer@nilsonreport.com CHAPTER 5 STUDENT LOANS January 2, 2014 The growth of student loan debt from 2004 to 2014 Please read: http://mercatus.org/publication/student-loan-debt-increases-281-percentover-ten-years A FEW SLECTED QUESTIONS AND QUIERIES QUESTION 1. How do you explain this explosive growth? QUESTION 2. What does this mean, micro and macro for people of color? What does it mean for those people in the lower 40 % by income or new worth What does it mean for our society What are its implications for our economy What to do about it? 3. Compare and contrast student loan with credit card and auto debt As the growth of credit card debt slowed and as the Crash hit the mortgage debt world, student loan debt exploded to overtake credit card debt and to overtake auto debt. 4. . What are the effects of not having lending criteria applied to the making of student loans 5. What should the bankruptcy discharge rules be for student loans? Should there be any special rules to govern student loans that are used at for profit educational institutions Here are two websites that may be useful. www.studentloanborrowerassistance.org www.studentaid.gov Here are a few recent articles. Digging Deeper Into Student Loan Debt Posted: 04/09/2013 11:49 am . As student loan debt rises at an alarming rate in the United States, some analysts fear that this trend could cause another economic crisis. From 2005 to 2012, student loan debt grew from $364 billion to $904 billion -- an increase of 13.9 percent annually. In a recent Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City working paper, Kelly Edmiston, Lara Brooks, and Steven Shepelwich concluded that: High debt levels, coupled with high default rates, present a number of challenges for individual student loan borrowers, but do not necessarily pose a substantial burden on society at large. High aggregate student loan debt may have only a minimal impact on the U.S. federal government and its taxpayers, but individual debt can be a major problem for borrowers. Too often, high school graduates do not know how financial aid works, how much aid they really need, or even that they have to repay student loans. With more financial education at this critical juncture, a young college student will maximize scholarships and minimize loans. This knowledge can also be empowering -- motivating a student to finish a degree program on time. It is also important to dig deeper into "the student loan problem." There are two key considerations that should mitigate some of our concerns about aggregate U.S. student loan debt. •Although the average student loan is approximately $26,000, the median loan is about $13,000. There is a substantial difference between the mean and the median because some borrowers amassed student loan bills, skewing the student loan mean to twice the median. $13,000 is certainly nothing to sneeze at, but for individuals that pay their loans back over ten years, the monthly loan payment is lower than the typical car payment. •A deeper analysis of student loan debt suggests that most of the increase in aggregate debt has resulted from an increase in the number of borrowers. When the economy is in bad shape, more people make the decision to pursue a college degree. Over the past five years in particular, many post-secondary institutions have seen a marked rise in enrollments. Don't get me wrong, high student loan debt is worrisome. A high individual debt burden restricts one's discretionary purchasing power. If I need to budget $190/month for student loan payments, I have less ability to consume more generally. This is a problem because it limits economic growth. While student loan debt may not trigger an economic crisis, it is a serious problem for many borrowers. If you are a recent graduate in a poor economy, it is extremely difficult to pay back that loan if you cannot find a job that pays well. Seventeen percent of individuals with student loan debt are delinquent on their payments. This is a higher delinquency rate than most other forms of debt. Moreover, bankruptcy does not free the borrower from student loan debt. But student loans play an important role in the United States. College is expensive, and most students cannot finance their education without loans. Student loan debt is used to make an investment in human capital. Since this investment may seem intangible to young people, they may start to wonder: is college worth it? The answer is yes, for two reasons: •As of January 2013, the unemployment rate was 8.1 percent for high school graduates with no college, but only 3.7 percent for college graduates. •College graduates earn $21,900 more per year than high school graduates who do not have a post-secondary degree. Teenagers need help understanding financial aid. High school counselors and parents play critical roles in facilitating these important conversations. Once they start college, it is really important that students complete a degree. On average, only 60 percent of students enrolling in a post-secondary institution complete their degree program within six years. Not surprisingly, the delinquency rate on student loans is much higher for the 40 percent that start -- but do not finish -- college. Although student loan debt may not be a collective crisis, it can certainly be a crisis for the individual borrower. It is crucial that teenagers think long and hard about the degree they plan to pursue, the work prospects for people with that degree, and their future ability to repay student loans. Follow Mike English on Twitter: www.twitter.com/@moeconomics How many Americans borrow/have borrowed for college? • Nearly 20 million Americans attend college each year. (Source: Chronicle of Higher Education) • Of that 20 million, close to 12 million – or 60% - borrow annually to help cover costs. (Source: Chronicle of Higher Education) • There are approximately 37 million student loan borrowers with outstanding student loans today. (Source: Federal Reserve Board of New York) • As of the first Quarter of 2012, the under 30 age group has the most borrowers at 14 million, followed by 10.6 million for the 30-39 group, 5.7 million in the 40-49 category, 4.6 million in the 50-59 age group and the over 60 category with the least number of borrowers at 2.2 million for an overall total of 37.1 million. (Source: FRBNY) How much do Americans borrow/have borrowed for college? •There is roughly somewhere between $902 billion and $1 trillion in total outstanding student loan debt in the United States today. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York reports $902B while the Consumer Finance Protection Bureau reports $1T. •Roughly $864 billion is outstanding federal student loan debt while the remaining $150 billion is in private student loans(Source: Consumer Finance Protection Bureau). Private student loans are not made or backed by the federal government. •As of Quarter 1 in 2012, the average student loan balance for all age groups is $24,301. About one-quarter of borrowers owe more than $28,000; 10% of borrowers owe more than $54,000; 3% owe more than $100,000; and less than 1%, or 167,000 people, owe more than $200,000. (Source: FRBNY) •Among all bachelor's degree recipients, median debt was about $7,960 at public fouryear institutions, $17,040 at private not-for-profit four-year institutions, and $31,190 at for-profit institutions. (Source: College Board) •As of October 2012, the average amount of student loan debt for the Class of 2011 was $26,600, a 5 percent increase from approximately $25,350 in 2010. (Source: The Project on Student Debt) Who borrows/has borrowed? Among all 2007-08 bachelor's degree recipients: • 66% graduated with some education debt, while 10% had borrowed $40,000 or more. • 62% at public four-year institutions borrowed. • 72% at private nonprofit four-year institutions borrowed. • 96% at private for-profit institutions borrowed. Associate’s degree and certificate recipients, 2007-08: • 38% of associate’s degree recipients at public institutions borrowed. • 98% of associate’s degree recipients at private for-profit institutions borrowed. • 30% of certificate recipients at public institutions borrowed. • 90% of certificate recipients at private for-profit institutions borrowed. Among students who earned graduate degrees in 2007-08: • 26% had no education debt at all. • 14% had undergraduate debt but no graduate school debt. • 7% had borrowed $80,000 or more for graduate school. • 5% had borrowed between $60,000 and $79,999. (Source: The College Board) The majority of borrowers still paying back their loans are in their 30s or older. Of the 37 million Americans with outstanding student loan debt: • Almost 40% of these borrowers are under the age of 30. • Nearly 42% are between the ages of 30 and 50. • 17% are older than 50. • Borrowers age 30-39 carry $307 billion in student loans, followed by those under 30 at $292 billion, $154 billion in the 40-49 age group, 50-59 at $106 billion and the over 60 category carrying $43 billion, for a total outstanding debt of $902 billion. (Source: FRBNY) How many student loan borrowers struggle with repayment? • Of the 37 million borrowers who have outstanding student loan balances, 14%, or about 5.4 million borrowers, have at least one past due student loan account. • Of the $870B-$1T in outstanding student loan debt, approximately $85 billion is past due. (Source: FRBNY) • The official FY 2010 two-year national student loan cohort default rate rose to 9.1 percent, up from 8.8 percent in FY 2009, while the three-year rate declined slightly from 13.8 percent to 13.4 percent. (Source: U.S. Department of Education) • Only about 37 percent of federal student loan borrowers between 2004 and 2009 managed to make timely payments without postponing payments or becoming delinquent. • For every student loan borrower who defaults, at least two more borrowers become delinquent without default. • Two out of five student loan borrowers – or 41%- are delinquent at some point in the first five years after entering repayment. (Source: Institute for Higher Education Policy) • As of 2012, there are now more than $8 billion in defaulted private loans, or 850,000 distinct loans in default. (Source: CFPB) Who struggles most? • As of early 2012, borrowers in their 30s have a delinquency rate (more than 90 days past due) of about 6%, while borrowers in their 40s have a delinquency rate double that, at about 12 percent. Borrowers in their 50s have a delinquency rate of 9.4% and those over 60 have a delinquency rate of 9.5%.(Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York Consumer Credit Panel) Students who drop out of college before earning a degree often struggle most with student loans: • From 2004 to 2009, 33% of undergraduate federal student loan borrowers who left without a credential became delinquent without defaulting and 26 percent defaulted, vs. 21% with a credential who became delinquent without defaulting and 16% who defaulted.(Source: IHEP). And the number of drop-outs is on the rise: • Nearly 30 percent of college students who took out loans dropped out of school, up from fewer than a quarter of students a decade ago. (Source: Education Sector) • More than half of students who take out loans to enroll in two-year for-profit colleges never finish. At traditional nonprofit and public schools, the percentage of students with loans who started college in 2003 and dropped out within six years is about 20 percent. (Source: Education Trust) Type of institution attended can also make a difference: • From 2004-09, a third or less of federal student loan borrowers at four-year, public or private nonprofit institutions became delinquent or defaulted on their loans, while nearly half or more (45 percent and 53 percent, respectively) of their borrowers were making timely payments on their loans. • One-quarter to one-third of borrowers at for-profit and public two-year institutions were making timely payments on their loans, and more than half of all borrowers in these sectors were delinquent or had already defaulted. (Source: IHEP) Why do they struggle? • 48% of 25-34 year-olds say they’re unemployed or under-employed. • 52% describe their financial situation as just fair. • 70% say it has become harder to make ends meet over the past four years. • 42% of those under 35 have more than $5000 in personal debt that does not include a mortgage. • Student loans account for the most common form of increasing debt among ages 18-24 (54% have seen increased school loan debt) while those in the older group attribute increased debt equally to school loans (37%) and credit cards (37%). (Source: Demos and Young Invincibles) How well do students and alumni understand their options to minimize borrowing and manage the debt once they have it? • As of 2012, only 700,000 borrowers had enrolled in Income-Based Repayment (Source: Project on Student Debt), but the Obama Administration estimates that IBR could reduce monthly payments for more than 1.6 million student borrowers. (Source: White House Fact Sheet) • About 65 percent of high-debt student loan borrowers misunderstood or were surprised by aspects of their student loans or the student loan process. (Source: Young Invincibles) • Approximately one-third of recent grads, if they could do it all again, would have pursued more scholarships or financial aid options, pursued a major that would have led to a higher paying job, or gotten a job while in college and started saving earlier. (Source: Accounting Principals) How is student debt impacting borrowers - and the U.S. economy? A college degree does increase an individual’s potential for earnings: • In 2010, people ages 25 to 34 with bachelor's degrees earned 114 percent more than did those without high-school diplomas. • College graduates earned 50 percent more than did young adults who completed only high school, and 22 percent more than did those with associate degrees. • The median income for young adults with a bachelor's degree was $45,000, and with an associate degree, $37,000 (Source: National Center for Education Statistics) Why Do Students Borrow So Much? Recent National Trends in Student Loan Debt By Kenneth Redd Educational Resource Information Center (U.S. Department of Education) College students are leaving their higher education institutions with more educational loan debt than ever before. From academic year 1994- 1995 to 1999-2000, the amount postsecondary education students borrowed through the federal student loan programs jumped from $24 billion to $33.7 billion (U.S. Department of Education 1999 and 2000a). Cumulative federal student loan debt for bachelor's degree recipients rose 19 percent, while total debt for borrowers who received master's and other advanced degrees more than doubled (Scherschel 2000). What has led to the increased use of student loans? Is the rising indebtedness harming students' futures? While concern about rising student debt levels remains high (Scherschel 1999a and 2000), recent data reveal that much of the increased borrowing occurred due to the expansion of the loan programs rather than to growth in college costs. Further, many of the new loan recipients came from middle- and upper-income families, and most undergraduate borrowers do not appear to have been adversely affected by their added indebtedness. Reasons why Borrowing has Increased Several recent studies (King 1999, Redd 1994, Scherschel 1999a and 1999b) provide three possible reasons for the growth of student loans. First, increases in federal grant aid have not kept pace with rising postsecondary education costs, and the widening gap between college prices and grant aid compelled more students to borrow. Second, students' financial need has increased as educational costs have grown, and more of this need is met by loans. And third, increases in loan limits and ease of borrowing have allowed more students to receive loans. Each of these reasons has merit and deserves consideration. There is no question that postsecondary education costs grew rapidly during the 1990s. The College Board's most recent Trends in College Prices report (College Board 2000) shows that, when adjusted for inflation, tuition and fee charges at four-year public colleges and universities increased 49 percent during the decade; at four-year private institutions, tuition prices rose 32 percent. Meanwhile, median income for families with a head of household age 45 to 54 (families most likely to have college-aged children) grew by just 4 percent, and appropriations for Federal Pell Grants (aid for low-income undergraduates) increased only 15 percent. At first glance, these factors would appear to have been the primary causes for the growth in borrowing. However, data from the National Center for Education Statistics' National Postsecondary Student Aid Study (U.S. Department of Education 2000b and 2000c) show that, for middle- and upper- income undergraduate students, amounts of loans actually grew faster than their total costs. For families with income of $40,000 to $59,999, the average annual amount of federal student loans grew to $3,729 from $3,216 during the 1992-93 to 1995-96 period, but total cost of attendance (tuition, fees, room, board, books, educational supplies, and other expenses) fell from $14,150 to $13,267. Costs declined because a greater share of the students were enrolled at lower-cost four-year public institutions in 1995-96 than in 1992-93. Despite the shift in enrollment to less expensive colleges and universities, students from middle-income families borrowed more. Among all undergraduate borrowers, average federal student loans grew 16 percent but educational costs increased just 3 percent. Clearly, growth in educational costs does not completely explain the increase in borrowing. Similarly, amounts borrowed grew much faster than upper-income students' demonstrated financial need. Financial need is defined as the difference between students' and families' total postsecondary education costs and the estimated amounts they can afford to pay from their income and other resources. For undergraduates from families with income of $80,000 or more, financial need increased only 3 percent, but average loan amounts jumped 13 percent. Low-income students faced the opposite extreme; for undergraduates from families with income of under $20,000, financial need jumped 23 percent, while average amounts borrowed only grew 11 percent (U.S. Department of Education 2000b and 2000c). These results strongly suggest that much of the growth in borrowing also can be attributed to the changes made in the Higher Education Act (HEA), the federal law that governs the financial aid programs. In 1992, the law increased the annual and cumulative maximum amounts students could borrow (Redd 1999). Annual loan limits under the Stafford Subsidized Loan program (loans provided to students based on their financial need) for second-year undergraduates were raised to $3,500 from $2,625. The maximum loan to students in the third or higher year of undergraduate study was raised to $5,500 from $4,000, and graduate/professional student loan maximums grew to $8,500 from $7,500. More importantly, the law also authorized a new loan program-the Stafford Unsubsidized Loan program-which essentially allowed all students, regardless of their families' financial need or income, to receive assistance. Students also were allowed to receive both subsidized and unsubsidized loans in the same academic year. When the new unsubsidized loan amounts were combined with the maximum subsidized amounts, undergraduates in the junior or senior years could borrow up to $10,500 in federal student loans annually. Income Levels of Students Who Received Loans: Much of the recent growth in federal student loan borrowing has been through the Stafford Unsubsidized Loan program. From its inception in 1993-1994 to 1999-2000, the amount of unsubsidized loans more than tripled-rising from $4.1 billion to $12.9 billion. In the same period, amounts of subsidized loans grew 40 percent, from about $12.5 billion to $17.5 billion (U.S. Department of Education 1999 and 2000a). Because students may receive unsubsidized loans regardless of their families' incomes, a large share of the added loan dollars appear to have gone to students from middle- and upper-income families. The percentage of undergraduate students from families with income between $60,000 and $79,999 who received federal student loans grew from 56 percent in 1992-93 to 67 percent in 1995- 96. At the same time, the proportion of borrowers from families with income of less than $20,000 who received federal loans dropped from 52 percent to 49 percent (U.S. Department of Education 2000b and 2000c). Middle- and upper-income families who might not have qualified for need-based Stafford Subsidized Loans became eligible to receive Stafford Unsubsidized Loans. While the unsubsidized program allowed more middle- and upper-income students to receive loans, it is possible that a number of these students were borrowing more than they really needed to attend postsecondary education (King 1999, Redd 1994 and 1999). The Effects of Loans on Borrowers who Receive Degrees However, the growth in indebtedness has to be put into a larger context. For some students, borrowing could be a wise investment because it allows them to finish their educational programs and increases the odds of achieving success in employment and other areas of life. For others, borrowing might lead to financial burdens. It is commonly suggested that loan repayment obligations may cause some loan recipients to delay home and car purchases, marriage, child rearing, and other aspects of life (Baum and Saunders 1998). Recent information (Baum and Saunders 1998, Choy 2000, Davis 2000) shows that despite the recent increases in borrowing, loan repayment obligations represent just a small portion of most borrowers' after-college salaries. For borrowers who received bachelor's degrees in engineering from four-year public colleges and universities in 1999, monthly loan repayments accounted for just 4.4 percent of average starting salaries. For computer science majors, loan repayments represented only 4.5 percent of average wages, and among education majors, loan repayments equaled only 7 percent of starting salaries. These findings are not meant to suggest that all borrowers were able to repay their loans without hardship. Students from medical, dental, and other professional degree programs typically face debts of $100,000 or more (National Association of Student Financial Aid Administrators 1999). Another study (Davis 2000) shows that borrowers who do not finish their educational programs have a much more difficult time in repaying their loans. Students who leave higher education without obtaining a bachelor's degree often have lower incomes than degree recipients, which makes it much harder for noncompleters to repay their loans. Summary Federal student loan borrowing grew primarily because the maximum loan limits were increased and middle- and upper-income students became eligible for Stafford Unsubsidized Loans. However, despite the increases in cumulative debt that occurred, most undergraduate loan recipients appear to be able to repay their loans with little difficulty, as long as they complete their degree programs. However, repayment obligations are much more difficult for professional school students, who often leave their institutions with debt of $100,000 or more, and for undergraduate borrowers who do not complete degree programs. More research would provide greater insights into how indebtedness affects these students after they leave higher education. References Baum, S. and D. Saunders. (1998). " Life After Debt: Results of the National Student Loan Survey." Journal of Student Financial Aid, 28(3) 7-23. EJ 584 134. Choy, S.P. (2000). Debt Burden After College. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Education, National Center for Education Statistics Report Number 2000-188. College Board. (2000). Trends in College Prices. Washington, DC: The College Board. Davis, J.S. (2000). College Affordability: Overlooked Long-Term Trends and Recent 50State Patterns. Indianapolis, IN: USA Group Foundation. King, J.E. (1999). "Crisis or Convenience: Why Are Students Borrowing More?" In Financing a College Education: How It Works, How It's Changing. Edited by J.E. King. Phoenix, AZ: American Council on Education/Oryx Press. ED 427 630 National Association of Student Financial Aid Administrators. (1999). Financial Aid Policies and Practices at Graduate and Professional Schools: Results from the 1998 Survey of Graduate Aid Policies, Practices, and Procedures. Washington, DC: National Association of Student Financial Aid Administrators. Redd, K.E. (1994). The Effects of Higher Loan Limits and Need Analysis Changes on FFELP Borrowing in Pennsylvania, July to December 1992 to 1993. Harrisburg, PA: Pennsylvania Higher Education Assistance Agency. ED 369 368. Redd, K.E. (1999). "The Changing Characteristics of Undergraduate Borrowers." In Financing a College Education: How It Works, How It's Changing The following report may be helpful. http://www.nera.com/nera-files/PUB_Student_Loans_0312.pdf Special Rules for Dischargeability of Student Loans in Bankruptcy Student loans are, for the most part, not dischargeable in bankruptcy. That means that if you have a student loan, in most cases you will not be able to eliminate the student loan debt in bankruptcy. Student loans used to be dischargeable under certain circumstances prior to October 2005. However, in October 2005, the bankruptcy law on student loans was rewritten to make all educational loans nondischargeable. Can I File Bankruptcy on Student Loans in San Diego? If you are asking the question, can I file bankruptcy on student loans, in most cases the answer is no. With the revisions to the Federal bankruptcy law in 2005, and the Brunner Test, which is controlling law in San Diego County as well as throughout the State of California, there is a very tough standard that you would need to meet in order to be able to wipe out student loans in bankruptcy. Under this standard, set forth by the Brunner Test, you need to show that you are so physically or mentally disabled that you cannot engage in substantial gainful employment. For this reason, it is rare case in which a borrower is able to eliminate a student loan in bankruptcy. History Prior to 1998, you could file a Chapter 7 or Chapter 13 bankruptcy on student loans if the loan had been in repayment status (not including any deferment period) for at least 7 years at the time that your case is filed. On October 7, 1998, the Bankruptcy Code was amended to make it more difficult to file bankruptcy on student loans. The 1998 law made student loans nondischargeable if the loan was made or guaranteed by the Federal Government unless you could show that nondischargeability would pose an “undue hardship” upon you and your dependents. Student loans still remained dischargeable if the loans were not made or guaranteed by the Federal Government. On October 17, 2005, the New Bankruptcy Law went into effect and drastically changed your ability to discharge student loans for most people. The new law, in effect, treats privately funded student loans in the same manner as government backed loans were treated since 1998: you cannot eliminate them in most cases. The only exception is that if you can meet the standard set forth by the Brunner Test. Under the new law, in effect since 2005, all educational loans, whether governmentbacked student loans or privately funded loans, are nondischargeable in either a Chapter 7 case or Chapter 13 case unless you can show that nondischargeability would post an “undue hardship” upon you and your dependents. Undue Hardship – The Brunner Test The Bankruptcy Code does not define what constitutes an “undue hardship.” To determine whether or not an undue hardship exists, sufficient to allow you to obtain a Hardship Discharge of an educational loan in bankruptcy, the Court will apply a specific test, known as the “Brunner Test.” The Brunner Test is a 3-Part test first established in 1985 by the Second Circuit Court of Appeals. At the time the test was established, it was not controlling in the State of California. Fifteen years after the decision was made by the Second Circuit Court of Appeals, the Federal Circuit Court having jurisdiction over California, namely the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals, made the test applicable in California. On September 11, 1998, the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals, which is the Federal Circuit Court that has controlling jurisdiction over California Bankruptcy Courts, formally adopted the Brunner Test and made it the applicable test in our state. Since that time, the Brunner Test has been the controlling test that is applied by California Courts and judges in deciding whether to grant you Hardship Discharge of your educational loans when you file for bankruptcy. Under the Brunner Test, the Court will apply a 3-Part test to determine whether an undue hardship exists sufficiently for the Court to grant you a Hardship Discharge when you file for bankruptcy: (1) You must establish that you cannot maintain, based upon your current income and expenses, a minimal standard of living for yourself and your dependents if you are forced to repay your loans; (2) You must show that additional circumstances exist indicating that your current state of affairs is likely to persist for a significant part of the repayment period of your loans; and (3) You must have made good faith efforts to repay your loans. In practice, it is very difficult to obtain a Hardship Discharge under the Brunner Test. Once you pass the first part of the test- you establish that you cannot maintain a minimal standard of living if forced to repay your student loans- you must still show the Court that your situation is not going to change for a significant part of your repayment period. It will not be presumed by the Court that your current state of affairs is not going to change for a significant part of your repayment period. Rather, you must make an affirmative showing and prove to the Court that you have an insurmountable barrier to financial recovery that is likely to remain with you for a substantial portion of your repayment period. Technically, under the Brunner Test, your barrier to financial recovery does not necessarily need to be so extreme that it rises to the level of a physical disability, learning disability, mental illness, or other similar extreme circumstance. In reality, bankruptcy judges frequently reserve granting a Hardship Discharge to the extreme case- a case where you are physically unable to work and there is virtually no chance that you will recover and obtain gainful employment in the future. If there is hope for you to engage in gainful employment, most judges would expect you to find a job and pay off your loans. Even if you have an extreme case, you must further show that you have made good faith efforts to repay your educational loans. This means, for example, attempting to work out a repayment plan, consolidating your loans under the Federal Direct Loans consolidation program, and other similar good faith efforts to repay your educational loans prior to filing bankruptcy and requesting a Hardship Discharge. Partial Discharge Discharging student loans in bankruptcy is not always an all-or-nothing proposition. Bankruptcy Courts are Courts of Equity and judges have equitable powers and may exercise their equitable powers to partially discharge a portion but not all of your student loans based upon your individual circumstances. To obtain a partial discharge of your student loans you will still need to meet all 3 parts of the Brunner Test with respect to the portion of your educational loans that you are seeking to discharge. If and only if you meet all 3 parts of the Brunner Test, then the judge may exercise his or her discretion to grant you a partial discharge of your student loan debt. HEAL Loans Health Education Assistance Loan (HEAL) Act loans are subject to an even stricter standard (stricter than the Brunner Test) and are harder to discharge than any other type of educational loan debt. In particular, discharging a HEAL Loan in bankruptcy requires a finding by the Court that, among other findings, it would be “unconscionable” not to discharge a HEAL Loan. Unconscionability is a very difficult standard to meet. Adversary Proceeding Required If you can establish that your case meets the standard for granting a hardship discharge or partial discharge of your student loan debt, you will need to initiate an adversary proceeding in your Chapter 7 or Chapter 13 case and request that the Court make a legal determination that your loans are discharged by your Chapter 7 or Chapter 13 discharge. KEY QUESTIONS Student Loans in Bankruptcy by Chen http://www.policyarchive.org/handle/10207/bitstreams/19283.pdf NON BANKRUPTCY RULES FOR FORGIVENESS From http://studentaid.ed.gov/repay-loans/understand/plans/income-based December 24, 2013 If your student loan debt is high relative to your income, you may qualify for the IncomeBased Repayment Plan (IBR). Most major types of federal student loans—except for PLUS loans for parents and Consolidation Loans that repaid PLUS loans for parents—are eligible for IBR. Income-Based Repayment (IBR) is designed to reduce monthly payments to assist with making your student loan debt manageable. If you need to make lower monthly payments, this plan may be for you. To qualify for IBR, you must have a partial financial hardship. You have a partial financial hardship if the monthly amount you would be required to pay on your IBReligible federal student loans under a 10-year Standard Repayment Plan is higher than the monthly amount you would be required to repay under IBR. Your payment amount may increase or decrease each year based on your income and family size. Once you've initially qualified for IBR, you may continue to make payments under the plan even if you later no longer have a partial financial hardship. -------------------------------------------------------------------------------Eligible Federal Loans The following loans from the William D. Ford Federal Direct Loan (Direct Loan) Program and the Federal Family Education Loan (FFEL) Program are eligible for IBR: Direct Subsidized Loans Direct Unsubsidized Loans Direct PLUS Loans made to graduate or professional students Direct Consolidation Loans without underlying PLUS loans made to parents Subsidized Federal Stafford Loans Unsubsidized Federal Stafford Loans FFEL PLUS Loans made to graduate or professional students FFEL Consolidation Loans without underlying PLUS loans made to parents -------------------------------------------------------------------------------Loans That Are Not Eligible The following loans are not eligibile for repayment under IBR: PLUS loans made to parents Consolidation Loans that include underlying PLUS loans made to parents Private education loans -------------------------------------------------------------------------------Monthly Payments Under this plan, your monthly payments are based on your income and family size; adjusted each year, based on changes to your annual income and family size; usually lower than they are under other plans; never more than the 10-year standard repayment amount; and made over a period of 25 years. -------------------------------------------------------------------------------Advantages of IBR Pay based on what you earn—Under IBR, your monthly payment amount will be 15 percent of your discretionary income, will never be more than the amount you would be required to pay under the 10-year Standard Repayment Plan, and may be less than under other repayment plans. Interest payment benefit—If your monthly IBR payment amount doesn’t cover the interest that accrues (accumulates) on your loans each month, the government will pay your unpaid accrued interest on your Direct Subsidized Loans or Subsidized Federal Stafford Loans (and on the subsidized portion of your Direct or FFEL Consolidation Loans) for up to three consecutive years from the date you began repaying your loan under IBR. Limitation on the capitalization of interest—While you have a partial financial hardship, interest that accrues but is not covered by your loan payments will not be capitalized, even if interest accrues during a deferment or forbearance. 25-year forgiveness—If you repay under IBR and meet certain other requirements, any remaining balance will be forgiven after 25 years of qualifying repayment. 10-year public service loan forgiveness—If, while you are employed full-time for a public service organization, you make 120 on-time, full monthly payments under IBR (or certain other repayment plans) you may be eligible to receive forgiveness of the remaining balance of your Direct Loans through the Public Service Loan Forgiveness Program. -------------------------------------------------------------------------------Disadvantages of IBR You may pay more interest—A reduced monthly payment in IBR generally means you’ll be repaying your loan for a longer period of time, so you may pay more total interest over the life of the loan than you would under other repayment plans. You must submit annual documentation—To set your payment amount each year, your loan servicer, the organization that handles billing and other services for your loan, needs updated information about your income and family size. You must provide the documentation or your monthly payment amount will be changed to the amount you would be required to pay under the 10-year Standard Repayment Plan, based on the amount you owed when you began repaying under IBR, and will no longer be based on your income. This amount will be higher than your prior IBR payment that was based on your income. If you do not provide the required income documentation, unpaid interest will also capitalize. You may have to pay taxes on any loan amount that is forgiven after 25 years. -------------------------------------------------------------------------------Using the Repayment Estimator to See How Much You’d Pay Under IBR Your loan servicer, the company that handles the billing and other services on your federal student loan, can help you choose a loan repayment plan that’s best for you. Before you contact your loan servicer to discuss repayment plans, you can use our Repayment Estimator to get an early look at which plans you may be eligible for and see estimates for how much you would pay monthly and overall. -------------------------------------------------------------------------------Tools and Resources for IBR Want more detailed information about IBR? 1.Download the IBR fact sheet. 2.Browse the IBR Questions and Answers (Q&As). Q&As are grouped into six categories: General Information Eligible Loans Determination of IBR Monthly Payment Amount Married Borrowers Application Process Other Information -------------------------------------------------------------------------------Want to Apply for IBR? Contact your loan servicer before you apply for IBR. Your loan servicer will answer your questions about the IBR plan and help you to decide whether IBR is the right plan for your situation. If you are ready to apply for IBR, go to StudentLoans.gov, sign in, and complete the electronic Income-Based (IBR)/Pay As You Earn/Income-Contingent (ICR) Repayment Plan Request. -------------------------------------------------------------------------------Need Help Repaying Your Student Loans? If IBR is not right for you, contact your loan servicer to discuss other repayment options. You may be able to change your repayment plan to one that will allow you to have a longer repayment period. Also ask your loan servicer about your options for a deferment or forbearance or loan consolidation. CHAPTER 6 Loans In Which A Person’s Home Is The Collateral. I. Understanding Home Ownership in the United States The pressure to buy a home and then buy a bigger home. These cultural norms are a driving force in the U.S. and are supported with various kinds of tax breaks and other government subsidies. Home construction, home improvements and mortgage finance are very big pieces of the US economy. In order to regulate mortgage finance we need to understand the cultural imperatives to own a home and the policies that aim to facilitate those imperatives. In order to understand the demand for home equity loans rather than purchase money mortgages it is necessary to think “credit card spending” with home foreclosure remedies. As a starter please read this article from 2001 http://www.nytimes.com/2001/11/25/business/a-boom-built-upon-sand-gone-bust.html (The Green Tree Financing Story- precursor to the Housing Finance Crash) II. Tax and other government policies aimed at facilitating home ownership. III. Scope of Mortgage Debt. Mortgage debt is several times the total of all other types of consumer debt rolled together. Ratio of mortgage debt to entire consumer debt Growth of mortgage debt 1990 – 2007 2000 – 2007 OR 8 1975 1990 1998 2005 2009 2012 $1 Trillion $2 Trillion $2.8 Trillion $5 Trillion $10.5 Trillion $9 Trillion IV. History of Mortgage Debt in the United States. 1. Homestead Acts 2. Farm Mortgages 3. 1900 – depression Build up of demand; rising prices; 5 year balloon notes to control interest rate risk for the lender; problem of refinancing at the end of that five year period when prices stopped rising or when the crash and depression reduced the availability of funds to lend. Most of the funds came from deposits so when they dried up … 4. Depression to the end of World War II. Government tries various methods to restart home purchases and home construction and ameliorate the effects and damages of the depression and enormous number of foreclosures. 5. Post WW II; FHA, VA Fannie Mae, Ginnie Mae: role of government in promoting and facilitating home ownership and home construction. Interest rate concessions; making loans available; lower down payment requirement. Racial disparity of post WWII home push to the suburbs and other places where minority families could not move. Redlining 6. 1999 Low Interest rates: rising home values; rising percentage of homeowning families. Explosion of refinancing; growth of home equity loans and combining refinancing with home equity loans. Growth of securitization as source of the funds to lend; separating risk of default from the party who makes the loan. 7. The explosion of sub-prime mortgage products combined with the rising real estate values and the death of credit standard underwriting. 8. The Crash 9. After the Crash – what next??? The expansion of home ownership. How to do it effectively?? 1. History of Mortgage financing from 1900 to 1970 Prior to 1900 a great deal of the home financing in the US was done through the various homestead programs and with institutions that financed the purchase of farms. Commencing in the early part of the twentieth century these were supplemented by various other sources that provided funds to lend to families to purchase their homes, in the city or in the country. The bulk of this lending was done by banks, or building and loan associations or savings and loan associations which took in deposit and then lent those funds out to prospective home purchasers. The spread between what the financial institutions were paying for the deposits and what they were charging for the loans was the “profit.” In order to insure themselves against a unexpected increase in the rate they had to pay depositors, the institutions kept the home loans to a term of five years or less. At a time when real estate values were rising and there were ample funds to loan, this was not much of a problem. When the home loans came due the original lender gave a new loan or the homeowner found a new lender and used those funds to pay off the loan. If not funds were available the home owner could avoid foreclosure by selling the home since the rising home values made it likely that the value of the home would exceed the debt. These increase in values and opportunity for profits for the financial institutions created the same kind of pre bubble, giddy atmosphere as was created in the early parts of the twenty first century and there was an explosion of new home construction and home loans. All of this was stopped in its tracks by three developments. The first of course was the stock market crash; The second was the contraction of funds available to loan; and The third was the concomitant leveling off of home values. As a result when the five year term loans matured the home owner could not find any source to repay the entire principal of the loan and an extraordinary number of homes were foreclosed upon. Almost immediately the home construction business drew to a halt which exacerbated the employment problems. Between the time of the crash and the end of World War 2 the government tried a number of vehicles to end the foreclosure crisis and to restart the home construction industry. . Depression to the end of world war ii. Government trying to figure it out and ameliorate the effects and damage of the depression and enormous number of foreclosures . Post World War 2- FHA – VA - Fannie Mae, Ginnie Mae; role of government . the importance to the economy and the society of home building and home ownership; the push for home ownership; including the interest rate deduction; racial disparity of post ww2 home push to the suburbs and other places where minority families could not move. . 1995 low interest rates; rising home values; refinancing growth; growth of securitization and mortgage brokers; separating risk of default from the party who made the loan . The explosion of sub prime mortgages combined with the rising values combined with the death of credit standards It is crucial to consider and understand the supply side and the sources of the funding of the explosions from 1970 – 2005 including FHA and Fannie Mae. It is just as important to understand the power of the search for an above market rate of return in the private investment sector that stepped in when government sources were temporarily stuck in the early part of the 21st century. Demand side Consider the following factors: 1. Traditional purchase money first mortgage 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. First time home buyer/ higher prices First time buyer outside historical parameters for buying a home Effect of higher prices Trading up; why do people trade up? . 2000 – 2005 the various effects of: low interest rates, securitization, and the rise in real estate values; also the efforts to increase the % of home ownership a. the explosion of refinancing please read the following two articles http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/2003/el2003-29.pdf http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/bulletin/2002/1202lead.pdf QUESTIONS; HOW DID IT WORK AND WHY. LOOK AT THE NUMBERS ; LOOK AT THE PROCESS; LOOK AT THE PLAYERS AND WHO MAKES MONEY Use of the money Fees and the like Who provided it; competition Explosive growth Financial formulas b. THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE HOME EQUITY LINE OF CREDIT A MIX OF THE CREDIT CARD WITH THE HOME MORTGAGE Trillion dollars per year of home equity withdrawals 2001 -2005 1990 – 2006 6.2 trillion Pay down credit card debt (and build it up again or not?) Home improvements Vacations College At the beginning of this period some states, such as Texas did not allow home equity lines of credit. What might they have made that policy decision? Consider the tax benefits of borrowing on a mortgage rather than any other kind of borrowing; Consider the cash flow impact of borrowing on a mortgage rather than a credit card loan. and the Run a cash flow analysis on a home owner who is ready to refinance and who is encouraged to borrow extra dollars for a room addition. What are the risks and benefits of taking that loan? d. Securitization and the search for higher rates of return. Growth of the mortgage brokerage business and the split between sales and credit and the breakdown of credit standards. e. THE GROWTH OF THE SUB PRIME MORTGAGE MARKET Please read http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/06/01/ChomPennCross.pdf Consider the following factors in trying to understand the bubble that led to the crash. 1. NEW HOUSE PRICES ARE HIGHER AND HIGHER 2. PRESSURE TO PUT MORE PEOPLE INTO HOUSES, ESPECIALLY PEOPLE OF COLOR 3. THE CREDIT CARD SUB PRIME WORLD SPILLS OVER TO MORTGAGE DEBT 4. FNMA GETS STUCK PRESSURE TO MAKE LOANS AVAILABEL BUT.; THEY RELAX THEIR STANDARDS 5. THE WORKD OF I BANKERS AND LAWYERS SEE THE PROFITS TO BE MADE IN THE PRIVATE SECURITIZATION WORLD SO THEY MULTIPLY IT AND ATTRACT ENORMOUS AMOUNTS OF CAPITAL 6. THE MORTGAGE BORKERS THAT WERE DOING WELL ON REFI AND REFI AND HECKLE AND NEW HOMEPRUCHASES ARE DELIGHTED; THEY MAKE THE MONEY, THEY HAVE LITTLE OR NO RISK 7. THE ROLE OF THE RATING AGENCIES. The role of the rating agencies 8. FRENZY Please read Breaking New Ground in U.S Mortgage Lending as of 2006 http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/regional/ro20062q/na/2006_summer04.html Please predict the future growth of mortgage debt in the United States. When Home Equity Loans or Lines of Credit Can Lead to Trouble Use your home equity loan or line of credit wisely -- here's how. Many homeowners have a home equity loan or line of credit but don't know the best way to use it. Using home equity can be smart in certain circumstances, and not so smart in others. What is home equity? Your home equity is the difference between the value of your home and your mortgage balance. With a home equity loan or line of credit, you use this equity as collateral in order to get the loan. (To learn more about home equity loans and lines of credit in general, including how to get one, read Nolo's article Home Equity Loan Basics.) With the current financial crisis, you may have heard experts advising getting a loan or line of credit even if you don't need the money now. However, it's wise to use caution when using a home equity loan or line of credit, given that: • Like any loan, you'll pay fees and interest. • Your home is collateral for the loan, so if you default on the loan, you could lose your home. • By its very nature, a home equity loan depletes equity in your home. Here are some of the best ways to use your home equity for a loan or line of credit. Emergencies Traditionally, financial experts have advised homeowners to open a home equity line of credit for use in emergencies. This strategy is especially helpful for those concerned about losing their jobs. Because the lender must document your income before giving you a line of credit, if you wait until you are unemployed to apply, the lender will most likely reject your application. New advice for hard financial times. In these shaky times, some experts advise that homeowners actually take money out of their line of credit, or get a home equity loan, even before they need the cash. This is because in the past, as long as you had equity in your home, you could draw on it in the form of a loan or line of credit. But with today's flat and falling home prices, some risk-adverse lenders are turning off the tap on home equity loans. That might mean you can't get a home equity loan or line, or that your existing home equity line of credit will be reduced, or eliminated altogether. If you take out money ahead of time, you can use the cash to consolidate other bills like credit card bills -- provided you cut up all the credit cards and actually close the accounts. This can also give you some financial breathing room in hard times. The more conservative approach. Not all experts advocate the "use it or lose it" school of thought. The most conservative advice suggests you should leave your home equity in place. If in doubt about what's best for you, consider talking to a trusted financial advisor. Capital Investment Both conservative and more liberal financial experts agree, if you've got equity to use and don't need to hold onto it as a safety net, the best way to use it is as a prudent capital investment. Some examples include: • home improvements with high value returns • education for the kids • financing a sound business plan, and • other financial moves that have a good chance of providing an equal or better return on your money than the cost of the loan. Real Estate Investment Today, lower home prices make buying another home or real estate investment property a potentially sound capital investment, but only over the long haul (more than five or ten years). If you use a home equity loan to buy real estate, be sure that rental income will offset all or most of your carrying costs or that you have other means to carry the investment risk until it pays off. Unwise Use of Home Equity Experts agree that you should not use home equity to buy luxury items like big gas guzzling cars, boats, RVs, vacations, home theaters, and other items that don't give you a return on your money. Using equity money to make monthly payments on the equity loan itself, other debts, utility payments, and small household bills, is often a sign of financial distress. The same is true if you use equity money to buy consumables such as groceries, gasoline, clothing, and similar essentials. If your income doesn't cover those items, your household budget isn't balanced and it's time to seek financial counseling. The Home Equity Crisis Ahead By Mara Der Hovanesian on January 15, 2008 Even banks that dodged the subprime bullet face losses from loans based on homes now at risk Subprime mortgages have taken a lot of blame for banks' big losses. But there's another problem lurking behind the mess: home-equity lending. Buoyed by rising prices, borrowers increasingly tapped into the equity on their properties to finance a new car, renovations, or even a down payment, making equity a key source of consumers' strength. But with the housing market in disarray and prices plunging, the business of home-equity lending is souring. At least $14.7 billion in loans and lines of credit were already delinquent through the end of September—the highest level in a decade. "After subprime, home-equity lending is the biggest problem the industry has right now," says analyst Frederick Cannon of Keefe, Bruyette & Woods. What's more, there's little that can be done to prevent the pain from the deterioration of this $850 billion market. A lender on a mortgage has the first claim on the underlying property. In the case of foreclosure, it can sell the property and recoup some money. The bank with the home-equity piece has no such collateral and is usually out the money. "The home-equity lender is going to get hosed," says Amy Crews Cutts, deputy chief economist at mortgage giant Freddie Mac (FRE). JPMorgan Chase (JPM), Washington Mutual (WM), IndyMac (IMB), Countrywide Financial, and others are getting hit. On Jan. 16, JPMorgan announced it set aside an additional $395 million for troubled home-equity products in the last quarter, compared with just $125 million for subprime mortgages. Washington Mutual reported in the latest period that its bad home-equity loans and lines of credit surged by 130% from the end of 2006, forcing the bank to up losses by $967 million. Even lenders of a conservative bent, those that managed to sidestep much of the subprime mess, are getting hammered: Wells Fargo (WFC) took a recent $1.4 billion writedown, largely from home-equity lending. Piling Higher Until recently, the preponderance of home-equity lending came in the form of lines of credit. They allowed borrowers to convert their equity into cash to pay down credit-card debt and the like. But as the boom raced on and housing prices soared to unimaginable heights, banks started offering second-lien, or piggyback, loans that buyers could use to finance their down payments. The practice allowed buyers, especially subprime ones, to buy ever-bigger houses they could ill afford. Traditional underwriting standards were thrown out the window, with buyers increasingly borrowing more than the value of their homes. As a result, this segment soared to 14.4% of the home-equity market in 2006, according to industry newsletter Inside Mortgage Finance. The boom brought about some especially toxic home-equity loans. Homeowners gamed the system, steadily cashing out every bit of equity from their houses—a situation that arose in part because banks didn't track whether borrowers took out subsequent loans from competitors. Another bad practice: a home-equity loan on top of a payment-option adjustable-rate mortgage. Those ARMs allow borrowers to make monthly payments that amount to less than the interest. The principal keeps growing, eroding the equity, which makes it a risky home-equity loan on top of an already risky mortgage. In a rapidly rising housing market, such practices didn't seem particularly reckless. After all, homeowners could quickly refinance, using newly accumulated equity to pay off a second loan, or even a third. So lenders were confident they would get their money back. "The proposition was that borrowers would refinance and pay this sucker off in six months or a year," says Guy Cecala, publisher of Inside Mortgage Finance. "But the market died." And a dramatic drop in prices started wiping out the value of many of these loans. Say a buyer purchased a home for $300,000, taking out a mortgage for $240,000 and a piggyback loan for $60,000 to cover the down payment. If the price of the house then dropped by 20%, to $240,000, the equity evaporates. That's what's now happening in some of the hardest-hit states such as Florida and California. So banks are getting stuck with home-equity loans that are worthless. That's because borrowers who don't have any equity in their homes are more likely to walk away entirely. Standard & Poor's (which, like BusinessWeek, is owned by The McGrawHill Companies (MHP)) looked at investment pools, analyzing the performance of 640,000 first mortgages with a piggyback loan attached to them. They found that those loans are 43% more likely to go into default than stand-alone mortgages. As a result, banks are scrambling to change their ways. Some are implementing stricter underwriting standards, ensuring that new borrowers have plenty of skin in the game by putting up more cash. Chase, for example, which tightened standards several times in 2007, lowered how much it would lend to borrowers in California and Florida by 10%. "Given our current underwriting standards, we wouldn't have done 30% of the homeequity loans we originated in 2006," says Thomas A. Kelly, a spokesman at Chase. Banks also contend that most of the problem loans and lines of credit came from thirdparty brokers and wholesalers, which they say did a poor job assessing borrowers' ability to repay. Wells calculates that independent brokers, which represented just 7% of its home-equity lending, accounted for 25% of its third-quarter losses. So Wells and other lenders are now refusing to buy home-equity products from that group. Meanwhile, the list of casualties is expanding to those who own and insure investment pools filled with home-equity loans. One of the worst-performing assets in E*Trade's (ETFC) $17 billion investment portfolio: bonds backed by home-equity loans. After more than a third of the bonds were downgraded to junk, the online broker in late November sold the troubled bonds and other investments to hedge fund Citadel. Radian Guaranty (RDN), which lost business to the banks when home-equity loans that doubled as down payments reduced the need for their mortgage insurance, started insuring securities backed by home-equity loans instead. In the latest quarter, it announced losses of $1.1 billion related to those deals. "We essentially stopped writing this business," Radian's Mark Casale said in a recent call with investors. "Unfortunately, we're still feeling the effects." The following article is one of the very very few pre 2005 articles on a key contributing factor to the Crash. Home is Where the Equity Is. Mortgage Refinancing and Household Consumption Erik Hurst Graduate School of Business University of Chicago, Illinois 60637 and Frank Stafford Department of Economics Institute for Social Research University of Michigan Ann Arbor, Michigan 48109 - 1220 August 2002 Excerpts from: Home is Where the Equity Is: Mortgage Refinancing and Household Consumption Abstract: This paper documents the extent to which homeowners use housing equity to smooth their consumption over time. Unlike drawing down other forms of saving, accessing accumulated home equity can be quite costly. Theoretically and empirically, a key distinction can be drawn between those refinancing their home mortgage to improve their wealth position from those who had a consumption smoothing motivation to refinance. Incorporating characteristics of a mortgage into a traditional permanent income model with exogenous liquidity constraints, one can understand household refinancing behavior in a world where mortgage interest rates are historically high and rising - up to now, an empirical puzzle. This model predicts a large consumption stimulus as mortgage rates are reduced allowing households with low pre-existing levels of liquid assets to more easily access their accumulated home equity. Using data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, households that experienced an unemployment shock and who had limited initial liquid assets to draw upon are shown to have been 25% more likely to refinance in the early 1990s. On average, liquidity constrained households converted over two-thirds of every dollar of equity they removed while refinancing into current consumption as mortgage rates plummeted between 1991 and 1994. In contrast, no such behavior was found in non-liquidity constrained refinancers. We estimate a corresponding stimulus of at least $28 billion from the refinancing activity of liquidity constrained households during the 1991-1994 period when mortgage interest rates were falling. VI. Mortgage Refinancing, Liquidity Constraints and Consumption It is quite conceivable that forward looking households would have equity trapped in their home. A series of negative income shocks could easily have depleted a household’s liquid saving. Given the large fixed costs associated with accessing their home equity, some households may prefer to alter their consumption away from their optimal path instead of refinancing. We saw such behavior predicted from the model in Section III. In these instances, households will be essentially liquidity constrained; they wish to increase their consumption, but are confronted by an unfavorable cost structure. However, the liquidity constraint can be partially alleviated in periods of declining interest rates as the net benefits to accessing the accumulated home equity are now larger. In order to compare the consumption behavior of liquidity constrained refinancing households, we first have to isolate households who we plausibly believe would be liquidity constrained. In this section, 15 Even if the present value wealth gain is not independent of the amount of equity that a household would like to remove, we VI. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS There are two reasons why a household may choose to refinance. 1) In periods of relatively low interest rates, the household would refinance to receive a lower stream of mortgage payments and consequently receive an increase in lifetime wealth, referred to as the “financial motivation” to refinance, and 2) households may refinance so as to access accumulated home equity - referred to as the “consumption smoothing motivation” to refinance. While the first motivation has been studied in detail in the literature, we are the first to model and test for the consumption smoothing motivation to refinance. If households receive a negative income shock they are more likely to choose to refinance if their reserves of more-liquid assets are limited, all else equal. Empirically, households are found to use their home as a financial buffer. Homeowners who had low levels of beginning period liquid assets and who subsequently experienced an unemployment shock were 25 percent more likely to refinance than other households – although they had to pay a higher rate to do so. The probability of refinancing diminished for households who experienced an unemployment shock and who had greater amounts of liquid assets to buffer the shock. Additionally, households who experienced a spell of unemployment and who had low levels of liquid assets were far more likely to remove equity during their refinancing process. These findings reconcile what have been termed as an Home Mortgage Finance Home ownership has been an important American value and the percentage of American households who own their own home has grown significantly to nearly sixty six per cent. Over the past half decade this growing percentage of home ownership has combined with rising real estate values, and historically low interest rates to produce a record breaking number of refinancings, and huge home equity withdrawals, Home equity is the largest "savings account" for most Americans, and as the real estate value cycle has put money in their savings accounts they have been withdrawing money through refinancing and through home equity withdrawals. Those who were able to secure long term fixed rate borrowings gained a good deal from the refinancings, even if they may have borrowed additional funds. Those whose rates are adjustable, or who had only short term fixed rates may encounter problems when interest rates rise. The assigned articles discuss these developments. Think about both individual family units that withdraw equity and compare and contrast their situations before and after the withdrawals. What are the primary reasons that people refinance? What are the primary reasons that people take out home equity loans? Why do you think is behind the deducibility of interest on a home mortgage? Do you agree with this policy? Problem Number 1 In 1998 Mr. and Mrs. Homeowner bought a home for $165,000; they put down @35,000 and took out a mortgage for the balance of $130,000. In 2005 the value of the home is $265,000 and interest rates have dropped from 6% to 5%. They have credit card debt of $25,000 and decide to withdraw $25,000 to pay off that debt and another $15,000 for home improvements and $4/000 for a once in a lifetime vacation. Compare and contrast their balance sheet before and after the transaction and their housing expenses and finally, consider the other ramifications of having more debt secured by the home and less credit card debt. In 2006 one of the largest home equity lending companies entered into a settlement agreement regarding allegations that its employees had encouraged prospective borrowers to fill in inaccurate information on their credit application in order to make the applications look better. Several years ago it came to light that Green Tree Acceptance Corporation was providing the financing for manufactured homes to thousands of people who clearly did not qualify for these loans. What are the causes and effects of such actions? What are the remedies when a consumer defaults on her home mortgage? What are the remedies when a consumer defaults on a loan secured by her car or her furniture? FIRST TIME HOME BUYERS Securitization and the Mortgage crisis http://fcic-static.law.stanford.edu/cdn_media/fcic-reports/2010-0407Preliminary_Staff_Report_-_Securitization_and_the_Mortgage_Crisis.pdf Chapter 7 SUBPRIME Credit Is the goal of sub-prime credit 1. To open the opportunity to borrow to people who would not qualify under lending criteria for prime products? or 2. To create profit by lending to people who do not have access to prime lending products? II. Differentiation Points A. B. rules Cost – interest rate, fees Practices – enforcement of Car title loans vs. article 9; credit card cross default . Sub-prime only products Payday , car title , tax refund anticipation loans, sued care dealer finance Normal products at sub prime rates and with sub- prime practices I. Introduction In this chapter we look at some peculiarly subprime products such as payday lending, car title lending, tax refund anticipation loans and rent to town and also the subprime products in mainstream lending such as mortgages, car loans and credit cards. First a definition or description of the term subprime. Here is what the FDIC says. The term "subprime" refers to the credit characteristics of individual borrowers. Subprime borrowers typically have weakened credit histories that include payment delinquencies, and possibly more severe problems such as charge-offs, judgments, and bankruptcies. They may also display reduced repayment capacity as measured by credit scores, debt-to-income ratios, or other criteria that may encompass borrowers with incomplete credit histories. Subprime loans are loans to borrowers displaying one or more of these characteristics at the time of origination or purchase. Such loans have a higher risk of default than loans to prime borrowers. Generally, subprime borrowers will display a range of credit risk characteristics that may include one or more of the following: •Two or more 30-day delinquencies in the last 12 months, or one or more 60-day delinquencies in the last 24 months; •Judgment, foreclosure, repossession, or charge-off in the prior 24 months; •Bankruptcy in the last 5 years; •Relatively high default probability as evidenced by, for example, a credit bureau risk score (FICO) of 660 or below (depending on the product/collateral), or other bureau or proprietary scores with an equivalent default probability likelihood; and/or •Debt service-to-income ratio of 50% or greater, or otherwise limited ability to cover family living expenses after deducting total monthly debt-service requirements from monthly income. This list is illustrative rather than exhaustive and is not meant to define specific parameters for all subprime borrowers. Additionally, this definition may not match all market or institution specific subprime definitions, but should be viewed as a starting point from which the Agencies will expand examination efforts. And Investopedia Definition of 'Subprime Loan' A type of loan that is offered at a rate above prime to individuals who do not qualify for prime rate loans. Quite often, subprime borrowers are often turned away from traditional lenders because of their low credit ratings or other factors that suggest that they have a reasonable chance of defaulting on the debt repayment. And finally an article from the Wall Street Journal Blog bemoaning the difficulties in defining sub prime. Defining Subprime: Easier Said Than Done. The Securities and Exchange Commission’s probe into Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac appears to be hinging on a simple question: What’s the definition of a subprime mortgage? The SEC is investigating whether the mortgage titans’ disclosures to investors of subprime and other risky mortgages may have misled investors about their decisions to take on more risk. So far, four current or former officials of the companies have acknowledged that they could face civil charges from the SEC, including Daniel Mudd and Richard Syron, the former chief executives of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, respectively. The trick in this case is that there never was an agreed upon definition of a “subprime” mortgage. Fannie and Freddie got into even more trouble by buying up lots of Alt-A mortgages, which is even harder to define but generally consisted of loans between prime and subprime where borrowers didn’t have to document their incomes. So what are some of the potential definitions of subprime? The FDIC in 2001 said that loans with credit scores below 660 generally had a “relatively high default probability.” The mortgage industry, by contrast, generally said that loans below 620 were subprime. (While there weren’t explicit definitions of subprime loans, federal regulators did have detailed definitions of “high cost” mortgages. Those were often confused with subprime loans because those mortgages were the most likely to go to borrowers with weak credit.) In other cases, subprime referred not to the borrower, but to the loan. Some in the industry considered subprime mortgages to be those that weren’t eligible for sale to Fannie and Freddie. Over the past decade, the mortgage titans gradually relaxed their loan-purchase standards, which made that definition unusable. While around 5% of loans guaranteed by Fannie in 2007 had credit scores below 620, the company said that only 0.3% of its loans were considered “subprime.” That was because Fannie defined subprime loans only as those that were flagged as “subprime” by the loan seller or that were purchased from subprime originators. “There’s a broad agreement on what the qualities of a subprime loan are, but there’s no very technical definition. There’s a big gray area,” says Mark Calabria, director of financial regulation studies at the libertarian Cato Institute who recently published a paper exploring some of these issues. Further muddying the waters, as lending standards deteriorated, more borrowers were able to take out mortgages with no down payments, with minimal income verification, and with special “interest only” features that allowed them to avoid making principal payments for several years. Some analysts have argued for a much broader definition of “subprime” to include these loans. Here’s an example: nearly 15% of loans bought by Fannie in 2007 were “interest only.” If those loans went to borrowers with great credit, it would be hard to argue that they were subprime loans. But if they went to borrowers who made minimal down payments, it would similarly be hard to argue that these were traditional “prime” loans. These definitions were the subject of some intense debate by members of the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission. What is the difference between subprime and predatory? Please read the following articles: Ronald Mann on sub- prime is a good thing. After the Great Recession: Regulating Financial Services for Low and Middle Income Communities by Ronald Mann http://scholarlycommons.law.wlu.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=4275&context=wlulr Subprime Lending Is Back, And That's Not Such A Bad Thing Don’t look now but banks are once again issuing lines of credit to customers with bad credit histories. Bank credit cards, retail credit cards and auto loans are all more readily available to subprime borrowers over the last year according to a March report from Equifax. Bank-issued credit card lending to sub-prime consumers jumped 41% between 2010 and 2011 hitting a four-year high in December 2011 with 1.1 million new bank credit cards issued. Plus, at $12.5 billion, bankcard limits are at their highest level since 2008 when the limit stood around $27.4 billion. No Surprise Here, Bank Of America Looks To Charge More Fees Halah TouryalaiForbes Staff Here Are The Banks That Lost The Most Under The Durbin Amendment Halah TouryalaiForbes Staff 21 images Photos: Ten Top Credit Card Choices From College To Retirement Retail credit cards also saw an increase in lending to riskier borrowers. From 2010 to 2011 there was a 4.7 percentage point increase in retail card originations to sub-prime borrowers, making up 31% of 2011 retail credit card originations, Equifax says. Subprime borrowers are also seeing credit lines easing in the auto loan arena. Equifax says new auto finance loan amounts increased $11.6 billion from 2010 ($164.6 billion) to 2011 ($176.2 billion), hitting the highest originations level since 2007 ($221.1 billion). “The evidence of increased lending to sub-prime consumers demonstrates banks’ ongoing efforts to grow lending by providing credit opportunities to more consumers,” said Equifax Chief Economist Amy Crews Cutts. “Year-over-year results show borrowers are taking advantage of the new opportunities and seeking to diversify their financial activity, which is building momentum toward economic improvement.” That might be especially true for banks whose revenue pipelines have been squeezed in part because of new rules and regulations. The so-called Durbin amendment, for instance, limits the fees banks can collect from merchants like Target and Walmart when their customers swipe their debit cards there. The Card Act is another revenue killer for banks which, among other things, keeps them from charging overdraft fees. And there may be more limitations on the way as the Consumer Finance Protection Bureau recently launched an inquiry asking banks for data about their overdraft practices. The New York Times wrote about the subprime lending comeback saying “As financial institutions recover from the losses on loans made to troubled borrowers, some of the largest lenders to the less than creditworthy, including Capital One and GM Financial, are trying to woo them back, while HSBC and JPMorgan Chase are among those tiptoeing again into subprime lending.” Indeed, Trefis finds that JPM’s credit and debit card business is the most valuable unit, contributing to just under a quarter of its value. The bank reports first quarter earnings Friday and Trefis expects an increase in JPMorgan’s outstanding card loan portfolio and improvement in its provisions for credit card loans as fewer loans are expected to go bad. For the likes of Bank of America, JPMorgan Chase, Citi and Wells Fargo increasing revenue in this low growth and heavily regulated environment is a big challenge for the industry. So it’s not such a huge surprise that lenders are looking to widen their scope in their search for new borrowers. After all, their investors are banking sector’s growth prospects very closely in the post-crisis world. Plus, increased lending, even if it is to subprime consumers, shouldn’t be completely frowned upon because it’s one way to help boost economic growth. Besides, lending to subprime borrowers wasn’t the whole problem–it was lending to them without so much as verifying employment, their income and assets. Remember NINJA loans? With that in mind, the most important thing for lenders is to keep the lessons learned from 2008 crisis fresh in their memory. The key will be managing the risk that comes with territory of lending to less than stellar borrowers. QUICK HISTORY OF SUB PRIME LENDING McLEAN, Va. (12/12/07)--In an effort to improve their credit history, many consumers are unknowingly signing up for subprime credit cards--often with disastrous consequences (USA Today Dec. 9). Targeted to young adults with no or little credit history, as well as to those with a tarnished credit history, issuers of subprime credit cards--referred to as predatory by some critics--are taking advantage of vulnerable consumers who can least afford the excessive fees. How excessive? In one example, with a low credit limit of $250, some applicants were socked with an array of fees that totaled $178, leaving the user just $72 to spend on that card during the year. Instead of improving their credit history, victims are sinking deeper in debt. The National Consumer Law Center, Boston, issued a warning to consumers on Nov. 1 that these high-fee, lowcredit predatory credit cards are merely a way for some issuers to extract as many junk fees as possible from consumers desperate for credit. What should you watch for? * Low limits. If the card carries an unusually low line of credit--say, only a few hundred dollars--that’s the first clue it may be a predatory credit card. * Phrases that may not sound like fees. In the fine print, look for phrases such as account maintenance, account set-up, program, participation, and activation fees. * Fees that put you over the limit. Excessive fees--which add up quickly--reduce your available balance right off the bat. Cardholders who don’t deduct those fees from their available balance increasingly are slapped with over-the-limit fees. * ”Good-guy” claims. The issuer may make the claim that it’s going out of its way to help users get out of debt trouble and give credit to subprime borrowers. One issuer justified its predatory credit card by stating that its “mission” is to bring affordable banking services to minority communities. And with millions of cash-strapped homeowners facing foreclosure, claims like these may sound enticing. Looking for an alternative? Get a secured credit card, says Susan Tiffany, director of personal finance information for adults at the Credit Union National Association's Center for Personal Finance. “You’ll have to deposit money with your credit union or other reputable lender, and then use that line of credit to build a good credit history. Repay purchases in full and on time each month. Then after a time, say six months to a year, apply for a traditional unsecured card with a higher limit.” Subprime loans are pricey, but can help credit history By Bankrate.com So maybe you've never filed for bankruptcy, foreclosed on a house or defaulted on a loan. You have, however, paid a few bills late, which lowered your credit score. If your credit score dropped below 620, you may have made yourself a subprime lending customer. Subprime loans are a mixed bag for those with blemished credit histories. They can help renters own homes and cash-strapped folks pay off debts. They also cost more and come with significant risks. Make sure you belong in the subprime category and understand all its pitfalls before you proceed with a subprime loan. Think about it Experts caution people to carefully weigh the benefits and drawbacks of taking out a subprime loan. Having one and handling it well can help repair a damaged credit history, but a subprime loan can cost thousands more in interest than standard mortgages. Subprime lending, by its very nature, places lenders at risk. When all is said and done, that means banks and other players charge higher rates for subprime loans to compensate for potential losses from customers who may run into trouble or default. Subprime loans also cost more because they are considered "nonconforming," or not up to the standards of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Those two quasi-governmental agencies buy traditional, "conforming" mortgages from lenders, repackage them and sell them to Wall Street investment firms as securities. Track record counts Borrowers can fall into the subprime category for any number of reasons, and assessing how risky a customer is can be a difficult thing for lenders. The process relies less on the computerized credit scoring methods widely favored by traditional lenders and more on a borrower's debt payment track record, according to subprime experts. In the end, customers get stamped with a school-like ranking: A for those with the best credit, B, C or D for those with progressively worse histories. An E can show up as well, but is extremely rare. One question, two answers Where someone falls on the scale depends on a number of things. And two lenders may look at the same borrower and arrive at two different credit grades because the categories aren't set in stone. Someone with a generally good credit record, but who paid their mortgage 30 days late within the past year, could earn an A-minus. The grade of D could be the result of bankruptcy or foreclosure. Subprime lenders will look at a potential borrower's general pattern of financial behavior. If you are usually on time with your payments, you'll most likely be a B or a C consumer. A borrower's credit grade determines a number of factors, including what rate the loan will carry and how much of a home's value will be loaned. On a 30-year fixed mortgage, for instance, a borrower just shy of an A rating would most likely be able to borrow 90 percent of a new home's value at a rate a couple of percentage points or so above the going rate. Someone with D credit could borrow less at a higher interest rate. Use of the term predatory When is sub prime predatory and When is it not predatory Discussion Issues: Please consider the effects of Securitization on sub prime debt; Please consider the effects of selling debt Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series The Impact of Local Predatory Lending Laws on the Flow of Subprime Credit Giang Ho and Anthony Pennington-Cross Working Paper 2006-009A http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2006/2006-009.pdf February 2006 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Research Division P.O. Box 442 St. Louis, MO 63166 The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. The Impact of Local Predatory Lending Laws on the Flow of Subprime Credit A shorter version is forthcoming in the Journal of Urban Economics Giang Ho & Anthony Pennington-Cross* Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Research Division The Impact of Local Predatory Lending Laws on the Flow of Subprime Credit: North Carolina and Beyond Abstract: Local authorities in North Carolina, and subsequently in at least 23 other states, have enacted laws intending to reduce predatory and abusive lending. While there is substantial variation in the laws, they typically extend the coverage of the Federal Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act (HOEPA) by including home purchase and openend mortgage credit, by lowering annual percentage rate (APR) and fees and points triggers, and by prohibiting or restricting the use of balloon payments and prepayment penalties. Empirical results show that the typical local predatory lending law tends to reduce rejections, while having little impact on the flow (application and origination) of credit. However, the strength of the law, measured by the extent of market coverage and the extent of prohibitions, can have strong impacts on both the flow of credit and rejections. Introduction The current mortgage market consists primarily of two segments – the prime market and the subprime market. The prime market extends credit to the majority of households. The subprime market provides more expensive credit to households who do not qualify for a prime mortgage. These households tend to be less financially secure and located in lowincome areas and areas with a concentration of minorities. The combination of higher borrower costs and higher rates of delinquency and foreclosure have led to public policy concerns over fairness and accessibility of credit. Subprime lending represents an opportunity for the mortgage market to extend the possibility of home ownership beyond traditional barriers. These barriers have existed because the prime segment of the mortgage market uses lending standards (credit scores and documented employment history, income, and wealth, among other factors) to accept or reject loan applicants. Applicants that are rejected or expect to be rejected can look to the more expensive subprime market. In this fashion the subprime market completes the mortgage market and can be welfare enhancing (Chinloy and MacDonald [4]) because it provides the opportunity of home ownership to a larger portion of the population. Over the past ten years subprime lending has grown rapidly -- from $65 billion to $332 billion of originations from 1995 through 2003 (Inside Mortgage Finance [17]).1 According to the Mortgage Bankers Association of America, the rate that loans were in foreclosure from the 1 These numbers are derived from type B&C loans. B&C loans are loans with less than an A (or prime) rating. See the Mortgage Markets Statistics Annual published by Inside Mortgage Finance for more details on loan classification schemes. first quarter of 1998 to the third quarter of 2004 rose by more than 400 percent for subprime loans while declining by approximately 25 percent for prime loans. In addition, during the same time period anecdotal evidence of predatory lending in the subprime market was gaining more public and regulatory attention.2 Therefore, the welfare benefit associated with increased access to credit is believed to have been reduced by some unscrupulous lending in the subprime mortgage market. In response to public concerns of predation in the subprime mortgage market, federal regulations generated under the Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act (HOEPA) restrict some types of high-cost lending. Many states, cities, and counties have used HOEPA as a template and have extended the restrictions on credit to an even broader class of mortgages. These restrictions include limits on allowable prepayment penalties and balloon payments, prohibitions of joint financing of various insurance products (credit, life, unemployment, etc), and requirements that borrowers participate in loan counseling. By introducing geographically defined predatory lending laws, policymakers have conducted a natural experiment with well defined control and treatment groups. Since state boundaries reflect political and not economic regions, we can compare mortgage market conditions in states with a law in effect3 (the treatment group) to those in neighboring states currently without a predatory lending law (the control group). However, instead of examining whole states we focus on households that are geographically close to each other (border counties) and as a result are in similar labor and housing markets. 2 See HUD-Treasury report (HUD-Treasury [16]) and Federal Reserve HOEPA Final Rule (Federal Reserve [8]). 3 Laws are first enacted by the local legislature and become effective typically at a later date. It is not until the law becomes in effect that lenders are required to follow the new rules and restrictions. Data at the individual loan level are used to identify the impact of local predatory lending laws on subprime applications, originations, and rejections. Specifically, we find that there is substantial heterogeneity in the response of the mortgage market to local predatory lending laws. In fact, in contrast to previous research on the impact of the North Carolina law, the flow of subprime credit can increase, decrease, or be unaffected by the laws. To help understand this heterogeneity we create an index that measures the strength of the local predatory laws. This index measures the increase in market coverage and the extent that certain lending practices and mortgage types are restricted. This paper provides at least four contributions to the literature: (i) a wide variety of local predatory lending laws are characterized, (ii) the question of whether the market response in North Carolina (reduce flow of credit) was typical or atypical is examined, (iii) the importance of the strength of the law on the flow of credit is examined and (iv) the probability of a state introducing a predatory lending law is treated as jointly determined with the flow of subprime credit. Given the perception that predation has occurred in the subprime market and not in the prime market, the volume of lending as measured by the number of originations and applications may be lower than expected, given the distribution of credit risk, r (Φ) . One of the primary purposes of predatory lending laws is to weed out the “lemons” in the subprime mortgage market. If households feel that the predatory lending law has been successful, there may be less need to spend time and energy to identify the dishonest loans and other households may feel more comfortable applying for a mortgage; in this scenario Λ(.) is reduced to zero or much closer to zero. Therefore, if the subprime market is operating as a lemons market the introduction of the predatory lending law should have two countervailing forces. First, as illustrated in Figures 1 and 2, the law should reduce applications and originations because of tighter lending standards. Second, as illustrated in Figure 3, the law should induce potential applicants back into the market; If the law removes or heavily regulates the dishonest loans there would be little or no fear of being taken advantage of and no need to expend effort sorting honest loans from dishonest loans. Therefore, in markets with a substantial lemons problem, or big Λ(.) , the impact of a predatory lending law could be neutral or could increase the rate of subprime application and origination. In addition, if Λ(.) is not strictly proportional, but has a larger impact on potential borrowers closer or farther away from Φ S , then the introduction of a predatory lending law could also increase or decrease rejection rates. National Lending Restrictions – Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act Congress enacted HOEPA (Pub. L. 103-325, 108 Stat. 21600) by amending the Truth in Lending Act (TILA, 15 U.S.C 1601). In 1994, the Board of Governors implemented HOEPA through 12 CFR part 226 (Regulation Z), which articulates specific rules governing lending practices. HOEPA and the regulations promulgated under it define a class of loans that are given special consideration. HOEPA-covered loans (loans where HOEPA applies) include only closed-end home equity loans that meet APR and finance fee triggers. Home purchase loans and other types of lending backed by a home, such as lines of credit, are not covered by HOEPA. The original version, in 1994, set out the framework and defined the triggers and restrictions. The second version, in 2002, adjusted some of the triggers and restricted some additional practices. In the 2002 version, HOEPA protections were triggered in one of two ways: (i) if the loan’s APR exceeded the rate for Treasury securities of comparable maturity by 8 percentage points or more on the first lien and 10 percentage points or higher on higher liens or (ii) if finance charges, including points and fees paid at closing for optional insurance programs and other debt protection programs, were greater than 8 percent of the loan amount or a fixed $480 amount indexed annually to the consumer price index. For HOEPA-covered loans, creditors were not allowed to provide short-term balloon notes, impose prepayment penalties greater than five years, use non-amortizing schedules, make no- documentation loans, refinance loans into another HOEPA loan in the first 12 months, or impose higher interest rate upon default. In addition, creditors were not allowed to habitually engage in lending that did not take into account the ability of the consumer to repay the loan. Regional Restrictions – State and Local Predatory Lending Laws A number of states and local municipalities have sought to impose restrictions on predatory lending that reach further than HOEPA and Regulation Z. Ho and PenningtonCross [15] provide a detailed description of each law in Appendix A.6 Beginning with North Carolina in 1999, at least 23 states have passed predatory lending laws that are currently in effect: including Arkansas, California, Colorado, Connecticut, Florida, Georgia, Illinois, Kentucky, Maine, Maryland, Massachusetts, Nevada, New Jersey, New Mexico, New York, North Carolina, Ohio, Oklahoma, Pennsylvania, South Carolina, Texas, Utah, and Wisconsin. Both the original and the 2002 versions of HOEPA defined a class of high-cost refinance mortgages that were subject to special restrictions. The state laws tend to follow this lead and expand the definition of covered loans. For example, North Carolina – the first state to enact predatory lending restrictions -- includes both closed-end and open-end mortgages but not reverse mortgages and limits loan size to the conventional conforming limit (loans small enough to be purchased by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and therefore not considered part of the jumbo market). HOEPA covers only those closed-end loans that are not for home purchase (typically refinance and second mortgages). North Carolina did leave the APR triggers the same as the HOEPA triggers, although the points and fees triggers were reduced from the HOEPA 8 percent of total loan amount to 5 percent for loans under $20,000. For 6 Every attempt was made to include all laws in effect by the end of 2004 that, similar to HOEPA, use triggers to define a class of loans eligible for restrictions and disclosures. Because other laws are likely to exist, those discussed here should be viewed as a sample of all the state and local predatory lending laws. Other states have laws that do not focus on high-cost or subprime lending and do not have any triggers (Idaho, Michigan, Minnesota, Mississippi, Nebraska, New Hampshire, Oregon, Tennessee, Washington, and West Virginia). loans $20,000 or larger, the same 8 percent trigger is used or $1,000, whichever is smaller. The North Carolina law also prohibits prepayment penalties and balloon payments for most covered loans. But the law also prohibits the financing of credit life, disability, unemployment, or other life and insurance premiums, while HOEPA included them only as part of the trigger calculation. While most states followed the North Carolina example by expanding the coverage and restrictions associated with HOEPA, there is substantial variation in the laws. In an attempt to quantify the differences in the local laws, we created an index. The higher the index, the stronger the law is. In addition, the index can be broken down into two components. The first component reflects the extent that the law extends market coverage beyond HOEPA. The second component reflects the extent that the law restricts or requires specific practices on covered loans. Table 1 summarizes the construction of the law index. The full index is the sum of all the assigned points as defined in Table 1 and the coverage and restrictions indexes are the sum of points assigned in each subcategory. The coverage category includes measures of loan purpose, APR first lien, APR higher liens, and points and fees. In general, if the law does not increase coverage beyond HOEPA it is assigned zero points. Higher points are assigned if the coverage is broader. In each category the highest points are assigned when all loans are covered. For example, points assigned for loan purpose range from zero to four and the highest point total (four) indicates that the law covers all loan purposes. The points assigned for extending first lien APR trigger ranges from zero to three depending on how low the trigger is. For example, 7 percent triggers are assigned one point while 6 percent triggers are assigned two points. In addition, laws that do not have a first lien trigger are assigned three points. A similar scheme is used to assigned points for higher lien triggers and the points and fees triggers. In general, if the law includes multiple triggers within a category the most stringent trigger is used to assign the points. 7 The restrictions index includes measures of prepayment penalty restrictions, balloon restrictions, counseling requirements, and restrictions on mandatory arbitration. If the law does not require any restrictions then zero points are assigned. Higher points indicate more restrictions. For example, laws that do not restrict prepayment penalties are assigned zero points, while laws that prohibit all prepayment penalties are assigned four points. Laws that prohibit or restrict the practice more quickly are assigned higher points. For balloon restriction, the points vary from zero for no restrictions to four when the law prohibits all balloons.8 The last two restrictions measure whether the law requires counseling before the loan is originated or restricts fully or partially mandatory arbitration clauses. Table 2 reports the calculated full (law) index, the coverage index, and the restrictions index for each law identified as being in effect by the end of 2004. The average law index is 10.16, varying from 4 in Florida, Maine, and Nevada to 17 in New Mexico and Cleveland. The coverage index and the restrictions index have a mean just over 5. The coverage and restrictions indexes are only modestly correlated at 0.19. This indicates that, while laws that increase coverage more also tend to increase the restrictions more, the relationship is very noisy. Therefore, there are laws that increase coverage without increasing restrictions Literature on Local Predatory Lending Laws Research on the impact of predatory lending laws has been primarily focused on the impact of the North Carolina law. Various data sets, both publicly available and privately held, have been used for analysis. However, regardless of the method and author affiliations, the North Carolina law was found to have a significant impact on the flow of credit. Papers by Ernst, Farris, and Stein [7] and Quercia, Stegman, and Davis [22, 23] use tables of mortgage conditions before and after the North Carolina law became effective, or in effect, and compares these metrics with growth rates in nearby states and the nation as a whole. Using the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) data set and a list of subprime lenders created by HUD, Ernst, Farris, and Stein [7] find that the volume of loans originated did decline relative to the rest of the U.S. However, using data leased from a private data vendor called LoanPerformance (LP), Quercia, Stegman, and Davis [22] find no volume impact on purchases or low credit score loans. However, they do find some evidence that interest rates are higher on average, refinance activity declines, and the prevalence of prepayment penalties is lower; but the impact on balloons and high loan-to-value loans is mixed. Using the same data, Quercia, Stegman, and Davis [23] find that the decline in volume in North Carolina was largely associated with refinancing loans. The LP data set differs greatly from the HMDA data because it provides much more detail about loan characteristics and is very expensive to lease for one year (over $100,000). In addition, the LP data likely does not provide a complete picture of the subprime mortgage market because it includes only loans that are securitized. If loans of better quality (A- rated) or pricing tend to have higher rates of securitization, then the LP data represent only one segment of the subprime market. Chomsisengphet and Pennington-Cross [5] show that the rate of foreclosures, as reported by the Mortgage Bankers Association of America (MBAA), shows different time series properties than the LP data and was on average almost three times the LP foreclosure rate. Therefore, for the purpose of volume comparisons, HMDA is the preferred source because of its better market coverage. Harvey and Nigro [13, 14] and Elliehausen and Staten [6] go beyond univariate tables and estimate multivariate equations to identify the impact of the laws in North Carolina, Chicago, and Philadelphia. Since publication the Philadelphia law is no longer in effect. On both Harvey and Nigro papers a proprietary version of HMDA along with the HUD subprime lender list is used while Elliehausen and Staten use proprietary loan information provided by nine members of the American Financial Services Association (AFSA). AFSA has been an active participant in legal challenges of local predatory lending laws and represents some of the largest subprime lenders (Ameriquest Mortgage Company, Conseco Finance Corporation, Countrywide Home Loans, Equity One, CitiFinancial, Household Finance Corporation, Key Consumer Real Estate, Washington Mutual Finance and Wells Fargo Financial, Inc.). All three papers include explanatory variables that control for location and borrower characteristics, as available. Harvey and Nigro estimate at the loan level the probability of applying for a subprime loan, originating a subprime loan, and being rejected on a subprime application in a logit estimation. Elliehausen and Staten count the number of originations up to the county level and create a panel data set from 1995 through 2000 and estimate a negative binomial regression on all observed originations covering the whole U.S. Despite these many methodological and data source differences, all three multivariate papers find evidence that the introduction of the North Carolina law substantially reduced the flow of credit in the subprime mortgage market. Consistent with the simple theory of a market without considering any lemons issues, the reduction in flow was attributed more to a reduction in applications than an increase in rejections. In addition, low-income areas and households tended to have larger declines. Data Design, Identification, and Probit Estimation To examine whether the experience in North Carolina is typical we use the publicly available version of HMDA in conjunction with the HUD subprime lenders list.9 Any loan application or origination associated with a lender on the list is identified as a subprime loan. All other loans are treated as not-subprime, that is, as a conventional loan. Because it is impossible to fully characterize borrower and location characteristics, the sample is reduced to include only locations where a new predatory lending law has been introduced and other locations that are physically nearby. The locations where the law comes into effect can be viewed as the treatment group and locations where no new law comes into effect can be viewed as the control group.10 Therefore, only counties that border other states without a local predatory lending law are used for the treatment group. The control group includes only counties in neighboring states that border the treatment state and do not have a predatory lending law in effect during the examined time period (the year before and after the introduction of the law). This contrasts with other studies (Harvey and Nigro [14], Elliehausen and Staten [6]) that have used the whole of the U.S. or regions to define both control and treatment groups. To help remove the impact of any temporary reaction to each law and any market reaction prior to the law coming into effect, only the year before and the year after the law is in effect are included in the sample. This approach should help to increase the comparability of the 9 http://www.huduser.org/datasets/manu.html, accessed on 2/1/05. HUD generates a list of subprime lenders from industry trade publications, HMDA data analysis, and phone calls to the lender confirm the extent of subprime lending. Since this list is defined at the lender level, loans made by the subprime lenders may include both prime and subprime loans. In addition, subprime loans made by predominately prime lenders will also be incorrectly identified as prime lending. Therefore, an alternative interpretation of the loans identified using the HUD subprime lender list is that it identifies the extent of specialized subprime lending -- not full-service lending. 10 This geographically based sampling does not create a “matched” sample, where one similar loan in the treatment location is matched with another loan in the control location. In short, all observed loans in the specified location and time periods are included. treatment group and the control group because they are geographically closer and, as a result, likely to be more economically similar than full state and region comparisons. This approach and HMDA availability reduce the sample to ten local predatory lending laws: California, Connecticut, Florida, Georgia, Maryland, Massachusetts, North Carolina, Ohio, Pennsylvania, and Texas. Identification Strategy To identify the impact of a local predatory lending law, the location and timing of the law becoming effective, along with borrower and location characteristics, are included. Table 4 describes the variables and data sources. Similar to Harvey and Nigro [13, 14], three separate dependent variables will be tested for impacts of local predatory lending laws -the probability of applying for a subprime loan, the probability of originating a subprime loan, and the probability of being rejected on a subprime application. The key variable of interest is Ineffect. This variable indicates that a loan is in a location when and where a predatory lending law is effective. It is defined as zero before the law is effective, even in the treatment location, and is always zero in the control location. Ineffect is constructed by interacting the variable Law, which indicates locations where the law will eventually be in effect, and Postlaw, which indicates the time period after a law has become effective. Therefore, Law identifies the treatment location and Postlaw identifies the time period the treatment is in effect. The reference group is defined as locations where the law will never be in effect in the time period before the law is in effect. There are no priors regarding the coefficients on Law or Postlaw, because they will capture prevailing probabilities associated with location and time that are not controlled for by other variables. Given the results from prior research we would expect Ineffect to be negative for the application and origination outcome and potentially insignificant for the rejection outcome. Conclusion Starting with North Carolina in 1999, states and other localities across the U.S. have introduced legislation intended to curb predatory and abusive lending in the subprime mortgage market. These laws usually extend the reach of the Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act (HOEPA) by including home purchase and open-end mortgage credit, lowering annual percentage rate (APR) and fees and points triggers and prohibiting and/or restricting the use of balloon payments and prepayment penalties on covered loans. While prior literature found evidence that the North Carolina law did reduce the flow of credit, the results in this paper indicate that the typical law has little impact on the flow of subprime credit as measured by loan origination and application. However, rejections do decline by over 10 percent for the typical law. The reduction in rejections may reflect less aggressive marketing, additional pre-screening by lenders, increased self-selection by borrowers, or other factors. While a reduction in rejection rates may not have been the intent of the predatory lending law, it does indicate that borrowers are benefiting by saving non- refundable application costs when rejected for a subprime loan. However, not all local predatory lending laws are created equal. The results indicate that the heterogeneity in law strength can help further explain the mechanisms that make one law decrease the flow of credit and another actually increase the flow of credit. The strength of the law is measured along two dimensions – coverage and restrictions. Some laws provide broad coverage of the subprime market (Colorado) and others very little coverage (Texas). Some have substantial restrictions (Georgia) on allowable lending, while others have very few restrictions (Maine). The results indicate that coverage and restrictions tend to have opposite impacts. In general, laws with more extensive restrictions are associated with larger decreases in the flow of credit. In fact, laws with the strongest restrictions can decrease applications by over 50 percent. In contrast, laws with broad coverage can increase applications by even more than 50 percent. Therefore, although on the surface local predatory lending laws seem to have little impact, the design of the law can stimulate the subprime market, depress the subprime market, or leave volumes relatively steady but with lower rejection rates. As a result, the design of the law can have economically important impacts on the flow and make- up of the mortgage market. In future research it would be helpful to determine how product mix adjusts to the introduction of these laws. For example, the laws make no distinction between initial interest rates on fixed rate and adjustable interest rate loans. But adjustable rate loans tend to have lower initial rates, resulting in substitution rather than fewer loans, and can include teaser terms that temporarily reduce the rate below the benchmark. Therefore, adjustable rate loans may be one way to avoid the trigger APR levels in predatory lending laws and shift a borrower out from under the protective coverage of the regulations. There also may be a regulatory burden associated with these laws that needs to be passed on to consumers through higher interest rates and upfront fees. Lastly, these laws may reduce the availability of the secondary market leading to liquidity issues in the subprime market, which may also increase the cost of credit. References 1. G. Akerlof, The Market for “Lemons”: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488-500 (1970). 2. B. W. Ambrose, A. Pennington-Cross, and A. M. Yezer, Credit Rationing in the U.S. Mortgage Market: Evidence from Variation in FHA Market Shares, Journal of Urban Economics, 51, 272-294 (2002). 3. P. Calem, K. Gillen., and S. Wachter, The Neighborhood Distribution of Subprime Mortgage Lending, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 29(4), 393-410 (2004). 4. P. Chinloy and N. MacDonald, Subprime Lenders and Mortgage Market Completion, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 30(2), 153-165 (2005). 5. S. Chomsisengphet and A. Pennington-Cross, Borrower Cost and Credit Rationing in the Subprime Mortgage Market, Presented at the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association Mid-Year meetings in Washington D.C. (2004). 6. G. Elliehausen and M. E. Staten, Regulation of Subprime Mortgage Products: An Analysis of North Carolina's Predatory Lending Law, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 29(4), 411-434 (2004). 7. K. Ernst, J. Farris, and E. Stein, North Carolina’s Subprime Home Loan Market after Predatory Lending Reform, Durham, NC: Center for Responsible Lending, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, (2002). 8. Federal Reserve, Truth in Lending, Final Rule, 12 CFP part 226, Regulation Z; Docket No. R-1090, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2002). 9. M. Ferguson and S. Peters, What Constitutes Evidence of Discrimination in Lending? Journal of Finance, 50(2), 739-748 (1995). 10. W. H. Greene, Marginal Effects in the Bivariate Probit Model, Leonard N. Stern School of Business working paper (1996). 11. W. H. Greene, Gender Economics Courses in Liberal Arts Colleges: Comment, Leonard N. Stern School of Business working paper (1998). 12. W. H. Greene, Econometric Analysis, Fifth Edition, Prentice-Hall, Inc., Upper Saddle River, New Jersey (2003). 13. K. D. Harvey and P. J. Nigro, How Do Predatory Lending Laws Influence Mortgage lending in Urban Areas? A Tale of Two Cities, Journal of Real Estate Research 25(4), 479-508 (2003). 14. K. D. Harvey and P. J. Nigro, Do Predatory Lending Laws Influence Mortgage Lending? An Analysis of the North Carolina Predatory Lending Law, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 29(4), 435-456 (2004). 15. G. Ho and A. Pennington-Cross, The Impact of Local Predatory Lending Laws, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis working paper No. 2005-049B (2005). Available at http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2005/2005-049.pdf 16. HUD-Treasury, Curbing Predatory Home Mortgage Lending, United States Department of Housing and Urban Development and the United States Treasury Department (2000). Available at huduser.org/publications/hsgfin/curbing.html. 17. IMF, Mortgage Market Statistics Annual, Inside Mortgage Finance Publications, Inc., Bethesda Maryland (2004). Available at www.imfpubs.com. 18. G. S. Maddala, Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics, Cambridge University Press (1983). 19. E. C. Norton, H. Wang, and C. Ai, Computing Interaction Effects and Standard Errors in Logit and Probit Models, The Stata Journal, 4(2), 103-116 (2004). 20. A. Pennington-Cross, Subprime Lending in the Primary and Secondary Markets, Journal of Housing Research, 13(1), 31-50 (2002). 21. A. Pennington-Cross, Credit History and the Performance of Prime and Nonprime Mortgages, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 27(3), 279-301 (2003). 22. R. Quercia, M. A. Stegman, and W. R. Davis, The Impact of North Carolina’s Antipredatory Lending Law: A Descriptive Assessment, Durham, NC: Center for Community Capitalism, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill (2003). 23. R. Quercia, M. A. Stegman, and W. R. Davis, Assessing the Impact of North Carolina’s Predatory Lending Law, Housing Policy Debate, 15(3), 573-601 (2004). 24. R. Scheessele, 1998 HMDA Highlights, Housing Finance Working Paper Series, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, HF-009 (1998). October 1, 2008 Sam Magavern An edited version of this essay appeared in the Buffalo News, October 3, 2008 and is available at http://www.buffalonews.com/149/story/453788.html. Subprime lending has triggered a global financial crisis, but it remains misunderstood. Here are some basic facts, culled from an upcoming report on abandoned housing by the Partnership for the Public Good. Subprime loans are high cost loans, ostensibly designed for people with less than “prime” credit. In reality, mortgage brokers and lenders often succeed in selling subprime loans to people with good credit. According to the Wall Street Journal, by 2006, fully 61% of subprime loans were going to people who qualified for conventional loans. Subprime lending grew very fast: from 7% of home loans (2000) to 21% (2006), creating a $600 billion industry. This explosion was fueled by many factors, including the deregulation of financial services, which allowed non-banks, such as mortgage companies, to lend with very little oversight. Traditional, fully-regulated banks make only 30% of subprime loans. Subprime loans include many negative features beyond high rates and fees. Most subprime loans in recent years have come with low teaser rates that reset into expensive adjustable rates after two years. About 70% include prepayment penalties that trap borrowers in the loans and prevent them from refinancing affordably if they discover they’ve been duped. They have been marketed with intensive advertising and highpressure, often fraudulent, sales techniques designed to prey on elderly and other vulnerable homeowners. Many lenders have broken even today’s lax lending laws. Ameriquest paid $325 million, and Household International paid $484 million, to settle predatory lending lawsuits. Most importantly, subprime lending was never about expanding access to homeownership. Only 38% of subprime loans are for home purchase, and only 9% go to first time homebuyers. The rest are home equity loans and refinancings. What are home equity loans used for? In 2004, 58% went for home improvements and personal spending, and 27% went to pay off credit card debt. Essentially, Americans are pawning their houses: using them as collateral for expensive, high-risk loans. Thus, subprime lending has decreased homeownership by leading to foreclosures. Homeownership rates for the bottom two fifths of the income scale dropped from 45.4% (1980) to 42.4% (2005). The Center for Responsible Lending (CRL) estimates that one out of five subprime loans made in 2006 will end in foreclosure. CRL calculates that subprime lending has created a net loss of one million homeowners. Buffalo has not escaped the subprime debacle. A 2008 federal study found 9,080 subprime loans in western New York, of which 22% were overdue, 5.5% were in foreclosure, and 1.9% had been foreclosed. CRL predicts that 15.6% of the subprime loans made in the Buffalo area in 2006 will end in foreclosure. As the government attempts to repair the credit system, it must begin to regulate subprime lenders just as it regulates banks, and it must strictly limit the ability of lenders to sell credit on unaffordable and exploitative terms. Sam Magavern teaches in the Affordable Housing Clinic at the University at the Buffalo Law School and is one of the founders of the Partnership for the Public Good. I. Standalone sub prime http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/fyi/2003/012903fyi.html http://www.fdic.gov/news/news/financial/2005/fil1405a.html a. Payday What is Payday Lending? Who uses it? and what are the concerns? Estimates are 30 to forty billions dollars per year. Hard to verify. A few states have several limits a few are wide open and there is everything in the middle Missouri efforts and payday lending in Missouri Federal efforts/ military bases Rise of the online payday lending Who owns the payday lenders? Who provides the money? Rise of the mainline bank payday lending What ingredients create the opposition? Why continue it? Sub Prime Products The Payday Loan Industry in Missouri A Study of the Laws, the Lenders, the Borrowers and the Legislation Executive Summary Sponsored by BBB Serving Eastern Missouri and Southern Illinois ●15 Sunnen Drive ● Suite 107 ● St. Louis, MO 63143 ● Phone: (314) 645-3300 ● www.stlouis.bbb.org BBB of Southwest Missouri ● 430 S. Glenstone Avenue ● Springfield, MO 65802 ● Phone: (417) 862-4BBB ● www.southwestmissouri.bbb.org A Study of the Payday Loan Industry In Missouri Executive Summary Purpose Of This Study One of the Better Business Bureau’s responsibilities is to inform the public of questionable or unfair practices in the marketplace. In the past few years the payday loan industry, termed by many as “predatory lending,” has grown significantly, both nationally and in Missouri. In 1996 there were an estimated 2,000 payday loan outlets nationally, and by 2008, that number grew to an estimated 22,000. During 2008, 2.8 million payday loans were made by 1,275 lenders licensed in Missouri, according to the Missouri Division of Finance. This study examines current Missouri laws regulating payday loans and how these laws compare with those of other states. The study also looks at the status of pending legislation and the effects of past legislation on the industry. Sources used in this study include Missouri Division of Finance; 2001 Performance Audit by State Auditor Claire McCaskill; current state laws; Form 10-Ks filed by some companies with the U.S. Securities & Exchange Commission; interviews with officials; National Consumer Law Center; bills introduced in the Missouri Legislature and Congress; Web sites of lawmakers; FDIC Center for Financial Research; AARP; court suits; Consumers Union; Missouri Secretary of State; PACER and Case.net (the court case tracking systems of federal and Missouri courts respectively); Arkansas Supreme Court; Consumer Federation of America; Center for Responsible Lending; the Community Financial Services Association of America (CFSA); and BBB staff visits to nursing homes. Current Missouri Laws In 2001, then-Missouri Auditor Claire McCaskill issued a Performance Audit regarding the payday loan industry. She noted that statutes at that time did not limit the interest rates lenders charge and that an annual percentage rate (APR) of 391% was common. While not recommending a specific interest rate that the Legislature should impose, the audit did recommend that the number of renewals of loans be reduced. The next year, the Legislature passed laws that would allow a lender to charge fees and interest up to 75% of the amount of the loan. On a two-week loan, that translates into a 1,950% APR, the highest allowed among the 43 states that have either banned or set APR caps on payday loans. There are no APR caps in the seven other states. The new laws also allow up to six renewals of loans. Since enactment of the laws, payday loans made to consumers average more than 400% APR, according to the Division of Finance. Missouri’s usury law is ineffective in policing exorbitant interest rates as the Division notes on its Web site: “It applies to very little anymore because there are so many exceptions.” Also on the site, the Division characterizes the current state laws as consumer friendly in that they “subject this type of lender to a host of consumer safeguards, i.e., places a 75% cap on interest and fees on the initial loan and renewals, limits renewals to no more than six . . . .” Obtaining a payday loan license in Missouri is a simple process. All that’s required is an application and payment of a fee. There is no background check or determination of financial capability, a Division spokesman said. Missouri’s Laws Compared With Those Of Other States The laws enacted by the Legislature in 2002 require the Division of Finance to report biennially to the Legislature several facets of the payday loan industry. Responses by lenders to the biennial request are not sworn statements. Among the requirements of the report is that a comparison be made with states adjoining Missouri. The Jan. 14, 2009, report to the Legislature shows that of the nine contiguous states, only Missouri allows renewals of payday loans, allowing up to six renewals. The lax payday loan laws in Missouri have made the state attractive to lenders. Among the nine contiguous states, only Tennessee has more payday loan locations (1,481) than Missouri (1,275) with the next highest being Kentucky with 785, according to the Division of Finance’s report. The report also shows that the APR allowed by Missouri’s statutes of 1,950% based on a two-week loan of $100 is by far the highest of the nine contiguous states. The next highest was the Arkansas law which allowed an APR of 520%, but that law was declared unconstitutional by the Arkansas Supreme Court on Nov. 6, 2008, because it allowed “usurious” rates of interest in violation of the state’s constitution. The rest of the states’ laws based on a two-week payday loan of $100 allow APRs of 390% except for Illinois which allows 403%. The Lenders While the number of payday loan licenses in Missouri may seem large, there are only 24 companies with 10 or more licenses. They operate at 719 locations, or 56% of the total number of locations in the state. Seventeen of these larger lenders are based out of state. Their headquarters are in Arkansas, Texas, North Carolina, Georgia, Tennessee, Ohio, Colorado, Pennsylvania, Kansas, Alabama and Illinois. There are also 34 out-of-state online companies that are licensed payday lenders in Missouri. The three largest companies licensed to provide payday loans in Missouri are: • QC Holdings, Inc., a publicly traded company which does business under the name Quik Cash, headquartered in Kansas City, Kan.; • Advance America, Cash Advance Centers, Inc., headquartered in Spartanburg, S.C., also a publicly traded company; and • Bn’T Loan, LLC, of Springfield, Mo., which has licenses at various retail locations. The three companies operate 292 payday loan locations in Missouri or about 23% of the total number of locations. Missouri accounted for 30% of QC Holdings’ total branch gross profits last year, while Illinois accounted for 7%. The Form 10-Ks filed with the U.S. Securities & Exchange Commission reveal that Cash Advance and Quik Cash made a combined $5.5 billion in payday loans nationally in 2008. The primary business of both companies is payday lending, and both companies began operations as the payday lending industry began its great expansion, QC Holdings in 1992 and Advance America in 1997. Bn’T Loan, LLC was created in 2002. As the phenomenon of payday loans soared, the reputation of companies making them declined. Said one large lender, “Certain banks have notified us and other companies in the payday loan and check-cashing industries that they will no longer maintain bank accounts for these companies due to reputation risks. . . .” Nursing Homes Have Payday Loan Licenses Two allied groups headquartered in Sikeston, Mo., operate 62 nursing homes in Missouri with payday loan licenses. Principals in the two allied groups are James and Judy Lincoln, Sikeston; Mathias P. Dasal, Eldon, Mo.; Gary Crane, Rogers, Ark.; and Timothy Drake, Pascagoula, Miss. The sole director of a third group of 30 nursing homes is Don Bedell, Sikeston, who also is sole director of a payday loan company that has licenses at the homes. Nursing homes have regularly made loans to their employees at high interest rates, deducting the payback of the loans from the employees’ next paycheck. In September 2006, then-Gov. Matt Blunt announced that nursing homes would no longer be allowed to make payday loans to their employees, saying, “Employers should not be making money off the wages they pay their hardworking long-term care facility employees.” A spokesman for the Department of Health and Senior Services said that since then, the department has been in negotiations with the nursing home owners, and that the negotiations “became serious” this year. In April, he said the department and nursing home owners reached an oral agreement, which will allow a parent company of nursing home subsidiaries to hold a payday loan license and to conduct payday loan operations at nursing homes that it owns, with payback of the loans being deducted from the employees’ paychecks. Employees will take out a loan through computer terminals at the nursing homes, the spokesman said. The transition to the system, which in essence changes the present system very little, will be completed by late September, the spokesman said. Department officials said loans were made only to employees and not to residents of the homes. The Borrowers As might be expected, the definition of the typical customer taking out a payday loan differs widely between companies that make them and consumer advocates. Two large payday loan companies or their trade association say that borrowers are under 45 years old, a large percentage have incomes of at least $40,000, nearly half are homeowners, at least 87% have high school diplomas and more than half have attended college. That picture of the typical borrower is in sharp contrast to that painted by officials and consumer advocates. The Consumer Federation of America says that “payday loan borrowers are typically female, make around $25,000 a year, are renters, and more likely to be minorities than the general population.” Former Missouri State Auditor Claire McCaskill said in an audit that “title and payday consumers are generally lower income individuals. Title and payday lenders estimated 70 percent of their consumers earned less than $25,000 annually.” In a press release from the office of U.S. Rep. Luis Gutierrez (D-Ill.), who introduced a bill that some say is friendly to the payday loan industry, it was noted: “Concentrated in low-income and minority neighborhoods, payday lenders typically offer short-duration loans, waiving the credit history requirement imposed by traditional banks. Unfortunately, those who most need these loans are often the least able to repay them.” The Missouri Division of Finance conducted a study in 2007. The survey of about 3,700 borrowers showed that the average age of consumers taking out payday loans was 43 and income was $24,607. Borrowers were classified by vocation with 21% being “labor,” and 12% classified as “secretarial/clerical.” The survey showed that 439 loans or 12% were made to consumers on Supplemental Security Income (SSI) or disability. On its Web site, AARP has this to say about the elderly and payday loans: “As studies show that older people are incurring greater debt than ever before, and are filing for bankruptcy in record numbers, they may find that their usual sources of credit are no longer available. They may join the ranks of other low- and moderate- income consumers (who) turn to non-traditional credit sources for very expensive loans.” In a press release announcing his filing of a bill, U.S. Sen. Richard J. Durbin (D-Ill.) said, “These excessive rates are often hidden and can have crippling effects on those individuals who can afford it least.” Last year, customers of payday loan companies filed 473 complaints with BBBs alleging wrongdoing on the part of their lenders. Bane Or Boon? As with the identity of the typical borrower, the question of whether payday loans are beneficial or not receives widely disparate answers from the industry and consumer advocates. The Community of Financial Services Association of America (CFSA), the trade association for the industry, says on its Web site, “Typically, a customer uses a payday advance to cover small, unexpected expenses between paydays to avoid expensive bounced- check fees, late bill payment penalties, and other less desirable shortterm credit options.” A major lender notes, “We believe that our customers choose the payday loan product because it is quick, convenient and in many instances a lower-cost or more suitable alternative for the customer than the other available alternatives.” Another major lender says, “We believe customers use cash advances as a simple, quick and confidential way to meet short-term cash needs between paydays while avoiding the potentially higher costs and negative credit consequences of other alternatives.” Consumer advocacy groups think differently. A study by the Center for Responsible Lending noted: “Despite attempts to reform payday lending . . . lenders still collect 90 percent of their revenue from borrowers who cannot pay off their loans when due, rather than one-time users dealing with short-term emergencies.” In comments to the Federal Trade Commission, the Consumer Federation of America stated: “The essential features of a payday loan make them a debt trap for borrowers” because the loans are made without considering the borrower’s ability to repay and interest rates are exorbitant. The Center for Responsible Lending said in another survey that “the entire payday lending industry relies on a business model that encourages chronic borrowing.” The consequences of the “debt trap” may be severe. A study made under the auspices of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corp. (FDIC) was titled “Do Payday Loans Cause Bankruptcy?” The researcher concluded: “We find that payday loan applicants approved for their first loans file for Chapter 13 bankruptcy significantly more often than rejected first-time borrowers.” And several consumer groups, in a letter to the sponsor of an industry- friendly bill in Congress, said, “Using payday loans doubles the risk a borrower will end up in bankruptcy within two years.” Borrowers who cannot pay off a payday loan also may find themselves as defendants in court actions. One of the largest lenders in Missouri has filed more than 100 small claims suits in Missouri to force borrowers to pay. A Center for Financial Responsibility study listed the cost of payday lending to borrowers who have five or more loans per year in the 50 states and the District of Columbia. California topped the list at $365 million, while Missouri ranked second with $317 million. Legislation A bill introduced in the U.S. Senate by Sen. Durbin began by saying that governments have been trying “to prohibit usurious interest rates in America since colonial times.” Currently, there are four pending bills in Congress and two were introduced in the recently concluded Missouri Legislature. But if the past--when several bills both at the state and federal level died in committee or were not assigned to a committee--is any indication of the future, the prospects of meaningful regulation of payday lenders is questionable. Bills were introduced in the U.S. House or Senate in 2005, 2006, 2007 and 2008. And in Missouri bills were introduced in the House or Senate in 2006, 2007 and 2008. Only one of the bills was enacted into law--a bill passed by Congress in 2006 for military service members and their families that placed an APR cap of 36% on several consumer credit products including payday loans. Only two of the bills introduced this year provide protection against extremely high interest rates. These bills have been introduced: • U.S. Senate Bill 500 – Introduced on March 19, 2009, by Sen. Durbin. The bill would cap interest rates on several consumer credit products including payday loans at a 36% APR and would provide a penalty for violation of the law of a year in prison or a fine of $50,000. • U.S. House of Representatives Bill 1608 – Introduced on March 19, 2009, by Rep. Jackie Speier (D-Calif.). This bill is identical to Senate Bill 500. • U.S. House of Representatives Bill 1214 – Introduced Feb. 26, 2009, by Rep. Gutierrez. The bill would cap fees and interest at 15 cents per dollar, an APR of 390% on a two-week loan. Twelve consumer advocacy groups sent a letter to Rep. Gutierrez opposing the bill, saying it would “stall or stop the significant progress that has been made at the state level to curb usurious lending” and that “legalizing payday lending at triple- digit rates runs counter to President Obama’s promise to cap payday lending and other loans at 36 percent annual rates.” • U.S. House of Representatives Bill 1846 – Introduced April 1, 2009, by Rep. Joe Baca (D-Calif.). One of the main provisions of the bill is that it would preempt state laws on payday lending, including those in states that have banned payday lending entirely. The bill also calls for a 390% APR. • Missouri Senate Bill 20 – Pre-filed Dec. 1, 2008, by Sen. Rita Heard Days (D-St. Louis). The bill allows a 390% APR (based on a two-week loan) for the first 30 days of a loan and an APR of 36% thereafter. The bill also prohibits renewal of payday loans. The legislative session ended with no action taken on the bill or its companion bill, Missouri House Bill 150, pre-filed by Rep. Mary Still (D-Columbia). Effects Of Past Legislation More and more states are clamping down on the payday loan industry with legislation that either bans payday lending entirely or provides stiff regulation of the industry. More than 200 bills have been introduced in state legislatures in recent years. And as laws are enacted, payday lending companies have ceased operations in those states. “In states where a 36% cap is mandated, without additional fees, we are unable to operate at a profit,” said QC Holdings in its 10-K report filed with the Securities & Exchange Commission. And Cash Advance said in its 10-K, “Any federal law that would impose a national 36% APR limit on our services, like that proposed in the Durbin bill, if enacted, would likely eliminate our ability to continue our current operations.” The company also noted that since 2007 it has closed or will close payday loan outlets in Arkansas, New Mexico, New Hampshire, Oregon and Pennsylvania. Not only is the industry facing the possibility of prohibitive legislation at the federal and state levels, local governments have entered the picture by restricting payday lending through zoning and permit laws. In addition to the prospect of increased regulation by federal, state and local governments, payday loan companies also find themselves as defendants in court actions. Class action suits are pending against two of Missouri’s largest payday lenders in Arkansas, California, Florida, Georgia, North Carolina, Pennsylvania, South Carolina and Missouri. Class action suits have been filed in St. Louis County Circuit Court and the U.S. District Court in Jefferson City, Mo. Both suits are pending appeal regarding procedural matters. The suit in St. Louis County alleges that QC Holdings (Quik Cash) violated Missouri law by renewing loans more than six times, by failing to determine the customer’s ability to repay the loans, and by charging interest and fees which were more than 75% of the face amount of the original loan. Conclusions Missouri’s weak payday loan laws have attracted major out-of-state lenders to engage in predatory lending, costing Missourians who can least afford it millions of dollars a year. Because the continually increasing debt owed to payday loan companies is so onerous, some consumers are caught in the “debt trap,” unable to pay the loan off or meet other needs such as utilities, rent and food. Bankruptcy is the only answer for some of these consumers. The bill introduced in Congress by Sen. Durbin and its companion bill in the House, if enacted, would appear to halt the usurious practices, not only in Missouri but nationally as well. The Missouri Legislature has not joined the parade of states which have taken action recently to either prohibit or severely restrict payday lending. Payday loans are banned in 12 states while three others have adopted restrictive laws. The two bills introduced in this session of the Missouri Legislature, while forbidding renewals, would still allow an APR of 390% on a two- week loan. Payday loan companies have ceased operations in states that have enacted strict regulations on payday lending, including placing a 36% or less APR cap on interest and fees. BBB Researcher: Robert H. Teuscher, July 2009 Subprime Auto Lending Revs Up Posted: 05/24/2012 3:11 pm Updated: 05/24/2012 3:20 pm Car dealer David Kelleher of Glen Mills, Pa., says lately he's growing accustomed to a new kind of customer: lawyers, doctors and other high-salaried professionals who are now considered subprime credit risks. As the current chairman of the Chrysler National Dealer Council, Kelleher said this includes individuals who lost their financial footing when their investments soured in the recession or a real estate deal went bad. "We're seeing a new face of the subprime customer; that's for sure," said Kelleher, who owns David Chrysler Jeep Dodge. Subprime lending is on the rise in the auto industry, and even though the term "subprime" makes people nervous, some players in the auto industry welcome it. They see it as a way to reach customers who have been cut off from buying cars these past few years. When the credit crisis hit in the fall of 2008, it was hard even for those with the best credit scores to receive a car loan. But while this kind lending could boost auto sales by opening up a larger market, it also can pose a risk to subprime customers, who are susceptible to scams that could result in higher interest rates. As the car market and the credit markets recover from the recession, loans have slowly started to be granted for individuals with lower and lower credit scores. These people end up paying higher interest rates, though. Since this January, about 8 percent of car buyers have secured loans with an interest rate of 10 percent or more, which indicates that the bank sees them as a high risk, said Jessica Caldwell, a senior analyst at Edmunds. Currently the average interest rate for a car loan is about 4 percent. The increase in subprime lending is helping boost car sales to people who have been holding off. "There was a significant population who had no access to credit," Caldwell said. "People get nervous when you hear we're letting subprime people back into the market, but these people were really cut off … It's not a hog-wild lending frenzy, giving loans to anyone who walks in." Data from credit tracking firm Experian backs up what Edmunds has found: Subprime lending for the first quarter of 2012 climbed 11.4 percent over the same period last year, accounting for 23.16 percent of auto sales for the first quarter. After the credit crisis hit in the fall of 2008, subprime lending plunged to 17.99 percent of auto sales during the first quarter of 2009. But consumers shouldn't confuse subprime auto lending with subprime mortgages, said Melinda Zabritski, director of automotive credit for Experian. Delinquency rates are lower for these types of car loans as people tend to pay their car loans before they pay credit card loans and sometimes even before they pay their mortgage. "Everyone says that's because you need a car to go to work," Zabritski said. "Delinquencies right now are historically low." Still, consumers with subprime credit scores need to be careful, warned Chris Kulka, senior counsel for government affairs for the Center for Responsible Lending. Because these customers often have a harder time securing a loan, dealers may take advantage of them. If a dealer sets up financing for a customer, that dealer is allowed to add in a percentage markup that gets paid directly to the dealer. So, for example, if the subprime customer qualified for a 10 percent loan, the dealer could add in another 5 percent and tell the customer he or she qualified for a 15 percent loan. The Center for Responsible Lending is lobbying to make this practice illegal. "We think subprime customers are much more affected by this than other consumers," Kulka said. "We remain concerned that if the market takes off, but we haven't addressed these issues, that's a problem." Chrysler is selling more cars to subprime customers than almost any other auto manufacturer, especially when it comes to its Dodge brand, Edmunds said. Year to date, about 12 percent of all Chrysler purchases have been made with subprime loans, with about 20 percent of Dodge buyers assuming subprime loans. In comparison, 11.5 percent of Fiat buyers have a subprime loan. And 8.5 percent of Jeep buyers take on a subprime loan. Kia, Mitsubishi and Suzuki also are finding that more than 20 percent of their customer base take on subprime loans, Edmunds said. Ralph Kisel, a spokesman for Chrysler, said subprime customers are the biggest growth area for the entire industry. "Credit availability is bringing these customers back to [the] market at a disproportionate level versus prime customers," he said. For Kelleher, the increase in subprime lending means he's hearing more stories from people hard hit by the recession who now feel like they are on the rebound. He recently had a customer who lost both his $200,000 job and a substantial fortune in real estate. He filed for bankruptcy but now is back working and needed a car. "In a lot of these cases, the people aren't going to be subprime forever," Kelleher said. "We were able to get this gentleman a loan. And if things go right, maybe he'll buy from us again." Special Report: How the Fed fueled an explosion in subprime auto loans Wed, Apr 3 2013 By Carrick Mollenkamp JASPER, Alabama (Reuters) - Thanks largely to the U.S. Federal Reserve, Jeffrey Nelson was able to put up a shotgun as down payment on a car. Money was tight last year for the school-bus driver and neighborhood constable in Jasper, Alabama, a beaten-down town of 14,000 people. One car had already been repossessed. Medical bills were piling up. And still, though Nelson's credit history was an unhappy one, local car dealer Maloy Chrysler Dodge Jeep had no problem arranging a $10,294 loan from Wall Street-backed subprime lender Exeter Finance Corp so Nelson and his wife could buy a charcoal gray 2007 Suzuki Grand Vitara. All the Nelsons had to do was cover the $1,000 down payment. For most of that amount, Maloy accepted Jeffrey's 12-gauge Mossberg & Sons shotgun, valued at about $700 online. In the ensuing months, Nelson and his wife divorced, he moved into a mobile home, and, unable to cover mounting debts, he filed for personal bankruptcy. His ex-wife, who assumed responsibility for the $324-a-month car payment, said she will probably file for bankruptcy in a couple of months. When they got the Exeter loan, Jeffrey, 44 years old, was happy "someone took a chance on us." Now, he sees it as a contributor to his financial downfall. "Was it feasible? No," he said. The Maloy dealership wouldn't discuss the loan. "I got nothing to say to you," an employee said. At car dealers across the United States, loans to subprime borrowers like Nelson are surging - up 18 percent in 2012 from a year earlier, to 6.6 million borrowers, according to credit-reporting agency Equifax Inc. And as a Reuters review of court records shows, subprime auto lenders are showing up in a lot of personal bankruptcy filings, too. It's the Federal Reserve that's made it all possible. MONEY, MONEY EVERYWHERE In its efforts to jumpstart the economy, the U.S. central bank has undertaken since November 2008 three rounds of bond-buying and cut short-term interest rates effectively to zero. The purchases of mostly Treasury and mortgage securities - known as quantitative easing and nicknamed QE1, QE2 and QE3 - have injected trillions of dollars into the financial system. The Fed isn't alone. Central banks from Tokyo to Frankfurt to London are running their printing presses overtime. The heavily indebted advanced economies are trying to reflate their way out of the prolonged bout of crisis and recession that crystallized with the collapse of Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc in 2008. That crisis, of course, followed a nearly decade-long cycle of easy money and exotic financial products that itself began with the collapse of the tech-mania bubble of the late 1990s. The Fed's program, while aimed at bolstering the U.S. housing and labor markets, has also steered billions of dollars into riskier, more speculative corners of the economy. That's because, with low interest rates pinching yields on their traditional investments, insurance companies, hedge funds and other institutional investors hunger for riskier, higher-yielding securities - bonds backed by subprime auto loans, for instance. Lenders like Exeter have rushed to meet that demand. Backed by Wall Street banks and big private-equity firms, they have been selling ever-greater amounts of subprime auto loans in the form of relatively high-yield securities and using the proceeds to fund even more lending to more subprime borrowers. Expansion of the subprime auto business was chronicled in a 2011 Los Angeles Times series. Since then, growth has continued apace. Consider that in 2012, lenders sold $18.5 billion in securities backed by subprime auto loans, compared with $11.75 billion in 2011, according to ratings firm Standard & Poor's. The pace has continued so far this year, with $5.7 billion of the securities issued, compared with $4.4 billion for the same period last year, according to Deutsche Bank AG. On Monday alone, three deals totaling $1.6 billion of subprime auto securities were announced by Wall Street banks. To make up for the risk of taking on increasing numbers of high-risk borrowers, subprime auto lenders charge annual interest rates that can top 20 percent. The Exeter loan Nelson and his wife got, for example, carried a 21.95-percent rate. Exeter, which is majority-owned by private-equity giant Blackstone Group, assumes that one in four borrowers will default on their loan, according to an Exeter investor pitch book reviewed by Reuters. "Exeter works with auto dealers throughout the country to help consumers who do not qualify for prime financing," a company spokeswoman said. "Exeter offers conventional financing with affordable payments tailored to each customer's individual circumstances." A Blackstone spokesman declined to comment. BUBBLE TROUBLE Critics of the Fed say the growth in subprime auto lending is just one of several minibubbles the bond-buying program has created across a range of assets - junk bonds, subprime mortgage securities, and others. The yield chase delivered big windfalls to some Wall Street firms and hedge funds holding securities that soared in value. But so much money has flowed into these assets, the critics say, that the markets for some are beginning to resemble the housing boom in the run up to the financial crisis. "It's the same sort of thing we saw in 2007," said William White, a former economist at the Bank for International Settlements. "People get driven to do riskier and riskier things." White is among the growing number of economists coming round to the view of Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas President Richard Fisher, a non-voting member of the central bank's policy-making panel and a longtime critic of quantitative easing. "We are sailing deeper into uncharted waters," Fisher said in a speech six days after the Fed's September 13 announcement of QE3. "Why would the Fed provision to shovel billions in additional liquidity into the economy's boiler when so much is presently lying fallow?" A bust in the subprime auto market wouldn't have consequences nearly as devastating for lenders, investors or the broader economy as the housing bust did. Securities underpinned by subprime auto loans, estimated at about $80 billion between 2006 and 2012, are a fraction of the $1.6 trillion in mortgage-backed products Wall Street created between 2006 and 2009, according to S&P data and the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, created by the U.S. government to analyze the financial crisis. And whatever its faults, the Fed's program, consistently supported by most members of the central bank's policy-making body, has helped pull the U.S. economy out of recession and boosted the stock market to record levels. In congressional testimony last month, Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke, the main proponent of the bond-buying program, said low interest rates have "helped spark recovery in the housing market and led to increased sales and production of automobiles and other durable goods." Indeed, auto sales have recovered to nearly pre-crisis levels. New car, pickup truck and sport-utility vehicle registrations are projected to increase 6.6 percent this year to 15.3 million, according to automotive market-analysis firm Polk. Registrations could exceed 16 million in 2015, a number last seen in 2007. A Fed spokesman declined to comment. Subprime auto loans may seem like an obscure corner of finance, but the names behind the expansion are familiar. Santander Consumer USA Inc, a unit of giant Spanish bank Banco Santander SA, is one of the biggest sellers of securities backed by subprime auto loans, according to S&P. In 2011, KKR & Co, Warburg Pincus and Centerbridge Partners bought a 25 percent stake in the Santander unit for $1 billion. Capital One Financial Corp, General Motors Co and Ally Financial Inc are also steadily increasing loans to subprime borrowers. PERFORMANCE ANXIETY Less well-known upstart Exeter, founded in 2006 and based in Irving, Texas, is run by executives from AmeriCredit Corp, an auto-finance company acquired by General Motors in 2010. It reported $100 million in originations in May 2010. It expected to hit $1 billion in 2012 and $2.2 billion by 2015, according to the pitch book. The company has grown to 46 branches with 532 employees serving more than 6,600 dealers, from one branch and six employees serving 120 dealers in 2006. In 2008, a Goldman Sachs Group Inc fund, through an investment in a private-equity fund, helped infuse money into Exeter. Then, in 2011, Blackstone bought its controlling stake, turbo-charging Exeter's expansion as the Fed decided to keep pumping money into the economy. In October, Wells Fargo & Co, Citigroup Inc, Deutsche Bank AG and Goldman agreed to provide it loan commitments totaling $1 billion. After the Blackstone deal, in particular, the push was on for Exeter to expand its loan book, according to a former employee. "Everybody was under extreme pressure to hit goals," this person said. "Your job is in jeopardy. It was not sugar-coated." To win more business from dealerships, Exeter lowered its "holdback fee" - the small fraction of the loan amount that the lender keeps as a cushion against losses - to between $395 and $495 from about $795. The August 2012 Exeter investor pitch book touts the firm's "highly sophisticated risk management process," which employs a "decision science" system underpinned by "predictive models." The marketing book adds: "The end result is to deploy tools to management allowing for precision control over credit performance." This process results in customers with an average credit score of 556 and average annual income of $38,393, according to the pitch book. These borrowers pay an average interest rate of 21.4 percent a year. (Median U.S. household income was an inflation-adjusted $50,054 in 2011, according to the Census Bureau. On the widely used FICO creditscoring scale, produced by Fair Isaac Corp, 640 or less is considered subprime.) As for those Exeter clients who fall behind on payments, another former Exeter employee said, "they're check to check." TITLE LOANS, PAYDAY LENDERS That's the case for Wayne Loveless. Loveless and his wife in January 2012 got an Exeter loan to buy a 2006 Buick Rendezvous from Victory Nissan in Dickson, Tennessee. But Loveless, working as a cook at the local O'Charley's restaurant, had trouble keeping up with the $329 monthly payment. In February last year, the family got a title loan secured by a 2001 Ford Windstar van. In May, subprime lender World Finance gave them a $1,500 loan, secured by a television, a PlayStation and a DVD player. Court records show that Loveless took out payday loans totaling about $5,500 from AmeriCash, ACE Cash Express and Cash In A Wink. (Payday loans, which are shortterm loans secured only by the borrower's future work pay, and title loans, also shortterm but secured by an auto title, are a popular but expensive route to ready cash for many strapped Americans.) Loveless said some of that money helped cover car-loan payments and some went toward the cost of caring for his wife's mentally disabled brother. "It's stressful because... you're always begging for more money," he said. In July, Loveless and his wife filed for Chapter 7 bankruptcy, which erases unsecured debt and calls for liquidation of assets to pay down remaining debt. At the time, Loveless owed Exeter $9,900, excluding the value of the car. Loveless recently lost his job as a cook and now works for a company that services fire extinguishers. He and his wife kept the Buick. As the Lovelesses were struggling last year, Exeter issued $500 million in securities backed by subprime auto loans in two sales, in February and September. (Whether the Loveless loan was part of those sales couldn't be determined.) Like subprime mortgage securities issued in the past decade, each Exeter security was divided into tranches, or layers, based on the risk and return of each. Investors couldn't get enough of them, bidding up prices and thus lowering yields. In February, the yield on the top-rated tranche was 2.029 percent. By September, demand had increased so much that the yield was just 1.312 percent. Ratings agency DBRS gave the least-risky tranche its top rating - triple-A - in part because Exeter used a cushion to protect investors against losses and because it had a management team experienced in subprime, the agency said in its ratings reports. Exeter's proprietary model "declines approximately 50 percent of submitted applications," the agency said. MOODY'S WEIGHS IN Moody's Investors Service, in a move rare among ratings agencies, issued a report in March 2012 saying it would not have assigned a high investment-grade rating to the notes. "Exeter is small and unrated, with limited experience and little asset performance history," it said. Chuck Weilamann, a senior DBRS official, declined to comment on the Moody's report. He said DBRS was comfortable with the rating, noting that of the $142 million top-tier notes backed by subprime auto loans in the first sale, half had been paid off. "It is performing in line with expectations," he said. Regardless of the relative safety of such securities, a rapidly growing lending business that bakes into its assumptions a 25 percent failure rate is almost certain to result in more people defaulting on more loans. In 2011, Exeter Finance was listed as a creditor or participant in 252 bankruptcy proceedings, according to an online database of federal court filings. In 2012, the number increased to 1,144. Brett Wadsworth, the lawyer in Jasper who handled Jeffrey Nelson's bankruptcy, said the bulk of the filings he works on involve subprime debt - loans his clients shouldn't have gotten in the first place. "Most of them that's getting those types of loans are the same ones who's getting the cash loans or payday loans or title loans," Wadsworth said. Charles Thomas, an electrician in Park Forest, Illinois, filed for Chapter 7 bankruptcy only four months before he took out loans from Exeter and Santander in November 2011. Efforts to buy a car failed at six different dealers, but an online car-loan application he had filled out prompted an employee from Family Hyundai to call: Thomas had been preapproved. Thomas settled on a 2012 Hyundai Sonata financed by Exeter. His wife got a 2008 Hyundai Sonata financed by Santander. "They presented both deals to me at the same time," Thomas said. "You begin to try to rationalize, well maybe it was our time for the sun to shine on us." A Family Hyundai employee said the dealership doesn't comment on individual customers. Santander Consumer, citing privacy concerns, declined to comment. After his wife lost her job at a logistics company, the $900 in monthly car payments proved to be too much. Thomas in February filed for Chapter 13 bankruptcy protection, which would allow him to reorganize his debts. Thomas's bankruptcy court filing lists personal property of $25 in a checking account, $1,000 in household goods and $300 in clothing and a retirement account valued at $24,000. It also shows he owes $22,060 to Exeter, and $11,538 to Santander. AN APPETITE FOR RISK Despite the risk that borrowers like Thomas present, investors have proved increasingly willing to put their money into subprime auto debt for lower relative returns. According to Barclays Plc, the average spread - a measure of investors' risk tolerance - between top- rated securities underpinned by prime and subprime auto loans and a benchmark interest rate hit 0.32 percentage point in February. That represents a remarkable increase in risk appetite from the 8.85-percentage-point spread at the peak of the financial crisis in autumn 2008. With so much investor money backing subprime auto loans, and the resulting expansion of lending to questionable borrowers, some market watchers are beginning to sound alarms - albeit muted ones. Fitch Ratings in March said it was "concerned that the competitive landscape is creating an environment that encourages lenders to compete by easing credit terms." Concerns are arising inside the business, too. At the annual American Securitization Forum conference in Las Vegas in January, Goldman Sachs banker Robert McDonald said persistent bullishness in pooled auto debt "worries me a bit." Noting the narrowing of spreads, he said investors in subprime auto debt might ultimately balk if not paid enough to take on the risk. In Alabama, Jeffrey Nelson continues to drive a bus for the Walker County school system and to work as a constable for his neighborhood. His financial struggles continue, too. "It's one hit after another," he said recently at a local mall restaurant over a dinner of bourbon-glazed chicken - some of it packed up for later. "Three days ago, I lost my iPhone. Had to buy another." Court records show Nelson has monthly income of $1,592.97, while monthly expenses total $1,563.00, leaving about $29 in his wallet. His ex-wife got the Suzuki SUV. He still owns a 1996 Dodge Ram pickup truck. If he can scrape together the money, he said, he'll buy blue lights and a siren to put on the truck for his work as a constable. (Edited by Paritosh Bansal and John Blanton) © Thomson Reuters 2011. All rights reserved. Users may download and print extracts of content from this website for their own personal and non-commercial use only. Republication or redistribution of Thomson Reuters content, including by framing or similar means, is expressly prohibited without the prior written consent of Thomson Reuters. Thomson Reuters and its logo are registered trademarks or trademarks of the Thomson Reuters group of companies around the world. Thomson Reuters journalists are subject to an Editorial Handbook which requires fair presentation and disclosure of relevant interests. http://www.consumerfed.org/pdfs/driving_borrowers_rpt.pdf Public Pensions Finance Payday Lenders Some of the nation’s largest banks, including Wells Fargo and U.S. Bank, continue to offer payday loans despite growing regulatory scrutiny and mounting criticism, according to a report issued earlier this year by the Center for Responsible Lending. Evidently gouging low-income borrowers into long-term debt charging outrageous interest rates of 500%, or more, is too good for big banks to resist. Regulators have issued numerous warnings about abusive payday loan practices. Last May, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation said the agency was “deeply concerned” about payday lending. The Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, which oversees the nation’s largest banks, said in June 2011 that the loans raised “operational and credit risks and supervisory concerns.” The Consumer Finacial Protection Bureau has been examining whether banks violate consumer protection laws in the marketing of these products. Fifteen states have banned usurious payday lending to protect workers and just last week state authorities took action against certain predatory payday lenders. Obviously, included in the portfolios of most of the nation’s massive state and local public pensions (whether through actively managed accounts or index funds), are stocks of large banks which derive a portion of their earnings from fleecing payday borrowers. It may be unreasonable to expect public pensions to forego investing in major banks, or scrutinize every activity of the major banks in which they invest and object to banking practices they find reprehensible. However, according to industry sources, in addition to large banks, some of the largest payday loan companies are publicly traded, such as Cash America (CSH), and Dollar Financial (DFC). Some other large lenders include Community Choice Financial and SpeedyCash. Other lenders, according to the industry, are backed by investors large and small, such as hedge funds, private equity companies and family offices. For example, Payday One, was formerly offered by Think Finance, a company which claims to be “privately held and backed by some of Silicon Valley’s most respected venture capital firms, including Sequoia Capital and Technology Crossover Ventures.” It’s more than likely that public pensions loading-up on hedge funds and private equity are, due to the lack of transparency related to alternative investments, inadvertently financing payday marauders. Virtually all public funds that invest with alternative managers agree to reduced transparency regarding the investments held in alternative portfolios, including denying public access to such information. I’ve witnessed alternative managers and investment consultants advise public pensions that ignorance regarding strategies and investments is beneficial, permitting plausible deniability and avoidance of headline risk. You’ll never have to admit to things which you purposely do not know. Among publicly-traded payday lender Cash America’s top institutional holders is Earnest Partners LLC, which owned $75 million of the stock at June 30, 2013. (Other major holders of Cash America and Dollar Financial stock with significant public pension clients include Vanguard and BlackRock.) According to its website, Earnest Partners manages approximately $20 billion in assets for clients around the world, including corporate pension plans, state and municipal pension plans. According to published reports, the firm was recently terminated as a domestic midcap equity manager handling $514 million for the Ohio Police and Fire Pension. (Ironically, earlier this year Ohio’s Supreme Court announced it would hear a payday lending case that could close the licensing loophole payday stores use to charge borrowers triple-digit interest. It seems Buckeyes can’t decide whether to prohibit, or profit from, payday lending.) I don’t know whether Cash America stock was included in the $514 million portfolio Earnest Partners managed for the Ohio Police and Fire Pension but, given the outrageous returns related to payday lending, as public pensions migrate further into alternative investments, they should, in my opinion, determine whether they are, directly or indirectly, financing the business of screwing the poor. -------------------------------------------------------------------------------This article is available online at: http://www.forbes.com/sites/edwardsiedle/2013/09/04/public-pensions-finance-paydaylenders/ a. Tax refund anticipation loans What is tax refund anticipation loans? Who uses them? What are the concerns? http://www.nclc.org/images/pdf/high_cost_small_loans/ral/report-ral-2011.pdf Rent to Own What are the common features that are problematic and may tip the balance to restrict or prohibit? Federalism / state law or federal law? Big question in this field. II. Subprime product for conventional credit a. b. Auto Lending Car purchase financing buy here pay here dealer financing What is car title lending? Who uses it? What are the concerns? What makes it objectionable Cost – fees – method of enforcement Buy here pay here auto dealer financing Added problem- quality of the car c. Subprime credit cards What is the difference between a prime credit card and a subprime credit card? What turns a subprime credit card financing to a predatory subprime credit card financing? As defaults exploded in the late 1990’s and early 2000’s what were the impact of shifting to a higher percentage of subprime credit card customers? Please read the following article http://www.bos.frb.org/commdev/c&b/2008/fall/Anderson_subprime_credit_cards.pdf d. Subprime Mortgage Products What are the differences between a prime mortgage loan and a sub prime? As the crash started, think about the huge shift to sub prime, why it happened and what its effects were? What turns a sub prime home mortgage to a predatory sub prime mortgage loan Price Default Penalties Enforcement terms and rights IS THERE A LIMIT TO THE PRICE OR CONDITIONS OR PRACTICES THAT SOCIETY SHOULD TOLERATE OR SHOULD WE JUST MAKE THE COMPARISONS AS ACCURATELY AS WE CAN AND LET THE PARTIES MAKE THEIR OWN BARGAIN?? Please read carefully the following article: http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/06/01/ChomPennCross.pdf http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2006/2006-009.pdf The subprime auto lending industry isn’t anything new; for years investors have taken the risk on borrowers who have less than perfect credit, and lending companies that specialize in high interest auto loans have offered loans to people who do not qualify for regular auto loans. But while many advertised rates for auto loans are at percentages in the low single digits, subprime auto loans can carry interest rates that are 20% or even higher. These loans are granted under the assumption that a quarter of those borrowing will ultimately default. But there is a lot more than the borrower’s vehicle that is at stake. The high car payments often sends an already strapped budget into a downward spiral and borrowers can wind up bankrupt. The impact of securitization on the expansion of subprime credit ☆ • Taylor D. Nadaulda, <img alt="Corresponding author contact information" src="http://origin-cdn.els-cdn.com/sd/entities/REcor.gif">, <img src="http://origincdn.els-cdn.com/sd/entities/REemail.gif" alt="E-mail the corresponding author">, • Shane M. Sherlundb, <img src="http://origin-cdn.elscdn.com/sd/entities/REemail.gif" alt="E-mail the corresponding author"> Abstract This paper investigates the relationship between securitization activity and the extension of subprime credit. The analysis is motivated by two sets of compelling empirical facts. First, the origination of subprime mortgages exploded between the years 2003 and 2005. Second, the securitization of subprime loans increased substantially over the same time period, driven primarily by the five largest independent broker/dealer investment banks. We argue that the relative shift in the securitization activity of investment banks was driven by forces exogenous to factors impacting lending decisions in the primary mortgage market and resulted in lower ZIP code denial rates, higher subprime origination rates, and higher subsequent default rates. Consistent with recent findings in the literature, we provide evidence that the increased securitization activity of investment banks reduced lenders' incentives to carefully screen borrowers. Chapter 8 Surveys: Surveys of Consumer Finances, Sentiment and the like To be knowledgeable about consumer credit in the United States it is necessary to be familiar with several consumer “surveys.” In the financial area the Fed Three year survey is the key document. Take a careful look at it; pick out several areas of interest and see what you can learn from the most recent results of the survey. For example, the extent of student loan debt in the United States has become a very important topic. Look at the various information available about that development. I. Survey of Consumer Finances In the economic area the Fed three year study is a font of knowledge and information and is all the more useful because of its historical comparisons. The Federal Reserve Board in April will begin a statistical study of household finances, the Survey of Consumer Finances, that will provide policymakers with important insight into the economic condition of all types of American families. The survey has been undertaken every three years since 1983. It is being conducted for the Board by NORC, a social science research organization at the University of Chicago, through December of this year. The data collected will provide a representative picture of what Americans own--from houses and cars to stocks and bonds--how and how much they borrow and how they bank. Past study results have been important in policy discussions regarding recovery of households from the Great Recession, changes in the use of credit, use of tax-preferred retirement savings accounts, and a broad range of other issues. "This survey is one of the nation's primary sources of information on the financial condition of different types of households," Federal Reserve Board Chairman Ben S. Bernanke said in a letter to prospective survey participants. "Our previous surveys…have helped the Federal Reserve and other parts of the government make policy decisions and have also supported a wide variety of basic research, public discussion, and education." Participants in the study are chosen at random from 127 areas, including metropolitan areas and rural counties across the United States, using a scientific sampling procedure. A representative of NORC contacts each potential participant personally to explain the study and request time for an interview. Summary results for the 2013 study will be published in early 2015 after all data from the survey have been assessed and analyzed. Provide a few pages of the most recent survey. Provide some questions that require use of those pages and that demonstrate the value of the survey http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/bulletin/2012/pdf/scf12.pdf Consider the light that the Survey casts on the following two issues. 1. How and when did student loan debt become such a major issue? Where was it in relation to car debt and credit card debt in each of the last five surveys? What do we know about the income levels of people with the highest levels of student debt? 2. Who is suffering the most from the Crash and who is recovering the most quickly? More recently the New York Fed and Equifax have developed an instrument that is more current and has other advantages. II. Survey of Consumer Sentiment Provide a few pages of the most recent survey Provide some questions that require use of those pages and that demonstrate the value of the survey . Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) The Consumer Expenditure Survey (CE) program consists of two surveys, the Quarterly Interview Survey and the Diary Survey, that provide information on the buying habits of American consumers, including data on their expenditures, income, and consumer unit (families and single consumers) characteristics. The survey data are collected for the Bureau of Labor Statistics by the U.S. Census Bureau. The CE is important because it is the only Federal survey to provide information on the complete range of consumers' expenditures and incomes, as well as the characteristics of those consumers. It is used by economic policymakers examining the impact of policy changes on economic groups, by businesses and academic researchers studying consumers' spending habits and trends, by other Federal agencies, and, perhaps most importantly, to regularly revise the Consumer Price Index market basket of goods and services and their relative importance. The most recent data tables are for July 2011 through June 2012, and were made available on March 27, 2013. See Featured CE Tables and Economic News Releases sections on the CE home page for current data tables and the news release. The 2011 public-use microdata is the most recent and was released on September 25, 2012. It’s the last Tuesday of the month, which means it’s the day we hear about how consumers are feeling about the economy from the Conference Board. Today the Consumer Confidence Index says that consumers are downright gloomy. But come Friday, you may hear something different about how consumers are feeling from the University of Michigan, which releases its Consumer Sentiment Index. You may be asking yourselves what’s the difference between these two monthly metrics? Sr. Producer Paddy Hirsch explains the difference in today's Money Matters segment. "Both measure consumers' ability or willingness to buy stuff," says Hirsch. "So say you're thinking about buying a refrigerator. So the consumer confidence questions -- the questions that they ask when they're polling people -- essentially ask you are you going to be happy buying a refrigerator in six months time. The consumer sentiment people, they're asking you how you feel about buying a refrigerator right now. " 6. Concluding Questions The Index of Consumer Sentiment is now constructed from responses to five questions, three of which concern economic expectations, with each question given equal weight. The original “index of consumer attitudes” included responses to a price expectations question as well. Except for eliminating the question on price expectations, the definition of the index appears to have been very stable for fifty years. Yet one of the principal investigators long ago called for careful reconsideration of the index in the concluding paragraph of her paper:“The index of consumer attitudes which was related here to individual purchases is still in an experimental stage. Ahead is the challenging problem of seeing whether closer correlations with purchases can be established by improving the index—by adding new series, revising the weighting of components, and refining the attitudinal measures themselves” (Mueller, 1957, p. 965). Almost a half-century later, we take up the challenge to improve the measurement of consumer confidence. The findings reported in this paper suggest that improvement is feasible. Drawing on these findings, we close with three major questions regarding the effective measurement of consumer confidence: 1. Should the Survey of Consumers and similar surveys ask consumers about national business conditions? 2. Should the qualitative questions of the Survey of Consumers be continued as is, complemented by probabilistic questions, or replaced by probabilistic questions? 3. Should the responses to the various questions be aggregated into an index or presented separately? If an index is thought desirable, how should it be constructed? Although it is premature to assert definitive answers to these questions, we feel ready to offer tentative responses, drawing in part on the findings of this paper. Regarding the first question, we do not see an obvious rationale for asking consumers about such distant, ambiguous phenomena as “national business conditions.” The respondents are not experts, as in the Livingston panel and the Survey of Professional Forecasters.4 If the objective is to use expectations data to predict personal consumption, expectations for the nation should be relevant only to the extent that they are an input into formation of personal expectations. Hence, why not ask more questions that probe personal expectations directly, and eliminate the questions on national business conditions? The case for this change is especially strong if the month-to-month changes in the ICS are being driven largely by spurious volatility in the responses to question BUS12.5 We do think that consumers may usefully be queried about well-defined macroeconomic events that are directly relevant to their personal lives. The question eliciting expectations for growth in the value of a mutual-fund investment exemplifies what we have in mind. One might similarly elicit expectations for aspects of government policy that directly affect consumer finances; for example, tax policy and social security policy. Regarding the second question, we think that the traditional qualitative questions of consumer-confidence surveys should at least complemented by, and perhaps replaced by, probabilistic questions inquiring about well-defined events. Although probabilistic questioning has obvious conceptual advantages, economists had little experience with it before the early 1990s, and skepticism about its feasibility was rampant. However, substantial experience has accumulated in the past ten years through the administration of probabilistic questions in SEE and in such major national surveys as the Health and Retirement Study (Hurd and McGarry, 1995, 2002) and the 4 These surveys of experts are described in Caskey (1985) and Keane and Runkle (1990), respectively. A possible scientific reason to retain questions on national business conditions is to study expectations formation; one may want to understand how individuals use their perspectives on national conditions to form their personal expectations. This objective is distinct from the longstanding purpose of the Michigan survey. Moreover, expectations formation may be much better studied through intensive interviewing than through short telephone surveys. National Longitudinal Study of Youth-1997 Cohort (Fischhoff et al., 2000; Dominitz, Manski, and Fischhoff, 2001). This experience, plus the new findings on the Survey of Consumers reported in this paper, make plain that probabilistic questioning is feasible and yields richer information on consumer beliefs than is obtainable with traditional qualitative questions. Finally, we suggest that the producers of consumer confidence statistics prominently report their findings for separate questions. The responses to separate questions are much more readily interpretable than are monthly reports of an index constructed from disparate, non-commensurate elements. We do not go so far as to suggest a halt to reports of indices; simple summaries of masses of data often are a practical necessity. However, we do think it long overdue to reconsider the particular structure of the ICS and similar indices. Consumer Confidence to Be Measured at State Level Rather Than Just National Forget national consumer confidence figures for a moment. The Conference Board has just announced that when it releases its monthly Consumer Confidence Index you are no longer just going to see the national figure. The Conference Board is now going to be breaking out eight states individually as well. The Conference Board will begin its new effort for eight U.S. states beginning with the March 21 release. Alongside the national and regional figures will be state-specific findings from the monthly Consumer Confidence Survey. The new report may seem too narrow to matter, but this will highlight even closer the difference between where sentiment and confidence are rising or dropping. The eight lucky states are California, Texas, New York, Florida, Illinois, Pennsylvania, Ohio and Michigan. With this report having so many more households, it is going to be one more noticed over the monthly Reuters/University of Michigan Consumer Sentiment readings released each month. The University of Michigan report is released on a preliminary basis and then given one revision at the end of each month. It is based on questions from only 500 households each month. Krugman Doesn’t Understand IS-LM, Part 1 → Preliminary March 2013 Michigan Consumer Sentiment Falls to 14 Month Low Posted on 15 March 2013 by Doug Short The University of Michigan Consumer Sentiment preliminary number for March came in at 71.8, a substantial decline from the February final reading of 77.6. The Briefing.com consensus was for no change. Briefing.com’s on estimate was for 79.0. The latest number takes us back to the range normally associated with recessions. See the chart below for a long-term perspective on this widely watched index. I’ve highlighted recessions and included real GDP to help evaluate the correlation between the Michigan Consumer Sentiment Index and the broader economy. To put today’s report into the larger historical context since its beginning in 1978, consumer sentiment is 16% below the average reading (arithmetic mean) and 15% below the geometric mean. The current index level is at the 19th percentile of the 423 monthly data points in this series. The Michigan average since its inception is 85.2. During non-recessionary years the average is 87.7. The average during the five recessions is 69.3. So the latest sentiment number puts us only 2.5 above the average recession mindset and 15.9 below the nonrecession average. It’s important to understand that this indicator can be somewhat volatile. For a visual sense of the volatility here is a chart with the monthly data and a three-month moving average. For the sake of comparison here is a chart of the Conference Board’s Consumer Confidence Index (monthly update here). The Conference Board Index is the more volatile of the two, but the broad pattern and general trends are remarkably similar to the Michigan Index. And finally, the prevailing mood of the Michigan survey is also similar to the mood of small business owners, as captured by the NFIB Business Optimism Index (monthly update here). The trend in sentiment since the Financial Crisis lows has been one of slow improvement. We saw a major drop in sentiment in 2011 followed by a rapid return to the general trend of higher highs. The March preliminary reading is much lower than analysts expected. Apparently the impact of smaller paychecks for John and Jane Doe following the expiration of the 2% FICA tax cut and the upward trend in gasoline prices have taken their toll on the consumer’s state of mind. Caveats on the Use of University of Michigan Consumer Sentiment This survey is quantitatively derived from a fairly complex questionnaire (sample here) via a monthly telephone survey. According to Bloomberg: This release is frequently released early. It can come out as early as 9:55am EST. The official release time is 10:00. Base year 1966=100. A survey of consumer attitudes concerning both the present situation as well as expectations regarding economic conditions conducted by the University of Michigan. For the preliminary release approximately three hundred consumers are surveyed while five hundred are interviewed for the final figure. The level of consumer sentiment is related to the strength of consumer spending. Please note that this report is released twice per month. The first is a preliminary figure while the second is the final (revised) figure. This is a survey, a quantification of opinion rather than facts and data. The question – does sentiment lead or truly correlate to any economic activity? Since 1990, there seems to be a loose general correlation to real household income growth. ← February 2013 Industrial Production Growth Strong Global consumer confidence increased in the first quarter of 2013, rising two index points to 93 from 91 in Q4 2012, according to findings from the Nielsen Global Survey of Consumer Confidence and Spending Intentions. Improved consumer attitudes about job prospects, personal finances and the ability to spend in the U.S., across key Asian export markets and throughout northern and central Europe helped drive the quarterly uptick. On a year-over-year basis, however, the Q1 2013 index score of 93 is a point lower than it was in Q1 2012. In the latest survey, conducted Feb. 18–March 8, 2013, consumer confidence rose in 55 percent of markets measured by Nielsen, compared with a 33-percent increase in the previous quarter. North America (94) reported the biggest quarterly increase of four points, followed by Asia-Pacific (103), which increased two index points. Declines were reported in the Middle East/Africa region (85), which decreased 11 index points, and in Latin America (94), which declined two index points. Europe’s regional consumer confidence index of 71 held steady from Q4 2012. Confidence increased four points in the U.S. (93), three points in Germany (90), 14 points in Japan (73), and held steady in China (108) from their levels in Q4 2012. Purchase Historical Data The Conference Board Consumer Confidence Index® Improves in April 30 Apr. 2013 NEW YORK, April 30, 2013…The Conference Board Consumer Confidence Index®, which had declined in March, increased in April. The Index now stands at 68.1 (1985=100), up from 61.9 in March. The Present Situation Index increased to 60.4 from 59.2. The Expectations Index improved to 73.3 from 63.7 last month. The monthly Consumer Confidence Survey®, based on a probability-design random sample, is conducted for The Conference Board by Nielsen, a leading global provider of information and analytics around what consumers buy and watch. The cutoff date for the preliminary results was April 18. Says Lynn Franco, Director of Economic Indicators at The Conference Board: “Consumer Confidence improved in April, as consumers’ expectations about the shortterm economic outlook and their income prospects improved. However, consumers’ confidence has been challenged several times over the past few months by such events as the fiscal cliff, the payroll tax hike and the sequester. Thus, while expectations appear to have bounced back, it is too soon to tell if confidence is actually on the mend.” Consumers’ assessment of current conditions improved moderately in April. Those saying business conditions are “good” increased to 17.2 percent from 16.4 percent, while those stating business conditions are “bad” decreased to 28.1 percent from 29.1 percent. Consumers’ assessment of the labor market was mixed. Those claiming jobs are “plentiful” edged up to 9.8 percent from 9.5 percent, however those claiming jobs are “hard to get” increased to 37.1 percent from 35.4 percent. Consumers were considerably more upbeat about the short-term outlook. The percentage of consumers expecting business conditions to improve over the next six months increased to 16.9 percent from 15.0 percent, while those anticipating business conditions to worsen decreased to 15.1 percent from 17.7 percent. Consumers’ outlook for the labor market was also more positive. Those expecting more jobs in the months ahead improved to 14.2 percent from 13.0 percent, while those expecting fewer jobs decreased to 22.4 percent from 26.0 percent. The proportion of consumers expecting their incomes to increase rose to 16.8 percent from 14.6 percent, while those expecting a decrease declined to 16.0 percent from 17.7 percent. Source: April 2013 Consumer Confidence Survey® The Conference Board About The Conference Board The Conference Board is a global, independent business membership and research association working in the public interest. Our mission is unique: To provide the world’s leading organizations with the practical knowledge they need to improve their performance and better serve society. The Conference Board is a non-advocacy, not-forprofit entity holding 501 (c) (3) tax-exempt status in the United States. www.conferenceboard.org About Nielsen Nielsen Holdings N.V. (NYSE: NLSN) is a global information and measurement company with leading market positions in marketing and consumer information, television and other media measurement, online intelligence, mobile measurement, trade shows and related properties. Nielsen has a presence in approximately 100 countries, with headquarters in New York, USA and Diemen, the Netherlands. For more information, The next release is scheduled for Tuesday, May 28 at 10 A.M. For further information contact: Carol Courter at +1 212 339 0232 carol.courter@conference-board.org Chapter 9 Sources of the Dollars that are Lent. Most of our inquiry concerns the borrowers and the decisions of the borrowers to borrow and the impact of those decisions. We now turn to the supply of the dollars. It is crucial to the sellers of consumer lending that consumers borrow. In addition there is a third party at the table, but provider of the dollars that are lent. One can make the case that the Crash of 2007 was caused by the cumulative effect of actions by all three parties. Consumers in a frenzy to borrow; lenders and mortgage brokers in a frenzy to make profits by making loans and then selling those loans; and finally investors in a frenzy to make over market returns by investing dollars for the lenders to lend and the borrowers to borrow. Add in the rating agencies in a frenzy to keep their business and perhaps become sloppy in their rating of mixed securitization pools; and lawyers and investment banks and perhaps accountants in a frenzy to make profits by putting together transactions that accommodate all of these other frenzies. For this as well as for other reasons it is essential to understand the source of the dollars that are lent. Lenders have historically obtained the money they lend either; (1) by borrowing themselves at rates lower than the rates at which they intend to lend; (2) from capital or equity infusions; or (3) in the case of the Bailey Building and Loan of Bedford Falls by receiving deposits from customers and paying those depositors a rate of interest lower than the rate of interest they intend to charge to their borrowers. Securitization originated in the 1920s when mortgage insurance companies sold guaranteed mortgage participation certificates for pools of mortgage loans. Investors actively traded these certificates until the real estate market crashed during the Great Depression. In order to strengthen the housing market during the first great depression the U S government tried several remedies. One of them was to inject more dollars into the lending supply by creating a market and a fund for purchasing loans approved by the Federal Housing Administration (FHA). This government participation encouraged private investors to put their dollars into a fund that would purchase these mortgages. The hope was that this would increase the volume of home loans that could be made and it had some success. Following the Second World War the target was expanded to include VA as well as FHA approved loans. In the late 1970s and early 1980s securitization rose like a phoenix from the ashes. The twin energy crises of the 1970s wreaked havoc on the economy and banks experienced severe disintermediation. Freddie Mac – a federal purchaser of mortgages from members of the Federal Reserve System – responded to this by taking legislative initiatives to improve liquidity in the secondary market for mortgage loans so as to increase the availability of investment capital for housing finance.”[2] Sources: From Bailey Building and Loan to Securitization Bailey building and loan – using deposits Raising capital Borrowing from lenders to lend Small loan Payday- small to larger Securitization: US mortgage finance history Secondary market Then private securitizations Credit cards, car loans and huge market for mortgages. Benefits and worries?? In the 2000 During the crash Post crash Future. Discussion Questions: Why is housing finance so crucial? Why is owning a home an key value in the United States? What role, if any should government have in the housing finance market and why or why not? What about the role of the Federal government in student loans? What about credit cards or car loans? Reuters) - The leaders of the U.S. Senate Banking Committee on Tuesday outlined plans for legislation to wind down government-owned mortgage financiers Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac that they said would continue to provide access to long-term, fixed-rate mortgages. Committee Chairman Tim Johnson, a Democrat, and Senator Mike Crapo, the panel's top Republican, announced the agreement after working for months to bridge a partisan divide with the hope of moving legislation this year. They said they were putting finishing touches on a draft bill they planned to release "in the coming days." Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, which own or guarantee 60 percent of all U.S. home loans, provide a steady source of mortgage funds by buying loans from lenders and packaging them into securities they sell to investors. Their central role in housing finance led the government to bail them out to the tune of $187.5 billion when they ran into trouble in the midst of the financial crisis of 2007-2009. Lawmakers from both parties want to revamp the $10 trillion mortgage market to make it less likely taxpayers will ever be put on the hook again. Under the outline from Johnson and Crapo, private interests would take the first 10 percent of any mortgage losses, before an emergency government backstop would kick in. "This agreement moves us closer to ending the five-year status quo and beginning the wind down of Fannie and Freddie, while protecting taxpayers with strong private capital," Crapo said in a statement. The work by Johnson and Crapo builds off a bipartisan measure previously proposed by Senators Bob Corker of Tennessee and Mark Warner of Virginia. While the announcement from Johnson and Crapo marks the latest step forward, threading the needle between centrist lawmakers, liberal Democrats and conservative Republicans is still likely to prove a difficult task. "This is another step towards reform, but we are still years away from having either the legislative capacity or market willingness to embrace a new mortgage finance system," said Isaac Boltansky, a policy analyst with Compass Point Research and Trading. Under the proposal, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac would be wound down and replaced with a new government reinsurer called the Federal Mortgage Insurance Corp., which would only provide assistance after private creditors had taken a hit. The entity would be financed by fees on lenders who want the government backstop. Included in the outline is a mandate that strong underwriting standards be built into the new system. It would also require a 5 percent downpayment for all but first-time buyers, although that requirement would be phased-in over time. Some consumer and housing advocates worry that a system with rigid down payments will prevent less affluent Americans from accessing credit even if a limited government role is retained. "There is near unanimous agreement that our current housing finance system is not sustainable in the long term and reform is necessary to help strengthen and stabilize the economy," said Johnson. "This bipartisan effort will provide the market the certainty it needs, while preserving fair and affordable housing throughout the country." The outline from the two senators said they plan to "eliminate affordable housing goals" and instead establish housing-related funds to ensure housing is available for all types of borrowers and renters. These funds would be financed through a user fee on lenders that seek FMIC backing. To ensure community banks are not squeezed out of the system, the senators said they would seek to establish a "mutual cooperative jointly owned by small lenders" to offer a cash window for eligible loans while allowing the institutions to retain mortgage servicing rights. Any housing reform plan passed by the Democrat-controlled Senate must also make its way through the Republican-controlled House before it can be signed into law. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were seized by regulators in 2008 as loan defaults drove them toward insolvency. But they have since returned to profitability and have returned $202.9 billion in dividends to taxpayers for their federal bailout. (Reporting By Margaret Chadbourn; Editing by Tim Ahmann and Andrea Ricci) Reuters) - The leaders of the U.S. Senate Banking Committee on Tuesday outlined plans for legislation to wind down government-owned mortgage financiers Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac that they said would continue to provide access to long-term, fixed-rate mortgages. Committee Chairman Tim Johnson, a Democrat, and Senator Mike Crapo, the panel's top Republican, announced the agreement after working for months to bridge a partisan divide with the hope of moving legislation this year. They said they were putting finishing touches on a draft bill they planned to release "in the coming days." Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, which own or guarantee 60 percent of all U.S. home loans, provide a steady source of mortgage funds by buying loans from lenders and packaging them into securities they sell to investors. Their central role in housing finance led the government to bail them out to the tune of $187.5 billion when they ran into trouble in the midst of the financial crisis of 2007-2009. Lawmakers from both parties want to revamp the $10 trillion mortgage market to make it less likely taxpayers will ever be put on the hook again. Under the outline from Johnson and Crapo, private interests would take the first 10 percent of any mortgage losses, before an emergency government backstop would kick in. "This agreement moves us closer to ending the five-year status quo and beginning the wind down of Fannie and Freddie, while protecting taxpayers with strong private capital," Crapo said in a statement. The work by Johnson and Crapo builds off a bipartisan measure previously proposed by Senators Bob Corker of Tennessee and Mark Warner of Virginia. While the announcement from Johnson and Crapo marks the latest step forward, threading the needle between centrist lawmakers, liberal Democrats and conservative Republicans is still likely to prove a difficult task. "This is another step towards reform, but we are still years away from having either the legislative capacity or market willingness to embrace a new mortgage finance system," said Isaac Boltansky, a policy analyst with Compass Point Research and Trading. Under the proposal, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac would be wound down and replaced with a new government reinsurer called the Federal Mortgage Insurance Corp., which would only provide assistance after private creditors had taken a hit. The entity would be financed by fees on lenders who want the government backstop. Included in the outline is a mandate that strong underwriting standards be built into the new system. It would also require a 5 percent downpayment for all but first-time buyers, although that requirement would be phased-in over time. Some consumer and housing advocates worry that a system with rigid down payments will prevent less affluent Americans from accessing credit even if a limited government role is retained. "There is near unanimous agreement that our current housing finance system is not sustainable in the long term and reform is necessary to help strengthen and stabilize the economy," said Johnson. "This bipartisan effort will provide the market the certainty it needs, while preserving fair and affordable housing throughout the country." The outline from the two senators said they plan to "eliminate affordable housing goals" and instead establish housing-related funds to ensure housing is available for all types of borrowers and renters. These funds would be financed through a user fee on lenders that seek FMIC backing. To ensure community banks are not squeezed out of the system, the senators said they would seek to establish a "mutual cooperative jointly owned by small lenders" to offer a cash window for eligible loans while allowing the institutions to retain mortgage servicing rights. Any housing reform plan passed by the Democrat-controlled Senate must also make its way through the Republican-controlled House before it can be signed into law. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were seized by regulators in 2008 as loan defaults drove them toward insolvency. But they have since returned to profitability and have returned $202.9 billion in dividends to taxpayers for their federal bailout. (Reporting By Margaret Chadbourn; Editing by Tim Ahmann and Andrea Ricci) Securitization is a complex series of financial transactions designed to maximize cash flow and reduce risk for debt originators. This is achieved when assets, receivables or financial instruments are acquired, classified into pools, and offered as collateral for third-party investment. Then, financial instruments are sold which are backed by the cash flow or value of the underlying assets. Securitization typically applies to assets that are illiquid (i.e. cannot easily be sold). It is common in the real estate industry, where it is applied to pools of leased property, and in thelending industry, where it is applied to lenders' claims on mortgages, home equity loans, student loans, vehicle loans and other debts. A list of the types of financial debt instruments that have been securitized is included in these materials. Any assets can be securitized so long as they are associated with a steady amount of cash flow. Investors "buy" these assets by making loans which are secured against the underlying pool of assets and its associated income stream. Securitization thus "converts illiquid assets into liquid assets" by pooling, underwriting and selling their ownership in the form of asset-backed securities (ABS). Securitization utilizes a special purpose vehicle (SPV) (alternatively known as a special purpose entity [SPE] or special purpose company [SPC]) in order to reduce the risk of bankruptcy and thereby obtain lower interest rates from potential lenders. A credit derivative is also generally used to change the credit quality of the underlying portfolio so that it will be acceptable to the final investors. II. History Asset securitization began with the structured financing of mortgage pools in the 1970s. For decades before that, banks were essentially portfolio lenders; they held loans until they matured or were paid off. These loans were funded principally by deposits, and sometimes by debt, which was a direct obligation of the bank (rather than a claim on specific assets). After World War II, depository institutions simply could not keep pace with the rising demand for housing credit. Banks, as well as other financial intermediaries sensing a market opportunity, sought ways of increasing the sources of mortgage funding. To attract investors, bankers eventually developed an investment vehicle that isolated defined mortgage pools, segmented the credit risk, and structured the cash flows from the underlying loans. Although it took several years to develop efficient mortgage securitization structures, loan originators quickly realized the process was readily transferable to other types of loans as well." In February 1970, the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development created the transaction using a mortgage-backed security. The Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA or Ginnie Mae) sold securities backed by a portfolio of mortgage loans. In February 1970, the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development created the transaction using a mortgage-backed security. The Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA or Ginnie Mae) sold securities backed by a portfolio of mortgage loans. To facilitate the securitization of non-mortgage assets, businesses substituted private credit enhancements. First, they over-collateralized pools of assets; shortly thereafter, they improved third-party and structural enhancements. In 1985, securitization techniques that had American Bankruptcy Institute been developed in the mortgage market were applied for the first time to a class of non-mortgage assets — automobile loans. A pool of assets second only to mortgages in volume, auto loans were a good match for structured finance; their maturities, considerably shorter than those of mortgages, made the timing of cash flows more predictable, and their long statistical histories of performance gave investors confidence. The first significant bank credit card sale came to market in 1986 with a private placement of $50 million of outstanding bank card loans. This transaction demonstrated to investors that, if the yields were high enough, loan pools could support asset sales with higher expected losses and administrative costs than was true within the mortgage market. Sales of this type — with no contractual obligation by the seller to provide recourse — allowed banks to receive sales treatment for accounting and regulatory purposes (easing balance sheet and capital constraints), while at the same time allowing them to retain origination and servicing fees. After the success of this initial transaction, investors grew to accept credit card receivables as collateral, and banks developed structures to normalize the cash flows. III.Benefits of Securitization There are good reasons why securitization has taken off. The existence of a liquid secondary market for home mortgages and other financial debt instruments increases the availability of capital to make new loans. This increases the availability of credit. Securitization also helps to decrease the cost of credit by lowering originator’s financing costs by offering lenders a way to raise funds in the capital market with lower interest rates. Finally, securitization reallocates risk by shifting the credit risk associated with securitized assets to investors, rather than leaving all the risk with the financial institutions. IV.Who are the Players in the Securitization Process? The primary players in the securitization of any particular pool of assets can vary. Included in these materials is a flow chart for the MBS (mortgage backed securities) issue identified as “Meritage Mortgage Loan Trust 2005-2, Asset-Backed Certificates, Series 2005-2.” The flow chart illustrates the roles of and the relationships between the various primary parties in a typical issue. Each party is addressed below: A. Originators – the parties, such as mortgage lenders and banks, that initially create the assets to be securitized. B. Aggregator – purchases assets of a similar type from one or more Originators to form the pool of assets to be securitized. C. Depositor – creates the SPV/SPE for the securitized transaction. The Depositor acquires the pooled assets from the Aggregator and in turn deposits them into the SPV/SPE . D. Issuer – acquires the pooled assets and issues the certificates to eventually be sold to the investors. However, the Issuer does not directly offer the certificates for sale to the investors. Instead, the Issuer conveys the certificate to the Depositor in exchange for the pooled assets. In simplified forms of securitization, the Issuer is the SPV which finally holds the pooled assets and acts as a conduit for the cash flows of the pooled assets. E. Underwriter – usually an investment bank, purchases all of the SPV’s certificates from the Depositor with the responsibility of offering to them for sale to the ultimate investors. The money paid by the Underwriter to the Depositor is then transferred from the Depositor to the Aggregator to the Originator as the purchase price for the pooled assets. F. Investors – purchase the SPV’s issued certificates. Each Investor is entitled to receive monthly payments of principal and interest from the SPV. The order of priority of payment to each investor, the interest rate to be paid to each investor and other payment rights accorded to each investor, including the speed of principal repayment, depending on which class or tranche of certificates were purchased. The SPV makes distributions to the Investors from the cash flows of the pooled assets. G. Trustee – the party appointed to oversee the issuing SPV and protect the Investors’ interests by calculating the cash flows from the pooled assets and by remitting the SPV’s net revenues to the Investors as returns. H. Servicer – the party that collects the money due from the borrowers under each individual loan in the asset pool. The Servicer remits the collected funds to the Trustee for distribution to the Investors. Servicers are entitled to collect fees for servicing the pooled loans. Consequently, some Originators desire to retain the pool’s servicing rights to both realize the full payment on their securitized assets when sold and to have a residual income on those same loans through the entitlement to ongoing servicing fees. Some Originators will contract with other organizations to perform the servicing function, or sell the valuable servicing rights. Often, there are multiple servicers for a single SPV. There may be a Master Servicer, a Primary Servicer, a Sub-Servicer, and a Default or Special Servicer. Each will have 672 responsibilities related to the pooled assets, depending on the circumstances and conditions. V. The Why’s and How’s of Securitization A. True Sale and HIDC Status The securitization process is designed, in most cases, to make the pooled assets “bankruptcy remote.” To accomplish this, the transfer of the pooled assets from the Originator to the SPV must be accomplished by way of a “true sale.” If the asset transfer is not a true sale, investors are vulnerable to claims against the Originator, including the claims of a bankruptcy trustee that might be appointed if the Originator were to file bankruptcy. Without “bankruptcy remoteness,” Investors would bear the risk of default in the underlying pooled assets, as well as any claim by the Originator’s bankruptcy trustee that the pooled assets or cash flows from those assets are part of the bankruptcy estate which could be used to satisfy claims of the Originator’s creditors. A true sale also protects the Originator from claims by investors. If the pooled assets are sold into an SPV, the Investor can only seek payment from that entity, not from the general revenues of the Originator. In order to create the desired “bankruptcy remoteness,” the pool assets must be transferred by “true sale.” Such a sale also provides the SPV with Holder in Due Course (HIDC) status and protection. In order to gain HIDC status, the SPV must satisfy the requirements of UCC section 3-302. The SPV must: take the instrument for value, in good faith, without notice that the instrument is overdue, dishonored or has an uncured default, without notice that the instrument contains unauthorized signatures or has been altered, and without notice that any party has a claim or defense in recoupment. Additionally, the instrument, when issued or negotiated to the holder, cannot bear any evidence of forgery or alteration or have irregularities that would give rise to questions of authenticity. The main benefit of HIDC status is that the holder may enforce the payment rights under the negotiable instrument free from all by a limited number of defenses as outlined in UCC 3-305. The HIDC takes the note or instrument free from competing claims of ownership by third parties. B. Pooling and Servicing Agreement One of the most important documents in the securitization process is the Pooling and Servicing Agreement (PSA). This is the contract that governs the relationship between the various parties in the securitization process. The PSAs in many securitization deals can run 300- 500 pages in length, spelling out the duties and obligations of each party and the mechanics by which the actual securitization is accomplished. Included in these materials is an excerpt of the PSA for the Meritage Mortgage Loan Trust 2005-2 AssetBacked Certificates, Series 2005-2. Securitization provides a vehicle that allows lenders to lend well beyond the dollars they could otherwise raise; it provides the investors with a way of investing in the profits that will be made off of consumer borrowing; and it provides lenders with a way to “lay off” the risk of the loans that it makes. “ It's A Wonderful Mortgage Crisis Dec 22, 2008 7:00 PM EST What the classic holiday movie "It's a Wonderful Life" can teach us about the mortgage industry meltdown. It's traditional during the holiday season to watch the great Frank Capra movie "It's a Wonderful Life," and this year, the film is particularly relevant—it can help us to better understand our current economic malaise and the mortgage credit problem that is at the center of the crisis. In one of the most famous scenes, there's a run on the Bailey Building and Loan, a small bank owned by George Bailey, the tortured character played by Jimmy Stewart. As depositors clamor to get their money back, Stewart tells them, "You're thinking of this place all wrong, as if I had the money back in the safe. The money's not here. Your money's in Joe's house, that's right next to yours. And in the Kennedy house and Mrs. Macklin's house and a hundred others. Why, you're lending them the money to build. … Give us 60 days." In the language of finance, Bailey is explaining that the Bailey Building and Loan made and held "whole loans," mortgages that have not been securitized. Its liabilities are the deposits the bank's depositors have come to withdraw, and its assets are the highly illiquid mortgages that it holds as a result of lending money to the town's residents to build their homes in Bedford Falls. If the movie were remade today (and let's hope it's not), here's what would happen in Bedford Falls. A different George Bailey—played, say, by Brad Pitt—would have "originated" home loans in Bedford Falls. Pitt would have then sold those loans to Freddie Mac or to Fannie Mae or to another loan aggregator. Each of those loans would then ultimately have been "securitized" into one of many "tranches": cut up into many slices based on the risk of repayment of each chunk of the loan. The various slices from thousands of loans all over the United States would then be pooled, again by potential risk of default, and that pool would issue a mortgage-backed security that was "rated" by one or more of the federally sanctioned ratings agencies: Moody's, Standard & Poor's and Fitch. (In the current crisis, those investments had cryptic names like "GSAMP 2006-S5 A2" and "WAMU 2007-HY6 2B1.") The idea behind the pooling of loan slices is a powerful one—by sorting the payments to those supplying capital into specific risk categories, it is possible to lower the cost of capital to borrowers. Now, what would the Bailey Building and Loan do with the proceeds it receives from selling the loans that it originated? It would buy securities that would be held as assets on its balance sheet and, depending on the risk and value of those securities, it would continue to originate more loans. So far, this all seems well and good. The securitization has lowered the cost to borrowers and made the assets held by the Bailey Building and Loan appear to be more liquid—instead of lumpy whole loans, its new assets are securities that, at least in theory, can be sold and that are priced in the market. The problem is that while the Building and Loan would buy securities such as treasury bonds, it would also likely buy small amounts of a lot of mortgage-backed securities, such as the above-mentioned GSAMP 2006-S5 A2 and hundreds of other such securities. These securities aren't heavily traded in markets, but the top category of these offerings typically was treated by bank regulators as extremely safe—likely to return the full value of the investment made in them with interest—because of their very high investment grade ratings. When housing declined in value throughout the United States, many mortgage-backed securities became imperiled, and as a result, many of the nation's banks became insolvent. So in the presence of a run, in our remake, Brad Pitt might say this: "Why, don't ask for your money back right now when the housing market is in decline. You know that money isn't in the safe; it's invested in GSAMP 2006-S5 A2 and WAMU 2007-HY6 2B1 and the like. I can't give you your money back unless and until those multiyear-duration securities get repaid (if they ever do) or if they somehow revert back toward par value and I can sell them. Since they're trading at cents on the dollar, they have a long way to go. Just give me 60 days, and maybe the Treasury will bail me out." Jimmy Stewart told his depositors that he knew that their investment in the Bailey Building and Loan was "good," even though its assets were not liquid. This is because he knew the location of each home held as collateral, the occupant-borrower, the prospects for repayment and more. All that Brad Pitt's George Bailey could ever know is that he bought securities rated highly by each and every one of the three government-endorsed rating agencies, and that the investment banks that underwrote them thought those securities were sound investments. Nothing more. He'd have no idea who the borrowers are, where the homes are located, what their condition is or whether they are even occupied, much less the likelihood that a particular borrower could weather the storm. The contrast is what makes a new viewing of "It's a Wonderful Life" compelling this holiday season—it's a reminder of a simpler time, and simultaneously a stark reflection of what went wrong in the current crisis. Benefits to the Originators, especially FIs For FIs, securitisation is an opportunity offered in the form of capital relief, capital allocation efficiency, and improvements in financial ratios. •Lower cost of borrowing: Securitisation reduces the total cost of financing as assets are transferred to a separate bankruptcy-resistant entity. To that extent FIs need not maintain capital to maintain their capital adequacy norms. Also, entities with a riskier credit profile can benefit from lowered borrowing costs. •A source of liquidity: FIs could face a liquidity crunch either due to their risky credit profile or delayed receivables. The liquidity provided by securitisation acts as a very powerful tool, that FIs could use to adjust the asset mix quickly and efficiently. Further, the risks in an asset portfolio can be identified and apportioned to arrive at an effective asset mix. •Improved financial indicators: Securitisation leads to capital relief that improves the company’s leverage and in turn the Return on Equity. The repercussions of securitisation on the balance sheet of a company can vary depending on the strategy for its capital structure and its appetite for increasing or decreasing leverage. •Asset-Liability Management: Securitisation offers the flexibility in structuring and timing cash flows to each security tranche. It provides a means whereby customised securities can be created which helps in matching the tenure of the liabilities and assets. •Diversified fund sources: By securitising its receivables, the instrument of which could be sold to global investors, the originator has an opportunity to diversify its funding source. •Positive signals to the Capital Markets: Lenders are at times trapped in a situation where they cannot rollover their debt due to downgrading of their ratings, possibly due to economic changes. Under these circumstances, securitisation enables lenders like FIs to increase the rating of debt much higher than that of the issuer through the intrinsic credit value of the asset. This enables the FIs to obtain funding. •An avenue for divestiture: Securitisation offers an optimal exit route for entities that wish to exit a business comprising of financial assets without going through the mergers and acquisition route. Benefits to the Investors Investors purchase risk-adjusted securities based on its level of maturity and seniority. For instance, an auto loan or credit card receivables backed paper carries regular monthly cash flows, which can match the requirements of investors like mutual funds. •New Asset Class: Securitised products provide new investment avenues for investors to enhance their return or to diversify their portfolio. For instance, an investor in the United States whose investment is predominantly in US assets can diversify by investing in securities offered by an SPV in Asia. •Risk Diversification: As the underlying pool of receivables is spread across diverse customers the investors need not have a thorough understanding of the underlying assets. The investor is insulated from customer specific event risk. •Customisation: Securitisation of financial assets allows tailoring of cash flows to the risk profile of the investors. A certain stream of cash flow coming from an underlying asset pool can be broken into tranches and offered as per the investor risk appetite. •Decoupling with Originator: The investor is insulated from the credit profile of the Originator. This separation of the Originator and the investor helps at the time of bankruptcy or default or credit downgrades. Please read : http://www.americansecuritization.com/uploadedfiles/ASF_NERA_Report.PDF And http://fcic-static.law.stanford.edu/cdn_media/fcic-reports/2010-0407Preliminary_Staff_Report_-_Securitization_and_the_Mortgage_Crisis.pdf And http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/epr/12v18n2/1207peri.pdf Other sources of dollars that Payday lenders lend. Public Pensions Finance Payday Lenders Some of the nation’s largest banks, including Wells Fargo WFC +0.48% and U.S. Bank, continue to offer payday loans despite growing regulatory scrutiny and mounting criticism, according to a report issued earlier this year by the Center for Responsible Lending. Evidently gouging low-income borrowers into long-term debt charging outrageous interest rates of 500%, or more, is too good for big banks to resist. Regulators have issued numerous warnings about abusive payday loan practices. Last May, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation said the agency was “deeply concerned” about payday lending. The Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, which oversees the nation’s largest banks, said in June 2011 that the loans raised “operational and credit risks and supervisory concerns.” The Consumer Finacial Protection Bureau has been examining whether banks violate consumer protection laws in the marketing of these products. Unlike Louisiana Public Pensions, Some Fletcher Hedge Fund Investors Got Money Out Edward "Ted" SiedleContributor Kentucky Retirement System Whistleblower Sends Unite Here Union Report to SEC Edward "Ted" SiedleContributor Rhode Island Public Pension 'Reform' Looks More Like Wall Street Feeding Frenzy Edward "Ted" SiedleContributor AFSCME's Unstoppable Rhode Island Pension Forensic Investigation Edward "Ted" SiedleContributor Fifteen states have banned usurious payday lending to protect workers and just last week state authorities took action against certain predatory payday lenders. Obviously, included in the portfolios of most of the nation’s massive state and local public pensions (whether through actively managed accounts or index funds), are stocks of large banks which derive a portion of their earnings from fleecing payday borrowers. It may be unreasonable to expect public pensions to forego investing in major banks, or scrutinize every activity of the major banks in which they invest and object to banking practices they find reprehensible. However, according to industry sources, in addition to large banks, some of the largest payday loan companies are publicly traded, such as Cash America (CSH), and Dollar Financial (DFC). Some other large lenders include Community Choice Financial and SpeedyCash. Other lenders, according to the industry, are backed by investors large and small, such as hedge funds, private equity companies and family offices. For example, Payday One, was formerly offered by Think Finance, a company which claims to be “privately held and backed by some of Silicon Valley’s most respected venture capital firms, including Sequoia Capital and Technology Crossover Ventures.” It’s more than likely that public pensions loading-up on hedge funds and private equity are, due to the lack of transparency related to alternative investments, inadvertently financing payday marauders. Virtually all public funds that invest with alternative managers agree to reduced transparency regarding the investments held in alternative portfolios, including denying public access to such information. I’ve witnessed alternative managers and investment consultants advise public pensions that ignorance regarding strategies and investments is beneficial, permitting plausible deniability and avoidance of headline risk. You’ll never have to admit to things which you purposely do not know. Among publicly-traded payday lender Cash America’s top institutional holders is Earnest Partners LLC, which owned $75 million of the stock at June 30, 2013. (Other major holders of Cash America and Dollar Financial stock with significant public pension clients include Vanguard and BlackRock.) According to its website, Earnest Partners manages approximately $20 billion in assets for clients around the world, including corporate pension plans, state and municipal pension plans. According to published reports, the firm was recently terminated as a domestic midcap equity manager handling $514 million for the Ohio Police and Fire Pension. (Ironically, earlier this year Ohio’s Supreme Court announced it would hear a payday lending case that could close the licensing loophole payday stores use to charge borrowers triple-digit interest. It seems Buckeyes can’t decide whether to prohibit, or profit from, payday lending.) I don’t know whether Cash America stock was included in the $514 million portfolio Earnest Partners managed for the Ohio Police and Fire Pension but, given the outrageous returns related to payday lending, as public pensions migrate further into alternative investments, they should, in my opinion, determine whether they are, directly or indirectly, financing the business of screwing the poor. CHAPTER 10 ECONOMIC IMPACT January 7, 2014 The goal of this chapter is to provide you a basis for understanding the economic impacts of consumer borrowing and lending on individuals and households (“micro”) and on the overall economy (“macro”) so you can figure in the good, the bad and the ugly and the beautiful in your calculation for how much and how to regulate consumer borrowing/lending. The central questions for our inquiry are: On a micro basis what is the economic impact of consumer lending or borrowing? On individuals, on family et al. On a macro basis what is the economic impact of consumer lending or borrowing opn the overall economy? Did the explosion in consumer lending cause the crash of 2007? What effect did the explosion in subprime mortgages and credit card lending have? To what extent, if any, can/do consumer lending developments have a major (macro) effect on the overall economy. If you knew that such an explosion would cause a crash every 80, or 50 or 10 years, would that have any effect on your decisions regarding regulation?? Don't Expect Consumer Spending To Be the Engine of Economic Growth It Once Was By William R. Emmons http://www.stlouisfed.org/publications/re/articles/?id=2201 (may be a better way of reading this article because it includes helpful graphs, but it also includes some complicated math and economic talk) Can American consumers continue to serve as the engine of U.S. and global economic growth as they did during recent decades? Several powerful trends suggest not, at least for a while. Instead, new sources of demand, both domestic and foreign, are needed if we are to maintain healthy rates of growth. Unfortunately, this won't be easy because consumer spending constitutes the largest part of our economy, and replacements for it— more investment, more government spending or more exports—either can't be increased rapidly or might create unwanted consequences of their own. How We Got Here: The Consumer-Driven U.S. Economy It is no exaggeration to say that consumer spending was the dominant source of economic growth in the United States during recent decades. For example: During the 10 years ending in the last prerecession quarter (third quarter of 2007), inflation-adjusted personal consumption expenditures (PCE) grew at a continuously compounded annual rate of 3.47 percent, while overall inflation-adjusted annual growth of gross domestic product (GDP) averaged only 2.91 percent. During that period, the remainder of the economy—consisting of investment (I), government purchases of goods and services (G), and net exports (NX)—grew at only a 1.70 percent inflation-adjusted annual rate. Expressed in terms of its contribution to average quarterly real GDP growth during the decade ending in the third quarter of 2007, PCE accounted for 81.3 percent, while the other components (I, G and NX) contributed only 18.7 percent. Over the quarter-century ending in the third quarter of 2007, consumer expenditures grew, on average, at a 3.50 continuously compounded annual rate, while the rest of the economy (I, G and NX) grew at a 2.79 percent annual rate. PCE accounted for 70.8 percent of average real GDP growth during those 25 years (1982: Q3 through 2007: Q3), while all other components (I, G and NX) contributed 29.2 percent. Consumer spending accounts for a majority of spending in all advanced nations. What makes the U.S. experience of recent decades unusual is that the share of consumer spending in GDP was relatively high already before it began to increase substantially further during the 1980s, 1990s and 2000s. In dollar terms, PCE's share of GDP in the third quarters of 1977, 1987, 1997 and 2007 were 62.5, 65.9, 66.7 and 69.5 percent, respectively. Thus, consumer spending was a large and increasingly important part of the American economy during the decades preceding the recession and remains so today. International dimensions of U.S. consumer spending. As consumer spending grew rapidly in the U.S., we imported consumer-oriented goods and services even more rapidly. Imports of all goods and services increased at an annual, inflation-adjusted rate of 6.5 percent during the decade ending in the third quarter of 2007. But imports of consumer goods—44 percent of all imports—increased at an annual average rate of 7.5 percent. U.S. imports contributed importantly to growth in many exporting countries around the world. U.S. consumers, therefore, served as the locomotive not only for the U.S. economy but for the global economy. Because we incurred large trade deficits, we required a corresponding inflow of foreign capital to finance them. These three facets of U.S. and global economic growth—high-spending and low-saving American consumers, large U.S. trade deficits, and substantial inflows of foreign capital—are important contributors to the so-called "global imbalances" long noted by international economists and policymakers. These imbalances may have contributed to the U.S. housing bubble, the global financial crisis and the ensuing Great Recession. The correlation between the share of U.S. GDP accounted for by private investment spending and the rate of economic growth generally has been positive. Looking at 10year periods, the correlation between the private investment-spending share of the economy in any year and the economic growth rate in that year ranged between a low of 0.43 and a high of 0.68, with an overall value of 0.50 for the 60-year period 1951-2010. The bottom panel of the table shows decade-long averages of the private investmentshare of GDP and decade averages of real economic growth rates. The correlation between the variables in these two columns is 0.14, indicating a tendency, albeit a weak one, for decades of relatively low private investment spending, such as in 2001-2010, to also be decades in which economic growth was low. In sum, the primary reason a consumer-dominated economy may not be desirable is that consumer spending may crowd out investment spending, which is a key determinant of long-term growth. Of course, the tendency of consumer spending in the U.S. to be high when private investment spending and economic growth are low may be due to more complex causes or pure chance, but the simple correlations presented here are at least suggestive of a more direct connection. Five Trends Working Against Consumer Spending At least five major trends currently evident suggest that U.S. consumer spending may grow more slowly in the near future than it has for decades. Lower wealth. First and foremost, U.S. household wealth took a beating during the Great Recession. The inflation-adjusted average wealth of an American citizen, which plateaued at about $210,000 during the first half of 2007, remained about 24 percent lower on Sept. 30, 2011 ($160,000), despite having rebounded from the depressed level of the first quarter of 2009 ($152,000; all figures are expressed in terms of 2005 dollars).4 Many lower- and middle-income households are feeling especially strong balance-sheet pressure as house prices—representing their principal asset in many cases—continue to weaken even as stock-market values—overwhelmingly owned by high-income households—have recovered some of their losses. Negative equity—a situation in which a household's mortgage debt exceeds the market value of the house— now affects between 22 and 29 percent of all households with mortgages, according to various estimates.5 In sum, the loss of significant amounts of wealth and the severe pressure in some households to deleverage their balance sheets (reduce debt) are likely to contribute to restrained consumer spending for some time. Stagnant incomes. The economic recovery under way since mid-2009 has been mediocre, at best. Job growth barely matches population growth, while incomes of the typical worker are barely keeping up with inflation. Average weekly earnings, after inflation adjustment, for a private-sector worker increased just 12 cents, or 0.03 percent—from $350.80 to $350.92—during the five years through October 2011.6 Continuing a trend in evidence even before the recession, most of the overall gains in income appear to be flowing to high-income workers. Tight credit. Consumer lenders either have disappeared altogether or are offering credit on a much more restricted basis than before the downturn. By all accounts, mortgage credit is less available to all but the strongest borrowers than was the case just a few years ago. Even borrowers with high credit scores need substantial equity in order to borrow for house purchase or mortgage refinancing. According to Federal Reserve surveys of banks' lending officers, credit standards for nonmortgage consumer loans have begun to loosen only since 2010, after tightening for about four years.7 Credit standards for mortgage loans have not loosened significantly, after having been tightened sharply between 2006 and 2010. Fragile confidence. Major consumer-confidence indexes have rebounded from their lowest levels during 2009 in the immediate aftermath of the recession, but they remain below the levels that prevailed just as the recession began in late 2007.8 Inflationadjusted per-capita consumption expenditures grew at a 2.4-percent annualized rate during the decade ending in December 2007, but have grown at only a 1.4-percent annualized rate in the 28 months since the recession ended (June 2009 through October 2011). Looming reversal of stimulus. Unprecedented doses of monetary- and fiscal-policy stimulus since the recession began partly offset the contractionary forces on consumer spending noted above. Government support for consumer spending on this scale is not feasible indefinitely, however. The Federal Reserve has explored options to "exit" its extraordinarily accommodative monetary policy, while Congress and the president agree that budget consolidation is necessary in the not-too-distant future. In both cases, a tightening of policy measures represents a withdrawal of support for household incomes and wealth and, therefore, consumer spending. Individually, any of the five obstacles noted above might be surmountable. But combined, these contractionary forces make the outlook for broad-based consumer spending growth challenging. To be sure, some households weathered the economic and financial storms well, but we can't count on these fortunate few to step up their spending sufficiently to offset the lost spending caused by declines in wealth, income, access to credit, confidence and government support. Rebalancing the U.S. and Global Economies Unfortunately, it will take time for business investment and exports—the sectors essential for creating robust, sustainable growth for years to come—to expand sufficiently to replace the spending power long provided by consumers. Business investment and exports today are relatively small sectors of the U.S. economy. To see the scale of the restructuring challenge, consider this simple thought experiment. A sustained one percentage-point decline in the average growth rate of consumer spending would require either business-investment growth or export growth to double immediately from their prerecession long-term average rates in order to make up the shortfall. More realistically, both investment and export growth might increase to offset slower consumer-spending growth, but the required accelerations still would be substantial. If consumer spending indeed grows more slowly for some time than it did before the recession, and if business investment and exports take some time to ramp up to become permanently larger components of the U.S. economy, we are left with two undesirable short-term alternatives. Either the overall economic growth rate will decline, as slower consumer-spending growth cannot be fully compensated by faster investment and export activity, or one could attempt to fill the private-demand shortfall with increased direct government spending, tax cuts and transfer payments to households. In fact, these dismal scenarios are not hypothetical; they've already happened. The recession itself could be described as a period in which consumer spending contracted sharply, while other sources of private demand were unable to offset the shortfall. The subsequent recovery, such as it is, largely has been the result of massive government interventions in the form of financial rescues, unprecedented monetary stimulus and record-breaking government budget deficits. We're left with extremely low short-term and long-term interest rates, as well as historically large budget deficits—all of which must reverse at some point. Only a few policymakers have discussed the significant challenges posed by our consumer-dominated economy.9 Our objective is clear, if not easily attainable: We must actively restructure our economy to become more friendly to business investment and exports in order to put long-term growth on a sustainable foundation. We must come closer to balancing our trade and our government budgets, and we must generate a far higher share of the savings we need for investment in our own economy.10 Higher saving rates also would insulate us somewhat from potential disruptive shifts in capital inflows and outflows initiated by foreign investors. It appears likely that consumer spending will recede as the main engine of U.S. economic growth, at least for the near future. At the same time, other nations that depended heavily on U.S. purchases of their consumer-focused exports for their own growth will need to restructure their economies to promote alternative sources of long-run sustainable economic growth—not least to provide growing markets for our exports. To assure strong, sustainable growth in the long term, the U.S. economy needs to include a larger role for business investment and exports than has been the case in recent decades. Author William R. Emmons Assistant Vice President and Economist Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis New St. Louis Fed Banking and Economic Research US GDP is 70 Percent Personal Consumption: Inside the Numbers Rick Mathews US GDP is 70 Percent Personal Consumption Inside the Numbers It seems most people understand, personal consumption drives the American economy. Personal consumption historically represents 70% of our nation’s GDP. In part II our series examining gross domestic product as a means to understand what is holding back our nation’s economic recovery we will examine personal consumption expenditures using the expenditure approach: C + I + G + (X - M) = GDP C = Personal Consumption Expenditures I = Gross Private Fixed Investment G = Government Expenditures and Investment X = Net Exports M = Net Imports Attempting to balance the playing field for all readers, we will use the following definitions which include hyperlinks for those wishing to enhance their comprehensive knowledge of the material presented. The personal consumption expenditures price index (PCE) measure is the component statistic for consumption in GDP collected by the Bureau of Economic Analysis. It consists of the actual and imputed expenditures of households and includes data pertaining to durable and non-durable goods and services. It is essentially a measure of goods and services targeted towards individuals and consumed by individuals. Personal consumption expenditures are officially separated into three categories in the national income and product accounts: durable goods, non-durable goods, and services. Durable goods are the tangible goods purchased by consumers that tend to last for more than a year. Common examples are cars, furniture, and appliances. The two most important subcategories of durable goods in the National Income and Product Accounts are "motor vehicles and parts" and "furniture and other household equipment." Durable goods purchases are usually about 10 to 15 percent of personal consumption expenditures. This percentage tends to be at the low end during business-cycle contractions and at the high end during business-cycle expansion. Non-durable goods are the tangible goods purchased by consumers that tend to last for less than a year. Common examples are food, clothing, and gasoline. In fact, the three most important subcategories of non-durable goods in the national income and product accounts are listed as "food," "clothing and shoes," and "gasoline and oil." Non-durable goods purchases are usually about 25 to 30 percent of personal consumption expenditures. Services are activities that provide direct satisfaction of wants and needs without the production of tangible goods. Common examples are information, entertainment, and education. The four primary subcategories of services in the National Income and Product Accounts are "housing," "household operation," "transportation," and "medical care." Expenditures on services are the largest of the three consumption categories, coming in at about 55 to 60 percent of personal consumption expenditures. By extension C = Durable goods + Non-durable goods + Services To place the importance of personal consumption expenditures in context, during 2011 the nation’s GDP was $15.1 Trillion. Personal consumption expenditures accounted for $10.7 trillion of that total! While none can deny the critical role of personal consumption expenditures in our economy, what far too many do not understand is how far and how fast expenditures have changed In 2011 expenditures on goods contributed $3.6 trillion in 2011, nearly one-fourth of total GDP. That is a very significant portion of expenditure yet only 7% of GDP today is expended on durable goods such as automobiles and furniture. Non-durable goods, such as food, clothing and fuel contribute 16% toward GDP. Per the U.S. Census Bureau’s September 2012 report, Americans spent $45.8 billion at gas stations. That total actually exceeded what we spent as a nation in restaurants and bar $44.1 billion. But for all the expenditures we make on goods, it is our service expenditures which actually provide the bulk of personal consumer expenditures. This was not always the case in America. As late as 1968, American expenditures on total goods represented nearly 40% of GNP. Today, expenditure on services actually exceeds that amount as they totaled 46% in 2011. American expended more than $7 trillion on services in 2011. A large driver of this growth has been the dramatic increase of the financial services and health care services industries. If there is a positive note on this change in expenditures it might be services are both consumed and produced domestically, as they are difficult to export. Housing and utilities, health care expenditures, financial services and insurance, and food and accommodations accounted for three-fourths of all service sector spending. Which leads us to the premise of this essay series, if we understand what constitutes the components of our GNP, Why haven’t we been able to more significantly enhance economic growth and by extension lower unemployment? Academics will contend, America has attempted both traditional and nontraditional methods for stimulating economic growth. Multiple fiscal and monetary policies been run out in succession trying to sway our nation’s purchasing decisions. Some have been more effective than others such as Cash for Clunkers and the variety of federal mortgage refinancing programs. Yet even these have not achieved the levels of participation hoped for. As example, less than a quarter of the hoped for federal mortgage refinances have been processed. Multiple economic and psychological explanations have been put forth regarding the tightening of America’s spending habits. Consumer confidence repeatedly is cited as an implement to increased economic growth. Our ongoing rate of heightened unemployment/underemployment is noted as limiting spending expansion. Retrenchment of household debt garners support for reductions in discretionary spending by consumers. Yet some small progress has continued as noted by the BEA’s September report, eal gross domestic product — the output of goods and services produced by labor and property located in the United States — increased at an annual rate of 1.7% in the second quarter of 2012 (that is, from the first quarter to the second quarter), according to the "second" estimate released by the Bureau of Economic Analysis. In the first quarter, real GDP increased 2%. The increase in real GDP in the second quarter primarily reflected positive contributions from personal consumption expenditures (PCE), exports, non-residential fixed investment, and residential fixed investment that were partly offset by negative contributions from private inventory investment and from state and local government For information on revisions, see "Revisions to GDP, GDI, and Their Major Components." All of which leads us into our investigation of I; gross private fixed Investment the next essay of this series exploring Gross Domestic Product and its effect on the economic recovery. UNLV| September 28, 2012 Where Is the U.S. Economy Headed? Stephen P. A. Brown The growth rate of U.S. real gross domestic product (GDP) slowed from a 4.0 percent annualized rate in fourth quarter 2011 to a 2.0 percent rate in first quarter 2012 and then a 1.3 percent rate in second quarter 2012. As of second quarter 2012, U.S. real GDP remained 6.0 percent below its potential (Chart). Is economic growth likely to accelerate and close the gap with potential GDP, or is it likely to languish? To answer this question, we examine the recent course of spending in the economy and its likely course over the next few quarters. Contributions to GDP Growth In the first two quarters of 2012, much of the growth in U.S. economic activity was the result of personal consumption spending (Table, page 2). In fact, consumption spending grew at a faster rate than GDP in both quarters. In the first half of 2012, personal consumption spending accounted for 1.8 percentage points more of GDP than it did over the time period from 1995 through 2012. Table. Contributions to the Growth of U.S. Real GDP 2011 Ql 2011 Q2 2011 Q3 2011 Q4 2012 Ql 2012 Q2 Real GDP (percent change annual rate) 0.1 2.5 Contributions to Real GDP Growth Final Domestic Sales 0.59 1.93 2.32 2.21 2.29 Personal Consumption 2.22 0.70 1.18 1.45 Business Fixed Investment -0.11 1.30 1.71 0.93 Residential Investment -0.03 0.09 0.03 0.26 Government Purchases -1.49 -0.16 -0.60 -0.43 Net Exports -0.03 0.54 0.02 -0.64 0.06 0.23 Exports 0.75 0.56 0.83 0.21 0.60 0.72 Imports -0.72 -0.02 -0.81 -0.85 -0.54 -0.49 Inventory Investment -0.54 0.01 -1.07 2.53 -0.39 Note: Data are reported at seasonally adjusted annual rates. Source: U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis 1.3 4.1 1.47 1.72 0.74 0.43 -0.60 1.06 0.36 0.19 -0.14 2.0 1.3 -0.46 Overall private investment—business fixed investment, residential investment, and inventory investment—also contributed to GDP growth in the first half of 2012. Dominated by the movements in business fixed investment and inventory investment, total investment spending decelerated sharply from fourth quarter 2011 to second quarter 2012. Residential investment rose strongly from fourth quarter 2011 to first quarter 2012, but saw slower growth in second quarter 2012. The decline in total government purchases—including federal, state, and local— contributed to a slowing of GDP growth from third quarter 2010 through second quarter 2012. From first quarter 2011 through first quarter 2012, much of the decline came from the federal government. In second quarter 2012, most of the decline came from state and local government. The Necessity of a Spending Acceleration For the economy to show stronger growth, we must see an acceleration of overall spending— whether the spending comes from consumers, investors, the government, or an improved export-import balance. In the next few sections, we examine the prospects for accelerated spending in each of these categories. The Outlook for Consumption Spending Consumer spending, which excludes residential investment, accounts for about 71 percent of GDP. As such, it is the single largest component of spending. During the recession and recovery, consumer spending maintained a slightly stronger pace than overall GDP. Consumer spending didn't slip by as much as GDP during the recession, and it didn't grow by as much during the recovery. In addition, the variation in consumption spending during the recovery has contributed some of the volatility in GDP growth. As we look forward, personal consumption and retail sales show signs of strong acceleration into third quarter 2012. Surveys of consumer attitudes offer conflicting signals—with consumer sentiment rising and consumer confidence slipping. Slow employment growth certainly remains a concern for consumer spending. Combined, these indicators suggest strengthening consumption spending in third quarter with the possibility of slower growth in fourth quarter. Investment Spending Investment spending currently accounts for about 14 percent of GDP. During the recession and recovery, investment spending was much more volatile than GDP. It saw a much sharper decline and a stronger recovery. Nonetheless, investment spending was 10.6 percent lower in second quarter 2012 than it was at GDP's prerecession peak (fourth quarter 2007). The outlook for investment spending depends on the type of investment. Business fixed investment faces a number of near-term challenges from the industrial sector. Industrial production remains below its prerecession levels; industrial capacity utilization remains below its historical average; and the purchasing manager’s index is below 50. All of these factors suggest relatively little reason for strong investment spending in the industrial sector. On the other hand, private service-producing employment is relatively robust. Together, these factors suggest a continuation of moderate growth in business fixed investment spending. On the other hand, the housing market is providing evidence of strengthening residential investment Housing sales, starts, permits, and prices are on a general upward trend. The number of months of existing supply for sale in many markets also suggests a need for new construction. All these signs bode well for increasing residential investment. After a strong buildup in fourth quarter 2011, inventory drawdowns have contributed to weaker economic activity in the first two quarters of 2012. Even with strong retail sales, the inventory-to-sales ratio remains high by post-recession standards. That ratio suggests we can expect inventory investment to make small negative contributions in the remainder of 2012 before turning positive in 2013. Government Spending When federal, state, and local government purchases of goods and services are combined they currently account for about 18 percent of GDP. Over the course of the recession and recovery government spending saw slightly stronger growth than GDP. Unlike other sources of spending however, government spending increased during the recession and decreased during the recovery. In fact, overall government spending has declined for eight consecutive quarters, from third quarter 2010 through second quarter 2012. Reduced federal government spending has been an important part of reduced government spending, but state and local government spending also declined as state and local governments faced declining revenues. Looking forward, we see the potential for a sharp reduction in federal government spending as the result of the so-called fiscal cliff. Otherwise, only moderate cuts in federal government spending are likely. State government tax revenues are increasing with economic activity, and increased spending seems likely as we move forward. Local government spending is another issue. In most states, local governments rely highly on property taxes. With property taxes lagging behind property values, local governments are likely to see further reductions in revenues and face continued pressure for fiscal austerity through 2013. Net Exports U.S. net exports are currently about minus 3 percent of U.S. GDP. In the first half of 2012, the United States saw gains in net exports, with a net stimulus to GDP growth. Increases in exports more than offset increased imports. Looking forward, we can expect weakness in the European and Asian economies to weaken export growth. At the same time, however, a weak international economy will reduce the cost of U.S. oil imports. These two factors will mostly offset each other, and changes in net exports will have little effect on overall U.S. economic activity. The Overall Direction of the U.S. Economy Combining the outlooks for consumption, investment, and government spending with that for net exports, we see the likelihood of a slow improvement in the growth rate of U.S. GDP as we assess the second half of 2012 through the end of 2013. Consumer spending is showing signs of acceleration. Investment spending—particularly residential investment—is also evidencing gains. Barring a plunge off the fiscal cliff, government spending is likely to be less of a drag. Net exports can be expected to make relatively little contribution to the direction of the economy. Third quarter 2012 is shaping up to be stronger than second quarter. Fourth quarter may be a bit weaker than third. It still looks to be quite a few years before GDP closes the gap with potential GDP. ¹Service production typically requires less capital investment than manufacturing. 2 This government spending figure excludes transfer payments, which account for about 17 percent of GDP. 3 See Brown, Stephen P. A. and Kylelar P. Maravich, "Fiscal Cliff Raises Specter of U.S. Recession," Economic Commentary, Center for Business and Economic Research, University of Nevada, Las Vegas, August 24, 2012. http://cber.unlv.edu/commentary/CBER-24August2012.pdf. Stephen P. A. Brown, Ph.D. Director Center for Business and Economic Research University of Nevada, Las Vegas The Consumer: A Supporting Part or the Lead Role? For decades, the American consumer was the backbone of the economy. Buoyed by rising home values, a decrease in the savings rate and an increase in debt, consumers consistently increased their spending at a rate higher than the nation’s gross domestic product (GDP). In fact, according to the Bureau of Economic Analysis, inflation-adjusted personal consumer spending - a broad measure of consumer spending - grew at a continuously compound annual rate of 3.47 percent versus an overall inflation-adjusted GDP growth rate of 2.91 percent. While consumer spending grew to a total of 70 percent of GDP during the last decade, that increase wasn’t out of line with previous trends in the U.S. Between 1991 and 2000, consumer spending composed 67.3 percent of GDP, slightly higher than the 64.6 percent rate between 1981 and 1990. But when the global financial crisis hit in 2008, the consumer was hit hard. With rising unemployment, plummeting home equity and overall household indebtedness at all-time highs, consumers had to pull back and economic growth contracted along with that pullback (fig. 1). In the two years since the economy came out of the Great Recession, GDP growth has been tepid, in large part because consumers aren’t spending as much as they did before. Their share of GDP is stable, but since they aren’t spending as much, overall GDP growth isn’t robust. If consumers continue to constrain their spending as they pay down debt, increase their savings and attempt to make up for shrunken paychecks and retirement accounts, increases in GDP will have to be made up by other GDP components such as investment spending, net exports or government spending. In the absence of a bigger contribution to GDP from those sources - which doesn’t look likely in the near future - the decline in consumer spending is likely to have ongoing implications for the U.S. and global economies. In this month’s commentary, we’ll discuss how consumer spending has historically contributed to the U.S. economy, the pros and cons of consumer spending versus other types of spending, the factors behind the decline in consumer spending, what consumer spending and consumer confidence look like today and what economic growth might look like in the near future in an environment where consumers spend less. We’ll also discuss what this means for investors and how it might impact the markets. Impact of Consumer Spending In the last half century, consumer spending has increasingly driven U.S. economic growth. Not only has the American consumer consistently fueled economic growth, that spending has increased over the decades as other sources of traditional economic growth have declined. In fact, during the 25 years between 1982 and 2007, consumer spending grew at an annualized pace of 3.5 percent in contrast to the rest of the economy, which grew at a rate of 2.79 percent (fig. 2). Because the consumer spent so voraciously during these years, more goods and services were imported, leading to an ongoing trade deficit. Exports are another component of GDP; as consumer spending rose, the trade imbalance grew, leading to a decline in net exports. Both business investment and government expenditures – the other two components of GDP - have also fallen as consumer spending has increased, but not as dramatically as net exports. In theory, consumer spending is the same as any other component of GDP. However, economists believe that business investment is a healthier driver of economic growth than either consumer or government spending because economies that invest more grow at a faster rate. When consumer spending dominates an economy, it can tend to crowd out investment spending, ultimately impairing the economy’s ability to grow in a more sustainable manner. Federal Reserve Board research revealed that higher investment spending is associated with overall higher economic growth, while higher consumer spending is associated with lower economic growth. This holds true when analyzing short-term and long-term trends. Factors Affecting Consumer Spending A variety of factors are impacting the consumer’s ability and willingness to spend. These include the housing bust, deleveraging, high unemployment, sluggish wage growth and loss of net worth. Economists agree that the housing bust has had the largest impact on the consumer. The Fed reported that the median American home equity value fell by 42 percent in the threeyear period between 2007 and 2010 (fig. 3). Although the housing market has shown signs of recovery this year, nearly 24 percent of all mortgage borrowers owe more than their homes are worth. While those numbers are falling and more than 700,000 homeowners climbed into positive home equity in the first quarter of 2012, the amount of equity that was wiped out during the housing bust has contributed to consumers feeling poorer and wanting to deleverage further. Total household debt nearly doubled between 2000 and 2008, fueled by rising home equity. Americans took advantage of this seemingly easy source of credit, increasing total overall consumer indebtedness to $13.8 trillion. Besides home equity and mortgage debt, consumers also took on additional credit card and student loan debt. Just when indebtedness reached its peak, credit tightened, and so another source of spending power dried up. Some lenders went out of business, while others tightened credit standards so that only the most creditworthy borrowers could get loans. Credit standards for non-mortgage loans have loosened slightly since 2010, but mortgage lending standards still remain tight, according to the Fed. As far as deleveraging goes, consumers are making progress. Total household debt has fallen for 16 straight quarters, declining by 0.4 percent in the first quarter of 2012. While indebtedness is falling, the personal savings rate is climbing. It fell to less than 2 percent in 2005 and has rebounded to 3.9 percent as of May 2012 (fig. 4). While this is a positive for consumers - less debt and more savings - it isn’t encouraging for an economy dependent on consumer spending. One of the major factors contributing to a fall in consumer spending is a significant decline in household wealth since the Great Recession. According to the U.S. Federal Reserve, the inflation-adjusted net worth of the average American consumer has fallen 24 percent since 2007. This decline actually wiped out two decades of American wealth, which puts the typical consumer’s net worth back where it was in 1992. Major culprits in this decline in real wealth were the collapse of the housing market, an increase in household debt - including credit card and student loan debt - and a decline in wages. The income of the average American fell by 8 percent in 2010. Although the wage picture has stabilized in the past few years, job growth has barely kept up with population growth, and incomes are just pacing inflation. In fact, the average weekly wage of an American consumer increased just 12 cents during the five years from October 2006 to 2011. That means wages actually declined when taking inflation into consideration. The cumulative effect of these blows to the balance sheet and income statement of the American consumer is akin to a reverse wealth effect, inhibiting their ability and willingness to spend. Consumer Spending & Confidence Today Consumer spending increased at a rate of 2.5 percent in the first quarter of 2012, according to the Commerce Department’s most recent data. This is below the recent historic rate of 3.5 percent and was revised downward twice - from 2.9 to 2.7 percent, then to the most recent 2.5 percent figure. On a positive note, U.S. household net worth rose by 4.7 percent in the first quarter, fueled by a rising stock market and increases in home equity, according to the Fed. However, household wealth still remains about 5 percent below its pre-Great Recession peak. Overall, GDP increased 1.9 percent in the first quarter, down from 3 percent in the fourth quarter, hardly a robust pace. This low economic growth rate is reflected in a persistently high unemployment rate, anemic retail sales and low wage growth. In June, the economy only added 80,000 jobs, the third month in a row of weak job growth. While the unemployment rate has come down, it remains at 8.2 percent, and the economy employs nearly 5 million fewer people than it did when the recession began. As of mid-July, 12.7 Americans remain out of work and millions more have dropped out of the workforce, becoming so discouraged that they have given up looking for work. With so many Americans looking for work and so few employers hiring, there is no upward pressure on wages, so wage growth is virtually non-existent. Actually, when adjusted for inflation, hourly wages are lower than they were when the recession officially ended in June 2009 (fig. 5). Despite these discouraging signals about the job market, there are some bright spots. Unemployment claims dropped to their lowest level in four years in mid-July, and companies hired more temps in June than they had since February. The housing market has also been showing encouraging signs, with fewer foreclosures and an increase in sales, leading many economists to conclude that this vital part of the economy is finally starting to contribute to economic growth after years in the doldrums. In more good news, a large surge in the amount of credit accessed by consumers in May was a sign that financial institutions are granting more credit and that consumers may be willing to spend some of that windfall. Overall consumer credit increased at an annual rate of 8 percent, while revolving credit such as credit cards increased at a rate of 11.25 percent. Still, consumer confidence remains fragile. The Conference Board reported that its Consumer Confidence Index fell two months in a row. Consumers expressed slightly more confidence about the current economic outlook but less confidence in the short-term and long-term outlooks. The Thomson Reuters/University of Michigan Index of Consumer Sentiment also fell, with households reporting that they plan to cut back on spending. This index has fallen four straight months and in June fell to its lowest level for 2012 (fig. 6). Retail sales have reflected this sluggish mood. In early July, major retailers including Macy’s, Costco, Kohl’s and Target reported disappointing sales. The only bright spot is discount retailers, who are reporting sales increases as consumers continue to search for bargains. What to Watch For If consumer spending continues at the anemic pace it has maintained during the past year, it’s likely that GDP growth won’t accelerate. The Fed predicts that the U.S. economy will grow at an annual rate of 2.5 percent, while the International Monetary Fund is less optimistic, forecasting 2.1 percent growth through the end of this year. Neither rate is at a pace that would significantly increase employment or tempt businesses to invest or consumers to spend. The interplay of forces in the U.S. economy can be reinforcing either in a positive or negative way. For example, if consumers did significantly loosen their purse strings and spend at a more robust pace, businesses might be more willing to invest, creating more jobs. The resulting tax revenues would help local, state and federal government avoid more job cuts and benefit cuts that could negatively impact the economy, at least in the short run. The increase in jobs could further spark consumer confidence, thus increasing spending, which would have a ripple effect on business investment and government tax revenue. The reverse is also true - if consumers, businesses or the government won’t spend, the economy doesn’t have much chance of growing. To get a handle on whether the consumer is starting to spend, watch statistics such as quarterly government reports on GDP, which contain information about consumer spending. Monthly retail sales reports are also indicators of whether the consumer is in a buying mood and, if so, exactly what types of goods and services they are buying. Energy prices, if they continue to fall, are likely to provide some relief and dollars that consumers can potentially deploy into spending in other areas. Most economists believe that jobs are the key to increased consumer confidence and hence consumer spending. If the pace of job creation picks up from current low levels and unemployment claims continue to drop, employed consumers are more likely to spend because they have confidence that they will have a paycheck and the ability to stay afloat financially. The housing market is another key data point. A home is typically a consumer’s largest source of wealth. The more homes that are underwater, the poorer consumers feel and the less likely they are to spend, except where necessary. Where We Go From Here Absent an increase in consumer spending, the economy will likely continue to muddle along at a low rate of growth. Combine this with the upcoming election, the uncertain sovereign debt situation in Europe, expiring Bush tax cuts, and tax increases and budget cuts set to take effect in January, and the overall outlook isn’t too rosy. There are some positives. The election, regardless of its outcome, will resolve a lot of the uncertainty that is plaguing the markets. And new political leadership will hopefully be able to deal with the fiscal cliff issue in a politically responsible way, one that begins the difficult work of cutting the budget deficit without applying severe cuts and tax increases that could spark another recession. The gross domestic product (GDP) is the amount of goods and services produced in a year, in a country. The Great Recession refers to the 2007-2012 global recession. The Federal Reserve is the central banking system of the United States. The sevenmember Board of Governors is a federal agency charged with the overseeing the 12 District Reserve Banks and setting national monetary policy. The Conference Board is a global, independent business membership and research association working in the public interest. The Conference Board is a non-advocacy, notfor-profit entity holding 501 (c) (3) tax-exempt status in the United States. The Consumer Confidence Index is issued monthly by the Conference Board. Based on 5,000 households, it is an indicator designed to measure consumer confidence, which is defined as the degree of optimism on the state of the economy that consumers are expressing through their activities of savings and spending. The University of Michigan Consumer Sentiment Index is a consumer confidence index published monthly by the University of Michigan and Thomson Reuters. At least 500 telephone interviews are conducted each month of a United States sample. 50 core questions are asked. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) is the intergovernmental organization that oversees the global financial system by following the macroeconomic policies of its member countries, in particular those with an impact on exchange rate and the balance of payments. Consider Boshari Emmons work on the impact of the Crash on younger households and households of color. The Profitability to financial institutions of various aggressive pricing and practices regarding consumer debt and particularly sub prime consumer debt. http://www.lance-williams.com/files/22003/economic_commentary_0812.pdf http://cber.unlv.edu/commentary/CBER-28Sept2012.pdf http://www.mckinsey.com/insights/blobal_capital_markets/will_us_consumer_debt_redu ction_cripple_the_economy 92-0381 Chapter 11 Sociological Impacts of More or less Consumer Credit Our next three chapter move to the social sciences; we examine the sociological impacts of consumer credit, then economic impacts and finally we look thoughtfully at consumer behavior as it impacts whether or not to borrow and how much to borrow. Remember you are the regulator and decision maker ; you know about various kinds of consumer credit. In decided whether to regulate, if so, how and how much it is important to evaluate the consequences of more or less credit availability. So let’s start with this question. QUESTION: How do you decide the optimal amount of credit availability? And the spread of that availability? In your role as regulators/legislators, think about the benefits, risks and damages to individuals, households and society in general of the consumer lending explosions between 1980 and 2007. Please consider whether it is okay to create or to fail to take action to stop a situation when you know the situation is likely to cause failure and disruption to households and society and a reduction in class mobility. Think also about the net damage/benefit for a family that borrowed to live in a safer neighborhood, lived there for several years and lost their home to foreclosure. Now, let’s move to the Benefits to the individuals and families of the availability of more credit rather than less To the extent possible let’s separate the sociological impacts into micro and macro aspects. Of course, this is somewhat artificial and there are sociologists who feel it is dishonest and wrong, but at least for these initial purposes it may be useful. By micro I mean impacts on individuals and families and neighborhoods; by macro I mean impact on the society in general and perhaps the entire community. Examples include various aspects of credit such as risky home mortgages, credit card debt expansion and payday lending. Where is the line? What is the balance? How do we reduce the damage What if that destroys the benefits? Also we will need to break some of these issues down quintile by quintile. Particularly on the most vulnerable lower quintiles. How high must the sociological damage be in order to require regulation? Soft dollars / hard dollars What are the primary benefits to individual consumers from being able to obtain credit? Detriments? What are the primary benefits to American society from millions of consumers who have been precluded from legal borrowing being granted access to that market? Detriments? Measure the following according to benefits to individual, benefits to society Risk or damage to individual, Risk or damage to society Vacations 3 days in the Ozarks 3 months in Tahiti Buying good shoes Buying good food Attending sporting events Purchasing jewelry Lottery tickets All types of legal gambling Smoking Illegal drugs Contribution to the church Going to law school Paying for home improvements How do we measure all of this? Purchases beyond likely ability to pay Home Car Credit cards Other types of borrowing. Education How do we measure life satisfaction? How do we measure life dissatisfaction or distress? What does life satisfaction lead to? Micro and macro What does dissatisfaction with life lead to? Micro and macro Does over indebtedness cause illness? Does it led to deterioration in mental health? Does it cause family disruption or violence? What can we document and how? What do we know? Quote from ?? Other families, long denied the benefits of homeownership, found opportunities to purchase homes using loans with few underwriting standards and onerous terms. Subprime lenders exploited the economic vulnerability of these marginalized families, a vulnerability created by the policies of neoliberalism as well as the legacy of rec ism and sexism inextricably intertwined with US capitalism. This side of the story of the subprime boom and bust must be excavated to prevent increasing financial exclusion of marginalized families, which is best fought with attention to labor and housing condition and the challenges faced by different family groupings on the basis of their race and gender configurations. How do we define a society – happiness quotient. Freedom from various harms Discussion Questions: What are the detriments of increased consumer borrowing. DETRIMENTS OR RISKS Illness Mental illness Harmful conduct Foreclosure Cost to society What is the relationship, if any between overindebtedness and class mobility What is the relationship, if any between subprime borrowing and minority groups? To what extent, if any is the pernicious effect of culture of advertising and survival needs combine to overload low income consumers with debt ? Please read: http://www.moneyadvicetrust.org/images/DebtMentalHealthWhatDoWeKnow(FINAL).pdf Please consider these issues and questions as you read the article that follows: The drivers of consumption and the policy makers supporting them created a condition in which high levels of consumer debt became necessary to sustain and support the growth and transformation of the financial markets? What is the effect of credit availability upon class mobility? Overindebtedness reinforces existing class divisions and thwarts class mobility The effects of reduced economic mobility The effect of catching up and then falling back. If credit is the only resource available then it will be accessed, whatever the cost. Excerpts from The Consumer Debt Crisis and the Reinforcement of Class Position By Lois R. Lupica* Credit: “1526 . . . from pp. of credere ‘to trust, entrust, believe.’” I. INTRODUCTION Consumers are indebted to a degree never before seen in history. While consumer over-indebtedness has been many years in the making, only recently has this crisis attracted widespread public attention. The precipitous collapse of iconic financial institutions and the corresponding seizure of the financial markets in the United States, for the first time, have drawn widespread public attention to the operation of the financial system and its connection to and relationship with consumer debt. This public attention has resulted in initiatives launched in various directions to identify the “causes” of the debt crisis in an effort to develop effective solutions. Intense scrutiny has uncovered a multitude of structural and cultural causes of consumer overindebtedness, with a focus on consumer behavior, lender practices, market incentives, and the public and private policies sustaining them. For example, shifts in consumptive norms, erosion of the value of frugality and long-term savings, financial ignorance and illiteracy, faulty judgment, and an increasing tolerance toward debt have all been identified as consumer- driven causes of over-indebtedness. . An appraisal of these “causes” offers a chilling picture of how we got to this point of crisis. Limiting consideration to these apparent and obvious causes of over-indebtedness, however, results in an incomplete picture. A comprehensive map sketching the full measure of factors contributing to the collapse of consumers’ “debt-supported house of cards” reveals that the fundamental underlying cause of the consumer debt crisis is found in the incentives that have shaped the very structure of the consumer marketplace. The drivers of consumption and the policy-makers supporting them created a condition, opportunistically or deliberately, in which high levels of consumer debt became necessary to sustain and support the growth and transformation of the financial markets. The markets affirmatively, aggressively, and insistently encouraged an ever-more rapid and high-risk consumer lending and borrowing cycle, which in turn both fueled and was fueled by ever- increasing levels of consumption and debt. Consumers acquiesced to the efforts made to persuade them to buy and borrow more. Over the past few decades, these dynamics became the established order, thus resulting in widespread consumer overindebtedness. And yet the virtually unregulated financial market has, until recently, operated with unquestioned legitimacy and invincibility. Against the backdrop of a reordered and globalized economy, the past decades have seen financial wizardry transform simple consumer credit transactions into complex securitized and collateralized debt instruments and their derivatives—all conducted with little regulation, public scrutiny, or criticism. Driven by fee income and high yields and unburdened by regulatory oversight, originators, investors and participants at every level of the consumer-borrowing-andlending chain yielded to the incentives to alter the way the consumer lending and financial markets operate. By creating a self-reinforcing supply and demand cycle, investment banks and other participants in the securitized debt market have, opportunistically or deliberately, encouraged retail lenders to make a high number of risky loans to a broader array of consumers, which has created a seemingly insatiable demand for the sale of this consumer debt in the public markets. Such high levels of debt have adversely impacted countless consumers’ lives, compounding existing social, economic, and political inequalities, and threatening opportunities for mobility and advancement. Debt has frustrated the chances for countless Americans to exercise social, economic, and political power. It is this power— to make choices, to realize opportunities, to be heard and to have realistic hope for a future that is better than the past—that is at the core of our ostensibly mobile and open society. Simply put, over- indebtedness reinforces existing class divisions and thwarts class mobility. Few concepts have been as fundamental to the study of cultural, sociological, political, and economic forces as “class.” The role of class analysis in the development of social and economic theory and even its continued relevance, however, remain contested. Some believe that viewing social and economic policies and resulting structures through the lens of class is irrelevant, or at the very least, passé. Yet others believe a study of class dynamics is essential to understanding public and private policies that “make for inequality of a normatively troubling kind.” This Article argues that in light of the magnitude of the crisis and the fragmented approach with which solutions have been offered to date, a broader examination of the relationship between factors, policies, and practices that have caused the crisis—essentially an examination of the factors that impact class creation, reinforcement, and mobility—becomes ever more essential. The study of public and private policies and their impact on class mobility is closely aligned with the issue of the appropriate relationship between government and the marketplace. Over the past twenty years, the economy has, in a very real sense, been reordered. The deregulatory efforts of recent years have opened up new opportunities for many participants in the financial markets. This shifting landscape has also resulted, however, in new disquiet and uncertainty, with initial unease evolving into fundamental questions about the risk and even the legitimacy of essentially unregulated markets. Particularly in light of the remote relationship between consumer borrowers and their ultimate lenders, coupled with the credit market’s information asymmetries, the public’s confidence in the unregulated markets in which consumer credit transactions take place has been called into question. This Article critically examines the public and private policies and practices that have contributed to consumer over-indebtedness and discusses the relationship of these policies to class creation, reinforcement, and mobility. It also explores the extent to which these public and private policy decisions have acquiesced to and facilitated the debt crisis and how this attendant impact on class mobility can be justified. Part II explains the various conceptions of class recognized in the United States and outlines a working definition of the factors that mark one’s class position. Part III analyzes the multi-pronged origins of the current consumer debt crisis and also describes the relationship between the insidious hegemonic forces that have aligned and thus contributed to current day strengthening of class divisions and thwarted mobility. Part III further discusses the role debt plays in the lives of low-means consumers. Part IV describes the class-related effects of over-indebtedness.38 Because the public trust in the credit markets has been eroded, and in light of the market’s negative externalities, Part IV argues that broad-spectrum intervention and oversight is needed. Finally, this Article concludes in Part V by arguing that understanding the causes of consumer over-indebtedness and its impact on class mobility and opportunity is essential to the question of whether existing policies and practices supporting this system are defensible. II. AN APPROACH TO CLASS ANALYSIS Mapping the contours of class divisions in the United States is a “culturally complex process,” and one that is often met with resistance. Confounding attempts to explain the class impact of a given public policy is the ahistoric effort to deny that an identifiable class structure even exists. The media, politicians, and Americans’ general optimism about prospect and advancement rebuff the public recognition of class divisions in favor of the boundless opportunity myth. Pursuant to this myth, reliance on a class-based conceptual framework to explain differences between groups suggests acceptance of a permanence of one’s relative position along the hierarchy. Interestingly, while Americans balk at viewing social and economic hierarchies as classbased, we have an inherent cultural tolerance for high levels of inequality.47 The corollary that balances this tolerance, however, is a deeply held belief in unlimited prospect and opportunity. As such, to overtly acknowledge class distinctions and to identify and analyze the forces that affect class creation, reinforcement, and mobility is deemed by some to be an untenable concession that opportunity and advancement may not be available to everyone. It is this ideological commitment to opportunity and advancement that makes the analysis of public and private policies’ impact on class so critical. Engaging in class analysis in a specific contextual realm not only affords an opportunity to examine policy decisions and how they are operationalized, but also allows for the normative evaluation of such policies. Answering the question of how and to what extent given public and private policies adversely affect material standards of living and inequalities in life chances not only aids in our understanding of these policies, but also enables us to think expansively about the types of transformation that can ameliorate or eliminate them. The starting point in any class analysis is identification of the common elements that contribute to the constitution of a class. For purposes of this Article, having access to similar levels of rent-seeking assets, or wealth, is identified as the essential core element members of a class hold in common. Wealth is defined, however, in a broad conceptual way to include not only the typical capital-related markers, but also common social, cultural, and political conditions that arise as a consequence of the accumulation of assets, including human capital. These conditions, taken as a whole, are tied directly to the capacity of a class to exercise social, economic, and political power, and to commensurate restraints on such power. This power and these constraints enable each class to flourish, as well as navigate and endure societal exigencies, with a collective degree of capacity, autonomy, and legitimacy. Correspondingly, social, economic, and political opportunity allow persons within a class to move to a higher rung and enjoy a more expansive choice of resource allocation and greater degree of control over their lives. To illustrate, to be a member of a “lower class” may mean one has diminished economic stability, fewer resources with which to resist coercive influences, a greater susceptibility to market temptation, and less confidence that hard work will lead to opportunity and transformation for current and future generations. Accordingly, conditions creating opportunity and mobility would enable a person to move from this “lower class” to a higher one within which he or she would have more financial, social, and cultural capital and a commensurately greater degree of autonomy and power. III. THE “CAUSES” OF THE CONSUMER DEBT CRISIS A. The Creation of Wants 2. The Rise of the Consumer Credit Industry: Deregulation and Credit’s Democratization The past decades’ expansion of a culture increasingly marked by consumerism has been tracked by the parallel transformation of the consumer credit markets; consumer credit has played a substantial role in enabling much of the increased cultural emphasis on consumption. As retailers of goods, services, and entertainment began to actively engage in the aggressive and insistent encouragement of consumers to “consume more than they intend and perhaps more than they can afford,” credit providers facilitated these purchases, by “democratizing” the availability of credit. The transformation of the consumer credit industry, however was an incremental process and the market, as it exists in the United States today, did not develop in a social and moral vacuum: the market has shaped and has been shaped by the values of the industry and its constituent communities. Its evolutionary development has been punctuated by deliberate strategic decision-making by both industry leaders and policymakers. Major policy shifts first began following the Great Depression of the 1930s. At that time, the government’s fiscal plan was focused upon stimulating economic growth and one central target of this focus was consumer credit. Government loan guarantees and other regulatory structures were put into place to create a market for consumer lending. When the revolving charge card was introduced in the early years following WWII, its debut marked a pivotal and strategic turning point in the consumer credit market. Timed to take advantage of the expanding economy, the credit card industry’s initial business model focused upon the pursuit of economies of scale: increasing the number of credit card holders, while at the same time maximizing the number of merchants who accepted credit cards as a form of payment. Credit card lenders at this time, however, took a comparatively conservative approach to lending: fixed interest rate loans marketed to borrowers deemed creditworthy, judged according to strict underwriting standards. Aided by technological advances, national banking networks emerged in the ensuing boom years, presenting the need to expand customer markets to maintain profitability. Banks’ marketing methods became more targeted and aggressive: the first mass-mailing credit card solicitation resulted in millions of new customers, although largely confined to consumers with consistent records of reliable credit repayment. Regulatory restrictions in the form of interest rate caps, however, kept strict limits on credit card issuers’ potential for profitability. It was not until the 1970s that regulatory, technological, and competitive forces aligned, forever altering the fundamental structure of the consumer credit industry. The most significant rule change arose out of the Supreme Court’s 1978 decision in Marquette National Bank of Minneapolis v. First of Omaha Service Corp. This decision had the effect of removing barriers to the consumer credit industry’s growth by allowing banks to move their credit card headquarters to states with high usury caps. Banks were thus able to raise interest rates on consumer credit by expanding their operations beyond state borders. The Marquette decision was followed over the next decade by the enactment of numerous laws further deregulating the consumer credit industry. Despite a largely unregulated environment, banks issued comparatively conservative credit products until as recently as the late 1980s. For example, most credit cards continued to offer fixed interest rates, charged annual fees, and were marketed to borrowers with strong credit histories. It was not until the early 1990s that the consumer banking industry found the good-credit-risk market close to saturated. New entrants into the consumer credit supply market, including pay day lenders, rent-to-own centers, and other non-bank lenders, put increasing pressure on traditional banks to increase their market share in order to maintain profitability. The proliferation of the high-cost non-bank lenders began at the same time the traditional banking industry was becoming increasingly consolidated. In response to these competitive pressures, banks’ card issuers took measures to expand their target markets to include less affluent households. Citicorp credit card division’s decision to alter its business model is reflective of industry practice at that time: After increasing the finance charges on its credit cards, Citicorp sought to expand the social frontiers of its credit card portfolio by soliciting lower-income households. This was an important marketing shift because the early focus on more affluent, middle-class households produced large numbers of unprofitable, albeit low-risk, convenience users. Bankers had hoped that a larger proportion of these cardholders would revolve a portion of these purchases or occasionally forget to pay their credit card bills. Instead, they soon realized that they were stuck with costly deadbeat clients, who zealously paid off their charges within the specified grace period. As inflation rates climbed to double digits, the architects of [this business model] encountered a crucial institutional crossroads: continue losing even more money on large numbers of low-risk, middle-class clients or increase their lending to higher-risk, lower-income households that previously had been avoided. Credit card issuers further sought to increase profits by raising interest rates and charging higher fees and penalties following the Supreme Court’s decision in Smiley v. Citibank. The Court held that late payment, over-limit, cash advance, returned check, membership, and other fees fell within the definition of “interest”—making their proliferation, as well as industry profits, virtually unhindered by regulation. The consumer credit industry has continued to modify its business model and marketing practices with the persistent goal of expanding demand and increasing profits. In addition, the credit products currently offered more widely are far more expensive than they were twenty years ago and “[the credit card industry] has shifted from a lending and underwriting paradigm to a sales paradigm; penalties, fees, and default interest at rates that were illegal a generation ago are no longer regrettable outcomes to be avoided but central to the business model.” Credit cards have become as ubiquitous as cash and are used ever- more commonly. According to the Federal Reserve, Americans are now carrying $943.5 billion in revolving credit card debt, up 6.8% from a year ago: [B]etween 1989 and 2001: Credit card debt among very low-income families grew by an astonishing 184 percent. But middle-class families were also hit hard—their credit card debt rose by 75 percent. Very low-income families are most likely to be in credit card debt: 67 percent of cardholding families with incomes below $10,000 are affected. Moderate-income families are not far behind: 62 percent of families earning between $25,000 and $50,000 suffer from credit card debt. Moreover, in the first quarter of 2008, consumers financing the purchase of a new car through an auto finance company had an average outstanding balance of $28,174, with a loan-to-value ratio of 94% and maturity of 62.6 months.140 In 2003, mortgage originations and refinancings hit a decade high, with $3.802 trillion of housing-backed loans made. These high debt levels have been incurred at a time where household savings levels are at an all-time low, leaving many without a safety net in the event of an unexpected expense or interruption in income. Enormous pressure has been brought to bear on consumers to buy instead of save, and to borrow, rather than wait. A similar culture of free borrowing has been encouraged by the mortgage banking industry. Aided by rising real estate values, consumers have taken advantage of the mortgage market’s liquidity, borrowing against their homes to a greater degree than before seen in history. Seemingly under the impression that the market’s rising valuations would continue forever, liberal mortgage underwriting, low introductory variable rate products, and low- and no-documentation loans with high loan-to-value ratios led many consumers to buy more house than they could afford and carry larger mortgages than could be repaid. The present day escalation in the number of housing foreclosures - the very issue that brought public attention to the crisis of consumer over-indebtedness—is a consequence of the normalization of lax underwriting, overly optimistic value projections, the conversion of unsecured debt into home-secured debt, and the lure of low introductory rates for adjustable rate mortgages, as well as the escalation of subprime and predatory lending. .The credit industry has created this pressure and knows where consumers’ social, economic, and psychological vulnerabilities lie. It knows that consumers tend to discount the long- and short-term consequences of credit use, due to the temporal disconnect between the charge and receipt of a bill. This discounting and underestimation extends to a number of features of credit use, including present and future balances, the importance of interest rates, the likelihood of a late payment, the speed at which interest accrues,152 the implications of merely making the minimum payment due; as well as the likelihood of exceeding credit limits, and credit products have been designed to opportunistically exploit these susceptibilities. As observed: The adverse [sic] consequences for using credit cards is abstract (i.e., a printed bank statement) and delayed, and thus is likely to have less of an impact on behavior. High interest rates and penalties are present when payments are delinquent, often making it difficult to reduce the total amount of debt for individuals who do make payments. Thus, although not inevitable, credit cards allow for disadvantageous allocation of funds by allowing immediate impulsive purchasing at high long-term cost. Simply put, the credit industry knows that the classic economic model of the rational market actor does not prove to be an accurate description of consumer behavior in practice. Moreover, the “consumer protection” regulatory model currently in place is premised on the concepts of disclosure and private enforcement. With few meaningful limits placed on the cost of credit, disclosure has proven to offer little consumer protection; the display of onerous credit terms in the context of aggressive marketing has not corrected the information asymmetries in access to information that characterize the consumer lending market. Moreover, with recourse for abuses available only on the basis of individual consumer transactions rather than on systemic flaws in the operation of the market itself, consumers with relatively small claims and truncated access to information are excluded from regulatory protections. Myriad reported cases have illuminated the barriers consumers face in seeking a remedy for harms caused by creditor behavior or industry practices. Defending consumers’ affirmative responses to offers of credit as part of the supply and demand cycle places the risk of loss solely and squarely on consumers. Thus, it is not surprising that consumer financiers, in accounting for consumers’ systematic biases, have reported record profits in recent years—profits which have been directly correlated to record levels of consumer over-indebtedness. B. Needs Financed by Debt The tension between the desire and resistance to consume is felt by consumers at all levels of the class spectrum. Among consumers in poverty, however, this tension creates an even greater pull: studies have demonstrated that consumers often buy things to “compensate for worries and doubts about their self-worth, their ability to cope effectively with challenges, and their safety in a relatively unpredictable world.” The world is a far less predictable place for people lacking resources. Economic and social stability is compromised, as is the ability to hope and plan for the future. Consumption can act as a salve, a way of feeling as if one has a degree of control over a world that too often feels out of control. When debt is used in an attempt to escape extreme financial exigency, however, consumers are seeking more than a mere salve. In such circumstances, consumers are not primarily concerned with emotional comfort, the satisfaction of material desires, or the creation of an identity; they are concerned with the basics of survival. The prescription has to get filled, groceries have to be bought, the baby needs a crib, and the car needs gas—today. If credit is the only resource available, failing sufficient income, assets or public assistance, it is accessed—whatever its cost. Lower-wealth consumers are caught in a vise: wedged between desiring the material goods that have become part of the American identity, and needing to use credit for fundamental subsistence. The decline in real wages, particularly in the service sector, coupled with increases in part-time employment and layoffs have meant that workers’ relationships with their employers have become progressively more tenuous. Jobs are less likely to offer health insurance or long-term wage and retirement security than they were in decades past.Moreover, an estimated twelve million renter and homeowner households now pay more than fifty percent of their annual incomes for housing, and a family with one full-time worker earning the minimum wage cannot afford the local fair-market rent for a two-bedroom apartment anywhere in the United States. The dearth of affordable housing presents a significant hardship for low-income households, preventing them from meeting their other basic needs, such as nutrition and healthcare, or saving for their future. The spike in the price of gasoline has had an enormous impact on poor families, many of whom own older, less efficient vehicles. When unexpected expenses arise, many families are forced to “dissave” (withdraw savings, sell assets, or borrow) to meet their obligations. With few assets, the vast segment left out of the so- called “ownership society”179 has strained to bridge the divide between income and expenses. In the absence of savings, a living wage or public assistance, credit becomes what enables many families to survive. At the time the traditional credit industry relaxed its underwriting standards and made credit more widely available, it also created new credit products tailored for the lowincome consumer. The credit aggressively offered to low-income and low-means consumers is categorically different than that used by middle-class consumers. These products have higher interest and fee rates, more onerous terms, and are designed for long-term borrowing, rather than convenience use. Easy access to this credit has significantly contributed to high consumer debt levels. In addition to credit issued by the traditional banking sector, an entire sector of the credit industry has emerged in recent decades specifically designed to serve the “need borrower.” Known colloquially as “fringe bankers, ”these lenders offer credit to augment other lending sources. Marked by convenience of location, lax underwriting, and high interest rates, these lenders have identified their target market as those consumers who need credit for the basics of subsistence. Lower-income homeowners are also vulnerable to predatory mortgage lenders, who offer easy but expensive money to purchase homes, pay property taxes, make home repairs, and pay other household expenses. These predatory loans are distinguished by high interest rates, unnecessary fees, risky terms,and low- to no-credit underwriting standards.192 Like other post-credit democratization credit offers, these loans are distinguished by information asymmetries and consumer manipulation in the loan origination process.193Not surprisingly,the incidence of home foreclosures in the subprime market over the past eighteen months has reached record highs. It is projected that one in five subprime mortgage loans made in 2005–2006 will end in foreclosure, which means that over two million families will lose their homes in the next few years. The equity that will be lost through these foreclosures is projected to be in excess of $160 billion. The classical economic argument that consumers as self-determined agents reap benefits from markets that are free of regulatory constraints does not hold for consumers driven to borrow by coercion and need. As observed: Agency does not [allow for] choice for individuals who are powerless. What it does represent is a perpetual marginality. Contrary to notions of agency, individuals have little power to make sustaining transformations when the underlying structure is flawed. . . . Hierarchical decision-making results in policies and laws that exclude the group of persons who are powerless to oppose those laws and policies that are not in their best interests. Borrowers who are driven by need, however, know that payday lenders are exploiting them, that credit cards are a trap, and that rent-to- own stores are a rip-off, but in the face of such dire need, the price of credit and the effects of indebtedness become irrelevant. In the absence of alternatives, these borrowers do not have the luxury to meaningfully consider the long-term consequences of incurring high priced debt. C. The Secondary Market for Consumer Credit Driven by commercial and investment bankers, speculators, traders, lawyers, accountants, investors, and other participants, the financial markets have experienced a massive transformation in virtually every respect over the past decade and a half. Advanced information systems have led to the invention of innovative investment products, including complex securitized assets and their derivatives, backed by mortgage-related loans and other consumer credit receivables Unprecedented economic growth has enabled the utilization of new technologies and opened myriad new markets and opportunities. The invention of these securitized and derivative products has allowed both financiers and investors to hedge market and currency risk, further enabling the meeting of financial institutions’ goals of borrowing cheaply, transferring and diversifying risk, accessing new sources of capital, and taking advantages of economies of scale. Such market innovations have also fundamentally altered long-held retail consumer lending policies and practices.For example, lenders’ compensation models shifted in response to changes in risk exposure; once the risk is removed from the loan originator’s balance sheet via the securitization transfer, lenders are incentivized to focus on the volume of loan originations, not necessarily the quality or default risk of each loan. This led to the implementation of numerous measures designed to expand the consumer borrowing base and to increase both consumption and consumer borrowing. Accordingly, consumer credit, including credit cards, became more widely and aggressively marketed, and home purchase loans, refinancings, and equity lines of credit became increasingly and insistently promoted to ever-riskier borrowers. Many of the mortgage loans currently in default were written in compliance with industry and “market sanctioned underwriting guidelines”— notwithstanding the fact that they were no- document, 100% loan-to-value ratio loans. With the risk of consumer default shifting to investors in the secondary market, the potential for lost accountability on the part of front-line lenders arose, resulting in an agency problem. The strategy to both expand consumption and borrowing and transform these loans into low-risk, high yield securities has also resulted, until recently, in the banking industry’s booking unprecedented profits in recent years. While minimizing risk and making money is what the banking industry does—with rewards meted out based on who does this best— with escalating profits comes the risk of complacency. As a result of this complacency, originators, investors, rating agencies, insurers, lawyers, accountants, and regulators failed to recognize some of securitization’s fault lines and failings in its market’s operation. A central failing of the market is directly tied to the “too-clever-by- half”structure of many of these transactions: few investors and other participants in the market truly understood these transactions, the nature of the investments being sold, or how to evaluate the quality and value of the underlying assets. Appreciating and accurately valuing the assets supporting asset- backed securities (ABS) is fundamental to structured finance. In the absence of a precise understanding and valuation of a securitized asset, the exercise in arbitrage fails, and the credit rating ends up being based upon a misunderstanding that in turn determines the faulty ABS’s pricing. This has the potential to further lead to failings in the fundamental structuring of transactions, with, for example, senior tranches’ fallibility far greater than their rating (and pricing) suggests. Originators, bond insurers, investors, and rating agencies all got caught up in the exuberance of this re-imagined market The rapidity with which the market moved, the long runs of high yields, and the complexity of the investments led to overdependence on rating agencies to evaluate risk. Rating agencies, in relying upon originators to pay their fees, were faced with conflicting loyalties. Moreover, it has been exposed, with the benefit of hindsight, that rating agencies relied upon financial models that were alternately based on incomplete and dated assumptions about asset value and performance. Investors blindly accepted the rating agencies’ assessments and substituted the agencies’ evaluations as a proxy for their own diligence. The confluence of these market failings has resulted in what has alternately been described as a “credit crisis,” a “melt-down” and even a “conflagration,” leading to the quest for answers to the questions of what, how, and why things went so wrong. When viewed in hindsight, however, it is just these factors—“the collective misjudgment of risk; a zealous search for yield; and the failure of oversight”—that constitute the foundation of this market’s current failure. Paradoxically, however, it is the very same factors—a willingness to bear extraordinary market risk in exchange for high return, without the burden of regulatory constraints—that were the central reasons for the market’s success. IV. THE CLASS-IMPACT OF CURRENT DAY CREDIT POLICY: THE “EFFECTS” OF OVER-INDEBTEDNESS AND A FRAMEWORK FOR OVERSIGHT The connection between consumer over-indebtedness, the disruptions in the financial markets, and the adverse impact the debt crisis has had on consumers’ lives has finally been recognized, sparking much heated public and private discussion about how to “solve the problem.” As part of the effort to find effective solutions, a host of proposals have recently been put forth by scholars, journalists, legislators, and the credit industry, primarily focusing on remedies at the consumer borrowing and lending level. These proposals include (i) greater scrutiny of sub- prime mortgage loans and the curtailment of predatory mortgage lending, (ii) the imposition of substantive restrictions on the price and terms of credit, (iii) voluntary changes in the credit card industry’sbusiness practices, (iv) adjustments to the Bankruptcy Code, (v) governmental refinancing of mortgage loans, (vi) the prohibition of mandatory arbitration provisions in consumer loan contracts, and (vii) early financial literacy education for consumers. The events of late 2008, including the demise and near-demise of iconic investment banks, the breakdown of Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac and the American Insurance Group (AIG), the unprecedented volatility in the stock market,and corresponding freeze in the credit markets have all resulted in additional enactments and proposals designed to “fix” the damaged credit markets. The government takeover of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the infusion of over $250 billion from the United States Treasury into American banks, the “bailout” of AIG, the commercial paper back-stop program, and the proposal to expand the reach of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation are now being trumpeted as the way out of this crisis. While, to varying degrees, each one of these ideas has merit, in the absence of a broadbased comprehensive plan to address past harms to consumers, coupled with a wideranging strategy for ensuring that a crisis of the present magnitude does not happen again, these proposals being sold as “solutions” ring hollow. They will have nothing more than a palliative effect because they fail to reflect a full recognition of the essential problem at the foundation of the crisis: that the fundamental underlying cause of the consumer debt crisis is found in the incentives that have shaped the very structure of the consumer and credit marketplaces. Consumer debt provided the fuel for the explosion of the markets for consumer goods, services, and credit. Debt became necessary to sustain the markets’ very existence, and thus widespread incentives to increase consumer debt levels emerged. Accordingly, without an alteration of market incentives and a major re- tooling of expectations at every level, the problem will not be solved and the current crisis will repeat itself. At a minimum, greater public oversight of credit transactions at every level is necessary to address many of the debt crisis’s causes and effects. The thorny issue, however, is the nature and degree of such oversight. The concern, of course, is that greater regulation of the consumer credit markets will adversely impact the lives of consumers, particularly financially marginal consumers, by limiting or cutting off a source of needed funds. For all of the harms that flow from easy credit access, credit serves a very important function: it acts as a private safety net, often necessary for short and long-term well being. As noted, in many circumstances, credit is needed to navigate financial hardships and cash- flow interruptions. Particularly for consumers with lesser means, credit can be and is used when food stamp or other public assistance payments are interrupted, upon threats of, or actual eviction, when the car breaks down, and at times of disruption of health care coverage. Moreover, one of the oft-cited benefits of access to credit, particularly in the form of credit cards, is the private nature of the loan. Unlike emergency public assistance, no “criteria of need” must be met, nor must the nature of the emergency be disclosed. Credit card transactions are private and anonymous, void of any stigma at the point of borrowing or purchase. Needed funds can be obtained immediately, without any bureaucratic delay or obstacle. Furthermore, credit cards have become essential for many transactions common to consumers of all classes. Necessary to rent a car, check into a motel, rent a video, and make on-line purchases, in their absence, many opportunities that fall both in the “needs” and “wants” categories are foreclosed. Particularly for low-means consumers without access to a full range of traditional banking services, curtailing access to credit may cause those already marginalized to “fall further out of the mainstream.” With respect to mortgage-related credit, without its reasonable availability, it would not be possible for many to purchase a home. Many studies document the individual and community benefits of home ownership, including its encouragement of family stability and responsibility. Additionally, as the largest asset held by most families, homeownership has a direct impact upon inter-generational wealth transfers. Without a doubt, credit has become an essential part of the consumer economy and is relied upon by many as both a convenience and a necessity. But with increasingly creative and complex credit transactions taking place in a virtually unregulated environment, the fallacy that the transformed and liberalized market offers more good than harm to consumers has been exposed. As noted: Of course, [market] liberalizing measures were pursued in the belief that they would generate positive effects. Classical economic philosophy holds that the liberalization of market activity will increase both national and international efficiency. Because efficiency maximizes wealth creation, such policies could also be said to maximize social welfare. To equate social welfare with aggregate social wealth, however, is to adopt only one of a number of potential measures of social welfare. Even if one ignores measures of welfare not related to wealth, the equation of social welfare with national wealth overlooks distributive concerns. Indeed, efficiency-increasing measures such as economic liberalization may exacerbate preexisting distributive inequalities. Classical economic measures of efficiency and welfare are simply “indifferent to the distribution of income and wealth. The past months have exposed not simply credit market inefficiencies, but credit market dysfunction of the highest order. Notwithstanding the magnitude of the crisis, however, any regulatory proposals will be greeted with resistance: a classic response to any new regulatory proposal is the cry of “the sky is falling,” and in this context, the cry will be, “credit will dry up.” Studies have demonstrated, however, that regulation does not always and necessarily have such anticipated and predicted effects. For example, when the United States Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit announced a new rule limiting the terms pursuant to which nonbankruptcy mortgage foreclosures would be allowable, immediate predictions that this rule would shut down the consumer home mortgage market were made. Pundits called for an emergency statutory amendment that would, in essence, repeal the rule. In the interim, however, when there was no such repealing legislation, the market adjusted and the home lending market, both pre- and post-rule, was unaffected. The popular wisdom associated with the enactment of Sarbanes- Oxley Act provides a more recent example of an overstated prediction of the impact of a regulatory scheme. As noted in a recent article: It has become received wisdom on Wall Street that the Sarbanes- Oxley Act has damaged American competitiveness. It made listing in the American market less attractive to foreign companies and drove initial public offerings overseas. It raised costs for American companies without providing any significant benefit. A new study, however, found that among the sample of foreign companies studied, the wisdom that greater regulation adversely impacted a firm’s performance turned out to be false: those firms with good growth prospects suffered a decline in stock price upon leaving the American markets in an effort to avoid the reach of Sarbanes-Oxley. Sarbanes-Oxley was enacted largely in response to a crisis of confidence in the public markets. We are currently seeing a similar erosion of confidence in the credit markets at every level. The financial markets’ imperfections have created rents that have been captured by creditors and related parties at the expense of consumers. The shift of these rents has adversely affected consumers’ market choices, as well as “economic opportunities and the investments that maximize these opportunities.” Thwarted opportunities and extreme imbalances in information and power destabilize the legitimacy that a market-oriented system demands. Markets gain legitimacy from the public’s trust, and when such trust is undermined, intervention becomes necessary. Economic growth and profits drove the design of the financial system, and in light of the markets’ externalities, limits on the design must be crafted. As a threshold matter, a number of fundamental measures must be put in place to alter the incentives driving the participants in the financial markets. Higher capital requirements must be imposed upon banks, in light of the revealed inadequacy of the levels currently required. Greater retained capital will go a long way toward ensuring greater stability among lenders. Second, securitizing originators must be required to retain a significant portion of the securities they originate. In this way, credit underwriting risk is shared, and not simply transferred. Moreover, pricing models for mortgage-backed securities must reflect the market reality that real estate values cyclically fall—as well as rise. Disclosure and oversight of derivative transactions, including credit default swaps, must be regulated under federal securities laws, not simply by state law insurance statutes, if at all. Additionally, credit rating agencies’ role in the markets must be dramatically re-imagined. With their “reputational capital” dissipated, they must labor to regain their credibility by, at a minimum, erasing any potential for the appearance of or actual conflicts of interest. Ultimately, because the collapse of the financial markets has demonstrated that faulty and inadequate pricing and risk assessment holds the potential for catastrophic and wide-ranging thirdparty effects, regulation must require that the transaction parties bear the financial consequences for their misjudgment. This pervasive misjudgment among the players in the borrowing- lending-sellinginvesting cycle has impacted consumers’ lives with the force of a hurricane.272 In the absence of adequate income, assets, or public financial safety net to meet basic needs, consumers have accessed the credit markets. While ensnared in the cycle of indebtedness, many families have been forced into a position of further reliance upon ever-more debt. At the point where a consumer’s liabilities eclipse his or her assets, the indicators of upward class mobility—economic equilibrium and stability, the ability to enhance human capital in order to specialize, the wherewithal to take risks and have a positive vision of the future, as well as the capacity to offer future generations greater opportunities—correspondingly disappear. By sanctioning levels of indebtedness beyond consumers’ ability to repay, these policies have shifted the risk of loss from the financial industry to the consumer. This risk shift and corresponding losses have resulted in skewed allocations of social, economic, and political power at the macro level and autonomy at the micro level. Moreover, these losses have directly foreclosed many consumers’ opportunities for future asset accumulation and wealth, thus making transformations difficult to effectuate and sustain. It is the accumulation of assets—both intra and inter-generationally—that results in fluid opportunity and class mobility. Furthermore: [A]ssets have a variety of important social, psychological, and economic effects. Simply put, people think and behave differently when they are accumulating assets, and the world responds to them differently as well. More specifically, assets improve economic stability; connect people with a viable, hopeful future; stimulate development of human and other capital; enable people to focus and specialize; provide a foundation for risk taking; yield personal, social, and political dividends; and enhance the welfare of offspring. At the most fundamental level, class positioning is reflective of wealth: “the inherited accumulation of property, competencies, beliefs, tastes, and manners that determines, for most of us, our socioeconomic lot and our share of civic power.” While wealth is keyed to class position, “the distribution of opportunity follows that of wealth.” In addition, “[w]hen too many economic resources are held by too few, when the benefits of growth elude broad swaths of working families, opportunity itself becomes a rare commodity, out of the reach of the majority. Too much inequality precludes a meritocracy.” The idea that America is a meritocracy lies at the foundation of our society. Inequality is tolerated so long as hard work will result in the improvement of one’s location along the class continuum. Paradoxically, as citizens and consumers, we claim to believe in the importance of opportunity and mobility, but at the same time we have acquiesced to the public and private policies that have foreclosed them. V. CONCLUSION Over the past decades, consumer spending and corresponding indebtedness have provided the central source of fuel for the country’s economic growth: as a collective resource, consumers have been the chief target of exploitation by the providers of goods, services, and credit. The enormous investments made in the creation and maintenance of the transformed consumer markets have driven this exploitation. As the supporters of the policies behind the markets’ transformation began to affirmatively recognize that high levels of consumer debt were necessary to sustain the markets’ unprecedented profitability, a relentless campaign was waged to convince, cajole, and coerce consumers to build their lives around consumption through the routine use of credit. The hegemony of the markets has proven to be a powerful force, inexorably altering cultural norms, consumer behaviors, and attitudes toward debt. The forces that have created this condition must be acknowledged before steps can be taken to address them. If these policies and their impact on class mobility are not acknowledged, they cannot be discussed. If these issues are not discussed, the larger forces that have created the current debt crisis will not be identified or acknowledged And naïve, confined, palliative and ineffectual solutions will be the only one offered. Only when we see the connection between the myth of classlessness and the privilege enjoyed by those with social, economic, and political power can we begin to systematically address the major spheres. Sociology of the Credit Card: Private Troubles and Public Issues By Ritzer A SOCIOLOGY OF CREDIT CARDS Sociology in general, and sociological theory in particular, offers a number of ways of dealing with the credit card industry and the individuals affected by it. Throughout much of the 20th century sociological theory has been divided between macro theories (such as structural functionalism and con¬flict theory) that would be most useful in analyzing the credit card industry itself and micro theories (such as symbolic interactionism and phenomenological sociology) that would be most helpful in analyzing individuals within our consumer society. However, sociological theory has generally been plagued by an inability to deal in a fully adequate manner with micro-macro relationships, such as the relationships between the credit card industry and individuals. Sociologists have grown increasingly dissatisfied with having to choose between large-scale, macroscopic theories and small-scale, microscopic theories. Thus, there has been a growing interest in theories that integrate micro and macro concerns. In Europe, expanding interest in what is known there as agency-structure integration parallels the increasing American preoccupation with micro-macro integration. Mills: Personal Troubles, Public Issues This new theoretical approach has important implications for the study of sociological issues in general – and in particular for the kinds of social problems discussed in this book.27 Micro-macro integration leads the sociological study of social problems28 back to one of its roots in the work of the American social critic and theorist C. Wright Mills (1916–1962). Mills is important to us here for two reasons. First, in 1953 Mills coauthored, with Hans Gerth, a now almost-forgotten theory of micro-macro integration: Character and Social Structure. As the title suggests, the authors were interested in the relationship between micro-level character and macro-level social structure. According to Gerth and Mills, one of their goals was “to link the private and the public, the innermost acts of the individual with the widest kinds of socio-historical phenomena. Thus, their thinking is in line with the most recent developments in sociological theory. Of more direct importance here is the now-famous distinction made by Mills in his 1959 work, The Sociological Imagination, between micro-level personal troubles and macrolevel public issues Personal troubles tend to be problems that affect an individual and those immediately around him or her. For example, a father who commits incest with his daughter is creating personal troubles for the daughter, other members of the family, and perhaps himself. However, that single father’s actions are not going to create a public issue that is, they are not likely to lead to a public outcry that society ought to abandon the family as a social institution. Public issues, in comparison, tend to be problems that affect large numbers of people and perhaps society as a whole. The disintegration of the nuclear family would be such a public issue. What, then, is the relationship between these two sets of distinctions—personal troubles/public issues and character/social structure—derived from the work of C. Wright Mills? The character of an individual can certainly cause personal troubles. For example, a psychotic individual can cause problems for himself and those immediately around him. When many individuals have the same character disorder (psychosis, for example), they can cause problems for the larger social structure (overtax the mental health system), thereby creating a public issue. The structure of society can also cause personal troubles for the individual. An example might be a person’s depression resulting from the disjunction between the culturally instilled desire for economic success and the scarcity of well-paying jobs. And the structure of society can create public issues, as exemplified by the tendency of the capitalist economy to generate periodic recessions and depressions. All these connections and, more generally, a wide array of macro-micro relationships are possible. However, the focus of this book is the credit card industry as an element of social structure and the way it generates both personal troubles and public issues. A useful parallel can be drawn between the credit card and cigarette industries. The practices of the cigarette industry create a variety of personal troubles, especially illness and early death. Furthermore, those practices have created a number of public issues (the cost to society of death and illness traceable to cigarette smoke), and thus many people have come to see cigarette industry practices themselves as public issues. Examples of industry practices that have become public issues are the aggressive marketing of cigarettes overseas, where restrictions on such marketing are limited or nonexistent, as well as the marketing of cigarettes to young people in this country (for example, through advertisements featuring the controversial “Joe Camel”). Similarly, the practices of the credit card industry help to create personal problems (such as indebtedness) and public issues (such as the relatively low national savings rate). Furthermore, some industry practices—such as the aggressive marketing of credit cards to teenagers—have themselves become public issues. One of the premises of this book is that we need to begin adopting the same kind of critical outlook toward the credit-card industry that we use in scrutinizing the cigarette industry. Interestingly, Galanoy has suggested a warning label for credit cards, like the ones found on cigarette packets: Caution. Financial experts have determined that continued bank card use can lead to debt, loss of property, bankruptcy plus unhealthful efforts on long-lived standards ad virtues.33 Mills’s ideas give us remarkably contemporary theoretical tools for understanding a critical analysis of the credit card industry and the problems it generates. His conception of the relationship between personal troubles and public issues is the major (although not the only) theory undergirding this book. Marx: Capitalist Exploitation In addition to adopting Mills’s general approach, I will draw on several other important theoretical sources to deal with more specific aspects of the relationship between people and the credit card industry. One is the work of the German social theorist Karl Marx (1818-1881), especially his ideas on the exploitation that he saw as endemic to capitalist society. To Marx, this exploitation takes place in the labor market and the workplace, where capitalistic firms exploit their workers by paying them far less in wages than the value of what they produce. In Mills’ terms, Marx believe that capitalistic firms create personal troubles for workers by exploiting them so greatly, and the impoverished state of the workers eventually becomes such an important public issue that the workers are likely to rise, up and overthrow the capitalist system and replace it with a communist system. Mills was in fact one of the first major American sociologists to be drawn in the direction of Marxian theory. However; time has not been kind to Marxian theory, and many of Marx’s predictions have not come to pass. There have been many changes in the capitalist system, and a variety of issues have come to the fore that did not exist in Marx’s day. As a result, a variety of neo-Marxian memories have arisen to deal with these new capitalist realities. One that concerns us here is the increasing importance to capitalists of the market for goods and services. According to neo-Marxian’s exploitation of the worker continues in the labor market, but capitalists also devote increasing attention to getting consumers to buy more goods and services. Higher, profits can come from both cutting costs and selling more products. The credit card industry plays a role by encouraging consumers to spend more money, in many cases, far beyond their available cash, on the capitalists’ goods, and services. In a sense, the credit card companies have helped medalists to exploit consumers. Indeed, one could argue that modern capitalism has come to depend on a high level of consumer indebtedness. Capitalism could have progressed, only so far by extracting cash from the consumers. It had to find a way to go further. Capitalists’ reliance on widespread consumer credit parallels early capitalists’ exploitation of the labor market. In an effort to in increase profits, they sought to progressively lengthen the workday in order to exploit more of the laborer’s time and effort. When they had pushed the workday to unconscionable lengths, the government was forced to intervene by restricting work hours. The capitalists then sought new ways to exploit workers, and they eventually did so with technological advances that allowed workers to produce more in less time. When capitalists reached a point of diminishing returns in their efforts to squeeze more out of workers for less, they turned their attention to consumers. With the aid of the credit card industry as well as advertising and marketing industries, they eventually discovered new ways of acquiring more of the consumer economic resources, even resources the consumers did not yet have. Simmel: The Money Economy A second German social theorist, Georg Simmel (1858-1918), can also help us understand the personal troubles created by credit cards. Writing more than 40 years before the invention of the credit card, Simmel focused (as mentioned earlier in this chapter) on money, but much of what he had to say about the money, economy and the personal troubles it creates are of help to us in understanding the modern world of credit cards.35 Simmel pointed to many problems associated with a money economy, but here of special concern in this book. • The first problem, similar to one discussed in Marxian theory, is the “temptation to imprudence" associated with a money economy. Simmel argued that money in comparison to its predecessors, such as barter, tends to tempt people into spending more and going into debt. My view is that credit cards are even more likely than money to make people imprudent. People using credit cards are not only likely to spend more but are also more likely to go deeply into debt. Thus, Simmel’s work, like Marx’s leads us to a concern with the way in which the credit card industry creates personal troubles of overspending and indebtedness. • Second, Simmel believed that money makes possible many types of "mean machinations" that were not possible, or were more difficult, in earlier economies. For example, bribes for political influence or payments for assassinations are more easily made with money than with barter. Clearly, bribery and assassination are public issues but they also cause personal troubles for large numbers of people. Although bribes or "assassinations are generally less likely to be paid for with a credit card than with cash, other types of mean machinations become more likely with credit cards. For example, some organizations associated with the credit card industry engage in fraudulent or deceptive practices in order to maximize their income from credit card users. Again, such practices are clearly public issues (or at least they should be) that cause personal troubles for the many victims. • The third problem with a money economy that concerned Simmel was the issue of secrecy, especially the fact that a money economy makes payments of bribes and other types of secret, transactions more possible. However, our main concern in this book is the increasing lack of secrecy and the invasion of privacy associated with the growth of the credit card industry. That industry, as well as other entities within society have been able to collect vast amounts of very personal information on millions of citizens. The existence of that information, and the ability of various agents to access some or all of it, is a major public issue. They way that information has been used has also created personal troubles for many individuals. Weber: Rationalization The next issue of concern has to do with the "rationalization" of society and its relationship to creditcards. Although Simmel wrote on rationalization, the premier theorist on the rationalization process was the German sociologist and economist Max Weber (1864-1920). Weber defined rationalization as the process by which the modern world has come to be increasingly dominated by structures devoted to efficiency, predictability, calculability, and technological control Those rational structures (for example, the capitalist marketplace and the bureaucracy) have had a progressively negative effect on individuals. Weber described a process by which more and more of us would come to be locked in an “iron cage of rationalization.” This public issue can be seen as creating a variety of personal troubles, especially the dehumanization of daily life. For example, Weber saw the bureaucrat as becoming a little more than a faceless cog in a bureaucratic machine. The credit card industry has also been an integral part of the rationalization process. By rationalizing the process by which consumer loans are made, the credit card industry has contributed to our society’s dehumanization. Interestingly, one school of neo-Marxian theory, critical theory, has brought together ideas from both Marx and Weber that are relevant to this analysis of the credit card industry. While building on Mark’s concern with the economy, the critical school focuses on culture. Mass culture is seen as pacifying and stupefying. It could be argued that the consumer culture that credit cards help foster has such effects on people by helping to keep them immersed in the endless and mindless pursuit of goods and services. The critical school also disparages the rationalization process—especially the tendency to engage in technocratic thinking, in which the focus is merely the discovery of the optimum means to ends that are defined by those in control of the larger society. The credit card can be seen as a product of such thinking. Because it works so well as a means, people are discouraged from reflecting on the value of the ends (the goods and services of a consumer society), critically analyzing those ends, and finding alternatives to them. Globalization and Americanization A sociology of credit cards requires a look at the relationship among the credit card industry, personal troubles, and public issues on a global scale. It is not just the United States, but also much of the rest of the world, that is being affected by the credit card industry and the social problems it helps create. To some degree, this development is a result of globalization, a process that is at least partially autonomous of any single nation and that involves a reciprocal impact of many economies.In the main, however, American credit card companies dominate the global market. Thus, in this book I will deal with the spread of the credit card industry around the world under the heading of Americanization rather than globalization. For this issue, instead of drawing on the ideas of long-dead thinkers like Mills, Marx, Simmel, and Weber, I will rely on more contemporary work. The central point is that, in many countries around the world, Americanization is a public issue that is causing personal troubles for their citizens. This book addresses the role played by the credit card industry in this process of Americanization and in the homogenization of life around the world, with the attendant loss of cultural and individual differences. Micro-Macro Relationships The various theoretical resources underpinning this book are all brought to bear on a central issue in the sociological study of a particular social problem: personal troubles, public issues, and the burgeoning credit card industry. Along the way, I will have a number of things to say about responses to these problems—which brings us back to the theory of micro-macro relationships. Although the book’s focus is the way the macro-level credit card industry creates a variety of public issues and personal troubles, it is important to realize that people, at the micro level, create and re-create that industry by their actions. Not only did people create the industry historically, but they help to recreate it daily by acting in accord with its demands and expectations. However, people also have the capacity to refuse to conform to the demands of the credit card industry. If they were to do so on a reasonably large scale, the industry would be forced to alter the way it operates. People can also be more proactive in their effects to change the credit card industry. However, there are limits to what individuals, even when acting in concert, can do about macro-level problems. In many cases, macro-level problems require macro-level solutions. Thus, I will also deal with actions that the credit card industry, as well as the government, can take to deal with the public issues and personal trouble s discussed throughout this book. The theoretical approach underlying this analysis allows us to understand both the adverse effects of the credit card industry and the steps that people and larger social structures can take to ameliorate or eliminate them. OTHER REASONS FOR DEVOTING A BOOK TO CREDIT CARDS Although problems associated with the credit card society are the major focus of this book, there are several other reasons credit cards are worthy of such extensive treatment. First, credit cards represent something new in the history of money. In fact, as I will discuss below, they might not even be subsumable under the heading of money. Second, since they burst on the American scene in mid-century, credit cards have experienced enormous growth, both in this country and around the world. Anything that has grown so rapidly and has become so ubiquitous, demands attention. Third, credit cards are not only of monumental material significance but are also of great cultural, or symbolic, importance. As a well-known motivational researcher put it, “a credit card is a symbol of this age.” Please read : Race, Power and the Subprime Foreclosure Crisis: a Mesoanalysis http://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/wp_669.pdf Chapter 12 Behavioral Economics In order to develop a system of rational regulation of consumer lending and consumer borrowing it is essential to understand whether consumers might borrow when that borrowing is reasonably likely to be to their detriment. If that is the case then it is also essential to understand why consumers might make decisions that are reasonable likely to cause them damage. This field of study is roughly called behavioral economics. Historically, economists have based their theories of consumer borrowing behavior on the fact that consumers are rational actors. Under this assumption the only reason that people would make unwise borrowing decisions is that they lack the knowledge or information necessary to make a wise decision. In a few chapters we will look at various financial literacy efforts and at laws that require disclosure about borrowing transaction. Such efforts seek to address this weak spot in consumer decision- making. More recently, the field of economic psychology in Europe and behavioral economics in the US has begun examining other reasons that consumers might make borrowing decision that seem not to be objectively in their interests. In this chapter we endeavor to consider the following Discussion Questions: What are some of the human characteristics that lead people to borrow unwisely, to their detriment? How might a society choose to remedy this situation? What is the role of faulty perceptions, undue optimism and hyperbolic discounting? Regarding hyperbolic discounting read: http://economics.mit.edu/files/328 What is the downside of or objection to protecting the consumer who is likely to make a mistake from making such a mistake? Are these objections philosophical, or practical or financial or ??? Why is behavioral economics important to understand in the formulation of public policy regarding consumer credit? Is this unique to the USA? Are the answers different in Germany? In Canada? Is it unique to the 21st century? What is the public policy question? Whom to protect? i.e keeping the problem gambler out of the casino? How much to regulate? Whether to use soft paternalism? Please read one of the following articles: A. Classical: The Neo Classical Economics of Consumer Contracts by Richard Epstein http://papers.ssrn.com/so13/papers.cfm?abstract_id=982527 B. Predatory Plastic by Oren Bar Gill- excerpts follow C. After the Great Recession: Regulating Financial Services for Low and Middle Income Communities by Ronald Mann http://scholarlycommons.law.wlu.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=4275&context=wlulr D. Sunstein http://papers.ssrn.com/so13/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2182619 EXCERPTS FROM BAR GILL ARTICLE TO FOLLOW Chapter 13 Introduction to the regulation of Consumer Credit; Disclosure Requirements, Financial Literacy Education, and who counsels the borrower that is in financial distress. We began our study with the history of consumer finance in the U.S. and the peculiar nuances of various types of consumer borrowing and lending. We moved for last three chapters to the world of social science as we analyzed the economic and sociological impacts of the considerable increases in the amount of consumer lending and consumer borrowing in the late twentieth and early twenty first centuries, and we have looked at how and why American consumers borrow as they do. We have also looked at the pressure to lend that may inflame the situation. Now, with all that in mind, we are ready to decide how much regulation we think this world cries out for and what types. A. Cultural of Borrowing / Purchasing Remember the introductory readings from Schor, Warren and Caldor. The essential notion is that before we can decide how much and what kinds of regulations will be optimal for a particular country we need to understand the borrowing behaviors of folks in that country. There are at least two basic reasons to regulate consumer borrowing/lending. The first worry is that if it is unregulated it will lead to frequent economic crashes which will cause massive damage. Hyman Minsky asserts that overspending by consumers will inevitably lead to an economic crash when the bubble bursts. Is this every eighty years (1929 -2005) or every fifty years or every decade? The second worry is micro rather than macro; unless we regulate, individual citizens will make decisions which will cause each of them harm. In a society where neither of those harms is likely to occur, then the need for regulation is reduced. If we conclude that consumer behavior is likely to lead to both of these results then the need for such regulation is heightened. Once we decide on the level of regulation we need to decide what kind. For example, if we think consumers will act in their interests if they understand financial decision making and the essence of the specific borrowing transaction then we might increase the level of financial literacy education and the amount of disclosure requirements. If we think the problem is not one that can be ameliorated by disclosure or education then we might need to prohibit certain kinds of credit offerings such as payday loans or invoke doctrines such as the denying enforcement of credit transactions where the consumer should not have been eligible for the credit extension or limit costs or fees for various kinds of credit offerings. If we think that the source of the problem is too much investment capital chasing above market returns we might consider regulating investment vehicles such as securitization. So, the first item on our survey might be aimed at evaluating the proclivity of consumers in that country to borrow beyond their ability to repay or to use a dangerous borrowing product. We might inquire about the following topics: Degree of Financial Literacy; Vulnerability to Peer pressure ; Extent of Undue optimism; Extent of Hyperbolic discounting; and Extent of income and asset disparity You will recall the distinctions drawn by behavioral economists between soft paternalism and hard paternalism; in this chapter we will look at three areas of “soft” paternalism, disclosure, financial literacy education, and counseling. We begin with disclosure. B. Disclosure Study Questions How does disclosure fit in? What problem is it intended to help with? Why should we require disclosure? What value might it have? How will we know if it is working? What have we tried? Is the goal attainable? Is the ultimate decision to which the disclosure is aimed: (1) to borrow or not to borrow; or (2) is this the appropriate borrowing vehicle or lender once I decide to borrow? What is the optimal method of enforcing effective disclosure? To whom does the creditor owe a duty? What is the creditors' likely response to disclosure measures? If we cannot meaningfully disclose what should we do? Ban the product?? Penalize the Lender? What are the benefits and dangers of prohibiting or discouraging transactions that are “too” complex? What is soft paternalism? Is it possible to provide meaningful disclosure to consumers? C. A bit of history In 1960 Senator Paul Douglas of Illinois introduced a "truth in interest" bill designed to provide consumers with accurate information about the interest charged by various lending institutions. In most instances, borrowers did not know the total cost of receiving loans, and in many cases this ignorance resulted from the widespread use of deceptive methods of reporting interest rates and the price of credit. Often the practice of quoting monthly interest rates rather than annual percentages misled debtors; at other times, lenders quoted loans as "so much down and so much per month" but never revealed the actual interest rate. Unscrupulous lenders employed a host of other tactics to mislead potential customers. Douglas's bill stipulated that lenders provide all borrowers with two basic facts: the total charges for the cost of money being lent and an expression of these charges as an annual interest rate on the unpaid balance of the loan. Douglas's bill received the avid support of labor unions, credit unions, and other consumer groups, but met vigorous opposition from banks and other lending institutions. He emphasized that his disclosure bill would not regulate credit or impose any ceilings on interest rates but only sought to provide consumers with full and accurate information so that they could make informed choices. Nevertheless, critics charged that such disclosure would confuse the public and saddle purveyors of credit with needless costs. Douglas labored unsuccessfully for truth in lending legislation for the remainder of his senatorial career, attracting increasing support but never amassing the necessary votes for passage of a bill which was stalled in the Banking Committee by chairman A Willis Robertson (D.Va. ) father of Pat Robertson. In 1967, the year AFTER Senator Douglas left the Senate and the year after Sen. Robertson lost his primary, the legislative logjam broke, and Wisconsin Senator William Proxmire's truth-in-lending bill passed. When President Johnson signed the measure, Proxmire attributed the achievement to the indefatigable efforts of Paul Douglas. In the 1970’s the Truth in Lending Act was a powerful tool for consumers and their advocates. As financial transactions have become more complex and as the statute and regulations have been amended it has become less effective as a weapon and more difficult intellectually to develop the right mix of information and clarity. D. Before we look at the present or the future let’s look at the past. Here are two looks by authors who write from the creditors’ point of view. Truth in Lending Simplification (described in an article in 1981) By TIMOTHY D. MARRINAN* and PETER D. SCHELLIE** 37 Bus. Law. [ix] (1981-1982) page 1297 Date: IX. THE FUTURE OF CREDIT COST DISCLOSURES A. Immediate Future There are two activities under way right now, one legislative and one regulatory, that will affect the Simplification Act. The first involves legislation introduced by Senator Jake Garn to make four amendments to the Truth in Lending Act. The four amendments contain changes that would cut down on civil liability in cases involving nonsubstantial violations, absolving creditor of statutory damage liability, and that would remove the minimum recovery in truth in lending cases. The pending legislation would amend the law by removing arrangers of credit altogether from coverage under the Truth in Lending Act. It would clarify the relationship between state and federal law, and generally, would displace all similar state laws subject to an override. And, finally, it would defer the effective date until October 1, 1982. At the regulatory level, the Federal Reserve Board is also looking at the question of the arranger of credit definition. Its response, at least as contained in its proposal, was not to exempt altogether arrangers of credit who have been brought in under the new lawreal estate brokers being the largest category of affected persons-but rather to clarify when these people are involved in arranging credit. The proposal did, however, contain a request for comments on the alternative of exclusion as well. B. Near Future It seems very likely that at the congressional level we're not going to see very much activity very soon. Congress has worked on the Truth in Lending Act for almost five years, and has worked through the issue very carefully. Now, despite the fact that some, including Senator Garn, have an earnest belief that the current law does not serve the consumer simply because it delivers too much information, Congress seems to be ready to leave the Act alone. Mention was made earlier of the information overload concept that seemed to undergird the whole simplification effort. The term information overload is not intuitively clear, and there remains a great lack of information about the concept. Indeed, the only testimony that has been presented on it was presented by one witness who talked about labelling canned goods. That was the extent of the information overload data presented to Congress that helped to lead to the Simplification Act. So the pieces of information, the data that have been compiled, are simply not very adequate to make further changes unless there's a quantum leap in what is known about human reaction to information. Midterm changes or corrections will most likely not be made by Congress, other than possibly some very fine tuning. By the same token, the Federal Reserve Board is in a wait-and-see position. It is waiting to see what kind of problems will arise-how many problems will be legitimate problems with which it must deal-before it revises the Official Staff Commentary. The Federal Reserve Board has announced that it's going to follow a new course in providing guidance with respect to requirements under the Truth in Lending Act. Instead of issuing interpretations, it will periodically revise the commentary, which will provide all of the interpretations in one place. Presumably, the timing of those updates will be responsive to the volume and nature of problems that come up both in the creditor community and in the courts as the Simplification Act is implemented in day-to-day activities. C. Long Term In the 1980s, generally, consumer credit cost disclosure will most likely continue to play a critically important role, and, with the possible exception of discovering that far too much information is being provided, disclosure will probably continue in a form very similar to what exists now. It is interesting to note that in terms of credit cost disclosures, the deregulation dynamic cuts both ways. There is increasing sentiment and widening support for deregulation. On the other hand, there is a parallel movement that involves ensuring that the market is in a position to regulate itself after the government's influence has been displaced. In the credit area, traditionally, that goal of market regulation has been thought of as being achievable only if consumers have information-meaningful, useful, comparable information-that they can use in making judgments that will assure that the market works efficiently. So for disclosure issues in the credit area, at least, deregulation will mean different things to different people. If the industry is saying to government, "Let the market operate," a legitimate response that one can expect to hear is, "The market can't operate unless consumers are provided with information that's good enough to allow it to operate efficiently." At the same time, activity will continue on the part of both major constituencies on consumer credit cost matters. Both of the constituencies, consumer groups and creditor groups, see pros and cons in the role of credit cost disclosure. The sentiment in the credit industry against cost disclosure is based on real skepticism as to whether it is effective, whether it does any good, and whether the benefit derived is worth the cost. In effect, the time and expense of making these comprehensive disclosures are being questioned in the face of the results. The consumer group is concerned about whether those who are in most need of assistance in credit transactions are able to understand and use the disclosures that they do receive. This has come out recently in connection with the discussion of overriding state usury ceilings. To an industry argument that the Truth in Lending Act will prevent abuses if there are no usury ceilings, consumer groups have countered that this is not so because a large portion of the consumer market cannot, will not, or does not use the disclosure information available. Therefore, disclosure is an ineffective method of consumer protection, at least as to some segments of the consuming public. There are, however, people from both of those credit constituencies who actively support disclosure. Industry groups have supported it in many cases since it was deemed to be a desirable alternative to substantive regulation. In some cases the argument has been, "Allow us to undertake a specified practice but make us disclose it fully." A recent example is the Comptroller of the Currency's adjustable rate mortgage regulation in which not consumer lenders but mortgage lenders went to the comptroller's office and said, "We'll disclose anything, just give us freedom and flexibility in fashioning our variable rate mortgage programs." The response in large part was, "All right, we will permit that." So, in that respect, the industry has used disclosure as a bargaining tool to avoid substantive regulation. By the same token, of course, consumer groups generally have been supportive of disclosure because it does produce desirable results, at least to some extent. Again one must return to the question whether a large number of people have to use disclosure in credit shopping in order for it to influence market behavior. The answer to that is probably no. It seems likely that the creditor community can be effectively influenced by only a small segment of its target market in pricing and setting those decisions, and doesn't require 100% market awareness in order to influence market behavior. Those are the factors that are going to affect both the legislative and regulatory processes. But there is a third element and that is the litigation aspect. Again, it's difficult to judge how this litigation context will be affected by the Simplification Act. The narrowing of the statutory damage liability in closed-end credit and the simplified approach that has been reflected through the revised regulation and the final commentary will mean that there will not be the same magnitude of litigation in the future as in the past. Most assuredly, if legislation is passed doing away with the driving force for lawsuits, that is, a minimum guaranteed recovery and the concept of technical violations giving rise to that recovery, there will be even less. But the net result will be that there won't be the same kind of extensive litigation that we have had under the original act. CONSUMER DISCLOSURE IN THE 1990s Griffith L. Garwood, Robert J. Hobbs, and Fred H. Miller Georgia State University Law Review June 1, 1993 Vol 9 page 777 INTRODUCTION Disclosure has long been a cornerstone of consumer protection. Disclosure is an important component-and even the primary purpose-of numerous federal laws, including the Truth in Lending (TIL), Truth in Savings, Equal Credit Opportunity, Fair Credit Billing, Consumer Leasing, Fair Debt Collection Practices, Electronic Fund Transfers, and Magnuson-Moss Acts and the Federal Trade Commission's Holder in Due Course, Door to Door Solicitation, and Credit Practices Rules. Disclosure is also a feature of state consumer protection laws, although these laws more and more tend not to overlap the federal enactments, and instead focus on substantive regulation such as deceptive practices, the regulation of interest and charges, and matters of that sort. Although disclosure is by now a well established concept, debate continues whether the concept is working in all contexts, and whether the benefits of disclosure always outweigh the societal costs. This Article reviews the perceived successes and the difficulties of disclosure. It attempts to identify lessons that may be learned from looking at disclosure patterns, and to discern future trends and directions for disclosure requirements. I. CONTEXTS FOR AND TYPES OF CONSUMER DISCLOSURES Disclosure as a consumer protection device is employed in many contexts, sometimes with different objectives. To illustrate, disclosure may be directed at the general public with the goal of facilitating individual decision making, or it may be designed to generate general public discussion to formulate policy. Obvious examples are the regulation of credit and demand and interest bearing account solicitation advertising, intended to help the public at large with individual shopping decisions, and the statistical data on lending activity required by the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act directed at letting a community assess the performance of an institution in generally serving that community.1 A more modest aim is disclosure that targets specific groups of individuals. An example is disclosure with respect to credit and charge card solicitations and applications, where those who have been selected for solicitation by the card issuer are provided specific information.2 Disclosures may be focused more directly at persons already expressing interest in a product. An illustration is the home equity line application disclosures, where disclosures must be given with the application.3 The narrowest context is the requirement that new customers be afforded disclosure in connection with, for example, the installment sale or loan contract or note and mortgage they are signing or a schedule of fees and charges, interest rates, and terms of a new account they are opening.4 Not all disclosures are directed at potential or new customers. For example, existing customers are afforded disclosure on or with the periodic statement in open end credit and with respect to their asset accounts.5 Even former customers may be due disclosure; for example, they may be provided an "adverse action" notice under laws protecting against credit discrimination when accounts are terminated.6 Within the above contexts, the types of mandated disclosures may also vary. For example, some disclosures are quite general in describing a product. An illustration is the pamphlet required for home equity lines which discusses the general characteristics of home equity loans rather than any individual plan.7 A somewhat more specific type of disclosure, that still is not transaction specific, is the preprinted early adjustable rate mortgage (ARM) disclosure where the disclosure is related to the specific type of ARM of interest to the borrower.8 At the other end of the spectrum are the very specific disclosures required on open end monthly statements9 and in automatic teller machine (ATM) receipts that reflect individual account activity.10 Other types of disclosures are general in nature, but focus to a degree on general policies or terms, as well as on specific product information-for example, the initial disclosure in connection with an electronic fund transfer service.11 Most disclosures must be prepared for the consumer.12 A few disclosures, however, really are instructions on how to prepare the information yourself. For example, the ARM disclosures must contain an example of the calculations for a sample $10,000 loan with instructions for the user on how to calculate a possible worst case scenario for an individual loan.13 One constant, nonetheless, is the complexity of the rules that cover these diverse examples. To make the point, Truth in Lending alone, as embodied in Regulation Z and its staff commentary, contains some 125,000 words. II. BASIC OBSERVATIONS ABOUT THE DISCLOSURE APPROACH Notwithstanding the diversity of consumer disclosures and the complexity of the rules, some basic observations seem possible as to why disclosure has long been, and is likely to continue to be, a fundamental consumer protection device. We can also identify some prerequisites to effective disclosure. A Policies Behind Disclosure All mandated disclosure in whatever context and of whatever type in the consumer financial services provider-consumer relationship reflects two ideas that seem well accepted. First, it recognizes that consumers are less knowledgeable than is the provider about possible or existing terms of the relationship. The disclosure approach is based on the assumption that if appropriate information is provided, the consumer may use the information to avoid deleterious, uninformed, or unwise action, and to obtain better terms-thus making best use of the market mechanism.14 Both those who see disclosure as necessary to protect the consumer and those who see information as necessary to protect the functioning of the market are likely to support the concept. B. Disclosure as an Alternative Second, in the United States, disclosure as a consumer protection device is seen as consistent with our form of government, which is premised on an informed electorate. Thus disclosure serves as an attractive alternative to the substantive regulation of agreements and conduct as a method of achieving a balanced relationship between the service provider and the consumer. Consumer agreements normally are forms prepared by the service provider, and thus initially favor that party; the forms are often couched in legal language, absent "plain English" laws. They are often of considerable length. Normal legal principles favor allowing rules and standards to be set by the agreement of the parties rather than by regulation. But, if strictly adhered to, this may allow the provider to prevail unless the consumer reviews and understands the contract before signing. This is impractical. Disclosure can highlight the important terms and present them in intelligible language so that the consumer may quickly understand and bargain for a more balanced relationship-at least in theory. More realistically, the consumer can at least avoid an imbalanced relationship by choosing not to consummate the deal on the basis of the disclosures. Advance disclosure before the transaction is finalized allows the consumer to shop for advantageous terms and, because it fosters competition, facilitates market regulation of terms. This lessens the need to regulate agreements and practices by law. Evidence of effectiveness of disclosure acting as a market regulator exists, for example, in the Federal Reserve Board's Annual Percentage Rate Demonstration Project (1987), which tested the effect of publication of "shoppers guides" listing creditors' annual percentage rates. The Board found that the dispersion of interest rates declined in the markets with guides, as to some extent did their average level. Some evidence for this idea also exists in the legislative history of the Fair Credit and Charge Card Disclosure Act.15 The Act requires more information to be provided with credit card solicitations based in part on concerns about the level of credit card interest rates. Its proponents thought that better information would help drive down rates. The Act was supported by many persons as an alternative to federal rate regulation. Finally, one response to the disclosure requirements of Regulation CC16 may also make the point. Many institutions have chosen to provide prompt availability of funds with limited exceptions, rather than utilizing the more extensive exceptions allowed by the funds availability law.17 C. Prerequisites for Effective Disclosure A third observation is that, for any type of disclosure to serve its purpose, certain prerequisites must exist. These prerequisites include appropriate timing. Thus, disclosure generally should come at a time to permit the utilization of alternative sources to obtain the consumer financial services sought. A successful example of this concept in present law is the "advance" disclosure for closed-end residential mortgage transactions subject to the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act and for ARMs where disclosure must be provided within three days of receipt of an application.18 This disclosure is obviously more beneficial than the "contract" disclosure permitted for other closed-end transactions where disclosure typically comes at closing. Another prerequisite of effective disclosure is that it must be uniform and clear. Generally this suggests the need for specified terminology or format to aid comparison. It also requires a format that distinguishes the disclosures from other material, facilitating consumer understanding of the disclosures. illustrations of these propositions include the required Truth in Lending terminology and the Federal Trade Commission Rule on Preservation of Consumers' Claims and Defenses,21 which requires specific terminology and type standards for a mandated notice. The rules concerning funds availability are also an example in requiring disclosures to be grouped together, unrelated information to be excluded, disclosures to be highlighted when they appear in another document, and certain phrases to be used.22 Of course, not all disclosure rules are so specific. Certain Truth in Lending disclosure rules in open end credit do not require segregation,23 a particular location or type size,24 or uniform terminology (except as between initial and periodic disclosure). An additional prerequisite of effective disclosure is that it should avoid "information overload." Generally, to be effective, disclosures must be brief and simple enough to be readily assimilated. This means that certain details must be omitted. The failure to meet this prerequisite risks destroying the utility of disclosure. A disclosure that is not read at all or is too complex for practical use is no disclosure. Thus, sometimes summary disclosure rather than detailed descriptions are best. An illustration of this concept is the initial disclosure in relation to acquiring an electronic fund transfer service,26 where only a summary of information is required-such as a summary of the consumer's liability for unauthorized electronic funds transfers, the financial institution's liability for certain failures, and so on. Another illustration is the disclosure concerning the reasons for adverse action taken on credit transactions required under the Equal Credit Opportunity Act.27 While creditors must give the principal reasons, the staff commentary to Regulation B suggests that giving more than four reasons is not likely to be helpful to applicants.28 The commentary further takes the position that a creditor need not explain how or why a factor adversely affected an applicant.29 A final example is rebate disclosure. Under Truth in Lending, a disclosure is required of whether or not the consumer is entitled to a rebate of any finance charge upon prepayment, but not a description of the method of computing the earned or unearned finance charge, which would be unduly complicated. D. Myths A final general observation that may be made is that the rhetoric about disclosure often is at least part myth. For example, it is commonly proclaimed that disclosure laws are not substantive limitations and that disclosures don't change products. While this often is accurate, it is not invariably true. Increasingly, disclosure laws and disclosure formulate substantive rules. Two illustrations will suffice: (1) the home equity disclosure law in fact contained numerous limitations on contractual terms for home equity lines,31 and (2) the necessity to give detailed ARM disclosures for each variable rate mortgage program offered32 has undoubtedly limited product variation and offerings. Another assumption is that we can identify the truth and fully disclose it. Alfred North Whitehead once said that all truths are only half truths. He reasoned that trying to treat half truths as whole truths causes our problems. Many of the problems labored over in the discussions of truth in lending "simplification" reflect this phenomenon.33 In actual fact, Congress and the Federal Reserve Board have picked certain standards and levels of disclosure, which, although nominally referred to as representing the "truth" and "full disclosure," in fact represent neither. 34 On the other hand, the chosen standards may represent an acceptable balance, for an extreme pursuit of "truth" or full disclosure is probably neither workable nor desirable. If disclosure demands too much complexity, as observed, it is self defeating. Thus, Whitehead's half truths may be the only understandable ones. III. INHERENT ELEMENTS OF SELF DEFEAT As suggested above, it can be persuasively argued that the constant pursuit of ever more disclosures may diminish their effectiveness. Moreover, the cost of preparing forms, training personnel, monitoring compliance attempts, and the like for disclosure is not cheap. While effective disclosure allocates resources and produces other benefits that probably justify such expenditures,35 ineffective disclosure produces little to justify its cost, and may even misallocate resources. What factors lead to ineffective disclosure? First, disclosure that depends on voluntary action may not be very successful. For example, since credit advertising is not mandatory, detailed advertising rules that are "triggered" by certain statements may either simply suppress advertising or drive it to generalized statements. Voluntary "early" contract disclosure merely raises the risk that two rather than one set of disclosures may be necessary and that, if misdisclosure occurs, may be there additional risk of liability to noncustomers. Consequently, it is rarely used. Second, the technical requirements for uniform and clear disclosure, as well as the complexity of the disclosures themselves, tend to produce litigation that in turn may prompt further complexity and "over compliance."36 The civil liability37 and restitution38 rules for TIL disclosure violations encourage zero tolerance for ambiguity and thus prompt evermore complex rules to provide certainty in evermore complex transactions. A third factor is that as products evolve in more complex permutations and legislative or regulatory focus centers upon them, the inevitable trend is to longer and more complex disclosure. Perhaps the best illustration comes from a comparison of the early and later disclosure requirements for variable rate transactions.39 As ARM's became more common and complex, a simple three point disclosure (which many felt was ineffective in alerting borrowers to their risk) was broadened into a full blown set of new separate disclosures. Other examples include the disclosures in consumer buy downs and discounted and premium variable rate transactions,40 which have increased in complexity over the years, and the evolution from simple state disclosures in connection with credit card solicitations and applications to the subsequent broader federal activity in this area. IV. THE TRUTH IN LENDING EXPERIENCE Perhaps aspects of the above discussion can be highlighted by further examination of the primary federal credit disclosure law, the Truth in Lending Act. It took the decade of the 1960s to enact TIL and the decade of the 1970s to refine and simplify it. However, in the 1980s as credit products continued to evolve, it became more difficult to simply advise a consumer to shop for the lower APR. In the 1980s, the APRs on two major types of consumer credit sometimes became incomparable. For example, in the automobile finance area, 2.9% or 0% financing provided by dealers who sell their contracts to captive finance companies will not reflect the fact that consumers who choose this financing forego receiving a cash payment from the manufacturer. Legal and practical problems hinder imputing such additional amounts to the credit purchaser's APR. In contrast, third party lender finance charges would all be included in the APR. The inability of consumers to compare APRs at car dealers and lenders is not the only aspect of the problem today, however. APRs on open end home equity lines of credit (the most rapidly growing type of consumer credit in the 1980s), closed-end second mortgages, and unsecured loans also cannot be compared with confidence because open-end credit APRs are calculated differently than those for closed-end contracts.42 The gap in comparability of what some might think are "true" APRs on credit cards and personal loans has widened as well, as fees on credit cards have escalated and additional credit insurance products have proliferated for personal loans. Real estate closing costs, credit card annual fees, and credit insurance premiums, in the minds of some, are not part of the "real" APR even though they increase the actual cost of credit. Some believe that one of the primary benefits of TIL, providing a precise measure of the cost of alternative sources of credit, is now somewhat at risk.43 AB a result, some would suggest that changes in the consumer credit market may require a reexamination of the law. The current incomparability of APRs between major types of consumer credit is a troubling problem. AB a starting point, the compromises embedded in TIL as exceptions to the general TIL definition of the "finance charge"-both in the beginning and as a result of simplification-might be reexamined if the APR is to regain its full comparability. Some have suggested that inclusion of closing costs, credit insurance, broker's fees, application charges, seller's points, and filing fees in the finance charge might increase the comparability of APRs between transactions and reduce unseemly practices in the credit industry. Fictitious "cash" down payments are becoming more frequent in the car industry. The result may be consumers' confusion, improvident extensions of credit, and the undermining of the financier's underwriting criteria. Reinclusion of TIL statutory damages for misdisclosure of down payments might put a quick end to this deception. That would benefit consumers and financiers alike. Home improvement scams are staging a small comeback. A two contract, low-ball scheme is being used to circumvent the homeowners' TIL right to cancel during the three day cooling-off period. The second, higher-priced finance contract that will replace the cheaper contract under which work was begun complies with TIL, but is presented only after work is substantially completed. At this point, courts may require the consumer to tender the value of the work performed to rescind that second contract under Truth in Lending. This leaves the homeowner with a rescission right that may involve the obligation to refinance part of the home improvement transaction. This is substantially less protection than a right to cancel before any work is performed. Unfortunately, many of the victims of this scam seem to be particularly vulnerable elderly homeowners on fixed incomes who can ill afford the losses. TIL rescission rules could be tightened to protect against the scam. One idea might be to have a broader rescission right before any work is started; this would provide enough of a cloud on these transactions to make them less likely. Another potential challenge for TIL in the 1990s could be providing the consumer with better information to evaluate loan consolidations secured by a first or second mortgage on the borrower's home. Increasingly, consumers seeking a small personal loan are being switched into large, often high-rate, consolidation loans. For many consumers a disclosure comparing installments, total of payments, and finance charges between the consolidation loan and the credit to be consolidated might be sufficient to help them avoid improvidently putting their home on the line for an excessive mortgage. Some notice pointing out the effect of loan consolidation might be effective for other consumers. The 1980s witnessed two important improvements to TIL. The first, early . disclosure44-presented at the time the consumer may still be shopping for credit termswas introduced for certain types of credit, e.g., ARMs, credit cards, and home equity lines of credit. As noted earlier, the lateness of other TIL disclosure remains a problem, since most TIL disclosures are presented only after the consumer is psychologically bound to the transaction and the disclosures may be obscured by a sheaf of other documents. Earlier disclosure might enhance competition for other types of credit and the feasibility of this approach on a broader scale could be reevaluated. Unfortunately, early disclosure also means imprecise disclosure, since in many transactions the precise terms are not all known until near closing. Awareness of Typical Credit Rates 1969 1970 1977 Closed-end credit 14.5% 38.3% 54.5% Open-end credit 30.9% 59.5% 68.0% There also was a comparable increase in the sensitivity of consumers to interest rates and declining loyalty to prior lenders. See Fed. Res. Bd. ANNUAL PERCENTAGE RATE DEMONSTRATION PROJECT (Mar. 1987), which shows: Reasons for Choice of Credit for a Recent Credit Transaction 1977 1984-5 Low interest rate 6.8% 24.3% Previous experience 53.6% 39.3% Reference 8.1% 24.3% Availability of credit 7.3% 10.3% Convenience 3.7% 7.7% The second enhancement of the 1980s was requiring informational brochures for all ARM and home equity loans. These brochures provide more in-depth information than may be presented in the necessarily simplified disclosures for complex transactions. While the brochures, like the simple disclosures, will not be used by all consumers, they are a step forward in providing greater consumer information at a time useful to consumers. They may well represent a solution to the inherent problem of "truth" versus information overload. If some way could be found to test their effectiveness, additional opportunities to use them profitably might be identified. The early 1990s would also be an appropriate time to reassess the various TIL disclosure approaches with other consumer testing. The effectiveness of the model payments box,46 introduced in TIL simplification, should be verified. How well model disclosures (like "This obligation has a demand feature")47 have worked should be assessed. If the scheme is not working, alternatives could be explored. The experiment of the Federal Reserve Board with APR shoppers' guides in local newspapers demonstrated that savings may be enjoyed through increased competition spurred by this low-cost device. Part of the Massachusetts and New York consumer education effort for years, credit shoppers' guides list average rates for typical credit transactions in the local market by each credit extender. The Federal Reserve Board study demonstrated that proliferation of shoppers' guides has the potential to save consumers millions of dollars in finance charges each year.48 Encouraging credit extenders to provide their typical rates in response to a publisher's request could spur an increase in this most effective consumer education mechanism. Finally, disclosure of credit criteria might be useful. There appear to be no significant financial or demographic differences between finance company and bank borrowers. But finance company borrowers often pay substantially more for the money they borrow. One explanation may be an assumption that a bank's standards for eligibility are higher and a deep seated aversion by a substantial portion of the credit worthy population to having their credit application rejected. However, creditors' eligibility standards are almost universally considered proprietary and secret. Factors that credit scoring models find predictive may be so counter-intuitive that their disclosure would do no more than confuse, and the need for secrecy of the standards is understandable. But as a result, consumers cannot know which eligibility standards they will meet without actually applying and risking rejection. The effect of not making them public may diminish competitiveness in the industry. Some type of early Equal Credit Opportunity Act "reasons for action" notice on the application may encourage some high rate borrowers to increase their credit shopping. Alternatively, a more general disclosure might be considered along the lines of: "Studies have shown that applicants rejected by one creditor are often acceptable to other creditors at the same or lower rates." However, such a disclosure may well lack credibility when dispensed to high- and low-risk applicants alike. V. CONSUMER DISCLOSURE IN THE 1990s More disclosure may be inevitable and necessary in the 1990s; we have already seen one major addition in the Truth in Savings Act. But as previously discussed, merely adding more disclosure can amount to less effective disclosure. Adding more detail or volume of information with no change in approach is probably not the answer. What are possible answers? Sometimes imprecise information may serve better than detailed information that is ignored or is not understood because of length or complexity. An illustration may be the limited information49 now required by TIL about charges for late payments, which is likely to be useful even though a contractual or statutory grace period is not required to be disclosed. Similarly, the required security interest information also is probably useful even if details about after-acquired property and other incidental interests are not permitted to be disclosed. There is evidence, however, that the need to keep things simple is a lesson that needs to be constantly relearned. In part, demands for more disclosures are the understandable result of the expanding choice of product variations for consumers. A case in point are mortgages. Once mortgages were of a common type-fixed rate and of 25 to 30 years maturity. Today, there are variable as well as fixed rate mortgages, 15 year maturities, monthly and bi-weekly payment schedules, a wide variety of indices, margins, caps, and' shared equity, price adjusted, and other types of mortgages. We also see more variety and options in credit cards and deposit accounts. Following the old path raises the specter of even more complex disclosures as they try to keep up with new products. What this suggests is the need for a variety of new approaches like brochures, early disclosures, and shoppers' guides, each tailored to the particular situation. A second pressure for more disclosure comes from concern about increased risk for consumers. Variable interest rate transactions are inherently more risky than fixed rate ones in terms of default potential. The popular home equity line places at risk the consumer's principal asset, and the home has a long history of protection in the United States. Many programs, of course, have other built in credit risks, such as "teaser" rates. These risks are not all in the credit context; for example, if deposit insurance coverage is scaled back it might lead to demand for more extensive deposit account and investment disclosures. A third factor propelling more disclosure is the decline in local relationships between customers and financial institutions. These old relationships often produced informal information. Today, many consumers deal with out-of-state and impersonal creditors as mortgage servicing and credit card portfolios are sold. This had led, for example, to amendments to the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act that require mortgage lenders to provide disclosures to loan applicants that explain the lender's likelihood of transferring servicing during the life of the loan. That law also requires servicers to provide additional disclosures at the time of any subsequent transfer of that servicing. A fourth factor that might encourage more disclosure is regulatory ideas from abroad. In Europe, for example, variable rates are prohibited in Belgium, mortgages are limited to fifty percent of the purchase price in Italy, and in Holland all consumer credit extensions are registered and the lender is under a duty not to grant credit that would overextend the borrower. These restrictions are not likely to prove acceptable in the United States. But the disclosure alternative may have to be shown to be effective as further world integration occurs, and cross-border transactions raise ideas like these. In the disclosure context, some European ideas might be feasible. In Belgium, membership in a consumer organization enables the member to select the financial institution that will grant a loan on the most favorable terms, taking into account personal factors such as the number of children, income bracket, tax situation, grants, subsidies, insurance, and so on. In fact, the computer print-out furnished to the member supplies much more information, such as how to spread the loan over both partners in a family, a loan redemption chart, the difference between the "best buy" institution and those rated second, third, fourth, fifth, and so on. Another computer program enables the consumer to work out whether it would be advantageous to replace an existing loan with a new one. If a refinancing is advantageous, the program gives details of the institution at which the transactions should be carried out and how big the annual net benefit would be. This is a disclosure approach that might find wide acceptance in the United States. Finally, the source of credit may change, and this too may encourage new disclosure rules. In the future, there is likely to be more globalization of financial services. For example, if there now is a Citicorp, South Dakota, doing business with consumers across the country, why not a Citicorp, London or a Citicorp, Paris doing the same thing in the future? The prospect of a developed "European Financial Area" composed of twelve nations and 320 million people competing for American consumers raises some interesting questions that have bearing for Americans that might be doing business in these markets. These countries have different banking laws with different disclosure and consumer protection requirements. While a "banking directive" has been issued by the European Community to harmonize the essential rules,55 there still will exist some recognition of local concerns. Although the law of a financial institution's "home" country will generally prevail, the directive still leaves to the consumer's country some latitude as to regulating for the "public good," which rules may be enforced in the European Court of Justice. Should the future see American consumers dealing with European institutions under such a scheme both foreign and domestic law may be applicable. Will it be presumed that U.S. consumers are adequately protected by this structure? It is likely that additional disclosure, concerning at least such "choice of law" problems, may be called for as a condition to entry into United States markets. Particularly, if all these forces generate any substantial amount of new disclosures in the 1990s, it will be important to focus on eliminating outdated rules. The regulatory and legislative bodies that promulgate disclosure rules have begun to review the rules periodically to determine whether they still are needed and whether they are working appropriately. If not, they should be changed or repealed. A proposal by the Treasury calls for a comprehensive review of existing rules to identify possible places to reduce the burden of compliance.56 The FFIEC (which coordinates the activities of federal financial institution regulators) has recently completed a review of agency regulations to identify opportunities for burden reduction.57 It is now working on a subsequent review of the underlying statutes. There is always great inertia attached to eliminating disclosures, but it has been done. The old Regulation Z, section 226.8(o), governing disclosure of discounts for prompt payment, and section 226.11, on the comparative index of credit cost for open end credit, are history. In this regard, one subject for review might include the rule that a minimum finance charge is a penalty58 as no state law treats it as such. If this disclosure concept must be retained, the optional disclosure, that the consumer may be charged a minimum finance charge,59 may be the preferable formulation. A second candidate certainly is the boiler-plate disclosures about assumptions and spreader clauses.60 Any review, of course, alternatively may indicate that further disclosures are necessary. An example of this result is the enhanced disclosure for adverse action in business credit.61 In all of this, it must be kept in mind, however, that change itself can be burdensome-sometimes to the extent that it is not worth the effort. Another possible trend that may develop in the 1990s is further work to eliminate disclosure complexity generated through litigation in favor of a more orderly regulatory and statutory development of disclosure rules. This trend was inaugurated in the reduction of the kinds of disclosures for which statutory damages can be recovered under TIL.62 That effort appears to have been a factor in dramatically reduced TIL litigation. This helped to slow the prior trend to increased complexity and over compliance in disclosure. But much remains to be done in this regard. The current remedy scheme under the Fair Debt Collection Practices Act,63 for example, is not so limited. Here litigation has proliferated. Some would argue that this has resulted in hair splitting reminiscent of the finest (or worst) days-depending on one's perspective-under old TIL. Reliance on administrative enforcement, except in cases of actual damages, allows the focus to be upon whether the correct disclosure was made, and not on infinite interpretations of disclosure requirements to obtain settlement leverage or damages to offset owed debts. A downside of administrative enforcement, however, is it often is too infrequent to be effective, is only feasible for "mass wrongs," and, at times, may force inappropriate settlement due to inadequate resources on one side. A final possible trend may stem from the recognition that state disclosures added to federal disclosures sometimes provide very little additional benefit to consumers, and may be lost as attention is focused on the federal information. Some would argue that additional state disclosures can be counterproductive if they detract attention from the federal disclosures that are deemed important as a matter of national consensus, or if they so lengthen the mandated overall material as to diminish its effectiveness.65 There is evidence that both Congress and the states gradually are arriving at this conclusion. To illustrate, in essence Congress and the Federal Reserve Board have preempted all state disclosure rules relating to funds availability,66 and the same has occurred under the Fair Credit and Charge Card Disclosure Act.67 On the other hand, states sometimes are more aggressive in entering a field. In the absence of Congressional action concerning "credit repair" organizations which charge to provide information about-and may in fact often misrepresent-rights under the Fair Credit Reporting Act,68 a number of states have acted. Also, in the absence of Congressional action, a number of states have mandated disclosure and other rights concerning "rent-to-own" operations that constitute neither consumer credit sales nor leases under the Consumer Leasing Act.69 In some other areas, there is uncertainty as to the most effective disclosure approach. State disclosure schemes can test what is most effective. It may be appropriate for the federal law to set the "floor" for adequate consumer protection standards with the states permitted to experiment with yet better solutions. CONCLUSION Disclosure as a consumer protection tool is here to stay. However, for the law to continue to work effectively it is necessary to devote constant attention to its operation and development. We need to be open to ideas about how it can best work with respect to new contexts and products. We also need to assess past performance and decide whether existing rules remain viable. E. Now, on to the present and the future. i. First a post on Creditslips.org by a professor who is a consumer advocate. National Consumer Protection Week and Disclosure posted by Jean Braucher date of blog entry in Creditslips.org DATE??? It’s National Consumer Protection Week (NCPW)! Federal, state, local, and nonprofit consumer protection agencies and organizations are making extra efforts to promote consumer awareness. First I have to get out of my system thoughts of Tom Lehrer’s song, National Brotherhood Week: Step up and shake the hand/Of someone you can’t stand . . . It’s only for a week so have no fear/Be grateful that it doesn’t last all year. But to get back on message, of particular interest to Credit Slips readers is this part of the mission of consumer protection described on the NCPW website: "Financial Fraud Scams: American consumers owe a whopping $11.31 trillion dollars in debt and are behind on paying about $1.01 trillion of that amount. Mortgages, student loans, and credit cards account for a large portion of that debt. Consumers are often haunted with huge monthly payments, and fraudsters take advantage of that with debt relief scams, tax scams, and other financial fraud scams. Scams target individuals who are in financial distress, but they fail to fulfill their promises, and typically leave consumers worse off than when they started." Let me say that Lauren Willis has done a great job on this site recently taking us, patiently and painstakingly, through the many problems with the idea that disclosure can be refined into a digital juggernaut to protect consumers. I’m all for disclosure as a first line of consumer defense, particularly useful to the most savvy, but let’s do it simply and quickly, recognizing its limits, and get back to the main task of going after scammers and exploiters who systematically study human weaknesses and then harness them for their own gain. Disclosure can't do much about that, so we’re always going to need a lot of substantive consumer protection, too. A central idea in disclosure 3.0 is facilitating apps for evaluating credit products. So let the products get more and more intricate and then provide consumers with data dumps on their own usage, to be passed by them to app platforms. Really? Smart phone usage is growing (but app usage is growing more slowly. Even once everyone is tech ready for this brave new world, what a great new line for scammers, especially those who are also hackers. Access to all information about a consumer’s credit use! Oh boy! Have we got a deal for you! Millions of people a year are tricked into sending money over the Internet and by wire and check for nothing in return. My favorite is the “free puppy” scam (just wire money first for shots and shipping and perhaps surgery for the poor sick puppy). Millions more consumers end up in high-cost debt traps carefully designed and then redesigned to be one step ahead of consumer understanding and regulatory enforcement. More refined disclosure is not the solution to these problems. Warnings and preventive examination for too much complexity are more like it. See Scam Alert! And the CFPB examination manual. “We are all consumers” is a line I hear much too often from lawyers and law professors, and it's about as accurate as “One size fits all.” Disclosure can only do a small amount to advance the core mission of consumer protection, which is to prevent as much exploitation as possible of the most vulnerable consumers. ii. Next a look at a recent action by the Bureau: March, 2014 United States: CFPB Seeks Input On Proposed Model Forms For Prepaid Cards On March 18, 2014, the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau ("CFPB" or the "Bureau") announced that it is seeking feedback about "potential disclosures" that the Bureau "may propose to be used on the packaging of prepaid cards," in connection with an expected rulemaking in the spring. As it has done before, the Bureau is looking to develop a "model form" that would standardize financial product disclosures. Specifically, as to prepaid cards, the Bureau has explained that it wants its model form to "clearly present a prepaid card's most important fees." To this end, the Bureau has begun to consumer test its proposed disclosure forms. In February, the Bureau conducted its first round of interview testing in Baltimore, and on March 18, the Bureau tested its proposed disclosure forms with consumers in Los Angeles. Since its inception, the Bureau has focused its regulatory efforts on product disclosures. Indeed, the Consumer Financial Protection Act, which is Title X of the Dodd-Frank Act, mandates this focus. Section 1032 of the Dodd-Frank Act, 12 U.S.C. §5532, provides that the "Bureau may prescribe rules to ensure that the features of any consumer financial product or service, both initially and over the term of the product or service, are fully, accurately, and effectively disclosed to consumers in a manner that permits consumers to understand the costs, benefits, and risks associated with the product or service." And any final Bureau rule concerning mandated product disclosures also might include a model form that is consumer-tested. Section 1032, in turn, provides that when a "covered person" – that is a bank or nonbank regulated by the Bureau – "uses a model form included with a rule . . . . [that entity] shall be deemed to be in compliance with the disclosure requirements" of the proposed rule. In other words, using the model form provides a legal safe harbor. Any model form will reflect input that addresses the following questions: 1."Do you understand how much each of these cards will cost to use?" 2."What would you like to see added or changed? Is there some way to make the information clearer?" 3."Is there anything you find confusing?" iii. Next a look at What Disclosure Legislation Should Look Like from Consumer Advocates who are else experts in the field. The Truth, the Whole Truth, and Nothing But the Truth: Fulfilling the Promise of Truth in Lending Elizabeth Renuart Albany Law School Diane E. Thompson National Consumer Law Center October 12, 2007 Yale Journal on Regulation, Vol. 25, Summer 2008 Abstract: Evaluating the cost of credit and comparison shopping in the modern credit environment can be a daunting task, even for the most sophisticated shoppers. Lenders increasingly unbundle the costs of their loans from the interest rate into an array of fees, outsource their overhead to third parties who add to the consumer's cost, and unveil amazingly complex loan products that dazzle and confuse borrowers. At the same time, the preemption of state usury and consumer protection laws by Congress and the federal banking agencies spurred deregulation at the state level. Today, the consumer credit marketplace is governed almost exclusively by disclosure rules. The subprime mortgage crisis of 2007 resulted from allowing the market to police itself and from the failure of disclosure to curb abuses. Nearly forty years ago, Congress addressed the problems caused by lack of transparency in credit pricing when it enacted the Truth in Lending Act (TILA). Congress intended to promote informed consumer shopping and a level playing field for lenders by requiring standard disclosure of the cost of credit, most simply through the annual percentage rate (APR) and the finance charges upon which the APR is based. The value of the APR disclosure has deteriorated since 1968 due to exclusions from the finance charge definition created primarily by the Federal Reserve Board. The article documents the history of this decline for the first time and describes the consequences of an APR disclosure that has become incrementally weaker as an indicator of the true cost of the credit. This article draws upon financial literacy, cognitive psychology, and behavioral economics literature to justify the need for a more effective APR. The authors posit a simple litmus test for the finance charge that creates a more effective APR. They discuss why this test is superior to other proposed definitions of the finance charge and respond to arguments that a fee-inclusive APR is unhelpful to consumers and harms the industry. This article is particularly timely because the Federal Reserve Board is currently undertaking a sweeping overhaul of TILA disclosure regulations, including the finance charge definition. Given the state of the credit marketplace, the authors conclude that a robust APR is more critical now than it was in 1968. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1021318 http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1021318 THIS ARTICLE WAS ORIGINALLY PUBLISHED IN VOLUME 25 (SUMMER 2008) OF THE YALE JOURNAL ON REGULATION Xlll. Conclusion The drafters of TILA were aware that disclosures grounded in even basic computational skills were inadequate for most of the population 354 The creation of the APR was an attempt to provide one simple, comparable number that did not require any intermediate computational steps. The credit industry has transformed the market in the intervening forty years through unbundling, outsourcing of credit functions, and complex pricing structures. These changes should not be allowed to undermine a standardized, inclusive measure of the cost of credit. Does "fixing" the APR need congressional attention or can much of the slippage in the effectiveness of the APR be accomplished by Board action? To the extent that the Act contains explicit exceptions to the general finance charge definition, which it does, Congress bears the responsibility of fixing those loopholes. In light of our suggested litmus test, Congress should repeal provisions in section 1605 that exclude credit insurance premiums and certain real estate related fees when imposed only in credit transactions. Short of congressional action, however, the Board can and should pump up the utility of the APR to effectuate the goals of TILA. The responsibility for much of the leakage rests with the Board. The Act also gives the Board the authority to address the timing of the disclosures so consumers can be well informed earlier in the evaluation process. The moment is right, given the regulatory review process commenced by the Board in 2004-a process that is still in its early stages. The Board has already recognized that the APR is weakened by the unbundling of fees. If the Board is serious about financial literacy and informed consumer choice, it should embrace a "fully loaded" APR. iv. Next a letter to the Bureau from a creditor group. THE FINANCIAL SERVICES ROUNDTABLE Financing Americas Economy • HPC HOUSING POLICY COUNCIL March 7, 2013 Mr. Darrin King PRA Office Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection 1700 G Street NW Washington, DC 20552 Re: Quantitative Testing of integrated Mortgage Loan Disclosure Forms Dear Mr. King, The Financial Services Roundtable1 and its Housing Policy Council 2 (collectively, the Roundtable) thank the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (Bureau) for the opportunity to provide comments on the Bureau's proposed quantitative testing of integrated mortgage loan disclosure forms. Disclosures are critical to consumer financial empowerment; clear and effective disclosures can, and should, help consumers understand key terms and the options available to them. Disclosures are especially important in residential mortgage lending inasmuch as buying or refinancing a home typically is the largest financial transaction a consumer undertakes. The Roundtable has consistently supported testing because we believe testing improves the clarity and effectiveness of disclosure. Below are several suggestions that we believe will enhance the Bureau's testing. 1. Focus on the proposed disclosures' impact on consumer understanding of costs and terms We believe that the Bureau's proposed TILA-RESPA forms4 are more effective than the current forms5 and further testing is not needed on this point. Both the Federal Trade Commission and Federal Reserve Board studies have shown that the current TILA disclosures do not help borrowers understand the terms and cost of their loans. And, as the CFPB notes, it cannot establish a "baseline" test because currently there are no combined TILA-RESPA disclosures to test against. The CFPB's proposed forms are, in many respects, improvements over the current forms, but we remain concerned about the amount of information on the forms and whether items such as the "total interest percentage" and "lender's cost of funds" present information that is useful to consumers. Therefore, we encourage the Bureau to focus on consumer understanding of the key loan terms and settlement costs after reviewing the proposed mortgage disclosures. In other words, the testing should explore the extent to which the content in the proposed forms results in consumer understanding of the settlement costs and loan features. 2. Pose objective questions to measure consumer comprehension As proposed, the questions ask respondents to provide qualitative, opinion-based responses. The test asks the respondent to review two mortgage disclosures for different mortgages and then choose which mortgage they would prefer and why. There is no clear fact- or science-based "right" answer to the questions posed, and any choice the respondent makes would be subjective. The questionnaire also includes space for the respondent to explain her reasoning. The Supporting Statement does not explain what criteria the CFPB's contractor will use to evaluate the respondents' choices and explanations nor is it clear how the contractor and CFPB will ensure data derived from the testing is quantitative. To provide a sound basis for decision-making, the questionnaire must include objective questions from which data can be extrapolated and used by the CFPB to make informed decisions about the proposed mortgage disclosures. 3. Adjust methodology and timing The testing involves several variables, including two types of disclosures (current and proposed), two loan types (fixed-rate and adjustable-rate), two loan levels for each loan type (easy-to-understand and difficult-to-understand) and two consumer types (those with no prior mortgage experience and those with prior mortgage experience). The same questionnaire and time limitations are provided in each instance, no matter which type of consumer is given which disclosure for which loan type or level. This one-size-fits-all approach may not fully capture a respondent's understanding of the disclosures. For example, assume a consumer with no mortgage experience is asked to evaluate the current disclosures for a complex adjustable-rate mortgage, while an experienced respondent is evaluating the proposed disclosures for a less complicated fixed rate mortgage. The latter respondent presumably will finish her questionnaire within the allotted time without any difficulty, while the former respondent would likely have difficulty finishing her questionnaire in the allotted time. Respondents who are asked to evaluate more complex disclosures should be allowed additional time to ensure they have sufficient time to express their understanding. 4. Probe consumer's understanding of risk factors. While the Supporting Statement indicates that the survey will evaluate how well the proposed disclosures promote consumer awareness and understanding of risk factors in mortgages,6 only a few questions address that aspect. The Supporting Statement mentions interest-only payments, prepayment penalties, negative amortization, and optional payments as features that present unique risks to consumers, but only three questions ask about these risk features and each is a simple yes/no question.7 These questions do not evaluate whether a consumer understands the actual risk posed by these features or what the outcome might be if a loan has such features. We urge the CFPB to include questions that probe the respondents' understanding of the items it has identified as risk factors. 5. Remove biases in the survey questions and survey population Part 4 of the questionnaire asks respondents to first compare the application disclosure form to the final disclosure form for a given loan. Then, in pairs of questions, the respondents are asked whether various factors in the disclosures are "the same" or are "not the same" and then, in a follow-up question, explain what accounts for the differences. The follow-up question automatically assumes there is a difference between the two forms, and that assumption will likely bias the respondent to answer "not the same" to the first question. All the questions in this part should follow the model used in Question 30 in Part 4, which starts with, "If you answered 'not the same' above," and then asks for a response. This will eliminate the potential bias in the first set of questions. Survey respondents will include those with no mortgage experience, meaning those that have never bought a home but plan to, and those with mortgage experience, meaning those who have bought a home or refinanced in the past 5 years (2008 or 2009). Due to the financial crisis, many potential homebuyers have not engaged in home buying or refinancing in the past 5 years. This 5-year requirement narrows the pool of home buyer respondents to a detrimental degree by excluding those that have not invested in real estate since the market collapse. To prevent this bias, the survey should define those with mortgage experience as those who have bought or refinanced in the past 7 to 10 years. 6. Clarify the survey instructions The testing will be conducted in in-person group sessions of twelve persons or less. Thus, by design, the testing experience of each survey respondent in a group will be different. The Statement of Purpose states that respondents "will be told that each set of materials used by each respondent in the session is different."8 However, the read aloud instructions for the study proctor phrase this fact as conditional; for example, the proctor must say "your documents may look different than those provided to other participants, and you may receive a different number of documents for each part."9 It is natural for test-takers to look around the room to see if other people are finding a test is as hard or easy as they are, or if others are finishing faster or slower than they are. The instructions the proctor reads should include an explicit statement that each set of materials used by each respondent is different. This would alleviate anxiety among respondents. Sincerely, John Dalton President The Housing Policy Council Executive Director, General Counsel v. An Op Ed by a consumer advocate on the Bureau. Thanks largely to new rules from the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, taking out a mortgage is not the risky business it was during the bubble. But it is still the largest and most complex financial transaction in the lives of most people. And it still involves inherent imbalances in expertise between lenders and borrowers, including the use of intermediaries who may or may not be trustworthy. In short, conditions for abuse still exist. That is why the bureau’s new and long-awaited mortgage disclosure forms are important. It is also why they are disappointing. Required by the Dodd-Frank financial reform law, the new forms use an easy-to-read format to disclose complex terms; in addition to clear entries of principal, interest and closing costs, there is information on prepayment penalties and other complicated loan features. But the forms fall short in the crucial task of helping consumers assess and compare the total cost of various loans. Without that information, it is difficult for borrowers to know whether they are getting the best deal. What’s needed, as the National Consumer Law Center has pointed out, is prominent display of the loan’s full annual percentage rate, a single measure of the cost of credit that incorporates the interest rate, closing costs and other fees. On the new forms, that number is not reported until Page 3. Worse, it is calculated in a way that understates the loan’s cost, because it omits the cost of title insurance and some other closing charges. Both the bureau and the Federal Reserve had earlier proposed to include all closing costs in the annual percentage rate. The bureau says it changed its mind because including all costs might reduce the availability of certain kinds of loans. That may be true, but the loans it would restrict, in general, would be higher-priced loans, which would be subject to more regulation than lower priced ones. So lenders who resist regulation may resist offering them — which is as it should be. Better disclosure in itself does not restrict access to credit and, in fact, has been linked to reductions in the cost of credit because transparency fosters competition among lenders. The new disclosures are weaker than the earlier proposal in other ways. The agency had proposed that lenders be required to give borrowers a three-day review period whenever the loan terms were changed. The aim was to ensure that lenders would not spring new loan terms on borrowers at the last minute. The final rule limits but does not eliminate the lenders’ ability to introduce last-minute changes at the closing table. That’s too lenient. Lenders must be held to their promises. The bureau has stumbled on this one. The agency should act quickly to fix the flaws before the new rules and forms take effect, in 2015. vi. An editorial Reining in Payday Lenders By THE EDITORIAL BOARD • At some point — soon, we hope — the Federal Consumer Financial Protection Bureau will issue regulations for the payday lending industry. The bureau took an important step in that direction when it announced earlier this month that it would begin collecting complaints from borrowers who may have been hit with unreasonable fees, unauthorized withdrawals from their checking accounts or other abuses. The bureau should rein in all of these practices, but its most important task is to ensure that the loans are affordable — which means requiring lenders to determine in advance that the borrower has the ability to repay. Payday loans, used by 12 million borrowers annually, are not what they seem. They are advertised as convenient short-term transactions, but in fact the lenders generate profit by trapping borrowers in debt for as long as five months. The way it works is that borrowers take out small loans (averaging $375) and promise to repay the entire amount on payday, typically two weeks later. But only about 14 percent of the borrowers can afford to repay the loan in full, according to a new study by the Pew Charitable Trusts. The rest can only afford to repay part of the loan, which forces them to renew the loan again and again, at a cost of about $50 a pop. In the meantime, lenders often trigger overdraft fees by trying to withdraw money from the accounts of borrowers who have too little on hand to meet the obligation. In the end, the hapless borrower can pay as much as 400 percent in interest. Fifteen states have outlawed such exploitive lending. But the remaining 35 still allow payday lending that requires the full amount to be paid at once. After analyzing data from all over the country, Pew sensibly recommends that state and federal regulators forbid lump-sum repayment requirements, ensure that lenders clearly disclosure terms and require lenders to spread out payments over months rather than weeks. Regulators should also limit high-cost upfront fees, because they create an incentive for lenders to push borrowers into new loans as a way of driving up profit. These changes would mean less profit for the lenders but would protect low-income borrowers from being bled dry. We developed a shorter, simpler credit card agreement that spells out the terms for the consumer. Note that this is not a model form, and use is not mandatory. Our prototype is shown here. We believe our approach will help consumers better understand their credit card agreements. Tell us what you think of it. Review the sample agreement below. (You can also view a PDF copy.) The terms that are underlined in the agreement are defined in a separate list of definitions of credit card contract terms. Click any section of the agreement to learn more about it. Then leave your comments about the agreement or the definitions at the bottom of the page. If you want to see what current agreements look like, check out our Credit Card Agreement Database. II. Financial Literacy a. Financial Literacy Discussion Questions; WHAT IS IT? Why should we teach financial literacy? Which problem is it intended to remedy? How much should we spend on it and what might we expect from it? How shall we teach it? and How shall we measure what we are teaching and its impact and effect. Should we take any of this on faith? If not, how do we prove it and what is the standard? What is the downside of trying it? What are the reasons it may not work? How can it take into account or otherwise deal with new developments in products?? What is the impact of the bankruptcy education program? b. Two views of the value of financial literacy education Anna Lusardi is an outstanding spokesperson for the proponents of financial literacy education and Lauren Willis is the leading spokesperson for those who question the value and the priority of financial literacy education. Please read the following articles by them and make up your own mind. View 1. http://www.chicagofed.org/digital_assets/others/region/foreclosure_resource_center/more _financial_literacy.pdf View 2 selections from . Against Financial-Literacy Education By ABSTRACT: The dominant model of regulation in the United States for consumer credit, insurance, and investment products is disclosure and unfettered choice. As these products have become more complex, consumers’ inability to understand them has become increasingly apparent, and the consequences of this inability more dire. In response, policymakers have embraced financial-literacy education as a necessary corollary to the disclosure model of regulation. This education is widely believed to turn consumers into “responsible” and “empowered” market players, motivated and competent to make financial decisions that increase their own welfare. The vision created is of educated consumers handling their own credit, insurance, and retirement planning matters by confidently navigating the bountiful unrestricted marketplace. Although this vision is seductive, promising both a free market and increased consumer welfare, the predicate belief in the effectiveness of financial-literacy education lacks empirical support. Moreover, the belief is implausible, given the velocity of change in the financial marketplace, the gulf between current consumer skills and those needed to understand today’s complex nonstandardized financial products, the persistence of biases in financial decisionmaking, and the disparity between educators and financial-services firms in resources with which to reach consumers. Harboring this belief may be innocent, but it is not harmless; the pursuit of financial literacy poses costs that almost certainly swamp any benefits. For some consumers, financial education appears to increase confidence without I. INTRODUCTION .......................................................................................199 II. DOES FINANCIAL-LITERACY EDUCATION WORK? ....................................202 A. WHAT IS FINANCIAL-LITERACY EDUCATION? ......................................202 B. WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT THE EFFECTIVENESS OF FINANCIALLITERACY EDUCATION? .....................................................................204 III. IS FINANCIAL-LITERACY EDUCATION LIKELY TO WORK? .........................211 A. INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES AND CHASING MOVING TARGETS ...........212 B. INSURMOUNTABLE KNOWLEDGE, COMPREHENSION, AND NUMERICSKILL LIMITATIONS ...........................................................................219 C. THE PREVALENCE OF BIASES IN PERSONAL-FINANCE DECISIONMAKING ..............................................................................226 1. The Intangible-Transaction-Costs Schematic........................226 2. Overwhelming Information and Choices..............................228 3. High Financial and Emotional Stakes ...................................230 4. Discomforting Thoughts ........................................................234 5. Uncertainty and the Future ....................................................237 6. Opaque Attributes and Incommensurate Tradeoffs ............240 7. The Passivity Alternative: Defaults and “Experts” .................245 8. The Difficulty of Debiasing Personal-Finance Decisionmaking.......................................................................248 a. Poor Conditions for Debiasing ..............................................249 b. Individual Differences..........................................................252 D. REACHING CONSUMERS AT TEACHABLE AND VULNERABLE MOMENTS.........................................................................................253 IV. THE COSTS OF FINANCIAL-LITERACY EDUCATION ..................................260 A. TIME, EXPENSE, AND INEFFICIENT DIVISION OF LABOR.........................261 B. REGULATORY OPPORTUNITY COSTS ...................................................264 C. PARADOXICAL EFFECTS ON CONSUMER DECISIONMAKING ....................272 D. BLAMING THE CONSUMER .................................................................275 V. CONCLUSION ..........................................................................................283 AGAINST FINANCIAL-LITERACY EDUCATION 283 V. CONCLUSION Financial education can be compared to a road map to the American Dream. I believe that we need to teach all Americans the necessary tools to read that map, so that they can reach the Dream. —Secretary of the Treasury Paul O’Neill390 The financial-literacy education policy model locates the problem of and the solution to poor financial outcomes in the consumer, but these can be conceptualized just as easily as part of the choice architecture of personal-finance decisions. Because changing the consumer does not look promising, consumer financial woes are more tractably understood as the result of a government that fails to regulate, an industry that hawks inappropriate products, and a deluge of complex products that change quickly. Nothing is inherently wrong with consumers or the modern marketplace, but the largely deregulated interaction between the two creates welfare-reducing outcomes. Potential general approaches to improve that interaction include substantive prohibitions and mandates, enhancing the resources with which consumers approach the market, changing consumer financial-decision environments, or bringing seller incentives in line with consumer needs.391 Without regulation through education, all is not lost for public policy to improve consumer finances—we do have alternatives, and we should explore them. Nearly every promising public policy to improve consumer credit, insurance, and retirement investment behaviors would limit “choice” in some respect, yet all have the potential to enhance both consumers’ financial outcomes and consumers’ functional autonomy, in terms of reflecting the individual’s own goals and values and providing her with a sense of control over her decisions, actions, environment, and life path. These limits on individual choice present the central paradox of the ownership society in the modern marketplace of consumer financial services: to enhance true consumer autonomy, to give people more ownership and control over their own daily lives and ultimate destinies, requires regulatory interventions in that marketplace that limit formal choice. A stark example is the recent drop in the U.S. homeownership rate. The Federal Reserve Board’s decision not to regulate the subprime- mortgage market allowed consumers to obtain mortgages they could not afford , leading to a net loss of homeownership among users of subprime loans.392 Giving borrowers apparent control over whether, how much, and on what terms they could borrow against their homes has sent many of them to bankruptcy and turned others into renters, with substantially less control over their financial lives and living environment than they had before they obtained these loans. Ultimately, to have true control over their lives, consumers need to have less formal control over some decisions in their lives. The failed social policy of financial-literacy education denies this paradox and diverts attention from more creative approaches to improve consumer financial transactions. The challenge now is to develop and implement policies and legal rules that will reshape the consumer financial- services market into a landscape conducive to good consumer decisions and outcomes. Such regulatory interventions must navigate the heterogeneity of consumer knowledge, skills, and behavioral traits, while at the same time taking care not to hinder marketplace changes that would enhance consumer welfare. All approaches have costs and benefits that must be investigated before wholesale implementation. To be successful, each legal intervention will undoubtedly need to be both context-specific and amenable to change as the market evolves. This is a delicate, challenging, timeintensive and costly task, requiring requisition of the resources currently spent on financial education and more. In an idealized first-best world, where all people are far above average, education would train every consumer to be financially literate and motivate every consumer to use that literacy to make good choices. The costs of the education model would be low enough and the benefits high enough that citizens of the ownership society could flourish, and more rather than less education would be desirable. Regulation through education in such a world promises a free market and increased consumer welfare, seducing conservatives and liberals alike. Unfortunately, such an education is not possible, or, if it were possible, the price of such an education would be so high as to reduce social welfare. In the real, second-best world, less rather than more financial-literacy education may be better.393 The financial-literacy education model is premised on the promise of consumer sovereignty, that consumers can be taught to make welfare- enhancing choices in the insurance, credit, and investment marketplace, trained to read and travel “the road map to the American Dream.” Ironically, the model ensures instead the sovereignty of the market. Overtly, the model is an attempt at social engineering, trying to change not only consumers’ skills, but their thought processes, feelings, motivations, and ultimately their values.394 In the world that financial-literacy education advocates, consumers are but wealth maximizers, looking out for their own financial interests rather than shared societal and civic goals. Covertly, the model dupes consumers into thinking they can master the financial-services market, while placing blame upon them for their failure to do so, deflecting political pressure for change. But changing the personal-finance market or the manner in which consumers must maneuver in it—making the map easier to read and follow, giving them a guide, or building more direct routes to the American Dream— is likely to be more efficacious, and at a lower cost. Consumers can make welfareenhancing choices, but to be truly autonomous, those choices must be made in a context that consumers can navigate. c. Evaluating the effectiveness of financial literacy education. Effects of mandatory financial education on low- income clients J. Michael Collins J. Michael Collins is Assistant Professor of Consumer Science at the University of Wisconsin–Madison, Faculty Director of the Center for Financial Security, and an IRP affiliate. Public policies mandate financial education for financially distressed consumers in a variety of contexts, including bankruptcy and foreclosure, as well as for consumers faced with impending financial decisions. Financial education and counseling are provided in the workplace, in schools, by community groups, and as part of public programs. The impact of financial education on credit behavior is relatively untested. This article summarizes a randomized field study that evaluates a highly targeted mandatory financial education curriculum for very low-income clients in a housing voucher program. Prior research Several studies have documented the extent to which consumers in the United States and other countries fail to demonstrate financial literacy, numeracy, or both.1 Financial knowledge measures tend to be higher for more-educated consumers and lower for lowerincome consumers.2 Con- sumers’ understanding of interest and interest rates tend to be particular areas of weakness.3 One problem in financial literacy research is establishing ac- curate measures of financial knowledge. Many studies utilize self-reported knowledge scales (“how confident are you in your knowledge of…”). At least one study found that people tend to overestimate their financial knowledge relative to what they actually know.4 Thus, studies that rely on selfreported data may yield ambiguous findings. Selection bias is an even more significant problem within existing financial education evaluations.5 Unobserved characteristics including greater motivation and patience levels may drive certain individuals to seek out financial education or counseling. If these same characteristics also facilitate financial success, then selection effects and not financial education may be responsible for positive findings associated with financial literacy education. The types of services examined in previous studies include short programs delivered in the context of a particular deci- sion, more intensive one-to-one counseling, and longerterm formal education programs. The clients targeted are often moderate-income individuals faced with impending financial decisions, such as buying a home, investing for retirement, or correcting credit problems. Few evaluations have analyzed financial education programs targeted to very low-income families, and few have evaluated mandatory financial education programs delivered over several weeks. Furthermore, no evaluations have randomly assigned clients into treatment and control groups, so selection effects may have biased past evaluations. Overall, the evaluation literature suggests that financial edu- cation can help individuals gain financial knowledge and that financial knowledge is linked to financial behavior. Possible outcomes from financial education include greater levels of savings, use of bank accounts, and improved credit behavior. Because of selection effects, however, further studies are needed for better estimates of the causal impacts of financial literacy education. Modeling the effects of financial education The literature on financial literacy education lacks a strong theoretical framework. Most studies rely on a “black box” model such that information or counseling is the input and the expected outcome is a measurable effect on knowledge and/or behavior. In general, theories of behavior change in the financial education field are derived from the health literature. These approaches all emphasize that behavior change results from a combination of attitudes, social norms, and intentions; knowledge gains alone are insufficient. The model of behavior change that underlies this study is based largely on Ajzen’s Theory of Planned Behavior.6 It is expect- ed that housing voucher clients who complete a mandatory financial education program will exhibit greater improve- ments in three areas than a control group. First, consumers who complete a mandatory financial education program are expected to report greater increases in their self-assessed knowledge of financial issues. Second, they are expected to report greater improvements in their attitudes about saving and budgeting. Third, they are expected to exhibit greater improvements in objective measures of financial behavior including credit reports and bank statements. This model is admittedly simplistic, as it does not include social norms and instead assumes that social norms are similar across participants and are unaffected by the financial literacy pro- gram. This model recognizes that knowledge and behavior may interact through unobserved feedback mechanisms. For example, financial knowledge gained through past behavior may influence future behavior. The Long Island Community Development Corporation study I report here on a recent study that addresses some of the deficiencies in the financial education literature. Data for this study were provided by the Community Development Corporation of Long Island, New York (CDCLI). This non- profit agency is the regional administrator of federal rental housing vouchers. Low-income families receive vouchers to subsidize rental payments made to private landlords. Recipi- ents are also enrolled in the federal Family Self-Sufficiency (FSS) program. The FSS program allows families to earn additional income without losing their housing subsidies. All housing voucher clients in the FSS program are required to complete a financial education course, although clients have up to five years to complete the course. The CDCLI created a financial literacy program called “Financial Fit- ness” for these clients. Financial Fitness is delivered over five sessions and covers a range of topics including credit, savings, and budgeting. For this study, 144 very low-income housing voucher clients who needed to take the Financial Fitness course were randomly assigned to either a treatment group (which was required to take the course within one year of randomization) or a control group (which was prohibited from taking the course for one year). The majority of clients in the treatment group completed the five class sessions in one month or less.7 Due to attrition, 17 of the 144 clients who initially agreed to participate in the study were dropped from the final sample. The final sample comprised 60 clients in the treatment group and 67 clients in the control group. Multiple statistical techniques were used to address the differential rate of attrition between the treatment and control groups. Baseline characteristics Table 1 shows that clients in both the treatment and control groups had little savings and poor credit ratings at baseline (FICO scores below 680 are considered “subprime” in this study). Average outstanding debt was higher for the treat- ment group than for the control group, but not at statistically significant levels. However, the treatment group’s mean in- come was significantly higher than the control group’s mean income at baseline. As a reference point, federal guidelines define very low-income as income below 30 percent of an area’s median income, which equates to $24,000 for a family of four in this region (the mean family size for the entire sam- ple is four). A higher percentage of the treatment group had subprime credit scores than the control group (83 percent compared to 73 percent), a difference that was statistically significant at the 10 percent level. The treatment group was also more likely to be employed full time (52 percent com- pared to 39 percent), which was significant at the 10 percent level. Although not reported in Table 1, about one-half of the clients in both groups were African American, one in ten were Latino or Hispanic, and the remaining one-third were white. Two composite indices aggregated questions concern- ing clients’ self-reported financial knowledge and behavior. The statistical models indicate that financial education influnces clients’ self-reported financial knowledge and ulti- mately results in improvements in their financial behaviors. Although this study measured changes in clients’ attitudes and perceptions, these findings were largely nonsignificant and are therefore not reported. Effects are estimated using difference-in-differences specifications across 35 measures. The measures include data from credit reports and bank ac- counts, as well as clients’ responses to baseline and follow- up surveys. The surveys asked clients to rate their financial knowledge and behavior.8 Financial knowledge estimates Based on prior studies, financial knowledge has a strong association with financial behavior. It is expected that cli- ents who completed the financial education program would report greater increases in their understanding of a variety . of financial topics compared to clients in the control group. Clients completed a series of questions about how much they understood interest rates, credit ratings, managing finances, investing, and what is on their credit reports. Responses ranged from “nothing” (0) to “a lot” (4). A composite index was created that aggregates clients’ scores across the self- reported knowledge measures. Figure 1 shows the estimated effect of financial education on the aggregate index, as well as on three specific questions that were statistically signifi- cant. The baseline mean for the composite knowledge index was 1.75, and the difference-in-differences estimation indi- cates that the financial education program led to a 27 percent increase in this index at follow-up (to 2.23). The program was also associated with increases in clients’ knowledge of money management, what is on their credit reports, and current interest rates. Consistent with the program’s scope, Financial Fitness was not associated with improvements in clients’ self-reported knowledge of investing. While these self-reported knowledge gains are promising, the program’s ultimate goal was facilitating behavior change. Financial behavior estimates Clients answered a series of questions about their self- reported financial behaviors. Responses to these questions ranged from “poor” (0) to “excellent” (4). A composite index aggregates clients’ responses to the self-reported behavior questions. Figure 2 shows the estimated impact of the Financial Fitness program on the self-reported behavior index, as well as on three specific behaviors that were statistically significant. The mean score on the composite index was 1.22 at baseline. The statistical analysis indicates that the financial education program led to a 38 percent increase in the composite score at follow-up (to 1.68). Clients’ self-reported ability to control their spending, pay their bills on time, and budget were also significantly higher at follow-up. Savings account and credit report data contain two objective measures of clients’ financial behavior. The mean savings balance was $286 at baseline. The regression analysis indi- cates that the Financial Fitness program led to an increase of $362 in savings, an increase that was significant at the 1 percent level. Over one-third of the curriculum used in this study focused on managing credit and debt, a typical topic for courses provided to low-income families. Credit report data include a FICO score—named for the Fair Isaac Corporation, which developed the score. FICO scores range from 300 to 800 and are based on a proprietary formula using multiple variables contained in the credit report, including the number of accounts, amount and age of debt, and share of available credit in use by the individual. The statistical analysis indicates that the financial education program led to a statistically significant decrease in the percentage of clients with credit scores in the subprime range (again defined as 680 in this study). The marginal effect of the financial edu- cation program on the percentage of clients with subprime credit scores was estimated to be a decrease of 13 percent. Improvements in credit scores may allow clients to qualify for lower interest rates and help clients access additional credit. Discussion The Financial Fitness program was designed to help clients access basic banking services, learn budgeting skills, boost savings, and repair credit problems. This study shows that financial literacy education is indeed related to improved financial behavior among the program’s very low-income clients. The primary evidence of behavior change is the sig- nificant increase in savings account balances (an additional $362), as well as the modest decrease in the percentage of clients whose FICO scores were below 680. Clients’ self- reported knowledge gains were also greater for the treatment group than for the control group, especially in the areas of credit and money management. In contrast to the improve- ments in clients’ financial knowledge and behavior, the findings concerning financial attitudes were largely nonsignifi- cant. In the end, many of the findings are surprisingly robust given the relatively small sample size and the weak impacts reported in past studies. This study has several advantages over previous studies. It includes objective measures of behavior from bank accounts and credit reports, rather than relying solely on selfreported data. The financial education program was mandatory, which reduces the potential bias introduced when clients select into a program. Clients were randomly assigned to the treatment group or the waitlisted control group. This design minimizes concerns about withholding services, and randomization allows for better causal estimates than descriptive (e.g., pre-post) or quasi-experimental evaluations. Furthermore, the one-year follow-up period gave clients enough time to incorporate knowledge gains into their behavior. Behavior changes could then be documented in credit report and bank account data. Finally, because clients were enrolled in a housing voucher subsidy program, they were closely monitored and data were regularly available as part of the program’s administrative process. Despite these advantages, several caveats are worthy of discussion. Generalizing these results to other programs requires caution. Because clients’ initial financial circumstances were particularly dire, they may have responded more strongly to financial education than consumers with more stable financial situations. On the other hand, administrative notes suggest that clients experienced a variety of obstacles including domestic violence, unstable employment, drug and alcohol abuse, and problems finding and maintaining adequate day care. Given the array of problems clients confronted, one may expect that the Financial Fitness course would have more limited impacts. This study is also specific to very low-income households in a housing subsidy pro- gram that included a financial self-sufficiency component, which raises further questions about the study’s generaliz- ability. Because clients were enrolled in other programming, they may respond differently to financial education than cli- ents who are enrolled in housing subsidy programs that lack a self-sufficiency component, or clients who are not part of any type of housing subsidy program. There are also problems related to the study’s design. First, the sample is small and was reduced considerably by the consent process and attrition. The effects of consent and attrition are only partially observable. While an analysis of the consent process indicated that it did not bias the results, attrition was not random. Clients in the treatment group were more likely to leave the program. While the statistical mod- els included observable characteristics in order to minimize attrition bias, the models cannot account for unobserved characteristics related to clients’ decisions to leave the pro- gram. The second problem with the design is that members of the control group were aware of their participation in the study. The consent process alerted clients that they needed to complete the Financial Fitness course. Clients who were waitlisted and told they could not attend Financial Fitness classes for one year may have reacted to this information in ways that affected their survey responses and even their behavior. For example, clients in the control group may have initially intended to create a budget but upon being waitlisted decided to wait until they took the course. Program staff suggested that while some clients were excited about the program, most clients viewed it as just another requirement to remain eligible for their housing vouchers. Nonetheless, the design may have introduced some unobserved bias. Directions for future research This study has three primary implications. First, mandating financial education can have positive effects on savings and credit outcomes among very low-income individuals. Finan- cial education can also lead to improvements in clients’ self- reported understanding of financial issues. If increasing sav- ings levels and improving credit outcomes are policy goals, then incorporating mandatory financial education courses into public programs may be a successful public policy. Second, from a social welfare perspective, mandatory fi- nancial education programs may lead to improvements in savings levels and credit quality that are more valuable than the costs of service delivery. Additional benefits will be realized as improvements in clients’ credit ratings yield lower borrowing costs and greater access to credit. To the extent that financial education can be delivered at a cost equal to or below its marginal benefit, financial education is a good investment of public and private resources if improving low- income families’ financial status is a policy goal. Third, this study indicates that if influencing clients’ attitudes and perceptions is deemed important—and the literature suggests beliefs are a precursor to behavior change—then the content of financial literacy efforts should focus more on examining attitudes toward spending, saving, incurring debt, and taking financial risks. Providers of such courses should focus on the use of debt, planning for financial risks, and weighing the costs and benefits of taking on various types of debt versus paying off existing debt or saving. Teaching “values” is challenging, however, and may require innova- tive new approaches. It may also be possible to complement educational efforts with longer-term “coaching” services. Using regular check-ins, a financial coach can help clients implement the skills and knowledge they gain from formal financial education programs, as well as monitor clients’ progress over time. Coaches can help clients formulate and achieve financial goals and provide support for maintaining desired behaviors.9 Programs could also use peer groups as a sup- port structure to help clients adhere to financial goals and develop positive attitudes about money and savings. These approaches may help provide selfcontrol and impose con- straints on people who want to save and pay off debt, but who have difficulty putting their newfound knowledge and skills into action. Future research on financial literacy education could expand on these findings by examining longer time periods. A longer study period would allow for further analysis of the impact of financial education on credit and savings outcomes. Given the increased risk of attrition as the study period is lengthened, however, such an approach would require a substantially larger initial sample to allow for more extensive modeling.n 1For a review, see A. Lusardi and O. Mitchell, “Financial Literacy and Retirement Preparedness: Evidence and Implications for Financial Education,” Business Economics, 42, No. 1 (2007), 35–44. 2J. Agnew and L. R. Szykman, “Asset Allocation and Information Overload: The Influence of Information Display, Asset Choice and Investor Experience,” Journal of Behavioral Finance, 6, No. 2 (2005): 57–70. 3D. Moore, Survey of Financial Literacy in Washington State: Knowledge, Behavior, Attitudes, and Experiences, Technical Report No. 03-39, Social and Economic Sciences Research Center, Washington State University, 2003. 4Agnew and Szykman, “Asset Allocation and Information Overload.” 5S. Meier and C. Sprenger, Selection into Financial Literacy Programs: Evidence from a Field Study, Policy Discussion Papers, Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 2007. 6I. Ajzen, “From Intentions to Actions: A Theory of Planned Behavior,” in J. Kuhl and J. Beckmann (Eds.), Action Control: From Cognition to Behavior (pp. 1 l–39) (Heidelberg: Springer, 1985). 7Completing the course was mandatory. All clients were required to fill out baseline and follow-up surveys. The follow-up survey was administered 12 months after the baseline data collection for each client. The sample was completed in September 2007. Clients received a total of $60 dollars if they completed both surveys ($30 each survey). 8The original paper uses three difference-in-differences specifications, only one of which is reported in this article. The first specification is a traditional difference-in-differences experimental estimator. This approach estimates the difference in changes between the treatment and control groups from baseline to follow-up, using an indicator for assignment into the treatment group. The second specification uses propensity score matching to weight the traditional difference-in-differences experimental estimator. This speci- fication attempts to balance the treatment and control groups due to the differential level of attrition. The third specification, reported here, includes control variables to account for differences in the baseline values for each group that may be associated with the intensity of other services received. In most cases the results become more robust using the weighted estimator with controls, as might be expected. 9See, for example, A. Minzner, .S. Hebert, A. St. George, and L. LoConte, Evaluation of the CWF Coaching Pilot (Cambridge, MA: Abt Associates, Inc., 2006). FOCUS is a Newsletter put out up to two times a year by the Institute for Research on Poverty 1180 Observatory Drive 3412 Social Science Building University of Wisconsin Madison, Wisconsin 53706 (608) 262-6358 Fax (608) 265-3119 The Institute is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, university-based research center. As such it takes no stand on public policy issues. Any opinions expressed in its publications are those of the authors and not of the Institute. The purpose of Focus is to provide coverage of poverty- related research, events, and issues, and to acquaint a large audience with the work of the Institute by means of short essays on selected pieces of research. Full texts of Discussion Papers and Special Reports are available on the IRP Web site. Focus is free of charge, although contributions to the UW Foundation–IRP Fund sent to the above address in support of Focus are encouraged. Edited by Emma Caspar Copyright © 2010 by the Regents of the University of Wis- consin System on behalf of the Institute for Research on Poverty. All rights reserved. Do Financial Education Programs Work? by lan Hathaway and Sameer Khatiwada April2008 Do Financial Education Programs Work? by Ian Hathaway and Sameer Khatiwada In this paper we provide a comprehensive critical analysis of research that has investigated the impact of financial education programs on consumer financial behavior. In light of the evidence, we recommend that future programs be highly targeted towards a specific audience and area of financial activity (e.g. home- ownership or credit card counseling, etc.), and that this training occurs just before the corresponding financial event (e.g. purchase of a home or use of a credit card, etc.). Similarly, in light of a Jack of evidence, we also recommend that program evaluation be taken as an essential element of any program, and that it be included in the design of the programs before they are introduced. Jan Hathaway is a senior policy analyst in the Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. He can be reached at ian.hathaway@clev.frb.org. Sameer Khatiwada is a candidate for master of public policy at the John F. Kennedy School of Government at Harvard University and a former intern at the Bank. He can be reached at sameer_khatiwada@ksg08.harvard.edu. The authors describe five major steps they believe should be included when evaluating financial education programs: pre-implementation (and needs assessment), accountability, program clarification, progress towards objectives, program impact. In the pre-implementation stage, the target group is identified, needs are assessed, and goals are specified. Administering literacy tests on the target group is a good proxy for a needs assessment. General indicators of needs could be high rates of non-business bankruptcy filings, defaults on loans, and high consumer debt levels, among others. The accountability stage involves the collection of information on education and services provided, program cost, and basic information on program participants. The objective here is to determine who has been reached by the program and in what way; that is, whether the population in need is the population actually served. The program clarification stage helps the program planners review an ongoing program's goals and objectives and assess whether these goals and objectives should be revised. Next, the progress towards objectives stage involves obtaining objective measures (quantified data) of the impact of the program on the participants, and how those impacts relate to program goals. Finally, the program impact stage involves an experimental approach (comparing sample and control groups) to assess both the short-term and long-term effects of the program. Information collected in the previous stage (progress towards objectives) helps assess whether there were long-term and short-term effects. According to the authors, there is scarce evidence of evaluation of financial literacy programs at the final stage (program impact) because most financial education programs do not include impact evaluation as a component of their program design. 5. Conclusions So, do financial education programs work? The answer is: we can't say for sure one way or the other.Working backwards in our framework (see Figure 1), it does appear as though financial knowledge (i.e., financial literacy) does in fact lead to better financial behavior. This of course brings us to the question of whether those who are financially illiterate (i.e. lacking knowledge) are able to fill these knowledge gaps with financial education programs. Unfortunately, we do not find conclusive evidence that, in general, financial education programs do lead to greater financial knowledge, and ultimately, to better financial behavior. However, this is not the same as saying that they do not nor could not - it is just that current studies, while at times illustrating some success, leave us with an unclear feeling about whether we can grant a blanket application of these results specifically, to financial education programs more generally. There are two likely reasons that we don't see the conclusive evidence on the effectiveness of financial education programs that we are looking for. One possibility is that the programs are simply not effective at transferring knowledge. That is, it is not that financial education programs could not work, but rather, it is that they do not work, perhaps because they are poorly designed or administered. A second explanation is that because the formal evaluations of the programs that we examined earlier were completed ex post, it is the inability of these evaluations to capture whether the programs worked or not. The point here is that we just don't know if the programs are not working or if we' just don't understand whether they are working because they are not being evaluated properly. In light of this, we offer two suggestions for improving the impact of financial education programs on consumer behavior. First, while the overall evidence in favor of financial education remains unclear, we do see a pattern that highly targeted programs, unlike general programs, tend to be effective in changing people's financial behavior. As a result, we contend that programs should be highly targeted toward a specific audience and area of financial activity (e.g. home-ownership or credit card counseling, etc.), and that this training occurs just before the corresponding financial event (e.g. purchase of a home or use of a credit card, etc.). Secondly, we recommend that including formal program evaluation methods in the design of the program itself is critical in being able to measure whether the programs are achieving intended outcomes. As we stated before, the evidence in favor of financial education programs is unclear, and a major reason for this could simply lie in the measurement of impacts. It is critical that we get a handle on what works and what doesn't; effective program evaluation can do this. Finally, we note that research on effectiveness of financial education is relatively new, and thus limited. Similarly, it hasn't been until recently that we have seen important advances in better understanding household financial decisions; that is, how households decide how much to spend, how much to save, how to invest that savings, and ultimately, and how to finance these investment portfolios through some combination of income and borrowing.10 Progress on research in these areas is important because we need to understand how consumers behave and how they make decisions in the area of personal finance. Understanding this is critical in order to design programs that will influence these behaviors for better financial outcomes. Similarly, better understanding what works and what does not in financial education programs, through program evaluation and experimentation, is crucial in successfully filling financial knowledge gaps. 10 For more, see Campbell (2006), Guiso, Haliassos and Japelli (2002), and Athreya (2007) C, A study of counseling provided to consumers in financial distress. i. An assignment to be done in class. You and the other members of your group are staff to a Senator and have been given an assignment regarding consumer credit education. Please spend the first five minutes of your time becoming better acquainted with one another by each stating your name and answering a question such as: What is your favorite all time law school course or your least favorite all time law school course? Altogether you will have fifty minutes to develop your response to the Senator. After that time each of the three groups will report to the class and we will discuss each of the reports. Each group has been asked to develop a consumer credit course for a particular segment of society and we will compare and evaluate the similarities and differences for each target segment. We will spend about forty minutes making the reports and discussing them. Congress is about to pass a new bankruptcy law and the chair of the key committee in the Senate has become aware that in Canada bankruptcy debtors must go through an educational program in order to receive a bankruptcy discharge of their unsecured debts. You and your fellow group members are staff to this Senator and you must draft a memo to her indicating The following with regard to the curriculum for the bankruptcy education program. 1. What would be the goal of requiring bankruptcy debtors to take the course? 2. What topics would you cover and how would you cover them? 3. What problems do you believe you would encounter in developing and teaching this curriculum? 4. How would you evaluate whether the course is successful? ii. Study Questions What is the value of counseling and who should receive it? First time home buyers? People in default? People who file bankruptcy? What are we trying to do? What is the problem it is intended to remedy? Is it intended to change conduct; what can we learn from health issues? Bankruptcy debtors are required to obtain a “briefing” from a curtained counseling agency within six months before they file or their filing is defective. They are also required to receive an educational session from a certified provider before they receive their discharge. iii. Who are the counselors? Please read the following articles. NORTON BANKRUPTCY LAW ADVISER MAY 2010 Has SUN SET ON TRADITIONAL CREDIT COUNSELING AND IS THAT GOOD, BAD OR BOTH WHAT WILL RISE IN ITS PLACE? David Lander Thompson Coburn St. Louis, MO The 1990s were the heyday of the consumer credit counseling industry. Twenty years before, retail creditors and early credit card lenders had combined to equip a series of separate nonprofit organizations with the wherewithal to help both consumers and creditors. Consumers worried about their debt but not yet in serious difficulty received advice about paying bills and budgeting purchases and that advice was generally without charge (financial counseling only or FCO). Consumers often got relief from worry from FCO and creditors were satisfied because counseled consumers were less likely to default. Consumers with debt problems too serious to be solved by FCO were "sold" a free debt man- agreement plan (DMP). By pre-arrangement, most creditors offered valuable interest rate and installment concessions in return for enrollment in a 1 00% payment plan for unsecured creditors. Consumers for whom a DMP was the right choice benefitted from the concessions and from the fact that the agency dealt with all of their creditors. It was a great deal for creditors because it turned likely defaulters into likely payers. About the same percentage of folks who typically complete Chapter 13 plans would complete DMPs. The DMP was so valuable to creditors that they returned what they called "Fair Share" payments back to the agencies. From 1970 to the mid 1990s those•Fair Share payments (others labeled them collection fees) amounted to 15% of the amount collected. Miraculously, this was enough to allow the agencies that marketed effectively and operated efficiently to provide both. "advice only" and debt management plan administration without charging the consumer a direct out-of-pocket fee. The agencies claimed to provide education and budgeting help to consumers as well. It turned out that 15% was a bit rich. The fat in Fair Share could have inspired the agencies to provide enhanced and improved services, but instead it led to a host of problems including bloated executive salaries, perverse incentives for new entrants and growing skepticism from creditors and consumers. As consumer credit, especially credit card debt, expanded exponentially and defaults skyrocketed, Fair Share payments skyrocketed as well. Attracted by this pot of gold, entrepreneurial types who cared little about consumers or creditors flocked into the credit counseling business and found ways to take money from both-by advertising expansively and deceptively and selling everyone who walked in the door their most profitable item, a DMP. These new agencies often masqueraded as § 50l(c)(3) tax exempt nonprofits in order to comply with state Jaws but found creative ways of using excess revenue to line their own pockets. After several years of abuses, the IRS and states' attorneys general, led by Consumer -Federation of America and National Consumer Law Center, ran many, but not all of the "bad guys" out of the credit counseling business. As the clean up progressed, old-line agencies switched from face-to-face interviewing to phone banks and internet contacts, and the largest of them swallowed up many of the others. The result was an industry with a small number of very large providers using phone banks that hardly resembled the "counseling" and education they previously purported to offer. Creditors did not stand still through all these changes in the counseling industry. In response to too many sales of DMPs to consumers who did not need them, creditors developed criteria that qualified consumers for D.MP concessions. As the credit card industry consolidated, the larger lenders developed in-house concession pro- grams which bypassed the counseling agencies and avoided DMP Fair Share. These lenders reduced their Fair Share payments (which for some had become their second largest expense item) in several steps from 150;(, to about 5% of collections and reconceived this reduced Fair Share as grants tied to complex formulas.' The IRS crackdown on the phony nonprofits led the IRS to scrutinize all of the providers. The IRS rejected the characterization that a DMP was charitable or educational and it probed the complex relationship between the counseling agencies and creditors. At the height of these investigations and the resulting outrage, Congress chimed in-prohibiting the IRS from granting§ 50l(c)(3) status to agencies that relied too heavily on DMP Fair Share revenue. Although the relationship between counseling agencies and creditors has hardened considerably, it remains robust. Even today, some large creditors continue to refer selected customers to a few of the largest phone bank agencies, at least one of which was severely and justifiably embarrassed at a congressional hearing by the astounding salaries paid to multiple family members whose job responsibilities were obscure. Perhaps the starkest implication of all this change was the devastating reduction in the revenue of the surviving agencies. Fair Share had been cut by two thirds, there were fewer opportunities for a DMP and there was no money to provide financial counseling without a revenue source. Because their educational and counseling missions had always been suspect, the agencies had few friends in the consumer movement These factors dominated the period from the late 1990s to 2005 when two important developments occurred. The first was passage of amendments to the Bankruptcy Code which became effective in October 2005. Credit card lenders convinced Congress that many "unnecessary" bankruptcies could be prevented if consumers were required to obtain a "briefing" before they were eligible for bankruptcy and that repeat bankruptcy filings could be reduced if the discharge was conditioned on debtors completing "an instructional course concerning personal financial management" When the Executive Office of the United States Trustee advertised for honest providers of these briefing and instructional services, the folks first to come forward and to be accepted were cred- it counseling agencies that were nonprofit and seemed legitimate. There is considerable debate whether the statutory services are useful to debtors or creditors, but there is no doubt that these requirements have provided a new and badly needed source of revenue for the traditional agencies. Indeed, in 2008, nearly 25% of the "counseling" sessions provided by agencies affiliated with the National Foundation for Consumer Counseling (NFCC) related to the compulsory requirements of the Bankruptcy. Abuse Prevention and Cm1sun1er Protection Act of 2005. As competition among the providers for bankruptcy debtors has somewhat reduced the fees for these services, bankruptcy briefings and instructional courses have become a less robust source of replacement revenue for the agencies. The second recent revenue enhancing opportunity was precipitated by the devastating explosion of home foreclosures. Some credit counseling agencies had historically provided !-IUD first-time home buyer counseling as well as FHA counseling for homeowners who were behind on their mortgages. One major difference between housing counseling and credit card counseling is the source of funding. Much of the housing counseling is paid for by the federal government through a contract with an entity known as Neighborworks. When foreclosures exploded, Neighborworks needed more counseling capacity throughout the country. The credit counseling agencies had counselors, needed more customers and very much needed the revenue that these customers would provide. By 2008, foreclosure counseling constituted 50% of the counseling sessions pro- vided by NFCC member agencies. These sessions are primarily diagnostic to determine whether a consumer fits an available foreclosure forbearance program. Interestingly, there has been very limited independent evaluation of the "value" to consumers•of this type of counseling. So, where does this leave consumers worried about their debts, but for whom foreclosure forbearance is not relevant or realistic and who do not wish to file bankruptcy? Consider their plight and thought process as they watch late-night television; unable to sleep. First, they see the ad for a consumer bankruptcy attorney; then they see the ad for a credit counseling agency; finally, they are captivated by a new entrant to the mix-the loud, slick promo full of largely false promises by a Debt Settlement Provider (DSP). Indeed, as advertising by bankruptcy attorneys and credit counseling agencies has diminished, debt settlement industry ads have exploded. DSPs promise the magic that every consumer wants and which the credit counseling industry cannot honestly offer: the elimination of most credit card debt. After watching the three ads, it is no wonder that droves of consumers are succumbing to the false promises of debt settlement. The community of DSPs asserts it provides a valuable service to over-indebted consumers. Not surp1isingly, the community of credit counseling agencies thinks that DSPs do not provide valuable services and charge too much for whatever they do. The consumer advocacy community is appalled by the viral growth of DSPs. The March 20 I 0 issue of Consumer Reports warns consumers away from DSPs. The Consumer Federation of America, the National Consumer Law Center and Consumers Union have joined efforts to inform consumers precisely how little the industry offers, how much it charges and to seek regulatory prohibition of some dangerous practices. The Federal Trade Commission is involved in rule making that would require changes in the way DSPs charge and provide services. Attorneys General of several states have closed down large providers and others are engaged in enforcement activities. Ironically, at the same time the debt settlement industry is experiencing severe criticism, it is having marked success convincing state legislatures to provide a debt settlement industry friendly environment. Granted, there are renegade outliers in the debt settlement industry that even the mainstream of the industry opposes. Still, the almost universal use of high-volume advertising, the get-rid-of- debt-quick promises, the large, up-front fees and the high failure rates make it hard to believe that there is any magic for consumers in the rising DSP tide. So, for those for whom foreclosure forbearance is not relevant, the choice is between bankruptcy, debt settlement or credit counseling. For those about to lose their house or car or whose debt is clearly beyond their ability to pay, bankruptcy along with a good bankruptcy lawyer is the only viable alternative. At the margins; folks who won't consider bankruptcy and those less in need of bankruptcy who might benefit from lender concessions should undertake direct negotiations with card issuers or engage a reputable credit counseling agency to develop a DMP. It is possible to conceive of an industry, expert at extracting debt reduction concessions that most consumers could not realize alone, that advertises honestly and charges fairly. Unfortunately, that is not the debt settlement industry that exists today or that is likely to exist in the near future. Over indebted consumers who want help understanding bow to live within their means or who want to change their behaviors need advice from professionals in an industry that also does not presently exist. The credit counseling industry might have shifted to fill this gap in the late 1990s when they were awash with cash, but they were never sufficiently consumer-client-centered, they had insufficiently trained staff, paid salaries that were too low, and did too little quality training or evaluation. Certainly there are individual counselors who combine commitment with quality skills and a consumerclient-centered approach, but the current configuration of phone banks and limited time and skills make this the exception. The consumer debt crash has created an environment in which social work schools or business schools might develop curriculums and a career path for students who would work in this "future" and badly needed profession. High quality client- based nonprofit human service providers such as the Financial Clinic in New York and the Centers for Working Families program funded by the Annie Casey Foundation offer a model for this profession and perhaps could hire the first generation of "to be trained professionals." A few of the best and most ambitious of the existing credit counseling and housing counseling agencies might also rise to the occasion. All of this will require a level of rigorous evaluation that is currently absent across the board in housing and credit card counseling. The past couple of years has seen an explosion of prestigious business and other professional schools launching efforts to bring scholarly research and publication to consumer indebtedness. They are a discipline looking for a purpose and perhaps they will help fill this gap. Social Workers and Financial Capability in the Profession's First Half-Century PAUL H. STUART During the post-World War II suburbanization of the United States, as families moved from the working class into the middle class, from cities to the suburbs, and from renting to owning homes, they incurred debt in a variety of new ways. These debts-incurred through home mortgages and time purchases of house- hold appliances, furniture, and recreational goods and services-meant that the new middle-class lifestyle was "sustained by a heavy bet on the future-long-term mortgages for the home, the installment plan for the future" (Wilensky & Lebeaux, 1965, p. 113). For millions of families, middle-class incomes depended on two jobs and, often, overtime pay. In addition, the prosperity of the post-World War II era was unevenly distributed, and there were barriers to the social mobility that had at first appeared to be within the grasp of all. As borrowers were encouraged to take on more debt than they could sustain, new problems and "new opportunities for service" arose, as detailed in Industrial Society and Social Welfare by Wilensky and Lebeaux (1965, p. 174). They cite an examination of the finances of 83 middle-income young suburban couples, who "prefer the high-interest installment plan to the free charge account[s]" often pro- vided by stores. The couples "show colossal indifference to and ignorance of 12 and 18% interest rates of revolving credit plans' at the department store" (p. 175). In response to these trends, Wilensky and Lebeaux (1965) advocate that family service agencies should undertake "skilled, hardheaded advisement of clients in the purchase of homes and expensive commodities" for the "increasing numbers of people" experiencing "real problems." Prescient as this observation seems today, the half-century following the pub- lication of Industrial Society and Social Welfare saw only isolated attempts to incorporate building clients' financial capability into social work practice. In part, social work practice followed social policy. The New Frontier and Great Society programs of the 1960s focused on social services to prepare clients for the work force and political mobilization. After Richard Nixon's victory in the presidential election of 1968, job training programs and income supports became ascendant. Although social work practice theorists considered environmental modification a promising intervention, this has usually meant the social worker acting to modify the environment on behalf of the client rather than the social worker acting to help clients increase their financial capability. In 1973, Richard M. Grinnell Jr., called for a renewal of environmental modi- fication by social caseworkers. His definition of environmental modification included "enriching the environment through provision of new stimuli, outlets, resources, and services" and "helping the individual make profitable use of these opportunities and inputs" (p. 219). While this definition would have been quite compatible with interventions designed to create institutions to promote increased financial capability, Grinnell did not include such interventions. Similarly, Kemp, Whittaker, and Tracy (1997) did not explicitly discuss building clients' financial capability in their otherwise excellent exposition of personenvironment practice, an approach to social work practice. Wilensky and Lebeaux (1965) presented the idea of social workers doing finan- cial counseling as something new, a response to the unprecedented growth of the suburban middle class, fueled by industrial expansion. However, a glance at the history of social work practice suggests that social workers and their predecessors in state charities, private charity organizations, and settlement houses were heavily invested in building the financial capability of their clients in the Gilded Age and Progressive Era, through advice-giving, financial education, and the creation of new institutions for saving and borrowing. As Charlotte Towel observed in 1930, "In the long life of social work, one is aware of fluctuating emphases ... Back and forth the pendulum swings [but] change does not necessarily imply growth; it may imply regression" (p. 341). This chapter will review social workers' concern with clients' financial capability in the profession's early history, explore the decline of professional concern for financial capability, and conclude with the importance of building client financial capability today. The interest of early social workers in financial capability originated from the mission of the emerging social work profession-the alleviation and prevention of poverty (Popple & Reid, 1999). Often expressing their goals in moralistic terms, early social workers attempted to build up the financial capability of families and neighborhoods in a society that was experiencing increasing disparities in wealth and income, even as the average wages of industrial workers were rising. Building financial capability, social workers believed, would secure the financial position of poor people, smoothing out the swings of good times and bad that seemed to characterize their clients' lives. Social work as an occupation originated during a period of crisis in American society. Urbanization, immigration, and industrialization resulted in increasing and seemingly unbridgeable chasms between urban and rural people, between rich and poor, native-born and immigrants, and Protestants, Catholics, Christians, and Jews (Addams, 1893b). In a period of increasing crisis, social workers, like other progressives, attempted to heal the rifts in the society by providing practical advice (in Charity Organization Societies), by being good neighbors (in settlement houses), or by saving children (in nascent public and private child welfare agencies) (Stuart, 1999a). Unlike child welfare workers, charity organization and settlement workers regarded themselves as generalist practitioners-they engaged with clients or neighbors about a range of problems that the clients or neighbors were experiencing and attempted to resolve those problems. As was the case with child welfare workers, many of the problems encountered by charity organization and settlement workers resulted from poverty, so service to the poor, specifically finding ways to prevent poverty and bring the poor out of poverty, dominated professional discussions at the turn of the twentieth century. Charity organization societies (COS) and settlement houses were established in most American cities between 1880 and 1910. Charity organization societies attempted to organize charitable giving, directing assistance to those found to be "truly needy" and studying the causes of poverty. Settlement house residents moved into immigrant neighborhoods, becoming neighbors of the poor; neigh- borliness would result, it was hoped, in bridging the gaps between social classes. As Jane Addams (1893a), put it, Hull House was started in the belief that the mere foothold of a house, easily accessible, ample in space, hospitable and tolerant in spirit, situated in the midst of the large foreign colonies which so easily isolate themselves in American cities, would be in itself a serviceable thing for Chicago. Hull House endeavors to make social intercourse express the growing sense of the economic unity of society (p. 27). Both charity workers and settlement residents emphasized the development of financial capability. Settlement house residents helped organize the Women's Trade Union League in 1903 as a means to improve the working conditions and pay of women workers (Davis, 1964). Josephine Shaw Lowell, the secretary of the Charity Organization Society of the City of New York (NYCOS), argued that all workers needed a living wage, one that made it possible "to secure what they have learned to consider the necessaries of life" (Lowell, 191lb, p. 412). She enjoined friendly visitors to make special efforts to persuade the family to prepare for the future and to lay by for the idle time of the next year; [they] can then inculcate lessons in economy and in saving which may be the means of lifting the family permanently on to a higher level than they would ever have attained without [the visitors'] friendly encouragement (Lowell, 19lla, pp. 147-148). Emphasizing thrift and savings, then, seemed a key to solving the problem of poverty. Poor people needed access to financial institutions. Charity organizations promoted what we would call today the empowerment of the poor, as well as providing good advice and persuasion; Lowell argued that workers needed to organize labor unions to secure decent compensation. In 1890, she founded the New York Consumers' League, an organization that pressured employers to improve the wages and working conditions of women workers in New York City. Nine years later, Lowell and other members of the New York Consumers' League helped establish the National Consumers' League. THRIFT AND SAVINGS Thrift was a catchword of charity organizations; visitors were instructed to use their influence to guide families, and especially husbands, in the direction of savings and careful budgeting. Lowell (1884) outlined a variety of provident schemes that would "help people to help themselves" (p. 109). She pointed out that savings banks, by the 1880s "immense business enterprises;' had been initiated in Europe during the eighteenth century as charitable enterprises, a way to help poor people manage their financial resources. In the United States, savings banks were established early in the nineteenth century, many of them by reformers. By the 1870s, savings banks held "between a quarter and a third of all the wealth in all the financial institutions in the country" (Wadhwani, 2006, pp. 126-127). Mary Richmond, secretary of the Baltimore Charity Organization Society (COS), advised friendly visitors to develop habits of thrift among the poor. Thrift was not a "merely economic" virtue, but an indication of a person's optimism and self-commitment. Visitors could advocate thrift "for both economic and moral reasons" (Richmond, 1899, pp. 108, 110). In the 1880s and 1890s, charity organization societies created savings banks, small loan programs, and pawnshops for the poor as alternatives to commercial enterprises that often exploited or ignored the poor. Savings was a necessary aspect of thrift, according to Mary Willcox Brown (1899), who was to succeed Mary Richmond as secretary of the Baltimore COS. Savings institutions were essential; the savings bank was "educational because it shows an improvident class the need of foresight; a thriftless body the utility of being frugal. It is educational because it teaches men to be independent and trains children to recognize the power they have of accumulating a small capital" (p. 71). Based on a successful experiment initiated by the Charity Organization Society of Newport, Rhode Island, in 1879, the Castleton Charity Organization Society, on New York's Staten Island, created a savings society for its clients in 1883. According to Anne Townsend Scribner (1887), of the Castleton COS, "The main objects gained... by the introduction of the Savings Society are two: first, the inculcation of thrift; and, second, the aid to friendly visitors which the society offers. To raise the needy above the need of relief is one of the first principles of the Charity Organization Societies. That the Savings Society is a wonderful aid in this work of helping the poor to help themselves has been proved beyond question by the society's work on Staten Island" (p. 144). The savings plan was simple; volunteer collectors visited families weekly to collect a prearranged amount to be saved, providing a receipt for the deposit. Once deposited, the funds could be withdrawn at any time, as needed for emergencies or when the amount saved was enough for a major purchase. Like industrial life insurance policies that were marketed to the poor beginning in the 1870s, the savings plan provided a form of budgeting that enabled poor people to plan for the future (Stalson, 1942). The plan proved to be popular, even providing an entree for friendly visitors to the homes of families "where entrance would be impossible on other than a business footing" (Scribner, 1887, p. 146). Soon other charity organizations on Staten Island joined in the project. The NYCOS established a "Penny Provident Fund;' aimed largely at schoolchildren, in 1899. The fund provided savings stamps for persons who saved from one to fifty cents, and encouraged them to establish regular savings accounts when the savings amounted to $10 or more. Within a year, the fund had ten thousand depositors and deposits of over $3,600 (Cruce, 2001; "How to Save Pennies;' 1890). Reformers and self-help organizations continued to establish savings banks and other financial resources for the poor during the Progressive Era. The Independent Order of St. Luke, an African American self-help organization, established the Provident Savings Bank of Richmond, Virginia, in 1903. As a result, Maggie Lena Walker, the grand secretary-treasurer of the order, was the first woman to head a bank in the United States (Brown, 1989; Simmons, 1975). Although they were criticized for their often amateurish approach to problems of urban poverty (Cummings, 1892), settlement houses, like charity organization societies, engaged in efforts to improve the financial capability of their neigh- bors. Settlement residents espoused a goal of the protection and enhancement of working-class standards of living" (Woods & Kennedy, 1922, p. 200). In addition to their support for labor unions, settlement houses studied small loans taken by their neighbors and introduced savings plans and small loan enterprises (Report of the Social Settlement Committee, 1896). Some settlements also introduced cooperative ventures such as buying clubs to provide groceries, coal, and other necessities to neighbors at a reasonable cost. Residents of New York's Greenwich House were informed about the neighborhood's savings banks, postal savings offices, penny provident stamp stations, sources of loans, and laws regulating loans in New York State. "Trustworthy loan associations," residents were informed, were "unfortunately few in number" (Dinwiddie & Ferguson, !913, p. 39). Many charged "all that the traffic will bear:• in the words of Robert Treat Paine, a Boston philanthropist and treasurer of the Workingman's Loan Association (Paine, 1895, p. 15), even adding fees to excessive interest rates. LOANS Both COS workers and settlement house residents viewed themselves as gen- eralists in social work; they encountered a variety of problems and developed solutions for them (Stuart, 1999a). The savings plans developed in the late nineteenth century were examples of responses to a perceived problem. When periods of unemployment increased the demand for credit, charity organization societies established remedial or provident loan associations, organizations that made "small loans at reasonable rates" (National Federation of Remedial Loan Associations, 1919, p. 33; for an example of a charity organization society that organized a remedial loan association, see Johnson, 1916). However, the extent of the financial problems encountered by clients suggested that more specialized action was necessary. Most troubling was the increasing use of credit-both for immediate needs and for major purchases. In 1895, Joseph Lee reported that loan sharks, installment buying, and pawn shops were charging "from 36% to 100% per annum" interest on loans to poor people (p. 506). Chattel mortgages, loans on movable personal property such as household furniture, carried reported interest rates as high as 120% in Cambridge, Massachusetts (Birtwell, 1899). Improved regulation of small loans, particularly reducing interest rates and fees, seemed to be the solution, but most state laws delegated regulation of small loans to municipalities, complicating reform efforts. A survey of pawnshops in ten cities revealed effective annual inter- est rates of between 30% and 300% (Patterson, 1899). In 1894, the NYCOS organized the Provident Loan Society of New York as a separate organization, with offices in the United Charities Building, headquar- ters for a number of charitable and philanthropic organizations, including the NYCOS. The purpose of the society was to "help people help themselves without loss of self-respect" by providing loans at reasonable interest rates to the neediest (Provident Loan Society, 1919, p. 21). The success of the Provident Loan Society resulted in the organization of similar "remedial loan" organizations in cities across the country and the organization of a national organization, the National Federation of Remedial Loan Associations (Ham, 1910). Although the founding of the Provident Loan Society had "partially solved" the small loan problem in New York "for those who can borrow on the pledge of per- sonal property;' difficulties remained for people in need of small loans (Wassam, 1908, p. iv). The New York School of Philanthropy's Bureau of Social Research, which had been created as a result of a grant from the Russell Sage Foundation (RSF), conducted studies of salary lenders and the chattel loan business in 1908 and 1909. Clarence W. Wassam's The Salary Loan Business in New York City (1908) found that salary lending-loans secured by the borrower's future paycheck-was widespread, and lenders charged very high interest rates. Arthur H. Ham's 1he Chattel Loan Business (1909) described businesses in New York that loaned small amounts of money using personal property, such as household furniture, as col- lateral. Although a small number of loan associations started by philanthropic organizations were doing good work, Ham concluded that they did not provide effective competition; many chattel lenders continued to charge very high rates of interest, tacking on fees that made the effective interest rate even higher. In 1909, RSF, the "center of intelligence of the charity organization movement" (Hammack, 1994), created a Remedial Loan Division to encourage the formation of remedial loan associations and to advocate for legislation to regulate small loan programs, with Ham as the director (Anderson, 2008). In addition to serving as the director of the RSF Remedial Loan Division, Ham served as a vice president of the New York Provident Loan Society. Ham and other reformers lobbied for legislation regulating small loan businesses that catered to the poor, and encouraged the formation of remedial loan associations in other cities. The foundation also supported the organization of a National Federation of Remedial Loan Associations, and Ham and representatives of local societies discussed the remedial loan movement at several National Conferences of Charities and Correction and at the New York Academy of Political Science in the 'teens. Ham was a member of a standing committee on remedial loans which planned several sessions at the 1910 National Conference (Organization of the Conference for 1910, 1909). By the 1920s, lobbying for regulatory legislation and monitoring the implementation of regulations were seen as professional responsibilities, in part because of the example of the remedial loan campaign (Bruno, 1923). Over the next three decades, the Russell Sage Foundation was successful in setting up numerous remedial loan associations and credit unions and in secur- ing regulatory legislation in 34 states, based on a model law, the Uniform Small Loan Law, drafted by Ham and his associates. Although the impetus for remedial loan associations and small loan regulation originated with the charity organization societies, social workers were not for the most part involved in the operation of the loan associations. The New York Provident Loan Society hired "a practical pawnbroker;' a person with experience in the business, not a social worker, to manage its credit business when it was established in 1894 (Provident Loan Society, 1919). Although remedial loan societies were encouraged to cooperate with charity organization societies, specialization resulted in the separation of social workers from the activity. The federal government reformed the national banking system with the enact- ment of the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 (38 Stat. 251), which established the Federal Reserve System. However, the Act regulated national banks and not small lenders, who usually operated on a local level (Mehrling, 2002). The Glass-Steagall Act of 1933 ( 48 Stat. 162) separated commercial banking and investment banking and created the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), which insured bank deposits. As was the case with the Federal Reserve System, the FDIC did not regulate small lenders, Thus, reform efforts directed at small lenders focused on the state rather than the federal level (Kelso, 1948b). THE FAMILY BUDGET Much early research in social work focused on the cost of living and the budget necessary for a family to maintain an adequate standard of living. English studies, notably Charles Booth's Life and Labour of the People of London (1889-1903) and Seebohm Roundree's Poverty: A Study of Town Life (1901), inspired much of this work (Appelbaum, 1977; O'Connor, 2001). Hull-House Maps and Papers (Residents of Hull- House, 1895), which included data on the incomes and expen- ditures of people in Chicago's near West Side, provides an early example, as does W. E. B. DuBois's The Philadelphia Negro (1899). Margaret F. Byington's Homestead: The Households of a Mill Town (1910), a volume of the Pittsburgh Survey funded by the NYCOS, included data on workers' incomes and the cost of living. The first article published in the new social work research journal, the Social Service Review, was Leila Houghteling's "The Budget of the Unskilled Laborer" (1927a), a summary of her book-length study of Chicago workers, The Income and Standard of Living of Unskilled Laborers in Chicago (1927b). Houghteling, a former super- intendent of the United Charities of Chicago's Haymarket district, earned one of the first doctorates awarded by the University of Chicago School of Social Service Administration and was a member of its faculty at the time of her death in 1927 ("Leila Houghteling:' 1927). In his review of estimates of the poverty line between 1904 and 1965, Gordon M. Fisher (1997) found that "much of the work on poverty lines and standard budgets during the first two decades of the twentieth century was done by social workers." As a result, studies of the poverty line were not mere "sociological investigation" but "constructive work" as Jane Addams put it: "using investigation as the basis of wide-ranging programs of community mobilization and action [and] using investigation as the basis of publicity" (O'Connor, 2001, p. 31). Diana Karter Appelbaum (1977) analyzed studies of the poverty line completed from 1906 to the 1970s. She concluded that the theoretical family budgets on which the poverty line was based reflected arbitrary judgments as well as prevailing social values. Estimates of the poverty line "served the dual purposes of providing a definition of poverty ... and of furnishing guidelines to social workers to help them decide how much aid a family needed to reach an adequate level" (p. 516). Initially, social workers used family budgets to provide a guide to calculating the appropriate amount of assistance to be provided to a relief recipient (Goodyear, 1906). In time, budget studies came to have other uses as well. Data on the cost of living could provide guidance for reform efforts, as sociologist Robert C. Chapin (1910) told the National Conference of Charities and Correction. After comparing workers' wages in several industries to the cost of living, Chapin concluded that "it is difficult to believe that [these workers earn] a living wage, save for a single man" (p. 456). In 1912, the National Conference's Committee on Standards of Living and Labor called for minimum wage commissions to be established in each large city to estimate the cost of living as the basis for a minimum wage. The committee's report would be endorsed by Progressive Party presidential candidate Theodore Roosevelt and would provide the domestic plank of the 1912 Progressive Party Platform (Stuart, 1999b). Committee member Florence Kelley (1912), general secretary of the National Consumers' League, which had been campaigning for minimum wage legislation since 1908, told the conference that insufficient wages underlie a vast proportion of the need for correctional and reformatory work. They entail upon the community child labor, tuberculosis, underfeeding, lack of refreshing sleep, and the consequent nervous break- down. They underlie industrial employment of mothers, whose neglected children consequently fail in health and morals. The children in turn crowd the hospitals, dispensaries, juvenile courts, and custodial institutions (p. 396). A minimum wage commission would study the cost of living in a city and recommend minimum wage rates based on their investigations (Lovejoy, 1912). The Committee on Standards of Living and Labor had recommended minimum wage legislation affecting all workers, but the earliest minimum wage legislation in the United States provided for women workers only. In 1912, Massachusetts enacted the first minimum wage legislation, a weak bill that provided for a Commission that could make recommendations for minimum wages for women in particular industries (Berkowitz & McQuaid, 1988). However, Oregon first amended its constitution to permit minimum wage legislation for men and women, and then enacted minimum wage legislation that provided minimum wages for women. By 1913, seven states had enacted minimum wage laws and five additional states were studying the issue (Kelley, 1913). The provision of mothers' pensions by both private and public agencies provided another use for the family budget. Caroline Goodyear (1906), a District Agent for the NYCOS, calculated a minimum budget for an "adequate standard of living" in New York City to guide decisions about the amount of pensions, ongoing as opposed to emergency relief, granted to families. This was to be the first of numerous studies of adequate family budgets. The New York Association for Improving the Condition of the Poor (AICP) calculated family budgets for recipients of its widow's pension program, usually in consultation with a dietitian and the mother (Matthews, 1914). A NYCOS report found that a family budget "helps family and social worker to plan ahead with reference to necessary expenditures rather than adjusting present expenditures simply to meet present needs" (Committee on Home Economics, 1919, p. 1). As public mothers' pension programs were established, beginning in Illinois and Missouri in 1911, social workers in the new public entities administering the new public programs became engaged in estimating budget needs (Goodwin, 1997). Gertrude Vaile (1914), a graduate of the Chicago School of Civics and Philanthropy (now the University of Chicago School of Social Service Administration) and executive director of the Denver Board of Charities and Corrections, told the National Conference that the size of pension is another point needing careful consideration. We feel strongly that if a pension is to be granted at all it should be sufficient to exempt the family from the need of any other charitable relief and maintain a wholesome and dignified standard of living. Only on that basis can a family be expected to live as they should ... The amount of the pension is deter- mined by making a careful estimate of the necessary budget and subtracting from it what the family can provide from their own resources (p. 675). As educational programs for the new profession of social work were established, budgeting and the social worker's role in using budgets with clients were topics for course work and for publications. For example, the Chicago School of Civics and Philanthropy published The Charity Visitor (Sears, 1918). This "hand- book for beginners" included advice for new social workers and a chapter on "Estimating a Family Budget" by Florence Nesbitt, a pioneer dietician and social worker. Nesbitt's chapter was also published separately by the Chicago Council of Social Agencies as The Chicago Standard Budget (Nesbitt, 1918a). SOCIAL WORK AND HOME ECONOMICS The association of social work with another nascent profession-home economicssupported the interest in family budgets. Although "the widest pos- sible variation ... will be found among the families that come under the social worker's care:' Florence Nesbitt (1918b) observed, the need for certain educational work is practically universal. None of the mothers are familiar with the simple principles of nutrition which must be known by one who would make intelligent choice of foods. None possess such a knowledge of the comparative values of different foods, kinds of clothing, household materials and supplies, as will enable them to lay out their money to the best advantage. All need more or less instruction in dietetic standards and help in planning the family budget. (p. 26). In a Children's Bureau study of mothers' pension administration in nine loca- tions nationwide, Nesbitt (1923) found that the social workers "gave a great deal of instruction in diet, management of income, and care of health ... they taught the mothers to keep expense accounts and to budget their incomes" (p. 34). Nesbitt was "one of the best-known home economists in social service" ("Our Contributors:' 1935, p. 690), and had a long career bridging the two professions. Beginning as a dietitian in the Cook County Mothers' Pension program, she spent most of her career in social work, becoming assistant general superintendent of the United Charities of Chicago by the 1930s. By the mid-1930s, the Chicago Standard Budget, revised several times since its appearance in 1918, was regarded as an authoritative source for estimating family needs (Douglas, 1935). The American Home Economics Association had a Social Work Committee in the 1910s and early 1920s. The committee encouraged home economists to attend the National Conference of Social Work. At the 1917 National Conference, the committee sponsored a luncheon discussion of the relationship between home economics and social work (Winslow, 1917). The committee's chair, Emma Winslow, was on the faculty of Columbia University's Teachers College and a member of the NYCOS Committee on Home Economics. In 1919, the committee published Winslow's pamphlet, Budget Planning in Social Case Work. In addition to Nesbitt and Winslow, Sophonisba Breckinridge, an instruc- tor and head of the Research Department at the Chicago School of Civics and Philanthropy, taught in the Department of Household Administration at the University of Chicago and served as assistant dean of women from !904 until !920, when the Chicago School became the university's School of Social Service Administration (SSA) and Breckinridge a full-time SSA faculty member. Marion Talbot, a pioneer in home economics, a mentor to Breckinridge, headed the Department of Household Administration and served as Dean of Women at the University of Chicago during those years. Much of home economics was practiced in the public schools, through classes in cooking, textiles, and child care; however, many home economists realized "the large scope of the field and the fact that it could not all be reached through the school" (Midwinter meeting, 1921, p. 10). Although Nesbitt and Winslow remained active in social work circles during the 1920s, and Breckinridge was an important figure in the social work profession during the 1920s and 1930s, interest in interprofessional collaboration faded during the decade. Social work entered a period of expansion, with the establishment of new professional schools, the expansion of state-supported social and health services for children, and an increasing professional self-consciousness. Homemaker services were provided by some private social agencies in the 1920s and in state public assistance programs established by the Social Security Act of 1935, sometimes under the supervision of home economists. As in the Mothers' Pension and private family welfare programs of the 1920s, social workers provided social services to beneficiaries of the public assistance programs established by the Social Security Act. Although caseloads were often very large, many social workers in public assistance provided financial advice to their clients. In addition, the Works Progress Administration provided a Housekeeping Aides Program for unemployed women in the 1930s and early 1940s. Nonprofessionals who had been trained by home economists and social workers provided house- keeping services on a temporary basis to families in need of them, usually because of the mother's illness (Morlock, 1942). However, although the homemakers provided some instruction in household management, including budgeting, the focus of most homemaker programs was on providing substitute services when the mother was away from home (Brewster, 1965). PROFESSION-BUILDING AND SOCIAL MOVEMENTS In part, the decline of interest in home economics-and in building clients' financial capability generally-may have been an unintended consequence of increased specialization in social work, and the directions that specialization took (Stuart, 1999a). Even by 1910, it seemed that there were too many social movements, each focused exclusively on a particular goal. In that year, Mary E. Richmond, the chairperson of the National Conference's Committee on Families and Neighborhoods, convened a conference session on "The Inter-Relation of Social Movements:' Richmond observed that "more social movements, national in scope, have been organized during the last ten years than the sum of all the movements organized before that date and still surviving" (Richmond, 1910, p. 212). The result of this proliferation had been confusion-although many of the national movements had been initiated by settlement houses or charity organization societies, the average worker felt estranged from the movement and had difficulty relating to it. At the session, Howard S. Braucher, of the Playground Association of America; Owen R. Lovejoy, of the national anti-child-labor movement; Lawrence Veiller, of the National Housing Association; and Alexander M. Wilson, of the National Association for the Prevention of Tuberculosis outlined their organizations' campaigns and solicited social worker participation. Richmond (1910) addressed three pleas to the national organizations: (1) to relate the national movements to the work of the charity organization societies and the settlements, (2) to recognize the rehabilitation of families and neighborhoods as necessary and important, and (3) to link the specialized goals together, not only with neighborhood and family workers but also with each other. Richmond recommended that the specialized social movements recognize the work of charity organization societies and settlement houses-family and neighborhood rehabilitation-as important in itself and as a potential ally in their more specialized campaigns. To do so, the specialists would need to make their campaigns intelligible to generalists, in particular charity and settlement workers. However, fragmentation characterized reform campaigns in the 1920s. As had happened with the provident loan movement, reform campaigns focused on achieving limited goals in a difficult policy environment. Both charity work and• settlement work became more specialized during the decade. Settlement houses focused increasingly on recreation and adult education (Stuart, 1990). Charity work became family case work, ironically as a result of Richmond's prodding. She led an RSF effort to create a national organization of charity organization societies, which became the American Association for Organizing Family Social Work in 1919 and the Family Welfare Association of America in 1930. Family social workers became increasingly interested in psychological aspects of casework and in 1930, two years after Richmond's death, labor activist A. J. Muste complained that family agencies, the successors to the COS, "have gone psychiatric in a world which has gone industrial" (Stuart, 1999a, p. 51). Some social workers continued to be concerned with financial capability. Robert W. Kelso, a leading social work administrator in the 1920s and 1930s, who became the first director of the University of Michigan's social work program in 1935, published a monograph on the small loan business in the United States in 1948. After tracing the history of remedial loans and efforts to regulate the small loan business, Kelso offered an optimistic assessment of the social responsibility of small loan businesses: Today, under the protection of [regulatory] statutes, a legitimate business can set itself up as a genuine banker for the low-income family, making a decent profit, sufficient to encourage capital to remain in the business of sell- ing credit. At the same time the necessitous borrower can seek a loan, how- ever small, with full knowledge of what he has to pay back, and certainty that sharp practice will not force him to pay more for credit than a legally defined and predetermined amount (Kelso, l948a, pp. 42-43). Another social worker, Helen Hall, the headworker of Henry Street Settlement in New York, was engaged throughout her career in consumer affairs. She chaired the National Federation of Settlements committee that commissioned a study of unemployment in 1928, on the eve of the Great Depression (Andrews, 1997). During the 1930s, she served as consumer representative on the New York State Milk Advisory Committee and was a founder of the Consumers' National Federation. She was a board member of Consumer's Union in the 1950s. With two other settlement houses, Henry Street Settlement sponsored a study of consumer and credit practices of low-income people, which became sociologist David Caplovitz's The Poor Pay More (1963). In contrast to Kelso's optimistic conclusions fifteen years earlier, Caplovitz found that the cost of credit for poor people was far higher than for the middle class. In an address to the National Conference of Social Work in 1966, Assistant Secretary of Labor Esther Peterson cited Caplovitz and called for new regulatory legislation "on this whole complex of consumer credit and contracts;' echoing presentations at the conference a half-century earlier (Peterson, 1966, p.50). However, when Caplovitz left academic research in the 1980s, he became a bankruptcy lawyer rather than a social worker (Reifner, 1992), Gordon Fisher (1997) has observed that, while social work was the primary profession involved in the construction of family budgets during the Progressive Era and the 1920s, economists became dominant after World War II. In 1948, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) unveiled "the city worker's family budget;' developed by economist Dorothy S. Brady of the BLS and an advisory committee chaired by economist Hazel Kyrk of the University of Chicago, The committee included "experts in the fields of consumption economics, standards of living, and labor economics" but not social work (Brady, 1948, p. 312). The city worker's family budget, which would be revised periodically by the BLS and which would inform estimates of the poverty line in the 1960s, would provide "a modest but adequate standard of living" (Kellogg & Brady, 1948, p. 133). CONCLUSION Social workers withdrew from improving the financial capability of clients as other, more expert, professions took up the task. Now, more than half a century after other professions and groups took responsibility, there is little or no professional assistance available to clients, providing an opportunity and a challenge to the profession. Interest in building clients' financial capability may be growing as larger numbers of people are affected by problems resulting from financial illiteracy and excessive interest rates. The winner of the 2009 Influencing State Policy contest for BSW students and her faculty mentor, for example, worked on a successful statewide campaign to regulate the interest rates charged by payday lenders in Ohio (Influencing State Policy, 2010). The times seem right for a revival of interest in increasing the financial capa- bility of social workers' clients. The "mortgage meltdown" of 2008 illustrated the problem of overextended borrowing. But this is only a part of the problem. Wilensky and Lebeaux's warning in 1958 that middle- and lower middle-class people were in danger of overborrowing seems prescient. Today, payday loans, credit card debt, and other forms of installment debt endanger consumers (Longman & Boshara, 2009; Stegman, 2007). In the past, social work's genius was its willingness to confront the real problems encountered by people, their clients and neighbors. Today, social workers must again develop interventions that will increase the financial capability of the many people who are trapped by the ongoing economic crisis. REFERENCES Addams, ). (1893a). The objective value of a social settlement. In H. C. Adams (Ed.), Philanthropy and social progress (pp. 27-56). New York: Thomas Y. Cromwell. Addams,). (1893b). The subjective necessity for social settlements. In H. C. Adams (Ed.), Philanthropy and social progress (pp. 1-26).. New York: Thomas Y. Cromwell. Anderson, E. (2008). Experts, ideas, and policy change: The Russell Sage Foundation and small loan reform, 1909-1941. Theory and Society, 37,271-310. Andrews, ). (1997). Helen Hall and the Settlement House Movement's response to unemployment. Journal of Community Practice, 4(2), 65-75. Appelbaum, D. K. (1977). The level of the poverty line: A historical survey. Social Service Review, 51, 514-523. Berkowitz, E., & McQuaid, K. (1988). Creating the welfare state: The political economy of twentieth-century reform (2nd ed.). New York: Praeger. Birtwell, M. L. (1899). Chattel mortgages. Proceedings of the National Conference of Charities and Correction, 26, 296-305. Brady, D. S. (1948). The city worker's family budget. Proceedings of the National Conference of Social Work, 75, 310-316. Braucher, H. S. (1910). The social worker and the Playground Association of America. Proceedings of the National Conference of Charities and Correction, 37, 219-222. Brewster, B. M. (1965). Extending the range of child welfare services. Children, 12(4), 145-150. Brown, E. B. (1989). Womanist consciousness: Maggie Lena Walker and the Independent Order of St. Luke. Signs, 14,610-633. Brown, M. W. (1899). The development of thrift. New York: Macmillan. Bruno, F. ). (1923). The co-operation of social workers with public officials in the enforcement of law-from the point of view of social workers with private agencies. Proceedings of the National Conference of Charities and Correction, 50, 327-333. Byington, M. (1910). Homestead: The households of a mill town. New York: Charities Publication Committee. Caplovitz, D. (1963). The poor pay more: Consumer practices of /ow-income families. New York: Free Press. Chapin, R. C. (1910). Present wages and the cost of living. Proceedings of the National Conference of Charities and Correction, 37, 449-457. Committee on Home Economics, Charity Organization Society of the City of New York. (1919). Budget planning in social case work (COS Bulletin No. 3). New York: Charity Organization Society of the City of New York. Cummings, E. (1892). University settlements. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 6(3), 257-279. Cruce, A. (200I). Ahistoryofprogressive-era school savings banking1870 to1930 (CSDWorking Paper 01-3). St. Louis, MO: Washington University, Center for Social Development. j 02_Birkenmaier_Ch02.indd 57 !0/24/2012 !:37:04 AM I Chapter 14. Price Controls January 23, 2014 a. Study Questions on Price Controls What are the benefits of controlling the price of borrowing? What are the detriments of controlling the price of borrowing? What are some of the challenges to controlling the price of borrowing? b. The History of Usury Law in the United States Please read the following article. http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/bank/bt_9805.html c. The Economic Effects of Usury Rates: The Economic Effects of Usury Rates: What does the following chart teach us about the micro effects of usury rate? Y = Bank’s minimum acceptable interest rate for this borrower Z = Maximum interest rate this borrower can afford W X Y Z 1 Tom 4 44 2 Dick 8 40 3 Harry 12 36 4 Jack 16 32 5 Jill 20 28 6 Peter 24 24 7 Paul 28 20 8 Mary 32 16 9 Matthew 36 12 10 Mark 40 8 11 Luke 44 4 12 John 48 0 Person Bank’s minimum acceptable interest rate for this borrower Maximum interest rate this borrower can afford 16% usury ceiling Market-clearing interest rate 0 0 48 1 Tom 4 44 2 Dick 8 40 3 Harry 12 36 4 Jack 16 32 5 Jill 20 28 6 Peter 24 24 7 Paul 28 20 8 Mary 32 16 9 Matthew 36 12 10 Mark 40 8 11 Luke 44 4 12 John 48 0 The typical economists view of the economic harm done to one and all by usury rates: Please read the article that follows An Economic Perspective on Interest Rate Limitations by Thomas Durkin 9 Georgia State Law Review 821 ( 1993) GEORGIA STATE UNIVERSITY LAW REV1EW [Vol. 9:821 1993] PERSPECTIVE ON INTEREST RATE LIMITATIONS 823 My purpose today, however, is not to review or summarize the views of interest rate observers (economists or otherwise), but rather to focus on the reasons for the profession's unanimous or near-unanimous conclusion. This discussion forms the first part of my remarks. Following this I will briefly review two additional arguments about interest-rate ceilings which are more philosophical than economic in nature. Although there is more divergence in the economics profession on the philosophical arguments than on the economic ones, many economists find the philosophical arguments against ceilings compelling as well. Next, I will quickly look at and criticize some arguments occasionally advanced as favoring price ceilings•, Finally, I will briefly examine some principles to follow if there is a decision to establish ceilings anyway, despite the strength of the contrary arguments. As part of this last discussion, I will only mention some red herrings and economically tangential issues, such as the question of state versus federal authority, which economists usually regard as sideshows. ECONOMIC ARGUMENTS AGAINST PRICE CONTROLS Economists list four major objections to price ceilings or controls, each sufficient by itself, it seems, to recommend elimination of binding controls: A) controls create shortages; B) controls reduce competition; C) controls• waste resources; and D) controls have adverse impacts on the macroeconomy including negative impacts on employment, output, and income.3 A. Controls Produce Shortages In the nineteenth century Thomas Carlyle called economics the "dismal science" when he wrote about Thomas Malthus's theories of population growth and inadequate food supplies (still a concern today). It seems possible in the late twentieth century, however, that the phrase sticks in many minds because of the tendency of economists to derive things that sometimes seem intuitively obvious using assumptions, axioms, theorems, rules of deductive logic, and even equations and esoteric branches of mathematics in the process. One of these derivations is the so called "Law of Demand"' which (without worrying here about the assumptions or the deductive processes) suggests simply that quantity demanded of anything varies inversely with price, other things equal. Thinking of credit, this means that at a lower price. borrowers will demand more (other things equal) and at a higher price, less. 1v1aybe the amount demanded will be a little more at a lower price and maybe a lot more, but it will certainly be as much or more at a lower price and not less. Conversely, we might contemplate a corresponding "law" of supply. Again without worrying about the behavioral assumptions, the mathematics, or the details of the derivations, this component of theory derives the intuitively obvious conclusion that producers offer more of a product at higher prices, other things equal. Again thinking of credit, this suggests that amounts offered will be greater at higher interest rates, other things equal, a contention that seems reasonable on its face. Taking both "laws" together, supply and demand suggest the likelihood that there must be some price (high, low, or in between) at which demand just equals supply. This is the equilibrium or market price (interest rate for credit markets) at which trading (lending and borrowing) take place. It may vary over time depending on demand and supply conditions. Obviously, of course, things are not this simple in the real world. Users show by their actions that they demand lots of different financial and credit products and suppliers provide lots of varieties. There are size, production cost, security, and risk differences, and many other complications as well. Still, the simple conception remains useful for each credit product or variety in the marketplace there is a demand, a supply, and an equilibrium price at which' trading (borrowing and lending) takes place. There may be higher or lower interest rates depending on production cost, risk, and degree of interaction with other credit submarkets, but the basic supply demand framework remains useful regardless. In each credit submarket supply and demand conditions, which may vary sharply between submarkets, determine an equilibrium or trading price. One of the complications that •arises is the possibility of legislatively mandated rate ceilings or controls. Interest rate ceilings are as old as recorded history; historians have found them in the ancient Laws of Manu in India, the Code of Hammurabie in Babylon, the Old Testament, and the statutes of AN ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE ON INTEREST RATE LIMITATIONS Thomas A. Durkin† INTRODUCTION It is my pleasure today to have this opportunity to speak to such an august gathering of attorneys about a 4500 year old economic question, the efficacy and usefulness of price controls in financial markets. Most of the historical as well as present, concern in this area involves interest rate ceilings on credit, which will be the focus of most of my remarks. Much of what I say, though, pertains equally well to other financial controls such as deposit rate ceilings. Consequently, I am discussing those other controls at the same time, even if I do not seem to address them as specifically or extensively. There is an old joke about economists, most often repeated by economists themselves, that if you laid all members of the profession end to end, they would reach halfway to the moon but they still would not reach a conclusion. Please let me assure you that this old saying does not reflect economists' views about interest rate ceilings; they long ago reached a conclusion on that question. I suspect Nobel Laureate Milton Friedman spoke well for the entire profession in 1970 when he reported, "I know of no economist of any standing ... who has favored a legal limit on the rate of interest that borrowers could pay or lenders receive-though there 'must have been some." In a pithy 1982 comment on controls, former Chairman of the President's Council of Economic Advisors Paul McCracken suggested a reason why: "The list of people who made the sun stand still does not contain many names after Joshua, and the list of those who successfully commanded interest rates to stand still is even shorter." My purpose today, however, is not to review or summarize the views of interest rate observers (economists or otherwise), but rather to focus on the reasons for the profession's unanimous or near-unanimous conclusion. This discussion forms the first part of my remarks. Following this I will briefly review two additional arguments about interest-rate ceilings which are more philosophical than economic in nature. Although there is more divergence in the economics profession on the philosophical arguments than on the economic ones, many economists find the philosophical arguments against ceilings compelling as well. Next, I will quickly look at and criticize some arguments occasionally advanced as favoring price ceilings. Finally, I will briefly examine some principles to follow if there is a decision to establish ceilings anyway, despite the strength of the contrary arguments. As part of this last discussion, I will only mention some red herrings and economically tangential issues, such as the question of state versus federal authority, which economists usually regard as sideshows. I. ECONOMIC ARGUMENTS AGAINST PRICE CONTROLS Economists list four major objections to price ceilings or controls, each sufficient by itself, it seems, to recommend elimination of binding controls: A) controls create shortages; B) controls reduce competition; C) controls waste resources; and D) controls have adverse impacts on the macro economy including negative impacts on employment, output, and income. A. Controls Produce Shortages In the nineteenth century Thomas Carlyle called economics the "dismal science" when he wrote about Thomas Malthus's theories of population growth and inadequate food supplies (still a concern today). It seems possible in the late twentieth century, however, that the phrase sticks in many minds because of the tendency of economists to derive things that sometimes seem intuitively obvious using assumptions, axioms, theorems, rules of deductive logic, and even equations and esoteric branches of mathematics in the process. One of these derivations is the so-called "Law of Demand" which (without worrying here about the assumptions or the deductive processes) suggests simply that quantity demanded of anything varies inversely with price, other things equal. Thinking of credit, this means that at a lower price borrowers will demand more (other things equal) and at a higher price, less. Maybe the amount demanded will be a little more at a lower price and maybe a lot more, but it will certainly be as much or more at a lower price and not less. Conversely, we might contemplate a corresponding "law" of supply. Again without worrying about the behavioral assumptions, the mathematics, or the details of the derivations, this component of theory derives the intuitively obvious conclusion that producers offer more of a product at higher prices, other things equal. Again thinking of credit, this suggests that amounts offered will be greater at higher interest rates, other things equal, and a contention that seems reasonable on its face. Taking both "laws" together, supply and demand suggest the likelihood that there must be some price (high, low, or in between) at which demand Just equals supply. This is the equilibrium or market price (interest rate for credit markets) at which trading (lending and borrowing) take place. It may vary over time depending on demand and supply conditions. Obviously, of course, things are not this simple in the real world. Users show by their actions that they demand lots of different financial and credit products and suppliers provide lots of varieties. There are size, production cost, security, and risk differences, and many other complications as well. Still, the simple conception remains useful: for each credit product or variety in the marketplace, there is a demand, a supply, and an equilibrium price at which trading (borrowing and lending) takes place. There may be higher or lower interest rates depending on production cost, risk, and degree of interaction with other credit submarkets, but the basic supply-demand framework remains useful regardless. In each credit submarket supply and demand conditions, which may vary sharply between submarkets, determine an equilibrium or trading price. One of the complications that arises is the possibility of legislatively mandated rate ceilings or controls. Interest rate ceilings are as old as recorded history; historians have found them in the ancient Laws of Manu in India, the Code of Hammurabie in Babylon, the Old Testament, and the statutes of ancient Greece and Rome. The ancient laws and writings contain two main threads: A) somehow, lending is not productive and therefore there should be controls on its price; and B) borrowing occurs because the borrower has great need and so charging a price for it is uncharitable. Ancient scholars and medieval schoolmen developed both ideas more fully and their influence survives today, albeit with diminished influence in this commercial age. Rather than origin, however, the pertinent question about rate ceilings and controls is their impact. The "laws" of supply and demand give the answer. If officials establish an interest rate ceiling that is below the rate (price) at which demand equals supply for a particular credit type, then there is a shortage of that type of credit. At a price below the equilibrium price the amount demanded (which increases at lower price) then exceeds the supply (which decreases at lower- price). By definition if demand exceeds supply at a given price there is a shortage. The market response would be a price rise to equate demand and supply, but the rate ceiling precludes an increase and the shortage persists. The situation is analogous to the gasoline lines of a few years ago. Mandatory price controls on gasoline created a situation where price could not equate demand and supply. At the artificially low price demand exceeded supply resulting, by definition, in a shortage and leading to the gasoline lines. Eventual removal of the price controls allowed higher prices to decrease the amount demanded, increase the amount supplied, and quickly eliminate the shortage and the lines. There is, however, one big difference between credit and gasoline lines: the nature of the rationing device. In the gasoline case the available supply goes to those first in line, those lucky enough to arrive at the right time, those willing to tolerate waits, or even to the relatives and friends of gasoline station owners or those willing to pay bribes. In the credit case rationing would more likely be governed by adjusting risk acceptance rather than by choosing those chronologically first in line. In particular, creditors would reject outright those borrowers they believed to be risky, eliminating them from the applicant line. Second, creditors undoubtedly would also adjust nonprice aspects of the credit offer, such as by requiring larger down payments or equity, shorter maturities, and more collateral. Both kinds of action would generate selective impacts on the population of borrowers. Likely losers would be newer, younger, or otherwise less well known borrowers: small businesses and farms, less financially stable firms and consumers, and those demanding small amounts of credit where the production cost is high per dollar of loan. Creditors might also impose fees and raise uncontrolled aspects of the price and eliminate or reduce grace periods and collect more quickly and more vigorously. On occasion interested observers dispute the argument that interest rate ceilings cause credit shortages, contending instead that there is plenty of credit around despite the ceilings. What, of course, they are really saying is not that economic theory is wrong, but rather that the ceilings are not binding they are set above the supply-demand equilibrium rate and so are not constraining the market at that time. Saying, for example, that there is plenty of credit card credit available despite rate ceilings says nothing when the ceilings are far above market rates (as they should be to prevent shortages). The question is what happens when ceilings are below the supply-demand equilibrium rate. Those are the ceilings that cause shortages. Thus, shortages and rationing that selectively affect certain population segments and classes of borrowers are the economic result of interest rate controls that impede the convergence of supply of and demand for credit. Is this a problem? Certainly, some people hold the view that consumers and maybe businesses as well would be better off without credit. If credit were not so readily available, according to this view, credit users would be better able to practice self-denial, to avoid overburdening themselves with debt, and even- possibly to save a little more. This view completely overlooks economic experience, which shows that most borrowers use credit responsibly and, more importantly, for productive purposes. Neither consumers nor businesses borrow, after all, for the purpose of wasting the resources, and unlike the debtors contemplated in Leviticus and Deuteronomy they do not, by and large, borrow because of distress. Rather, most borrowing in a modem economy occurs for investment purposes. Consumers invest in homes, durable goods like automobiles and appliances, and durable services like education and medical care. Each of these forms of capital provides a flow of returns over time in the form of valuable consumer services. Consumer capital is analogous to business capital like factories, machines, and equipment, which provides investment returns over time to business. By investing in capital goods and services both consumers and, businesses can raise total returns available from their resources and increase the level of their real wealth. Interest rate ceilings interfere with this process by restricting credit availability and potentially lowering the real wealth of those rationed from the market. By itself, this a strong indictment of controls. Controls and shortages also ruin the usefulness of markets in indicating that changing conditions warrant changes in' quantities demanded and supplied-in the jargon of the profession, controls destroy market signals. If rate ceilings hold interest rates below the free market level, there is no signal to savers that more funds are needed or to borrowers that less credit demand is appropriate. High interest rates signal the need for smaller amounts of credit demand and larger amounts of supply, but nonprice rationing hides this information and continues the shortage. Markets can transmit information about the need for change, but only if controls do not interfere with the effectiveness of the dynamic signals. B. Controls Reduce Competition Cloudy signals discourage potential suppliers from entering the market. In effect, price controls become a barrier to entry. With controls in place, potential entrants have little enthusiasm for the market or for increasing supply. But, free entry is a prerequisite for competitive conditions in markets. The benefits of competition in markets are well understood, but they bear repeating because they are often overlooked. First, competition assures that products or services, including credit, are available to those who demand them at minimum production cost for the quantity and quality of service. Thus, competition produces efficiency. Second, free competition reduces potential conflicts of interest and concentrations of power that, along with higher prices, are the hallmarks of uncompetitive markets. As soon as substantial barriers to entry are put in place, the competitiveness of markets begins to deteriorate and the benefits of competitive markets to decline. As competitiveness ebbs, prices rise, the quality of service declines, or both. Interest rate ceilings and controls produce a barrier to entry and reduce the likelihood of competitive conditions. C. Controls Waste Resources If the bad news is that controls cause shortages and impede competition, the good news is that they are not always fully effective because imaginative people find ways around them. But that is bad news too, because both they and the government waste resources in finding ways around them and in enforcing them. The evasion issue merits a closer look. Not surprisingly, economists have thought about and studied reactions to regulation. In recent years the field has been very active, and economists have developed interesting economic theories about the origins of, motivation for, and reactions to regulatory change. One theory suggests that regulation itself is important in generating regulatory change. This theory suggests that, in effect, regulation functions as a tax, raising costs. It has the result of making production of regulated services more costly or it raises the cost of entering regulated markets. As a result, in a competitive market suppliers of products are constantly looking for ways around the regulations or are constantly shifting resources from regulated to unregulated ways of doing things. In other words, they are looking for ways to reduce costs. There is no intent here to imply that the attempt to avoid regulation is a cynical reaction. Very simply, the attempt to avoid regulation is merely a rational economic reaction to business cost pressures in a competitive market. But it does produce constant testing of the frontiers of the regulations themselves. Often these tests and the shifts of resources into unregulated related activities result in new regulations. These, in turn, are tested anew and the process cycles on, giving rise to the descriptive term "regulatory dialectic. Ongoing regulatory change is costly, however, because of the constant need for operating and procedural upheavals as well as the necessity of devoting considerable resources to the dreaded "L words" of business: lawyers, legislation, and litigation. Interest rate ceilings and controls seem to be a good illustration of the dialectical process of regulatory change. In fact, to a great degree, most of the legislative and regulatory changes of the past seventy-five years in the consumer credit field, particularly at the state level, have involved price control efforts and reactions to attempted escapes. Clearly, disputes over add-on rates, discount rates, simple interest, and even credit card billing methods involve pricing and reactions to price controls. Likewise, small loan legislation, the time-price doctrine, the Marquette doctrine, dual business restrictions, and even convenience and advantage licensing concern pricing and its control. Controversies over credit insurance, leasing, and rental purchase, by and large, involve credit pricing and control. Furthermore, issues involving real estate points and fees, rule of seventyeight's refunds, and even disclosure matters such as components and itemization of finance charges are, at least in part, manifestations of reaction to price control. As each of these issues cycles on, the economy continues to pay for our legacy of price controls with each hearing, legislative change, mandatory operational variation, and lawsuit these issues generate. It is not possible, of course, to say how consumer credit markets might have developed in this country without the legacy of ceilings and controls, but it seems certain some things would have been different. Probably most of these issues would never have developed. At the least, it seems that much of the cost associated with the regulatory dialectic would have been less, and the economy could have devoted fewer resources to regulatory changes and enforcement efforts. D. Controls Have Negative Macroeconomic Impacts Although analysts have not devoted as much time or attention to the effects of financial controls on the macro economy, it seems again that the likely impact is dismal. First, by keeping interest rates below their free market equilibrium rate, interest rate ceilings reduce savings. Second, by reducing savings the ceilings also keep borrowing and investment below their free market levels. Third, savings and investment below choice, which implies that resources are engaged in second-best uses, together promise negative impact on output, employment, and income. Inefficiencies associated with regulatory avoidance and enforcement also involve shifts of resources to less effective uses, reinforcing the negative effect. Although no one has measured the actual impact and, indeed, it may not be measurable, there is no reason to suspect anything other than these negative outcomes. II. PHILOSOPHICAL ARGUMENTS AGAINST PRICE CEILINGS The economic arguments against price ceilings are not the only telling criticisms. Rather, further arguments, broader in generality, and maybe in appeal to some noneconomists, equally suggest the folly of financial price ceilings or controls. A. Controls are an Improper Role for Government A first criticism is that placing controls on the private contracting of lenders and borrowers is not an appropriate role of government in a free society, except perhaps in cases of unquestionably unconscionable behavior by one of the parties. In effect, the issue is whether, apart from clearly unconscionable conduct, it is the proper role of government to tell individuals they cannot engage in certain activities or transactions when they fully understand what they are doing, they freely choose to do so, when they regard these transactions as beneficial to themselves, and when the activities are harmful to no one. Many people, including many economists, argue this is not a proper role of government, but others disagree. The others apparently take a more paternalistic view, contending, in effect, that the law should not permit borrowers to pay rates above some ceiling, presumably to protect them from themselves. It is possible to apply economic analysis here, too. There is a widespread myth, perpetuated perhaps by those whose personal resources enable them to provide for their own needs and wants easily, that individual consumers become worse off when they enter into credit agreements. This, of course, is not the case when consumers enter into credit agreements by free choice and there is no deception or unconscionable behavior by the creditor. Consumers choose to enter such contracts because they perceive the benefits to themselves in the form of returns on the uses of the funds, typically assets such as houses, automobiles, education, durable goods, and medical care, but also preferred consumption time patterns, to be worth the cost they must pay savers (usually through financial institutions) to borrow the savers resources. In the jargon of economics, the net present value is positive. If lives were infinite in length or if needs to purchase houses, durables, and other assets were uniformly distributed over consumers lives and did not tend to come in bunches, consumers might demand less credit. Lives are not infinitely long, however, and asset needs do come in bunches, typically in the twenty-five to forty-five age brackets. Many people believe that limiting consumers' opportunities to make their own choices does them a disservice. Beyond this, there is the question whether a few government officials are better prepared to make choices for millions of citizens anyway. Legislators and officials have their own experiences and biases which do not necessarily match the views of all their constituents all of the time. Unsuitability of government's choices together with imagination of entrepreneurs and the fungibility and substitutability of money have produced the regulatory dialectic noted earlier. That path leads to bureaucracy, enforcement, reporting burden, new managerial efforts to evade, and distortions in resource allocation. These produce a dead-weight loss to society. B. Controls do not Solve the Identified Problem Anyway Most significantly, another criticism of interest rate ceilings is that they do nothing to address the problem that inspires them, namely, high interest rates. The level and variation of interest rates depends on broader factors than just conditions in the controlled markets or submarkets. Rather, particular interest rates are under the influence of capital market conditions generally, and these reflect many wider influences ranging from wage rates and inflation rates to resource allocation choices of society and even to world economic conditions. Looking at consumer credit markets alone is not sufficient to understand capital markets or trends in interest rates, including consumer credit interest rates. And controlling consumer credit rates will not favorably affect capital markets. Market interest rates consist of a list of components, all of which may fluctuate: a realreturn component, an inflation adjustment, a risk adjustment (including a liquidity premium), and an adjustment for fixed costs (if any). The real return is the return that the ultimate lender requires in units of constant purchasing power-a real return of three percent per year, for example. The inflation adjustment, in turn, compensates for money's changing value. If inflation of four percent per year over the life of the credit is expected (in other words money is expected to decline in. value four percent per year), then the lender would reasonably require seven percent (three percent real return plus four percent for inflation). Likewise, if the lender expects some losses, then there must be compensation for the losses. If losses of three percent per year are expected, then the lender would require another three percent per year or ten percent in all, considering all three components. Finally, the market interest rate must cover all fixed costs. If the fixed costs are small relative to the loan size (say, on a ten million dollar commercial paper note of a low-risk issuer), the impact on the market rate is almost negligible. In contrast, if fixed costs for credit analysis, payment processing, and regulatory compliance loom large relative to the credit amount, then their impact on the required market rate will be substantial. The point of all this is that high or fluctuating rates result from a variety of factors, not all of which are specific or limited to the type of credit under consideration. In recent history enthusiasm for rate ceilings has most often involved consumer and mortgage credit, of course. But high rates in the former largely arise because of high fixed costs on small credit amounts. Credit costs depend on such things as wage rates, postage rates, and trends in automation and technology. It is not clear that interest rate ceilings favorably - affect any of these factors. High rates in the mortgage credit case most often result from higher inflationary expectations and higher market interest rates generally. These may change with the business cycle or even with international developments. It is not obvious what price ceilings could do in these cases, except create shortages. In sum, rate ceilings and controls are not effective solutions to high interest rates. High interest rates are caused by factors such as operating costs and inflation expectations that are outside the purview of interest rate ceilings. In a large sense interest rates are like a thermometer that measures the economy's temperature. High or rising rates measure economic symptoms and may well indicate economic problems or ills. But controls do not even treat symptoms; they merely do violence to the thermometer. III. CRITICISM OF ARGUMENTS THAT PURPORT TO SUPPORT CONTROLS Despite 4500 years of sorry experience with price ceilings on credit, controls still have their supporters. Let us now look at some of their arguments. A High Rates Disadvantage the Needy All of the reasons advanced from time to time which purport to support the need for interest rate ceilings and controls all illustrate the above criticism of controls: they are not effective solutions to the problems they are supposed to address. For example, even today some observers argue the ancient and medieval contention that taking interest is wrong because it involves uncharitableness toward the needy. These people may apply this contention only to interest rates above some low level or only to some kinds of credit or borrowers (low-income consumers, for example). Nonetheless, despite any limitations, the contention is the same: high rates charged at least to some consumers for some kinds of credit are uncharitable or unfair. Unfortunately, rate ceilings and controls are not an effective remedy to the problems of necessitous borrowers, and controls will adversely affect many others too. As already discussed, most borrowing is not done out of necessity by the needy and desperate, but rather by those who have resources and incomes and who desire to change the time path of their income and consumption flows. These include businesses that borrow current resources for investing in facilities and equipment that provide a greater flow of investment returns, consumers who borrow to invest in assets such as houses, autos, durable goods, education, and health care that provide a greater real wealth. Necessitous or desperate people normally are unable to borrow anyway, and so interest rate ceilings to protect them is the wrong remedy to apply to their needs. This is not the place to discuss proper private or government programs to help the needy, except to say that interest rate ceilings and controls are not among the useful suggestions. Rather, control efforts disrupt commercial activities among the nonneedy without doing anything for those who are desperate. B. Controls Address the Problem of Unequal Bargaining Power A second argument is, that ceilings are needed to redress unequal bargaining power and keep rates from rising to astronomical levels. But this ignores the forces of competition. An individual creditor is not free to charge an arbitrary price as long as other creditors are charging lower prices for similar services and the public is even partially aware of the existence of alternatives. Today it is hard to argue otherwise. Many credit markets are free of ceilings and prices still fall within relatively narrow ranges across creditors. Residential first mortgage credit, for example, has been free of rate ceilings since passage of the Depository Institutions Deregulation Act of 1980, but the uncontrolled rates are not astronomical. In fact, rates have fallen sharply since 1980, and they tend to fluctuate very sensitively with changes in the economy. Rates in local markets, as revealed in many newspaper surveys, tend to be quite similar across creditors, even if not exactly the same. While individual consumers may not have great strength of bargaining power individually, they do have immediate and obvious alternatives. The breadth of potential buyers taken together, each of whom individually has alternatives, gives consumers market power of their own, and those who shop for credit can police the market for those who do not. Certainly, it is difficult to argue that monopoly conditions are prevalent in many credit markets today. Rate ceilings or controls could only make the situation worse by establishing barriers to entry. C. Credit is a Utility that Government Should Regulate A third argument is that credit, and, indeed, financial services generally, are so important today that they should be considered public utilities subject to public direction and price control. But, financial firms are much different from typical public utilities. For one thing, financial firms do not produce outputs like electric power where scale economies and advantages of large size are alleged to be sufficient to drive out competitors and produce a monopoly. Evidence of economies of scale for financial firms is very slight and only then for movement out of the very small firm size classes. Furthermore, financial firms do not require the large, fixed capital investments of electric, water, and other public utilities that suggest a public interest in protecting them from competition so they are profitable and the investment is forthcoming. For financial firms monopoly is unlikely and so public action to protect against monopolistic pricing is not needed. Even if monopoly were likely, however, it is not at all clear that public utility-type regulation would solve problems in the financial area. Public utility regulation typically sets prices in such a way as to provide a reasonable return on invested assets. In the credit area a single price would result in preferred risk classes or loan sizes, most likely large loans to low risk borrowers. If there were to be multiple prices for different risk classes and loan size with each price supposed to bring a guaranteed return on assets invested in that type of credit, there would be immense difficulties with allocation of joint costs. It seems highly improbable that the bureaucratic mill could provide better answers than free market credit production. In addition, investments in loans and other financial assets are much more mobile than investments in power plants and gas pipelines. If public pricing decisions were inadequate, assets would migrate to other credit markets, other kinds of activities, or even to other countries. D. Controls Help Avoid Overburdening Consumer with Debt A fourth argument supposedly supporting the usefulness of price controls on credit is that controls help avoid overburdening consumers with excessive debts. But excessive is, at least to a degree, in the eyes of the beholder. If the objective is to set rate ceilings so that no or few consumers can borrow, this objective will not be consistent with the, views, wants, or needs of the affected individuals. If, in contrast, the goal is to reduce credit availability only to those unable to pay, controls seem to be the wrong response. Inability to repay typically arises after the fact due to loss of job, sickness, marital problems, or other personal difficulties. Prior interest rate controls are unlikely to help solve these problems. If in the remaining cases consumer insolvency arises from creditors' lack of information about the financial condition of new applicants, the solution is improvement in information systems and not in interest rate controls that disrupt commercial relations for many others as well. E. Controls Assure that Consumers Pay "Fair" Rates for Credit Finally, on occasion rate ceilings are suggested as means of assuring that consumers pay "fair" rates for credit. But, fair for whom? In a competitive market credit transactions can occur only if lenders and borrowers agree that the price is "fair." A regulatory agency can never achieve this match for each of the millions of credit transactions that take place annually. If ceilings make creditors unwilling to generate small amounts of credit or credit to riskier borrowers, for example, then those excluded from the market may not agree that ceilings have made prices "fair" for them. Of course, sales credit might -still be available because merchants could raise prices and use the difference to subsidize the credit losses. Cash buyers might not feel the prices are fair, however, and would shop elsewhere. The likely result of the rate ceiling would be development of a class of stores, which sell credit goods largely to poor risks but at higher prices. The stores would use the excess income on the goods to subsidize the risky credit operation and not earn as high a profit as the high goods prices might otherwise suggest. This would frustrate the goal of achieving a "fair" price (if that means a lower price) for credit and might actually make matters worse because market segmentation would tend to increase and competitive forces to decline. In sum, legislation restraining gross income from finance changes necessitates adjustments in credit availability, fees, goods prices, or some combination. There is no magic way to reduce prices. IV. DESIGNING CEILINGS The foregoing should, I hope, be convincing arguments that credit rate ceilings and controls are not good public policy. If ceilings are necessary, nonetheless, perhaps for political reasons, let me suggest a few developmental principles that can help minimize difficulties. The first principle is, of course, if at all possible, to set ceilings high enough that their sole effect is to eliminate truly unconscionable behavior but not otherwise to interfere with the smooth functioning of the credit markets. Ceilings can serve a useful function if government officials are able to use them as a standard of unconscionability but they do not otherwise impede legitimate commerce. Ceilings might have to be very high for small amounts of credit for short periods. Moreover, the existence of ceilings should not serve as an invitation for establishment of bureaucratic monitoring, reporting, interpreting, and enforcing regimes that submerge the usefulness of an objective unconscionability standard under a mountain of red tape. Second, ceilings should not vary by type of creditor. Ceilings specific to certain creditors merely make those creditors favor or not favor certain types of credit producing market segments and barriers to entry. The objective should be to encourage easy access for creditors to all submarkets to discourage market segmentation and tendencies toward monopoly. Third, for the same reason, ceilings should not depend on the type of goods financed. Some goods may have better collateral value than others, but the main differences in consumer credit interest rates arise from variations in credit size and type of customer rather than collateral differences. Thus, ceilings dependent on collateral type may well induce preferences by credit size and type of customer, again tending to produce segmented markets and greater likelihood of monopoly power. Fourth, ceilings should employ the same components and definitions as other regulationsincluding disclosure regulations. It makes no sense, for example, that a percentage rate calculated under the ceiling requirements be some different percentage under disclosure regulations because the components or compounding methods required are different. If they are different, at a minimum the ceiling regulations should be regarded as applying only to ceilings and not to disclosures and vice versa. Neither area should serve as a cause of litigation in the other. Finally, ceilings should not vary by geographic area or state. A hodgepodge of unrelated ceilings merely serves to complicate the operations of creditors, to make creditors prefer one area over another (tending to segment markets), and to impede the development of efficient credit flows to credit-needy areas. Variations among states, eventually causes real resources, including employees, to change locations for artificial, inefficient reasons. Such differences can be, and in fact have been, sources of long and drawn out legal maneuvering and litigation, which economists regard as sideshows to the underlying economic issue of the inappropriateness of controls. Recent acts in the sideshow include questions surrounding the legality of exporting and importing interest rates, concerns over the rights of states versus the Federal government in regulating interest rates, and all the controversial aspects of the so-called "Marquette doctrine." Rate ceilings that did not vary by geography would make all of these costly problems disappear. CONCLUSION In sum, this economist agrees with the unanimous or near unanimous view of the profession: ceilings or controls on interest rates have been a bad idea for a long time and will continue to be a bad idea in the future. Controls create credit shortages, they impede competition, they waste resources, they harm the macro economy, they interfere with free choice, and probably most tellingly, they do not work anyway. At the next American Bar Association Consumer Financial Services Ten-Year Outlook Conference we will celebrate the millennium, the coming of the year 2000 and, we hope, a new era. After 4500 years of experience-with credit controls, I hope that conference win not have to address this issue when discussing the outlook. d. The arguments in favor of Price Controls. Earlier in these materials we read selections (Pages ___ to ___ infra) from the seminal article by Professor Wallace that lays out the rationale for imposing price effective controls on the cost of borrowing. You will recall that Wallace recognizes the various negative effects of price controls and acknowledges the impact on those consumers who will be excluded from borrowing. Please refresh your recollection of that argument and then compare the Durkin analysis with the analysis of Professor Wallace at page ___ e. With that background in mind let's look at the idea of price controls in regard to various specific lending products from the clearest and simplest to the most complicated Auto finance: New Car sale and financing Issue on sale price separate from financing; big trap for the unwary; New car: Saturn example Used Care: How to regulate if the sale and financing are from the same dealer on a used car? Furniture What is the time price differential? What role did it play in the history of the regulation of the price of borrowing? Credit Cards Home Mortgage What is the role of Federal Preemption in credit cards and home mortgages and payday lending? Chapter 15. Prohibited Transactions Several years ago Senator, then Professor Elizabeth Warren and Professor Oren Bar Gill proposed a variation of the Consumer Products Safety Commission as the right type of regulatory agency for consumer financial products. The result is the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau. Here is some information about that Bureau. Prepared Remarks by Richard Cordray Director of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau Press Conference with Mayor Rahm Emanuel Chicago, Illinois December 5, 2012 Thank you for having me here today. It is great to be back in Chicago, this fascinating city of so many unexpected dimensions, where I spent my law school days. During my first year, I lived on the South Side across the park from where Mayor Washington lived. Outside his building, a large family of green-and-gold “wrong way” parrots, who perhaps had confused their migration patterns from South America, had built an enormous nest. Little did they know they had stumbled upon the safest home in the Northern Hemisphere, since the Mayor’s police security detail was parked underneath their tree 24 hours a day, seven days a week! I also understand that the Mayor was a fierce and valiant defender of those parrots. This is just one instance of the intricate tapestry of our communities and the interesting connections they represent. My own public service roots were planted firmly in local and state government in Ohio. But your former county executive, the late John Stroger, was the person who introduced me as the nation’s County Leader of the Year for 2005 – an award won this year by your own Toni Preckwinkle. Your very fine City Comptroller, Amer Ahmad, worked alongside me when I served as the Treasurer of Ohio, and he did a fantastic job there as I am sure he is also doing here. And, of course, your Mayor – everyone knows your Mayor, and can see his relentless tenacity to find every single way he can, whether big or small, to make life better for all those who live or work in the City of Chicago. From my experience in state and local government, I have found that strong partnerships are sometimes difficult to build, but always the best way to get things done. So I especially appreciate the announcement we are making here today. Chicago is the first city in the country to agree to share information directly with us, the new Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, about enforcing the laws that ensure people are treated fairly in the confusing and complex consumer financial markets. We want to learn from and expand on the ways you protect consumers, and to share these approaches nationwide. We also want you to be able to take advantage of the new resources we bring to the arena, including strong analytical tools and a broad mandate to protect consumers against illegal practices. Every day, millions of Chicagoans use financial products with the goal of achieving prosperity through hard work and sound decisions. Mortgages allow families to invest in a home and pay for it over time. Credit cards give us convenient access to our money when we need it. Student loans make it possible for people with ambition and drive to finance an education and brighten their future. But, as the past few years have revealed all too clearly, if these products are misused, then they also have the potential to wreak havoc on consumers and the wider economy. Debt can devastate people’s lives. Individual financial problems then become community problems. We saw that quite clearly with the mortgage crisis. The foreclosure epidemic sucked the vitality out of once-vibrant neighborhoods. Vacant properties are not only eyesores, but can become magnets for drugs and crime, and they also lower property tax revenues as they decline in value. If these properties turn into a dead loss and have to be leveled, you know who pays for that? Of course, the city has to do that. When neighbors see their own property values decline, entire neighborhoods suffer, and cities are forced to bear the bottom-line cost of problems created by others. In this manner, predatory lending exhibits what my economics training at the University of Chicago would denote as “externalities.” That is a sterile academic term, but the upshot is that predatory lending hurts more than its immediate targets; it assaults the very foundations of stable communities. The damage can take years and years to repair. The Consumer Bureau was created to ensure that such irresponsible and illegal practices do not continue to plague our lives and our communities. Partnerships like this one are at the heart of our efforts to improve how consumer financial markets work for people. You are on the frontlines, and we are glad to join you there and partner with you as a new federal agency focused exclusively on in consumer financial protection. We want to know what you are seeing and how that informs what we should be doing – where our supervision and enforcement teams should focus their attention, and what problems our policymakers should undertake to fix. We need to do this work together, and to promote responsible business practices. When honest businesses prosper, communities can flourish and so will America’s economy. We have already begun our work to enforce the law against unfair, deceptive, and abusive acts or practices. We are launching brand-new federal supervision of payday lenders and debt collectors and credit reporting companies. Because of your close relationship with your constituents, you have a unique ability to help us spread our reach more broadly. By working in partnership, we can succeed in educating, empowering, and protecting our citizens. They deserve to have someone standing on their side. At the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, we look forward to teaming up with you to do just that. Thank you and next up, I would like to introduce a man who is never afraid to be on the frontlines for the people he represents: your Mayor, Rahm Emanuel. The CFPB blog aims to facilitate conversations about our work. We want your comments to drive this conversation. Please be courteous, constructive, and on-topic. To help make the conversation productive, we encourage you to read our comment policy before posting. Comments on any post remain open for seven days from the date it was posted. CONSUMER FINANCIAL DODD-FRANK AND CONSUMER PROTECTION ACT’S “ABUSIVE” STANDARD By Tiffany S. Lee* “‘[T]he addition of ‘abusive’ to the standard in the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau provisions is ‘the most egregious’ part of Dodd-Frank.” — Richard Hunt, President of the Consumer Bankers Association.1 I. Introduction The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Financial Protection Act (“DoddFrank Act”) ushers in a new era of consumer protection and financial regulation. The Act spans 2,300-pages and regulates a panoply of consumer and commercial financial products.2 Considering the wide range of business practices effected, what about the inclusion of a single word— abusive—has the Consumer Bankers Association so upset? Title X of the Dodd-Frank Act, the Consumer Financial Protection Act (“CFPA”),3 creates a new federal agency dedicated solely to consumer protection: the Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection (“the Bureau”).4 This agency is expected to be juggernaut.5 Its purpose is to act as a consumer watchdog and ensure “markets in consumer [financial products] are fair, transparent, and competitive.”6 When the Bureau assumes its responsibilities on July 21, 2011, it will regulate virtually all consumer financial products, from loan products like mortgages to transactional products such as checking accounts,7 affecting over $14 trillion in consumer debt and services.8 The scope of the Bureau’s expansive power turns in part on the definition and application of a single word: abusive. Specifically, the Bureau is empowered to take any authorized action, including rulemaking, to prevent a credit or service provider “from committing or engaging in unfair, deceptive, or abusive acts or practices” in connection with a consumer financial product.9 Prior to the Dodd-Frank Act, federal regulators (such as the FederalTrade Commission (“FTC”)) already had the authority to ban actions that were defined as unfair or deceptive under the Federal Trade Commission Act. But the CFPA adds the legal standard abusive, which expands the standard of misconduct.10 For two reasons, the term abusive will play a critical role in determining the scope of the Bureau’s power. First, though the CFPA provides several definitions, abusive has been used only in limited contexts, so its use as a legal standard has limited jurisprudential history.11 Second, the abusive standard itself may be subject to abuse if the Bureau uses it to ban products or practices that would have been helpful to consumers.12 As a result, the interpretative deficiency surrounding the term is fueling allegations that the CFPA drafters overstepped their powers by drafting such a broad standard.13 Such suspicions have provided the Bureau’s influential critics with ammunition in their efforts to undercut the agency’s power.14 This article, however, contends Congress chose the word abusive consciously as a way to create additional powers that go beyond the previous powers of the FTC to control unfair and deceptive practices.15 Although there has been criticism that the word abusive is unacceptably vague, the term actually has a history in other statutes that shows how the Bureau should begin applying the CFPA’s definition of the standard. Analogy to past application of the same term in other statutes and recent federal provisions against unethical consumer financial practices reveal that the standard applies to at least three practices: (1) extending high-risk credit without adequately assessing each consumer’s ability to repay; (2) using aggressive sales and marketing tactics to harass, oppress, or abuse consumers; and (3) steering consumers who qualify for low-cost credit to highercost products. The development of regulations for these three practices will allow the term to be better understood and manageable. Part II presents the purpose and policies behind the creation of the Bureau and the inclusion of abusive in the Act. It also contends that though the standard is broader than the unfair and deceptive standards, its inclusion in the CFPA is necessary to restore consumer confidence in our financial markets. Part III examines how the three abovementioned practices fall under the abusive standard. It then fleshes out specific consumer financial contexts where the Bureau should take action, such as home mortgages, payday lending, and private student loans. II. The Rationale For the Inclusion of Abusive Congress included the term abusive in the CFPA to resolve consumer protection failures leading up to the subprime mortgage crisis.16 Indeed, inadequacies of previous consumer protection statutes contributed to the severity of the crisis. As a legal standard, abusive is not as new or unfamiliar as some believe. While the addition of the abusive standard raises several policy considerations, the turmoil of the last few years indicates that a broader standard is necessary to restore financial stability and confidence in our financial markets. A. The Mortgage Crisis & Failed Consumer Protection The subprime mortgage crisis was caused in part or at least exacerbated by a flawed system of consumer protection.17 Essentially, bank and non-bank lenders extended exploitative loans, which should have never been approved and which borrowers simply could not afford.18 Companies became increasingly deft at bypassing regulation using controversial (and ultimately unethical) practices such as loan flipping, prepayment penalties, complex product offerings to unsophisticated consumers, and so on.19 This led to an economic meltdown, as millions of borrowers—unable to repay their mortgages— defaulted and walked away from their homes.20 Put simply, the pre-crisis consumer protection system had too many gaps, allowing unscrupulous credit practices. Prior to the enactment of the CFPA, consumer financial protection was fractured across seven federal agencies, such as the Office of the Comptroller of Currency and Office of Thrift Supervision.21 In the wake of the crisis, Congress centralized consumerprotection authority with the Bureau. The new agency will operate as a fully independent agency, have access to a wealth of industry data, be well-funded, and have a powerful director.22 In addition to the structural problems, the CFPA also addressed statutory inadequacies of the consumer protection system. Statutorily, the federal agencies—particularly the FTC— did not have sufficient rulemaking authority to attack unethical practices that preceded the crisis.23 Pre-crisis, the FTC was the primary consumer financial regulator, but its powers were limited in several ways. Under section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act (“FTCA”), the FTC may only prohibit acts that fall within the FTCA’s definitions of unfair and deceptive.24 “Unfair” and “deceptive” acts and practices must each meet different three-part tests, which have high thresholds and are difficult to satisfy, thus advances in consumer financial protection, through the FTC, have been limited.25 A practice is unfair where it “(1) causes or is likely to cause substantial injury to consumers, (2) cannot be reasonably avoided by consumers, and (3) is not outweighed by countervailing benefits to consumers or to competition.”26 Under the second element of the unfairness test “some courts have held that consumers can avoid injury by choosing another product or service. This makes the second element hard to prove.”27 Regarding the third unfairness element—essentially a cost-benefit analysis—lenders have successfully argued that “pro- viding credit is a benefit even if questions can be raised about a borrower’s long term ability to repay it.”28 For example, consider Borrower A who has a 30-year fixed home mortgage at a 15% interest rate.29 A different lender convinces Borrower A to refinance their home with an adjustable-rate mortgage that has an initial two-year fixed interest rate at 7%, but after year two will jump to a fully indexed rate, mostly likely several percentage points above Borrower A’s original 15% interest rate. Further, the lender incorporated a $7,000 penalty if Borrowers prepays the loans early, making the huge interest rate jump almost unavoidable.30 Even though this new mortgage has a “built-in potential for payment shock”31 at year two, some courts would hold that Borrower A has received a significant benefit because refinancing reduces the loan’s original interest in the consumer financial industry.38 It enables the Bureau to prevent any covered person or service provider from engaging in “unfair, deceptive, or abusive acts or practices” in connection with any transaction for a consumer financial product or service.39 The definition of “covered person” includes bank and non-bank entities and is broadly defined as “any person that engages in offering or providing a consumer financial product or service.”40 There exists considerable interpretative history for what is “unfair” or “deceptive”, as such practices have been prohibited for some time.41 By comparison, abusive is a newer term to the regulatory landscape,42 thus the CFPA provides several definitions for the term: (d) Abusive—The Bureau shall have no authority under this section to declare an act or practice abusive in connection with the provision of a consumer financial product or service, unless the act or practice—(1) materially interferes with the ability of a consumer to understand a term or condition of a consumer financial product or service; or (2) takes unreasonable advantage of— (A) a lack of understanding on the part of the consumer of the material risks, costs, or conditions of the product or service; (B) the inability of the consumer to protect the interests of the consumer in selecting or using a consumer financial product or service; or ( C) the bureau will define, interpret, and limit the abusive standard will continue to be an issue of frenzied debate for years to come. rate by more than half. Some courts decline to deem such practices as “unfair,” even though borrowers often fail to understand the risks associated with these types of loans, leading to an inevitable default.32 Sheila Bair, Chairwoman of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, testified that reasonable reliance by the consumer on a covered person to act in the interests of the consumer.43 The standard is considerably more expansive than prior consumer protection standards, because it places greater weight on subjective analysis when determining what practices should be considered illegal.44 Its inclusion in the CFPA acknowledges the cost-benefit prong of the unfairness analysis, a factor that has been used in last thirty years, is not suitable to provide adequate consumer protection in all contexts.45 Moving forward, under the abusive standard, even if a provider discloses all risks or provides a beneficial product—passing the unfair or deceptive tests—these circumstances would not absolve the providers from responsibility. The Bureau could still prohibit such conduct as abusive.46 Regulators and financial companies can look to the these elements taken together mean that situations that cannot withstand the FTCA’s statutory requirements are rare, and there- fore, enforcement actions are equally rare despite the existence of many unethical practices.33 An act or practice is deemed “deceptive” when “a representation, omission, or practice misleads or is likely to mislead the consumer; a consumer’s interpretation of the representation, omission, or practice is considered reasonable under the circumstances; and the misleading representation, omission, or practice is material.”34 The deceptive test is also generally difficult to meet because consumers must have evidence that a consumer financial company made a false or unsupported statement.35 This is a great challenge for consumers because almost all industry data is held by the offending companies themselves, making it very difficult to build a case.36 Because of the various factors discussed above, the FTC and other federal agencies became either unwilling or unable to implement necessary prohibitions to prevent unethical practices, despite their prevalence.37 B. The Solution to Statutory Failures: Adding the “Abusive” Standard Congress recognized the statutory failings of the pre- crisis consumer-protection system. To resolve this, it intentionally included the abusive standard in section 1031 of the CFPA. The standard provides the flexibility to address the rapid changes legislative origins of abusive for guidance on how the Bureau may apply it. Chairwoman Sheila Bair made one of the first suggestions for Congress to use the abusive standard and supported expansion of the unfair and deceptive standards.47 In a 2007 congressional hearing on how to improve federal consumer protection, Chairman Bair proposed that Congress consider: adding the term “abusive.” “Abusive” is a standard contained in HOEPA [Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act] that the Fed [Reserve] is looking at using in the context of mortgage lending . . . “[A]busive” is a more flexible standard [than unfair or deceptive standards] to address some of the practices that make us all uncomfortable.48 A survey of federal legislation shows that the term abusive is not as new as some critics assert.49 Some commentators suggest that the abusive standard is merely a repurposing of doctrine of unconscionability—a doctrine first introduced in the English courts of equity and later codified in the Uniform Commercial Code.50 More frequently, commentators point to existing federal legislation that already use an abusive standard— some of which have been in place for more than thirty years—as evidence that the standard is not so unique.51 At least three federal consumer-protection provisions give various federal agencies the power to prohibit certain acts or practices as abusive. These are the (1) Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act;52 (2) Fair Debt Collection Practices Act;53 and (3) Federal Telemarketing Sales Rule. Regulators and financial institutions can also look to other federal provisions (such as Final Rules to Truth-in-Lending Act) that may not use the abusive standard, however, subsequent to the crisis, have banned practices that had evaded regulation under the unfair and deceptive tests. The Bureau can look to both types of provisions to interpret and apply the abusive standard.54 Despite a lengthy statutory definition and analogous provisions, great tension still exists regarding the scope of the abusive standard.55 Is abusive a purely subjective standard examined only from the consumer’s perspective, or does it reflect the idea that both the provider and consumer must take a certain level of responsibility in financial transactions? Unlike unfairness, abusive does not include a cost-benefit analysis.56 Therefore, would the Bureau be able to ban non-traditional products that may be abusive, but which consumers would otherwise find very beneficial? Consider auto-title loans— short-term loans secured by the title of a consumer’s car.57 Could the Bureau limit the number of auto-title loans extended to a given consumer within a one-month period, even though many consumers find having multiple auto-title loans particularly attractive?58 Critics assail the standard as vague59 and overly broad, because it is based in part on consumer perception.60 Regulators and courts will be required to engage in subjective analysis of the consumer’s mindset in a transaction, yet “it is unclear how a lender could guarantee a customer’s understanding . . . .”61 Consider payday loans or cash advance loans, a product that has historically passed the unfair or deceptive tests62 but may no longer be immune to regulation because of the greater emphasis on consumer understanding in the abusive standard.63 The loan rollover—the ability for one to roll their loan balance from one term to the next for increasing fees—is an attractive feature of payday loans, but it can create a cycle of debt.64 Many consumers systematically “overestimate their belief that they will pay off the loan at the end of the period and thus underestimate the likelihood that they might end up rolling over the loan.”65 By offering the rollover option with the knowledge that consumers are unlikely to repay, could the payday lender be abusive under section 1031(d)(2)(A), taking “unreasonable advantage of a lack of understanding on the part of the consumer?” These types of questions are propelling the consumer financial industry and legislators to demand more clarity around the standard or to strip the Bureau of such broad authority as this standard provides. C. Responding to Criticism: the “Abusive” Standard Is Work- able and Necessary Standard to Restore Consumer Confidence The uncertainty around the abusive standard has caused resistance from politicians and the consumer financial industry.66 Critics argue the standard’s vagueness and subjective nature will result in adverse policy consequences. Many predict the legal uncertainty, increased risk of litigation, and compliance costs will lead to a chilling effect on innovation and availability of credit.67 This could have a significant impact on economic recovery in this country.68 A reduced availability of credit products may harm the economically disadvantaged disproportionately, as they already have limited access to credit and further regulatory efforts could even further constrain available credit to the group.69 While there may be some adverse consequences to the abusive standard, the high degree of concern is unwarranted because the standard is not unduly vague and it is necessary to ensure a similar financial crisis is not repeated. From an administration standpoint, new legal standards are frequently drafted and enacted into law.70 By analogy when Congress initially enacted the unfair or deceptive standards in the FTCA, they intentionally drafted the language broadly to allow regulators and courts to continue to refine its definition and provide the flexibility to close regulatory gaps.71 One can also compare the abusive standard to broad language in federal antitrust legislation. In the Sherman Act, Congress gave the FTC authority to deal with “unfair methods of competition,”72 and declared illegal any “restraint of trade or commerce.”73 The language in the Sherman Act is “intentionally vague” to “allow each administration to interpret and enforce laws.”74 The broader language allowed flexibility for courts and regulators to adapt to changing conditions in the marketplace and to balance competing interests of private business and consumers.75 Analogies to these acts demonstrate that the abusive standard as drafted is not unduly vague. Millions have suffered as a result of the crisis, thus extensive change is needed to restore consumer confidence.76 The crisis demonstrated the need to shift to a more paternalistic, government-led approach to consumer financial protection; otherwise, some companies will continue to evade regulations as they historically have done.77 Pre-crisis consumer protection focused on disclosures and making consumer understand what they were getting into.78 The CFPA shifts the emphasis from disclosure to one of fairness; companies must now ask themselves: “Are we being fair?”79 John C. Dugan, the former Comptroller of the Currency during the crisis observed, “[T]here will be significantly more consumer protection regulation and enforcement over time, because that’s clearly what Congress wanted.”80 As Senator Christopher Dodd, one of the coauthors of the Act said: “Financial reform [is] not about punishing the financial services industry. Rather it [is] about restoring order, stability, and, most of all, confidence to our financial system.”81 These comments demonstrate the need for greater statutory reform, which the abusive standard satisfies. In summary, having a consumer watchdog with broad enough statutory reach to go after unethical practices is one of the first steps to restoring consumer confidence and economic stability. The abusive standard plays an integral part in achieving this goal. The standard is not as new or unduly vague as critics allege, and it is necessary to address the problems of failed consumer protection that played such a large part in the recent financial crisis. I. Defining and applying the abusive standard Some fear when the Bureau assumes its responsibilities in July 2011, it will overwhelm the financial industry with new regulations.82 To the contrary, any rulemaking or enforcement actions will likely not happen so quickly, because they take time to develop.83 Also, the Obama Administration has yet to appoint or confirm a director for the Bureau.84 Without a director, the Bureau cannot establish any new rules to protect consumers.85 Nor can the Bureau exercise any authority over non-bank businesses that currently evade regulation.86 Even once a director is nominated, the confirmation process will likely drag on for months.87 In light of this inevitable delay, exactly how the Bureau will define, interpret, and limit the abusive standard will continue to be an issue of frenzied debate for years to come.88 To contribute to these discussions, this section suggests how the Bureau may apply the abusive standard by identifying several classes of practices the Bureau should prohibit. These practices should be foremost in the Bureau’s mind as it utilizes its rulemaking and enforcement authority. In first applying the abusive standard, the Bureau must address the concerns of consumers and legislators, yet not alienate the financial industry—or otherwise risk the wrath from these groups.89 It is a very fine line. Many of the most blatantly abusive practices, such as hidden balloon payments, bait and switch tactics, etc., have already been prohibited through the CFPA or recent regulatory action.90 In order to build credibility and cooperation with consumers and financial companies, initially, the Bureau should use the abusive standard to prohibit unethical practices that have been banned in other consumer contexts by existing federal legislation. Using other federal legislation as support for its actions, the Bureau can establish credibility and avoid the perception of being arbitrary. If a practice is banned in one consumer financial context, it should not be tolerated in another. The three classes of practices that the Bureau should deem abusive are: (1) extending credit without regard to borrower’s ability to repay; (2) using overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics in consumer transactions; and (3) steering borrowers to certain products for the purpose of increasing lender compensation without meaningful benefit to the borrower. This Part analyzes each practice with a focus on three key factors: (1) what conduct constitutes the abusive practice, (2) why the practice falls under the CFPA’s definition of abusive and what existing legislation the Bureau can leverage to justify this prohibition, and (3) how the Bureau may apply this prohibition in different consumer financial contexts. By using this analytical framework, the contours of abusive can be more firmly established. A. Extending Credit Without Regard for the Ability to Repay Under its authority to prohibit abusive practices, the Bureau should prohibit the extension of credit to a borrower without adequate regard to a borrower’s reasonable ability to repay. 1. Conduct Constituting the Extension of Credit Without Regard to a Borrower’s Reasonable Ability Repay Extending credit without regard to a borrower’s ability to repay occurs when a lender: (1) fails to adequately verify a borrower’s credit, income, and financial obligations to determine a borrower’s reasonable ability to repay the loan or (2) inflates a borrower’s income in order to obtain a loan larger than the borrower can reasonably repay.91 For a secured loan, rather than relying on a borrower’s ability to make scheduled payments, lenders extend credit based on the liquidation value of the borrower’s collateral, such as a home or car. Put simply, lenders rely on the ability to seize a borrower’s equity in the asset to satisfy any outstanding obligation.92 This is commonly referred to as asset-based lending.93 For an unsecured loan, lenders rely on the recovery of high fees in the event of missed payments, rather than on the borrower’s ability to repay.94 These practices are particularly prevalent in the area of subprime or high-risk lending.95 Subprime and high-risk loans are “loan[s] with more burdensome terms than those of a ‘prime loan’ and is designed for a borrower who lacks the income or credit score to qualify for a prime loan.”96 High-risk products include payday loans, auto-title loans, and student credit products.97 2. Why is Failing to Perform an Adequate Assessment on a Borrower’s Repayment Ability “Abusive?” a. Falling Under the Statutory Definition of Abusive The Office of the Comptroller observed that extending credit absent a determination of a borrower’s reasonable repayment ability is “not consistent with established lending standards”98 and “generally forms the basis of abusive lending.”99 In light of these comments and as discussed below, the Bureau should find extending credit without adequate regard to a borrower’s ability to repay an abusive practice under section 1031(d)(2)(A) of the CFPA.100 First, extending credit without regard to a borrower’s ability to repay should be defined as abusive because under section 1031(d)(2)(A) of the CFPA, such practice takes “unreasonable advantage of . . . a lack of understanding on the part of the consumer of the material risks, costs, or conditions of the product or service . . . .”101 Consumers often fail to fully understand common financial products because of their complexity and prolix agreements.102 In the prime market, lenders are less able to exploit consumers’ lack of understanding because competition drives out bad products.103 Borrower exploitation is much more common in subprime markets where consumers are financially unsophisticated and more vulnerable to opportunistic lenders.104 Because of limited financial literacy, consumers do not comprehend key terms of a financial product, such as variable interest rates, annual percentage rates, and prepayment fees.105 Therefore, consumers fail to grasp the total cost of a loan, which leads to a poor understanding of their ability to make timely payments to lenders.106 Consequently, many consumers simply do not comprehend the material risks and costs associated with financial products such as mortgages, payday loans, and overdraft fees. Many subprime lenders, knowing or likely knowing of the consumers’ lack of understanding,107 nevertheless fail to adequately verify each borrower’s repayment ability, opting instead to extend loans relying on borrowers’ collateral or high fees. As the FTC has observed, such loans are intentionally structured to fail.108 Though the Bureau has yet to define what constitutes “unreasonable advantage,” the language could be construed to establish a quasi-duty of care owed by lenders to borrowers, limiting the amount that a lender could profit when one of the three prohibited conditions109 described in section 1031 exist.110 Also, if an “unreasonable advantage” is likely to be reviewed from the perspective of a reasonable consumer in the specific circumstance, the analysis could account for individual characters and attributes, such as financial literary.111 Against this backdrop, it is highly plausible that the Bureau would consider a lender to have taken “unreasonable advantage” of a borrower by extending a loan that the lender knows or should know is likely to fail. For example, in payday lending, it is estimated that over 90 percent of lender profitability is generated from high fees and penalties collected from borrowers who decline to pay or default on the initial loans and rollover their loans back-to-back over five or more successive payment periods.112 By offering such products, which lenders know or likely know the borrower is unlikely to repay, the lenders are taking unreasonable advantage of the borrower.113 Although one or two rollovers may actually assist the borrower, repeated rollovers with high fees serves only to place the consumer in a far worse financial position.114 The risk inequity between payday borrowers and lenders demonstrates why such loans are unreasonable. When lenders provide loans that borrowers are unlikely to repay, the consequences are significantly worse for borrowers than lenders. Consumer advocates claim that by failing to adequately verify a borrower’s repayment ability, lenders “trap borrowers into collateral-based loans they clearly cannot repay.”115 Borrowers may lose important assets, such as their home or cars; be forced to perpetual, high- cost refinancing; or be forced to declare bankruptcy.116 On the other hand, lenders profit handsomely, whether or not scheduled payments are made. This is done through their ability to seize the borrower’s collateral to satisfy the outstanding loan, profit from forced refinancing, or collect high fees associated with default.117 Lending without an adequate assessment of a borrower’s repayment ability is even more unreasonable, because it departs from customary underwriting principles.118 The Office of the Comptroller observed that a basic principle of loan underwriting requires a proper assessment of the “borrower’s capacity to make scheduled payments.”119 Ignoring basic loan underwriting lies at the heart of abusive, or as they are also commonly called, predatory practices.120 Given this outcome, lenders take unreasonable advantage of the borrower’s lack of understanding. When lenders knowingly lead borrowers into loans that will fail, borrowers are subject to significant harm from defaulting on failed loans, and despite the harm to borrowers, lenders receive a windfall. Therefore, the Bureau should prohibit as abusive the extension of loans absent an adequate assessment of a borrower’s ability to repay. b. Analogous Federal Legislation This section outlines the Federal Reserve and Congress’ decisions to ban the extension of credit without the regard for a borrower’s ability to repay for home mortgages and student credit-cards.121 Congress and the Federal Reserve took action because such practices took advantage of a borrower’s lack of understanding or misplaced reliance on lenders.122 Due to the similarities between these and other consumer financial sectors, the Bureau should prohibit such lending in other contexts.123 i. Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act In 1994, Congress gave the Federal Reserve authority, through HOEPA, to prohibit acts or practices related to any mortgages that the Federal Reserve determined were “unfair, deceptive . . . or associated with abusive lending.”124 Congress focused on preventing practices designed to “take advantage of unsophisticated borrowers.”125 In 2008, the Federal Reserve Board finalized rules prohibiting asset-based lending for high- priced mortgage loans,126 as part of its mandate under HOEPA to prevent those activities “associated with abusive lending.”127 In mortgage lending, brokers receive a commission on each loan closed. They are incentivized to close as many and as large loans as possible, rather than looking out for the long-term interests of the borrowers.128 As a result of these misaligned incentives, lenders inflated borrowers’ stated incomes to gain approval for larger- than-needed loans, understated borrower obligations, or failed to verify borrowers’ ability to repay.129 Inevitably, borrowers mistakenly relied on lenders to determine their ability to repay, unaware of high risks and unable to comprehend the complexities of a high-priced mortgage loan lenders sold to them.130 Accordingly, they became exposed to tremendous foreclosure risk.131 Such circumstances created a windfall for lenders. They profited regardless of whether or not borrowers met their loan payments.132 If borrowers met payments, lenders would profit from high-interest charged.133 If borrowers did not meet their payments but were able to refinance, lenders profited from the high fees and pre-payment penalties associated with refinancing. In the event of a borrower default, lenders usually recovered money owed in part from the foreclosure of the borrower’s homes.134 Each result heavily favored lenders to the severe detriment of borrowers. Several states, including New York, followed the Federal Reserve and enacted requirements for lenders to assess consumers’ ability to repay.135 Congress later expanded the prohibitions against asset-based lending across all consumer mortgages, in Title XIV of the CFPA.136 Given the strong measures taken against this practice in home mortgages, the Bureau should follow suit for similar practices in other contexts. ii. Credit Card Reform Act As part of the Credit Card Reform Act, enacted in 2009, Congress required credit card companies to first assess students’ reasonable ability to repay before approving them for a credit card.137 The Act specifically prohibited the issuance of credit cards to students, unless they were employed or had a reliable cosigner. The rationale for this requirement focused on how most students—by virtue of their youth and inexperience—do not understand consumer credit and the consequences of creating long- term credit card debt.138 Consequently, creditcard companies capitalized on this lack of understanding by offering easy credit and encouraging students to use credit cards without first verifying students’ repayment ability.139 This is in stark contrast to an adult’s application for a credit card, which generally requires verification of a consumer’s ability to repay based a consumer’s income, household income, work and credit history, and so forth.140 Although, the average student credit card limit is only $500, these products are highly profitable for the companies issuing them.141 Credit card companies profit when students use and pay the credit debt on time, but also profit if the students default, thanks to the ability to charge the highest interest rate on unpaid balances and students’ reliance on their families to cover the outstanding debt.142 Disturbed by the vulnerability of unsophisticated students—and windfalls received by credit card companies—Congress prohibited the extension of credit cards to students without regard to their ability to repay.143 3. How the Bureau May Implement This Prohibition Congress’ decision to require lenders to perform an adequate assessment of a student borrower’s repayment ability indicates a failure to do so is unreasonable not only for secured, larger-sized loans (like mortgages) but also for unsecured, small- sized loans.144 The Bureau may use this reasoning to prohibit the extension of payday loans without a determination that the borrower has a reasonable ability to repay. Payday loans are a type of subprime loan that have come under considerable public pressure and media scrutiny.145 Payday loans are intended as short-term cash advances provided for a fee, secured by a borrower’s post-dated check. Ideally, these loans are only intended to cover short-term emergencies.146 Most typically, a lender extends a $300 loan with a $50 fee to be repaid in two weeks.147 This loan equates to a high annualpercentage rate of 435 percent.148 Payday lending is a $35 billion industry and growing; loans are provided online and at over 22,000 locations nationwide.149 Despite state efforts to regulate the industry, lenders have frequently found creative ways to avoid state-level regulation and judicial action, necessitating the creation of a federal regulatory approach.150 Payday lenders do not provide an adequate assessment of a borrower’s ability to repay, thus the Bureau should deem the failure to do so as abusive given the disproportionate impact this practice has on borrowers compared to the lenders. Similar to consumers who receive high-priced mortgages or student credit cards, consumers who take out payday loans are usually financially unsophisticated.151 Though borrowers may be aware of the finance charges associated with the loan, they still lack an understanding of other material risks, costs, and conditions. These aspects include a high annual percentage rate, which limits a borrower’s ability to effectively compare alternative products;152 a systematic overestimation by borrowers of their ability to repay the loan; and a lack of understanding of the actual cost of the loan upon multiple renewals.153 Moreover, many borrowers do not realize that lenders have no obligation to conduct accurate assessments of borrowers’ abilities to repay.154 Payday lenders capitalize this lack of understanding. They typically perform limited verification on borrowers. Lenders require only proof the borrower receives a regular paycheck, has a bank account, or receives public benefits.155 Lenders do not possess an adequate view of the borrower’s true financial position.156 As such, lenders provide loans designed to fail.157 What makes the failure to properly verify borrower re- payment ability so unreasonable is outlined by analyzing loan rollovers. Only 25 percent of payday loans are paid off on time.158 An estimated 76 percent of payday loans are made to repay a pre- vious payday loan.159 As discussed in Part III.A.2.a., borrowers are consequently consumers, and at least perform selective assessments.169 To fail to conduct a more reasonable verification would be to perpetuate predatory loans.170 As Professor Elizabeth Warren commented about payday loans, “it is important from a regulatory standpoint that people are not at the mercy of lenders who build business models around fooling people. There’s a real problem . . . [and] I anticipate a lot of change in this [payday loan] area.”171 Accordingly, as illustrated by the analogies to high- priced mortgage loans and students credit cards, the Bureau can justify prohibiting as abusive any extension of credit without adequate regard to a borrowers’ abilities to repay— especially given the windfall to lenders at the expense of naïve borrowers. B. Overly Aggressive Sales and Marketing Tactics Another practice the Bureau should prohibit is overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics that are used to coerce or intimidate borrowers into entering a credit transaction.172 1. What Constitutes Overly Aggressive Sales & Marketing Tactics? Another practice the Bureau should prohibit is overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics that are used to coerce or intimidate borrowers into entering a credit transaction. forced to rollover the first loan into a new loan in order to pay off the first at high additional costs, leading to a perpetual cycle of debt.160 Professor Elizabeth Warren— the Special Advisor to the Obama Administration responsible for laying the groundwork for the Bureau— To determine what conduct constitutes abusive sales and marketing tactics, the Bureau can find authority in the Fair Debt Collection Practices Act and Federal Telemarketing Sales Rule.173 Obviously, some “hard-sell” sales tactics will exist in the marketplace. Overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics, however, should be viewed as any conduct a lender may engage in, “the natural consequence of which is to harass, oppress, or abuse any person” in connection with the sale or marketing of a consumer financial product.174 Government reports and academic studies outline some of these practices. These include engaging in incessant sales calls, either made through the telephone or door-to-door visits; discouraging borrowers from investigating lower cost alternatives; pressuring borrowers to sign documents immediately or without reading them; and so forth.175 One tactic that has been observed that rollovers are the most dangerous feature of payday lending.161 On average, borrowers will rollover the same loan nine times before repayment, usually in back-to-back succession. 162 This doubles the ultimate repayment amount.163 For example, if a borrower rolls over their $300 loan, eight times, borrower will pay $705 in principal, interests, and fees.164 What is even more concerning is that 90 percent of the payday lenders’ profitability derives from borrowers who are unable to repay and must rollover their loans. Thus, payday lenders are not incentivized to perform in-depth checks of a borrower’s ability to repay. The more people use the loans as they are intended and repay on-time, the less profitable payday lenders will be. This strengthens the assertion that payday lenders, who fail to adequately verify a borrower’s repayment ability, are taking unreasonable advantage of borrowers’ lack of understanding of risks by purposefully ignoring the fact that they are leading borrowers into loans they cannot repay.165A Department of Defense report—which led to heavy federal regulation of payday loans for the military— explains the exploitative nature of this industry: “It is clear that the payday lending business model is based on the repeat high loan fees from one borrower in successive transactions, without the extension of new principle.”166 Small-dollar loans, like payday loans, are useful to American families as they provide a source for fast, short-term cash, thus the Bureau’s intent is not to eliminate them.167 Nor is the Bureau able to impose usury caps.168 To facilitate the speed of the transaction, requiring an extensive verification of ability to repay is somewhat problematic. Yet, with its existing data, payday lenders could analyze and generate profiles of those borrowers who are most likely to default, use the profile to screen new and existing particularly effective occurs when lenders “send out solicitations that are designed to resemble collection notices, so that frightened homeowners will reply, only to be cajoled into taking out high cost loans.”176 These acts are done with the purpose of selling a loan by subjecting the borrower to undue psychological or emotional pressure.177 2. Overly Aggressive Sales and Marketing Tactics Fall Within CFPA’s Standard a. Falling Under the Statutory Definition of Abusive Section 1031(d)(1) of the CFPA states that any practice is abusive if it “materially interferes with the ability of a consumer to understand a term or condition of a consumer financial product or service.”178 Aggressive sales and marketing tactics materially interfere with a consumer’s ability to understand the terms of the product because they are intended to be or have the effect of overwhelming, confusing, or causing anxiety in the consumer.179 Lenders rely on threats, emotional and psychological pressure, and borrower ignorance to push prospective borrowers through an application process in pursuit of credit beyond what the borrowers want, need, or can afford.180 All of this severely limits a consumer’s ability to make sound judgments on the product being offered.181 A joint federal taskforce characterized the effect of aggressive sales tactics like the CFPA’s §1031(d)(1) definition of an abusive practice. The report stated: “These practices interfere with, and in some cases, deprive borrowers of the opportunity to understand the terms of a proposed loan.”182 Some lenders even use federally required disclosures to confuse consumers.183 Loan officers “typically schedule a home loan closing every thirty minutes, an unrealistic amount of time for even a highly literate borrower to read through all the [approximately 50 pages] fine print.”184 Buried in the documents will be the three to five pages of disclosures.185 Lenders move through the documents rapidly; by doing so, it communicates to the borrower that they are expected to not ask questions or are expected to understand the documents easily.186 This is designed to “‘overload, overwhelm, distract, and . . . fatigue borrowers.”187 This rushed feeling creates a sense of stress, “leading to truncated reasoning” rather than a careful understanding of aspects of the loan.188 This articulates the negative impact overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics have on a consumer’s ability to understand the important terms of a loan. Therefore, overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics fall within the CFPA’s definition of abusive. b. Analogous Federal Legislation The Bureau’s decision to prohibit overly aggressively sales and marketing tactics as abusive can leverage similar reasoning and definitions used by Congress and the Federal Reserve used to curb such practices under the Fair Debt Collection Practices Act189 and the Federal Telemarketing Sales Rule.190 Like the CFPA, the purpose of these provisions is to prevent and eliminate abusive practices that became serious national problems. i. The Fair Debt Collection Practices Act In 1977, Congress established abusive as a legal standard in the Fair Debt Collection Practices Act (“FDCPA”). The standard, enforced by the FTC, was intended to protect a major part of consumer finance: debt collection. The FDCPA uses the abusive standard broadly to encompass abusive, deceptive, and unfair practices.191 Specifically section 1692(d) states: “A debt collector may not engage in any conduct the natural consequence of which is to harass, oppress, or abuse any person in connection with the collection of a debt.”192 This section also enumerates specific conduct as a violation of this prohibition, including the use of repeated calling to annoy or harass the listener; use of obscene language or “language the natural consequence of which is to abuse the hearer or reader”; and threats of violence.193 These behaviors are akin to overly aggressive sales and marketing practices discussed above. The statute gives the FTC added flexibility by enabling “the courts, when appropriate, to proscribe other improper conduct, which is not specifically addressed” in the statutory language.194 Since 1978, the FTC has brought over sixty enforcement actions against parties who violated this Act;195 many involved lenders engaging in abusive debt collection in violation of 1692(d).196 This gives the Bureau a considerable body of case law to consider in forming policy and regulations to further define abusive under section 1031 of the CFPA.197 ii. The Federal Telemarketing Sales Rule The Bureau can also look to the Federal Telemarketing Sales Rule (“FSTR”), a part of the Telemarketing and Consumer Fraud and Abuse Prevention Act,198 for more recent guidance.199 Congress designed the FSTR to prohibit deceptive and abusive telemarketing activities.200 It is estimated that unscrupulous businesses utilize advances in telemarketing as a way to victimize consumers, costing consumers $40 billion a year.201 To implement the Act, the FTC promulgated the FTSR based in large part on the FDCPA definition of prohibited practices—conducts that “harass, oppress, or abuse” a borrower.202 The FTSR enumerates certain acts as abusive, including: all types of threats, intimidation, or obscene language;203 patterns of unsolicited calls intended to annoy, abuse, or harass any person; and refusal to identify the calling party.204 Commentary by the FTC also provides an even more expansive definition of abusive acts of intimidation including “acts that would place undue pressures on the consumer, or which call into question a person’s intelligence, honesty, reliability, or concern for family . . .[or] [r]epeated calls to a consumer who has declined a telemarketing offer.”205 Lenders engaging in any of these acts render consumers unreasonably more susceptible to telemarketing schemes. Such practices are, therefore, considered abusive. The Bureau should look to the FSTR and the FDCPA for considerable guidance when justifying the prohibition of overly aggressive sales and marketing practices in other consumer financial contexts. 3. How will the Bureau Implement this Prohibition? Consulting applicable federal legislation, the Bureau will establish regulations to eliminate the most abusive practices. While reports indicate overly aggressive marketing and sales tactics are common in several areas, the industry requiring immediate regulation is home mortgages, given its gross impact on the financial crisis.206 There are two reasons the Bureau should deem overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics to be abusive in home mortgages. First, prohibiting these practices will reduce the kinds of predatory subprime loans that resulted in millions of foreclosures. The severity of the financial crisis resulted in part from the proliferation of such unaffordable loans.207 Once borrowers realized they could not afford these subprime loans that were inherently designed to fail, foreclosures ensued.208 There is a broad consensus amongst commentators that aggressive marketing and solicitation tactics are central aspects of predatory subprime lending.209 Practices, such as incessant calling and excessive disclosures, negatively impacted borrowers’ abilities to make informed decision and allowed lenders to take advantage of them.210 Most subprime borrowers have lower income, often have less education, and frequently lack the financial sophistication to adequately scrutinize a loan.211 Unscrupulous subprime lenders preyed on unsophisticated borrowers by using fear and psychological pressure to interfere with consumers’ understanding of the terms and conditions of a given transaction. Certain groups, such as the elderly, who have significant equity in their homes but limited financial education, were the most susceptible to lenders engaging in these tactics.212 Ultimately, lenders engaged in overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics coerced borrowers “to continue through the loan application process in cases in which the customer would prefer to discontinue the process.”213 Consequently, lenders “direct[ed] them to products that may not be the best for their needs – or affordable in the long run.”214 Under the abusive standard, the Bureau has the flexibility to ban overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics, reducing the numbers of consumers who are pressured into unfair loans. Second, the nation’s current financial straits demand regulation of overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics far more than aggressive debt collection or telemarketing. Congress justified the FDCPA prohibitions by pointing to the size and growth of the $5 billion debt-collection industry in 1976.215 By the same reasoning, restricting overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics is even more necessary. The total losses resulting from the subprime mortgage crisis are estimated to hit $636 billion;216 eight million borrowers will lose their homes to foreclosures “because of an inability to repay unsound loans.”217 Given the magnitude of the subprime mortgage crisis, and the common association between consumer foreclosures and aggressive sales tactics—the Bureau should prohibit overly aggressive sales and marketing tactics as abusive. C. Steering Practices The fallout of the subprime-mortgage crisis not only revealed the need to regulate aggressive marketing and sales tactics and asset-based lending but also loan steering. 1. Conduct Constituting Abusive Steering Practice Steering occurs when a lender or loan originator directs a consumer away from a certain type of product towards a less beneficial alternative.218 Most often the lender has access to alternative products or terms for which the consumer is eligible, yet lenders will steer consumers away from better suited products, toward a detrimental alternative.219 Steering is done to increase the lender’s revenue through additional kickbacks or profits generated for the lender by selling a different product.220 These acts occur despite an expectation or reliance by the consumer that lenders will act in the consumer’s best interests.221 The practice of loan steering is commonly reported in mortgage lending, overdraft fees,222 student loans, and other consumer products.223 Consider overdraft payment programs.224 Cases have been reported where banks steered consumers who frequently overdraw on their accounts into fee-based overdraft programs in order to maximize bank revenue, rather than less expensive overdraft options or other credit alternatives.225 The most frequent users of overdraft programs are lower-income individuals with less financial sophistication. Critics allege banks use these programs to exploit these consumers’ lack of knowledge and naivety to generate an estimated $38 billion annually.226 In November 2010, the FDIC issued guidance, strongly discouraging steering in overdraft programs, but only after the CFPA was proposed.227 2. How Does Steering Fall Within the Definition of Abusive a. Falling Under the Statutory Definition of Abusive Steering should be defined abusive under section 1031(d)(2)(C) of the CFPA. Section 1031(d)(2)(C) states an act or practice is abusive if it “takes unreasonable advantage of the reasonable reliance by the consumer on a covered person to act in the interests of the consumer.”228 For many consumer finance transactions, there is evidence that consumers rely heavily on a lender’s advice when selecting a product or loan.229 In the mortgage context, this reliance is developed as lenders may cultivate themselves as a “trusted advisor”230 or through an established relationship between the borrower, lender, and an affiliated institution.231 Because of this reliance, consumers inaccurately (though commonly) believe lenders are obligated to obtain the best interest rates and terms for them.232 For example, in a national Fannie Mae Survey, over half of all Hispanic and African-American borrowers surveyed believed that “lenders are required by law to provide the best possible loan rates.”233 Despite recognizing that many consumers rely on their lenders, lenders still steer consumers towards products or loans with disadvantageous terms compared to other available products. In a speech to the Consumers Union, Professor Warren observed “[t]oo many profit models have been built around steering customers into products they can’t understand or may not be able to afford.”234 Accordingly, lenders profit from and take unreasonable advantage of this reliance by placing consumers in loans which did not meet their financial and personal needs.235 In many cases, this practice forces borrowers into unmanageable or crippling debt.236 b. Analogous Federal Legislation in the CFPA Prohibitions against steering already exist in the home- mortgage context and thus steering should no longer be tolerated in other consumer credit contexts as well.237 The CFPA amended TILA to impose restrictions on steering by loan originators and on yield spread premiums for mortgages. In home mortgages executed prior to April 1, 2011, lenders typically paid loan originators—mortgage brokers and their employees—higher compensation if the borrower agreed to an interest rate that is higher than the rate required by the lender. This is commonly referred to as a yield spread premium.238 Because of this compensation structure, brokers were highly incentivized to steer and influence borrowers towards loans with higher interest rates in order to gain the additional compensation, often at the expense of the borrower.239 The practice became so prevalent that Fannie Mae estimated that as many as 50 percent of subprime borrowers could have qualified for lower prime rate interest loans.240 While disclosure requirements existed, they had little impact.241 Section 1403 of the CFPA prohibits a “mortgage originator from receiving, directly or indirectly, compensation that varies based on the terms of the loan, other than the amount of the principal.”242 It also prohibits originators from steering borrowers from a qualified mortgage (one with generally less risky terms) to a non-qualified mortgage (one with generally riskier terms); to a loan that the consumer lacks a reasonable ability to repay; or to a loan that has “predatory characteristics (such as equity stripping, excessive fees, or abusive terms).”243 Even though changes in the CFPA were not to go into effect until April 2011, on August 16, 2010, the Federal Reserve Board took several actions to immediately protect consumers from steering in advance of the CFPA provisions.244 From testimony and consumer testing supporting its decision, the Board concluded (1) consumers are simply not aware or lack an understanding of yield spread premiums and the large incentive that brokers have to steer borrowers; (2) consumers who understand that creditors pay loan originators “may not fully understand the implications of this practice”; and (3) consumers place significant reliance on their trust and relationship with the broker to provide terms that are in the consumers’ interest.245 In announcing the new rules, just a month following the enactment of the Dodd-Frank Act, the Board actions may reflect what actions the Bureau may take once it takes authority over consumer financial protection. 3. How the Bureau Should Implement Anti-Steering Prohibitions The CFPA and Final Rules to TILA adopted by the Board signaled a willingness to embrace some quasi-form of fi- duciary duty owed to borrowers by lenders to act in borrowers’ best interests in home mortgages.246 The spirit of these protections should apply broadly to consumer finance, as the circumstances that led the Board to label steering as an abusive practice in home- mortgage industry are present in other credit markets. One such example is private student loans. Private student loans are loans extended by private institutions to students and families in order to pay for higher- education costs.247 These loans are outside of government-sponsored student loan programs and are not subsidized by the federal government.248 Private loans are significantly more risky and ex- pensive than their federal counterparts.249 Unlike federal student loans that are offered at fixed rates, private student loans have variable interest rates. On average, the base interest rate is twice that of federal loans.250 Reported interest rates for private loans in 2010 averaged from 11 to 12 percent251 and went as high as 18 percent.252 In contrast, rates at about the same time for government-supported student loans were 5.6 to 6.8 percent.253 The private student loan industry bears many alarming similarities to the precrisis subprime mortgage industry.254 It possesses limited regulatory activity, features high-risk borrowers, and appears to inflict disproportionate harm on lower-income borrowers.255 Other statistics call attention to tremendous growth of the industry. In August 2010, the Federal Reserve reported that national student loan debt surpassed credit card debt; approximately 20 percent of the loans are private student loans.256 In the 2005–06 year, private student lenders originated $17.3 billion in loans, tripling in size from the five years prior.257 These conditions demonstrate a need for active regulation of private student of obtaining private loans without first exhausting one’s federal loan options could lead to “a lifetime of excessive and unnecessary debt.”276 This is particularly alarming because student loans can- not be discharged through personal bankruptcy proceedings.277 Overall, private student loans enjoy fewer consumer protections, have less flexible repayment options, and generally expose borrowers to greater financial risk than federal student loans.278 Despite these consequences, many preferred lenders may nevertheless steer students away from federal loans by electing to not confirm whether the student has exhausted his or her federal loans. As a result, Congress explicitly included this industry within the Bureau’s jurisdiction. Additionally, the CFPA creates a private education loan ombudsman, demonstrating Congress’ intent to reign in abuses.259 Under its authority to prohibit abusive practices, the Bureau may elect to prohibit private student lenders, who have a preferred lender status with educational institutions, from steer- ing students (1) to enter higher than necessary private student loans when they qualify for low cost federal loans and (2) steering students to larger loans than students need.260 Such acts have the practical effect of increasing lender compensation, since lenders generate greater interest payments from a larger loan. When entering into private student loans, students rarely shop around.263 They instead rely heavily on the preferred vendors recommended by their schools’ financial aid office. Over 90 percent of students seeking loans will go with the school’s “preferred lenders.”264 Therefore, placement on a preferred list is highly competitive.265 A student’s reliance on a preferred lender is generally based on the student’s lack of understanding of the difference be- tween federal and private loans.266 Students simply do not possess the financial sophistication to make informed decisions.267 Also, the reliance on the lender is based on a misguided, but not unreasonable, expectation that as preferred lenders to their school these lenders are required to act in the best interests of the school and, by extension, the student.268 Preferred private student lenders are aware of the stu- dent’s reliance and lack of understanding.269 In fact, that is likely why they compete so fiercely to get on a school’s list of recom- mended lenders.270 The incentive structure for these lenders deters them from verifying with the school whether the borrower has exhausted their federal loans and offering a lesser loan amount. Of private student loans extended in 2009, 64 percent of students had not exhausted their federal loans.271 More concerning is that 26 percent of private loan borrowers, who qualified for federal loans, failed to even use federal loans at all.272 By steering a student to a larger loan without regard to federal loan access, lenders take unreasonable advantage of the students’ reliance and thus engage in an abusive practice. This is the type of practice that the Bureau and section 1031 seeks to prevent.273 The larger loan automatically exposes students to more risk than a federal loan.274 As Senator Jared Polis, a member of the House Education and Labor Committee, observed “[p]rivate student loans are one of the riskiest and most expensive ways to pay for college . . . [it] can be riskier than using a credit card.”275 The result ment.279 Such practices are abusive and the Bureau should take action to prohibit preferred private student lenders extend student loans without verifying whether the student has exhausted their federal loan options. The problems of private student loans became so severe that the House passed an amendment to the Dodd-Frank Act, requiring lenders to obtain certification from the borrower’s schools confirming students had exhausted federal loans.280 Congress had recently approved a student self-certification requirement, so the Senate declined to approve the amendment until results on self- certification were more extensive.281 Initial field studies indicate that self-certification has not been effective in curbing student awareness.282 In light of the proven ineffectiveness of similar dis- closures283 selfcertification is unlikely to provide the necessary protections to stem loan steering.284 Therefore, the Bureau should prohibit steering as an abusive practice in the context of private student loans. Iv. Conclusion The Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection will play an integral role in redeveloping stability in the consumer financial industry. Practices that once fell outside the FTCA’s unfair and deceptive standards will no longer evade regulation under the Consumer Financial Protection Act’s abusive standard. Despite some criticism to the contrary, the term abusive is neither new nor unduly vague. Further, the abusive standard is necessary to provide adequate protections against future financial crisis related to consumer credit products. By analogy to past application of abusive as a legal standard in other statutes, one can confidently say that the CFPA’s abusive standard applies at least three classes of practices. Developing the regulation of such practices will allow the abusive standard to be better understood. *J.D., May 2012, Loyola Law School Los Angeles. My deepest gratitude to Professor Lauren Willis for her guidance. Thank you to Professor Richard Alderman of the University of Houston Law Center, Gail Hillebrand of the Consumers Union, Kathleen Keest of the Center for Responsible Lending, Professor John Pottow of the University of Michigan Law School, and John Wright of Wells Fargo Bank for their valuable insight. I would like to acknowledge Professors Aaron Caplan, Bryan Hull, Laurie Levenson, and John Nockleby for their mentorship. Special thanks to Ali Mojibi, John McClintock, Jeffrey Payne, Andrew Lichtenstein, Kathy Huang, and many others for their support. This Article is dedicated to my family. Discussion Questions How do you decide whether to prohibit a product or practice? How many people like it? How dangerous is it? Is the analogy to the faulty toaster a good one? Is the analogy to the FTC rules regarding misleading ads or the FDA letting a drug onto the market. How should they balance benefits vs. dangers? Should they ban or heavily regulate Payday loans in general or only those to special targets such as the mentally challenged or those in the military? Is limiting interest on payday loans a price control or a prohibition? What is the relationship between their mandate and the concept of unconscionability or the concepts of deception? One of their earliest proposals was to deny enforcement on credit obligations where the credit granter did not follow basic underwriting standards? Was this a good choice? Why do you think they started there? They limited their scrutiny to subprime mortgages. Why do you think they made that decision? Isn’t taking advantage of the consumer’s lack of knowledge a basic tenet of capitalism? Where does it cross a line and become wrongful? What duty does the lender owe to the borrower? What about steering a consumer to a less advantageous product? Who kind of duty does the credit granter have to the customer? What may the parties reasonably expect from one another? What about marketing to groups with known limitations: People with under a certain i.q? High school students? College Students? Consider each of the following> Please reread the Ronald Mann article at page _________ How Risky Is It to Make a Non-QM Mortgage? And Is QM Going to Hold Back Access to Credit? posted by Adam Levitin One of the huge questions hanging over the mortgage market today is what will happen to access to credit for credit impaired or non-traditional borrowers. There is a real concern that the Dodd-Frank Act’s mortgage reforms will reduce the availability of mortgage credit because lenders’ fear liability for making mortgage loans that fail to qualify as “Qualified Mortgages” (QM) and are thus potentially subject to an Ability-toRepay (ATR) defense. I've blogged on aspect of QM before (here, here, here, here, here, here, here, and here). Based on a preliminary analysis, I think this concern is overblown, and in this very long post I attempt to work through the potential liability for lenders that make non-Qualified Mortgages. (I note that all of this is my tentative readings of the statute; we really don’t know how courts will interpret it, and others may see better readings than I do now.) Still, my back-of-the-envelope calculation suggests that it is quite low in terms of loss given default and could probably be priced in at around 18 basis points in additional cost for a portfolio with weighted average maturities (actual) of five years. Even with rounding up, that's 25 basis points to recover additional credit losses, which is not a big impact on credit availability. I invite those who would calculate this differently to weigh in in the comments—it’s quite possible that there are factors I have overlooked here, as this is a really preliminary analysis. Ultimately, I don't think ATR liability really matters in terms of availability of credit. What matters is the lack of liquidity--meaning a secondary market--in non-QM loans, as lenders aren't going to want a lot of illiquid loans on their books, and that is a function of the GSEs' credit box, not CFPB regulation. Because this post is REALLY long (the Mother of All QM Posts), here’s where it goes (yes, I feel like I'm doing one of those unwieldy 100+ page UFTA decisions, so I'm going to have a table of contents!): First, it gives the legal background on the Dodd-Frank Act ATR requirement; Second, it covers the Qualified Mortgage safe harbor to the ATR requirement; Third, it covers the civil liability to the CFPB and Attorneys General for failing to verify ATR; Fourth, it covers private civil liability for ATR violations; Fifth, it covers the private civil damages for ATR violations; Sixth, it addresses the likelihood of liability of ATR liability; Seventh, it attempts to calculate a reasonable loss given default rate for ATR and the affect on mortgage pricing (please note that I am not attempting to work in compounding anywhere here; this is a ballpark analysis, not a precise figure); Eighth, it considers whether the real issue is ATR so much as the costs imposed by contested foreclosures (which ATR might make more common); and Ninth, it suggests that ATR may not really matter in terms of access to credit, as the real limitation will be the lack of liquidity for loans that do not meet the GSEs’ underwriting guidelines independent of QM. Phew. 1. The Ability-to-Repay Requirement The single-most substantive regulation for consumer banking included in the DoddFrank Act is the Ability to Repay (ATR) requirement for mortgages (sorry Durbin Amendment, I love you, but mortgages are just bigger than debit). Title XIV of the Dodd-Frank Act amends the Truth in Lending Act (TILA) to provide that “no creditor may make a residential mortgage loan unless the creditor makes a reasonable and good faith determination based on verified and documented information that, at the time the loan is consummated, the consumer has a reasonable ability to repay the loan, according to its terms, and all applicable taxes, insurance (including mortgage guarantee insurance), and assessments.” 2. The Qualified Mortgage Safe Harbor The Dodd-Frank Act directs the CFPB to create a safe harbor for “Qualified Mortgages” or QMs. The CFPB has defined a QM (with some minor exceptions) as a mortgage meeting six criteria 1.regular payments that are substantially equal (ARMs and step-rate mortgages excepted) and always positively amortizing 2.term of no more than 30 years 3.limited fees/points (caps vary with mortgage size) 4.underwritten using the maximum interest rate in the first five years to ensure repayment 5.income verified 6.backend debt-to-income ration of no more than 43% (including simultaneous loans) The last three requirements are satisfied prior if the loan is eligible for GSE purchase or guarantee. If the loan is a QM it qualifies for a safe harbor from the ATR requirement. If the loan is a regular QM, this is an absolute, irrebuttable safe harbor, while if the loan is a high-cost QM (defined as pricing at 150 basis points over prime for first liens, and 350 basis points over prime for junior liens), then the safeharbor is a rebuttable one. To understand the importance of the safe harbors, it is necessary to understand what happens if a lender doesn’t comply with this ability to repay (ATR) requirement. This has been a source of a lot of confusion. There is definitely some risk for lenders, but I think it is much less than generally perceived by the lending industry. What is critical to understand is that a loan can be non-QM, but still satisfy the statutory ATR requirement. The statute only prohibits loans that are made without verified ATR. 3. Civil Liability to CFPB and Attorneys General for ATR Violations If a loan is made without verified ATR, there is the possibility of a CFPB enforcement action within three years of the violation. TILA is a “Federal consumer financial law,” by virtue of being an “enumerated consumer law” and the Dodd-Frank Act provides that “It shall be unlawful for…any covered person…to offer or provide to a consumer any financial product or service not in conformity with Federal consumer financial law, or otherwise commit any act or omission in violation of a Federal consumer financial law”. The CFPB can seek a civil monetary penalty and/or an injunction for violations of Federal consumer financial laws. The CFPB, of course, has limited enforcement resources; as long as a lender is making a good faith effort to verify ATR, CFPB enforcement seems unlikely. The mere fact that loans have high default rates should not by itself be a problem for ATR liability, although it does suggest a possible problem with the lender’s ATR analysis and might raise some eyebrows. Note that the CFPB's statute of limitations on an ATR violation is shorter than the generic CFPB statute of limitations. Generally, the CFPB has three years from the discovery of a violation in which to bring an action. But that does not apply to actions "arising solely under enumerated consumer laws." Instead, the enumerated consumer law's statute of limitations applies, and for TILA it is three years from the violation, not three years from discovery of the violation. (There might be caselaw interpreting this differently, of course.) ATR violations can also brought by state attorneys general within three years of the date of the violations (not from the date of the discovery of the violation). It isn't clear, however, how the remedy would work. The state AGs are authorized to bring an action to "enforce" the ATR rule, but the only remedy prescribed by the statute for an ATR violation is one of setoff or recoupment. Neither remedy is of any use to a state AG because the state AG is not a debtor and therefore wouldn't have any right of setoff. (Remember, setoff requires mutually owing debts.) I think the intention is civil liability to the attorney general for the amount allowed for the TILA setoff (below), but the statute isn't clear. Given that the state attorney general has no right of setoff or recoupment, it isn't clear what it would mean for a state attorney general to bring an ATR violation. Perhaps injunctive relief is possible, but I don't see a TILA provision authorizing state AGs to bring an action for injunctive relief. State AGs have authorization to bring actions under Title X of the Dodd-Frank Act (other than against national banks and federal thrifts). It's not clear if that only allows for actions enforcing the organic provisions of Title X, such as UDAAP, or whether it also extends to enforcing the provision that “It shall be unlawful for…any covered person…to offer or provide to a consumer any financial product or service not in conformity with Federal consumer financial law, or otherwise commit any act or omission in violation of a Federal consumer financial law”. (If so, then state AGs can enforce all of the enumerated consumer laws.) 4. Private Civil Liability for ATR Violations The real risk, it would seem, for failing to verify ATR is that that it creates TILA liability. It is not clear, however, just what this TILA liability is. There are two possibilities. The first is that there is both liability for an affirmative cause of action under TILA and as TILA setoff defense, while the second is that there is only liability for a TILA setoff defense. TILA’s generic remedy provision, 15 USC 1640(a), provides for damages in a private right of action, but this remedy is limited to original creditors; assignees are liable only to the extent that a violation is apparent on “the face of the disclosure statement”. That’s language that has no applicability to an ATR violation, which isn’t a disclosure violation. Therefore, there is no assignee liability for a direct TILA right of action on ATR. But isn’t even clear that there is originating creditor liability for a direct affirmative cause of action. Section 1640(a) provides for affirmative damages, "[e]xcept as otherwise provided in this section," and elsewhere in section 1640 there is the specification of a remedy for an ATR violation of a "defense by recoupment or set off". 15 USC 1640(k). I think it would be fair to read this as saying that a defense by recoupment or set off is the exclusive remedy for an ATR violation. But this is far from clear at least on the face of the statute. If there is an affirmative cause of action available, it is subject to a three-year statute of limitations from the date of the ATR violation and can be brought only against the originator. A TILA defense, in contrast, can be brought at any time during the life of the loan, and can be raised against anyone attempting to collect on the loan, be in the originator or any assignee. If a defense is the exclusive remedy, there are two important implications. First, the TILA remedy is triggered only when the creditor tries to collect on the loan by "intiat[ing] a judicial or nonjudicial foreclosure of the residential mortgage loan, or any other action to collect the debt in connection with such loan". I read "intiat[ing]...any other action" to mean bringing a judicial action, not just any attempt to collect such as sending out a billing statement. If so, the consumer really does not control the timing of the TILA ATR defense. Second, because the TILA remedy is a setoff, it only reduces the collection on the loan. (Setoff is a broader concept than recoupment--setoff involves offsetting any mutual debts, whereas recoupment involves offsetting debts from the same transaction. For this reason I will only refer to setoff.) The TILA ATR remedy does not prevent the foreclosure (unless, presumably, the TILA setoff is greater than the unpaid balance on the loan). Although, there is no statute of limitations for the TILA defense, it can only be raised as a setoff defense to a collection action, which means that there have to be mutually owing debts. If the money has been collected from the debtor, there are no longer mutually owing debts, and the funds the debtor has paid cannot be clawed back. Thus, if a foreclosure sale's proceeds have been distributed, it is too late to raise the defense, other than against the collection of a deficiency judgment. Third, how a TILA setoff defense this applies in a nonjudicial foreclosure is not clear. A defense or counterclaim simply has no application to a nonjudicial foreclosure. Perhaps this means that any borrower that can raise an ATR claim can convert a nonjudicial foreclosure into a judicial one, but there’s nothing making clear how this works. In any case, I’m going to focus here on the TILA defense, because that’s where I think the real issue lies, not in an affirmative cause of action. I think this is the case because an affirmative cause of action: 1.is questionable, at least from the face of the statute, whether there is such a right of action; 2.the affirmative cause of action has a shorter statute of limitations than the defense; 3.the affirmative cause of action has limited defendants; 4.plaintiffs would lack the facts to be able to sufficiently plead a case to get past Iqbal and Twombly and would therefore likely lose on motions to dismiss (this problem doesn't exist for a defense); and 5.the affirmative cause of action has small enough damages that it isn’t an attractive sort of suit to bring for most attorneys, even with the attorneys’ fee provision; pro se actions are more likely in the foreclosure context where the homeowner is motivated to try to reduce losses or fight the foreclosure rather than opportunistically seek a gain. The possibility of a class action isn't much of a concern because TILA caps class action damages at the lesser of $1 million or 1% of the defendant's net worth. There's the possibility of TILA violations being predicates for state law UDAP class actions, where no damages cap exists, but I don't see this as a real risk for lenders that actual make some attempt to underwrite loans. 5. Calculation of ATR Private Civil Liability Irrespective of how the TILA defense works procedurally, it does not prevent a foreclosure. (The same is true if an affirmative cause of action exists.) Instead, if successful, it simply reduces the foreclosing lender’s claim on the foreclosure sale proceeds. The reduction is by the sum of: 1.actual damages resulting from the failure to verify ATR. 2.statutory damages of between $400 and $4000. 3.the consumers’ costs of the litigation plus “reasonable” attorneys’ fees 4.the sum of all finance charges and fees paid by the consumer on the loan within three years of the ATR violation, unless the failure to verify ATR “is not material.” It’s worth unpacking all of these. (Again, these are the same damages as in a direct affirmative cause of action, if one exists.) What are “actual damages” from failure to verify ATR? From other similar “actual damages” provisions, such as those in the FDCPA, we know that “actual damages” can include emotional harm to the borrower. It might also include consequential damages, such as harm to the consumer’s credit score, which can have effects on employment, insurance, and other loan pricing. It might also include the relocation costs from a foreclosure (although generally those costs would not have been incurred at the time the defense is raised). But what about the loan itself? Is that actual damages? Actual damages requires a loss causation requirement, meaning that it must be shown that but for the failure to verify ATR, the borrower would not have incurred the damages. But I could see a reading in which there is an assumption of loss causation, in that the loan was made only because the lender failed to verify ATR. If so, then actual damages would be all amounts paid on the loan plus the outstanding balance (principal, interest, fees, etc.). That said, I don’t think the loan itself would likely be included in actual damages as it is too speculative to say that the borrower wouldn’t have gotten a loan at all based on after-thefact underwriting. Perhaps the borrower could have gotten a loan, just at a higher rate. Still, there is some question as to what, if anything, “actual damages” are. The statutory damages are the easy part and are capped at $4,000, with judicial discretion within the allowed range. Costs and attorneys’ fees can be quite expensive. If a case gets litigated all the way, it could easily be $50,000 (remember, consumer attorneys are generally not billing $1,000/hr) and possibly much more, especially if the consumer retains expert witnesses. The finance charges and fees could add up to quite a lot, if the default is late in the life of the loan. Figure that on a $200,000 loan at 6%, this is $12,000 per year (I’m doing simple annual interest). If it’s a $1.2 million loan, that’s $72,000/year. That turns into real money fast. Of course, all of this is subject to the TILA materiality requirement. It’s not quite clear what the materiality requirement means in this context—the TILA provision regarding materiality was drafted for other types of TILA violations, and the set-off defense is written to piggyback on the pre-existing TILA provision. The materiality requirement means that the failure to verify ATR was material…but to what? Here are three possible readings: 1.Material to the harm to the borrower? 2.Material to the default on the loan? 3.Material to the foreclosure? I think it should be #2 the default on the loan, but the statute isn’t explicit about this, and it strikes me as a potential problem for a borrower trying to raise an ATR defense. Let’s assume that reading #2 is correct. I think the burden of proof on materiality is on the defendant creditor, but there are two important limitations on this strand of liability. First, liability for finance charges and fees is limited to those paid (not billed) in the first three years since the ATR violation. And second, this is a cap, not a floor. I'm skeptical that finance charges in year three or even perhaps year two can be shown to have a material connection to failure to verify ATR. (The QM safeharbor in contrast looks out to five years for underwriting.) If a borrower defaults at month 30, the fact that the loan wasn’t really underwritten in month 0 doesn’t seem particularly relevant. Underwriting is, at best, a prediction of future risks. But it is really hard for even the best underwriting to predict a borrower’s financial condition out beyond the immediate future. Measures like credit scores and income and DTI are inherently retrospective. They cannot capture the prospective changes in employment, family status, health, or property values that drive many defaults. Thus, I would think that the risk of losing finance charges is really only an issue for a fairly short window post-origination. Again, however, the burden of proof here is on the creditor, which means that the creditor will have to litigate this point, which might cost more than the liability avoided. So what does all this liability mean in the worst case scenario? Let’s assume a $200,000 loan at 6% annual interest, which defaults at the end of year 2, and that all finance charges paid (24 months worth) are assumed material. Let’s assume that the LTV on the house is 95%, so the house is worth $210,500. Let’s also assume $50,000 in costs and attorneys’ fees. If there are no actual damages, then the lender is looking at $78,000 in set-off liability: •Zero actual damages; •$4,000 in statutory damages; •$50,000 in costs and attorneys’ fees; •$24,000 in finance charges and fees paid. With a $78,000 setoff applied to a $200,000 loan, the lender's claim is reduced to $122,000. If the property sells for market value or even substantially less, the lender recovers that $122,000 in full. That’s a 39% (0.39) loss severity on the loan, which is quite serious (and doesn't account for future lost interest). And if the LTV is higher, the loss severity might be worse because there might not be enough equity in the property to pay off the loan, although in such a case the setoff will not be paid in real dollars, as discussed below, but in tiny deficiency judgment dollars or uncollectible nonrecourse dollars. ATR liability, however, does not stop with TILA itself. A TILA violation could be a predicate for a state law UDAP claim (or potentially also an FDCPA violation). That might itself carry further statutory damages, although it is unlikely in most cases to increase the lender’s total liability significantly. (This is more of a concern for an affirmative cause of action, which might produce a class, rather than a defense, which will surely be one-offs.) But this adds some uncertainty to the question of loss severities. In any case, we need to apply the loss severity to the likelihood of loss. 6. Likelihood of Liability for ATR Violation In order for there to be ATR liability, several things need to happen. First, there has to be a default on the loan. Second, that default needs to result in a foreclosure. Third, that foreclosure has to be contested. Fourth, the borrower needs to show that the lender did not consider his/her ability to repay when making the loan. That’s a lot of different gates to run through. If a loan is in fact well-underwritten, but simply doesn’t qualify for QM, the default rate should be fairly low. Let’s assume 10%, which I think is really quite high. Of course, if the loan is well-underwritten, then an ATR defense should not be successful at all. If a lender is simply making loans based on collateral values, there is an ATR problem, but even then, let’s say 25% of loans default. Even then, not all defaults result in foreclosures. A lot depends on servicing. Let’s assume that the foreclosure rate on defaulted loans is 90%. Most foreclosures are not contested. I don’t know any hard statistics on this, but I’d guess than no more than 5% are contested. Let’s double that to 10% for our purposes here. This means that we’re talking about .25 * .9 * .1 =2.25% (0.0225) of all non-QM loans resulting in contested foreclosures. Not all of these ATR defenses would be successful, of course, but for our purposes here, let's assume that they all are. 7. Loss Given Default for ATR Violations If we apply this 2.25% loss probability figure to the 39% loss severity estimate, we’re talking about 87.75 basis point increase (0.008775) in loss given default. So on a portfolio with an average original loan balance of $200,000, that translates to an average loss of $1,755 per loan. This risk is covered by increasing the interest rate by 18 basis points for five years. That’s not a huge affect from QM itself. Even if the 18 bps were rounded up to 25 bps (as mortgages come in 12.5 or 25 bp intervals), this is hardly a prohibitive change in the cost of credit. Indeed, the lender quite likely just increases the cost by 12.5 bps and charges $100 in fees. Moreover, to the extent that a property is underwater, the setoff isn’t being paid in real dollars, but either in uncollectible deficiencies, or in deficiency judgment dollars. If the loan is non-recourse, the lender hasn’t lost anything to the extent that the setoff is applied to the underwater part of the balance. (The setoff reduces the amount owed and hence the amount underwater.) If the loan is recourse, the lender’s loss is of the deficiency judgment, but given that these tend to sell for 3-4 pennies on the dollar, we’re talking about a loss of 1 basis point. If the property is not underwater, the lender is paying in real dollars, but this means that ATR is really a concern for lenders only when there is a collection possible. On top of this, I think I’m likely overestimating both probability of loss and loss severities due to the ATR defense. Even if my numbers are off by 40%, the impact is still only 25 bps. If I'm right, that means that all of the hand-wringing about QM is simply not justified. Still, I recognize that there’s some uncertainty here, which makes pricing more difficult. 8. The Cost of Delay: Direct ATR Liability May Not Be the Real Issue Perhaps the biggest risk for lenders created by ATR is the issue of delay. If a borrower raises an ATR defense against a non-QM loan, the borrower should be able to get past a motion to dismiss, as there is a question of fact outstanding. It’s not clear to me that a lender, much less a lender’s assignee, can prove ATR verification based simply on affidavits and pleadings. (How to prove ATR easily seems to me to be a major issue lenders’ counsel should think about.) It strikes me as requiring a more detailed investigation that might preclude an early summary judgment motion. This delay gives the consumer significant leverage for extracting a settlement, even if ATR was in fact verified. Indeed, ATR gives a borrower one more ground on which to contest a foreclosure. The mere fact that a foreclosure is contested will impose costs on the lender. A contested foreclosure will be a slower foreclosure, which means lost time value. The ATR defense also likely means that any non-judicial foreclosure will effectively become a judicial foreclosure. Beyond this, litigating a foreclosure is expensive, even if successful. The lender may be able to recover its costs from the foreclosure sale proceeds, if there is sufficient equity in the property, or from a deficiency judgment, possibly with interest, but those are delayed recoveries that impose an up-front liquidity burden on lenders who have to fund the foreclosure litigation. And if the loan is accruing interest at a belowmarket rate, delay is also imposing an opportunity cost. To be sure, none of these costs are specific to ATR. They are generic to contested foreclosures, but the possibility of an ATR defense (and particularly the recovery of attorneys’ fees, which enables the possible funding of foreclosure litigation) might increase the frequency of contested foreclosures. 9. Does ATR Matter for Non-QM Loans? Or Is the Real Problem the Lack of a Secondary Market? Even putting aside the TILA defense risk on non-QM mortgages, there is still the chicken-and-egg problem of liquidity in non-QM mortgages, and I think that's where the real risk of constriction of access to credit lies. Depositories aren’t going to want to make non-QM mortgages in any volume if there isn’t a secondary market for the loans that provides them with potential liquidity. A secondary market in non-QM loans is going to depend on the GSE credit box and/or the revival of the private label securitization market. There's little reason to be optimistic about either. Last May the FHFA directed the GSEs to purchase only QM loans or loans exempt from the ATR requirement. This means that after Jan. 10, 2014, the GSEs, will only purchase loans subject to the ATR requirement if they are fully amortizing, with terms no longer than 30 years, and points and fees of no more than 3% of the total loan amount (or other applicable limits). These aren't huge limitations on the mortgage market. Eliminating IOs and Payment Option loans, 30/40s and plain 40s, and high point/fee mortgages isn't where the real credit constriction will come. There weren't a lot of these loans happening post-bubble in the first place. Instead, the real issue is DTI requirements. But the GSEs are exempt from the QM requirements of a maximum DTI, income verification, and underwriting to the maximum interest rate in the first five years. Instead, their own underwriting standards (e.g., Desktop Underwriter) suffice. That's where the real action is. The contraction of credit is really going to be a function of how tight the GSE credit box is, not QM. It's possible that FHFA will allow the GSEs to buy non-QM loans, but I don't see that happening any time soon, and even if it does, again the real issue is the GSE credit box, not the CFPB's definition of QM. It's possible for there to a private-label secondary market in non-QM loans, but for the foreseeable future, the GSEs are the only secondary market to speak of. The Redwood and other private-label deals have financed some 16,000 loans since 2008--that's not a meaningful secondary market. I don't see that changing in any meaningful way until (1) the various servicing and trustee problems (including reps and warrants) are solved, and (2) there’s greater certainty about where housing financing reform is going. No one wants to invest a lot in creating a private-label securitization platform now that might not work after potential reforms. All of this is to say, it might not matter how much liability exists for an ATR violation. The real issue in terms of availability of credit is going to be the depth of the secondary market, and these days that is a function of what the GSEs will buy. That's not a legal issue, but a question of their risk appetite (and consider how a monopolist will accept lower volumes in exchange for higher margins) and public relations, in which any change to the credit box is perilous. CHAPTER 16 An overview of Bankruptcy- The Ultimate Consumer Protection January 23, 2014 The concept of bankruptcy is written into the US Constitution as one of the powers that is expressly granted to the Federal Government and not the states. A fair number of the drafters of that constitution spent time in debtors’ prisons as did David Copperfield’s close friend Wilkins McCawber. Current bankruptcy law in the United States provides several kinds of bankruptcy magic to the consumer or business that chooses to file. The first and simplest is the automatic stay which is similar to a temporary restraining order or a preliminary injunction. It tells nearly every type of creditor to stop whatever action it is taking against the bankruptcy debtor. In order to continue any such actions the creditor must come to court and meet a set of complicated standards to obtain relief from the stay. One of the most interesting aspects of the stay is that it is not granted by order or a judge but rather by the mere filing of the bankruptcy petition. To learn more about the stay consider taking a course in bankruptcy law. The second basic type of bankruptcy magic is the discharge of debt. In the overwhelming majority of consumer cases the court issues a routine order discharging the debtor from all liability on unsecured debts about sixty days after the filing. That order also releases the consumer from personal liability on secured debts although it does not extinguish the lien on the secured creditor’s collateral. Our inquiry will focus on the bankruptcy discharge. For more than a hundred years American law has provided consumers with an opportunity to wipe out their debts. This is often referred to as the “fresh start” and much of the debate about bankruptcy relief is whether it gives the consumer a “head start” rather than a “fresh start.” There are two types of consumer bankruptcies, chapter 7 and chapter 13. For the most part, the debtor or her counsel decide which chapter makes the most sense. In some areas of the country local custom or judicial behavior or something else skews the mix in favor of chapter 7 or in favor of chapter 13. Chapter 7 is intended to be a quick simple process in which a debtor says “I owe too much and can pay nothing. Take any non-exempt assets I have and sell them for the benefit of my creditors. In the meantime let me get on with my life and let me keep all my future wages for any work I do starting the day after I file.” In chapter 13, on the other hand, the debtor generally must pay some prescribed portion of her earnings for the benefit of her creditors for a three or five year period after filing. The means test is intended to shut the door to chapter 7 to creditors who “fail” the test, which means to the drafters that these are people who have sufficient earning capacity in relation to their debt that they should either not file bankruptcy or that they should file a chapter 13 and commit the prescribed portion of those earnings for the benefit of their creditors. Over the past thirty years the numbers of Americans filing bankruptcy has been an up and down story. It grew enormously in the same years that the increase in consumer credit exploded; in the last five years is had decreased. Here is a chart of those filings. A great many of these cases are short and uncomplicated. The debtor’s attorney, or the debtor herself or a bankruptcy preparer files the necessary papers and information about herself, her debts and her assets; a few weeks later she appears before a lawyer who is a bankruptcy panel trustee and answers questions; in most cases that is her last appearance and she will receive a bankruptcy discharge in the mail. Others are more complicated. ADD: Numbers of filing 1990 – 2013 If she filed too recently, or if she is proven to have committed various types of fraud her discharge will not be granted at all. Even if she does receive her discharge, as we will study in greater detail in a few pages, various types of debts are or may be excepted from discharge. Not surprisingly, most taxes and all types of family support are automatically excepted from her discharge. The Code also includes 22 specific types of conduct which Congress has determined should not be subject to the discharge, but most of these require some action to assure they are not discharged. These vary from obtaining the credit under certain false pretenses to damages from a willful and malicious act, to educational loans to fines and penalties from violation of election laws. The exceptions also include various types of credit card charges which we will review in a bit more detail in a moment. The discharge is of enormous benefit to the debtor and is of little financial consequence to the creditor since there is very little likelihood that this debtor would have paid much on the bill even if the charge had not been discharged. There is not so much controversy over the discharge of the honest debtor who does not have the assets or the potential earnings to satisfy any portion of her debts. Consumer bankruptcy law is very complicated in that it attempts to distinguish between those consumers who are honest and do not have the assets or potential earnings to satisfy any meaningful portion of their debts and those who may have the potential earnings to satisfy a meaningful portion of their debts. The Means Test: The rules for keeping out debtors who hide their assets are simple, but the rules for keeping out debtors who folks think should pay some or all of their debts because they have the potential earnings is much more complicated. To obtain a discharge under chapter 7 the debtor must turn over to a trustee for the benefit of the creditors all assets other than a few selected items which States (or the Federal Government in some states) have marked as exempt from collection activities of creditors. This makes little difference to 99% of people who seek bankruptcy relief because they simply do not have many such assets. They may for example keep all or most of the tax sheltered retirement assets, some portion of their homestead and “tools of the trade.” . But what about human capital and the chance to earn more than the average person earns in the years to come. Should a graduating doctor be able to discharge her credit card debts when she may earn enough to pay a healthy portion or all of those debts. She has amassed no non-exempt assets while she was a student but she has the potential to do so in the future and why should she be able to discharge past debts when she has future earning capacity? None of this seemed to matter much to folks until the 1990’s. The number of people filing bankruptcy was marching upward at a rapid clip. One group asserted this was inevitable given both the huge increase in credit card debt and the lending to folks who had previously been deemed unworthy of credit cards The other group argued more loudly and more effectively that the loosening of the bankruptcy standards in 1979 was the primary cause of the increase and therefore the rules needed to be tightened. The battle continued from the machinations of the Bankruptcy Review Commission in 1994 through various iterations of what became the 2005 amendments to the Bankruptcy Code but ended in many changes, the most important of which was the imposition of a means test to close the door to a simple discharge of a debtor who the systems thinks should pay. Professor Douglas Baird asserts that ”The strongest objection to the introduction of means testing is not that a discharge should be available to high-income debtors who could pay much of what they owed. Indeed most courts had already found that the filing of a bankruptcy petition by someone who had the ability to repay debt was itself grounds for dismissing the case. Rather, the problem associate with means testing was one associated with many reform efforts. The game may not be worth the candle. Any mechanism sufficiently fine-tuned to catch bad actors without foreclosing access to the fresh start to people who in fact deserved it is too complicate and imposes too many costs, particularly on those whose right to a fresh start is not in doubt.” Baird “The Elements of Bankruptcy at page 36. Although it is technically possible for a Judge to find abuse of the system and shut the chapter 7 door to a debtor whose “current monthly income” is below the median for their census area, it is very unusual and thus debtors whose “current monthly income” for the six months prior to filing is below the median for her census area will find the chapter 7 door open. This is true likewise for those whose current monthly income ( a defined term) is above the median if the amount left after subtracting defined allowances for living expenses and the payment of secured and priority debt is low enough to miss various defined trigger points. These trigger points are based on either: the total amount of the discretionary dollars that the formula determines would be available to pay that debt over sixty months or; the ratio of those dollars to the amount of unsecured debt scheduled by the debtor. The means test is only applicable to those debtors whose debts are primarily consumer debts. The bankruptcy discharge not only provides the debtor with an affirmative defense to any effort to collect a discharged debt but it also provides an injunction against parties who try to collect or otherwise enforce such a debtor Debts That Are Not Dischargeable The law provides a laundry list of individual debts that are not subject to discharge even if the debtor receives one. tort or debts that society determines of particularly (once again in the words of Professor Baird “important.” These include child support, alimony and many tax obligations. They also include student loans. Others are debts that arose out of bad conduct such as deliberate torts. Thus, a bankruptcy discharges all of a consumer’s unsecured debts unless they are of the type excepted from discharge or unless the debtor “reaffirms” the debt in a manner that comports with the rules of “reaffirmation.” For purposes of our course one of the most interesting of these exceptions is credit card debt incurred shortly before bankruptcy and /or for "luxury" items. Should debts be discharged if they were incurred on the eve of bankruptcy? What about debts for luxuries? And, under what circumstances should we conclude that a debtor misrepresented her likelihood of paying for the expense she put on her credit card. See text of 11 U.S.C. 523 (b)(2) especially subsection (C). Special Rules for Dischargeability of Student Loans in Bankruptcy Student loans are, for the most part, not dischargeable in bankruptcy. That means that if you have a student loan, in most cases you will not be able to eliminate the student loan debt in bankruptcy. Student loans used to be dischargeable under certain circumstances prior to October 2005. However, in October 2005, the bankruptcy law on student loans was rewritten to make all educational loans nondischargeable. Can I File Bankruptcy on Student Loans in San Diego? If you are asking the question, can I file bankruptcy on student loans, in most cases the answer is no. With the revisions to the Federal bankruptcy law in 2005, and the Brunner Test, which is controlling law in San Diego County as well as throughout the State of California, there is a very tough standard that you would need to meet in order to be able to wipe out student loans in bankruptcy. Under this standard, set forth by the Brunner Test, you need to show that you are so physically or mentally disabled that you cannot engage in substantial gainful employment. For this reason, it is rare case in which a borrower is able to eliminate a student loan in bankruptcy. History Prior to 1998, you could file a Chapter 7 or Chapter 13 bankruptcy on student loans if the loan had been in repayment status (not including any deferment period) for at least 7 years at the time that your case is filed. On October 7, 1998, the Bankruptcy Code was amended to make it more difficult to file bankruptcy on student loans. The 1998 law made student loans nondischargeable if the loan was made or guaranteed by the Federal Government unless you could show that nondischargeability would pose an “undue hardship” upon you and your dependents. Student loans still remained dischargeable if the loans were not made or guaranteed by the Federal Government. On October 17, 2005, the New Bankruptcy Law went into effect and drastically changed your ability to discharge student loans for most people. The new law, in effect, treats privately funded student loans in the same manner as government backed loans were treated since 1998: you cannot eliminate them in most cases. The only exception is that if you can meet the standard set forth by the Brunner Test. Under the new law, in effect since 2005, all educational loans, whether governmentbacked student loans or privately funded loans, are nondischargeable in either a Chapter 7 case or Chapter 13 case unless you can show that nondischargeability would post an “undue hardship” upon you and your dependents. Undue Hardship – The Brunner Test The Bankruptcy Code does not define what constitutes an “undue hardship.” To determine whether or not an undue hardship exists, sufficient to allow you to obtain a Hardship Discharge of an educational loan in bankruptcy, the Court will apply a specific test, known as the “Brunner Test.” The Brunner Test is a 3-Part test first established in 1985 by the Second Circuit Court of Appeals. At the time the test was established, it was not controlling in the State of California. Fifteen years after the decision was made by the Second Circuit Court of Appeals, the Federal Circuit Court having jurisdiction over California, namely the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals, made the test applicable in California. On September 11, 1998, the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals, which is the Federal Circuit Court that has controlling jurisdiction over California Bankruptcy Courts, formally adopted the Brunner Test and made it the applicable test in our state. Since that time, the Brunner Test has been the controlling test that is applied by California Courts and judges in deciding whether to grant you Hardship Discharge of your educational loans when you file for bankruptcy. Under the Brunner Test, the Court will apply a 3-Part test to determine whether an undue hardship exists sufficiently for the Court to grant you a Hardship Discharge when you file for bankruptcy: (1) You must establish that you cannot maintain, based upon your current income and expenses, a minimal standard of living for yourself and your dependents if you are forced to repay your loans; (2) You must show that additional circumstances exist indicating that your current state of affairs is likely to persist for a significant part of the repayment period of your loans; and (3) You must have made good faith efforts to repay your loans. In practice, it is very difficult to obtain a Hardship Discharge under the Brunner Test. Once you pass the first part of the test- you establish that you cannot maintain a minimal standard of living if forced to repay your student loans- you must still show the Court that your situation is not going to change for a significant part of your repayment period. It will not be presumed by the Court that your current state of affairs is not going to change for a significant part of your repayment period. Rather, you must make an affirmative showing and prove to the Court that you have an insurmountable barrier to financial recovery that is likely to remain with you for a substantial portion of your repayment period. Technically, under the Brunner Test, your barrier to financial recovery does not necessarily need to be so extreme that it rises to the level of a physical disability, learning disability, mental illness, or other similar extreme circumstance. In reality, bankruptcy judges frequently reserve granting a Hardship Discharge to the extreme case- a case where you are physically unable to work and there is virtually no chance that you will recover and obtain gainful employment in the future. If there is hope for you to engage in gainful employment, most judges would expect you to find a job and pay off your loans. Even if you have an extreme case, you must further show that you have made good faith efforts to repay your educational loans. This means, for example, attempting to work out a repayment plan, consolidating your loans under the Federal Direct Loans consolidation program, and other similar good faith efforts to repay your educational loans prior to filing bankruptcy and requesting a Hardship Discharge. Partial Discharge Discharging student loans in bankruptcy is not always an all-or-nothing proposition. Bankruptcy Courts are Courts of Equity and judges have equitable powers and may exercise their equitable powers to partially discharge a portion but not all of your student loans based upon your individual circumstances. To obtain a partial discharge of your student loans you will still need to meet all 3 parts of the Brunner Test with respect to the portion of your educational loans that you are seeking to discharge. If and only if you meet all 3 parts of the Brunner Test, then the judge may exercise his or her discretion to grant you a partial discharge of your student loan debt. HEAL Loans Health Education Assistance Loan (HEAL) Act loans are subject to an even stricter standard (stricter than the Brunner Test) and are harder to discharge than any other type of educational loan debt. In particular, discharging a HEAL Loan in bankruptcy requires a finding by the Court that, among other findings, it would be “unconscionable” not to discharge a HEAL Loan. Unconscionability is a very difficult standard to meet. Adversary Proceeding Required If you can establish that your case meets the standard for granting a hardship discharge or partial discharge of your student loan debt, you will need to initiate an adversary proceeding in your Chapter 7 or Chapter 13 case and request that the Court make a legal determination that your loans are discharged by your Chapter 7 or Chapter 13 discharge. KEY QUESTIONS Student Loans in Bankruptcy by Chen http://www.policyarchive.org/handle/10207/bitstreams/19283.pdf NON BANKRUPTCY RULES FOR FORGIVENESS Effect of the Discharge on Secured Debt The effect of the discharge on a debt that is secured by collateral is more complicated and the treatment of secured claims in bankruptcy is more complex than the treatment of unsecured claims. Although the personal liability of the debtor to pay her debts is extinguished by the bankruptcy discharge , the liens that secures the debts are NOT extinguished or discharged by the bankruptcy. The good news for the consumer debtor is that an “automatic stay” stops collection action including foreclosure and repossession as of the date of the filing of the bankruptcy; the bad news is that it is possible and are likely that these activities will begin again after the secured creditor has obtained relief from the automatic stay or after the bankruptcy is over. Here are some of the various rules that govern the treatment of a claim secured by collateral. In a chapter 7 case: 1. if the debtor has no equity in the property then the creditor will likely be able to obtain relief from the automatic stay to foreclose or repossess, or may simply wait until the case is over to start or restart its possessory enforcement activities; or the debtor may “redeem” the collateral by tendering in cash an amount equal to the value of the collateral. Any claim remaining to the secured creditor is an unsecured claim which is discharged. Or the debtor may agree to repay the entire debt due to the secured creditor even though part of that debt is under secured by “reaffirming” that debt. This is a controversial provision. If the debtor reaffirms the debt, she “waives” her right to a discharge on this debt and if the debtor later defaults she will be liable for any deficiency claim 2. if the debtor has equity greater than its exemptions then the Trustee may choose to sell this property, pay the claim of the secured creditor, pay the debtor the value of her exemptions and then pay the balance to unsecured creditors in accordance with their claims. Questions re :reaffirmation procedure and history In a chapter 13 case 1. The debtor’s plan may force the mortgagee to accept back due payments over several months, but the debtor may not change future payments in any way on a debt that is secured solely by a first mortgage on the debtor’s principal residence. 2. With regard to debts secured by anything other than the debtor’s principle residence, if the debt was incurred more than 910 days before the filing of the bankruptcy the debtor’s plan may reduce the amount of the secured claim to the value of the collateral. Any balance is treated with the unsecured claims. 3. With regard to debts secured by anything other than the debtor’s principle residence if the debt was incurred within one year of the filing of the bankruptcy the debtor‘s plan may not reduce the amount of the secured claim to the value of the collateral. 4. With regard to purchase money debts secured by a motor vehicle that was bought for personal use and which was incurred more than one year but less than 910 days before the filing of the bankruptcy, the plan may not reduce the amount of the secured claim to the value of the collateral. MAIN Q Whom should we release from debts without the requirement that they use any of their future income to repay those debts? III. THE SWEAT BOX: from an article by Ronald Mann at _________ If the most prominent feature of the statute is unlikely to generate a substantial increase in payouts to card issuers, how can we be sure that issuers will profit from the new law? My answer is to emphasize an entirely different intersection between the statute and the business model of the credit card issuer. In my view, the most important aspect of the new law is not the increased payouts associated with means testing, but the way in which the law encourages debtors to defer bankruptcy filings. To explain, let me talk briefly about the business models of credit card issuers and then about how the Act interacts with those models at the point of the bankruptcy filing decision. A. The Business Model Although credit card issuers have different business models, it is reasonable to place them along a spectrum from transaction-based to debt-based. Transaction-based issuers (like American Express and Diners Club) try to earn interchange fees that exceed the cost of funds and their transaction costs. Thus, those issuers attempt to maximize the number of cardholders that use their cards frequently for high-value purchases. Debt-based issuers, by contrast focus on debt servicing revenues. Thus, they attempt to maximize the number of customers who do not repay their account balances in full each month. That strategy would not seem unusual, but for the fact that the most profitable customers are sometimes the least likely to ever repay their debts in full. For many other types of lenders—a commercial lender like a mortgage company, perhaps— the most profitable customers are the ones least likely to default. The lender sells a relatively static product, such as a thirty-year fully amortizing mortgage loan for 75% of the value of the property, with a price at a more or less fixed level above the cost of funds. That lender profits a small amount on each loan that is repaid in a timely manner, and loses substantially on the loans that are not. The model works because the number of loans paid in full in accordance with their terms is perhaps fifty times the number of loans that default. Competition in that market drives the major lenders to very similar prices. Profitability depends on lowering administrative costs, while at the same time limiting bad loans through the exercise of judgment about the quality of potential borrowers. In sum, the model works best if all borrowers retain robust financial health throughout the term of their obligations.47 The business model of the debt-based credit card issuer is quite different. These lenders depend more heavily on automated techniques of data-mining and information analysis than on skills of subjective case-by-case judgment.48 Thus, only the most technologically adept can hope to remain profitable in the industry. The competitive pressure49 has led to a rapid increase in concentration in the industry, so that the ten largest issuers in the United States now hold about 88% of all credit card debt in the country; the top five hold more than 70%.50 The successful credit card lender profits from the borrowers that become financially distressed. Financially secure customers or “convenience users” do not generate any interest income, late fees, or overlimit penalties. The only source of revenue they provide typically comes from annual fees in some instances and interchange revenues.51 These charges might be substantial in some cases, but they only account for about 20% of industry revenues.52 Thus, for issuers that rely on lending, “convenience users” are useful only because of the possibility that they will mature into borrowers—as caterpillars mature into butterflies.53 For the credit card lender, the first hint of sustained profitability comes when the cardholder (now borrower) stops regularly paying her balance in full each month.54 If we imagine that this is caused by some adverse event affecting the borrower’s wages or some unusual expenditure that the borrower hopes to amortize against future wages, we might analogize the situation to that of a commercial borrower that loses a major customer or suffers a drop in earnings because of poor cost controls. In the case of the commercial borrower, the adverse events, if material, will lower the loan officer’s expectations of profit from the transaction. The analogy is not perfect, because the credit card borrower’s problem might involve no adverse event, but simply a momentary bout of profligacy or exuberance, motivated perhaps by the hope of an increased income in months to follow. Still, whatever the basis for the decision to carry a balance, this is not an event of concern. Rather, it suggests imminent profit, because the decision to carry a balance leads immediately to interest charges on the cardholder’s account, which accrue at a rate far exceeding the lender’s cost of funds. Moreover, once the borrower begins to carry a balance, the likelihood of late and overlimit fees can increase substantially. As the spiral increases, the distinction between the two models grows starker. When the first lost customer becomes the failure of an entire product line, the commercial loan will become a problem, probably suitable for a “special assets” division with officers particularly skilled at minimizing the losses from bad loans.55 As the credit card borrower spirals downward, however, with the monthly balances growing to amounts that equal, or even surpass, the borrower’s annual income, the issuer begins to earn large monthly profits on the relationship. The question for the lender is how long the borrower will remain in the unstable position before failure occurs. If this seems implausible, consider the evidence of the stark increases in charge offs related to the recent increases in minimum payments. In 2003, American regulators, acting through the Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council (an interagency group that oversees standards for federal examination of financial institutions), issued a “guidance” suggesting that lenders should not permit negative amortization and should require repayment in a “reasonable” time.56 When I first read this guidance, it seemed a trivial policy event, because it required so little that it seemed targeted primarily to the subprime lending market.57 Still, the annual reports of major American card issuers suggest that the guidance had an important effect even on mainstream lending practices. For example, MBNA reported that it promptly changed its standard procedure for calculating minimum payments from 2.25% of the principal balance to a requirement that each borrower pay 1% of their principal in addition to interest and fees.58 Thus, assuming that the interest rate is 24%, the minimum payment on a $5000 balance would increase from $112.50 to $150.59 Take note: this requirement that each borrower repay 1% of the principal each month does not mean that the loan will be repaid in 100 months. A borrower who made the minimum payments under that plan, and never made any future purchases, would not repay the outstanding debt for approximately 27 years, because the minimum payment would decline steadily as the outstanding balance declined.60 Yet even changes of this magnitude will apparently cause major disruption in the industry.61 The basic problem is that even minimum-payment increases as slight as those mentioned above are likely to push many borrowers past the point of liquidity. Hard as it may be to believe, it appears that a change from a $112.50 to a $150 minimum payment will be a change from a difficult payment to an impossible payment for some borrowers. Thus, the increased payment minima are expected to increase delinquency and chargeoff rates markedly. Indeed, industry analysts expect the effects to be substantial enough to force major changes in the fee practices of card issuers.62 The most salient example of this change was the 94% decline in MBNA’s profits early in 2005, which sources in the industry link to the increase in MBNA’s minimum payments.63 The fact that such a slight alteration in minimum payment requirements has such a substantial effect on delinquency, chargeoff, and bankruptcy rates64 suggests that those lenders are keeping an astonishing share of their portfolios balanced on a razor’s edge.65 After obtaining a successful portfolio, the standard way to increase profits is to focus on those customers who are unable to take their business elsewhere. If the customers do not have realistic options, lenders are free to raise the interest rates and fees that they charge to those borrowers.66 Ordinarily, a lender that unilaterally raises the fees that it is charging its most profitable customers might fear the loss of those customers to competitors. In this particular context, however, the risk that competitors will “poach” these profitable customers is relatively slight. One problem, discussed by a group of researchers at the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia in a recent paper, is that the “switching costs” are too high.67 An issuer that tries to attract distressed customers from a competitor will face an adverse selection problem.68 Recognizing that the existing issuer is likely to know more than the new issuer about the distressed customer, the new issuer must be concerned that the distressed customer that it attracts will be so close to failure that the relationship will be unprofitable.69 The basic idea is that an issuer that targets the distressed customers will get the worst of them (those that are so close to complete failure that they will be unprofitable).70 The best of the distressed customers (the ones far enough from complete failure to remain profitable) will remain with their existing lender.71 That problem, they argue, makes it hard for competing issuers to make strong efforts to obtain their business and in turn makes it easier for existing lenders to earn more profits from their captive customers.72 Other practical problems complicate the job of attracting the distressed customers of another card issuer. For one thing, the typical way of attracting customers from another card issuer is to offer a low “introductory” rate for balance transfers—often near 0%. But when the customers are already in distress, it might be difficult to profit (even over time) from an advance at a very low interest rate. To be sure, the new issuer might be able to profit if it could undercut the existing issuer’s rate and still charge a credible rate— beating a 24% or 30% rate with an offer of 18%—but as a marketing (or behavioral) matter, I doubt that a campaign targeting customers with a “great new rate of 18%” would be cost-effective. The new lender also must confront the problem that it can obtain the customer only if it repays the entire nominal balance of the debt owed by the customer. As discussed below, that amount is likely to substantially exceed the issuer’s “real” economic investment in the customer, and often will significantly exceed any amount that the issuer expects the borrower to repay. Collectively, those problems make me think that the issuer has quite a firm grip on its customers who have fallen into serious distress. Another key part of the business model, related to the high switching costs for distressed borrowers, is the increasing ability of the leading issuers to collect substantial revenues in the form of late and overlimit fees. It is commonplace that the average amount of those fees has been rising over the last several years.73 What is more interesting, and to the point, is that the aggregate amount of those fees, as a share of outstanding debt, has doubled since 1990, increasing from about 70 basis points per year in 1990 to 140 basis points per year in 2004.74 Referring back to Figure 1, this landscape suggests a three-pronged business strategy for the credit card lender: (1) limit the share of financially stable customers (the left part of the curve); (2) maximize the share of the portfolio that is at any time in the central (rising) part of the curve, and; (3) minimize losses from the borrowers who fail. The first prong (the left part of the curve) suggests that one strategy would be to use information technology to segment the market so that an issuer focused on lending revenues will have a relatively small share of customers at any given time that use the card only for payment transactions. More importantly, such an issuer hopes to attract the types of users who will use the card for borrowing transactions and thus become revenuegenerating users. To be sure, some issuers offer products designed to be profitable even in the hands of nonborrowing users. The products might bear annual fees or higher interchange fees. But even here, the goal is to target frequent card users. Because the marginal interchange revenue from each payment transaction typically exceeds the marginal cost of processing and because there is a fixed cost for issuing and maintaining each account, high-volume users are more profitable than low-volume users. Hence, the worst customers are those who accept cards and use them infrequently. Conversely, a customer who uses the card constantly for multiple transactions each day with a large dollar volume each month can be reasonably profitable for a lender, even if the cardholder pays off her entire balance each month. To be sure, if the lender seeking new customers cannot tell which of its nonborrowing customers are likely to mature into borrowing customers, the lender’s strategy might be to acquire as many high-volume customers as possible, whether or not they borrow, hoping that the larger the portfolio of customers, the greater the number of highly profitable borrowing customers the issuer will have in the end.75 But even that strategy focuses attention on the middle part of the curve, which clearly is where the real profits are made.76 The third prong (the right part of the curve) simply recognizes that issuers face the bloodfrom-a-stone problem discussed in the previous part of this essay.77 Little can be done to increase the recovery from people in severe financial distress. Therefore, it is unlikely that the Act will substantially increase recoveries from that portion of the curve. If most bankruptcy filers are in severe financial distress, the obvious solution is for lenders to cut their administrative costs and liquidate the debt when distress becomes overwhelming. Although my thoughts on this topic are relatively impressionistic, discussions with industry sources suggest that the major credit card issuers are increasingly moving towards selling defaulted credit card debt (at a price of approximately 10–12¢ on the dollar).78 The developing market appears to suggest that the debt is more valuable in the hands of the smaller companies that can collect more aggressively than reputable large companies.79 That leaves the second prong, or the central part of the curve. This part of the curve covers the spectrum from those who carry balances, to those who routinely make minimum payments, to those who miss payments altogether. As the discussion above suggests, the strategy makes sense only if the lenders can obtain an adequate return from their borrowers during the period they are in that part of the curve—the “sweat box” in my terms. If this seems implausible, notice that the interest rates that borrowers pay while they are in the sweat box greatly exceed the cost of the lender’s funds. Thus, if the borrower resides in the sweat box for very long—making substantial interest payments at a high rate—the lender with a lower cost of funds in effect receives a return of the funds that it has lent each month. To quantify this effect, I ran a simple experimental spreadsheet to see how hard it would be for a lender to recapture its investment. In general, the experiment80 assumes the following: • The lender’s cost of funds is 3%.81 incentives of borrowers to avoid financial distress and bankruptcy. Instead, I suggest, the proper approach should allocate losses between borrowers and lenders in a way that minimizes the net costs of financial distress. Generally, I argue that this calls for placing more risks on lenders, so that they will have an incentive to use information technology to limit the costs of distress. Accordingly, I believe that the Act is a move in the wrong direction. See Mann, supra note 24. • The lender charges 18% per month for the first three months that the borrower pays the minimum payment, 24% per month for the next three months, and 30% per month thereafter. • The monthly minimum payments are 2% while the annual interest rate is 18%, 2% + $50 when the annual interest rate is 24%, and 2.5% + $50 when the annual interest rate is 30%. • The borrower incurs a $40 late or overlimit charge every other month starting with the seventh month that it makes the minimum payment. Applying those assumptions to a borrower who starts out with a balance of $2000 and makes no new purchases, the stated balance at the end of 25 months is still $1270 (more than half the original loan). But looking at the “economic” balance—applying the lender’s cost of funds to the monthly balance instead of the stated interest rate—the entire loan has been repaid (with $6 to spare). A slightly different example is arguably more provocative: if we assume that the borrower makes a $100 purchase every three months and run the example for 34 months, we have a stated balance of $2070 (slightly more than the initial balance), but in “economic” terms the entire loan has been repaid (with $26 to spare). A final experiment, assuming a more aggressive issuer, assumes that the interest rate is 30%, 36%, and 42%, and that there is a $50 late or overlimit fee every month starting in the sixth month; in this example the economic balance is repaid in the thirty-second month, while the total stated balance remains more than $2800. If we imagine borrowers who limp along, carrying those balances for decades— neither discharging them in bankruptcy, nor ever paying them off entirely, perhaps making an occasional minor purchase—we can see how profitable this business model can be. I note that a recent survey of balance-carrying Americans suggests that the median family with a balance has been carrying it for thirty months (with an average of forty-three months).82 The examples above suggest that this is just about long enough for the lender to recover its investment, but not nearly long enough for the cardholder to repay its debt. B. The Effects of the Act With that business model in mind, let us turn now to the Act. Although the Act might have limited effect on transaction-based credit card issuers, I argue that the Act will have a major effect on debt-based issuers. Specifically, the dominant impact of the new law occurs in the central part of my curve, as the Act operates to delay the time of filing for a considerable group of financially distressed card users.83 If those card users continue to make payments until shortly before they surrender and file for bankruptcy, the delay in filing—lengthening the time in the “sweat box”—will increase the profits the lenders receive from those accounts, or decrease the losses the lenders will face when those customers ultimately file for bankruptcy.84 Put simply, the issuers have persuaded Congress to take the line in Figure 1 that demarcates the zone of high profitability from the zone of failure, and move it over by several months. One economic perspective on this situation would view the consumer credit industry as a private wage insurer, providing emergency funds to households in distress, while the bankruptcy system provides consumption insurance, protecting against sharp income dropoffs.85 The strengthening of the sweat box effect restricts the amount of consumption insurance that is provided publicly and thus increases the importance of wage insurance. Once the point is made, it is easy to see that several of the Act’s notable features are likely to defer the time of filing. Two distinct strategies are apparent: provisions that increase the cost of filing and provisions that decrease the benefit of filing. If we think of the bankruptcy decision as a determination of the point in time at which the benefits of bankruptcy are sufficient to overcome the natural aversion to the admission of failure that a bankruptcy filing represents, and if we expect that in most cases the starkness of financial distress will make the filing inevitable, we would expect these provisions to have the effect of delaying the time of filings, but not decreasing the aggregate number of them.86 The most obvious example, of course, is the stark increase in filing fees wrought by section 325 of the Act, so that it now costs $299 to initiate a chapter 7 bankruptcy proceeding.87 The fee increase is a valuable example of the effect of the statute, because the large fee—going to the government not to creditors—directly reduces the recoveries to be expected for creditors. The only value it represents to creditors is that it can defer—or deter—bankruptcy filings. Another simple and effective rule in this category is the extension of the period during which the debtor cannot file a new bankruptcy petition.88 Thus, the well-counseled debtor who chooses to file in response to a particularly distressing situation must accept that a bankruptcy filing will not be possible in the years to come even if the subsequent situation becomes worse than the current one. This would seem a relatively small problem if we were still in a world in which a bankruptcy filing provided a substantially complete fresh start. But as studies show, a large share of bankrupts continue to experience financial distress that is as bad as—or even worse—than the distress they faced before their filing.89 Another important obstacle is the increased bureaucratic responsibility of attorneys who represent borrowers, which flowed from the general congressional condemnation of the bankruptcy bar.90 This was a favorite theme of Senator Grassley: Today, many lawyers who specialize in bankruptcy view bankruptcy as an opportunity to make big money for themselves. This profit motive causes bankruptcy lawyers to promote bankruptcy as the only option even when a financially troubled client has an obvious ability to repay his or her debts. In other words, this profit motive creates a real conflict of interest where bankruptcy lawyers push people into bankruptcy who don’t belong there simply because they want to make a quick buck. **** Mr. President, I think there is a widespread recognition that bankruptcy lawyers are preying on unsophisticated consumers who need counseling and help in setting up a budget and who do not need to declare bankruptcy. Bankruptcy lawyers are the fuel which makes the engines of the bankruptcy mills run.91 The best example here probably is section 707(b). This provision—in the style of Sarbanes- Oxley—now requires the debtor’s attorney to certify that the lawyer has investigated the accuracy of the borrower’s filing information. One could say that this is nothing new, just a restatement of Rule 11 in another context. But provisions like section 707(b)(4)(A)— specifically requiring the debtor’s attorney to pay the costs and attorney’s fees incurred in connection with a successful motion to convert under section 707(b)—make it likely that consumer bankruptcy attorneys will in fact spend more resources collecting verifiable evidence of a pre-filing investigation than they did under pre-Act law.92 Indeed, some observers view much of the Act as laying an elaborate trap for those who make a living out of representing consumer bankrupts.93 Regardless whether the heightened investigation requirement has other salutary effects, it seems likely to increase the cost of a bankruptcy filing. Those who supported the Act suggested it would increase costs by about $150 to $200 per case, and there is little reason to think that they were exaggerating.94 Another example, typical of the drafting style of the Act, comes from the new rules in section 526 concerning debt relief agencies, which arguably apply to attorneys.95 If they do, there is a new avenue for attorney liability in connection with assistance provided to consumers.96 Even if they do not, those rules clearly will have the effect of limiting access to the bankruptcy courts previously provided by non-attorney petition preparers.97 Although it is too soon to know the impact of those rules—the magnitude of the impact probably will shrink over time, as attorneys adjust to the new system—they surely will raise filing costs in the short term. As filing costs rise, even the most desperately insolvent must delay bankruptcy, at least until they can save the amount necessary for the filing fee and the attorney’s fee.98 The new rules about credit counseling interpose another hurdle. Codified in Bankruptcy Code section 109, these rules generally require borrowers to seek credit counseling shortly before filing for bankruptcy.99 Given the urgency with which the financial position of consumers deteriorates, and Congress’s effort to close any avenue by which judges might forgive noncompliance, these rules can lead to great hardship in particular cases, as judges already have noted.100 But the major effect, it appears, will be to make it harder, more timeconsuming, and more expensive for consumers to file for bankruptcy.101 As with the rules discussed above, it is difficult to predict exactly how much of a hurdle this will be. Early indications are that in many cases debtors will have access to expeditious credit counseling, often over the Internet.102 But part of this hurdle surely is psychological: the humiliation of going through counseling doubtless will slow some cognizable group of people, for some time, from filing. The second strategy is more indirect, but no less effective: to lower the benefits of bankruptcy. It is here that I see the most salient effect of the means-testing requirement. If filing will not provide as much of a fresh start as it formerly did, then well-counseled debtors might wait to file until they are in deeper distress. The other obvious example is the expansion of the categories of nondischargeable debts.103 Here, for example, is one of the rare explicit references in the Act to the “open end credit plan” that is the regular product of the credit card issuer.104 Specifically, post-Act section 523(a)(2)(B)(iv)(II) prevents a discharge of any cash advances exceeding $750 during the 70 days preceding bankruptcy. Given the frequency with which distressed borrowers might be borrowing on a credit card to repay other pressing obligations, this provision can convert garden-variety dischargeable unsecured debt into nondischargeable debt that will pass through bankruptcy unaffected.* * * * * The discussion in this section is speculative. It depends on a variety of empirical assumptions about the behavior of distressed borrowers that are difficult to verify empirically. For example, I assume that the bill will have only a minor effect on the number of people who choose to file, although it will have a noticeable effect on when they file.105 That assumption makes sense if you believe (as the data indicate) that the overwhelming majority of filers are in such distress that they are all but compelled to file. As discussed above, there is data to support that assumption, but it certainly is not conclusive. Similarly, I assume that consumers are making payments right up to the moment that they file, and that the statute thus slows down both bankruptcy and the termination of revenues for the issuers. A contrary assumption certainly is plausible: the statute might defer the bankruptcy filing weeks or months past the point of hopeless distress, but payments might stop at the same time as they would have before the Act.106 These are empirical questions of course. I can imagine testing them, but I certainly acknowledge that it would be difficult. IV. THE REALITY Finally, I close with a few early assessments of the post-Act landscape, which tend to suggest, in hindsight, that credit card issuers overestimated the net profits they would earn from their investment in the Act. My discussion here is consciously tentative, resting as it does on data available in the first few months after the Act went into effect. I discuss three separate questions, in decreasing order of generality: (1) the overall filing rate, (2) the share of Chapter 13 filings, (3) and the amount paid to unsecured creditors in chapter 13 cases. 106.My intuition that the borrowers often pay until close to the bankruptcy date is supported by the rising complaints in the 1990s about “trapdoor” debtors. See Elizabeth Warren, The Changing Politics of American Bankruptcy Reform, 37 OSGOODE HALL L.J. 189, 198–99 (1999) (discussing complaints by creditors about “trapdoor” debtors, who file for bankruptcy before they are even delinquent on their debts). As the text suggests, credit card issuers now recognize that it is to their advantage to have the trapdoor debtor, rather than the debtors that stop paying months before bankruptcy overtakes their affairs. Conversations with issuers suggest that in the current market about 20% of bankruptcy filers are current on their debt at the time of their bankruptcy filing. Although the issuers with whom I had this conversation collectively had only about a 20% market share of American credit card debt, they assured me that between them their portfolios surely included the overwhelming majority of American bankruptcy filers: each of the two indicated that their portfolio included about 75% of all American bankruptcy filers. Source: Author’s Calculations Based on Data from Lundquist Consulting Several things about that figure are noteworthy. First, it displays the massive spike in filings in October of 2005, just before the October 17 effective date of the bill. Logically, that spike would consist of the “normal” October 2005 filings, plus two groups of people: early filers and new filers. The early filers are those who eventually would have filed anyway, but who chose to file early because of concerns about the onerous provisions of the Act. The new filers are people who but for the Act would never have filed—who would have “toughed it out” without a bankruptcy filing—but chose to file because of concerns that the Act’s procedures would be unduly harsh if they later turned out to need bankruptcy relief. My conversations with industry sources suggest that the spike was much larger than was expected. Thus, at the time, it was thought that much of the spike was new filings. But the shape of the curve in subsequent months suggests that a large share of the spike, at least, consisted of early filers. The reason for this is that ten months after the Act became effective, in August 2006, filings were still trending steadily upward from the preternaturally low level they reached shortly after the Act became effective. To see this point, consider Figure Three, which shows weekly filings for the first thirty-five weeks of 2004 and 2006, as well as a “difference” line, which shows the excess of the 2004 filings over the 2006 filings.107 As the trend line superimposed over the difference line illustrates, the difference has declined steadily during the first eight months of 2006. Two filing trends connected with the passage of the statute readily could explain those trends. First, the “early filing” effect discussed above: a lot of people filed before BAPCPA who otherwise would have filed later. That effect should depress filing rates after BAPCPA until it plays out. Second, the “deferral” effect discussed in Part III: the provisions that make filing more costly, more bureaucratic, and more humiliating should defer filings until people are deeper in distress. That effect should depress filings initially but ultimately fade away as well. It is too early to assign any specific share to the two effects. It is provocative, however, to see the period over which those effects have played out. I would not have expected pre- BAPCPA early filers to have filed ten months early. But if we discard that explanation, we have to think that the deferral effect operates over a similarly extended period. If so, the steady upward trend in filing rates reflects the period during which the deferred filings are slowly rising to their “normal” level. If we have not yet reached that level, BAPCPA is deferring some filings more than ten months. It is far too soon to be sure of the level at which filings will stabilize after BAPCPA. The data above illustrate graphically that the filing rates remain far below the pre-BAPCPA levels. Yet the steady convergence of post-BAPCPA filing levels with pre-BAPCPA filing trends suggests that we cannot yet be sure that the decline, if any, will be substantial. B. Chapter 13 Filings The second important question about the Act’s effect on credit card issuers is how it will affect the share of filings made under chapter 13, as opposed to chapter 7. The purpose of the means test, after all, is to force borrowers into chapter 13. But the provisions of the Act that relate to chapter 13 provide a strong countervailing influence. As discussed by Bill Whitford and Jean Braucher in their contributions to this symposium, those provisions remove the incentives for most filers to choose chapter 13.108 Thus, it is entirely possible that the Act as a whole will have the effect of lowering the rate of chapter 13 filings—a perverse outcome for credit card issuers used to receiving nothing in chapter 7, but a realistic one nonetheless. Again, it is far too soon to tell, but the early data are instructive. Figure Four shows the percentage of chapter 13 filings (as a share of all bankruptcy filings) for the last two years. Not surprisingly, the share of chapter 13 filings immediately after the Act is unusually high: the overwhelming majority of early filers would have been chapter 7 filers (as we can see from the October 2005 datapoint). Those left behind would be chapter 13 filers. What is interesting about Figure Four is that the chapter 13 rate is still falling steadily, several months after the Act’s effective date. Here, the data suggest a little more basis for a prediction than they did with respect to the overall filing rate. Although the chapter 13 share of filings has not yet fallen below the typical pre-Act share of about 30%, it is important to recognize that the higher rate in Figure Four is a share of an unusually low overall rate. Thus, as Figure Five illustrates, the gross number of chapter 13 filings now is much lower than it was before the Act. That suggests to me the likelihood that, as the total number of filings returns to a stable level, the share of chapter 13 filings will stabilize at a level below the pre-Act level. As with the total filing data, it is too soon to be sure where the filings will stabilize, but it does seem clear already that BAPCPA is not going to cause a major shift in favor of chapter 13 filings. C. Returns in Chapter 13 The final question is what credit card issuers can expect to receive in the chapter 13 plans approved under the Act. Here, Bill Whitford’s piece in this symposium provides a fascinating account of how the happenstance of a Michigan senator’s political weight in the Republican Party led to car lenders getting an unusually strong provision for their benefit—one more instance of the credit card issuers failing to get the statute that they “paid for” back in 1998.109 The key here is the amendments to Bankruptcy Code § 1325.110 That oddly written provision appears as a “hanging” unnumbered paragraph at the end of § 1325(a)—after § 1325(a)(9) but apparently operating to amend § 1325(a)(5): For purposes of paragraph (5), section 506 shall not apply to a claim described in that paragraph if the creditor has a purchase money security interest securing the debt that is the subject of the claim, the debt was incurred within the 910-day period preceding the date of the filing of the petition, and the collateral for that debt consists of a motor vehicle. Although the new language is so obscurely written that it could be interpreted in various ways—perhaps the intention is that there should be no allowed secured claims for car lenders111 —the most likely intent112 seems to be that the entire amount of the car lender’s claim should be treated as an allowed secured claim for purposes of § 1325(a)(5).113 That interpretation would have the effect of placing car lenders in a position quite similar to the position home lenders have held since the decision in Nobelman v. American Savings Bank.114 What that means for credit card issuers, in turn, is that there is greater pressure in debtor budgets to pay funds to the holders of car loans, leaving lower amounts available for unsecured creditors.115 Conversations with bankruptcy judges in the early days after the Act suggest to me that this particular provision is leaving unsecured creditors (including credit card issuers) with no recovery much more frequently than was the case in the pre-Act environment. Scholars herald the arrival of chapter 13 “zero-payment” plans—which pay nothing whatsoever to unsecured creditors.116 Thus, there is good reason to think that credit card issuers in fact will do worse under post-Act chapter 13 plans than they did under pre-Act chapter 13 plans. Hence, even if the Act does increase the share of bankruptcy filings that fall under chapter 13, it is not clear that this will produce any increased recovery for card issuers. V. CONCLUSION The credit card is perhaps the most important financial innovation of the twentieth century; it introduced substantial efficiencies in both payment and borrowing markets. The credit card, however, is associated with increases in spending, borrowing and financial distress.117 It is not clear why that is the case, although academics have suggested it may be due to cognitive impairments, compulsive behavior, excessive or unfair advertising, or fraudulent contracting practices.118 Reform-minded governments around the world currently are struggling with how to respond to the problems with credit cards without undermining the efficiency of payment and lending markets.119 Some responses focus on the payment functionality. Because credit cards might encourage consumers to spend too much, and perhaps more than they can repay out of monthly incomes, credit card use can lead to unplanned debt. The best responses to this problem shift routine payment transactions to debit cards and include such things as point-of-sale disclosures and limitations on advertising, credit card surcharges, and limitations on teaser rates and affinity and rewards programs.120 Other responses focus on the credit function. Because the credit card is so easy to use (that is, the transaction costs of credit card lending are so low), borrowers underestimate the risks associated with future revenue streams. The response is to intervene in the market for consumer lending or adjust the types of relief available in bankruptcy.121 Although policymakers around the world are loosening the rigor of their consumer bankruptcy systems—in large part due to the introduction of American-style consumer credit—the legislative desire to protect the credit card’s unique place in the U.S. economy was one of the most important motivations for the bankruptcy reform statute. Oddly enough, the credit card industry successfully convinced bipartisan majorities in both the House and Senate that there were serious deficiencies in the American bankruptcy system within which the card has had its phenomenal success. Thus, the central idea behind the “fresh start”—that the complete liquidation of all debts—has shifted towards a presumption in favor of repayment. Given the difficulties of sorting out the various factors that influence consumer bankruptcy filings, even hindsight is unlikely to give us a confident understanding of the effects of the Act on bankruptcy filings. For example, I doubt that the Act will deter borrowing to any significant extent. I am also skeptical that it will reduce the number of bankruptcies in any substantial way. Moreover, I think it most improbable that consumers will see the benefit of any increased bankruptcy payouts in the form of interest rate reductions. Still, these assumptions will be hard to test with quantitative data alone, especially in the early years of the Act’s operation. Thus, in the end, I expect that an informed sense of the actual impact of the Act will come only after years of experience. For now, I can offer just the speculations on which this essay is based. ADDITIONAL DISSENT TO RECOMMENDATIONS FOR REFORM OF CONSUMER BANKRUPTCY LAW Submitted by Honorable Edith H. Jones and Commissioner James I. Shepard The assistance of Professor Richard E. Flint and Ms. Kelly J. Wilhelm is gratefully acknowledged I. General Observations The consumer bankruptcy recommendations of a five-four majority of the Commission speak volumes about the error of entrusting reform to defenders of the institution that needs reforming.(2711) Many of these recommendations are not only unrealistic, they are simply deaf to the public debate over and frustration with this nation's bankruptcy system. And in conspicuous areas, the majority recommendations are also mute. It is foolish not to view with alarm the fact that 1.2 million people filed for bankruptcy relief in 1996, nearly 30% more than in the previous year, and that a similar proportional increase appears to be happening during 1997. When filings rise dramatically while unemployment is declining, it is inevitable that the next economic downtown will produce a cataclysm of filings. When the cataclysm occurs, the stability of our creditdriven economy could be shaken. The Commission's response to this reality, novel in our history, is silence. The reporter's introduction to consumer bankruptcy purports to conclude that the cause of the high rate of bankruptcy filings is debt. That controversial conclusion(2712) is about like saying that the cause of the high rate of divorce is marriage. Even if the debt-causes-bankruptcy theory is portentous, it is founded in politics and economics, not law. Because neither the reporter nor any member of this Commission is an economist, it is out of our bailiwick to speculate on the economic causes of increased filings. But if too much debt is the source of the bankruptcy problem, Congress should address it directly rather than indirectly through bankruptcy law. This Commission's report should not be taken seriously on purely economic issues. There remains a normative question which is very much within our competence to evaluate: whether a bankruptcy law that permits well over one million people a year to break their contracts and discharge debts -- during "good times" -- is functioning correctly. In this respect, the five-member majority tome on consumer bankruptcy is silent. Silence serves a number of purposes. It furthers the interest of those who file consumer bankruptcy petitions, many of whom advocated from the beginning of the Commission that the bankruptcy law wasn't broken, and the Commission shouldn't fix it. Silence stifles debate over whether bankruptcy relief should be means-tested like all other programs available in the social safety net. Silence ignores creditors' complaints that their interests are systematically short-changed by the Framework, while those of debtors are enhanced. Silence also obscures the impact of the Framework proposals, by concealing that those proposals create even more incentives than now exist to seek bankruptcy relief and that they favor Chapter 7 discharge over Chapter 13 repayment plans. Nowhere, as far as I can tell, does the Framework justify these untoward consequences. The Framework induces more people to seek bankruptcy relief by significantly increasing exemptions; by treating reaffirmations as installment redemption on discounted collateral; by voiding liens on any household good less than $500 "value;" by degrading rent-to-own contracts from rental agreements to security interests; and by allowing full dischargeability of any credit card debt incurred within the authorized credit limits more than thirty days before bankruptcy. The general lesson from these changes is: go on a shopping spree and declare bankruptcy in thirty-one days. The Framework is silent on any notion of personal responsibility for one's debts. Similarly disadvantageous to creditors and to bill-paying Americans who bear the hidden bankruptcy tax,(2713) the Framework effectively discourages Chapter 13 filings. This effect results (1) from allowing the debtor to make no more payments on secured debt in Chapter 7 (through reaffirmation) than would be required in a Chapter 13 cramdown plan, (2) from measures that may increase Chapter 13 payment requirements without increasing debtors' incentives to file in Chapter 13, and (3) from enhancing the exemption levels. The synergistic effect of these changes is skewed toward increasing use of Chapter 7. The Framework's silence about its impact on Chapter 7 filings is unsurprising, because it is completely irreconcilable with the early versions of the Framework that purported to enhance and encourage the use of Chapter 13. The Framework has in fact departed entirely, and entirely without explanation, from its initial premises. In March, the Framework was initially presented to the public as an integrated plan calculated to make the debtor's choice between Chapters 7 and 13 relief consequential. The Framework sought to enhance use of Chapter 13 and to balance debtors' and creditors' rights. As a tradeoff for this first Framework's attempt to ban all reaffirmations, the use of Chapter 13 would afford secured creditors higher and more certain payments on unsecured deficiency claims.(2714) As it matured into the final product, none of the first Framework's aims have been preserved. The five-member Framework sent to Congress in fact blurs the line between Chapter 7 and Chapter 13 significantly by conflating reaffirmations and installment redemption. As its general thrust is to encourage Chapter 7 liquidations rather than repayment plans, unsecured creditors have no corresponding assurance of receiving payments in Chapter 13. Other measures that would have protected creditors appeared in the March draft and were inexplicably dropped thereafter, removing any pretense of balance between debtors and creditors. The five-member majority proposals that go to Congress, unlike earlier drafts of the Framework, have dropped the following provisions: a more rigid limit on serial filings; affidavit practice to speed up relief from the automatic stay; reliance on the impending Rash decision for valuation for collateral; and dismissal of failed Chapter 13 plans rather than automatic conversion to Chapter 7. Admittedly, the present Framework eliminates the wholesale stripping of junior home mortgages, but the Framework remains, on balance, disrespectful of the state-law rights of secured creditors. Elsewhere, several of us have identified other "process" and substantive objections to the consumer Framework.(2715) In particular, the General Critique of the "Framework" lays bare the unstated political and economic assumptions which guide that document. Consistent with all of those objections, I have additional serious objections to recommendations and omissions of the consumer bankruptcy chapter. These are: • The Commission's failure to consider mean-testing for consumer bankruptcy relief; • the Commission's failure to address changes to § 707(b), and "substantial abuse" provision; and • the Framework's recommendations for dischargeability of student loans, credit card debt, the Chapter 13 superdischarge, and state court default judgments. Congress should consider means-testing for consumer bankruptcy relief; it should amend § 707(b); and it should decline to accept the Commission's recommendations that enhance discharge of debts for unjustifiable reasons. II. Means-Testing Bankruptcy Relief In 1980, just after the Bankruptcy Code was passed and amid an economic recession, annual filings stood at slightly over 330,000. Sixteen years later, following a sustained period of economic growth, the number of filings has risen suddenly and dramatically from just under a million to 1.2 million consumer bankruptcies in 1996. The disproportionate increase has continued in the first part of 1997. We now have an anomalous situation in which unemployment is falling but bankruptcy is rising. Moreover, it has been estimated that Americans pay a hidden bankruptcy tax of $300-400 per household as the losses occasioned by higher bankruptcies are redistributed through higher-priced goods and services.(2716) This is not the place to speculate on all of the causes of increased filings. But no one suggests that the filings are any longer demographically confined to the lowest socioeconomic groups or those who have irrevocably lost their jobs or have become physically disabled -- seeking bankruptcy protection has become more and more common among fully employed middle- and upper-class people. See Appendix attached hereto. More disturbingly, many debtors are now filing for bankruptcy protection before actually defaulting on debt. Id. As Congressman Pete Sessions recently described it, bankruptcy is "for some people . . . just another tool of financial management." Further, contrary to the implications drawn by many bankruptcy practitioners and academics before the Commission, the rapid increase in filings cannot mean that the bankruptcy system requires amendment to soften its impact on debtors. If it were unfair to them, there would not be a vast migration toward bankruptcy when, as we see today, employment prospects seem brighter than ever. In part, the bankruptcy boom springs from the intention of the 1978 Code. The drafters of the Code, many of whom have actively influenced this Commission's work, consciously sought to remove the social stigma from filing bankruptcy. The Code, for instance, replaced the term bankrupt with "debtor" and described a case filing as seeking an "order for relief." If you craft a social welfare statute, people soon learn to appreciate the benefits of seeking welfare. Social and moral changes have also accelerated the trend to accepting bankruptcy as a feature of "normal" life. Movie stars, governors and "famed heart surgeons" have taken advantage of the process to discharge their debts, so why shouldn't ordinary Americans? To take just one example from the wealth of bankruptcy- promoting advertising and literature a book titled Debt Free! offers "Your Guide to Personal Bankruptcy without Shame."(2717) A prominent bankruptcy judge once commented to me that when he graduated from law school around 1950, there were two things that "people never did: divorce and bankruptcy." This comment captures an insight often overlooked by those who make their living from the bankruptcy process. Declaring bankruptcy has a moral dimension. To declare bankruptcy is to break one's contracts and agreements. Our society cannot function if it becomes widely acceptable to do this. In fact, the sanctity of contract -enforced by the rule of law -- animated the growth, development and prosperity of the Western world. Enforceable contracts permit economic freedom to flourish and provide opportunity for all precisely because they are the product of voluntary action rather than state-sponsored preferences, priorities, or corruption. To regress from a norm in which contracts are enforceable threatens the foundation of our economic engine. Beyond contracts and mere transactional effects are the distrust, disaffection and misunderstanding that erupt in a society which broadly permits such promise-breaking as occurs in bankruptcy. The large number of heartfelt and often poignant letters received by the Commission from creditors who were short-changed by debtors in bankruptcy attests to this sad reality. No doubt, bankruptcy is a necessary feature of Judeo-Christian capitalist societies, but to advance the equally moral goals of protecting social cohesion and general welfare, it cannot become more than an act of grace available to those who are truly and seriously needy. We must not, to paraphrase Senator Moynihan and former Treasury Secretary Lloyd Bentsen, "define bankruptcy deviancy downward." Finally, bankruptcy has a macroeconomic effect on the cost and availability of credit. Graphically demonstrating this impact are hundreds of letters the Commission has received from credit unions. Credits unions' losses in bankruptcy directly affect their loan rates and practices, and in the past three to four years, those losses have dramatically increased. Other lenders, large and small, have had similar experiences. The rising number of bankruptcies will increase interest rates for all consumers and will cause businesses to scrutinize credit more closely and discriminate among borrowers. The real losers as the supply of consumer credit tightens are those at the bottom of the ladder. In the final analysis, bankruptcy "reforms" that favor bankrupts do not favor bill-paying customers. Without further belaboring what should be an obvious point, bankruptcy as a social welfare program is subsidized by creditors and, through them, by the vast majority of Americans who struggle and succeed to make ends meet financially. In light of these considerations, it is hard to justify why the Commission has not formally considered means-testing for bankruptcy relief, as a device to limit the adverse consequences of the filing explosion. Several factors have contributed to this failure. First, the advocates of means-testing received no encouragement or assistance from the Commission's staff. Second, the creditor community has until recently been reluctant to articulate a concrete proposal for means-testing. Third, the professionals who have been heavily involved in the Commission process exhibit the general reluctance of the legal profession to contemplate "reform" that may disturb their customary practices. Fourth, analogizing the bankruptcy system to the welfare office, or to similar programs that routinely engage in means-testing, discomfits bankruptcy professionals. Finally, it is a complex task to create fair and efficient means-testing criteria that would not administratively bog down the bankruptcy courts. If the Commission had engaged in this important debate, we might have considered at least five different options for means-testing. It appears that the primary considerations in setting up such a program are fairness and ease of administration together with the maximum feasible simplicity. The point of means-testing is to permit Chapter 7 discharge and liquidation of debt only to those debtors who are truly unable to repay their debts in the future. Those debtors who are income-earning, however, should not receive the benefits of the full discharge and the automatic stay to the extent that they are able to repay creditors the secured and a portion of the unsecured debts they have incurred. Each of the following proposals, listed in no particular order of importance, has the potential to accomplish the objective of means-testing within the noted constraints. 1. Section 707(b) could be amended to require that the court dismiss or convert the case of a debtor who has filed for Chapter 7 if, on the motion of a party in interest or the U.S. Trustee, it is found that the debtor has the ability to repay a portion of his debts in Chapter 13. This option would permit debtor-selection of bankruptcy relief to begin with, utilizing creditor oversight and the courts to determine the appropriateness of that relief within statutory guidelines. The provision might set as a threshold the debtor's ability to pay back 10% of unsecured debt within five years, or any other amount chosen by Congress. 2. Any debtor whose family income exceeded $35,000 or $40,000 per year, a solid middle-class income, might be permitted to file for Chapter 7 liquidation relief only by agreeing to pay for and submit to a full bankruptcy audit conducted by the panel trustee. 3. A presumptive income ceiling for the availability of Chapter 7 relief could be defined. Thus, any debtor whose family income exceeded an average middle-class income, say $35-40,000 per year, would presumptively be required to seek Chapter 13 repayment plan relief unless the debtor could establish extraordinary and compelling circumstances justifying Chapter 7 liquidation. Those circumstances could be codified and should include no less than serious and costly medical or health conditions; unique family circumstances (large number of dependents); being a fraud victim; or being out of work and unemployable for a sustained period of time. 4. A "least-common-denominator" means test would automatically channel any debtor seeking bankruptcy relief into a Chapter 13 proceeding if she is able to repay a minimum level of unsecured debt within five years. This proposal is administratively feasible, because it uses the information now recorded on the debtor's bankruptcy Schedules I and J, reflecting income and monthly expenditures, and derives the debtor's "disposable income" from those charts. A debtor and her attorney would immediately discern whether Chapter 7 or 13 relief was permitted and would so certify to the court. Court intervention would be required only for challenges to the certification or questions raised by the U.S. Trustee. The reform proposals of Four Dissenting Commissioners include proposals to enhance the integrity of debtor's schedules and thus, one hopes, to limit manipulation of this alternative. 5. The needs-based test suggested by some creditors derives from the assumption that all debtors should be directed into a Chapter 13 repayment plan to the extent their family income exceeds average costs of living in their area, as determined by statistics from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Immediate questions are raised about the complexity and fairness of this proposal, but those objections may be allayed in various ways. First, BLS statistics are already in use in one form or another by Chapter 13 trustees as a gauge against excessive expenditures claimed by Chapter 13 debtors. Second, if BLS statistics are fair geographically, they can be administratively disseminated to bankruptcy courts, trustees and debtors' attorneys and promptly updated. Third, the use of similar measures by family courts and tax collection agencies in working out debtor payment plans suggest their feasibility for bankruptcy plans. Fourth, the statute could except debtors from this standard under circumstances in which its application would be clearly unjust. Finally, to the extent this standard would require debtors to make higher payments than they presently contemplate, it is because such debtors have higher expenses and, presumably, higher income-earning history than average Americans. The proposal is therefore a progressive one, which would have its smallest impact on low-income debtors. Three vehement objections to means-testing bankruptcy relief, and requiring many income-earning debtors to pay back some portion of their debts, have been frequently voiced. The first is that, given the current high failure rate of cases in Chapter 13, it can hardly be expected that when debtors are forced into debt payment plans, they will be more likely to complete their court-ordered obligations. While this is certainly a possibility, it is mitigated by the alternative that such debtors would face. If they did not complete their Chapter 13 plans, their cases would be dismissed, and they would again be at the mercy of creditors. The option of converting to Chapter 7 liquidation in a meanstesting regime would necessarily be limited for those debtors who originally qualified only for Chapter 13 payment plans. It should also be noted that none of the presentlyconceived means-testing proposals requires a particularly draconian level of debt repayment. Moreover, once debtors become well aware that their earning capacity will limit the debt relief to which they may be entitled, they can plan their lives accordingly. It is patronizing and short-sighted to assert that debtors are too stupid and undisciplined to adjust their expenditures to the default standards that society will maintain. Second, it is often cavalierly asserted by bankruptcy professionals that requiring people to repay some portion of their debts amounts to unconstitutional "involuntary servitude." One court appropriately dismissed this odd notion as follows: Debtors further argue that § 707(b) is unconstitutional as a violation of the 13th Amendment in that the statute "could force persons into a state of involuntary servitude," debtors' brief p. 9. [Under Section 707(b), debtor's liquidation petition may be dismissed if the debtor could repay significant debt in a Chapter 13 case.] The 13th Amendment proscribes slavery or its functional equivalents, e.g. peonage, U.S. v. Kozminski, 487 U.S. 931, 941-42, 108 S. Ct. 2751, 2759, 101 L.Ed.2d 788, 804ff. (1988). As noted above, § 707(b) is intended to prevent debtors who are capable of paying their just debts from discharging them by misuse of an extraordinary privilege to which they are not properly entitled. If this violates the 13th Amendment, then it would seem that having to pay one's just debts is "slavery" or "peonage" -- put another way, debtors would read the 13th Amendment as if it provided a Constitutional right to a Chapter 7 discharge! The great majority of Americans who work hard to pay off their voluntarily-incurred debts might be a bit surprised to hear the Protestant Ethic described as "slavery." Judicial review of voluntarily-filed Chapter 7 cases for abuse does not force anyone to work and does not force debtors to divert any part of their income to payment of debts. Such judicial review merely requires debtors who already work and have enough income to pay their debts to "take their chances" under State law if they refuse to meet their obligations, by refusing in turn to grant equitable intervention to protect such debtors from State debt-collection mechanisms where insufficient cause for such intervention has been shown. In re Tony Ray Higginbotham, 111 B.R. 955, 966-97 (Bankruptcy N.D. Oklahoma 1990); see also In re Koch, 109 F.3d 1285, 1290 (8th Cir. 1997) ("Congress is free to limit Chapter 7 protection to truly needy debtors who cannot fund a Chapter 13 plan . . . ."). A third complaint by those who resist means-testing is that debtors cannot pay back anything, according to some empirical studies, or alternatively, there is no good proof that they can repay a portion of unsecured debts. I am not an economist or statistician and will not debate these hypotheses, although they are strongly controverted.(2718) Having been a member of the Commission's Consumer Bankruptcy Working Group, however, and having read the thousands of pages submitted to us on consumer bankruptcy, I draw two firm conclusions. First, too many letters from lenders and news articles depict instances of filings by people with steady jobs whose lifestyles got out of control or who gambled (sometimes literally) with their finances and lost. See, e.g., Appendix hereto. If they have steady income, and no exceptional problems such as physical disability, it does not seem unfair for society to ask them to repay some of their unsecured debts. Second, if by some chance it is true that no debtor can afford to repay some unsecured debts, then the critics of means-testing will be vindicated by that very program. No means-testing proposal I have seen would impoverish anyone with an impossible level of debt repayment. On the contrary, if all debtors are so needy as the means-testing critics contend, none of them will qualify for debt repayments, and all will receive a Chapter 7 discharge. The arguments for means-testing are clear and are also consistent with accepted public policy for similar situations. Means-testing is not a radical idea. We already use it to determine child care benefits, Medicaid benefits, social security benefits, supplemental security income, food stamp benefits and student aid benefits at the federal level alone. Moreover, as one professor has put it: Lack of means testing creates the moral hazard problem of allowing abusers to self-select their own debt remedy. This can do nothing but exacerbate abuse. Would we, for example, allow welfare recipients to select their own benefits? Would we allow golfers to determine their own "gimmies"? Of course not. So why allow debtors to select their own remedy? Would they not simply act in their own interest on average, therefore exacerbating abuse? The answer is probably "yes," so means testing (or some other gate keeping" machinery) is the only way to eliminate this moral hazard. Letter from James J. Johannes, Firstar Professor of Banking and Director, Puelicher Center for Banking Education, University of Wisconsin-Madison, to Mr. Brady Williamson (June 17, 1997). The Commission has in my view neglected its duty to investigate alternatives to the present-day reality of excessive bankruptcy filings. I hope that Congress will take up the challenge. IV. Dischargeability Issues A. General Observations While the Commission's Report acknowledges that it "did not undertake the task of honing the list [of exceptions to discharge] down," it did recommend certain clarifications and amendments to enhance fairness to all parties, to achieve uniformity in the law, to alleviate confusion, and to reduce the costs of litigation.(2732) However, a review of the suggested changes to Section 523(a) reveals a noticeable shift in the present balance of the law to a decidedly anti-creditor position. While the changes suggested by the Commission's Report might achieve its stated goal of uniformity, the price to creditors and to society as a whole is far too great. The goals sought to be achieved by the Commission through changes in dischargeability policy can be achieved without distorting the basic creditor-debtor balance of the present law. Although a fundamental purpose of consumer bankruptcy is the discharge of certain obligations, that purpose must be juxtaposed with and limited by legitimate concerns about culpable debtor conduct, the maintenance of the integrity of the bankruptcy system, and common societal good. Given the rising numbers of bankruptcy filings and the increasing amounts of debt being discharged through bankruptcy proceedings, it is incumbent that any recommendations for change in dischargeability policy be accompanied with an evaluation of the impact of the decision upon both the debtor-creditor relationship and society as a whole. As will be shown below, the Commission's Report failed to take this part of the process into consideration when arriving at its recommendations. B. Dischargeability of Student Loans The Commission's Report recommends that the provision of the Bankruptcy Code which makes student loans [other than loans for medical education governed by special federal legislation] nondischargeable in both Chapter 7 and Chapter 13 be overturned.(2733) The Commission's recommendations are based upon several conclusions: the present undue hardship exception is subject to "disparate multi-factor approaches;"(2734) many of the present defaults are from fly-by-night trade or technical schools which often do not even provide educational services;(2735) and its rejection of the premise that the nondischargeability of student loans is necessary for the continued viability of the guaranteed student loan program.(2736) The Commission's proposal will clearly eliminate any confusion or nonuniformity of decisions in the area of dischargeability of student loans. However, in reaching its decision the Commission discounted all the evidence presented to it on the impact this change would have on the continued viability of the guaranteed student loan program.(2737) Instead, the Commission relied upon nonstatistical information provided to it by the General Accounting Office that implied that the student loan program was instituted with default in mind and that the taxpayers were intended to pick up the tab for students' inability to repay loans.(2738) Furthermore, the Commission's proposal is based upon its own admission that in many cases the present cost of certain education does not translate into sufficient income to repay the loans,(2739) and therefore, society needs to treat these loans as mere grants or subsidies whose costs must be borne by taxpayers. Section 523(a)(8) provides useful and practical boundaries concerning educational loans by (1) preventing abuse of the educational loan system with restrictions on the ability to discharge student loans shortly after graduation and (2) safeguarding the financial integrity of governmental entities and nonprofit institutions who participate in education loan programs. The nondischargeability of guaranteed student loans helps to maintain the solvency of educational lending programs in order to enlarge access to higher education. Congress has within the last six years reviewed the advisability of nondischargeability and determined that it should remain.(2740) The Commission's Report shows a lack of understanding of guaranteed student lending practices. First, creditors in the majority of these cases lend money to individuals who might not qualify for credit under traditional credit criteria. The borrowers usually lack an established asset base or income-generated track record and have no collateral to justify the loan. The loan is made with the view that it is an investment in the borrower's future ability to generate income as a result of the increase in human capital due to education. Further, the lender is well aware that it takes time following graduation for a student to develop a career and sufficient earning capacity to repay the loan. In fact, this projected increased earning potential achieved through education is the primary factor considered by a lender in making loans under the student loan program.(2741) The unique character of educational lending led Congress to enact special lender protection under the bankruptcy laws. The Commission's comparison of educational loan creditors to creditors who lend debtors money to buy pizza highlights the naivete of the Commission's understanding of the student guaranteed lending industry. The Commission's Report is more an indictment of schools which do not adequately educate or train the students than it is a justification for making these loans nondischargeable.(2742) If shortfalls in the educational system are the problem, it should be addressed directly. Blame for a perceived lack of training or benefit should not be imposed on the taxpayers or the many non-profit institutions who provide funds to students. Congress has already made the public policy choice that the potential for abuse in the educational loan system outweighs the debtor's right to a fresh start. Finally, the Commission's treatment of student loans as a "subsidy" similar to the GI Bill is a gross mischaracterization and a disservice to those who earned their right to GI Bill benefits.(2743) It is highly unlikely that Congress contemplated that the student loan guarantee program was a mere mirage -- just a method to give students a cash subsidy or grant at the taxpayer's expense. The nondischargeability provision is intended to maintain the solvency of educational lending programs and thus promote access to higher education.(2744) Our present Code recognizes that through the hardship exception under certain circumstances some of these loans cannot be repaid. If the Commission felt that the hardship discharge needed to be clarified to ensure some degree of uniformity, it could have proposed that solution.(2745) In closing, it should be pointed out that there was no public outcry presented to the Commission for elimination of this exception. In fact, the report directed to be prepared by the Commission's Reporter did not recommend the repeal of this section.(2746) The overwhelming evidence received by the Commission opposed this repeal. If this repeal occurs, non-profit entities and governmental units will be forced to raise their fees to cover the rising losses. Non-profit entities may discontinue providing loans;(2747) and taxpayers will just end up picking up the tab.(2748) The concerns raised by these constituencies were overlooked by the Commission. The proposed recommendation, like many finally approved by the Commission, was just not supported by the record before it. This section should remain unaltered in both Chapter 7 and 13. C. Credit Card Debt There is uniform agreement that Section 523(a)(2)(A) is ill-equipped to deal with the question of the nondischargeability of debt incurred from the use of a credit card in those cases which do not involve actual fraud in the application for the card.(2749) The Commission correctly identifies the multitude of problems facing the courts as they have attempted to apply this section of the Code to the use of credit cards.(2750) The Commission then notes that the proliferation of cards and bankruptcy filings demand more orderliness in approaching the issue of nondischargeability debts incurred with properly obtained credit cards. However, the Commission's Report fails to identify the problem which it is trying to remedy. Instead, it merely assumes that some credit card debt is to be nondischargeable [no reason given], and then draws a bright line rule for the sole purpose of bringing some uniformity into the area. Its arbitrary thirty-day rule is totally disingenuous. Discharge is to be given to the "honest but unfortunate debtor;" in large part, debts are to be denied discharge due to the bad conduct of the debtor. The Commission's proposal is devoid of any discussion of the moral turpitude of the debtor or his intentional wrongdoing as a basis for the nondischargeability of credit card debt. The thirty-day period is also purely arbitrary and has no basis in reality. If its purpose is to balance rights of debtors and credit card lenders by assuring a period in which abuse of credit cards will not be tolerated while also forcing lenders to be more careful in extending credit, it fails. The proposal explicitly renders fully dischargeable all credit card debts incurred within the credit limits 31 days or more before bankruptcy. This is an open invitation to abuse and manipulation. Further, there is no way creditors can have an opportunity to forestall such abuse by tightening credit because not even one billing cycle would elapse from the dates of abuse until the debtor filed bankruptcy. Like so many of the Framework proposals, this one will discourage extensions of credit to marginal borrowers. It may be debtor-friendly, but is in no way consumer-friendly. The Report is correct in that the common law fraud principles should not apply in their entirety to credit card debt. Thus, issues such as whether the debtor knowingly made a misrepresentation or intended to deceive the creditor, or whether the creditor justifiably relied to his detriment on a misrepresentation, should not be the touchstones for this new nondischargeability section. The Report is also correct in its conclusion that a bright-line rule would necessarily reduce judicial time and resources. However, the Commission's proposal is a type of rough justice that totally misses the mark. It seriously undermines the integrity of the bankruptcy process by failing to equate nondischargeability to any concrete standard. Outside of taxes and family support obligations, certain debts are considered to be nondischargeable for the simple reason that the conduct of the debtor was not at an acceptable level. The evidence before the Commission clearly identified the evil which needed to be addressed -- the incurring of credit card debt while a person either contemplated bankruptcy [pre-bankruptcy planning] or had no reasonable ability to repay the debt [constructive fraud]. The following proposal addresses the evil and attempts to impose some degree of uniformity into the bankruptcy process. The goal of this proposal is to prevent a debtor from discharging credit card debt when he knew or reasonably should have known that he had no expectation of repaying it. In line with Congress's earlier decision to add section 523(a)(2)(C) (the "luxury goods" provision), a new section should be added to Section 523 as follows: All debts incurred through credit card use within sixty (60) days before the order for relief under this title are presumed to be nondischargeable. A debtor may rebut this presumption by showing the following: (1) that at the time a particular credit card debt was incurred, the debtor was not contemplating bankruptcy and (2) that at the time a particular credit card debt was incurred, a reasonably prudent person [not the debtor] would have expected that there was an ability to repay the debt. This proposal addresses culpable conduct, as nondischargeability policy ought to do. Moreover, enactment of this provision should not prevent applicability of section 523(a)(2)(A) or (B) if, before the sixty-day period, the debtor incurred credit card debt with intent to defraud. Final Discussion Question. To what extent is consumer bankruptcy discharge important to the economy as a liquidity measure? Chapter 17 Consumer Borrowing/Lending Around the World. You are the chief staff person to a United Nations Committee charged with a set of standards for consumer lending/borrowing around the world. The notion is to recognize that different countries will call for different regimens of regulation depending on a variety of factors. Here are some of the factors that will affect the policy decisions that the regulators/legislators from each country should consider A. Cultural of Borrowing / Purchasing Remember the introductory readings from Schor, Warren and Caldor and the chapter on Behavioral Economics? They are addressed to borrowers in the United States, but they point out the various sources of borrowers’ decisions. The essential notion is that before we can decide how much and what kinds of regulations will be optimal for a particular country we need to understand the borrowing behaviors of folks in that country. There are at least two basic reasons to regulate consumer borrowing/lending. The first worry is that if it is unregulated it will lead to frequent economic crashes which will cause massive damage of various types. Hyman Minsky asserts that overspending by consumers will inevitably lead to an economic crash when the bubble bursts. Is this every eighty years (1929 -2005) or every fifty years or every decade? The second worry is micro rather than macro, unless we regulate, individual citizens will make decisions which will cause them harm. In a society where neither of those harms is likely to occur, then the need for regulation is reduced. If we conclude that consumer behavior is likely to lead to both of these results then the need for such regulation is heightened. Once we decide on the level of regulation we need to decide what kind. For example, if we think consumers will act in their interests if they understand financial decision making and the essence of the specific borrowing transaction then we might increase the level of financial literacy education and the amount of disclosure requirements. If we think the problem is not one that can be ameliorated by disclosure or education then we might need to prohibit certain kinds of credit offerings such as payday loans or invoke doctrines such as the denying enforcement of credit transactions where the consumer should not have been eligible for the credit extension. So, the first item on our survey might be aimed at evaluating the proclivity of consumers in that country to borrow beyond their ability to repay or to use a dangerous borrowing product. We might inquire about the following topics: Financial literacy of the population; The role of peer pressure; Undue optimism; Hyperbolic discounting ; Others – level of desperation Middle class chasing the rich ; recent US study What will we expect the consumers to do now or as they become more able to buy i.e. China and India etc.. Other items of interest would include: . Chronology of various technological developments. For example in the US the credit card controlled the consumer payment market before the debit card could make any headway; in Canada they were available and presented together and the relative use of the debit card was enormously higher than in the United States in 2005. Another litmus test is the availability of sophisticated credit reporting systems. For example in the Philippines there are five debit cards for every credit card. . Percentage of home ownership, home mortgages and car ownership These are major items. In the US they constitute a significant percentage of the debt service requirements. In EU countries not so much. See the chart below on home ownership by country, on car ownership by country and by percentage of mortgage debt in Europe. . Effectiveness of enforcement mechanisms. How high are the barriers to collecting in the event of default by the borrower? Effectiveness of Enforcement mechanisms; a. Collection potential/barriers b. Institutional factors b. c. d. e. f. g. h. availability of funds to lend; Political instability or stability; Infrastructure of lenders; Economic and employment demographics Rising middle class; how rapid? Visa/Mastercard availability Profit potential Consumer Regulation Scorecard Proclivity to make damaging borrowing decisions Chronology Home Ownership Enforcement Mechanism Institutional or Policy Factors Availability of funds to lend/borrow Infrastructure of lenders Economy and Employment Profit Potential Visa/Mastercard Financial Sophistication of Borrowers Consumer Regulation Scorecard A quick look at selected countries CANADA Up until 2002 the contrast between the behavior of Canadian consumer and US consumers was stark and fascinating. Canadians simply did not borrow at the same pace or use the same kinds of credit mechanisms as consumers in the U.S. Starting in about 2002 this contrast dimmed and Canadians began to act more and more similar to U S consumer borrowers. This was true both for credit card debt and for mortgage debt. The numbers for credit card debt are a bit misleading because the US market increased an matured by 2000 while the market in Canada had grown much more slowly during the 1980’s and 1990’s. As a result of these differences comparing percentage growth or decline from these bases may be deceiving. Still, Canada suffered much much less than the United States from the worldwide economic recession of 2007 and bounced back much more quickly. Canadian consumer continued to purchase and continued to borrow and this buoyed their economy. However, starting in late 2011 it became clear that they were now exhibiting some of the same conduct that US consumers had exhibited in the two decades leading up to the 2007 crash. Although U.S consumers have reduced outstanding balances or deleveraged since the recession (although much of it involuntarily) Canadians have done just the opposite. As a share of disposable income, debt grew more slowly in Canada than in the US throughout the 2000’s and Canadians held lower levels of consumer and mortgage debt. that trend was reversed. While the U.S. debt to income ratio fell back to 110%, the ratio in Canada surpassed 150% and reached new highs with each passing quarter. Credit and mortgage debt alone surpassed 140% of disposable income, well above the peak reached in the U.S. just prior to the recession. In Canada, between 2006 and 2011 household balances of consumer credit and mortgage debt each expanded by around 50%, an average annual pace exceeding 8% and twice the growth in disposable income. Moody’s analytics 2012. (Storm Clouds Gather Around Canadian Consumer Credit by Deritis and Hopkins) For various reasons the pace of borrowing in Canada slowed from 2011. It is interesting to note that home equity second mortgages, or second mortgages of any type are very rare in Canada. BRAZIL Going further south perhaps the most interesting story is that of Brazil. One of the key BRICS nations with a solid and expanding economy and enhanced political stability, the door to the middle class, the door to enhanced purchasing power is wide open for Brazilian citizens. So, what do we know about their purchasing habits? Huge increase in mortgage debt as the expanding economy allows many first time home buyers; Lower interest rates are keeping the total monthly debt down even as the total amount of debt increases significantly. Government wants people to borrow and lend to spur the economy even as the default rate is high. Best example are the car loan experiments. In 2008 the government provided incentives to spur the sale of new cars and made financing more available This spurred the sale of cars but not long after lead to a spike in the number and rate of defaults. In response, policy makers said they were taking actions to prevent a credit bubble after vehicle financing surged 49% in 2012, payment terms expended to as much as 80 months. This seemed to work. Then, in May 2012, once again in order to increase the sale of cars the government encouraged banks to lend more broadly and more dollars on car purchases. Brazil does have an asset backed securities industry, the so call FIDC which grew to 312 funds worth 59 billion reals (32 billion dollars) from 2001 to 2012. Pyroll loans are a major source of crdit in Brazil. Credit cards were stymied for a time because of large charges that Mastercard and Visa iboth imposed. When the market was opened up to competition those charges were reduced and it is possible that new sources of reals available to lend will provide an increase in credit card debt. SOUTH AFRICA Consumer loans not backed by assets tripled in South Africa from 2009 to 2012. They rose by 39% in one year During a deadly miners strike it was estimate that most of the moner were so indebted that they needed the pay increases of up to 22% just to take hime a modest chuck of their paychecks. The raio of household debt to disposable income is 76.% in mid 2012. and now account for ten percent of the consumer credit, up from 8 per cent a year earlier. Reports indicate that nearly one half or in default and that a significant proportion is subject to wage garnishment. Every month millions of people in China experience sufficient upward mobility that they can begin to purchase appliances and other non necessities; every month millions move up to the point where they can buy smart phones and computers; every month millions step up ready to purchase their first car. Consider these issues for the following countries Korea Also China and Indonesia readings Eastern Europe?? South America: Brazil and Chile Chile EU France, Germany, UK and Turkey Asia China Indonesia South Korea India Africa South Africa Nigeria Consumer Credit in China Published : January 02, 2013 in Knowledge@Wharton "I'm a little embarrassed." Liu Jing leaned in closer and lowered her voice, revealing for the first time a hint of discomfort since the topic of credit cards had been broached. After a pause, she smiled, took a breath and said, "but let's chat." Liu was born in Henan, a province in central China 600 miles northwest of Shanghai. Despite coming from a solidly working-class family, she was encouraged to study hard as a child and prepare for the gao kao, China's rigorous college-placement examination. She received high marks and earned a coveted position at a public university in Beijing. While she had studied English in Henan, it was not until she arrived in Beijing that she discovered her gift for language. After four years at the university and despite never having left mainland China, Liu gained a strong command of English and an understanding of Western culture and business practices. She stood out as a model of success within China's stunted education system. She cultivated her skills by befriending Western exchange students and young British expatriates working in the capital. Due to her competent English, she landed a position as a junior executive at a digital advertising firm. While her salary was slightly below the entry-level standard for white-collar jobs in China, the position allowed her to remain in vibrant, growing Beijing. Soon after entering the workforce, however, Liu began to grapple with economic reality. Her salary barely covered her rent and other basic necessities. She also realized that with Western friends came lifestyle choices. If she wanted to maintain her English skills, she would have to be comfortable accompanying her Western friends to restaurants and bars, which meant additional spending. On the back of a napkin, Liu spelled out her financial conundrum. As a junior executive, she netted 5,000 RMB (US$800) a month after taxes. From this, she paid 2,000 RMB (US$320) per month in rent for a shared flat near Beijing's fourth ring road. This left her with 3,000 RMB (US$480) a month in disposable income, or 100 RMB (US$16) a day. With this sum, she had to cover her remaining living expenses. Liu tried to stretch her income as best she could, but when she suddenly lost her job due to a company acquisition, she was hard-pressed to make ends meet. At this moment, a friend recommended that Liu apply for a UnionPay credit card from one of China's large state-owned banks. She was hesitant at first, given the Chinese cultural tendency to avoid borrowing, but this was the help she needed. As she was no longer employed and was in a weak position to apply for a line of credit, she begged a friend in the accounting department of her former company to forge the necessary documents to show she was still employed and had a monthly income. Begrudgingly, her friend helped. A month later, Liu had her first credit card. At first, Liu used the card to make ends meet. She would borrow against her credit at the beginning of the month and pay off most of the balance within 30 days. But as time went on, the allure of this "extra" income and the social benefits it allowed compelled Liu to slowly increase her borrowing. She soon discovered that borrowing is a slippery slope. After using the card for one year, she had accumulated debt of 15,000 RMB (US$2,400), or three times her previous monthly income. "I don't really know exactly how my credit card works, like how much interest I need to pay every month," she acknowledged. Even so, she was acutely aware that this money would need to be repaid eventually. She had no plan for paying off the balance. She would try to save more, and perhaps her next job would pay her a higher salary. Until then, Liu Jing, an exemplar of China's new middle class, was trapped. A Variety of Credit Options Despite a personal credit system that is underdeveloped by Western standards, China has a long history of informal personal finance. Both usury and interpersonal interest-free lending date back nearly 3,000 years to the Western Zhou period. Cooperative loan societies, known as she, originallyestablished by Buddhist monasteries, were set up to fund large one-time expenditures such as funeral or travel expenses. Non-religious organizations also were formed to service other sectors of society. Mutual financing associations, known as hui, allowed members to contribute a set amount to a common pot each month. A lottery system, often a simple shake of the dice, determined who could use a portion of the funds that month. Participants would usually use the money to purchase large and relatively expensive assets. A farmer could use the funds to buy a new cow, or a merchant could invest in a new riverboat. The hui were hyper-local, and participation was often driven by patrilineal duty. This tradition continues in China today, where it is not uncommon to find small villages pooling their resources to help a resident make a critical investment. While traditional Chinese society offered a wide variety of credit options to both wealthy merchants and peasants, by the early 20 th century, China's personal credit industry was in flux. With the rise of larger and more sophisticated banks in China during the 19 th century, most high-level lending began to flow through official banks. In 1929, the Chinese Communist Party banned usury on an individual level. When the People's Republic of China was founded in 1949, private lending institutions were banned nationwide. The only remaining options for personal credit were the remnants of the traditional hui and she lending networks. The market for private lending remained shut until the 1980s, when, following the start of Deng Xiaoping's Reform and Opening movement, banks began formal lending programs and modern credit systems began to develop. Since being introduced in 1985, the number of credit cards issued in China has grown at an astonishing rate, reaching 285 million in 2011, five times the number in 2006. Growth has remained consistently high and is expected to continue at 31% per year over the next five years, according to an RNCOS report on the industry. According to the 2012 Chinese Credit Card Industry Bluebook, US$1.2 trillion of purchases were made with credit cards in China in 2011, a year-on-year increase of 48%. This figure represented almost 40% of all purchases of consumer goods. In 2000, the corresponding proportion was less than 10%. MasterCard projects that annual credit card spending in China will more than double by 2025, and over the next decade, the country is expected to become the largest credit card market in the world by number of issued cards, overtaking the United States. Although the figure is high, it is worth noting that in China, credit cards are still used mostly for large-ticket items, while cash is still the predominant payment method for smaller purchases. Indeed, one study on credit card holders in Shanghai showed that 80% of purchases below 100 RMB (US$16) are still made with cash. Despite these optimistic growth projections, China's cash-centric consumer culture and traditional beliefs about personal finance have meant that consumers are resistant to change, thus slowing the adoption of electronic payment methods. Many of these cultural beliefs stem from Confucian values, which see borrowing as shameful because it means living beyond one's means, and which state that a good person always saves for the future. Indeed, studies have shown that the majority of Chinese consumers remain uncomfortable about borrowing for daily consumption. However, recent studies, including one by Fudan and Monash Universities, have also shown that these traditional value systems are changing, and that Western consumptiondriven lifestyles are finding their way into China, especially among the youth. This is demonstrated by the materialization of a new class of yue guang zu, those "with no savings at the end of the month." This group includes young urban students and professionals under 35, largely in first and second tier cities, who have begun to abandon some of the cultural taboos surrounding borrowing money in order to fund their modern, highly consumerist lifestyles, in some cases spending well beyond their means. Many of these changes in the cultural attitude toward credit have been driven by aggressive marketing by banks issuing credit cards, which offer rewards, discounts and lucky drawings to encourage spending. A number of banks now make it very easy to obtain a card, even for young consumers with no income. Some bank customers have even reported receiving in the mail high-limit credit cards for which they never applied. While most young people remain responsible for fear of losing control of their finances, a small but growing group of ka nu, or "card slaves," has emerged. These ka nu usually begin using credit cards for convenience and security or because of the special offers, but end up losing control over their spending, usually to meet a social expectation or to maintain "face" among friends and co-workers. The needs of the family have always come before those of the individual in traditional Chinese culture. This, in combination with demographics, has exacerbated the trend toward increased reliance on credit. China's rapidly aging population and the government's one-child policy have created a "sandwich generation": those married with a young child and aging parents who have significant financial responsibilities that lead to higher credit card use. A Jiao Tong University study also examined attitude factors that drive credit card use, concluding that "social power," the desire to display material wealth, played a significant role in the willingness to take on debt. These findings point to the adoption of Western consumer-centric attitudes and the shedding of traditional reluctance to take on debt among young, urban Chinese. Paying off Debt "I have access to credit, but would only use it as a last resort," said Zhou Lin, a young entrepreneur based in Beijing. In 2007, Zhou opened her first boutique in Beijing's Haidian District, selling Korean and Japanese apparel to fashion-conscious university students. Since then, she has opened new stores and expanded beyond brick-and-mortar to new sales channels, including a robust e-commerce platform. With a keen aesthetic sense and an ability to hone in on China's ever-changing fashion trends, she is part of a wave of young Chinese entrepreneurs with their fingers on the pulse of China's consumer demand. Zhou readily admitted that she had more than one credit card. "I applied for them because of the benefits they provide. This one gives me deals when I travel abroad. The bank that offers this card organizes shopping events in Beijing, and if you use your card, you can get deals." Almost all of Zhou's friends had cards as well. She noted that having a credit card in the early 2000s was a status symbol. If you had one, it meant that you or your family had money. In recent years, however, the plastic cards have become commonplace and no longer bestow an air of privilege upon their holders. "I'll carry them when I travel outside of China for business," Zhou added. "If something goes wrong and I have to stay for an extra few days to meet with suppliers, I know my credit will cover me." Despite having multiple credit cards, Zhou rarely, if ever, used them in China. When shopping in Beijing, for example, whether for personal purchases or for business, her cards rarely left her purse. She attributed this behavior to her experiences with credit when she was 19. When she left Shanghai to attend a university in Beijing, Zhou's father issued a duplicate of his credit card under her name, for use in an emergency. While a common practice in the West, Zhou's situation was quite rare in China at the time. She was the only one among her college friends with a credit card. One day, after a prolonged argument with her father over the phone, Zhou decided to take revenge and used the card to go on a spending spree. She recalled that when her father received the bill, he was outraged and devastated. He spent the next few months paying off her debt. This taught Zhou an important lesson: Credit is dangerous and its use has serious implications -- a belief consistent with traditional Chinese values. Despite rapid economic growth, the Chinese government has recently been attempting to spur consumer spending, which has remained stubbornly low as a proportion of GDP. Before the global financial crisis, the cliché was, "Chinese save, Americans consume," with the average saving rate in most Chinese households running at over 40% of annual income. However, as consumption plummeted in Western countries in the wake of the financial crisis, the Chinese government realized the importance of encouraging domestic spending as a way to compensate for diminished demand for its exports, and it has attempted to change the savings culture. In the U.S., the credit card industry helped give rise to the middle class and the culture of consumerism. The Chinese government has begun deregulating the industry in an attempt to achieve the same result. One significant concern is whether regulatory oversight of Chinese banks is sufficient to prevent a consumer-credit bubble. Asia as a region has seen a number of such events over the last 15 years, and Hong Kong, Taiwan and South Korea have all experienced a credit card crisis driven by excessive household spending, which severely threatened the stability of domestic banks. Regulators are encouraging Chinese banks to improve their risk management, debt collection and new-product development,and industry insiders have called for the loosening of consumer credit to be backed by a sound risk-management infrastructure, transparency and a continued focus on solid criteria for lending. Even so, important questions remain as to whether Chinese consumers, with very little prior exposure to credit, can safely handle large-scale growth in credit availability. As China continues to evolve culturally and its financial institutions continue to mature, growth in the availability of consumer credit is only natural. Will a sophisticated ecosystem around personal credit, including the regulatory system and a cultural familiarity with and acceptance of credit, develop as it has in Western societies? Will the typical Chinese credit card customer look more like Liu Jing, on a slippery slope to insolvency, or like Zhou Lin, whose early credit-related mishaps fostered a mature respect for the benefits and risks of credit? The impact of consumer credit will have farreaching implications for the overall direction of Chinese economic development. This article was written by William Hart, Thomas Kidd, Lane Rettig and Nicholas Walker, members of the Lauder Class of 2014. This is a single/personal use copy of Knowledge@Wharton. For multiple copies, custom reprints, e-prints, posters or plaques, please contact PARS International: reprints@parsintl.com P. (212) 221-9595 x407. Indonesia Impedes Card Collectors By ERIC BELLMAN JAKARTA, Indonesia—Until about four years ago, Rusmani, an administrative assistant for a Jakarta electronics company, didn't even know what a credit card was. Today she has 13. The 28-year-old Ms. Rusmani—like many Indonesians she goes by only one name— earns less than $1,000 a month. She got her first card in 2010 from PT Bank Central Asia because the salesman offered her a free appointment book and told her that the card gets her free drinks at her favorite coffee shop, Starbucks SBUX +1.67%. Since then, she has been regularly contacted by all of the 20 banks that offer cards in Indonesia. They call her on the phone, they come to her office and even show up at her home, she says, once with a birthday gift. Her card collection is so big now that she has to carry two wallets. "Maybe the banks think I'm rich," said Ms. Rusmani, as she pulled out her latest card— still unsigned and unused—from the envelope it was delivered in. Credit cards are just taking off in Southeast Asia's largest economy, and the high interest rates banks can charge make the business particularly profitable. The number of credit cards in Indonesia has jumped 60% in the past five years to around 15 million last year, compared with a population of close to 250 million. The value of transactions through cards has almost tripled to around $21 billion. Jason Schneider The intense competition for millions of potential customers, though, is creating a new class of card holder—one who carries 10 or more cards just for the freebies and discounts they promise. Ms. Rusmani says that her PT Bank Negara Indonesia card gets her 50% off at Pizza Marzano, her HSBC Holdings HSBA.LN +0.46% PLC card gives her free movie tickets, her Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Ltd. ANZ.AU -H,80% card grants her a 10% discount on gasoline and her PT Bank Permata BNLIJK +0.65% card provides 15% off her grocery bill as well as some flights. By spending around $100 a month on her different cards, she estimates that she gets close to $40 in discounts. The plastic perks have been so successful at boosting business that the central bank slapped new restrictions on cards this year, concerned the marketing blitz could trigger a debt bubble. The restrictions will force millions of people to give up some cards, according to industry estimates. They also could derail the plans of card companies like Visa Inc. V +0.65% and MasterCard Inc. MA+1.28% and big global banks like Citigroup Inc., C +0.91% HSBC and Standard Chartered STAN.LN +3.20% PLC, which were targeting Indonesia as one of the last great untapped markets for them. Banks say that while they usually lose money on the discounts, they can make up those losses many times over if the card holder starts regularly using the card, paying more than 35% a year in interest on their balances. Steep discounts to encourage consumption on credit happen in other markets as well, including China and Brazil. Card issuers say they spend more on these kinds of promotions in emerging markets to be known to consumers as card use takes off. Indonesia still has a credit-card penetration rate of less than 15%, compared to more than 25% for Malaysia and Singapore, said Heri Gunardi, executive vice president and coordinator of consumer finance at PT Bank Mandiri, Indonesia's largest card issuer. "Our population is very big but [card] penetration is still low," said Santoso, senior general manager and head of consumer cards at Bank Central Asia, one of Indonesia's largest card issuers. "And the margins are still very high, which is why we can afford these promotions." But the archipelago's central bank, Bank Indonesia, is worried. The authorities are concerned that inexperienced banks and borrowers could trigger a credit-card debt bubble like the one seen in South Korea in 2003, when the government's crackdown on credit cards resulted in a decline in consumer spending. While Indonesia's nonperforming loan rate from credit-card debt has actually fallen in the past four years to around 3.5% last year from around 9% in 2009, the central bank says it doesn't want to take any chances. "Although our stress tests didn't show any bubble, we don't want a credit-card crisis," said Boedi Armanto, Bank Indonesia's head of accounting and payment system department. He said some banks at times offer cards to customers without finding out how much the people earn, which could lead to problems. Starting this year, cards can only be issued to people who are older than 18 and earn more than $300 a month. The combined credit limit isn’t allowed to go beyond three times the card holder’s monthly salary. Meanwhile, anyone making less than $1,000 a month will only be allowed to hold two cards. Because of the new rules, as many as four million cards will have to be canceled this year, said Steve Marta, general manager of the Indonesia Credit Card Association. As millions of multiple card holders this year decide which two cards to keep, the perks and discounts may only get more generous. "It will be more competitive now because banks are pursuing the same group of people trying to hold on to their customers," Mr. Marta said. Ms. Rusmani says she doesn't mind thinning out her deck of cards as long as she can keep the two that give her the biggest discounts. "If I don't get a discount then there is no reason to use a card," she said. — Andreas Ismar contributed to this article, Page 1 of 2 Needless to say home ownership is a key component of consumer credit. Here is a recent listing of Home ownership by country Rank Countries Amount #1 Ireland:83% #2 Italy:78% =3 United Kingdom:69% =3 Australia:69% =5 Finland:67% =5 Canada:67% =7 United States:65% =7 Belgium:65% =9 Sweden:60% =9 Japan:60% # 11 France:54% # 12 Denmark:53% # 13 Netherlands:49% # 14 Germany:43% Weighted average: 63.0% Another crucial factor is vehicle ownership. List of countries by vehicles per capita From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia Jump to: navigation, search Map of vehicles per capita 2011 This article is a list of countries by the number of motor vehicles per 1,000 people. All figures include automobiles, SUVs, vans, and commercial vehicles; and exclude motorcycles and other motorized two-wheelers. Rank This article is a list of countries by the number of road motor vehicles per 1000 inhabitants. Please consider that car is different from road motor vehicle as the latter includes automobiles, SUVs, trucks, vans, buses, commercial vehicles and freight motor road vehicles. The present list excludes motorcycles and other two-wheelers. Rank Country Motor vehicles per 1000 people Notes 1 San Marino 1,263 2010[1] 2 899 Monaco 2008[1] 3 797 United States 2010[1] 4 750 Liechtenstein 2010[1] 5 745 Iceland 2010[1] 6 739 Luxembourg 2010[1] 7 717 Australia 2013[2] 8 712 New Zealand 2010[1] 9 693 Malta 2010[1] 10 679 Italy 2010[1] 11 677 Guam 2004[3] 12 Puerto Rico 635 2010[1] 13 624 Greece 2010[1] 14 612 Finland 2010[1] 15 607 Canada 2009[1] 16 593 Spain 2010[1] 17 591 Japan 2010[1] 18 584 Norway 2010[1] 19 578 Austria 2010[1] 19 578 France 2012[4] 21 572 Germany 2010[1] 22 23 566 Switzerland 2010[1] 24 560 Lithuania 2010[1] 25 559 Belgium 2010[1] 26 548 Portugal 2010[5] 27 537 Poland 2010[1] 27 Bahrain 537 2009[1] 29 532 Qatar 2007[1] 29 532 Cyprus 2010[1] 31 528 Netherlands 2010[1] 32 527 Kuwait 2010[1] 33 520 Sweden 2010[1] 34 519 United Kingdom 2010[1] 35 513 Ireland 2009[1] 36 510 Brunei 2008[1] 37 485 Czech Republic 2010[1] 38 480 Denmark 2010[1] 39 476 Estonia 2010[1] 40 469 Barbados 2007[1] 41 434 Lebanon [6] 42 393 Bulgaria 2010[1] 43 Croatia 380 2010[1] 44 379 South Korea 2013[7] 45 364 Slovakia 2010[1] 46 362 Belarus 2010[1] 47 361 Malaysia 2010[1] 48 353 Trinidad and Tobago 2007[1] 49 346 Israel 2012[8] 50 345 Hungary 2010[1] 51 336 Saudi Arabia [6] 52 324 Taiwan 2013[9] 53 319 Latvia 2010[1] 54 314 Argentina 2007[1] 55 313 United Arab Emirates 2007[1] 56 309 Montenegro 2011[10] 57 293 Russia 2010[11] 58 Suriname 291 2010[1] 59 290 Libya 2007[1] 60 275 Mexico 2010[1] 61 249 Brazil 2011[12] 62 238 Serbia 2010[1] 63 235 Romania 2010[1] 64 230 Antigua and Barbuda 2009[1] 65 223 Saint Kitts and Nevis [6] 66 219 Kazakhstan 2010[1] 67 215 Oman 2007[1] 68 214 Bosnia and Herzegovina 2010[1] 69 206 Thailand 2012[13][14] 70 204 Saint Vincent and the Grenadines 2008[1] 71 200 Turkey 2012[15][16] 71 200 Uruguay 2009[1] 72 Iran 200 2012[17] 73 188 Jamaica 2010[1] 74 184 Chile 2010[1] 75 179 Fiji 2010[1] 76 177 Costa Rica 2010[1] 77 176 Seychelles 2010[1] 78 175 Mauritius 2010[1] 79 174 Belize 2007[1] 79 174 Tonga [6] 81 173 Ukraine 2010[1] 82 166 Saint Lucia [6] 83 165 Jordan 2010[1] 84 165 South Africa 2010[1] 85 163 Dominica [6] 86 159 Nauru 2004[18] 87 Moldova 156 2010[1] 88 155 Georgia 2010[1] 89 155 Republic of Macedonia 2009[1] 90 149 Singapore 2010[1] 92 147 Venezuela 2007[1] 93 146 Kiribati 2008[1] 95 133 Botswana 2009[1] 96 132 Panama 2010[1] 97 128 Dominican Republic 2009[1] 98 125 Tunisia 2010[1] 99 124 Albania 2010[1] 100 122 Grenada [19] 101 114 Zimbabwe 2007[1] 102 114 Algeria 2010[1] 103 107 Namibia 2010[1] 104 Turkmenistan 106 2008[1] 105 105 China 2013[20] 106 103 Armenia 2007[1] 107 101 Azerbaijan 2010[1] 108 101 Cape Verde 2007[1] 109 95 Honduras 2008[1] 110 95 Guyana 2008[1] 111 94 El Salvador 2007[1] 112 89 Swaziland 2007[1] 113 81 Bahamas 2007[1] 114 77 Hong Kong 2010[1] 115 77 Samoa 2007[1] 116 76 Sri Lanka 2012[21] 117 73 Peru 2010[1] 118 73 Syria 2010[1] 119 Mongolia 72 2008[1] 120 71 Colombia 2009[1] 121 71 Ecuador 2010[1] 122 70 Morocco 2007[1] 123 68 Bolivia 2007[1] 124 68 Guatemala 2010[1] 125 60 Indonesia 2008[1] 126 59 Kyrgyzstan 2007[1] 127 57 Bhutan 2009[1] 127 57 Pakistan 2010[1] 128 57 Nicaragua 2010[1] 129 54 Paraguay 2009[1] 130 54 Vanuatu [6] 131 50 Iraq [6] 132 45 Egypt 2009[1] 133 Palestine 42 2010[1] 134 41 India 2011[22] 134 38 Angola 2007[1] 135 38 Cuba 2008[1] 136 38 Tajikistan 2007[1] 137 37 Uzbekistan 2004[23] 138 37 Micronesia, Federated States of 2007[1] 139 35 Yemen 2007[1] 140 33 Comoros 2007[1] 141 33 Guinea-Bissau 2008[1] 142 31 Nigeria 2007[1] 143 30 Philippines 2010[1] 144 30 Ghana 2009[1] 145 28 Maldives 2010[1] 146 28 Djibouti [6] 147 Afghanistan 28 2010[1] 148 27 Congo, Republic of the 2007[1] 149 27 Sudan 2007[1] 150 26 Madagascar 2009[1] 151 24 Kenya 2010[1] 152 23 Vietnam 2013 [24] 153 22 Benin 2007[1] 154 22 Senegal 2008[1] 154 21 Cambodia 2005[1] 154 21 Zambia 2008[1] 155 20 Laos 2007[1] 155 20 Cote d'Ivoire 2007[1] 155 20 Slovenia 2011[25] 156 14 Cameroon 2007[1] 156 14 Gabon 2004[26] 156 Mali 14 2009[1] 157 13 Equatorial Guinea 2004[27] 157 13 Papua New Guinea [6] 158 12 Haiti [6] 158 12 Mozambique 2009[1] 158 12 Burkina Faso 2010[1] 159 11 Eritrea 2007[1] 159 11 North Korea 2006[28] 160 8 Malawi 2007[1] 160 8 Uganda 2009[1] 161 7 Myanmar 2010[1] 161 7 Tanzania 2007[1] 161 7 Gambia 2004[1] 161 7 Niger 2009[1] 162 6 Burundi 2007[1] 162 Sierra Leone 6 2008[1] 162 6 Chad 2006[1] 163 5 Congo, Democratic Republic of the 2007[1] 163 5 Guinea [6] 163 5 Mauritania [6] 163 5 Nepal 2007[1] 164 4 Central African Republic [6] 164 4 Lesotho 2004[29] 165 3 Ethiopia 2007[1] 165 3 Somalia [6] 165 3 Liberia 2007[1] 165 3 Bangladesh 2010[1] 165 3 Solomon Islands 2004[30] 166 2 São Tomé and Príncipe 2007[1] 166 2 Togo 2007[1] Excerpts from: Why The Worst Is Yet To Come For Indonesia's Epic Bubble Economy Record low interest rates have fueled an epic credit and consumption boom in Indonesia, which is no small matter given the fact that domestic consumer spending accounts for nearly 60 percent of the country’s overall $878 billion economy. For the past half-decade, Indonesia’s annual GDP growth rate has averaged about 6 percent – the fastest in Southeast Asia – thanks largely to their consumer spending boom. According to Moody’s, Indonesia’s compound credit loan growth rate has been over 22% for the past six years, while non-mortgage consumer credit nearly tripled in the last five years. During this time, credit card use has greatly proliferated, with the number of credit cards jumping by 60 percent, while the actual value of transactions almost tripled. Fears of a consumer debt crisis forced Bank Indonesia to limit the number of credit cards a single person is allowed to hold, while barring Indonesians who earn less than $330 (USD) a month from being issued credit cards. With such rapid consumer credit growth, it’s unsurprising to see a concomitant rise in consumer spending: Automobile registrations have more than tripled since 2004: International automakers including Nissan, Toyota and General Motors have taken notice of Indonesia’s automobile boom, and committed up to $2 billion to expand their manufacturing operations in the country in the next few years. Cheap financing has also been fueling a surge in motorbike sales, an indicator of domestic consumption, which grew 13.9 percent in August from a year earlier, after growing 21.3 percent in July. Retail sales that have been growing at an annual rate of 10 to 15 percent in recent years have attracted numerous Western consumer brands like L’Oreal, Unilever and Nestle that are seeking to cash in on Indonesia’s spending boom. Indonesia Also Has A Property Bubble Cheap credit and property bubbles go hand in hand, and Indonesia’s bubble economy is no exception. Though data for all Indonesian property markets are scarce, property markets in Jakarta and Bali are becoming frothy, especially at the higher end of the market. Jakarta condominium prices rose between 11 and 17 percent on average between the first half of 2012 and 2013, after rising by more than 50 percent since late 2008. Luxury real estate prices in Jakarta soared by 38 percent in 2012, while luxury properties in Bali rose by 20 percent – the strongest price increases of all global luxury housing markets. A small two-room apartment on the outskirts of Jakarta can cost nearly $80,000 USD (RM253,373), making housing unaffordable for many ordinary Indonesians. The surge in real estate activity spurred a 70 percent rally in Indonesian property shares in the first five months of 2013 (though they have sold off since then). Even Indonesia’s central bank has become worried about a property and credit bubble, causing them to issue new rules to curb speculation, including mandating a minimum 40 percent down payment for the purchase of a second house or apartment (bigger than 70 m²). Bank Indonesia has plenty to worry about when it comes to a mortgage bubble: from June 2012 to May 2013, outstanding loans for apartment purchases nearly doubled from IDR 6.56 trillion (USD $659.3 million) to IDR 11.42 trillion (USD $1.15 billion). In July, the Bali branch of Bank Indonesia gave a warning that it was “on alert” for a possible bursting of the island’s property bubble. Indonesian property boom apologists cite soaring incomes and economic growth as a justification for the rise of property prices, but the problem with their logic is that the country’s economic growth itself is being buoyed by a credit-driven bubble. -------------------------------------------------------------------------------This article is available online at: http://www.forbes.com/sites/jessecolombo/2013/10/03/why-the-worst-is-yet-to-come-forindonesias-epic-bubble-economy Banks From Around the World Target Middle Class With Financing for Autos, Home Kathy Chu Updated April 22, 2013 7:53 a.m. ET HONG KONG—Lenders from around the world are fueling a boom in short-term loans across Asia, helping push debt to record levels as a burgeoning middle class strives for a better lifestyle and banks look to diversify away from the slow-growing West. As China's middle class grows, so does their debt. Shaun Rein from China Market Research talks about what Chinese consumers are buying with the 320 million credit cards currently in circulation in China. Nonmortgage consumer credit in Asia outside of Japan rose 67% in the past five years to $1.66 trillion by the end of 2012, according to data provider Euromonitor International. In the U.S. the rise was only 10% during the same period as consumers cut back on debt following the financial crisis. The lenders are targeting Asia's middle class, which is expected to grow by an average of more than 100 million people each year. They are pitching everything from credit cards to short-term installment loans for motorcycles and appliances. Interest rates can range from 15% for secured auto loans to as much as 40% for unsecured loans, appliances and electronics, driven by high demand for loans and little or no credit history for the borrowers. Loans are typically paid back over six months to five years. For lenders suffering from a glut of deposits, low interest rates and weak economies in the West, Asia is crucial for their growth. By 2020, more than half of the world's middle class is expected to reside in Asia, compared with one-fourth in 2009, estimates Brookings Institution economist Homi Kharas. Rising borrowing is expected in economies at this stage of development, and many of the companies have experience lending in markets such as these. Enlarge Image Close But some people are concerned about the growth. "The worry that's developing is that debt is being pushed onto borrowers who might not have the capacity to repay," says Frederic Neumann, co-head of Asian economic research for HSBC Holdings HSBA.LN 1.03% HSBC Holdings PLC (UK Reg) U.K.: London GBp606.20 -6.30 -1.03% April 7, 2014 5:08 pm Volume : 18.91M P/E Ratio 10.98 Market Cap GBp115.66 Billion Dividend Yield 8.23% Rev. per Employee GBp247,733 04/07/14 Barron's: HSBC Highlights Tape... 04/04/14 Consolidation Wave Likely for ... 04/03/14 Soft Yen Helps Tokyo Shares More quote details and news » PLC. In Jakarta, Wiwik Sugiarti lined up at a department store with half a dozen others in February to arrange financing for a $400 LG Electronics 066570.SE +2.84% LG Electronics Inc. S. Korea: KRX KRW68800 +1900 +2.84% April 7, 2014 3:00 pm Volume : 1.68M P/E Ratio 70.42 Market Cap KRW10948.04 Billion Dividend Yield 0.29% Rev. per Employee N/A 04/04/14 Apple, Android Continue to Lea... 03/25/14 LG Offers Fresh Peek at Its Ne... 03/21/14 What WSJ Canada Is Reading Fri... More quote details and news » ' television set, months after buying a refrigerator and DVD player on credit. "It eases my monthly budget," says Ms. Sugiarti, 37 years old, the owner of a small grocery shop. "I can buy two or three things at the same time and not have to worry about how to pay for it now." In China, Citigroup Inc., which became the first Western bank to issue its own credit cards there last year, is seeing one of its fastest growth rates in credit-card accounts in the world, a bank spokesman said. The bank wouldn't disclose details on that growth. France's Crédit Agricole SA ACA.FR -2.00% Credit Agricole S.A. France: Paris €11.73 0.24 -2.00% April 7, 2014 5:39 pm Volume : 4.55M P/E Ratio N/A Market Cap €29.96 Billion Dividend Yield N/A Rev. per Employee €650,889 03/28/14 France's Ceva Spearheads Riski... 03/27/14 Banks Lead U.K. Shares Lower 03/25/14 Yuan Swings Between Gains and ... More quote details and news » plans to expand its auto loans in the country by more than one-third this year to roughly 54,000 through a joint venture with local partner Guangzhou Automobile Group Co. 2238.HK +0.36% Guangzhou Automobile Group Co. Ltd. Hong Kong $8.34 +0.03 +0.36% April 7, 2014 4:01 pm Volume : 8.20M P/E Ratio 16.52 Market Cap $57.87 Billion Dividend Yield 1.82% Rev. per Employee $599,351 More quote details and news » Amsterdam-based PPF Group NV's Home Credit, which lends in places such as Belarus and Slovakia, said it is approving about 5,000 loans daily in China for mobile phones, appliances and motorcycles, more than double the number in 2011. In Indonesia, where nonmortgage consumer credit nearly tripled in the last five years, domestic lenders Astra International ASII.JK +2.56% Astra International Indonesia: Jakarta IDR8000 +200 +2.56% April 7, 2014 4:14 pm Volume : 78.39M P/E Ratio 16.70 Market Cap IDR315771.71 Billion Dividend Yield 1.60% Rev. per Employee IDR1,462,470,000 More quote details and news » and PT Bank Danamon's Adira Finance are expanding, despite tighter lending standards, while Japanese lender Mizuho Financial Group 8411.TO -2.38% Mizuho Financial Group Inc. Japan: Tokyo ¥205 -5 - 2.38% April 7, 2014 3:00 pm Volume : 78.14M P/E Ratio 6.81 Market Cap ¥5091.70 Billion Dividend Yield 3.41% Rev. per Employee ¥50,165,400 03/27/14 Japanese Banks Name First Wome... 02/26/14 New Fed Rules Could Impact 17 ... 02/03/14 Asian Banks Push Into New Mark... More quote details and news » has purchased an Indonesian autofinance firm to get a foothold in the country's fast-growing consumer-finance market. More • Blackstone's Schwarzman Backs China Scholarship Even in India, where defaults on personal debt rose sharply during the global financial crisis, the number of credit cards outstanding ticked up 7% to 18.9 million last year, driven in part by Western players such as Citigroup and Standard Chartered STAN.LN 0.71% Standard Chartered PLC U.K.: London GBp1255.00 -9.00 -0.71% April 7, 2014 4:36 pm Volume : 4.77M P/E Ratio 0.12 Market Cap GBp30.72 Billion Dividend Yield 5.49% Rev. per Employee GBp188,767 04/07/14 Taiwan Exports Beat Expectatio... 04/01/14 Standard Chartered Names Hung ... 04/01/14 Hong Kong Family-Owned Banks T... More quote details and news » PLC. Lenders emphasized that they are being careful when they offer credit and said they were focusing on middle-class borrowers who could afford what they are buying. Citigroup is expanding credit-card, mortgage and other consumer lending in a "disciplined manner in several high-growth markets" in Asia including China, India, Taiwan and Australia, bank spokesman James Griffiths said. In the first quarter of 2013, Citigroup's consumer lending in Asia grew 1% year over year to $69.3 billion. Throughout Asia outside Japan, car and motorcycle loans nearly doubled from 2007 to 2012 to a record $219.7 billion. Appliance and electronics loans also more than doubled in the region to a high of $10.9 billion, Euromonitor data show. During this time, creditcard loans grew 90% to a record $234.1 billion, according to Euromonitor. Overall debt levels in many Asian economies are lower than in the West, but debt burdens relative to individual income are up to 30% higher compared with the U.S. in countries such as Malaysia, China, South Korea, Thailand, Indonesia and India, HSBC research shows. An added concern is that debt is a bigger burden for low-income people who have smaller financial cushions when times get tough. Asia has a tortured history with debt. Over the past decade or so, Taiwan, South Korea and Hong Kong have all grappled with credit-card meltdowns that destabilized their economies. Mindful of the risks, regulators in Asia are taking action. In the past year and a half, China, Malaysia and Indonesia have reined in mortgage, credit-card or motorcycle lending. Bank Indonesia Deputy Director Yunita Resmi Sari said the central bank imposed a minimum down payment for car and motorcycle loans last year to limit banks' credit risk and to ease consumers' debt burden. Consumer groups in Asia, which until recently were focused on issues such as high utility bills and rising food prices, are also becoming concerned about aggressive lending and debt collection. A leading Vietnamese provider of motorbike loans, Kuong Bank, advertises online a 1.91% monthly interest rate, equal to a more than 20% annual rate, but doesn't explain that borrowers pay interest on the full loan amount even as the balance is paid down, says Alice Pham, director of the Hanoi chapter of Consumer Unity & Trust Society, a research and advocacy group. Kuong Bank didn't respond to requests for comment. —Resty Woro Yuniar in Jakarta and Miho Inada in Tokyo contributed to this article. Write to Kathy Chu at kathy.chu@wsj.com EXECUTIVE SUMMARY TURKEY Consumer lending registers another year of strong growth The post-recession growth in consumer lending continued at an equally fast pace during 2013, as both outstanding balance and gross lending registered positive growth, though the outstanding balance growth was slower. Despite the decline in consumer optimism which has been growing since the end of the recession in 2012, consumers are still confident about the current and future outlook of the economy, and are willing to finance their spending with consumer loans. Despite government measures to reduce loanfinanced spending, declining APR also had a major influence on the growth in consumer lending. Government introduces new measures to strengthen consumer lending With the years of successive positive growth starting from the end of the recession, the government felt the need to introduce new measures to cut back consumer spending as well as to improve the health of the consumer lending category, which is essential to the functioning of the banking system. With major restructuring of the banking system following the recession of 2001, Turkish banks have become less vulnerable; yet, the growth in consumer lending and banks’ efforts to seize shares in this category have loosened their lending discipline. Starting in 2013, the government has introduced a series of measures including a centralised credit scoring system, helping banks to evaluate potential borrowers, thereby decreasing the risk of defaulting on consumer loans. Banks continue to dominate consumer lending in Turkey Consumer lending in Turkey is dominated by major private banks, such as Garanti Bankasi, Yapi ve Kredi Bankasi, as alternative lending institutions are almost nonexistent in major categories, except for auto lending. Only in auto lending, are there other lending institutions that have a significant share of loans extended. New lending institutions are expected to enter the mortgages category in 2013, and new players are expected to enter the category considering the growth potential in mortgages. Mortgages/housing category grows as property boom in major cities continues Despite being relatively new to the Turkish market, mortgages/housing grew strongly within consumer lending in 2013. Growing middle-class demand for new housing and the supply created by government agencies and private property developers also created a major market for mortgages/housing. Private banks compete with each other, while cooperating with developers to attract borrowers by offering accessible low-cost loans to consumers. The government’s major move for urban renewal is expected to result in even higher growth, with the government subsidising part of the interest charged for these loans. Consumer lending is expected to continue to see growth in all major categories Compared to the review period, consumer lending is expected to register strong growth over the forecast period. In terms of outstanding balance, growth will be even stronger due to increasing payment periods as a result of declining APR and growing confidence in the general outlook of the economy. Consumer Lending in Turkey - Industry Overview EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Consumer lending registers another year of strong growth Government introduces new measures to strengthen consumer lending Banks continue to dominate consumer lending in Turkey Mortgages/housing category grows as property boom in major cities continues Consumer lending is expected to continue to see growth in all major categories KEY TRENDS AND DEVELOPMENTS Urban renewal reform fuels further growth in mortgages/housing Positive growth continues across all consumer lending categories Government introduces new regulations to guarantee the health of the banking system Country Report Consumer Lending in Indonesia Mar 2014|Pages: 14 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 2013 another strong year amidst more restrictions Consumer lending in Indonesia boomed over the review period, driven by the rising number of middle-class households and continued economic growth. With Indonesian consumers growing more accustomed to the concept of borrowing money from the bank, more banks shifted their focus towards consumer lending. At the same time, the Indonesian government monitored the development of the country’s consumer lending industry and started to pass more legislation towards the end of the review period so as to prevent a credit bubble or overheating of the market. Some of these regulations were already in place over 2012/2013, including ‘Loan to Value’ legislation which regulates the minimum down payment amount for a loan application. This new legislation has been cited as the main reason behind slower gross lending growth in 2013 compared to 2012. Other legislation starting to be implemented is that with regard to the maximum number of credit cards which can be owned. Demand for apartments and small homes supports mortgages/housing growth Unlike in many other countries, mortgages/housing is not the main contributor to the consumer lending industry in Indonesia. Instead, auto lending – chiefly for motorcycles – was the most popular type of consumer lending over the review period. However, with urbanisation and the rising middle-classes, an increasing number of younger Indonesian families are purchasing their own homes instead of living with their extended family. This has led to strong growth in demand for small houses, and more recently in the cities for apartments among those with limited budgets. In turn, growth in mortgages/housing gross lending and outstanding balance has also been strong as more consumers turn to financial institutions to finance the purchase of their home. Local banks remain the top lenders to consumers in Indonesia As a still growing industry, the consumer lending environment in Indonesia still has relatively few players. The majority of loans to consumers over the review period derived from several key banks, many of which are government-owned, including Bank Rakyat Indonesia (BRI), Bank Negara Indonesia (BNI), Bank Tabungan Negara (BTN) and Bank Mandiri. The government-owned banks typically have a strong focus on mortgages/housing. In comparison, private local banks also offer more varied types of consumer credit, ranging from auto lending to multi-purpose loans (covered as part of other personal lending). These loan products cover smaller amounts than mortgages/housing and have shorter payment periods. More controlled consumer lending environment will keep growth in check To continue on from the several new regulations drawn up towards the end of the review period in an attempt to prevent the consumer lending industry from overheating, the Indonesian government is expected to implement further restrictions to regulate consumer lending over the forecast period. Amidst rising concerns about the growing proportion of non-performing loans among lower-income households in 2013, more regulations linked to income levels may be announced. All in all, the government’s efforts along with steadier demand are expected to result in less robust growth in gross lending and outstanding balance over the forecast period. Consumer Lending in Indonesia - Industry Overview EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 2013 another strong year amidst more restrictions Demand for apartments and small homes supports mortgages/housing growth Local banks remain the top lenders to consumers in Indonesia More controlled consumer lending environment will keep growth in check KEY TRENDS AND DEVELOPMENTS More legislation in place to prevent a credit bubble Mortgages/housing growth continues to soar More banks step up their loan offers to attract more consumers EXECUTIVE SUMMARY CANADA Rate of increase in consumer lending slows in 2013 Both mortgages/housing and consumer credit lending slowed in 2013, but remained firmly in positive territory. Lower margins for prime mortgage loans are guiding chartered banks to seek higher growth lending opportunities. Record low mortgage payments as a percentage of income are keeping consumers spending, but the days of double-digit gains in home equity are past. Consumer borrowing will become more dependent on gains in income rather than home-asset appreciation going forward. Low interest rates to prevail at least to end of 2013 The Bank of Canada is holding the line on interest rates, as a revised GDP forecast places growth lower than expected. Mortgage rates have hit record lows as chartered banks have looked to revive tepid mortgage lending in the face of slowing housing activity since the second half of 2012. Lower interest rates are also underpinning growth in non-card lending, particularly in auto lending. Lower margins on prime mortgages polarise lenders Margin compression on residential mortgages is forcing non-bank lenders out of the prime lending market. Growth in sub-prime mortgages and uninsured mortgages may cause regulators to scrutinise the lending practices of financial institutions for excessive risk going forward. Sub-prime lending is benefiting from favourable margins, and a larger pool of borrowers who have failed to qualify under the tightened mortgage regulations enacted since July 2012. Sub-prime lending is further bolstered by immigration-driven population growth and an increase in self-employed Canadians. Automobile loans drive non-card lending Following record auto lending growth in 2012, the pace of auto lending in 2013 has slowed but still represents one of the strongest opportunities among non-card lending categories. Auto lending durations are getting longer, and this is allowing consumers to purchase the vehicles they desire at record low monthly payments. Automakers are ramping up their new product introductions to capitalise on pent-up demand for new cars following years of recession-mediated purchase deferrals. A balanced real estate market bodes well for consumer credit The 2013 real estate market is returning to more sustainable levels in terms of both volume and value, which suggests moderate growth in both mortgages/housing and noncard lending going forward. If regulatory tightening of mortgage rules alone fails to cool housing activity in the longer term, look for modest increases in interest rates once the Canadian economy returns to GDP growth targets. Consumer Lending in Canada - Industry Overview EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Rate of increase in consumer lending slows in 2013 Low interest rates to prevail at least to end of 2013 Lower margins on prime mortgages polarise lenders Automobile loans drive non-card lending A balanced real estate market bodes well for consumer credit KEY TRENDS AND DEVELOPMENTS Tighter mortgage regulations cool the Canadian housing market Continuation of low interest rates a key support for residential lending Consumer debt continues to rise as a percentage of disposable income Consumer Lending in Germany Jan 2014| EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 2013 consumer lending primarily for home building, renovation and durables The German economy slightly cooled down in 2013, but consumer sentiment remained strong. Low unemployment, especially among young and middle-aged people, helped underpin many people’s readiness to take out new loans. Loans are primarily taken out for lasting assets such as home renovation, durables and home building. However, some German families also take out loans to cope with the rising cost of living, seeking to bridge monetary shortages via consumer credit. Consumers turn their back on overdrafts following negative media reports Overdrafts represented a key credit vehicle in Germany up to 2013, as nearly all consumers own a current account, but credit cards have only a very limited presence. In the past, most Germans had tolerated double-digit interest rates that most banks charge on overdrafts, because overdrafts do not require any paperwork. However, criticism by several consumer protection agencies, which featured across all major media in 2012 and 2013, has made consumers more aware of the losses incurred when using the overdraft option. More consumers thus avoided the use of overdrafts in the first place by taking out alternative types of loans. Home and education lending see strongest performance in 2013 Home and education lending have seen the strongest performance in 2013. In terms of home lending, strong performance is a result of the need for refurbishment in many German post-war buildings. In terms of education lending, rapid growth is a result of tightened curricula that leave students no time to have a job outside their studies. Both home and education lending are driven by public subsidies that are managed by the public body Kreditanstalt für Wiederaufbau (KfW). Growth of direct banks continues in 2013, but loses some momentum Direct banks such as Ing-DiBa, Comdirect Bank, 1822direct and Netbank gained share in consumer lending during the review period due to their offering flexible lending conditions and attractive rates of interest. The speed of growth of these banks has somewhat slowed towards the end of the review period, when compared to the first decade of the millennium, but has not stopped. Consequently, the two principal banking associations Deutscher Sparkassen- und Giroverband eV (DSGV) and Bundesverband der Deutschen Volksbanken und Raiffeisenbanken eV (BVR) lost ground in consumer credit, as well as the three major commercial banks Deutsche Bank, Commerzbank and HypoVereinsbank. Steady outlook for consumer lending in Germany over 2013-2018 Consumer lending is expected to remain quite stable in terms of outstanding balance, gross lending and non-performing loans over the forecast period. This is likely due to the tight lending criteria of German banks designed to prevent any type of credit bubble in the private lending sector. The high competitiveness of the German economy within the Eurozone and low unemployment will contribute to the stability of the consumer lending business. Home lending is expected to see the fastest growth in absolute terms, as Germans are keen to cocoon in times of global turmoil. Consumer Lending in Germany - Industry Overview EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 2013 consumer lending primarily for home building, renovation and durables Consumers turn their back on overdrafts following negative media reports Home and education lending see strongest performance in 2013 Growth of direct banks continues in 2013, but loses some momentum Steady outlook for consumer lending in Germany over 2013-2018 KEY TRENDS AND DEVELOPMENTS Repayment cycles become shorter due to low interest rates Confidence in real estate drives mortgages and home lending growth More consumers seek cheaper alternatives to overdrafts Country Report Consumer Lending in China Jan 2014 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Consumer lending slows further but remains robust Consumer lending slows further in line with a decelerating local economy and uncertain global outlook. However, overall consumer lending retained its robust double-digit growth pace in 2013, supported by the strong market demand for mortgages/housing and card lending. On the other hand, other consumer lending categories, such as auto lending and home lending, continue to register a strong growth momentum, boosted by consumers’ growing acceptance of credit consumption and the rising pursuit of personal wellbeing. Mortgages/housing remains dominant in the market Mortgages/housing has taken the lion’s share of total consumer lending in China over the review period, owing to the explosive development of the housing market. To curb speculation and prevent the bubble bursting, relevant authorities have introduced a series of measures, including increased down payments and housing loan rates to buyers of second homes and no loan at all to buyers of third properties. As a result, mortgages/housing has experienced decelerating value growth over the review period, but still remains dominant in total consumer lending in 2013, thanks to the strong market demand from newly-weds and ongoing urbanisation. Non-banking institutions are strong in innovative new launches Apart from banks, other non-banking institutions are also active in launching innovative consumer credit products. Alibaba Financial Co Ltd trial launched credit payment service to AliPay users who make online purchases on the online shopping platforms under Alibaba Group via their mobile phones and tablets. The automatically-granted consumer credit to AliPay users, ranging from RMB200 to RMB5,000, based on their age, job and online transaction records, makes it easier for mobile transactions, a move that is likely to be followed by other third party payment service providers in China over the forecast period. Supporting rules and regulations to promote consumer lending The State Council’s green light to the reduced card transaction fee since February 2013, proposed by People’s Bank of China, has resulted in a positive impact on card lending, which experienced the most robust value growth in outstanding balance in the same year, in addition to its relatively small consumer base as compared to non-card lending. On the other hand, Chinese consumers are more open to consumer credit, in line with their rising product awareness and increasing personal wealth. Consumer lending to maintain steady forecast growth Consumer lending is expected to maintain steady forecast value CAGRs in both outstanding balance and gross lending over the forecast period, to be underpinned by the steady market demand for consumer credit, particularly card lending. Dominant mortgages/housing is expected to record a declining percentage of total consumer lending value sales over the forecast period, following strict control of the housing market to prevent further bubbles. What’s the state of credit quality in the market? Has the economic downturn reset the lender competitive landscape? Consumer Lending in China - Industry Overview EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Consumer lending slows further but remains robust Mortgages/housing remains dominant in the market Non-banking institutions are strong in innovative new launches Supporting rules and regulations to promote consumer lending Consumer lending to maintain steady forecast growth KEY TRENDS AND DEVELOPMENTS Mortgages/housing represents a rising share of total consumer lending Card lending remains robust Cardless and contactless consumer credit emerges Country Report Consumer Lending in India Jan 2014 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Consumer lending grows at a high rate in 2013 despite tight economic conditions Consumer lending grew at a higher rate in 2013 than in 2012 and in 2011. This was despite negative economic sentiment in terms of low growth, high inflation and high interest rates. The high growth was partly due to smart positioning of products by banks, such as pushing credit cards, housing loans and auto loans to self-employed individuals and partly it was because the impact of recession was less on individuals compared to the corporate segment. Not only growth was higher in 2013, but bad assets were also on the lower side than in previous years. Sentiment remained negative in Indian economy in 2013 The overall sentiment remained negative in the Indian economy through 2013. The growth in gross domestic product was a fraction of its peak level in 2007. Inflation continued to remain high in certain pockets, as the price of vegetables soared. The Indian rupee depreciated significantly throughout the year. Reserve Bank of India – the apex body – did not find conditions conducive to cutting key rates. In the absence of rate cuts, banks were not in a position to cut lending rates, which was considered important to boost credit growth. The only silver lining was that the retail side of lending performed better than the corporate side, giving breathing space to all financial institutions Scheduled commercial banks continue to lead consumer lending in 2013 Banks such as State Bank of India, Punjab National Bank, ICICI Bank Ltd, HDFC Bank Ltd, Bank of India, Bank of Baroda and Axis Bank Ltd continued to dominate consumer lending in 2013. These entities fall under scheduled commercial banks (SCBs). The reason that these entities dominated was their decades-long experience in the Indian market, huge capital bases and wide branch networks. Apart from banks, several nonbanking financial companies (NBFCs) were also a part of consumer lending. Such entities were smaller in scale than banks because they could not raise money through savings and current deposits. NBFCs had to raise money from money markets and, therefore, they operate on a much smaller scale than banks. Apart from NBFCs, several microfinance institutions (MFIs) also operated in this business. SCBs, NBFCs and MFIs continued to attempt to reduce the share of informal money lenders in 2013. Card lending witnesses fastest growth in 2013 Credit card outstanding balance witnessed the fastest growth in 2013. This was because retail banking consumers continued to report significant growth in disposable incomes. Based on this, banks felt assured of their creditworthiness and focused more on credit cards in 2012 and 2013. Banks realised that the slowdown affected the corporate segment more than retail consumers. This was because a very small fraction of Indians worked in the corporate sector. A large part of the population continued to be self-employed in small businesses. Such consumers continued to post growth in their income and bankers realised their continued creditworthiness. Therefore banks targeted such individuals to grow their credit card portfolios. Consumer lending expected to post strong growth over the forecast period Consumer lending is expected to see continued strong growth in outstanding balance in constant value terms over the forecast period. This will be due to rising disposable incomes, the growth of banks and other financial institutions and increasing financial inclusion. More consumers will come under the ambit of organised means of financing, rather than informal money lenders, who generally charge exorbitant rates of interest. Consumer Lending in India - Industry Overview EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Consumer lending grows at a high rate in 2013 despite tight economic conditions Sentiment remained negative in Indian economy in 2013 Scheduled commercial banks continue to lead consumer lending in 2013 Card lending witnesses fastest growth in 2013 Consumer lending expected to post strong growth over the forecast period KEY TRENDS AND DEVELOPMENTS Fall in gold prices affects gold loan companies in the first half of 2013 Mortgages/housing lending witnesses stronger growth in 2013 Reserve Bank of India (RBI) accepts applications for fresh banking licence in 2013 Consumer Lending in Chile Jan 2014| EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Consumer lending records another year of growth Consumer lending posted year-on-year double-digit current value growth between 2010 and 2013. Auto lending and home lending supported fast growth, with ongoing urbanisation boosting consumer interest in automotive and home improvement purchases. Regulatory change increases control over the industry Following two important decisions by the Supreme Court of Justice, Chile’s regulatory agencies started to make significant changes to the laws governing consumer finance. The main modification is the ban on unilateral adjustments to contracts, a fairly common practice in the industry. Traditional banks continue to lead consumer lending Consumer lending continues to be dominated by traditional institutions. Banco Santander, Banco de Chile and Banco del Estado de Chile are the top players in consumer credit and mortgages/housing. These banks are expected to remain the leaders in the forecast period. Consumer unease puts pressure on banking legislation Student demonstrations and the proliferation of citizens’ organisations increased the pressure on the authorities to implement restraints on financial activity. The increase in the educational levels of Chileans has helped to create more active and involved citizens, who demand reform of the major institutions of the country to make them more transparent and open to scrutiny. Consumer lending’s future remains unclear The erratic performance of the main Asian economies has generated doubts about the economic prospects of Chile. As the country is highly dependent on copper exports to China and other Asian countries, a significant drop in the manufacturing activity of Asia would have a negative impact on Chile’s balance of trade. Chile faces a deficit scenario from 2013. This situation could become serious if the unemployment rate rises and the state’s budget decreases. Consumer Lending in Chile - Industry Overview EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Consumer lending records another year of growth Regulatory change increases control over the industry Traditional banks continue to lead consumer lending Consumer unease puts pressure on banking legislation Consumer lending’s future remains unclear KEY TRENDS AND DEVELOPMENTS Consumer credit booms, though some doubts remain “110% credit” supports the expansion of mortgages/housing loans Supreme Court decisions accelerate regulatory change http://www.rebels.co.za/images/downloads/8-TransUnion_Owen_Sorrour.pdf Final Discussion Question: What are the primary benefits and detriments of regulations that free up the flow of consumer credit? To those that limit the flow of consumer credit? Where is the sweet spot? To what extent would one set of rules for all countries in the world be a good or bad idea?