ARCHNES MASSAC USETTS INSTITCITE OF rEcHNOLOLGY Essays in Financial Economics JUN 02 2015 by LIBRARIES Hong Ru B.A., Fudan University (2008) M.Fin., Massachusetts Institute of Technology (2010) Submitted to the the Alfred P. Sloan School of Management in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy at the MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY June 2015 @ Massachusetts Institute of Technology 2015. All rights reserved. Author ..... Signature redacted the Alfred P. Sloan School of Management April 29, 2015 Certified by.... Signature redacted I Antoinette Schoar Michael Koerner '49 Professor of Entrepreneurial Finance Thesis Supervisor Accepted by ... Signature redacted Ezra Zuckerman Director, Sloan School of Management PhD Program 2 Essays in Financial Economics by Hong Ru Submitted to the the Alfred P. Sloan School of Management on April 29, 2015, in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Abstract This thesis considers three empirical essays on financial economics. The first chapter examines the effect of government credit on firm investment, employment, debt, profitability, and survival by using unique data from the China Development Bank (CDB). I explore the different effects of various types of government credit (credit to infrastructure vs. credit to state-owned enterprises (SOEs)). I also trace the effect of government credit across different levels of the supply chain. I find that CDB SOE industry loans crowd out private firms in the same industry but crowd in private firms in downstream industries. I also find private firms benefit from CDB infrastructure loans. I use the exogenous timing of municipal political leaders' turnover as an instrument for CDB loans to cities. The second chapter, joint with Antoinette Schoar, analyzes pricing and advertising strategies of credit card offers. We show that credit cards which have reward programs have lower regular APR but rely more heavily on backward loaded and more hidden payment features. Issuers target different reward programs at different types of the population: Programs such as miles, cash back and points are offered to richer and more educated customers, while low intro APR offers are offered to poorer and less educated customers. Our results also suggest that card features that are mainly demanded by sophisticated consumers cannot be shrouded and need to be priced upfront. Finally, using shocks to the credit worthiness of customers, we show that card issuers rely more heavily on backward loaded credit terms when customers are more protected. The third chapter studies the effects of privatization on both SOEs and privately-owned firms in China. Using political turnover as an instrument variable for privatization, I find that after privatization, the productivity of SOEs and private firms increases by 50% and 100%, respectively. Moreover, every 100 workers got fired by SOEs come with a 169 increase from private firms' hiring in the same industry and same province. I also find that politicians' fixed effect on SOEs is significant. Moreover, corrupt politicians make SOEs less efficient but more powerful in the market. Thesis Supervisor: Antoinette Schoar Title: Michael Koerner '49 Professor of Entrepreneurial Finance 3 4 Acknowledgments When I applied PhD programs five years ago, many people asked me: Are you sure this is what you want to do? Today, I can tell them: Yes, it is one of the best choices that I have ever made in my life. Along this exciting and arduous path, I am grateful to so many people for their support and encouragement. The first one I want to thank is Antoinette Schoar: she guides me step by step and teaches me how to think as a researcher in finance. I benefit a lot from our many long and engaging discussions. Her advice, support, and comments are invaluable. I feel so lucky to have her as my mentor, and I can't thank her enough. I am truly grateful to Nittai Bergman, Andrey Malenko, and Robert Townsend. They always push me to think harder and deeper. They make me a better researcher, and I am indebted to them. I also benefit a lot from discussions with Jean-Noel Barrot, Asaf Bernstein, Yan Ji, Mark Kritzman, Deborah Lucas, Eric Maskin, Tran Ngoc-Khanh, Stewart Myers, Stephen Ross, Felipe Severino, Daan Stuyven, Richard Thakor, Wei Wu, Yu Xu ,and Luo Zuo. My research in China has been benefited from many people; I learn a lot from working with Gao Jian whose comments about China are extremely insightful. He guides me toward the important research questions in China. I am deeply grateful to have him as my mentor and friend. I also want to thank Jinglu Feng, Yong Liu, Tianshan Meng, and Yue Wu from the China Development Bank for their generous supports. My family is always there for me. I want to thank my parents, Jianping Ru and Weiping Xie, for giving me the support that I needed to chase my dream. They guided me to where I am today. I also want to thank my son, Will, for all the joys you bring to my life. He is truly the best thing that has ever happened to me. Last, but definitely not least, I want to thank my lovely wife Wei Chen. Thank you for always being there along the way and helping me to be all that I can be. Without you, I couldn't achieve what I have today. You make me a better man. 5 6 Contents 1 Government Credit, a Double-Edged Sword: Evidence from the China Development Bank 13 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Literature review ........ ............................. Background: the China Development Bank and Local Government Financing in China . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.3.1 History of the China Development Bank . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.3.2 Local Government Financing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Data Description . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.4.1 D ata . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.4.2 Summary Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Empirical Analysis and Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.5.1 Firms' Response to CDB Loans . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.5.2 Instrument: City Secretary's Turnover Timing . . . . . . . . . 1.5.3 Second Stage: CDB City Level Loan Analysis . . . . . . . . . 1.5.4 Politician's Other Channels to Affect Local Economy . . . . . 1.5.5 CDB Industry Loan Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.5.6 Overall Effects of the Government Credit from CDB . . . . . 1.5.7 Politicians' Incentives Behind the Borrowing Patterns . . . . . C onclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 Do Credit Card Companies Screen for Behavioral Biases? 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Literature Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Data and Summary Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.3.1 Data Description . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.3.2 Descriptive Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . R esults . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.4.1 Customer Characteristics and credit card features 2.4.2 Pricing of Credit Cards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.4.3 Trade-off between Regular APRs and Late Fees . 2.4.4 Unemployment Insurance . . . . . . . . . . . . . C onclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 17 19 19 21 22 22 23 26 26 27 29 32 34 37 39 43 44 77 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77 82 83 83 85 87 87 89 95 95 97 98 3 Privatization, Politics, and Corruption 3.1 3.2 117 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Literature review and economic reform in China . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.2.1 Literature review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117 119 119 3.3 3.2.2 History of Chinese SEOs' reform . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Data Description . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121 122 3.4 3.3.1 D ata . . . . . . . . . . 3.3.2 Matching Politicians to 3.3.3 Summary Statistics . . Empirical Analysis . . . . . . . . . . 122 123 123 124 Privatization's effect on SOE itself . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Privatization's effect on private firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124 126 3.4.1 3.4.2 3.5 3.6 3.7 3.8 . . . . Firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128 3.5.1 3.5.2 3.5.3 Privatization's effects for SOEs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Privatization's effect on private firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Examination of exclusion condition and robustness check . . . 128 129 130 Influence of Politician in China . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.6.1 Policitian's fixed effects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131 131 3.6.2 3.6.3 Corruptions and firm's performance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Politicians' career path . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132 133 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134 135 8 List of Figures CDB Outstanding Loan Amount and New Issuance Political Turnover in China . . . . . . . . . . . . Local Government Borrowing . . . . . . . . . . Manufacturing Firms in China . . . . . . . . . . SOEs' Fixed Asset Patterns . . . . . . . . . . SOEs' Employment Patterns . . . . . . . . . . Shifts of CDB Industry Loan Over Time . . . . . . 2-1 2-2 2-3 2-4 2-5 2-6 2-7 2-8 Monthly Time Trend of Reward Monthly Time Trend of Size . . Monthly Time Trend of Color Monthly Time Trend of Picture Waterfall Regression Coefficients. Waterfall Regression Coefficients. Simple Visual Credit Card Offer High Visual Credit Card Offer 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 3-1 3-2 3-3 Manufacturing Firms in China. 137 138 139 . . . . . . . . . . . 1-1 1-2 1-3 1-4 1-5 1-6 1-7 . . Turnover and Privatization . . . Estimated Hazard Functions . . 9 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 10 List of Tables 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 Summary Statistics Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . CDB Loan's Effect on Firms: Evidence from OLS Regressions . . . . Exogeneity of City Secretary Turnover Timing . . . . . . . . . . . . . City Secretary Turnover Timing's Effect on Borrowing from CDB . . City Secretary's Turnover Effects on Firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Opposing Effects of CDB City Infrastructure Loan and Industry Loan (Use Secretary Year in Office as Instrument) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . CDB Province Industry Loan's Effect on Firms within Same Industry 55 56 57 58 59 (2SLS).......... 62 ................................... 61 Upstream Industry Loan's Effect on Firms in Downstream Industry (2SL S) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.9 1.10 1.11 1.12 1.13 1.14 1.15 63 What Private Firms Benefit from CDB Upstream Industry Loans (2SLS) Variables' Definition and Construction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . City Secretary's Turnover and Borrowing from CDB(off national-cycle) What Firms are Crowded Out in Private Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . CDB Loan's Effect on Firms (Use Secretary Year in Office as Instrument) Turnover Timing's Effects on SOEs under Different CDB Loan Amount CDB Loan and Firm Exit&Enter (Use Secretary Year in Office as Instrum ent) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.16 Politician's Other Channels to Affect Local Economy . . . . . . . . . 64 65 66 67 68 69 1.17 Where Does the CDB Industry Loan Go? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72 70 71 1.18 CDB Province Industry Level Loan and City Secretary Turnover (First Stage) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73 1.19 City Secretary's Promotion and GDP Performance . . . . . . . . . . 1.20 City Secretary's Characteristics and Borrowing from CDB . . . . . . 1.21 City Secretary's Borrowing from CDB and City's Debt Level . . . . . 74 75 76 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 Summary Statistics Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Descriptive Statistics for Format Design of Credit Card Offers Credit Card Features and Demographics . . . . . . . . . . . . Relationship Between APRs/Fees and Reward Program . . . . Mileage Program vs. Zero Introductory APR Program . . . . 2.6 2.7 Relationship Between APRs/Fees and Credit Card Offer Design . . . Regular APR vs. Late Fees . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114 115 2.8 Unemployment Insurance and Credit Card Features . . . . . . . . . . 116 11 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109 . 110 . 111 . 112 . 113 3.1 Summary Statistics Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140 3.2 Hazard Ratio Analysis of Politicians' Turnover . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141 3.3 Does Privatization Improve SOEs' Efficiency? (OLS) 142 3.4 Effects of Privatization on SOEs' Efficiency (Using Political Turnover Timing as Instruments) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143 3.5 3.6 Does Privatization Improve Private Firms' Efficiency? (OLS) . . . . . Does Bigger Privatization Have Bigger Effects? . . . . . . . . . . . . 144 145 3.7 3.8 DID Regressions Results(Estimated Privatization) . . . . . . . . . . . Exclusion Examination and Robustness Check . . . . . . . . . . . . . 146 147 3.9 2SLS Robustness Check . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.10 Do Politicians' Individual Fixed Effects Matter? . . . . . . . . . . . . 148 149 . . . . . . . . . . . . 150 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151 3.11 Do Bad Politicians Extract Rents From Firms? 3.12 Politician Career Path 12 . . . . . . . . . Chapter 1 Government Credit, a Double-Edged Sword: Evidence from the China Development Bank 1.1 Introduction Government credit programs are pervasive in many countries around the world and play an important role in capital allocation, especially to infrastructure investment and state-owned enterprises (SOEs). For example, the United States established its earliest federal credit program - the Farm Credit System - in 1916 to provide credit to agricultural and rural America. This was followed by a surge in additional government credit programs after the Great Depression. Some credit programs, such as the Rural Electrification Administration and the Small Business Administration, are still in place.' In 2010, the U.S. Government's outstanding commitments for loans and guarantees totaled approximately $2.3 trillion. This was roughly one-third the size of the loans of all the U.S. banks combined (Elliott (2011)). Outside the United States, many countries have development banks that typically issue government credit. 2 The literature has outlined two opposing views of the effects of government di'For detailed histories of the Farm Credit Council, please go to www.fccouncil.com documents. Rural Electrification Administration (REA) was the former agency of the U.S. Department of Agriculture that administered loan programs for electrification and telephone service in rural areas. Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC) was a U.S. government corporation started in 1932. It provided financial support to state and local governments, and made loans to banks, railroads, mortgage associations, and other businesses. RFC was the predecessor of the Small Business Administration. Small Business Administration (SBA) was founded in 1953 to provide loans, loan guarantees, contracts, counseling sessions, and other forms of assistance to small businesses. In 2007, the National Infrastructure Reinvestment Bank was proposed, later backed by President Obarma. 2 For example, Germany formed KfW Bankengruppe in 1948, a German government-owned development bank based in Frankfurt. Korea founded Korea Development Bank in 1954, which is a state-owned policy bank in South Korea. There are also many multilateral development banks such as the African Development Bank, the Asian Development Bank, the European Bank for Reconstruction, and Development and the Inter-American Development Bank Group. In the U.S., the National Infrastructure Reinvestment Bank was proposed in 2007. 13 rected credit. On the one hand, government credit can be justified by the existence of credit market failures. Private banks may not allocate funds to high social return projects with positive externalities if the returns are difficult to be captured (Stiglitz (1993)). Prime examples are infrastructure investments such as highways or airport constructions. Private firms could benefit from these projects' positive externalities. On the other hand, government credit could crowd out private sector investment, especially when the credit is given at below market rates or to firms that have distorted incentives (e.g., Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic (1998), King and Levine (1993a, 1993b), Rajan and Zingales(1998)). A concern is that inefficient established firms are subsidized (e.g., SOEs), while more efficient firms are crowded out (e.g., private firms), which harms the economy in the long run. Empirical studies have shown mixed results on whether government credit 3 crowds out private sector investment and growth or whether it encourages private sector (crowd in) (e.g., Blanchard and Perotti (2002), Cohen et al. (2011), Gale (1991)). Due to limited data, these studies usually explore only the effects of aggregate government credit. In this paper, I am able to add to the prior literature by analyzing the role of different types of government credit (infrastructure loans vs. industry loans to SOEs) in the context of China. In addition, I am able to trace the effect of credit across SOEs and private firms, as well as across different levels of the supply chain. I find that government loans to SOEs crowd out private firms in the same industry, but interestingly they crowd in private firms in downstream industries. Moreover, infrastructure loans appear to have positive effects on private firms. These opposing effects may shed light on the mixed results from previous studies. I study this issue based on a unique industry-level loan data set from the China Development Bank (CDB) for the period 1998 to 2013. I combine it with a firm-level panel data set from the Chinese Industry Census, which contains all manufacturing firms with annual sales of more than 5 million RMB ($700K) from 1998 to 2009. The China Development Bank is one of three policy banks with a mandate to provide credit support to infrastructure projects and SOEs in basic industries, primarily by lending to local governments. 5 The CDB loan data contain city-level, aggregate, outstanding loan amounts and issuances. Loans are categorized into infrastructure loans and industry loans to SOEs. The data set also contains province-level, aggregate, outstanding loan amounts and issuances, which are categorized into 95 industries.6 I first use a simple OLS regression framework. I find that CDB industry loans are associated with larger investment in assets, greater employment, and more debts 3 Government credit can also be viewed as government spending (Lucas (2012b)). CDB loans are subsidized. In China, CDB lending can be viewed as an extension of government fiscal policy. 'I am the visiting scholar in the China Development Bank and have access to their internal data system. This internal data is compiled in CDB headquarter from detailed monthly loan reports of each CDB branch. 5The CDB usually coordinates with local governments and lends to infrastructure projects and SOEs in the province or city. Most of CDB's loans are lent via local governments, which are implicitly or explicitly responsible for these loans. See more details in Section 1.3. 6 These industries include both infrastructure sectors (e.g., road transportation, water supply, public facilities) and industry sectors (e.g., agriculture, tobacco, software, oil refining, textile). See more details in section 1.4. 14 . of SOEs that receive these CDB loans. On the other hand, the amount of CDB industry loans to SOEs is negatively correlated with investment, employment, total sales ,and sales per worker of private firms in the same industry7 . In contrast to the industry SOE loans, the CDB city infrastructure loan amount is positively correlated with private firms' assets, debt, total sales, and sales per worker. Doubling the CDB industry loans is associated with a 0.6% increase in SOEs' assets and a 0.3% decrease in private firms' assets While the effects are significant, there is a potential endogeneity concern. Government credit might flow into areas or industries with especially high or low growth potential. Moreover, in China, it is the local government that borrows from the CDB for infrastructure projects and SOEs. The local governments, which enjoy closer relationships with the CDB, may be granted more loans. To address these concerns, I use the exogenous timing of political turnovers as a way to identify the causal effects of government directed credit.' In particular, I use the timing of municipal government turnovers as an instrument for CDB loans. In China, the city secretary (equivalent to a mayor in the U.S.) is replaced every five years on average. This turnover is decided not by an election but by a higher level communist party official. About half of the cities have the same five-year turnover cycle as the National Congress of the Communist Party. But some cities have different turnover cycles if they were newly founded during the 1990s and started on different cycles due to the year they were founded9. The city secretary plays a key role in CDB loan allocations. Infrastructure loans are usually lent to municipal governments directly. Industry firm loans are often lent to SOEs, and municipal governments are deeply involved in and are responsible for arranging these loans. To verify the instrument, I begin by testing the exogeneity of city secretaries' turnover timings. I find that turnover timing does not correlate with past economic performance. I conduct first-stage regressions by regressing cities' borrowing from the CDB on the number of years the city secretary has been in the city. I control for city-fixed and politician-fixed effects to mitigate concerns that the CDB might lend more to the cities or politicians that have better political connections. I find that most cities borrow significantly more during the first year of the secretaries' terms, and monotonically decrease borrowing during later years. The borrowing of the city goes up again when a new secretary comes in. On average, secretaries reduce total loan amounts by 36.4% each year during their tenure in office. I find similar borrowing patterns in both infrastructure and industry loans. Moreover, I also control 7The majority of the CDB industry credit goes to SOEs. These loans are subsidized. On average, the interest rates of the CDB loans are 100bps below the market rates. 8 Previous studies use the exogeneity of political variables (e.g., political cycle, political competitiveness and politicians' seniority) to overcome endogeneity of the government credit or spending (e.g., Bertrand, Kramarz, Schoar and Thesmar (2007), Carvalho (2013), Cohen et al. (2011), Dinc (2005)), Sapienza (2004)). 9 More than 100 new cities were converted from villages during the 1990s. For example, Fuyang, a city in northwestern Anhui province in China, was founded in 1996. Its turnover cycle started from 1996, and the next secretary began in 2000. This is dissimilar from the national cycle. 15 for year-fixed effects to take out the macro time trend of the national turnover cycle. When I select the "off-national cycle" cities 0 , I find that these borrowing patterns still exist. This further shows that the part of the variation from turnover timing is due to the different cycles among different cities, rather than the national turnover cycle only. I also find the secretaries' chances of promotion are associated with more borrowing from the CDB in their early terms. This is in line with the hypothesis that the political ambitions of the secretaries drive these borrowing patterns. In the second-stage regressions, I regress firm-level dependent variables on the estimated CDB city-level loan amounts. Consistent with OLS results, I find that increasing CDB city-level, aggregate, outstanding loans led to increases in SOEs' fixed assets, employment, and debt. Conversely, increasing CDB industry SOE loans led to decreases in private firms' fixed assets, sales, and sales per worker. Moreover, when CDB loans increase, the private sector has fewer firms," and higher ROA private firms are crowded out. On the other hand, I find that increasing CDB city infrastructure loans led to increases in private firms' fixed assets, employment, debt, and total sales. The CDB loans' opposing effects on private firms and SOEs also alleviate the concern that the timing of city secretary turnovers is driven by changing investment opportunities in a city. I further document that other channels through which the city secretary may influence the business in a city are not correlated with the turnover cycles (e.g., enforcing tax treaties better, raising money by requesting more transfers, and selling more land). Moreover, I find that for cities with no CDB loans, turnover timing has no effect on firms. These findings support my hypothesis that turnover timing provides exogenous variation of borrowing timing. The findings also help reduce the concern that alternative channels may play a major role. To explore the heterogeneous effects of government credit on private firms at different levels of the supply chain, I analyze province-level loan data in 41 manufacturing industries. I again use city-level turnover timing as the exogenous shock and match it at the province level. I identify the number of years the city secretary has been in the city and match this data to the city's biggest SOE industry at province level. If the city secretary is in the early term (within three years of entering the office), I consider it a shock to CDB province-level loans to the industry (i.e., the largest SOE industry of the city). In the first-stage regression, I find that province-level CDB loans in an industry are 33.2% higher if the corresponding city secretary is in the first three years of a term. In the second-stage regressions, I find that increases in CDB loans led to decreases in fixed assets, employment, debts, and sales of private firms within the same industry and same province. SOEs in the same industry and province experience increases in fixed assets, employment, debts, and sales. Therefor, CDB industry loans crowd out private firms in the same industry and crowd in SOEs. 10I exclude the cities whose turnover are at the same time as the national turnover cycle(year 1998, 2003 and 2008). The remaining "off national cycle" cities have different turnover cycles than the national cycle. " Firm-level data used in this paper record all manufacturing firms with annual sales of more than 5 million RMB ($700K). If a firm drops from the sample, it could be a bankruptcy or the firm's sales was below the threshold. It is also the same for firm enters. 16 Finally, I study CDB industry loan effects on upstream and downstream industries, and I use the input-output matrix to identify inter-industry relationships. For each industry, I pick its largest intermediate input from other industries as an upstream industry. I find that increasing CDB loans to the upstream industry led to increases in downstream private firms' fixed assets, debts, and sales. Evidence also suggests that private firms with better political connections benefit significantly more from these CDB upstream industry loans. In sum, although CDB industry loans crowd out private firms within the same industry, they crowd in private firms in downstream industries. To calculate the overall effects of the CDB loans on individual firms, I multiply the growth of different types of CDB loans (e.g., infrastructure loans, industry loans, and upstream loans) by the estimated coefficients. The total effect of CDB loans (including both infrastructure and industry credit) on annual asset growth of private firms is 3.4% on average. Annual asset average growth of private firms was 15.4% from 1998 to 2009. Therefore, credit from the CDB contributes 22% of the growth in the private sector. Moreover, the total CDB credit increases private firms' sales per worker by 10.8% annually. However, CDB industry credit to SOEs has negative overall impacts on private firms. On average, a $1 million increase in the CDB's outstanding industry loan amount led to a $0.52 million decrease in private firms' total assets. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 1.2 is the literature review. Section 1.3 provides the history of the CDB and local government debt in China. Section 1.4 describes the data. Section 1.5 gives the empirical analysis and presents the results. Section 1.6 concludes. 1.2 Literature review This paper relates to literature that examines whether government credit and spending crowds in or out the private sector. On the one hand, Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980) suggests the "social view" that SOEs can be justified under market failures (e.g., Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) and Greenwald and Stiglitz (1986)). Stiglitz (1993) argues that government directed credit can fund projects with high social returns where private banks might not allocate the funds. On the other hand, government credit could crowd out private sector investment, especially when the credit is given at below market rates or to firms that have distorted incentives. King and Levine (1993a, 1993b) explore the relationship between financial development and growth. They find that credit to SOEs is associated with lower growth of GDP, capital stock, investment, and lower efficiency. Rajan and Zingales(1998) find the fraction of domestic credit going to the private sector is strongly correlated with market capitalization to GDP. One explanation is that government involvement in industry crowds out the private sector. Bertrand, Schoar and Thesmar (2007) suggests that government intervention in banking may create implicit barriers to entry and exit in product markets by subsidizing poorly performing established firms. Many studies shows mixed evidence on whether government credit crowds out or crowds in the private sector. Gale 17 (1991) numerically estimates the effects of federal lending, suggesting credit subsidies are costly and raise private investment slightly. A survey from Schwarz (1992) shows limited evidence regarding the impact of U.S. credit programs on growth. Craig et al. (2007) find a small correlation between SBA loan guarantees and local economic growth. Shaffer and Collender (2009) find that total aggregate federal funding associates with significantly faster employment growth, but also with volatile incomes. In this paper, government credit from the China Development Bank can be treated as fiscal spending. Lucas (2012b) views federal credit programs as fiscal policy since credit subsidies are costly, and affect pricing and allocation in credit markets. For government spending, there has been a long debate between Keynesian and neoclassical' 2 theories. Vector auto regression on macro data is the standard method to study the effects of government spending shocks (e.g., Blanchard and Perotti (2002), Caldara and Kamps (2008), Fatas and Mihov (2001), Gali et al. (2007), Rotemberg and Woodford (1992), Ramey (2008)). The literature also explores exogenous shocks to government spending. Ramey and Shapiro (1998) use U.S. military buildups as exogenous shocks, finding that product and consumption wages fall after a military buildup. Burnside et al. (2004) use exogenous changes in military purchases as a fiscal shock, suggesting real wages decline and tax rates increase after the shock, and investments rise in the short term. This paper is closely related with Cohen et al. (2011). They use changes in congressional committee chairmanships as an exogenous shock to federal expenditure in states, finding that increasing fiscal spending makes firms reduce investments in new capital and R&D, and increase pay outs to shareholders. They aggregate government spending at the state level. However, we still know little about the effects of government credit or spending. One problem is that there is no detailed analysis on the impact of government credit in individual industries. This paper is based on far more detailed industry categories, which include 95 industries in China (e.g., farming, livestock, food, beverage, tobacco, non-ferrous metals mining and processing, software). I am able to separate the crowding out and crowding in effects of government credit by looking at different levels of the supply chain. This paper also relates to literature that studies political influences on government spending or credit. The political view assumes politicians have political and personal goals that conflict with social welfare maximization (Kornai (1979), Shleifer and Vishny (1994)). Political business-cycle literature started with Nordhaus (1975) and McRae (1977), and was followed by Alesina and Sachs (1988) to model how the government uses economic policies to influence elections under democratic political systems. Many recent empirical studies support this view. Sapienza (2004) finds that Italian state-owned banks charge low interest rates in a province in which the associated party is stronger. Dinc (2005) uses cross-country data to demonstrate that government-owned banks increase lending during election years in comparison to private banks. Dinc and Gupta (2011) show that in India, the government delays privatization of SOEs in regions with more political competition. Carvalho (2013) 2 Aschauer and Greenwood (1985), Barro (1981, 1989), Baxter and King (1993), Finn (1995), Hall (1980), and Mankiw (1987) use dynamic general equilibrium mode to study the effects of government spending. 18 uses Brazilian data and finds that politicians influence elections with bank lending. Bertrand, Kramarz, Schoar and Thesmar (2007) show that politically connected CEOs in France create more jobs in politically contested areas, especially during election years. Khwaja and Mian (2005) find that government banks in Pakistan favored politically connected firms by providing greater access to credit. Connected firms received 45% more loans and had 50% higher default rates on these loans. Private banks show no such political bias. However, there is little empirical evidence of the political view in countries without elections. In these countries, politicians are usually much more powerful. In China, government credit affects firms through local government debt instead of a firm's direct political connections with CDB. Municipal government plays a key role in CDB loan allocations. 1.3 1.3.1 Background: the China Development Bank and Local Government Financing in China History of the China Development Bank The China Development Bank was founded in 1994 from six SPC Investment Corporations 13. The CDB, along with Export-Import Bank of China and Agricultural Bank, were assigned as three policy banks during financial system reform in 1994. CDB investment covers basic industries and the infrastructure sector. In 2008, the CDB became a corporation with Ministry of Finance (MOF) and China Investment Corporation14 as its two shareholders. Although the CDB is now a corporation, it can still be viewed as an extension of the government's fiscal function. CDB's funding is largely from bond issuances. At its establishment in 1994, the CDB had $6.3 billion capital. The CDB is entitled to receive disbursements from stage budgets, repayments of principal and interest, and fiscal subsidies arranged from the state budget to national projects. In addition, the CDB was entitled to issue financial debentures to state-owned financial institutions. Commercial banks in China are the largest buyers of CDB bond. The total volume of financial debentures issued by the CDB are decided jointly by PBOC and SPC based on yearly credit and fixed-asset investment plans. Interest rates of financial debentures are decided by PBOC in consultation with SPC and MOF. The CDB had explicit guarantees from the central government until 200816. The guarantee gives the CDB the advantage to "State Planning Commission (SPC) is a macroeconomic management agency under the Chinese State Council that has broad administrative and planning control over the Chinese economy. These six Investment Corporations were policy institutions, established in late 1980s, affiliated directly with the State Planning Commission and functioning as long-term investment instruments on behalf of the government. "China Investment Corporation is a sovereign wealth fund responsible for managing part of the People's Republic of China's foreign exchange reserves. "The People's Bank of China is the central bank of the People's Republic of China, with the power to control monetary policy and regulate financial institutions in mainland China. 16 The guarantee became implicit in 2008 when the CDB changed its corporate governance from SOE to a corporation. However, the interest rate and the issuance volume is unaffected by this 19 finance the bond market cheaply, and its bond interest rate is slightly higher than the treasuries in China. By the end of 2013, the CDB had approximately $1.3 trillion outstanding loans, and most are financed through bond issuance. As shown in Figure 1-1, CDB loans started to increase in 2003, and grew over time, especially from 2008 through 2010. At the end of 2013, the CDB has 5.8 trillion RMB ($0.95 trillion) outstanding domestic loans and 1 trillion RMB ($0.16 trillion) overseas loan. The bank's lending rates were regulated by the Central Bank before 2008. Between 2008 and 2013, the lending rate was required to sit within a range of a referred rate set by the Central Bank. This range was expanded over the years until mid-2013. After July 20, 2013, the lending rate was liberalized. However, the deposit rate is still controlled by the government. The CDB has been regulated like other stateowned commercial banks, but in practice, CDB's long-term loan rates have been lower than those of state-owned commercial banks, and much lower than private or shareholding commercial banks, because 1) the CDB is less profit driven, and 2) CDB's administrative costs are lower than commercial banks". CDB's loans can be viewed as subsidized loans or government spending. The CDB is fully state-owned, just like other state-owned commercial banks such as ICBC, CCB, BOC and ABC 18 , but its behavior is different. CDB's business usually covers infrastructure sectors and uncontested markets in which other stateowned commercial banks have little interest. This phenomenon might due to three reasons. First, CDB's policy mandate pinpoints the bank in such policy-related areas. Second, the CDB finances its loans by issuing long-term bonds with sovereign ratings, whereas other state-owned commercial banks rely primarily on short-term deposits. Therefore, the CDB conducts long-term lending that not only caters to infrastructuresector requirements, but also matches its assets and liabilities durations. Third, CDB's managers and its elites used to work in central government agencies, such as NDRC'" or SPC, MOF, PBOC, etc., whereas those of commercial banks are lifelong bankers. Such career background disparities might led to differences in respective visions, political awareness, and behavioral preferences, which affect a bank's business. Generally, local governments initiate loan applications by submitting project proposals to the CDB. The CDB decides whether to accept or reject them. Allocation of the CDB loans depends on many determinants. First, based on the central government's yearly credit plan, the CDB gives each province an annual credit quota. For example, if the total credit amount increases by 20%, each province can also increase change. The CDB is still considered an extension of the government's fiscal function. 1 7 Unlike commercial bank, which usually have branches in all cities and villages in China, the CDB has branches only at the province level. One reason is that the CDB does not need local branches to attract depositors. Most of CDB's money is from bond issuances. The CDB usually focuses only on projects at city or province levels, and it does not invest often at village level or below. 8 1 ICBC stands for Industrial and Commercial Bank of China; CCB for China Construction Bank; BOC for Bank of China; ABC for Agricultural Bank of China. 19The National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC) of the Government of the People's Republic of China, formerly State Planning Commission and State Development Planning Commission, is a macroeconomic management agency under the Chinese State Council, which has broad administrative and planning control over the Chinese economy. 20 loans by 15% from the previous year. Second, the CDB keeps part of the quota, and has flexibility to allocate credit based on other determinants such as supporting national projects, political connections with local governments, how hard local governments lobby, etc. Local governments usually compete for CDB loans, especially in recent years. Although there is a general rule on credit allocations, final loan issuances do not necessarily accord with initial plans. 1.3.2 Local Government Financing Since 1989, local governments in China have been prohibited from incurring debt by budgetary law. As a result of tax-sharing system reform between local and central governments in 1994, the central government takes the majority (around 70%) of tax revenue. For example, the central government takes 60% of personal and corporate income taxes and 75% of value-added tax. At the same time, local governments bear the responsibility of infrastructure development but do not have the money to do so. With a thorough understanding of local governments' desires to boost local economies and develop local infrastructures, the CDB established direct connections with local governments and helped them create borrowing platforms by creating 100% stateowned companies. Local governments are then able to use these companies to borrow from banks and issue bonds legally. The CDB usually commits a certain amount of loans to fund infrastructure development within a certain period (normally 5 years). The CDB has several advantages to support local governments. First, it is mandated to invest in infrastructure sectors and pillar industries. Second, different from other banks, the CDB has special long-term funding resources through CDB bond issuances in domestic bond markets. Before 2008, the CDB was the primary resource for local-government financing, especially concerning long-term borrowing. In November 2008, along with 4 trillion RMB ($586 billion) stimulus plan2 0 , commercial banks started to lend to local governments aggressively. These were usually short-term loans (1 to 3 years). In 2010, the central government decided to pull back the stimulus plan. As a result, many commercial banks either stopped lending or rolled loans over to local governments. However, local governments' investments are usually long-term (such as infrastructure investments), and they needed loans to continue projects begun under the stimulus program. Therefore, after 2010, many local governments started issuing bonds and borrowing from shadow banking systems in China. The CDB is still a long-term, stable finance resource for local governments. This paper focuses on the period from 1998 to 2009, which overlaps with the stimulus plan by only one year. During the sample period, the CDB played the most important role in local government borrowing. 20 The 4 trillion (US$ 586 billion) stimulus plan was announced by the State Council of the People's Republic of China on November 9, 2008 to minimize the impact of the global financial crisis. The central government also ordered financial institutions (mainly commercial banks) to lend certain amounts within a limited period. Commercial banks started to increase lending dramatically, including lending to local governments. 21 1.4 1.4.1 Data Description Data This paper uses three data sets: (1) The China Development Bank, (2) The Chinese Industry Census (CIC), and (3) The Zechen and Baidu Encyclopedia Database. CDB data contain both city- and province-level loan data. At the city level, they record yearly aggregate CDB outstanding loan amounts and loan issuances to both infrastructure projects and industry SOEs from 1998 to 2010, across 310 cities in China2 1 . City-level data were collected by a CDB internal survey in 2010, on which branch managers at the province level manually categorized projects into various cities. At the province level, the CDB data set contains monthly aggregate CDB outstanding loan amounts and loan issuances in 95 industries for each of the 31 provinces 22 from 1998 to 2013. The industries include infrastructure sectors (e.g., road, air, rail transportation, water supply, public facilities, etc.) and industry sectors (e.g., agriculture, tobacco, software, oil refining, textile, etc.). In total, there are 27 infrastructure sectors and 68 industry sectors. Table 1.1 Panel B lists some large infrastructure sectors such as road construction, railway, water systems, and telecommunications. City-level loan data do not include province-level projects such as highways. CDB has only provincial branches, and each branch is required to report project information to headquarters at the end of each month. A CDB central server compiles the provincial data and updates them monthly. I use annual data during analysis. City- and province-level economic variables (e.g., GDP, income per capita, total employment, and fiscal income) are from the China Statistical Yearbook. The Chinese National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) collected the Chinese Industry Census (CIC) data, including all manufacturing firms in China with annual sales over 5 million RMB (about $700,000) from 1998 to 2009. It has detailed annual accounting data and firm characteristics such as number of workers, industry categories, locations, registration types, political hierarchies, government subsidies, wages, etc. In total, there are 711,892 firms in China. CIC appears to be the most detailed database on Chinese manufacturing firms, and the content and quality of the database are sufficient. Using firm registration type from CIC data, I classify firms as SOE, private, or foreign firms. Location data in CIC is an 11-digit number that locates the firm at the street level. I cut the first 4 digits to identify the city. Industry codes are the standard 4-digits, and I cut the first 2 to match CDB industry codes. There was a change in industry codes by Chinese National Bureau of Statistics in 2002, so I adjusted the industry codes to 2002 standard. Regarding the data set from politician profiles, I manually collected it from the Zechen Database, which records all mayors and secretaries of municipal committees in each city from 1949 through 2013. I collected a name list of mayors and secretaries, 1They do not include Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjing, and Chongqing, which are classified as provinces. 22 In China, there are 27 provinces plus Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjing, and Chongqing that are under direct control of the central government. Among these 95 industries, CDB added 11 new industries in 2005 and doesn't have data before 2005. 22 and their terms in office, at the monthly level. I also collected data for members of provincial committees of the Communist Party of China. These data cover all the 334 cities and 31 provinces in China. Based on the name list, I searched politicians' profiles from the Baidu Encyclopedia database, a Chinese-language, collaborative, web-based encyclopedia provided by the Chinese search engine Baidu. The Encyclopedia is the best Chinese online encyclopedia, and generally provides clear profiles of prominent people, better than official public profiles of politicians. However, the quality of politicians' profiles varies among cities, especially for small cities. To compensate, I uses Xinhua News 2 3 as a supplementary source to crosscheck data from the Baidu Encyclopedia. Final profile data includes 1,227 city secretaries and 97 provincial governors. Each profile had a politician's gender, age, and birthplace. Some politicians had the same name, which is common in China. To overcome this limitation, I conducted a thorough double check for politicians with the same name, and distinguished them with a separate ID number. When I merged the CDB city-level data with politicians' profiles, there were 310 cities in total (the remaining 24 cities did not have CDB loans). 1.4.2 Summary Statistics Table 1.1 presents summary statistics, and Table 1.10 in the Appendix contains a detailed definition and construction of each variables. CDB city-level loan data include 310 cities from 1998 to 2010. The data separate loans into two categories: infrastructure and industry. The top 2 panels of Figure 1-1 show that the total citylevel, outstanding loan amount increased from 321 billion RMB ($40 billion) in 1998 to 2,811 billion RMB ($433 billion) in 2010. Total loans for infrastructure increased from 27.4 billion RMB in 1998 to 1,143 billion RMB in 2010. Industry loans increased from 293.6 billion RMB in 1998 to 1,659 billion RMB in 2010. Overall, industry loans are bigger than infrastructure loans at the city level, but infrastructure loans grew faster. The bottom two panels of Figure 1-1 shows the ratio of city level infrastructure loan and industry loan to total loan amount respectively. For infrastructure loan, the ratio was almost 0 from 1998 to 2000 which is consistent with the top 2 panels of Figure 1-1. Moreover, the gap between top and bottom quartiles enlarged from 1999 to 2003 and closes a bit after 2003. It means that different cities have very different combinations of infrastructure and industry SOE loans. One reason is that city secretaries tend to help the local SOEs to borrow from CDB. I find industry loan amounts are significantly higher in cities with more SOEs. These cities with big state-owned sector borrow relatively less in infrastructure. For new loan issuances at the city level, the amount increased from 98 billion RMB in 1998 to 1,066 billion RMB in 2010. On average, annual loan issuances were about one-third of the outstanding loan amount. One feature of CDB loans is that both cash inflows and outflows are huge because investment projects are huge, and loans are often rolled over. "Xinhua News is the official press agency of the People's Republic of China, and the largest center that collects information and press conferences in China. It is also the largest news agency in the country. 23 CDB province-level loan data covers 31 provinces and 95 industries from 1998 to 2013. The middle 2 panels of Figure 1-1 show that total province-level outstanding loan amounts increased from 474 billion RMB ($59 billion) in 1998 to 5,888 billion RMB ($935 billion) in 2013. Total loans for infrastructure increased from 124 billion RMB in 1998 to 3,569 billion RMB in 2013, and total loans for industry increased from 326 billion RMB in 1998 to 2,205 billion RMB in 2013. Overall, industry loans were larger than infrastructure loans in 1998, but infrastructure loans grew much faster and surpassed industry loans. For new loan issuances, the total amount increased from 142 billion RMB in 1998 to 1,796 billion RMB in 2013. There was a drop in loan issuances in 2012. In comparison to city-level loans, province-level loans were larger than infrastructure projects. If a loan was for a provincial project such as highway construction, CDB did not break it down and assign it to various cities. Instead, it recorded it at the province level. From middle right panel of Figure 1-1, there was a large jump in infrastructure new loan issuances from 2008 to 2009, due to a four trillion RMB ($586 billion) stimulus package beginning in November 2008. After 2010, there was a decrease in infrastructure loan issuances, due primarily to a pull-back of the package. Chinese Industry Census data contain 711,892 firms in the manufacturing sector. Each has a unique registration number and company name. The registration number is a unique number to a company from SAIC 21. The registration number of a company that no longer exists is recycled. I use registration numbers as IDs for the companies. Unfortunately, CIC data do not record registration IDs for 2008 and 2009. I used a name-matching algorithm2 5 and recovered 90% of registration IDs. CIC also has registration types for the company, which depends on a company's shareholders. I used registration type to categorize companies into 3 groups: state-owned enterprises(SOEs), private companies, and foreign companies. SOEs are defined as stateowned or collective-owned enterprises. Private firms are defined as private-owned enterprises, private partnership enterprises, private limited liability company, or private limited company. If a firm's shareholders are mainly foreigners, it is classified as foreign firms. I exclude the firms from CIC data set if it has mixed ownerships (e.g., half private owned and half state owned). From Table 1.1, the average ROA was 9%, and the average number of employees was 108. Average ROA for SOEs was 5.2% and the employee number was 353. In China, SOEs are less efficient and have more employees. Tax_Corp is the effective annual corporate tax for each firm, missing if a firm's income before tax was negative. TaxVAT is the effective annual value-added tax rate of each firm. CIC recorded value-added tax in only 1998, 1999, 2000, 2003, 2005, 2006, and 2007. The average corporate tax rate was 19.41% and value-added tax rate was 15.09%, consistent with real tax rates 26. Figure 1-4 shows the time 2 1State Administration for Industry and Commerce of the People's Republic of China matched the name of each company in 2008 and 2009 with company names from 1998 to 2007 that had registration IDs. I grouped companies by city and industry to increase matching probability and accuracy. 26 The current corporate tax rate is 25%. For small businesses, it is 20%. For high-technology firms or other firms supported by the government, the corporate tax rate is 15%. Value-added tax rate varies between 13% and 17%. 21I 24 . trend of firm number and aggregate assets for SOEs, private firms, and foreign firms. The number of private firms increased dramatically from 1998 to 2009. The number of SOEs decreased over time, due primarily to privatization. Foreign firm numbers also increased slightly. For aggregate assets, the private sector again increased most, surpassing foreign and SOE sectors. SOEs' assets decreased from 1998 to 2002 and increased gradually after 2002. From 1998 to 2009, the private sector contributed greatly to China's double-digit economic growth, and on average, it had smaller firm sizes than SOEs and foreign companies. After matching CDB province industry data with CIC firm data, there were 41 industries in the manufacturing sector. In China, the political leader in a municipal government is called the Secretary of Municipal Committee of the Communist Party of China (equivalent to the mayor in the U.S.). For political turnover, the top panel of Figure 1-2 is a histogram of city secretaries' term lengths from 1997 to 2013, among the 334 cities. I rounded monthly turnover data into year frequency using June as the cutoff". Forty-three percent of city secretaries left the city in their fifth year. In some cases, city secretaries left before the fifth year, and in fewer cases, they remained. The national political turnover cycle is also 5 years, and it occurs around the National Congress of the Communist Party of China (CPC). Four national CPC congresses occurred in the data from 1997 to 2013: 1997, 2002, 2007, and 2012. Since the National Congresses of the Communist Party usually occur at the end of these years, the turnover could occur the next year. The middle panel of Figure 1-2 is a histogram of turnover years, concentrated in years 1998, 2003, 2008, and 2013. These years are one year after the National Congress of the Communist Party. However, some special cases appeared such that turnover did not occur every 5 years, and did not occur during a National Congress. The reason is because China experienced fast urbanization, and many cities were incorporated during 1990s. A city secretary's first tenure is usually 5 years, but the starting year might not have coincided with the national cycle. The bottom panel of Figure 12 shows the sub-sample of secretaries whose term lengths were not 5 years (e.g., 4 or 6 years). Turnover more likely occurred around National Congresses, suggesting provincial governments in China wanted to bring cities with different cycles back to the national cycle, so a few cases had 4- and 6-year terms. One explanation is that the turnover of provincial governors accorded with national cycle. New governors usually want to have their own people to be city secretaries. In the politicians' profile data, the average age of city secretaries is 50 years; the youngest was 32 and the oldest 62. The legal retirement age for males is 60, and 55 for females. "Promotion" is a dummy variable for whether a city secretary was promoted during turnover. 38% of city secretaries were promoted after their terms ended. Promotion is defined as being appointed to a higher political hierarchy in the government 28 2 1f secretaries left before June and their successors succeeded them before June, I considered the successor the city secretary for the entire year. If the secretaries left after June, I considered them the city secretary for the entire year. 28 City secretaries' political hierarchies vary across cities. Secretaries from Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjing, and Chongqing are at ministerial level. Fifteen cities in China are at vice-ministerial level: Dalian, Qingdao, Ningbo, Xiamen, Shenzheng, Haerbing, Changchun, Shenyang, Jinan, Nanjing, Hangzhou, Guangzhou, Wuhan, Chengdu, and Xian. Others are at the departmental level. I do not 25 1.5 1.5.1 Empirical Analysis and Results Firms' Response to CDB Loans There has been a long debate on the effects of government credit, especially for the private sector. Public goods such as infrastructure help economic growth since firms benefit from the infrastructures around them. However, government credit also crowds private sectors through tax channel, interest rate channel, etc. In China, tax and interest rate channels are shut off; the cities and even the provinces cannot change tax rates or categories. Only the central government can determine taxes. Although some tax treaties are flexible and local governments use them differently, the central government sets the rules for tax treaties, and manipulation is limited. Interest rates were not liberalized until July 20, 2013, after which banks determined their own interest rates on loans, but deposit rates were still controlled by the central bank strictly. The primary channel of crowding in China comes from competition between SOEs and the private sector. Chinese SOEs are important to many industries, even after the privatization wave from 1998 to 2005. Even today, SOEs control significant shares of assets (Figure 1-4). The majority of CDB's industry loans go to SOEs, and only a small share goes to the private sector, and then only to large, powerful private firms. It is rare that CDB lends money to small private firms such as entrepreneurs. I begin the analysis by OLS regressions and explore the correlations between CDB loan amount and a firm's asset investment, employment, borrowing as well as firm's performances such as ROA, total sales and sales per worker. I use the total outstanding loan amounts instead of new issuances because many new loan issuances are for old loans' rollover. I match province industry outstanding loan amounts with manufacturing firms in the same province and same industry. The regression is: Y,k,p,t = a - ,3 x LogLoan_ Pk,,,t + Controlp,to + YearFE + FirmFE+ El,(1.1) where Y,k,p,t is the dependent variables of firm 1 in industry k province p in year t such as logarithm of total assets, fixed assets, number of employees, total debts, ROA, sales per worker, and total sales. I control local economic condition variables, and year-fixed and firm-fixed effects. Panel A of Table 1.2 shows the regression results for SOEs. CDB industry firm loans had significantly positive correlations with SOEs' total assets, employment and debts. Panel B of Table 1.2 shows the regression results for private firms. CDB industry firm loans had significantly negative correlations with private firms' total assets, fixed assets, employment, total sales and sales per worker. These results show that CDB industry loan amounts may have positive impacts on SOEs' asset investment, employment and borrowing, and have negative impacts on private firms' asset investment, employment and sales. The CDB industry loans may crowd out private sector and crowd in SOEs within the same industry. Moreover, I also study the infrastructure loans. Panel C of Table 1.2 shows the regression include ministerial-level cities during city-level analyses since they are at the same level as provinces. I define promotion based on varying political hierarchies accordingly. 26 results for city-level infrastructure loans. It shows that private firms' total assets, fixed assets, debt, total sales and sales per worker are positively correlated with CDB infrastructure loans. However, there is a potential endogeneity concern that CDB credit allocations are endogenous. CDB lends to infrastructure projects and SOEs via local governments. The local governments with better relationships with CDB may borrow more. Furthermore, CDB is a policy bank with a mandate to provide credit supports to infrastructure and pillar industries, especially in undeveloped areas in China. In order to fix this problem, I use municipal government turnover timing as the instrument for CDB loans. 1.5.2 Instrument: City Secretary's Turnover Timing I first test the exogeneity of city secretaries' turnover timing. Mentioned above, city secretaries' terms are 5 years, and each city has its own turnover cycle. Although the types of turnover might be endogenous such as promotion, the timing of turnover is exogenous. I only use the variation from turnover timing. I use the Cox proportional hazard model, which includes politicians' demographics, economic performance, and time of turnover. The hazard rate of turnover is given by: h(t) = ho(t) exp(ixi + 2 x 2 + - - - + /kXk), (1.2) where X 1 ... Xk are politician's ages and gender, economic performance in the city such as GDP, income per capita, city government fiscal income, and city employment. I also include dummy variable NationalCycle to account for whether it a National Congress Party year. I have both time-varying and time-invariant variables, and I assume the time-varying variables are constant throughout a year. I followed Wooldridge(2002) to construct a hazard model, and report the coefficients and hazard ratios from the estimation in Table 1.3. I include previous CDB outstanding loans to test whether the timing of turnover is affected by existing CDB loans. In column 1 to 4 of Table 1.3, NationalCycle had a positive effect on city secretaries' turnover, consistent with patterns in Figure 1-2 since many city turnovers are in the national turnover years. Column 5 of Table 1.3 reports hazard ratios, and on average, the turnover probability increased by 39.3% during national turnover years. Age of a secretary had positive effects on the timing of turnover because when city secretaries get older, they are more likely to retire. The timing of turnover did not depend on a city's past economic performance and CDB loans. I include economic variables and city loans in two-year lags and find nothing significant. In columns 1 and 3 of Table 1.3, I exclude Age and Gender since they have some missing values. Again, timing of turnover did not depend on a city's economic performance and CDB loans. Then, I explore borrowing patterns over various periods of a city secretary's term. The CDB's primary lending method is to coordinate with local governments and support both infrastructure projects and industry firms, which are usually SOEs. The city secretary is the top-ranking politician in the city, and usually plays a large role during the lending process. The regression is: 27 LogLoant = a + / x PoliticianYeari, 3 ,t + Controlj,t-i + YearFE +cityFE + SecretaryFE+ sj,t, (1.3) where LogLoant is the CDB loan variables in city j in year t. I used the logarithm of CDB outstanding loan amounts and new issuance for infrastructure, industry, and total loans as dependent variables. PoliticianYearjj,t is the number of years that secretary i stayed in city j in year t. Controlj,t_1 are variables for economic conditions such as GDP, urban income per capita, fiscal income, and the working population. I also include city fixed effects, year fixed effects, and secretaries' personal fixed effect since cities have varying situations and secretaries have their own investment styles. Standard errors are clustered at the city level. In Table 1.4 Panel A, the coefficient of PoliticianYear was -0.364 at 1% significance in column 1; on average, if a city secretary stayed one more year, borrowing from CDB decreased by 36.4%. If I break loans into infrastructure and industry loans, the effects are stronger for industry loans. In columns 3 and 5 of Table 1.4 Panel A, the coefficient of PoliticianYearwas -0.122 for infrastructure outstanding loans and -0.338 for industry loan. Instead of using PoliticianYearjj,t, I use Year_ 1 ij,t, ... , Year_ 6 i,j,t, which are dummy variables for years that secretary i stayed in city j in year t. Year_ li,j,t equals 1 if it was the first year secretary i stayed in city j and zero otherwise. Year 2 i,j,t equals 1 if it was the second year secretary i stayed in city j and zero otherwise. Year_ 3i,j,t to Year_ 6 i,j,t were constructed similarly. LogLoanj,t = a+ /1 x Year_ li,j,t + 2 x Year_ 2i,j,t + /3 x Year_ 3i,j,t x Year_4ijt + /35 x Year_ 5 i,j,t + f36 x Year_ 6 3,,t +Control3 ,t-j + YearFE + cityFE + SecretaryFE+ Ej,t (1.4) +34 Results are shown in Table 1.4 Panel B. Year_1 is the missing category. Consistent with results in Panel A, Year_2's coefficient was -0.386 at 1% significance on total CDB outstanding loan; on average, city secretaries borrowed 38.6% less during their second years than first years. In column 1 of Table 1.4 Panel B, Year_3's coefficient was -0.749, Year _4's coefficient -1.071, Year_5's -1.429, and Year _6's -1.9. Borrowing from CDB decreased monotonically when a city secretary stayed longer in a city. In column 3 of Table 1.4 Panel B, CDB loan amount in a secretary's second year was 10.9% less than the first year, and decreased monotonically over time. This pattern was also true for infrastructure and industry loans, confirming results in Table 1.4 and suggesting that city secretaries borrowed more soon after they took the office, and slowed borrowing monotonically over their terms. This pattern was also true for infrastructure and industry loans. I exclude cities with the same turnover cycles as the national cycle, and perform regressions with equations (1.3) and (1.4) again. Table 1.11 in the Appendix shows that for these off-national-cycle cities, city secretaries had the same borrowing patterns; they borrowed more in the first year and decreased monotonically over time. For these cities, the secretaries also borrowed more during 28 early terms. The variation was not only from 5-year national turnovers, but also from these off-cycle cities. I find the similar patterns in CDB loan new issuances. Moreover, in Figure 1-3, I plot the average logarithm of CDB city total loan amounts after taking out the year fixed effects, city fixed effects and politician fixed effects. There are 3 national turnover cycles during my sample period: 1998 to 2002, 2003 to 2007, and 2008 to 2010. I cluster the cities by PoliticianYear for these 3 cycles respectively and calculate the average logarithm of CDB city total loan amounts for each bin in PoliticianYear. Figure 1-3 shows the "Zig-Zag" pattern during these 3 cycles. On average, city secretaries borrowed significantly more during their first year in office and monotonically decreased the borrowing over time. When a new city secretary came in, the borrowing spiked again. It verifies the results in Table 1.4. I also look at the borrowing pattern in each city. Most of them follow this "Zig-Zag" pattern. It alleviates the concern that certain cities with extreme values drive the results in Table 1.4. The next logical questions are: why city secretaries intended to borrow more during the early periods of terms? What are the incentives behind these patterns? In China, promotion is one of the most important career aspects to a politician. It is known well that city secretaries' and mayors' promotions in China depend heavily on local GDP growth. One way to boost up local GDP in short term is to borrow from CDB and invest as early as possible. See section 1.5.7 for more detailed discussions. 1.5.3 Second Stage: CDB City Level Loan Analysis In the second-stage regressions, I begin by studying city secretaries' turnover effects on firm decisions. To study heterogeneous impacts on various types of firms, I separate firms into 2 major categories: SOEs and private firms. SOEs' primary shareholders are state and collective owners. Private firms' shareholders are private investors such as individuals and institutions. Moreover, there is another type of firms with shareholders from foreign countries. These foreign firms can be considered as the subgroup of the private sector. Foreign firms in China usually have weaker connections with government than domestic private firms, and may suffer more from government credit than private firms. I match city secretaries' turnover data with manufacturing firms in the same city. The regression is: Y,t a+ #1 x Year 1 j,t +34 x Year_ 4 j,t + + /2 x Year _2, + /33 x Year_ 3 ,t /35 x Year_ 5j,t + /6 x Year _6,t +Contro1 ,t-1 + YearFE + FirmFE+ SecretaryFE+ Elt, (1.5) where Y,t is the dependent variables of firm I in year t such as logarithm of total assets, fixed assets, number of employees, total debts, etc. Year_ 1 j,t, ... , Year_6j,t are dummy variables for years secretaries stayed in city j in year t. For example, Year_2j,t equals 1 if it was the second year that a secretary stayed at city j and zero otherwise. Controlj,ti are variables for economic conditions such as GDP, urban income per capita, fiscal income, and working population. I control the year fixed 29 effects, firm fixed effects, and politician personal fixed effects. In the regressions, Year_1 is the missing category. Table 1.5 Panel A shows results for SOEs. In column 1, assets of SOEs, on average, were 1.9% smaller in the second year of a city secretary's term versus the first year. The coefficients for year 2 to year 6 were also negative, and decreased monotonically. This pattern is also true for fixed assets and debts (column 2 and 4). In column 5, in comparison to a city secretary's first year, ROA increased by 1% in the city secretary's second year, and monotonically in later years. In column 6 Table 1.5 Panel A, LogNumber is the logarithm of the total number of SOEs in each city annually, and controls for a year fixed effect, city fixed effects, and a secretary's personal fixed effect. There was no clear pattern of SOE numbers in various years during city secretaries' terms. In short, SOEs had more assets and debts in a city secretary's first year, and decreased overtime. Table 1.5 Panel B is for private firms. In column 1, assets of private firms, on average, were 1.5% smaller during the second year of a city secretary's term versus the first year. Coefficients for years 3 through 5 were negative, and decreased monotonically. This pattern was also true for debts in column 4. However, the number of private firms was smaller in the first year of a city secretary's term. CIC data contain all manufacturing firms with annual sales greater than $700,000. If a firm was dropped from the data, it either went bankrupt or had annual sales smaller than $700,000. Results in Table 1.5 Panel B suggest that, on average, private firms were crowded during the earlier periods of city secretaries' terms, but remaining firms grew. These different effects from turnover might suggest that different types of CDB credit might have different effects on private firms. CDB credit might also affect private firms differently at different levels of the supply chain. To explore which private firms were crowded, I separate firms into two group: those characterized by low and high ROAs. The dummy variable LowROA equaled 1 if a firm's ROA was below the median. In column 1 Table 1.12, the interaction term PoliticianYearLowROA had a negative coefficient, which means low ROA private firms increased assets more than efficient private firms during the early stages of city secretaries' terms. In columns 2 and 3, PoliticianYearLowROA had negative coefficients, which means low ROA private firms also increased fixed assets and employment more than efficient private firms during the early stages of city secretaries' terms. To link city secretaries' borrowing patterns and CDB loans' economic impacts, I use Year_ 1 i,j,t,..., Year_ 6i,j,t as instrumental variables to measure CDB outstanding loan amounts, and perform 2 two-stage, least-squares regressions. I include economic control variables such as GDP, urban income per capita, fiscal income, and working population, and firms' fixed effects, year fixed effects, and politicians' fixed effect as in the first-stage regressions. Table 1.13 shows 2SLS regression results. Consistent with previous evidence, CDB loans increased the assets, employment, and debts of SOEs, and decreased foreign firms' assets and employment. For SOEs, doubling CDB outstanding loans increased SOEs' fixed assets by 6.2%, increased employment by 5.8%, and increased debts by 7%29. For foreign firms, doubling CDB outstanding loans 29 1n Table 1.13, coefficients in columns 2 to 4 are 0.089, 0.083, and 0.101, respectively. Doubling 30 decreased the fixed asset by 11.8%, and decreased employment by 8.6%. From Table 1.5 Panel B and C, there were fewer private and foreign firms when city secretaries were in their early terms. To explore changes to firm numbers further, I calculate new firm entry and old firm exit for SOEs, private-sector firms, and foreign-sector firm. Again, exit does not necessarily mean a firm went bankrupt. It could be that the firm's annual sales were lower than 5 million RMB($700,000), so CIC did not record it. Enter does not necessarily mean the firm is new. It could be that the firm's annual sales were higher than 5 million RMB($700,000). Table 1.15 shows 2SLS regression results on number of firms that exited or entered CIC data by using PoliticianYear as the instrument for CDB loans. Columns 1 to 2 show that private firms exited more and entered less when CDB loans increased. Columns 3 to 4 show that foreign firms also exited more and entered less when CDB loans increased. Columns 5 to 6 show that SOEs exited less and entered more when CDB loans increased, which provides more evidence that private and foreign firms are crowded by CDB loans, and SOEs become stronger. However, various types of government credit should have different effects on private and foreign sectors. I separate CDB loans into infrastructure- and industry-firm loans. I perform 2SLS, and use Year_ li,j,t, ... , Year_6ijt as instrumental variables for both CDB infrastructure and industry loans. Table 1.6 shows 2SLS regression results. Interestingly, CDB infrastructure loans helped private and foreign sectors by increasing their assets, and industry loans crowded both private and foreign sectors. In column 1 to 7 in Table 1.6 Panel A, for private firms, CDB infrastructure loan increases increased assets, fixed assets, number of workers, debts, sales per worker, and total sales. CDB industry loan increases decreased assets, fixed assets, and sales per worker. In column 1 to 7 in Table 1.6 Panel B, for foreign firms, CDB infrastructure loan increases increased assets, debts, and sales per worker. CDB industry loan increases decreases assets, fixed assets, debts, and sales per worker of foreign firms. From these results, infrastructure loans supplemented both private and foreign sectors, but industry loans, which usually go to SOEs, hurt private and foreign firms. In sum, city secretaries borrowed more during early years of their terms, and during these years, SOEs increased their assets and debts, and became less efficient. For the private sector, there were fewer private firms, and the efficient ones were crowded. Moreover, infrastructure loans helped all SOEs, private firms, and foreign firms. Industry loans crowded both private and foreign sectors. Foreign firms decreased their assets and employment. The number of foreign firms also decreased during early years of secretaries' terms. Foreign firms can be viewed as the subgroup of the private sector but with weaker connections. It may explain why the crowding out effect is bigger on the foreign firms. In China, it is debatable whether political turnover correlates with other macro variables that influence local economies. The variation I use is from the varying political cycles among cities. I control year fixed effects to remove effects from the CDB city loans means Log(LoanCity) increases by Log(2), which equals 0.693. I multiply these coefficients by 0.693 to calculate the percentage increase of the dependent variables. All following analysis are based on the same calculation. 31 national turnover cycle. Moreover, I find disparate CDB loans' effects on private and SOEs from 2SLS regressions. It helps mitigate the concern that turnover timing of a city secretary correlates with demand changes or investment opportunities in a city. Disparate effects between infrastructure and industry loans in Table 1.6 further support the credit story instead of demand story in the city. 1.5.4 Politician's Other Channels to Affect Local Economy Another concern is whether CDB loans are the only way a city secretary can affect the economy; does the exclusion condition hold that local political turnover only affects the economy through CDB borrowing? When new city secretaries come to their cities, they usually have their own plans or preferences to develop local economies, and they have several tools to do it. For example, a secretary can build business districts to attract investment, speed approvals of city projects, provide better government services, etc. However, the biggest constraint is limited fiscal income. Local governments in China only share 20% to 30% of the tax revenue, and are responsible for infrastructure buildup. City secretaries have many good projects piled on the desks, but they require financial resources. There are three common ways to raise money: borrowing from CDB, selling more land, and asking for more transfers. In China, there are many pro-economic policies that are determined by the central government such as export tax rebates, corporate tax breaks for foreign companies and export companies, etc. City secretaries enforce these policies disparately. For example, they can simply give tax breaks to more firms. To rule out these channels, I regress the variable PoliticianYear on developed land, export amounts, fiscal income, fiscal transfers, average effective corporate taxes, and average effective value-added tax for each city to explore correlations between political turnover and these variables. Table 1.16 shows there were no correlations. However, it might take some time for a politician to act and effect local economies. To address this concern, I use a lagged PoliticianYearinstead and find no correlations, suggesting city secretaries do not sell more land to raise money, encourage exportation, increase fiscal income, ask for more fiscal transfers, or lower tax rates 0 during their early terms. I plot the time trend of SOEs' fixed assets and employment to demonstrate the effect of political turnover. The top 2 panels of Figure 1-5 examine SOEs' fixed-asset patterns for high CDB industry loan cities and low CDB industry loan cities. I define high and low categories as the top and bottom quartile of CDB city-level outstanding industry loan distributions among 310 cities annually. The plots show a clear effect of political turnover cycles on SOEs' assets in high CDB loan cities, but not in low CDB loan cities. SOE assets were higher during early periods of city secretaries' terms (i.e., 1 to 3 years) than during late periods (i.e., 4 to 6 years) in high CDB loan cities after 2003. In low CDB loan cities, this pattern is not evident, consistent with 2SLS regression results, which show that CDB loans increase SOE assets. One reason there 30 Export tax rebates offer a huge benefit for export firms in China, and the government gives part of the value-added tax or sales taxes back to firms. This is reflected by TaxVAT in Table 1.16 32 are no differences in SOE assets between early and late periods of a secretary's term in high CDB loan cities before 2003 is that before 2003, overall CDB lending size was very small in comparison to later years (Figure 1-1). Even in these high CDB loan cities, CDB did not lend much before 2003. The middle two panels of Figure 1-5 show stratification on high and low average effective corporate tax rates in the cities. I define high and low categories as the top and bottom quartile of average effective corporate tax rate distributions among 310 cities annually. SOE fixed assets have no clear difference between early and late periods of city secretaries' terms in either high or low corporate tax cities, disqualifying the channel with which city secretaries can offer more tax breaks to influence local economies. Another way to influence a local economy is through selling land. Land reserves play two roles in China. First, new business districts require land on which to build. Second, revenue from selling land goes to local governments whose fiscal income is limited. Selling land is a common way for a city to raise money, supplement fiscal income, and support local developments. The bottom two panels in Figure 1-5 examine SOE fixed-asset patterns for cities with large and small land developments. I define large and small categories as the top and bottom quartile of developed land distributions among 310 cities annually. The reason I do not use total land is that only developed land can be used to develop new districts or be sold. There is much deserted land in the western part of the country, and I exclude it during analysis. The bottom two panels of Figure 1-5 show no clear difference in SOE fixed assets between early and late periods of city secretaries' terms in the cities that have either large or small amounts of developed land. Figure 1-6 shows results from the same analysis as in Figure 1-5 but for number of employees, another important variable. Only the top panel for high CDB loan city shows a clear pattern that SOEs had higher fixed assets during early periods of city secretaries' terms (i.e., 1 to 3 years) than during late periods (i.e., 4 to 6 years) after 2003. All other panels do not have similar clear patterns. This confirms the exclusion condition of 2SLS. Third, I explore various effects of turnover timing in cities with different CDB loan levels. In Panel A of Table 1.14, I interact PoliticianYearwith dummy variable HighCDB for whether a CDB loan amount was above the median of all CDB loans in 310 cities from 1998 to 2009. I regress them on SOE variables. The interaction term PoliticianYearand HighCDB had negative coefficients with total asset, fixed assets, employment, debts, and sales per worker, suggesting turnover timing had larger effects when CDB loans were high. The main effects of PoliticianYeardid not have significant coefficients, so most of the effects of turnover timing were from high CDB loan areas. Panel B in Table 1.14 is restricted to SOEs with zero CDB loans in the city. There are no significant coefficients with PoliticianYearin these zero CDB loan areas. These results further support the exclusion conditions of turnover timing. 33 1.5.5 CDB Industry Loan Analysis Industry loan's effect on firms in the same industry Section 1.5.1 and 1.5.3 shows that at the city level, CDB loans for infrastructure help private and foreign firms grow. However, industry firm loans crowd private and foreign sectors. This section uses province-industry level loan data and explores more industry loan effects. The data offer the advantage of analyzing the effects of government credit on industries, and effects on related industries. Most extant studies are based on aggregate government credits or spending. Most CDB industry firm loans go to SOEs; approximately, 90% of total industry loans are for them. I regress the lagged aggregate assets of SOEs and private firms on CDB loans in the same province and industry. Table 1.17 Panel A shows that only SOEs' assets had positive coefficients. In column 1, the coefficient for LagAsset of SOEs was 0.058 at 1% significance. The unit of LagAsset and Loan _ P1 are both thousands of RMB; when a province has 1000 RMB more total assets of SOEs, the industry in this province can have 58 RMB more CDB outstanding loans the following year. Private-sector assets did not have significant coefficients, verifying that CDB industry firm loans usually go to SOEs. In Table 1.17 Panel B, I regress aggregate lagged assets of SOEs and private firms on aggregate infrastructure loans. Columns 1 and 2 of Table 1.17 Panel B are for province-level infrastructure loans, and columns 3 and 4 of Table 1.17 Panel B are for city-level infrastructure loans. Lagged SOE assets had no effects, but lagged, private-sector assets had positive effects on infrastructure loans, verifying that industry loans go primarily to SOEs. This disqualifies the alternative explanation that industry loans go to places with more investment opportunities, which happen to have more SOEs because infrastructure loans do not depend on aggregate SOEs' assets. Infrastructure loans tend to be lent to places with more private firms. The reason could be that areas with more private firms are often big cities or provinces that also require greater infrastructure investments. In China, cities in the same province usually focus on different industries, especially for SOEs that adjust slower than those in the private sector. I aggregate total assets of SOEs at the city-industry level each year and pick out the largest industry in each city. On average, only two cities in the same province focused on the same industry, and the city usually stuck to the same industry over time. Among 310 cities, 42% did not change industries from 1998 to 2009. 40% changed once, 14% twice, and only 3% more than twice. Based on these findings, I again use city-level turnover as a shock to CDB industry loans at the province level. I mark each city with its largest SOE industry annually. If city secretaries were in their earlier terms and based on previous conclusions, the city usually borrowed more industry firm loans for SOEs from CDB. I consider it a shock to a province-level CDB loan on the industry that is the largest SOE industry in the city. For example, city A in province B focuses on industry C. If city A's current secretary is in an earlier term, I consider it a shock to CDB loans of industry C in province B that year. Since cities in the same province usually focus on different 34 industries and the largest SOE industry in a city does not change often over time, if a city borrows more for its SOEs, it should be reflected in the province-level CDB loan in the industry. Formally, the regression is: LogLoanPIkp,, = a + 01 x Firstk,p,t + 132 x Secondk,,, + /33 x Thirdk,p,, +04 x Fourthk,p,t + 35 x Fifthk,p,t + 6 x Sixthk,,,t +Controlp,t-I + YearFE + provinceFE +IndustryFE+ Ek,p,t, (1.6) where LogLoanPIk,p,t is the logarithm of CDB outstanding loan amount in industry k, province p in year t. Firstk,p,t is a dummy variable that equals 1 if there is a city that focuses on industry k in province p that has a secretary who is in her first year. Secondk,p,, is a dummy variable that equals 1 if a city focuses on industry k in province p that has a secretary who is in her second year. Thirdkp,, to Sixthk,p,t are defined similarly. Controlp,ti includes lagged GDP, urban income per capita, fiscal income, and working population in province p. I control year, province, and industry fixed effects. Regression results are shown in Table 1.18. In the first column of Table 1.18, CDB industry loans were larger if a city that focused on this industry had a secretary who was in her early term; Firstk,p,t , Secondk,p,,, and Thirdk,,, had positive coefficients. I also combine the first two or three years and create dummy variables First- Secondk,,, and First- Thirdk,p,t. In columns 2 and 3 of Table 1.18, these two variables also had positive coefficients. On average, a province borrowed 33.2% more from CDB for an industry that focused on cities that had secretaries in the first three years of their terms. City secretaries borrowed more for a city's top SOE industry during their early terms, consistent with previous results that suggest secretaries borrowed more during earlier term. Next, I use Firstk,,, to Sixthk,p,t to instrument LogLoanPIk,p,t and perform 2SLS. I include all control variables such as economic variables Controlpt_1, yearfixed effects, and firm-fixed effects during first-stage regressions. The second-stage regression is: Yl,k,p,t -- a+ /3 x LogLoan PIkpt+Control,ti + YearFE + FirmFE+ 6 i,t, (1.7) where Yl,k,p,t is the dependent variables of firm I in industry k province p in year t such as logarithm of total assets, fixed assets, number of employees, total debts, ROA, sales per worker, and total sales. Again, I control local economic condition variables, and year-fixed and firm-fixed effects. Panel A of Table 1.7 is the 2SLS regression results for private firms. In columns 1 to 4 and 6 to 7, CDB industry firm loans had negative effects on private firms' total assets, fixed assets, employment, debts, sales per worker, and total sales. When industry loans doubled, private firms in the same industry, on average, decreased fixed assets by 14.8%, decreased employment by 9.7%, decreased debts by 20.1%, decreased sales per worker by 17.4%, and decreased total sales by 26.3%. In column 5 of Table 1.7 Panel A , CDB industry firm loans 35 had positive effects on private firms' ROAs. Panel B of Table 1.7 is 2SLS regression results for SOEs. Again, industry loans helped SOEs increase total assets, fixed assets, employment, debts, sales per worker, and total sales. When industry loans doubled, SOEs in the same industry, on average, increased fixed assets by 19.3%, increased employment by 13.0%, increased debts by 30.4%, increased sales per worker by 2.3%, and increased total sales by 12.6%. In sum, CDB industry loans make SOEs grow larger and sell more. Contrarily, private firms shrink in size and sell less. Since CDB industry firm loans usually go to SOEs, it is unsurprising that SOEs become stronger and crowd the private sector. The results from 2SLS are consistent with the OLS results in Table 1.2. Industry loan's effect on firms in the related industries It is well known that China's economy grew dramatically during the last two decades, and the private sector was the primary driver of this growth(Figure 1-4). Although government credit crowds the private sector in the same industry, it might complement the private sector in related industries. CDBaAZs strategy is to aid basic industries such as energy and mining to help related industries. For this sector, I use an input-output matrix to identify inter-industry relationships and study spillover effects of government credit. I use the national input-output matrix from 2007 from the National Bureau of Statistics of China to define upstream and downstream industries 3 '. The input-output matrix has 42 industries, and CDB classifies its loans into 95 industries, which is more detailed. I match these two industry classifications by combining CDB industries. For each industry, I pick the largest intermediate input from other industries as the upstream industry. At the firm level, I match each firm with its upstream industry CDB loan in the same province. After the merger, there were 25 industries in the manufacturing sector. Again, I use city-level turnover dummy variables to instrument UpstreamLoan and perform 2SLS. The first-stage regression is: LogUpstreamLoani,k1,,, = z+ 1 x Firstk',,t + /2 x Secondk',,,+ /33 x Thirdk',P,, +34 x Fourthk,t + 35 x Fifthk,t + 6 x Sixthk,p,t +Control,t_1 + YearFE + FirmFE+ ejt, (1.8) where LogUpstreamLoanI,kI,,, is the logarithm of CDB outstanding loan amount in the upstream industry of firm 1 in industry k, province p in year t. k' indexes the upstream industry of k. Firstk',,, is a dummy variable that equals 1 if there was a city that focused on industry k' in province p and that had a secretary who was in the first year. Second1,,, to Sixthk',,t are defined similarly. The second-stage regression is: 31I also use other years' input-output matrices to double check the definition of upstream and downstream industries and assess the same inter-industry relationships that do not change much over time. 36 Y,k,p,t = a + 3 x LogUpstreamLoanlpk, + Controlp,t-I + YearFE + FirmFE+ eI,t, (1.9) where Y,k,p,t are dependent variables of firm I at year t, which is in industry k, province p. LogUpstreamLoank,,,t is the estimated CDB loan to upstream industry k'. k' indexes the upstream industry of k. Panel A of Table 1.8 Panel A shows results for private firms. Generally, CDB loans to firms' upstream industry helped the private sector. In columns 1, 2, 4, 6, and 7 of Panel A Table 1.8, the upstream CDB industry firm loan had positive effects on private firms' total assets, fixed assets, debts, sales per worker, and total sales. When the upstream industry loan doubled, private firms in the downstream, on average, increased fixed assets by 9.4%, increased debts by 3.2%, increased sales per worker by 4.4%, and increased total sales by 4.9%. However, there was no change in employment or ROA. Moreover, in Table 1.9 Panel A, I interact the LogUpstreamLoanwith dummy Connected for whether the private firms' political hierarchy is above the city level or not. In China, every firm(include private firm) has a political hierarchy. It defines which level of the government the firm needs to report to. In another word, it determines which level of the government the firm is affiliated with. For example, city level firms means that the firms are under city governments and report to city governments. From the regression results in Table 1.9 Panel A, the private firms with better political connections can benefit significantly from the upstream loans. It means that although the CDB upstream loans have positive effects on downstream private firms but the connected private firms can benefit significantly more. Moreover, in order to check whether firm size is correlated with political hierarchy and drives the results, I control the interaction terms between firm total assets and the instrumental variables in Panel B Table 1.9. It turns out that the results in Panel B are very similar to Panel A. This confirms that political connection matters instead of the firm size. Table 1.8 Panel B shows results for SOEs. Generally, CDB loans to firms' upstream industry also helped SOEs. In column 1 to 4 and 7 of Table 1.8 Panel B, the upstream CDB industry firm loans had positive effects on SOEs' total assets, fixed assets, employment, debts, and total sales. When the upstream industry loan doubled, SOEs in the downstream, on average, increased fixed assets by 9.2%, increased employment by 8.7%, increased debts by 13.2%, and increased total sales by 5.8%. However, SOEs' sales per worker decreased. In column 5 and 6 of Table 1.8 Panel B , ROA and sales per worker both decreased. Although both the private sector and SOEs grew, unlike private firms, SOEs hired more workers and experienced lower efficiency. 1.5.6 Overall Effects of the Government Credit from CDB From the analyses above, CDB infrastructure loans help all types of firms: SOEs, private, and foreign. CDB industry loans that usually go to SOEs expand SOEs but crowd private firms in the same industry. Upstream CDB industry loans help private firms in downstream industries. What is the overall effects of government credit from CDB? 37 One component of CDB's mandate is to help basic industries. Although CDB industry loans crowd the private sector in the same industry, they help private firms in downstream industries grow. I use estimated coefficients and various types of CDB credits to study overall effects. In column 1 of Table 1.6 Panel A, the coefficient of CDB city-level infrastructure loans on private firms' total assets was 0.246, which means one unit increase in the logarithm of CDB city infrastructure loans increases the logarithm of each private firm's assets by 0.246 in the same city. For industry loans, column 1 of Table 1.7 Panel A shows that one unit increase in the logarithm of CDB province industry loans decreases the logarithm of each private firm's assets by 0.246 in the same province and industry. Column 1 of Table 1.8 panel A shows that one unit increase in the logarithm of CDB province upstream industry loans increases the logarithm of each private firm's assets by 0.092 in the same province and industry. Based on these coefficients and changes to CDB loans in infrastructures and industries, I find that, on average, total CDB credit increased private firms' assets by 3.4% annually from 1998 to 2009. During the same period, the average annual growth rate of private firms' assets was 15.4%. Therefore, CDB loans contributed about 22% to private-sector growth from 1998 to 2009. On average, a $1 million increase in CDB total outstanding loan amount led to a $0.33 million increase in private firms' total assets. If I exclude infrastructure loans, then from 1998 to 2004, CDB industry loans increased private firms' assets from 2% to 7% annually and a $1 million increase in CDB outstanding industry loan amount led to a $0.43 million increase in private firms' total assets. From 2005 to 2009, CDB industry loans decreased private firms' assets from 2% to 5% annually and a $1 million increase in CDB outstanding industry loan amount led to a $0.89 million decrease in private firms' total assets. Overall, from 1998 to 2009, a $1 million increase in CDB outstanding industry loan amount led to a $0.52 million decrease in private firms' total assets. Sales per worker is an important efficiency measurement in China, especially in the manufacturing sector. An abundant labor supply made labor costs cheaper in China, one of the most important reasons for dramatic growth in exports and the economy as a whole. Most manufacturing firms in China are labor intensive. Higher sales per worker means a firm can do more with fewer workers. From results in Tables 1.6, 1.7, and 1.8, CDB infrastructure loans increased sales per worker for private firms, and CDB industry loans decreased sales per worker for private firms in the same industry. CDB loans to upstream industries increased sales per worker for private firms in downstream industries. Based on these coefficients, I find that, on average, total CDB credits increased private firms' sales per worker by 10.8% annually from 1998 to 2009. During the same period, the average sales per worker annual growth rate of private firms was 20%. Therefore, CDB loans contributed more than 50% to the growth of the private sector's sales per worker from 1998 to 2009. If I exclude infrastructure loans, then from 1998 to 2004, CDB industry loans increased private firms' sales per worker from 2% to 9% annually. From 2005 to 2009, CDB industry loans decreased private firms' assets from 6% to 9% annually. I further explore the reasons behind disparate credit effects during various periods. Figure 1-7 plots total CDB loan issuances from 1998 and 2010 for the top 10 industries. In 1998, electric power supply and coal mining were the top two industries, 38 followed by petroleum and natural gas extraction, oil processing and refining, chemical products, etc. Except transportation equipment manufacturing, all of these were upstream industries. Manufacturing firms were usually direct downstream industries. The dominant weight on upstream industries can have large positive spillover effects on downstream industries, one reason industry credit can have positive effects on the private sector during earlier years. In 2010 and after 12 years, the top industries of CDB loans changed. Electric power supply is still the top industry of CDB loan issuances. However, three of the top 10 industries are in manufacturing sectors. Electronic equipment manufacturing ranks third, which was not included in the top 10 industries back to 1998. Special equipment manufacturing12 ranks fourth, and transportation equipment manufacturing ranks sixth. This could lead to bigger crowding effects in manufacturing industries, and smaller spillover effects for downstream industries. This might explain why CDB industry loans had positive effects on private sectors during earlier years, and negative effects during later years. During the past 20 years, China had dramatic GDP growth, and there were many shortages such as energy supply and mining. CDB loans in upstream industries helped solve these demand constraints, possibly explaining why CDB industry loans can help the private sector grow faster and become more efficient during earlier years. However, in later years, CDB focused less on basic industries, shifting to other industries such as electronic equipment. CDB loans to infrastructure always helped a firm grow and improve efficiency. Although there are increasingly new, modern cities in China, urbanization is far from over. 1.5.7 Politicians' Incentives Behind the Borrowing Patterns Section 1.5.2 shows that city secretaries borrow significantly more during their first year in office and decrease the borrowing monotonically overtime. The next logical questions are: why city secretaries intended to borrow more during the early periods of terms? What are the incentives behind these patterns? The political view suggests politicians had personal goals that did not necessary accord with social goals. In China, promotion is one of the most important career aspects to a politician. Li and Zhou (2005) find that the likelihood of promotion of provincial leaders increased with economic performance in China between 1979 and 1995. It is known well that city secretaries' and mayors' promotions in China depend heavily on local GDP growth. Although other determinants also matter such as political background and personal connections, GDP is one of few aspects that can be quantified. To verify the hypothesis, I calculated GDP growth from various periods and performed the regression: pomotionij = a + 01 x GPD_IIncreaset,, 3 + +3 x agej + 4 $2 x genderi + Ej x relationi, (1.10) Each observation represents one city secretary in one city 3 3 , where pomotioni is a 3 Special equipment includes equipment for mining, agriculture, medical, clothing, etc. "Some cases exist such that the same city secretaries were in different cities. The observation 39 dummy variable for whether city secretary i in city j got promoted during turnover. GPDJIncreaset,ijis the GDP increase from secretary i 's first year in city j in year t. I set t = 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 to examine effects from GDP increased in various stages of a city secretary's term. relationij is a dummy variable for whether city secretary i in city j was from the same hometown as provincial governor. ageij is the age of secretary i in city j during the turnover year. genderi is a dummy variable for whether a city secretary i was female. Standard errors clustered at the city level. Table 1.19 shows probit regression results. GDP increases increased city secretaries' promotional chances. GDP increases during the first couple of years of a city secretary's term had larger effects. In column 1 of Table 1.19 Panel A, the coefficient for GDP increases in the first year of a city secretary's term was 0.975. It decreases monotonically when I included more years (column 2 to 5). age had negative coefficients because older secretaries were more likely to retire and a rule states that to get promoted, a city secretary's age should be lower than 55 years. I also study CDB loan increase impacts on promotion. The probit model becomes: pomotionij = a + 31 x Loan_ Increaset,ij + 02 +/33 x age,3 + /4 x genderi + Ej, x relationi, (1.11) where Loan_Increaset,ij is the logarithm of CDB outstanding loan increase from secretary i's first year in city j in year t. I set t = 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 again. Table 1.19 Panel B shows that CDB loan increases had positive effects on promotion. This effect is primarily from loan increases during the first two years of secretaries' terms. In column 1 and 2 of Table 1.19 Panel B, coefficients for loan increases were 0.102 and 0.087, both significant. When I included later years(column 3 to 5), the coefficients are lower and less significant. relation had positive coefficients (column 1 to 5 of Table 1.19 Panel B), which makes sense since promotion decisions were usually made by provincial governors. Again, age has negative effects on promotion. In short, GDP growth had positive effects on city secretaries' promotions when their terms ended and earlier years' GDP growth had bigger effects. CDB loans also had positive effects on promotion probability, and loan increases during first two years of secretaries' terms had larger impacts on promotions. In China, borrowing from CDB is the primary method city secretaries use to boost local GDP during the last 15 years, and the loans take time to help the economy, so city secretaries should intend to borrow from CDB as early as possible. One concern is that politicians in China are assigned by the Communist Party instead of elected by voters. Moreconnected politicians can be assigned to better cities and can borrow more from CDB. Consequently, these politicians have greater chances of promotion. To deal with this, I focus on borrowing patterns from the timing of turnover. Most city secretaries' terms are 5 years, and based on duration model results, the timing of the turnover is unaffected by economic conditions and CDB loan amounts. Second, I control city is at the city/secretary level. For example, if one city secretary stayed in two cities, there are two observations for that secretary. 40 secretaries' personal fixed effects during regression to remove politicians' personal time-invariant effects. The borrowing patterns and promotions of a city secretary accord with the hypothesis that promotion is an important goal for city secretary, and promotions depend heavily on local GDP growth. One way to increase short-term GDP growth is to borrow from CDB and invest, explaining why city secretaries tend to borrow significantly more during earlier terms and slow borrowing later. However, there are several alternative explanations for this pattern. First, it could be that a city secretary's goal is to maximize social welfare, and the secretary wants to explore investment opportunities as early as possible during a term. Since city secretaries invest in good projects, GDP increases and they are promoted. Second, more-connected city secretaries have greater chances to get promoted and assigned to a better city with more economic growth potential. To separate the hypothesis from these alternatives, I include a dummy variable for city secretaries whose expected terms were fewer or equal to two years when they became secretaries. The bottom panel of Figure 1-2 shows a tendency to bring city turnover cycles back to national cycle. A city secretary would have known that there was a greater probability of turnover during these national turnover years. For example, if a city secretary began her term in 2011, she knew that the next turnover could be in 2013, a national turnover year, and there was only two years remaining. Retirement age is another cause. In China, the retirement age for male city secretary is 60, and 55 for female. I made dummy variable ShortTerm equal to 1 if national turnover or retirement was within two years when secretaries begin their terms. These secretaries expected their terms to be fewer than or equal to two years. If the secretaries' goal was to maximize social welfare, they should have borrowed and invested regardless of how long they expected to stay in the city. If their goal was promotion, they had less incentive to borrow if there were only two years remaining. In Table 1.20 columns 1 and 2, ShortTerm had negative effects on both CDB outstanding loan amounts and new issuances. The coefficient for CDB outstanding loans was -2.064. On average, for city secretaries who expected their terms to be less than or equal to two years from the beginning of their terms, they borrowed 50% less. If a city secretary wanted to explore good investment opportunities as soon as possible, they should still have borrowed and invested even if they expected short tenure. Second, I include dummy variable Younger for whether city secretaries were younger than 50 years when their terms began. In China, if city secretaries are more than 55 years old, they do not get promoted during turnover, and are usually assigned to a same-level, though less important, position until retirement. The hypothesis is that if city secretaries know there is a large chance to turnover again in the near future (e.g., 2 years), they have fewer incentives to borrow since a loan requires time to operate, and it will not help their promotions much. However, if city secretaries care about social welfare, they want to invest in good projects even if they will not help with promotions. Table 1.20 columns 3 and 4 show that if city secretaries were from the same home town as provincial governors, they borrowed 400% more. Again, if city secretaries wanted to explore good investment opportunities as soon as possible, they should still have borrowed and invested even if they were older and had 41 few chances at promotions. Third, I include dummy variable relation for whether a city secretary was from the same hometown as a provincial governor. Provincial governors make promotional decisions for city secretaries, and it is difficult identifying personal relationships between them. City secretaries are not necessarily from the same cities they rule, and neither are provincial governors. In the data, 94.64% of city secretaries were from other cities. The assumption here is that if a city secretary and provincial governor are from the same hometown, they are more likely to know each other, to have worked together previously, or for the governor to bring a city secretary with him/her during turnover. This cronyism is common in China. In the data, 8.42% of city secretaries were from the same hometowns as their governors. Table 1.20 column 5 shows that if city secretaries came from the same hometowns as the governors, they borrowed 18.9% more from CDB. If city secretaries or provincial governors cared about social welfare, they should have borrowed money based on project quality rather than relationships between them. A question that follows naturally is what prevented city secretaries from borrowing as much as possible during later terms? Although CDB loans during city secretaries' later terms do not help promotions, they can still borrow as much as they can unless there is a cost of doing so. Distress costs from high leverage is an obvious possibility. If a city already had many loans when a secretary began a term, the secretary should have known approximately the total borrowing during the term. Were the city constrained, the secretary had more incentives to move borrowing forward, and vice versa. To test this hypothesis, I use CDB debt-to-GDP ratio to measure constraints. City average CDB debt-to-GDP ratio was 2.4%, and I define a city as contained if the ratio were more than 6.9%(top quartile). Overall debt-to-GDP appeared low, but in China, a city shares about 20% to 30% of tax revenue. The fiscal income they can use to repay a loan is even smaller. In the top 25% of cities with a debt-to-GDP ratio greater than 6.9%, the median CDB debtto-fiscal income ratio was 219%; these cities are constrained. I used dummy variable Constrained for whether a city had a CDB debt-to-GDP ratio greater than 6.9% before the city secretary began a term. I also used the interaction of Constrained and PoliticianYear, with results in Table 1.21. PoliticianYear still had negative coefficients from columns 1 to 6. Constrainedhad positive coefficients on CDB outstanding loans for both infrastructure and industry, which is mechanical. For CDB loan new issuances (columns 2, 4, and 6), Constraineddid not have an effect, meaning constrained cities did or could not borrow more to invest or repay old loans. The interaction term PoliticianYearConstrained had negative coefficients. For example, in Table 1.21 column 1, the coefficient for PoliticianYearConstrainedwas -0.167 and the main effect of PoliticianYear was -0.274, suggesting that for constrained cities, secretaries tended to move more CDB borrowing forward. This supports the hypothesis that CDB loans are costly, and if city secretaries know they can borrow only a limited amount during their terms, they tend to borrow as early as possible. In sum, city secretaries borrow significantly more during early terms, and they borrow less if the expected turnover is in fewer than or equal to two years. City secretaries who are older than 50 when they begin their terms borrow significantly less. 42 A secretary who is from the same place as a provincial governor borrows significantly more. These results support the hypothesis that city secretaries want to borrow as early as possible to increase GDP and enhance promotion chance. Results are also against the hypothesis that city secretaries want to invest in good projects as soon as possible. However, instead of promotions, there could be other explanations for why short-term secretaries borrow less and younger secretaries borrow more. Perhaps short-term secretaries just want to live a quiet life and do not want to make huge changes during their short terms. Young secretaries are more ambitious and might have different educations than older generations. I do not disqualify these alternatives, but instead offer evidence that is consistent with the political view. These alternatives do not affect my identifications in the primary results. 1.6 Conclusion This paper explores the different effects of various types of government credit (infrastructure vs. industry credit). It traces the effect of government credit across different levels of the supply chain. Using unique industry, detailed loan data from China Development Bank, I find that government credits to infrastructure help firms expand in size, debt, employment, and sales per worker. Government credits to industries, which usually go to SOEs, help SOEs expand, but crowd private firms in the same industry. However, these industry loans help private firms in downstream industries. Overall, government credit from CDB supplemented the private sector with a contribution of approximately 22% to private sector growth from 1998 to 2009. These results shed light on the prior mixed empirical findings. I use municipal politicians' turnover timing as an instrument for loans from the CDB. I find that city secretaries borrowed more during their early terms, and I provide evidence that accords with the hypothesis that promotion is the incentive behind politicians' borrowing patterns. Although direct costs of government credit is essential (Lucas and Moore (2010), Lucas (2012a)) to evaluating government credit programs, they are beyond the scope of this paper. In future research, it is important to value the costs of these government loans to evaluate overall costs and benefits. Local-government indebtedness has a direct impact on housing prices and the shadow banking system in China. How does government credit affect households in China? What is the relationship between government credit and China's shadow banking system? Answers to these questions will elucidate China's government credit and the larger picture of the country's economy. 43 1.7 Bibliography Allen, Franklin, Jun Qian, and Meijun Qian. "Law, finance, and economic growth in China." Journal of financial economics.77.1 (2005): 57-116. Aschauer, David Alan, and Jeremy Greenwood. "Macroeconomic effects of fiscal policy." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. Vol. 23. (1985). Atkinson, Anthony Barnes, Joseph E. Stiglitz. "Lectures on public economics.", London, McGraw Hill (1980). Banerjee, Abhijit V. "A theory of misgovernance." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (1997): 1289-1332. Banerjee, Abhijit, Esther Duflo, and Nancy Qian. "On the road: Access to transportation infrastructure and economic growth in China." No. w17897. National Bureau of Economic Research (2012). Barro, Robert J. "Output Effects of Government Purchases." Journal of Political Economy 89 (1981): 1086-1121. Barro, Robert J. "Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth." Journal of Political Economy 98 (1990): S103-25. Baxter, Marianne, and Robert G. King. "Fiscal policy in general equilibrium." The American Economic Review (1993): 315-334. Bertrand, Marianne, Francis Kramarz, Antoinette Schoar and David Thesmar. "Politicians, Firms and the Political Business Cycle: Evidence from France" Working Paper, Chicago Booth (2007). Bertrand, Marianne, and Antoinette Schoar. "Managing with style: The effect of managers on firm policies." The Quarterly Journal of Economics (2003): 1169- 1208. Bertrand, Marianne, Antoinette Schoar, and David Thesmar. "Banking deregulation and industry structure: Evidence from the French banking reforms of 1985." The Journal of Finance 62.2 (2007): 597-628. Besanko, David, and Anjan V. Thakor. "Competitive equilibrium in the credit market under asymmetric information." Journal of Economic Theory 42.1 (1987): 167-182. Blanchard, Olivier, and Roberto Perotti. "An Empirical Characterization Of The Dynamic Effects Of Changes In Government Spending And Taxes On Output." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117.4 (2002): 1329-1368. Blanchard, Olivier, and Andrei Shleifer. "Federalism With and Without Political Centralization: China versus Russia, in Transition Economies: How Much Progress?" IMF Staff Papers (2001): 171-179. Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, and Jonas DM Fisher. "Fiscal shocks and their consequences." Journal of Economic theory 115.1 (2004): 89-117. Caballero, Ricardo J., Takeo Hoshi, and Anil K. Kashyap. "Zombie lending and depressed restructuring in Japan." The American Economic Review 98.5 (2008): 1943-1977. Caldara, Dario, and Christophe Kamps. "What are the effects of fiscal shocks? A VAR-based comparative analysis." No. 877. European Central Bank, (2008). 44 Carvalho, Daniel. "The Real Effects of Government-Owned Banks: Evidence from an Emerging Market." The Journal of Finance 69.2 (2014): 577-609. Cetorelli, Nicola, and Philip E. Strahan. "Finance as a barrier to entry: Bank competition and industry structure in local US markets." The Journal of Finance 61.1 (2006): 437-461. Chaney, Paul K., and Anjan V. Thakor. "Incentive effects of benevolent intervention: The case of government loan guarantees." Journal of Public Economics 26.2 (1985): 169-189. Chen, Ye, Hongbin Li, and Li-An Zhou. "Relative performance evaluation and the turnover of provincial leaders in China." Economics Letters 88.3 (2005): 421-425. Claessens, Stijn, Erik Feijen, and Luc Laeven. "Political connections and preferential access to finance: The role of campaign contributions." Journal of Financial Economics 88.3 (2008): 554-580. Clarke, George RG, and Robert Cull. "Political and Economic Determinants of the Likelihood of Privatizing Argentine Public Banks." Journalof Law and Economics 45.1 (2002): 165-197. Cohen, Lauren, Joshua D. Coval, and Christopher Malloy. "Do powerful politicians cause corporate downsizing?" Journal of Political Economy 119.6 (2011): 10151060. Cole, Shawn."Fixing market failures or fixing elections? Elections, banks and agricultural lending in India. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1 (2009): 219-250. Craig, Ben R., William E. Jackson, and James B. Thomson. "Small Firm Finance, Credit Rationing, and the Impact of SBA-Guaranteed Lending on Local Economic Growth." Journal of Small Business Management 45.1 (2007): 116-132. Demirguc-Kunt, Ash, and Vojislav Maksimovic. "Law, finance, and firm growth." The Journal of Finance 53.6 (1998): 2107-2137. Dinc, I. Serdar. "Politicians and banks: Political influences on governmentowned banks in emerging markets." Journal of Financial Economics 77.2 (2005): 453-479. Dinc, I. Serdar, and Nandini Gupta. "The decision to privatize: Finance and politics." The Journal of Finance 66.1 (2011): 241-269. Dyck, Alexander, and Luigi Zingales. "Private benefits of control: An international comparison." The Journal of Finance 59.2 (2004): 537-600. Elliott, Douglas J. "Uncle Sam in Pinstripes: Evaluating U.S. Federal Credit Programs." Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution (2011). Fatas, Antonio, and Ilian Mihov. "The effects of fiscal policy on consumption and employment: theory and evidence." Centre for Economic Policy Research Vol. 2760 (2001). Faulkender, Michael, and Rong Wang. "Corporate financial policy and the value of cash." The Journal of Finance 61.4 (2006): 1957-1990. Gale, William G. "Federal lending and the market for credit." Journalof Public Economics 42.2 (1990): 177-193. Gale, William G. "Economic effects of federal credit programs." The American Economic Review (1991): 133-152. 45 Gali Jordi, J. David Lopez-Salido, and Javier Valles, "Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption." Journal of the European Economic Association 5.1 (2007): 227-270. Gerschenkron, Alexander. "Economic backwardness in historical perspective." Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press (1962). Hanson, Samuel G., David S. Scharfstein, and Adi Sunderam. "Fiscal Risk and the Portfolio of Government Programs." HarvardBusiness School working paper (2014). Hart, Oliver, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. "The proper scope of government: theory and an application to prisons." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (1997): 1127:1162. Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter J. Klenow. "Misallocation and manufacturing TFP in China and India." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124.4 (2009): 1403:1448. Julio, Brandon, and Youngsuk Yook. "Political uncertainty and corporate investment cycles." The Journal of Finance 67.1 (2012): 45-83. Khwaja, Asim Ijaz, and Atif Mian. "Do lenders favor politically connected firms? Rent provision in an emerging financial market." The Quarterly Journal of Economics (2005): 1371-1411. King, Robert, and Ross Levine. "Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (1993a): 717-738. King, Robert, and Ross Levine. "Finance, entrepreneurship and growth." Journal of Monetary Economics 32 (1993b): 513-542. Kornai, Janos. "Resource-constrained versus demand-constrained systems." Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society (1979):801-819. La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. "Government ownership of banks." The Journal of Finance 57.1 (2002): 265-301. La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Guillermo Zamarripa. "Related Lending." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118.1 (2003): 231. Li, Hongbin, and Li-An Zhou. "Political turnover and economic performance: the incentive role of personnel control in China." Journal of public economics 89.9 (2005): 1743-1762. Lucas, Deborah and Damien Moore. "Guaranteed Versus Direct Lending: The Case of Student Loans" Measuring and Managing Federal Financial Risk, edited by D. Lucas, University of Chicago Press (2010). Lucas, Deborah. "Credit Policy as Fiscal Policy," MIT manuscript (2012b). MacRae, C. Duncan. "A political model of the business cycle." The Journal of PoliticalEconomy (1977): 239-263. Mankiw, N. Gregory. "The optimal collection of seigniorage: Theory and evidence." Journal of Monetary Economics 20.2 (1987): 327-341. Maskin, Eric, Yingyi Qian, and Chenggang Xu. "Incentives, information, and organizational form." The Review of Economic Studies 67.2 (2000): 359-378. Nordhaus, William D. "The political business cycle." The Review of Economic Studies (1975): 169-190. Rajan, Raghuram, and Luigi Zingales. "Financial dependence and growth." The American Economic Review 88 (1998): 559-586. 46 Ramey, Valerie A., and Matthew D. Shapiro. "Costly capital reallocation and the effects of government spending." Carnegie-RochesterConference Series on Public Policy. Vol. 48. (1998). Ramey, Valerie A. "Identifying government spending shocks: it's all in the timing." working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research, (2009). Rotemberg, Julio J., and Michael Woodford. "Oligopolistic pricing and the effects of aggregate demand on economic activity." Journal of political Economy (1992): 1153-1207. Sachs, Jeffrey, and Alberto Alesina. "Political Parties and the Business Cycle in the United States, 1948-1984." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 20 (1988):6382. Sapienza, Paola. "The effects of government ownership on bank lending." Journal of FinancialEconomics 72.2 (2004): 357-384. Schwarz, Anita M. "How Effective are Directed Credit Policies in the United States?: A Literature Survey." Vol. 1019. World Bank Publications (1992). Shaffer, Sherrill, and Robert N. Collender. "Federal Credit Programs and Local Economic Performance." Economic Development Quarterly 23.1 (2009): 28-43. Shleifer, Andrei. "State vs. Private Ownership." Journal of Economic Perspectives (1998): 133-150. Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. "Politicians and firms." The Quarterly Journal of Economics (1994): 995-1025. Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. "The grabbing hand: Government pathologies and their cures." Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press (2002). Stiglitz, Joseph E., and Andrew Weiss. "Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information." The American Economic review (1981): 393-410. Townsend, Robert M. "Optimal contracts and competitive markets with costly state verification." Journal of Economic Theory 21.2 (1979): 265-293. Williamson, Stephen D. "Do informational frictions justify federal credit programs?." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking (1994): 523-544. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. "Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data." Cambridge, MA: MIT Press (2002). 47 Figure 1-1: CDB Outstanding Loan Amount and New Issuance CDB Total City Loan Amount CDB City Loan New Issuance S0~ 8 8 0: 5- 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Year Total outstanding Loan Loan for Industry Firms - 1998 1999 Loan for Intastructure 4 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Year Total Issuance Issuance for Industry Firms -0- CDB Province Loan New Issuance CDB Total Province Loan Amount - S Issuance for Infrastruclure 4 8 S0~ 0 S0~ 0- 0 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 Year Total Outstanding Loan Loan for Industry Firms -6--- 2007 2009 2011 2013 1997 Loan for Intastructure - 2001 2003 2005 Year Total Issuance Issuance for Industry Firms --- Ratio of Infrastructure Loan to Total Loan Amount / 1999 2007 2009 2011 2013 Issuance for Infrastructure - Ratio of Industry Loan to Total Loan Amount '---a-. -C 9 A -A - 04 C 0-1 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Year -- a-- ---- Top 25 Percentile 4 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Year Top 25 Percentile ---- Median Ratio Bottom 25 Percentile - -- -+- Median Ratio Bottom 25 Percentile Figure 1-1 includes the plots of CDB outstanding loan amount and new issuance. The loans can be separated into infrastructure loan and the loan for industry firms. Infrastructure includes transportation(e.g.,road, railway, airport, bridge, tunnel), water supply, energy supply(e.g., gas,electric), telecommunication and public service(e.g., Sewage discharge) The top two panels are the loans at city level from 1998 to 2010. City level loan doesn't include the province level projects even though part of the project is located in the city such as high way. The middle 2 panels are the loans at province level from 1998 to 2013. The unit is billion RMB. The bottom 2 panels are ratios of infrastructure loan and industry loan to the total city level loan amount respectively. The solid lines are median ratio among 310 cities and dash lines are top and bottom quartile of ratios among 310 cities each year. 48 Figure 1-2: Political Turnover in China Histogram of City Secretaries' Tenure 0 0 - LL 1 2 3 4 5 6 Length of Tenure 7 8 9 10 Histogram of City Secretaries' Turnover Year 0 U- 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Turnover Year 2009 2011 2013 City Secretaries' Turnover Year(Tenure is not 5 years) - C1. 1997 1999 2001 2007 2003 2005 Turnover Year 2009 2011 2013 Figure 1-2 includes the plots of city level political turnover in China. The top panel is the histogram of city secretaries term length from 1997 to 2013 among 334 cities and 1,227 city secretaries. I round the monthly turnover data into year frequency by using June as the cutoff. 43% of the city secretaries leave the city in their fifth year. The middle panel is the histogram of the turnover year of all city secretaries from 1997 to 2013 among 334 cities and 1,227 city secretaries. The bottom panel is the histogram of the turnover year of the sub sample of city secretaries whose term is not 5 years. It is also from 1997 to 2013 among 306 cities and 689 city secretaries. The bottom penal shows that if the tenure is not 5 years (e.g, 4 or 6 years), the turnover usually happens in national turnover years. 49 Figure 1-3: Local Government Borrowing City Secretary's Borrowing Pattern 0 C-4 a)C- I I 0)- 0 5 PoliticianYear Cycle 10 II CD0 0 E M 0 -j LO 0D 15 ----- Loan Amount w/o Fixed Effects Figure 1-3 is the plots of logarithm of CDB city total loan amounts after taking out the year fixed effects, city fixed effects and politician fixed effects. The horizontal axis is the cycle of city secretary turnover. There are 3 cycles in total and every cycle has 5 years. From 1998 to 2010, there are 3 national turnover cycles: 1997 to 2002, 2003 to 2007, and 2007 to 2012. The left vertical axis PolitianYearis the number of years that city secretary has been staying in the city, which is from 1 to 5 years. For example, the first cycle (1 to 5 on horizontal axis) is from 1998 to 2002. I cluster the cities by PolitianYear(1to 5 years) from 1998 to 2002 and plot the average CDB city loan amounts for each bin of PolitianYear. I do the same thing for the second cycle from 2003 to 2007 which is from 6 to 10 in the horizontal line. For the third cycle is from 2008 to 2010 which is from 11 to 15 in the horizontal line. 50 Figure 1-4: Manufacturing Firms in China Number of Firms in Chinese Manufacturing Sector C~) - 0 LL 0 0 C 00 z I I I I 1998 1999 2000 2001 I I 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Year SOEs Number Foreign Firm Number 0 A * Private Firm Number Aggregate Assets in Chinese Manufacturing Sector C%1 . 0 C'- 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Year S SOEs Asset A Private Firm Asset Foreign Firm Asset Figure 1-4 includes the plots of aggregate firm assets and firm numbers in manufacturing sector of China. The data is the Chinese Industry Census(CIC) from 1998 to 2009 which includes all the manufacturing firms with annual sales more than 5 million RMB($ 700,000). The top panel is the firm numbers of SOEs, private firms and foreign firms from 1998 to 2009. The unit is thousand. The bottom panel is the aggregate firm assets of SOEs, private firms and foreign firms from 1998 to 2009. The unit is trillion RMB. 51 Figure 1-5: SOEs' Fixed Asset Patterns Logarithm of Fixed Asset, High CDB Loan Logarithm of Fixed Asset, Low CDB Loan a,- Nl OD 1998 1999 2006 260 2002 20 2Cr04 2005 2006 2007 2008 2D'09 Year Early Years(1 to 3) 0. - -- 1998 1999 2000 2001 Later Years(4 to 6) 2002 2003 2004 205 2006 Year Early Years(1 to 3) Logarithm of Fixed Asset, High Corp Tax Rate -- 2007 208 2009 Later Years(4 to 6) 0-- Logarithm of Fixed Asset, Low Corp Tax Rate Wt. A ~ ,/ M 4k/ 1998 1999 2000 2001 ~-.. 2002 2003 Earty Years(1 to 3) 2004 2005 2006 2007 Year -- 2008 2009 ,- ,- 1998 1999 2000 2001 &r-Later Years(4 to 6) S Logarithm of Fixed Asset, Large Developed Land ~ 20 -- 4 - I 2003 2004 2005 Year Early Years(1 to 3) -- 4 - -- 2006 2007 200 2009 Later Year( o6 Logarithm of Fixed Asset, Small Developed Land al~ , 0 re 1968 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Year --e Earty Years(1 to 3) --- 1998 Later Years(4 to 6) 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Early Years(1 Year to 3) ---- 2006 2007 2008 2009 Later Years(4 to 6) Figure 1-5 includes the plots of patterns of average SOEs' fixed assets from 1998 to 2009 in the cities where secretaries are in the early terms and late terms. The vertical axis is the average logarithm of SOEs' fixed assets. The top 2 panels are stratified on CDB loan amount. The left panel is the pattern for high CDB industry loan cities and the right panel is the pattern for high CDB industry loan cities. "high" and "low" categories are defined as the top and bottom quartile of CDB city level outstanding industry loan amount distribution among 310 cities each year. The middle 2 panels are stratified on average effective corporate tax rate in the city. The left panel is the pattern for high effective corporate tax rate cities and the right panel is the pattern for low effective corporate tax rate cities. "high" and "low" categories are defined as the top and bottom quartile of average effective corporate tax rate distribution among 310 cities each year. The bottom 2 panels are stratified on city developed land amount. The left panel is the pattern for cities with high developed land and the right panel is the pattern for the cities with low developed land. "high" and "low" categories are defined as the top and bottom quartile of developed land amount distribution among 310 cities each year. The dash lines are for the cities where secretaries are in the early terms(1 to 3 year). The solid lines are for the cities where secretaries are in the late terms(4 to 6 year). 52 , Figure 1-6: SOEs' Employment Patterns Logarithm of Employment, Low CDB Loan Logarithm of Employment, High CDB Loan N Wi * I' - In / ~6--- p I / I / I 4 I I -I 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Year 1998 1999 2000 201 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Year Early Years(1 to 3) Later Years(4 to 6) 6-+- Early Years(1 ---- to 3) Later Years(4 to 6) ----- Logarithm of Employment, Low Corp Tax Rate Logarithm of Employment, High Corp Tax Rate N. Ln C4 W) 9| 6 \k / \ ID 4, 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2 02 2003 2004 2005 206 2007 2008 2009 Year --- Early Years(1 to 3) -- Early Years(1 to 3) Later Years(4to6) 6-- Logarithm of Employment, Large Developed Land ci. *0 Later Years(4 to 6) Logarithm of Employment, Small Developed Land A ,, -- * 0 / , -- 0-- ,/ I / / / E I / - ~0 I / I Q 1W \~ U I / I 6 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 1998 1999 2000 201 2 02 2003 200 2005 2 06 2 07 2 08 2009 Year Early Years(1 to 3) ---- 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Year Later Years(4 to 6) Early Years(1 to 3) -- 6-- Later Years(4 to 6) Figure 1-6 includes the plots of patterns of average SOEs' number of employees from 1998 to 2009 in the cities where secretaries are in the early terms and late terms. The vertical axis is the average logarithm of SOEs' employee numbers. The top 2 panels are stratified on CDB loan amount. The left panel is the pattern for high CDB industry loan cities and the right panel is the pattern for high CDB industry loan cities. "high" and "low" categories are defined as the top and bottom quartile of CDB city level outstanding industry loan amount distribution among 310 cities each year. The middle 2 panels are stratified on average effective corporate tax rate in the city. The left panel is the pattern for high effective corporate tax rate cities and the right panel is the pattern for low effective corporate tax rate cities. "high" and "low" categories are defined as the top and bottom quartile of average effective corporate tax rate distribution among 310 cities each year. The bottom 2 panels are stratified on city developed land amount. The left panel is the pattern for cities with high developed land and the right panel is the pattern for the cities with low developed land. "high" and "low" categories are defined as the top and bottom quartile of developed land amount distribution among 310 cities each year. The dash lines are for the cities where secretaries are in the early terms(1 to 3 year). The solid lines are for the cities where secretaries are in the late terms(4 to 6 year). 53 Figure 1-7: Shifts of CDB Industry Loan Over Time CDB Outstanding Loan Issuance in 1998 (BIllion E eipowwem nd ha RMB) WOW pvOmton udWWPy cow Mk" WWdDneoftg Parolimm Idnaua eaIrmdo Opr an rdrkv - roduttsnUme0w0r w cheicatmetaM Tr.60owrbda0qudmut nuaamt T40u3wr proztionanda dn-mean- * cO.i~ua..IfnnuJ~uIra m'' 1 pgdu 0 100 00 200 5O 400 600 CDB Outstanding Loan issuance in 2010 (Billion RMB) Ekwtric pou, om anrd hot wam producton nd gappIV PffostjbOurdmntr Nfinram60Nfr*mm Tmn-traus N" M6*ude wpmrV4 COMMOee prduandsapmef 0 Me 4W0 6no 60 I 100 140 160 180 Figure 1-7 are plots of top 10 industries which have the biggest loan issuance from CDB. Data is restricted to CDB province level industry loan data. There are 41 manufacturing industries in total among 31 provinces in China. The top penal shows the CDB's biggest 10 industries in 1998. The amount of each industry is the sum of all CDB loan issuance amounts from all 31 provinces in China. The bottom penal shows the CDB's biggest 10 industries in 2010. The amount of each industry is the sum of all CDB loan issuance amounts from all 31 provinces in China. The unit is billion RMB. 54 Table 1.1: Summary Statistics Data Panel A: City Data Variable LoanCity IssuanceCity Loan _ INF _City IssuanceINF_City LoanINDCity Issuance _IND_ City N 3,605 3,605 3,605 3,605 3,605 3,605 3,587 3,568 3,587 3,579 3,605 3,325 3,605 3,158 Min 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 32.00 0.00 0.00 Max 1,268.20 0.01 0.08 S.D. 69.01 26.76 30.37 12.21 51.54 18.77 782.80 8,047.79 60.98 18,000.38 1.32 4.22 0.10 0.28 3,605 0.38 0.48 0.00 1.00 N 44,733 44,733 Mean 8.09 2.81 S.D. 43.33 16.23 Min 0.00 0.00 Max 1,369.09 1,004.12 LoanRoad Loan Rail 496 496 154.18 51.44 163.63 102.32 0 0 744.87 1260.99 Loan_ Water 496 12.60 23.95 0 203.29 Loan Tel 496 8.55 41.03 0 419.93 Panel C: Firm Data Variable N Mean S.D. Min Max LogAsset LogFixAst 2,949,514 2,933,323 9.72 8.46 1.48 1.77 0.00 0.00 20.16 19.11 LogWorker LogDebt 2,944,543 2,930,818 4.69 8.98 1.17 1.73 0.00 0.00 12.58 19.32 ROA Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales 2,949,502 2,918,158 2,931,478 0.09 5.25 9.95 0.20 1.24 1.46 -0.76 -8.12 0.00 2.44 17.38 19.24 Tax_ Corp 1,520,597 19.41 10.24 0.00 61.54 Tax VAT 1,356,623 15.09 13.92 0.00 86.91 GDP AvgIncome FiscalIncome Employment PoliticianYear Age Gender Relation Promotion Panel B: Province Data Variable Loan_PI Issuance_PI Mean 31.97 11.31 10.92 4.20 21.34 7.13 559.46 10,799.02 30.43 1,108.81 2.49 50.11 428.79 593.74 195.03 847.77 284.22 10,604.48 139,574.00 1,138.31 329,858.30 6.00 62.00 1.00 1.00 Panel A restricted to 310 cities from 1998 to 2010. LoanCity and IssuanceCity are the city level total CDB outstanding loan amount and new issuance. LoanINFCity and Issuance INFCity are the city level total CDB outstanding loan amount and new issuance for infrastructure. LoanINDCity and IssuanceIND_City are the city level total CDB outstanding loan amount and new issuance for industry firms. The unit of LoanCity to IssuanceIND_City is 100 million RMB. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. Age is the age of the city secretary. Gender is the dummy for whether the city secretary is a female. Relation is the dummy for whether the city secretary is born at the same place as the province governor. Promition is the dummy for whether the city secretary is promoted or not at the end of the term. Panel B restricted to 31 provinces from 1998 to 2013 among 95 industries. Loan_PI and Issuance_PIare the province level CDB industry outstanding loan amount and new issuance. There are 31 provinces and 95 industries in total. The total observation number is 44,733 which covers all 95 industries. Among these 95 industries, CDB added 11 new industries in 2005 and doesn't have data before 2005. LoanRoad, LoanRail, LoanWater, and LoanTel are the province level CDB industry outstanding loan amounts for road construction, railway construction, water system, and Telecommunication. The number of observations is 496 which covers 31 provinces from 1998 to 2013. The unit is in 100 million RMB.Panel C restricted to all manufacturing firms in Chinese Industry Census data from 1998 to 2009. LogAsset is the logarithm of each firm's total asset. Tax Corp is the corporate tax rate of each firm every year. TaxVAT is the value-added tax rate of each firm every year.For more detailed variable definition and construction, please see Appendix Table 1.10. 55 Table 1.2: CDB Loan's Effect on Firms: Evidence from OLS Regressions Panel A: SOEs Dependent Variable Log(Loan_ PI) GDPt_ 1 AvgIncomet- 1 FiscalIncomet-1 Employmentt- 1 Fixed Effects Observations R-squared Panel B:Private Firms Dependent Variable Log(LoanPI) GDPt-1 AvgIncomet -1 FiscalIncomet -I Employmentt_1 Fixed Effects Observations R-squared Panel C:Private Firms Dependent Variable Log(Loan INF City) GDPt_1 AvgIncomet-i FiscalIncomet Employment_ Fixed Effects Observations R-squared -1 (1) LogAsset (4) (3) (2) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt 0.006*** (0.002) -0.055*** (0.014) 0.002 (0.001) 0.156 (0.161) 0.001 (0.001) Yes 231,682 0.093 0.003 (0.003) -0.117*** (0.020) 0.001 (0.001) 0.393* (0.220) (1) LogAsset (5) ROA (6) (7) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales -0.002*** (0.001) 0.011*** (0.003) 0.000 (0.000) -0.174*** (0.038) -0.000 (0.000) Yes 231,682 0.008 -0.010*** (0.003) -0.010 (0.015) 0.000 (0.001) -0.570*** (0.174) 0.002* (0.001) Yes 225,214 0.189 (4) (3) (2) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt (5) ROA (6) (7) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales -0.003** (0.001) -0.013** (0.006) 0.000 (0.000) -0.324*** (0.062) 0.001** (0.000) Yes 756,826 0.219 -0.007*** (0.002) -0.049*** (0.009) -0.002*** (0.001) -0.423*** (0.086) 0.000 (0.001) Yes 753,444 0.107 -0.004*** (0.000) -0.001 (0.001) -0.000 (0.000) -0.209*** (0.012) 0.000 (0.000) Yes 755,947 0.033 -0.016*** (0.001) 0.025*** (0.006) -0.001** (0.000) -1.197*** (0.058) 0.000 (0.000) Yes 756,820 0.225 (1) LogAsset (4) (3) (2) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt (5) ROA (6) (7) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales 0.013*** (0.003) -0.046*** (0.006) -0.000 (0.000) -0.123** (0.055) 0.694 (0.688) Yes 1,022,595 0.215 0.012*** (0.004) -0.041*** (0.008) -0.001*** (0.000) -0.294*** (0.078) 2.804*** (0.912) Yes 1,017,890 0.108 0.002*** (0.001) -0.014*** (0.002) -0.000 (0.000) -0.136*** (0.012) 1.092*** (0.156) Yes 1,022,586 0.058 0.041*** (0.003) -0.139*** (0.006) 0.000 (0.000) -0.290*** (0.055) 3.445*** (0.627) Yes 1,021,059 0.245 -0.001* (0.001) Yes 230,283 0.040 0.010*** 0.017*** (0.002) -0.046*** (0.013) 0.001* (0.001) 0.309** (0.140) -0.001 (0.001) Yes 232,003 0.028 (0.003) -0.106*** (0.018) 0.002* (0.001) 0.215 (0.203) 0.000 (0.001) Yes 229,696 0.054 -0.007*** (0.001) 0.001 (0.005) 0.000 (0.000) -0.306*** (0.054) 0.001** (0.000) Yes 757,033 0.013 -0.010*** (0.002) 0.004 (0.005) -0.000 (0.000) -0.350*** (0.050) 1.295** (0.544) Yes 1,022,954 0.034 0.003* (0.002) -0.015* (0.008) 0.002*** (0.001) -0.036 (0.079) 0.002*** (0.001) Yes 752,871 0.081 0.009** (0.004) -0.063*** (0.008) 0.000 (0.000) 0.078 (0.072) -0.360 (0.945) Yes 1,016,623 0.091 -0.001 (0.003) -0.060*** (0.018) 0.001 (0.001) -0.311 (0.197) 0.001 (0.001) Yes 227,342 0.152 -0.022*** (0.001) 0.025*** (0.007) -0.000 (0.000) -1.499*** (0.067) 0.001** (0.000) Yes 755,687 0.273 0.032*** (0.003) -0.137*** (0.007) -0.000 (0.000) -0.627*** (0.059) 4.630*** (0.702) Yes 1,021,245 0.281 Note. In Penal A and B, Loan_ PI is at provincex industryx year level. It is the CDB industry loan (to SOEs) amount at each of the 31 provinces and 41 manufacturing industries. In Panel A, data is restricted to SOEs in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. It shows the OLS regression results by estimating equation 1.1. In Panel B, data is restricted to private firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are province level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect and firm fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level.In Panel C, LoanINFCity is the CDB infrastructure loan amount at city x year level. Data is restricted to private firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009 among 310 cities. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect and firm fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. 56 Table 1.3: Exogeneity of City Secretary Turnover Timing NationalCycle (1) Coefficient (2) Coefficient (3) Coefficient (4) Coefficient (5) Hazard Ratio 0.366*** (0.061) 0.340*** (0.064) 0.019** (0.008) 0.363*** 0.332*** 1.393 (0.063) 0.087 (0.462) (0.065) 0.018** (0.008) 0.133 (0.297) 0.044 (0.459) -0.164 -0.118 (0.536) 0.002 (0.011) -0.003 (0.012) (0.537) -0.000 (0.011) -0.000 (0.012) 0.769 2.167 2.755 (0.857) (4.034) (3.936) -1.658 -2.457 (4.720) -0.008 (0.010) 0.009 (0.010) 0.028 (0.043) -0.025 (0.041) (4.634) -0.006 (0.009) 0.007 (0.009) 0.033 (0.048) -0.030 (0.045) 2,878 36.51 2,652 Age Gender 0.123 GDPt_1 (0.293) -0.065 (0.067) -0.058 (0.064) GDPt-2 -0.001 (0.003) AvgIncomet-1 -0.001 (0.004) AvgIncomet-2 0.807 (0.837) FiscalIncomet -1 FiscalIncomet -2 0.000 (0.001) Employmentt-1 0.000 (0.001) Employment t-2 Log(LoanCityt_1) 0.001 (0.019) 2 ) Log(LoanCityt- 0.002 (0.018) Observations 3,012 Chi Squared 36.84 2,775 38.07 34.91 1.019 1.142 1.045 0.888 1.000 1.000 15.722 0.086 0.994 1.007 1.033 0.970 2,652 34.91 Note. The regressions are estimated at city x year level. Data restricted to 1,106 city secretaries among 310 cites from 1998 to 2011. Table shows the results from Cox proportional hazard regression by following Wooldridge(2002). Estimated coefficients are reported in column 1 to 4. Age is the city secretary's age. Gender is the dummy for whether the city secretary is female or not. NationalCycle is the dummy for whether it is the year of national congress party(1998, 2003 and 2008). GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. Log(Loan_ City) is the logarithm of CDB city level total outstanding loan amount. Column 1 and 2 only controls GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment one year ago. Column 3 and 4 controls GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment in the last two years. The time-varying variables are Age, NationalCycle, GDAvgIncome, FiscalIncome, Employment and Log(LoanCity). I assume these time-varying variables are constant during one year. Gender is time-invariant. Column 2 and 4 includes all the time-varying and time-invariant variables. Column 1 and 3 excludes Gender and Age of the city secretaries since these two variables has many missing values. Column 5 is the estimated hazard ratio from column 4. Standard errors are clustered at city secretary's level. 57 Table 1.4: City Secretary Turnover Timing's Effect on Borrowing from CDB Panel A Total Loan (1) (2) Dependent Variable LogLoanCity LogIssueCity PoliticianYear GDPt-1 AvgIncomet -1 FiscalIncomet -1 Employmentt-i Fixed Effects Observations R-squared -0.364*** (0.020) -0.269* (0.138) -0.004** (0.002) 0.874 (1.197) -0.954 (5.875) Yes 3,127 0.853 -0.308*** (0.029) 0.018 (0.167) -0.001 (0.007) -1.040 (1.428) 11.682** (5.870) Yes 2,795 0.685 Loan for Infrastructure Loan for Industry Firms (3) (4) LogLoanCity LogIssueCity (6) (5) LogLoanCity LogIssueCity -0.122*** (0.013) -0.222* (0.123) 0.004 (0.004) -0.449 (0.817) -2.004 (5.254) Yes 2,449 0.884 -0.165*** (0.025) 0.091 (0.296) -0.001 (0.007) -2.549 (2.250) 3.287 (6.935) Yes 2,227 0.588 -0.338*** (0.028) -0.156 (0.145) -0.005** (0.002) 0.837 (1.309) -9.066 (6.758) Yes 2,727 0.756 -0.252*** (0.037) -0.011 (0.205) -0.004 (0.007) 1.552 (2.031) -30.014*** (10.539) Yes 2,323 0.597 Panel B Total Loan (1) (2) Dependent Variable LogLoanCity LogIssueCity Year_2 Year_3 Year_4 Year_5 Year_6 GDPt-1 AvgIncomet 1 FiscalIncomet _i EmploymenttFixed Effects Observations R-squared 1 -0.386*** (0.031) -0.749*** (0.042) -1.071*** (0.063) -1.429*** (0.108) -1.900*** (0.144) -0.264* (0.138) -0.004** (0.002) 0.859 (1.196) -1.205 (5.867) Yes 3,127 0.854 -0.357*** (0.057) -0.660*** (0.074) -0.912*** (0.089) -1.318*** (0.168) -1.581*** (0.196) 0.022 (0.167) -0.001 (0.007) -1.089 (1.432) -11.934** (5.917) Yes 2,795 0.685 Loan for Infrastructure Loan for Industry Firms (3) (4) LogLoan City LogIssueCity (6) (5) LogLoanCity LogIssueCity -0.109*** (0.028) -0.240*** (0.035) -0.351*** (0.041) -0.467*** (0.081) -0.691*** (0.110) -0.223* (0.123) 0.004 (0.004) -0.439 (0.836) -1.976 (5.271) Yes 2,449 0.884 -0.167*** (0.063) -0.298*** (0.070) -0.509*** (0.082) -0.691*** (0.172) -0.870*** (0.218) 0.087 (0.300) -0.001 (0.007) -2.556 (2.277) 3.167 (6.973) Yes 2,227 0.588 -0.330*** (0.044) -0.703*** (0.064) -1.001*** (0.086) -1.341*** (0.151) -1.668*** (0.204) -0.154 (0.145) -0.005** (0.002) 0.856 (1.316) -8.969 (6.773) Yes 2,727 0.756 -0.327*** (0.081) -0.540*** (0.099) -0.731*** (0.123) -1.238*** (0.216) -1.337*** (0.240) -0.014 (0.202) -0.004 (0.007) 1.461 (2.011) -30.738*** (10.516) Yes 2,323 0.599 Note. The regressions are estimated at city x year level. Data restricted to CDB city level loan to 310 cites from 1998 to 2010. Panel A shows the results from OLS regression from equation 1.3. PoliticianYear is the number of years that the secretary has been staying in the city. Column 1 and 2 are the regressions on the logarithm of total CDB loan outstanding amount and total issuance respectively. Column 3 and 4 are the regressions on the logarithm of CDB infrastructure loan outstanding amount and new issuance respectively. Column 5 and 6 are the regressions on the logarithm of CDB industry firm loan outstanding amount and new issuance respectively. GDP, AvgIncom, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, city fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at city level. Panel B shows the results from OLS regression from equation 1.4. Year_2 is the the dummy for whether it is the second of the secretary in the city. Year_3 is the the dummy for whether it is the third of the secretary in the city. Year_4 to Year_6 are defined in the same way. The dummy for year 1 is the missing category. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, city fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at city level. 58 Table 1.5: City Secretary's Turnover Effects on Firms Panel A: SOEs Dependent Variable Year_2 Year_3 Year_4 Year_5 Year_6 GDPt_ 1 AvgIncomet - 1 FiscalIncomet - I Employmentt -1 Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Politician Fixed Effect City Fixed Effect Observations R-squared (1) LogAsset (2) LogFixAst (3) LogWorker (4) LogDebt (5) ROA (6) LogNumber -0.019*** (0.007) -0.032** (0.013) -0.047** (0.020) -0.075*** (0.027) -0.091*** (0.034) -0.021 (0.013) 0.000 (0.001) -0.243** (0.112) -0.008** (0.004) Yes Yes Yes No 382,317 0.108 -0.023*** (0.009) -0.042** (0.017) -0.056** (0.026) -0.098*** (0.035) -0.115*** (0.044) -0.095*** (0.019) 0.000 (0.001) 0.031 (0.160) -0.009 (0.007) Yes Yes Yes No 379,632 0.0523 -0.006 (0.006) -0.021* (0.012) -0.025 (0.017) -0.031 (0.023) -0.044 (0.030) -0.022* (0.013) 0.000 (0.001) 0.197* (0.112) -0.002 (0.002) Yes Yes Yes No 381,720 0.0642 -0.028*** (0.010) -0.043** (0.019) -0.065** (0.028) -0.097** (0.038) -0.128*** (0.048) -0.081*** (0.018) 0.000 (0.001) -0.105 (0.151) -0.010 (0.006) Yes Yes Yes No 378,567 0.0647 0.010*** (0.002) (0.007) 0.035*** (0.008) 0.003 (0.004) -0.000 (0.000) -0.107*** (0.027) -0.001 (0.002) Yes Yes Yes No 382,318 0.0437 0.019 (0.015) 0.056*** (0.018) 0.076*** (0.024) 0.035 (0.049) 0.070 (0.050) -0.035 (0.094) 0.004** (0.002) 1.813 (1.278) -0.003*** (0.001) Yes No Yes Yes 3,250 0.963 (1) LogAsset (2) LogFixAst (3) LogWorker (4) LogDebt (5) ROA (6) LogNumber -0.015*** (0.005) -0.032*** (0.009) -0.058*** (0.014) -0.096*** (0.019) -0.081*** (0.024) -0.047*** (0.006) -0.000 (0.000) -0.132*** (0.051) -0001 (0.001) Yes Yes Yes No 1,171,115 0.234 -0.008 (0.006) -0.011 (0.012) -0.022 (0.018) -0.060** (0.025) -0.008 (0.031) -0.039*** (0.008) -0.001*** (0.000) -0.257*** (0.073) 0.001 (0.001) Yes Yes Yes No 1,165,459 0.117 -0.004 (0.004) -0.005 (0.008) -0.013 (0.011) -0.025* (0.015) 0.002 (0.019) 0.003 (0.005) -0.001** (0.000) -0.269*** (0.047) -0.000 (0.001) Yes Yes Yes No 1,171,449 0.0317 -0.012* (0.007) -0.038*** (0.013) -0.070*** (0.019) -0.095*** (0.025) -0.111*** (0.032) -0.064*** (0.008) 0.000 (0.000) 0.072 (0.067) 0.000 (0.001) Yes Yes Yes No 1,163,749 0.103 -0.003*** (0.001) -0.003 (0.002) 0.002 (0.003) 0.006 (0.004) 0.008 (0.005) -0.008*** (0.001) -0.000 (0.000) -0.128*** (0.012) -0.001* (0.001) Yes Yes Yes No 1,171,106 0.0625 0.085*** (0.019) 0.144*** (0.021) 0.177*** (0.030) 0.212*** (0.056) 0.283*** (0.053) -0.091 (0.115) 0.003 (0.004) 2.394 (1.690) -0.001** (0.001) Yes No Yes Yes 3,233 0.974 0.017*** (0.003) 0.024*** (0.005) 0.028*** Panel B: Private Firms Dependent Variable Year_2 Year_3 Year_4 Year_5 Year_6 GDPt_ 1 AvgIncomet 1 FiscalIncomet -1 Employmentt -1 Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Politician Fixed Effect City Fixed Effect Observations R-squared 59 Table 1.5: City Secretary's Turnover Effects on Firms(Continue) Panel C: Foreign Firms Dependent Variable Year_2 Year_3 Year_4 Year_5 Year_6 (1) LogAsset (3) (4) (2) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt (5) ROA (6) LogNumber 0.020*** (0.007) 0.028** (0.014) 0.043** (0.021) 0.059** (0.029) 0.017* (0.010) 0.034* (0.019) -0.001 (0.002) -0.001 (0.003) 0.000 (0.005) 0.008 (0.007) 0.016** (0.008) -0.001 (0.002) 0.000* (0.000) -0.121*** (0.016) -0.001 (0.001) Yes Yes Yes No 256,887 0.0292 0.063*** (0.020) 0.120*** (0.027) 0.127*** (0.040) 0.141* (0.083) 0.311*** (0.064) -0.093 (0.116) 0.001 (0.001) 1.952 (1.597) -0.003*** (0.001) Yes No Yes Yes 2,976 0.968 0.110*** (0.036) GDPt- 1 -0.019*** (0.007) AvgIncomet-1j 0.000 (0.000) FiscalIncomet _1 -0.485*** (0.062) Employmentt_1-0.002 (0.007) Year Fixed Effect Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Politician Fixed Effect Yes City Fixed Effect No Observations 256,887 R-squared 0.175 0.056* (0.029) 0.075* (0.039) 0.164*** (0.050) 0.000 (0.010) -0.000 (0.001) -0.652*** (0.085) -0.003 (0.008) Yes Yes Yes No 255,976 0.0541 0.009 (0.007) 0.039*** (0.013) 0.043** (0.019) 0.081*** (0.026) (0.033) 0.047*** (0.007) 0.001* (0.000) 0.008 (0.011) -0.001 (0.022) -0.001 (0.032) -0.003 (0.044) 0.018 (0.055) -0.059*** (0.012) 0.001 (0.001) -0.262*** -0.334*** (0.064) -0.002 (0.005) (0.094) -0.002 (0.009) Yes Yes Yes No 255,513 0.0601 0.141*** Yes Yes Yes No 256,652 0.0673 Note. Data restricted to manufacturing firms in Chinese Industry Census data from 1998 to 2009 among 310 cities. Year_2 to Year_6 are at the city x year level. Panel A is for SOEs. Panel B is for private firms and Panel C is for foreign firms. Column 1 is the logarithm of total asset of the firm. Column 2 is the logarithm of fixed asset of the firm. Column 3 is the logarithm of total number of workers of the firm. Column 4 is the logarithm of total debt of the firm. Column 5 is the ROA of the firm. Year_2 is the the dummy for whether it is the second of the secretary in the city where the firm locates. Year_3 is the the dummy for whether it is the third of the secretary in the city. Year 4 to Year__6 are defined in the same way. The dummy for year 1 is the missing category. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. Column 1 to 5 are controlled by year fixed effect, firm fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. Column 6 is the logarithm of total number of firms in each city every year. Column 6 is controlled by year fixed effect, city fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. 60 Table 1.6: Opposing Effects of CDB City Infrastructure Loan and Industry Loan (Use Secretary Year in Office as Instrument) Panel A: Private Firms Dependent Variable Log(Loan _IND_ City) Log(LoanINF City) GDPt_1 AvgIncomet_1 FiscalIncomet-1 Employmentt_ 1 Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Politician Fixed Effect Observations Wald F-stat (1) LogAsset (4) (3) (2) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt (5) ROA (7) (6) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales -0.073*** (0.016) 0.246*** (0.033) 0.019* (0.010) -0.001*** (0.000) -0.191*** (0.050) 0.814 (0.725) Yes Yes Yes 851,720 474.3 -0.165*** (0.022) 0.236*** (0.046) 0.026* (0.014) -0.003*** (0.000) -0.434*** (0.070) 3.296*** (0.959) Yes Yes Yes 847,260 472.1 0.001 (0.005) -0.023** (0.009) -0.017*** (0.003) 0.000 (0.000) -0.148*** (0.011) 1.434*** (0.157) Yes Yes Yes 851,712 474.4 -0.134*** (0.018) 0.544*** (0.037) 0.013 (0.011) -0.002*** (0.000) -0.526*** (0.052) 3.664*** (0.707) Yes Yes Yes 850,374 478.0 (1) LogAsset (4) (3) (2) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt (5) ROA (7) (6) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales -0.104*** (0.023) 0.062** (0.031) 0.015 (0.014) -0.000 (0.000) -0.404*** (0.073) -3.892*** (1.169) Yes Yes Yes 194,732 288.4 -0.146*** (0.034) 0.059 (0.046) 0.033 (0.020) -0.001 (0.001) -0.574*** (0.101) -3.104* (1.670) Yes Yes Yes 194,108 284.1 -0.011 (0.007) -0.001 (0.009) -0.001 (0.004) 0.000* (0.000) -0.148*** (0.019) 0.312 (0.316) Yes Yes Yes 194,732 288.4 -0.109*** (0.026) 0.167*** (0.040) -0.022 (0.018) 0.002*** (0.000) -0.459*** (0.080) 3.241** (1.471) Yes Yes Yes 194,313 282.4 -0.021 (0.014) 0.052* (0.028) 0.021** (0.009) -0.001*** (0.000) -0.366*** (0.045) 1.358** (0.579) Yes Yes Yes 852,039 477.2 0.005 (0.023) 0.161*** (0.047) -0.027* (0.015) -0.000 (0.000) 0.137** (0.066) -1.474 (0.972) Yes Yes Yes 846,406 471.5 -0.146*** (0.019) 0.576*** (0.039) 0.028** (0.012) -0.002*** (0.000) -0.869*** (0.055) 4.944*** (0.784) Yes Yes Yes 850,546 475.8 Panel B: Foreign Firms Dependent Variable Log(Loan _IND_ City) Log(Loan INF _City) GDPt-1 AvgIncomet-_1 FiscalIncomet 1 Employmentt_1 Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Politician Fixed Effect Observations Wald F-stat 0.038* (0.022) -0.176*** (0.032) 0.009 (0.014) 0.000 (0.000) -0.230*** (0.076) -2.718** (1.156) Yes Yes Yes 194,545 280.6 -0.100*** (0.036) 0.092* (0.052) -0.021 (0.024) 0.000 (0.001) -0.285*** (0.109) -2.293 (1.944) Yes Yes Yes 193,752 283.4 -0.070** (0.029) -0.011 (0.040) -0.014 (0.017) 0.003*** (0.001) -0.680*** (0.091) 0.339 (1.492) Yes Yes Yes 194,583 289.1 Note. Table 1.6 are the two stage least squares results by using Year_ 1 to Year_6 as instrumental variable for logarithm of CDB loan for infrastructure and industry SOEs at cityxyear level. Log(Loan_INF_City) is the logarithm of the aggregate loan for infrastructure at city x year level. Log(Loan_IND_City) is the logarithm of the aggregate loan for industry firms at city x year level. Panel A restricted to the private firms in CIC from 1998 to 2009 among 310 cities. Panel B restricted to the foreign firms in CIC from 1998 to 2009 among 310 cities. In column 5, LogSales/Worker is the logarithm of Sales per worker. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, firm fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistics for weak identification tests are reported. 61 Table 1.7: CDB Province Industry Loan's Effect on Firms within Same Industry (2SLS) Panel A: Private Firms Dependent Variable Log(LoanPI) GDPti AvgIncomet - 1 FiscalIncomet-1 Employmentt- 1 Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Observations Wald F-stat (1) LogAsset (3) (4) (2) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt (5) ROA (6) (7) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales -0.246*** (0.034) -0.040*** (0.006) 0.001*** (0.000) 0.475*** (0.097) 0.000 (0.001) Yes Yes 693,782 52.15 -0.213*** (0.044) -0.073*** (0.007) -0.001*** (0.000) 0.317** (0.125) -0.000 (0.001) Yes Yes 690,071 52.71 0.020** (0.009) 0.003*** (0.001) -0.000 (0.000) -0.256*** (0.024) 0.000* (0.000) Yes Yes 693,774 52.11 -0.251*** (0.037) 0.014*** (0.005) -0.000 (0.000) -0.511*** (0.099) -0.000 (0.000) Yes Yes 692,560 52.58 (1) LogAsset (4) (3) (2) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt (5) ROA (6) (7) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales 0.196*** (0.017) -0.050*** (0.012) 0.001 (0.001) 0.027 (0.138) 0.002 (0.001) Yes Yes 230,336 88.78 0.279*** (0.022) -0.109*** (0.017) 0.001 (0.001) 0.207 (0.188) 0.001 (0.001) Yes Yes 228,818 87.91 -0.001 (0.004) 0.011*** (0.003) 0.000 (0.000) -0.173*** (0.030) -0.000 (0.000) Yes Yes 230,335 88.23 0.033* (0.019) -0.011 (0.012) -0.000 (0.001) -0.562*** (0.139) 0.002** (0.001) Yes Yes 222,680 84.03 -0.140*** (0.027) -0.016*** (0.004) 0.001*** (0.000) 0.168** (0.077) 0.000 (0.000) Yes Yes 693,966 51.31 -0.290*** (0.047) -0.043*** (0.007) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.803*** (0.131) 0.001 (0.001) Yes Yes 689,685 51.22 -0.380*** (0.042) -0.002 (0.006) 0.000 (0.000) -0.370*** (0.116) 0.000 (0.001) Yes Yes 692,874 52.39 Panel B: SOEs Dependent Variable Log(LoanPI) GDPt-1 AvgIncomet -1 FiscalIncomet -1 Employmentt-1 Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Observations Wald F-stat 0.187*** (0.016) -0.045*** (0.011) 0.001 (0.001) 0.197 (0.121) 0.000 (0.001) Yes Yes 229,774 91.84 0.304*** (0.024) -0.097*** (0.016) 0.002* (0.001) 0.024 (0.175) 0.002 (0.002) Yes Yes 228,127 87.17 0.181*** (0.020) -0.059*** (0.015) 0.000 (0.001) -0.397** (0.166) 0.002** (0.001) Yes Yes 225,486 81.87 Note. Loan_PI is the outstanding loan amount at province x industry x year level. In Panel A, data is restricted to private firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Panel A shows the two stage least squares regression results by using Firsth to Sixth as instrumental variable for logarithm of CDB province level outstanding loan amount in 41 manufacturing industries and 27 provinces (exclude Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjing, and Chonqing). GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are province level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect and firm fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistics for weak identification tests are reported. In Panel B, data is restricted to SOEs in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Panel B shows the two stage least squares regression results by using First to Sixth as instrumental variable for logarithm of CDB province level outstanding loan amount in 41 manufacturing industries and 27 provinces (exclude Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjing, and Chonqing). Loan_PI is the outstanding loan amount at province-industry level every year. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are province level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect and firm fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. CraggDonald Wald F-statistics for weak identification tests are reported. 62 Table 1.8: Upstream Industry Loan's Effect on Firms in Downstream Industry (2SLS) Panel A: Private Firms Dependent Variable Log(Upstream _Loan) GDPt- 1 AvgIncomet- 1 FiscalIncomet- 1 Employmentt- 1 Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Observations Wald F-stat (1) LogAsset (2) (3) (4) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt (5) ROA (6) (7) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales 0.092*** (0.011) -0.011** (0.005) 0.000 (0.000) -0.394*** (0.057) 0.001*** (0.000) Yes Yes 804,718 581.3 0.136*** (0.015) -0.034*** (0.006) -0.001 (0.003) 0.004*** (0.001) 0.000 (0.000) -0.235*** (0.013) 0.000** (0.000) Yes Yes 804,709 580.0 0.064*** (0.012) (0.004) -0.001*** (0.000) -1.333*** (0.053) 0.001** (0.000) Yes Yes 803,296 580.2 (1) LogAsset (2) (3) (4) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt (5) ROA (6) (7) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales 0.122*** (0.012) -0.067*** (0.012) 0.001 (0.001) 0.091 (0.135) 0.002** (0.001) Yes Yes 285,544 620.1 0.132*** (0.015) -0.109*** (0.015) 0.001 (0.001) 0.209 (0.174) -0.000 (0.001) Yes Yes 283,591 613.0 -0.009*** (0.003) 0.006** (0.003) 0.000 (0.000) -0.137*** (0.030) -0.000 (0.000) Yes Yes 285,544 617.9 -0.033** (0.014) -0.023** (0.012) -0.001 (0.001) -0.496*** (0.135) 0.001 (0.001) Yes Yes 275,484 577.8 -0.002*** (0.000) -0.670*** (0.077) 0.001 (0.001) Yes Yes 800,058 573.7 0.007 (0.009) 0.005 (0.004) 0.000 (0.000) -0.337*** (0.047) 0.001*** (0.000) Yes Yes 804,853 581.3 0.046*** (0.015) -0.019*** (0.006) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.051 (0.073) 0.002*** (0.000) Yes Yes 799,002 569.9 0.037*** 0.071*** (0.012) 0.042*** (0.005) -0.001*** (0.000) -1.672*** (0.060) 0.001*** (0.000) Yes Yes 803,712 579.0 Panel B: SOEs Dependent Variable Log(Upstream_ Loan) GDPt- 1 AvgIncomet- 1 FiscalIncometEmploymentt- 1 1 Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Observations Wald F-stat 0.125*** (0.011) -0.047*** (0.010) 0.001 (0.001) 0.227** (0.115) -0.000 (0.001) Yes Yes 283,980 607.8 0.191*** (0.017) -0.106*** (0.015) 0.003*** (0.001) 0.181 (0.171) 0.002 (0.001) Yes Yes 282,245 602.5 0.084*** (0.015) -0.073*** (0.014) -0.000 (0.001) -0.347** (0.155) 0.000 (0.000) Yes Yes 279,226 590.6 Note. Upstream Loan is the loan amount in firm's most related upstream industry at province x industry x year level. In Panel A, data is restricted to private firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Panel A shows the two stage least squares regression results by using First to Sixth as instrumental variable for logarithm of CDB province level outstanding loan amount in 25 manufacturing industries (collapsed from 41 CIC manufacturing industries) and 27 provinces (exclude Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjing, and Chonqing). Upstream_Loan is the outstanding loan amount in firm's most related upstream industry. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are province level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect and firm fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistics for weak identification tests are reported. In Panel B, data is restricted to SOEs in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Panel B shows the two stage least squares regression results by using First to Sixth as instrumental variable for logarithm of CDB province level outstanding loan amount in 25 manufacturing industries (collapsed from 41 CIC manufacturing industries) and 27 provinces (exclude Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjing, and Chonqing). Data restricted to SOEs in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Upstream Loan is the outstanding loan amount in firm's most related upstream industry. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are province level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect and firm fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistics for weak identification tests are reported. 63 Table 1.9: What Private Firms Benefit from CDB Upstream Industry Loans (2SLS) Panel A Dependent Variable Log(Upstream _Loan) Log(UpstreamLoan)* Connected GDPt_1 AvgIncomet-1 FiscalIncomet-1 Employmenti1 Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Observations Wald F-stat Panel B Dependent Variable Log(Upstream_ Loan) Log(Upstream_ Loan)* Connected GDPt-i Avgncomet _ 1 Fiscallncomet_1 Employmentti1 SizexIV Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Observations Wald F-stat (5) ROA (7) (6) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales 0.045*** (0.015) 0.120*** (0.024) -0.000 (0.003) -0.026*** (0.003) 0.066*** (0.011) -0.050*** (0.014) 0.072*** (0.012) 0.016 (0.019) -0.019*** (0.006) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.059 (0.073) 0.002*** (0.000) Yes Yes 799,002 1431 0.004*** (0.001) 0.000 (0.000) -0.237*** (0.013) 0.000** (0.000) Yes Yes 804,709 1456 0.037*** (0.004) -0.001*** (0.000) -1.340*** (0.053) 0.001** (0.000) Yes Yes 803,296 1457 0.043*** (0.005) -0.001*** (0.000) -1.674*** (0.060) 0.001*** (0.000) Yes Yes 803,712 1454 (5) ROA (7) (6) Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales 0.039** (0.015) 0.123*** (0.025) -0.000 (0.003) -0.026*** (0.003) 0.064*** (0.011) -0.050*** (0.015) 0.068*** (0.012) 0.020 (0.020) -0.020*** (0.006) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.080 (0.073) 0.016*** (0.000) Yes Yes Yes 799,002 1434 0.004*** (0.001) 0.000 (0.000) -0.239*** (0.013) 0.000** (0.000) Yes Yes Yes 804,709 1460 0.037*** (0.004) -0.001*** (0.000) -1.334*** (0.053) 0.001** (0.000) Yes Yes Yes 803,269 1460 0.042*** (0.005) -0.001*** (0.000) -1.661*** (0.060) 0.013*** (0.000) Yes Yes Yes 803,681 1457 (1) LogAsset (4) (3) (2) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt 0.091*** (0.011) 0.073*** (0.019) 0.135*** (0.015) 0.059** (0.023) 0.006 (0.009) 0.067*** (0.013) -0.011** (0.005) 0.000 (0.000) -0.390*** (0.057) 0.001*** (0.000) Yes Yes 804,718 1451 -0.034*** (0.006) -0.002*** (0.000) -0.666*** (0.077) 0.001 (0.001) Yes Yes 800,058 1441 0.005 (0.004) 0.000 (0.000) -0.333*** (0.046) 0.001*** (0.000) Yes Yes 804,853 1459 (1) LogAsset (4) (3) (2) LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt 0.085*** (0.011) 0.082*** (0.021) 0.129*** (0.015) 0.065*** (0.025) 0.006 (0.009) 0.071*** (0.014) -0.012** (0.005) 0.000 (0.000) -0.370*** (0.057) 0.001*** (0.000) Yes Yes Yes 804,718 1459 -0.035*** (0.006) -0.002*** (0.000) -0.648*** (0.077) 0.001 (0.001) Yes Yes Yes 800,058 1444 0.005 (0.004) 0.000 (0.000) -0.334*** (0.046) 0.001*** (0.000) Yes Yes Yes 804,226 1462 Note. Data is restricted to private firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Table 1.9 Panel A shows the two stage least squares regression results by using First to Sixth as instrumental variable for logarithm of CDB province level outstanding loan amount in 25 manufacturing industries (collapsed from 41 CIC manufacturing industries) and 27 provinces (exclude Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjing, and Chonqing). Upstream Loan is the outstanding loan amount in firm's most related upstream industry. Connected is the dummy for whether the private firm's political hierarchy is above the city(province level and national level) or not. In order to include the interaction term Log(Upstream Loan) * Connected in 2SL, I follow Wooldridge (2002). I first regress instrumental variables(First to Sixth) on Log(Upstream_Loan) with all exogenous variables and get fitted value Log(Upstream Loan). Second, I use Log(Upstream_Loan) and Log(Upstream_Loan) * Connected as instrumental variables for Log(Upstream_Loan) and Log(Upstream_Loan) * Connected, and perform the standard 2SLS again. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are province level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. Panel B is the robustness check by controlling the interaction terms between firm size(total asset) and the instrumental variables. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect and firm fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistics for weak identification tests are reported. 64 Table 1.10: Variables' Definition and Construction Loan _City IssuanceCity LoanINFCity IssuanceINFCity LoanINDCity IssuanceIND _City GDP AvgIncome FiscalIncome Employment PoliticianYear Age Gender Relation Promotion Loan_PI Issuance_PI LogAsset LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt ROA Log(Sales/Worker) LogSales TaxCorp TaxVAT Outstanding total CDB city level loan from 1998 to 2010. It covers 310 cities in China. The unit is 100 million RMB. Total CDB new city level loan issuance from 1998 to 2010. It covers 310 cities in China. The unit is 100 million RMB. Outstanding CDB city level loan for infrastructure projects from 1998 to 2010. It covers 310 cities in China. The unit is 100 million RMB. Total CDB city level loan issuance for infrastructure projects from 1998 to 2010. It covers 310 cities in China.The unit is 100 million RMB. Outstanding CDB city level loan for industry firms from 1998 to 2010. It covers 310 cities in China. The unit is 100 million RMB. Total CDB city level loan issuance for industry firms from 1998 to 2010. It covers 310 cities in China. The unit is 100 million RMB. City GDP amount from 1998 to 2010. It covers 310 cities in China. The unit is 100 million RMB. Data is from National Bureau of Statistics of China. Income per capita in the city from 1998 to 2010. It covers 310 cities in China. The unit is RMB. Data is from National Bureau of Statistics of China. City fiscal income amount from 1998 to 2010. It covers 310 cities in China. The unit is 100 million RMB. Data is from National Bureau of Statistics of China. City total number of workers from 1998 to 2010. It covers 310 cities in China. The unit is 100 thousand. Data is from National Bureau of Statistics of China. Number of years that the city secretary has been staying in the city. It covers 310 cities in China from 1998 to 2010. The age of the city secretary. It covers 310 cities in China from 1998 to 2010. Dummy for whether the city secretary is a female or not. It covers 310 cities in China from 1998 to 2010. Dummy for whether the city secretary is born at the same city as the province governors. It covers 310 cities in China from 1998 to 2010. Dummy for whether the city secretary is promoted to a higher position in the government or not in the end of her term. It covers 310 cities in China from 1998 to 2010. In China, different cities have different political hierarchy. For example, Shanghai, Beijing, chonqing, and Tianjing are in the ministry level (same level as province). I take this into account when define "Promotion". Outstanding total CDB province loan for each of the 95 industries from 1998 to 2013. It covers all 31 provinces in China. The unit is 100 million RMB. Total CDB province loan new issuance for each of the 95 industries from 1998 to 2013. It covers all 31 provinces in China. The unit is 100 million RMB. Logarithm of the total asset of the firm. The unit of asset is in thousand RMB. It covers all 711,892 firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Logarithm of the fixed asset of the firm. The unit of fixed asset is in thousand RMB. It covers all 711,892 firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Logarithm of the employee number of the firm. It covers all 711,892 firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Logarithm of the total debt of the firm. The unit of the total debt is in thousand RMB. It covers all 711,892 firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Contemporaneous ROA. It is calculated by dividing a firm's annual earnings by its total asset in the same year. It covers all 711,892 firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Logarithm of the sales per employee. It covers all 711,892 firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. Logarithm of the total sales. The unit of the total sales is in thousand RMB. It covers all 711,892 firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. The corporate tax rate of each firm by dividing corporate tax payable amount by the income before tax every year. Tax Corp is a missing value when income before tax is negative. It covers all 711,892 firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. The value-added tax rate of each by dividing value-added tax payable amount by the production value-added every year. TaxVAT is a missing value when production value-added is negative. It covers all 554,882 firms in CIC data in 1998, 1999, 2000, 2003, 2005, 2006 and 2007. CIC data doesn't record the value-added tax payment in 2001, 2002, 2004, 2008 and 2009. 65 Table 1.11: City Secretary's Turnover and Borrowing from CDB(off national-cycle) Panel A Total Loan Dependent Variable PoliticianYear GDPt-1 AvgIncomet -1 FiscalIncomet -1 Employmentt -1 Year Fixed Effect City Fixed Effect Politician Fixed Effect Observations R-squared Panel B Dependent Variable Year_2 Year_3 Year_4 Year_5 Year_6 GDPt-1 Avglncomet -1 Fiscallncomet -1 Employmentt -1 Year Fixed Effect City Fixed Effect Politician Fixed Effect Observations R-squared Loan for Infrastructure (1) (2) (3) (4) LogLoan_ City LogIssueCity LogLoanCity LogIssueCity -0.078** (0.031) -0.234 (0.157) -0.005*** (0.002) 0.023 (1.302) -1.083 (7.736) Yes Yes Yes 1,686 0.809 -0.190*** (0.023) 0.062 (0.194) -0.003 (0.008) -1.655 (1.604) -1.815 (8.707) Yes Yes Yes 1,542 0.639 -0.124*** (0.017) -0.228* (0.135) 0.003 (0.004) -0.652 (0.965) 0.539 (3.062) Yes Yes Yes 1,387 0.855 -0.161*** (0.032) 0.200 (0.379) -0.004 (0.007) -3.266 (2.811) 5.085 (6.218) Yes Yes Yes 1,278 0.553 Loan for Industry Firms (6) (5) LogLoanCity LogIssueCity -0.099** (0.041) -0.180 (0.201) -0.007*** (0.002) -0.535 (1.634) -6.179 (9.291) Yes Yes Yes 1,495 0.706 -0.242*** (0.033) -0.121 (0.233) -0.005 (0.008) 1.678 (2.265) -23.345*** (6.817) Yes Yes Yes 1,293 0.514 Total Loan Loan for Infrastructure Loan for Industry Firms (2) (1) LogLoanCity LogIssueCity (3) (4) LogLoanCity LogIssueCity (5) (6) LogLoanCity LogIssueCity -0.086* (0.047) -0.137** (0.063) -0.181** (0.091) -0.314** (0.154) -0.579*** (0.195) -0.224 (0.162) -0.005*** (0.002) -0.096 (1.327) -1.193 (7.917) Yes Yes Yes 1,686 0.810 -0.174** (0.073) -0.350*** (0.067) -0.527*** (0.085) -0.891*** (0.181) -1.050*** (0.194) 0.063 (0.201) -0.003 (0.008) -1.815 (1.612) -11.330 (9.092) Yes Yes Yes 1,542 0.640 -0.119*** (0.042) -0.228*** (0.045) -0.358*** (0.055) -0.487*** (0.095) -0.728*** (0.133) -0.224 (0.137) 0.003 (0.004) -0.676 (1.022) 0.616 (3.043) Yes Yes Yes 1,387 0.856 -0.161* (0.095) -0.261*** (0.083) -0.537*** (0.114) -0.624*** (0.201) -0.791*** (0.279) 0.196 (0.384) -0.004 (0.007) -3.229 (2.852) 5.065 (6.169) Yes Yes Yes 1,278 0.554 -0.043 (0.063) -0.179** (0.083) -0.207* (0.119) -0.415* (0.217) -0.611** (0.278) -0.169 (0.210) -0.007*** (0.002) -0.737 (1.727) -5.658 (9.528) Yes Yes Yes 1,495 0.707 -0.257** (0.111) -0.472*** (0.097) -0.644*** (0.130) -1.229*** (0.242) -1.316*** (0.231) -0.122 (0.234) -0.005 (0.009) 1.385 (2.283) -23.103*** (6.509) Yes Yes Yes 1,293 0.517 Note. Data restricted to CDB city level loan from 1998 to 2010. I exclude the city secretaries whose turnover are at the same time as the national turnover cycle(year 1998, 2003 and 2008). Panel A shows the results from OLS regression from equation 1.3. PoliticianYear is the number of years that the secretary has been staying in the city. Column 1 and 2 are the regressions on the logarithm of total CDB loan outstanding amount and total issuance respectively. Column 3 and 4 are the regressions on the logarithm of CDB infrastructure loan outstanding amount and new issuance respectively. Column 5 and 6 are the regressions on the logarithm of CDB industry firm loan outstanding amount and new issuance respectively. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, city fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at city level.Panel B shows the results from OLS regression from equation 1.4. Year 2 is the the dummy for whether it is the second of the secretary in the city. Year_3 is the the dummy for whether it is the third of the secretary in the city. Year_4 to Year_6 are defined in the same way. The dummy for year 1 is the missing category. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, city fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at city level. 66 Table 1.12: What Firms are Crowded Out in Private Sector (2) (1) (3) (4) Dependent Variable LogAsset LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt PoliticianYear -0.015*** -0.004 0.002 -0.018** (0.005) (0.007) Low ROA 0.148*** 0.089*** (0.004) (0.006) PoliticianYear*Low ROA -0.011*** -0.010*** (0.001) (0.002) GDPt-j -0.052*** -0.045*** (0.006) (0.009) AvgIncomet - 1 -0.000 -0.001*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.005) -0.052*** (0.004) -0.010*** (0.001) -0.002 (0.006) -0.000 (0.000) (0.008) 0.187*** (0.006) -0.003 (0.002) -0.067*** (0.008) 0.000 (0.000) FiscalIncomet_ -0.299*** -0.091 (0.050) (0.070) 1 -0.248*** -0.317*** (0.053) Employmentt_ 1 Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Politician Fixed Effect Observations R-squared (0.077) -0.001 0.001 -0.000 0.001 (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 899,857 895,698 900,086 893,378 0.261 0.133 0.0436 0.117 Note. Data restricted to private firms in Chinese Industry Census data from 1998 to 2009. Column 1 is the logarithm of total asset of the firm. Column 2 is the logarithm of fixed asset of the firm. Column 3 is the logarithm of total number of workers of the firm. Column 4 is the logarithm of total debt of the firm. PoliticianYearis the number of years that the secretary has been staying in the city. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, firm fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. 67 Table 1.13: CDB Loan's Effect on Firms (Use Secretary Year in Office as Instrument) Dependent Variable Log(LoanCity) SOEs Foreign Firms (4) (3) (2) (1) LogAsset LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt (8) (7) (6) (5) LogAsset LogFixAst LogWorker LogDebt 0.069** 0.089** (0.042) (0.031) -0.013 GDPti -0.096*** (0.011) (0.016) Avglncomet-1 0.001 0.001 (0.001) (0.001) Fiscallncomet -1 -0.333*** -0.088 (0.141) (0.099) -0.583 1.249* Employmentti(0.748) (0.519) Yes Year Fixed Effect Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Politician Fixed Effect Yes Yes Observations 305,516 303,351 Wald F-stat 307.8 300.5 0.083*** (0.029) -0.007 (0.012) 0.000 (0.001) 0.109 (0.098) -2.325*** (0.634) Yes Yes Yes 304,861 302.2 0.101** (0.044) -0.064*** (0.015) 0.001 (0.001) -0.250* (0.134) -1.626** (0.744) Yes Yes Yes 302,458 308.0 -0.106*** (0.033) -0.015* (0.008) -0.000 (0.000) -0.491*** (0.072) -1.133 (0.943) Yes Yes Yes 236,430 801.2 -0.170*** (0.046) -0.001 (0.011) -0.001** (0.001) -0.706*** (0.100) 0.381 (1.299) Yes Yes Yes 235,517 789.3 -0.124*** (0.030) 0.056*** (0.008) 0.000 (0.000) -0.272*** (0.075) -2.809*** (0.889) Yes Yes Yes 236,222 795.8 -0.051 (0.048) -0.057*** (0.013) 0.001 (0.001) -0.367*** (0.107) -0.093 (1.444) Yes Yes Yes 235,144 797.3 Note. Table 1.13 are the two stage least squares regression results by using Year_1 to Year_6 as instrumental variable for logarithm of CDB city level outstanding loan amount. Column 1 to 4 are based on SOEs in CIC from 1998 to 2009. Column 5 to 8 are based on foreign firms in CIC from 1998 to 2009. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, firm fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistics for weak identification tests are reported. 68 Table 1.14: Turnover Timing's Effects on SOEs under Different CDB Loan Amount Panel A: All Cities Dependent Variable (2) (1) (3) (4) (5) LogAsset LogFixedAst LogWorker LogDebt Log(Sales/Worker) PoliticianYear -0.007 -0.013 0.000 (0.007) (0.009) (0.006) PoliticianYear*HighCDB -0.013*** -0.010*** -0.012*** (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) HighCDB 0.025*** 0.023** 0.055*** (0.009) (0.011) (0.009) GDPt- 1 -0.008 -0.082*** -0.007 (0.013) (0.019) (0.014) AvgIncomet -1 0.000 0.000 0.000 (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) FiscalIncomet 1 -0.237** 0.031 0.181 (0.111) (0.160) (0.112) Employmentt-1 -0.008** -0.009 -0.002 (0.004) (0.007) (0.002) Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Politician Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Observations 382,317 379,632 381,720 R-squared 0.108 0.0523 0.0643 Panel B: Zero CDB Loan (1) (2) (3) Dependent Variable LogAsset LogFixedAst LogWorker PoliticianYear -0.073 (0.157) -0.062 GDPt- 1 (0.214) AvgIncomet-1 0.000 (0.001) FiscalIncomet-1 2.092 (1.946) -0.007 Employmentt_ 1 (0.005) Year Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Politician Fixed Effect Observations R-squared Yes Yes Yes 78,512 0.0391 0.003 (0.220) 0.121 (0.287) -0.001 (0.003) -0.288 (2.731) -0.009 (0.009) Yes Yes Yes 77,919 0.0237 -0.182 (0.142) 0.505** (0.228) 0.003* (0.002) 0.225 (2.091) -0.002 (0.003) Yes Yes Yes 78,261 0.0635 -0.018* (0.010) -0.007** (0.004) 0.006 (0.012) -0.074*** (0.018) 0.000 (0.001) -0.094 (0.151) -0.010 (0.006) Yes Yes Yes 378,567 0.0647 0.014* (0.008) -0.010*** (0.004) 0.013 (0.012) -0.029* (0.017) 0.000 (0.001) -0.365** (0.148) -0.004 (0.005) Yes Yes Yes 369,479 0.178 (4) (5) LogDebt Log(Sales/Worker) -0.025 (0.230) -0.385 (0.317) -0.001 (0.002) 3.216 (2.701) -0.010 (0.007) Yes Yes Yes 77,643 0.0305 0.130 (0.210) 0.828*** (0.319) -0.001 (0.002) -4.682 (3.084) -0.002 (0.006) Yes Yes Yes 75,212 0.0534 Note. Panel A is restricted to SOEs in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. PoliticianYearis the number of years that the secretary has been staying in the city. HighCDB is the dummy for whether the city's CDB loan amount is above the median of all CDB loan in 310 cities from 1998 to 2009. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, firm fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level.Panel B is restricted to SOEs in CIC data from 1998 to 2009 with 0 CDB loan amount in the city. PoliticianYear is the number of years that the secretary has been staying in the city. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, firm fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. 69 Table 1.15: CDB Loan and Firm Exit&Enter (Use Secretary Year in Office as Instrument) Private Firm Foreign Firms SOEs (2) (1) LogExit LogEnter (4) (3) LogExit LogEnter (6) (5) LogExit LogEnter 0.383*** -0.270*** (0.097) (0.067) 0.082 0.427 GDPt 1 (0.114) (0.271) -0.027 0.002 AvgIncomet _1 (0.004) (0.025) 2.075 -1.673 FiscalIncomet_1 (1.583) (2.393) 14.465 9.460*** Employmentt_ 1 (11.330) (3.505) Yes Yes Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes City Fixed Effect Yes Yes Politician Fixed Effect 2,632 2,152 Observations 68.35 62.43 Wald F-stat 0.321*** -1.123*** (0.150) (0.067) -0.046 0.593* (0.318) (0.251) -0.006 -0.047 (0.042) (0.003) -1.361 3.169 (2.225) (2.237) 18.686 -18.981 (11.957) (19.411) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 2,076 1,521 58.34 155.2 -0.405*** 0.310*** (0.106) (0.117) 0.306** -0.290 (0.129) (0.185) 0.012*** 0.008 (0.002) (0.006) 1.390 1.853 (1.107) (1.451) 28.998*** 17.325 (10.529) (10.925) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 2,444 2,434 65.00 40.16 Dependent Variable Log(Loan_ City) Note. Table 1.15 are the two stage least squares regression results by using PoliticianYear as instrumental variable for logarithm of CDB city level outstanding loan amount. Data restricted to manufacturing firms in CIC data from 1998 to 2009. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, firm fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at firm level. Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistics for weak identification tests are reported. 70 Table 1.16: Politician's Other Channels to Affect Local Economy Panel A: Current (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Dependent Variable DevelopedLand Export FiscalIncome FiscalTransfer TaxCorp TaxVAT PoliticianYear 0.139 (0.092) -0.298 (0.383) 0.473 (0.715) -0.411 (0.368) -0.066 (0.050) 0.019 (0.078) Observations R-squared 3,401 0.001 3,588 0.000 3,587 0.000 3,378 0.000 3,263 0.001 1,873 0.000 Panel B: Lagged (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Dependent Variable DevelopedLand Export FiscalIncome FiscalTransfer TaxCorp TaxVAT PoliticianYear -1 0.157 (0.110) -0.270 (0.356) 0.280 (0.998) -0.349 (0.341) -0.069 (0.049) -0.012 (0.079) Observations R-squared 3,110 0.001 3,279 0.000 3,277 0.000 3,091 0.000 2,956 0.001 1,601 0.000 Note. Data restricted to 310 cites from 1998 to 2010. In column 1, Developed_Land is the total developed land in each city every year. In column 2, Export is the total export amount in each city every year. In column 3, Fiscal__Income is the total tax fiscal income amount in each city every year. In column 4, Fiscal_Transfer is the total central government transfer amount in each city every year. In column 5, Taxcorp is the average manufacturing firm effective corporate tax rate in each city every year.In column 6, Tax__VAT is the average manufacturing firm effective value-added tax rate in each city every year. This table mainly explore the correlations between city secretary turnover and other channels that city secretary can influence the local economy. Panel A is for current turnover PoliticianYearand Panel B is for the lagged turnover PoliticianYearLag. Standard errors are clustered at city level. 71 Table 1.17: Where Does the CDB Industry Loan Go? Panel A: IND Loan Dependent Variable AssetSOEt_ 1 (1) Loan_PI (2) Issuance_PI 0.058*** (0.009) 0.016*** (0.002) 0.003 (0.007) Yes Yes Yes 6,518 0.640 Assetprivatet-1 Year Fixed Effect Province Fixed Effect Industry Fixed Effect Observations R-squared Panel B: INF Loan Dependent Variable AssetSOEt_ 1 Assetprivatet1 Year Fixed Effect Province Fixed Effect City Fixed Effect Observations R-squared Yes Yes Yes 7,334 0.687 (3) Loan_PI Yes Yes Yes 7,334 0.372 (4) (5) (6) Issuance_PI LoanPI Issue_PI 0.002 (0.003) Yes Yes Yes 6,518 0.344 0.051*** 0.013*** (0.002) (0.008) 0.002 0.003 (0.003) (0.007) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 6,230 6,230 0.386 0.735 (4) (3) (2) (1) LoanINFP IssueINFP LoanINFC IssueINF_C 0.015 (0.042) 0.063*** (0.014) Yes Yes No 297 0.905 0.007 (0.019) 0.025*** (0.005) Yes Yes No 297 0.843 0.009 (0.011) 0.035** (0.015) Yes No Yes 3,257 0.619 0.009 (0.007) 0.017** (0.009) Yes No Yes 3,257 0.561 Note. In Panel A,data restricted to CDB province level industry loan data from 1998 to 2009 in 31 provinces and 41 manufacturing industries. Loan_PI is the outstanding loan amount at provinceindustry level every year. Issue_PI is the loan new issuance amount at province-industry level every year. The unit is 1000 RMB. Asset_SOE is the total asset of SOEs in each province and industry every year. Asset_private is the total asset of private firms in each province and industry every year. The unit is in 1000 RMB. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, province fixed effect and industry fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at province level. In Panel B, column 1 and 2 are based on province level aggregate infrastructure loan data from 1998 to 2009 in 31 provinces. LoanINFPis the outstanding infrastructure loan amount at province level every year. IssuanceINFPis the infrastructure loan new issuance amount at province level every year. The unit is 1000 RMB. AssetSOE is the total asset of SOEs in each province every year. Asset_private is the total asset of private firms in each province every year. The unit is in 1000 RMB. Column 1 and 2 are also controlled by year fixed effect and province fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at province level. Column 3 and 4 in Panel B are based on city level aggregate infrastructure loan data from 1998 to 2009 in 310 cities. Loan_INF_ C is the outstanding infrastructure loan amount at city level every year. IssuanceINFC is the infrastructure loan new issuance amount at city level every year. The unit is 1000 RMB. Asset_ SOE is the total asset of SOEs in each city every year. Assetprivate is the total asset of private firms in each city every year. The unit is in 1000 RMB. Column 3 and 4 are also controlled by year fixed effect and city fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at city level. 72 Table 1.18: CDB Province Industry Level Loan and City Secretary Turnover (First Stage) Dependent Variable First (1) Log(LoanPI) Second 0.268*** (0.090) 0.366*** (0.099) Third 0.251*** (3) Log(LoanPI) (0.086) 0.128 (0.082) 0.057 (0.140) -0.097 (0.120) Fourth Fifth Sixth First-Second 0.339*** (0.103) First-Third GDPt (2) Log(LoanPI) 1 AvgIncomet- 1 FiscalIncomet -1 -0.022 (0.022) 0.190** (0.083) 0.005 (0.199) Employmentt_ 1 0.953 Year Fixed Effect Province Fixed Effect Industry Fixed Effect Observations R-squared Yes Yes Yes -0.021 (0.022) 0.184** (0.083) -0.000 (0.199) 0.916 (2.101) Yes Yes Yes 4,197 0.535 (2.094) 4,197 0.538 0.332*** (0.099) -0.020 (0.022) 0.181** (0.083) -0.011 (0.200) 0.977 (2.074) Yes Yes Yes 4,197 0.536 Note. The regressions are estimated at province x industry x year level. Data restricted to CDB province level industry loan data from 1998 to 2009 in 31 provinces and 41 manufacturing industries. Log(LoanPI) is logarithm of the outstanding loan amount at province-industry level every year. First is the dummy for whether the city secretary is in the first year of the term and the firm is in the city's largest SOE industry. Second is the dummy for whether the city secretary is in the second year of the term and the firm is in the city's largest SOE industry. The dummies from Third to Sixth are defined in the same way. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are province level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, province fixed effect and industry fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at province level. 73 Table 1.19: City Secretary's Promotion and GDP Performance Panel A: Promotion and GDP (5) (4) (3) (2) (1) Promotion Promotion Promotion Promotion Promotion Dependent Variable GDP Increase in 1st year 0.975** (0.481) 0.597*** (0.215) GDP Increase in 1st-2nd year 0.407*** (0.148) GDP Increase in 1st-3rd year 0.348*** (0.126) GDP Increase in lst-4th year 0.318*** GDP Increase in 1st-5th year (0.121) 0.270 (0.196) -0.079*** (0.011) 0.185 (0.333) Relation Age Gender 0.295 (0.194) -0.081*** (0.011) 0.191 (0.333) 0.299 (0.194) -0.080*** (0.011) 0.198 (0.331) 0.299 (0.194) -0.079*** (0.011) 0.203 (0.330) 0.303 (0.194) -0.079*** (0.011) 0.204 (0.330) 1,023 1,024 1,028 1,034 1,027 Observations 62.48 63.65 64.12 64.86 59.73 Chi squared Panel B: Promotion and CDB Loan Promotion Promotion Promotion Promotion Promotion Dependent Variable Log(Loan Increase in 1st year) 0.102*** (0.035) 0.087** (0.034) Log(Loan Increase in 1st-2nd year) Log(Loan Increase in 1st-3rd year) 0.055* (0.033) 0.062* (0.032) Log(Loan Increase in 1st-4th year) Log(Loan Increase in Relation Age Gender Observations Chi squared 1st-5th year) 0.430* (0.237) -0.084*** (0.013) 0.617 (0.388) 691 54.58 0.457** (0.218) -0.078*** (0.013) 0.663* (0.388) 758 48.75 0.431** (0.211) -0.074*** (0.012) 0.477 (0.364) 792 42.96 0.394* (0.207) -0.074*** (0.012) 0.410 (0.381) 810 43.85 0.057* (0.033) 0.426** (0.205) -0.074*** (0.012) 0.407 (0.381) 812 43.70 Note. Data restricted to 1,066 city secretaries among 310 cites from 1998 to 2010. Panel A shows the results from Probit regression. Promition is the dummy for whether the city secretary is promoted or not at the end of the term. GDP Increase in 1st year is the GDP increase in the first year of the city secretary's tenure. GDP Increase in lst-2nd year is the GDP increase in the first two years of the city secretary's tenure. The unit of GDP is 100 billion RMB. Panel B shows the results from Probit regression with CDB loan. Log(Loan Increase in 1st year) is the logarithm of CDB outstanding loan amount increase in the first year of the city secretary's tenure. Log(Loan Increase in lst-2nd year) is the logarithm of CDB outstanding loan amount increase in the first two years of the city secretary's tenure. Standard errors are clustered at city level. 74 Table 1.20: City Secretary's Characteristics and Borrowing from CDB Dependent Variable PoliticianYear (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) LogLoanCity LogIssue _City LogLoanCity LogIssue City LogLoanCity LogIssueCity -0.364*** (0.020) -2.064*** (0.086) ShortTerm -0.308*** (0.029) -1.919*** (0.142) -0.366*** (0.021) -0.300*** (0.030) 4.042*** (0.298) 2.026*** (0.212) Younger Relation GDPt-1 AvgIncomet-1 FiscalIncomet-1 Employmentt- 1 Year Fixed Effect City Fixed Effect Politician Fixed Effect Observations R-squared -0.269* (0.138) -0.004** (0.002) 0.874 (1.197) -0.953 (5.875) Yes Yes Yes 3,127 0.853 0.018 (0.167) -0.001 (0.007) -1.040 (1.428) -11.682** (5.870) Yes Yes Yes 2,795 0.685 -0.283** (0.138) -0.004** (0.002) 0.954 (1.189) -1.802 (5.659) Yes Yes Yes 2,921 0.851 -0.007 (0.170) -0.002 (0.007) -1.126 (1.433) -10.212* (5.803) Yes Yes Yes 2,644 0.676 -0.380*** (0.023) -0.299*** (0.032) 0.189*** (0.072) -0.271** (0.133) -0.004*** (0.001) 1.006 (1.181) -2.728 (5.179) Yes Yes Yes 2,782 0.857 0.085 (0.144) -0.002 (0.169) -0.002 (0.007) -1.344 (1.453) -10.223* (5.817) Yes Yes Yes 2,523 0.671 Note. The regressions are estimated at city x year level. Data restricted to CDB city level loan to 310 cites from 1998 to 2010. Column 1 to 6 are the regressions on the logarithm of total CDB loan outstanding amount and total issuance respectively. PoliticianYearis the number of years that the secretary has been staying in the city. ShortTerm is the dummy for whether the secretaries expect their terms to be less or equal than 2 years when they begin their terms. Younger is the dummy for whether the city secretaries are younger than 50 years old when they begin the terms. Relation is the dummy for whether the city secretaries are from the same place as the province governors. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, city fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at city level. 75 Table 1.21: City Secretary's Borrowing from CDB and City's Debt Level Loan for Infrastructure Total Loan Dependent Variable PoliticianYear Constrained PoliticianYear* Constrained GDPt_1 AvgIncomet -1 FiscalIncomet -1 Employmentt -1 Year Fixed Effect City Fixed Effect Politician Fixed Effect Observations R-squared (1) (2) (4) (3) LogLoanCity LogIssue City LogLoanCity LogIssueCity Loan for Industry Firms (6) (5) LogLoanCity LogIssue_ City -0.274*** (0.025) 0.726*** (0.128) -0.167*** (0.031) -0.283*** (0.039) 0.125 (0.179) -0.137*** (0.048) -0.112*** (0.015) 0.203* (0.119) -0.051 (0.036) -0.154*** (0.029) -0.039 (0.218) -0.041 (0.060) -0.234*** (0.034) 0.806*** (0.161) -0.158*** (0.041) -0.203*** (0.053) 0.243 (0.250) -0.189*** (0.067) -0.311** (0.142) -0.004* (0.002) 1.561 (1.178) -2.665 (5.189) Yes Yes Yes 3,127 0.859 -0.083 (0.180) -0.001 (0.007) 0.000 (1.462) -12.442** (5.926) Yes Yes Yes 2,795 0.689 -0.234* (0.126) 0.004 (0.004) -0.181 (0.856) -2.304 (5.299) Yes Yes Yes 2,449 0.884 0.059 (0.296) -0.000 (0.007) -2.209 (2.259) 3.272 (6.911) Yes Yes Yes 2,227 0.588 -0.205 (0.146) -0.006** (0.003) 1.410 (1.303) -11.028* (6.127) Yes Yes Yes 2,727 0.764 -0.171 (0.223) -0.005 (0.007) 2.811 (2.043) -31.956*** (11.404) Yes Yes Yes 2,323 0.604 Note. Data restricted to CDB city level loan to 310 cites from 1998 to 2010. Table shows the results from OLS regression from equation 1.3. Column I and 2 are the regressions on the logarithm of total CDB loan outstanding amount and total issuance respectively. Column 3 and 4 are the regressions on the logarithm of CDB infrastructure loan outstanding amount and new issuance respectively. Column 5 and 6 are the regressions on the logarithm of CDB industry firm loan outstanding amount and new issuance respectively. PoliticianYear is the number of years that the secretary has been staying in the city. Constrainedis the dummy for whether CDB debt to GDP ratio is at the top quartile among 310 cities. GDP, AvgIncome, FiscalIncome and Employment are city level GDP, income per capita, fiscal income and total employment respectively. All columns are controlled by year fixed effect, city fixed effect and politician personal fixed effect. Standard errors are clustered at city level. 76 Chapter 2 Do Credit Card Companies Screen for Behavioral Biases? 2.1 Introduction Retail financial products have grown in the heterogeneity and complexity of the terms they offer over the last two decades. A few recent papers have documented this growth of the retail financial sector, see for example Tufano (2003), Phillipon (2012) and Greenwood and Scharfstein (2013). But there are widely diverging views about the reasons behind this proliferation of new products and services. On the one side is a "functionalist" view as suggest by Merton (1992) or Miller (1993) or more recently Cochrane (2013). Greater product heterogeneity is seen as a reflection of increased financial innovation, which allows companies to better accommodate consumer demands and tailor products to their preferences. On the other side is a concern that the proliferation of new products and features aims to exploit consumers' behavioral biases and add complexity, which could make it difficult for consumers to compare prices and across products. This view has been summarized in Thaler and Sunstein (2008) or Campbell et al. (2011). While a large empirical literature over the last thirty years has documented different ways how consumers might make mistakes in choosing financial products, much less work has focused on how firms respond to these biases when designing product features and optimal pricing strategies. Recent advances on the theory side explore optimal supply side responses and equilibrium implications, if firms face consumers with behavioral biases. For an overview of the theoretical approaches see for example, Dellavigna (2009) or Koszegi (2013). In this paper we focus on the credit card industry to shed light on the pricing and product design strategies that credit card issuers use to attract and screen customers. We show that credit card issuers use different credit card features to separate more sophisticated from less sophisticated customers. For example, low introductory rates are offered to less educated and poorer customers, while miles are offered to more educated and richer customers. Conditional on the reward program, the pricing of the cards then differs significantly. Reward programs that are offered to less 77 educated consumers, have more expensive, backward loaded and hidden pricing features, compared to those offered to more sophisticated customers. In addition, cards with reward programs respond less to changes in the banks' cost of funds, which suggests that consumers are less sensitive to the pricing of these cards. Overall our findings suggest that credit card issuers screen for behavioral biases of customers in order to maximize the rents they extract from (unsophisticated) the customers. But we also document that card companies take into account the interaction between a customer's credit risk and heavily relying on a person's behavioral biases. Using exogenous shocks to the credit worthiness of customers via increases in state level unemployment insurance, we show that card issuers rely more heavily on backward loaded credit terms when customers are more protected. Our results draw on the recent theory literature that explores optimal supply responses when consumers have behavioral biases. Nonlinear pricing models under adverse selection a la Mussa and Rosen (1978) or Maskin and Riley (1984) cannot explain the typical three-part tariffs, which are prominent for credit cards contracts: the typical card has a low APR or even lower introductory APR and backward loaded fee structures with very high late fees and overdraft fees.1 These models predict marginal cost pricing for the last unit of consumption and suggest that the highest demand consumer will pay the lowest marginal price. The intuition is that under adverse selection firms do not want to distort the quantity chosen by the highest demand users in order to maximize the infra-marginal rents they can extract from these customers. Backward loaded credit card features with high late fees can only be optimal if customers do not understand their actual cost of credit, since in that case they will demand credit as if they were facing only the low APR. The two most prominent approaches of modeling behavioral biases in the credit card market focus either on self-control and time inconsistency problems of customers, or alternatively on myopic consumers who for example are not able to value more complex product features. An application of the first set of biases is the work by Heidhues and Koszegi (2010) or Grubb (2009) that derives the optimal credit contract if borrowers have self-control issues but naively underestimate their likelihood to be tempted in the future. The profit-maximizing contract for the issuer uses a three-part tariff with low introductory rates to make it look more attractive to consumers who underestimate their propensity to have self-control issues in the future. This contract maximizes the consumer's mistake, since it entices consumers to take on more debt than they optimally would. In contrast, sophisticated consumers will correctly forecast their propensity to have self-control issues and thus choose a less backward loaded contract. Similarly, Grubb (2009) suggests that three part tariff are an optimal response for firms that face consumers who are overoptimistic about how well they can forecast the variance of their future demand when choosing a card. A prominent example of firm responses to myopic consumers is the influential paper by Gabaix and Laibson (2006) on shrouded attributes. It suggests if myopic consumers have difficulty understanding the price of add-on features of a product, 'See for example Grubb (2009) for further discussion of this point. 78 companies can attract these consumers by charging a low base price or offering other enticing features, which are very visible to consumers. But then charging them high prices via hidden features. In the credit card context that would translate into features such as late fees, high default APRs or overdraft fees. As a result myopic or unsophisticated consumers transfer rent to the firm and also to more sophisticated consumers who avoid the expensive add-on features. The theory also suggests that products or features that are mainly demanded by sophisticated consumers are difficult to shroud and have to be priced at cost. 2 However, there are two additional implications of the model that have not been discussed in the literature, but as we will show, are important for the credit card industry. First, Gabaix and Laibson (2006) model a pooling equilibrium, since their firms have no other tool to separate customers. However, in their model firms would like to separate the sophisticated from the unsophisticated consumers, since part of the rents extracted from unsophisticated consumers go to the sophisticated consumers, since they avoid the costly add-ons and therefore access the product at a price below cost. We show that credit card companies seem to take into account that cross subsidy and design reward programs to separate sophisticated from unsophisticated customers. Second, the model does not take into account credit risk, since it was written for one shot product market interactions. However, in credit contracts an excessive reliance on shrouding and backward loading of payments, could change the credit risk of customers. In the extreme these pricing strategies could attract customers who cannot afford the products that are offered, since they do not understand the features. Or the backward-loaded nature of the contract could entice them to take on too much leverage that they ultimately cannot afford. This creates an endogenous limit in how heavily lenders can rely on these strategies. Our analysis suggests that banks are aware of this trade-off when designing credit card offers and rely more heavily on these backward loaded features when the credit risk of borrowers improves. To test the importance of these models for the retail finance market we use data on preapproved credit card offers and their contract features from the US credit card industry. Credit cards are an ideal testing ground to observe whether and how firms use communication and product features to target different customers, since the majority of credit cards in the US are sold via pre-approved credit card solicitations done by mail. This means that the information that customers get is also observable to researcher, once we obtain the card solicitation that customers received. In contrast in almost all other retail financial areas customer choices are intermediated by advisors who might change the information or even product features in ways that are unobservable to the research. The data for this study are obtained from Compremedia (Mintel) a company that collects monthly information on all credit card mailers sent to a set of about 7000 representative households, which work with Compremedia across the US. These clients are chosen to represent the demographic and economic 2 Carlin (2013) suggests a related model where heightened product complexity increases the market power of financial institutions because it prevents some consumers from becoming knowledgeable about prices. Here complexity works as a (negative) externality on all customers, rather than being targeted at particular subsets of the population. 79 distribution of the US credit card owning population. Customer characteristics are parallel with the type of information that credit card issuers observe when targeting customers. This data allows us to observe the supply side of the credit card market, i.e. the type of offers that customers receive. Our data set covers the time period between 1999 and 2011. Based on the pdf data that we receive from Compremedia, we created algorithms to extract card information and the features of the offer. We can classify the hard information of the offer such as APRs, fees, and reward programs. But we also can observe what we call the "soft" features of the offer, for example the use of photos, color, font size or amount of information provided in the mailer that the customer receives.3 We show that credit card issuers use different card features to target especially educated versus uneducated customers, and rich versus poor customers. Less educated customers and poorer customers receive more card offers with backward loaded payment features: Low introductory APRs but high late fees, penalty interest rates and over-limit fees. In contrast richer and more educated people receive almost no offers with introductory low APRs, and instead are more likely to receive card offers with cash back programs and points. And especially miles programs are targeted at more educated customers: Only 8% of offers have a miles program and they are exclusively offered to the highest income and educational groups. We then analyze the pricing structure of credit cards conditional on having different reward programs. First, we find that cards that either have cash back or points programs have lower regular APR. But at the same time these cards display much higher late fees as well as higher over limit fees. The same relationship holds when looking at cards that have introductory APR programs as rewards. Regular APRs are negatively associated with late fees, but cards that have an intro APR program show a significantly larger trade-off between regular APRs and late fees. These results go through when controlling for person specific and even bank fixed effects, which holds constant the credit risk of the person and the cost of credit for the bank. In this regression we de facto rely on the variation that comes from the fact that banks randomly send several offers to the same type of households to find out whether the customer responds to the backward loaded or shrouded features of the card. Therefore, we can estimate how banks on average change the pricing strategy of a card when using rewards programs such as miles, cash back and others. Following the approach in Ausubel (2001) we also show that these card features are associated with lower sensitivity of regular APR of credit cards to changes in fed fund rate. However, we find that late fees and default APR are more sensitive to changes in the Fed fund rate. These results suggest reward features might be used to lower the sensitivity of customers to the price of the cards, either by screening for customers with behavioral biases or by shrouding the less attractive features of a 3 Since financial institutions in the US have to follow TILA (the Truth in Lending Act) we know that all the information concerning the card have to be on the pre-approved mailer. In addition the mandatory Schumer box regulates the disclosure of most of the main card features that have to be included in the letter. However, issuers can choose how they display the information that they highlight in the main part of the text. 80 credit card offer. One interesting exception are miles programs, which we show are mainly offered to the most educated and richer groups of the population: These cards have significantly higher regular APR but lower late fees, and show a much smaller trade-off between the regular APR and backward loaded fees. We argue that this finding is in line with the idea in Gabaix and Laibson (2006) that product features which are demanded by more sophisticated (in our case measured as more educated) consumers cannot be easily shrouded and thus have to be priced upfront. Finally, we test whether credit card issuers rely more heavily on backward loaded or shrouded features, when the ultimate credit risk of customers is lower and thus the borrower's mistake in picking the high-priced product, does not significantly affect credit risk. For that purpose we look at exogenous shocks to customer creditworthiness, in particular changes in state level unemployment insurance (UI) in the US over the last decade. 4 UI was increased in staggered fashion across several US states over the last decade. These changes all went in the direction of providing higher levels of unemployment insurance as well as longer time period. By reducing the impact on consumer cash flows in the case of negative shocks, it reduces also a lender's exposure to one of the largest negative economic shock that customers might suffer. This allows us to run a standard Difference in Difference estimator to regress changes in card features on UI changes across states and across income groups. Our results show that he credit conditions of the borrower indeed affect the willingness of card issuers to rely on shrouding and backward loaded features. We find that increases in the UI levels leads to an increase in the fraction of offers that have low intro APRs and also an increase in other reward programs. But at the same time we see an increase in the late fees and default APR. Taken together these results suggest that credit card companies realize that there is an inherent trade off in the use of backward loaded features of credit card offers: They might help in inducing customers to take on more (expensive) credit, but at the same time they expose the lender to people who pose a greater risk. One separate reason why card issuers might use rewards programs which aim to increase the transaction volume of the card (e.g., miles, cash back or points) is that card issues get paid by the payment processors (visa and master card) based on how much vendor fees a card generates. While the incentive related to rewards programs surely are important, our results suggest that they are orthogonal to the channel we document in the paper. While one might argue that providing consumers with rewards (that are valuable) justifies an increase in the overall fees of the card, it does not explain why the form of the price increase should be via backward-loaded features, as we find in the case of points, cash back or introductory APR. In addition, as discussed before, we do see that reward programs that target more educated and richer people, like miles, have the opposite effect on the shape of the fee structure. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2.2 provides a detailed literature discussion. In section 2.3 we lay out the data used in the study as well 4We follow Agrawal and Matsa (2013) in using changes in the state level unemployment insurance limits as a source of variation in employees risk exposure. 81 as variables we constructed for the paper and the design of the sample. Section 2.4 summarizes our results and Section 2.5 concludes. 2.2 Literature Review Our paper builds on a large literature in economics and marketing that has looked at how individuals respond to information about product features is displayed when choosing between complex contracts such as retail financial products, medical insurance contracts or even cell phone plans. For example, Lohse (1997) demonstrates in an eye-tracking study that colored Yellow Pages ads are viewed longer and more often than black-and-white ads. Similarly, Lohse and Rosen (2001) suggests that the use of color and photos or graphics increases the perception of quality of the products that are being advertised and enhances the credibility of the claims made about the products when compared with non-color advertisements. Heitman et al. (2014) documents that the way prices and add-on features are displayed, significantly affects how well people choose between products. Besheres, Choi, Laibson and Madrian (2010) show that even when subjects are presented with very transparent and easy to digest information about different mutual funds, they select dominated savings vehicles. Bertrand et al. (2010) show that the advertising content indeed can have significant impact on product take up and even willingness to pay. They set up a field experiment with a consumer lender's direct mailing campaign in South Africa and find that advertising content which appeals to emotions (such as a woman's versus a man's face) or a simpler display of choices leads people to accept much more expensive credit products. We build on this earlier literature by analyzing if firms deliberately incorporate these behavioral biases when designing credit card offers. There is also a growing literature in household finance that has looked at credit card usage of borrowers to document that people make non-optimal choices. Agarwal et al. (2008) analyze more than 4 million transactions of credit card customer to show that customers on average pay significant fees (late payment and penalty fees) of about $14 per month, which does not include interest payments. These results confirm that fees indeed have significant bite and customers are not able to optimally avoid all the negative features of their cards. The paper also shows that customers seem to learn to reduce fees over time. But this learning is relatively slow, payments fall by about 75 percent after four years of account life. Using a similar data set, Gross and Souleles (2000) show that consumers respond strongly to an increase in their credit limit and especially to interest rate changes such as low introductory teaser rates. The long-run elasticity of debt to the interest rate is about -1.3 of which more than half reflects net increases in total borrowing (rather than just balance switches). In a related work, Agarwal et al. (2010) document that consumers who respond to the inferior offers of a lender have poorer credit characteristics ex ante and also end up defaulting more ex post. Similarly, Agarwal et al. (2009) show that over the lifecycle middle-aged households get the best credit terms, while older customers select worse credit. The authors conjecture that deterioration in cognitive abilities could 82 be a reason why older people choose worse terms.' These papers provide important confirmation that credit cards with disadvantageous features are being taken up and have a significant impact on borrowers cost of capital. Finally, we relate to a number of papers, which have documented large heterogeneity in the pricing or retail financial products even in the face of increasing competition. See for example the seminal paper by Ausubel (1991) which documents that credit card companies have very low pass through rates of any changes in their cost of capital. Hortacu and Syverson (2004) or Bergstresser et al. (2009) show wide dispersion in fees for the mutual fund industry that is related to changes in the heterogeneity of the customer base. More recently Sun (2014) and Celerier and Vallee (2014) show that even with the introduction of increased competition price dispersion does not go down and product complexity might go up. Similarly, Hastings, Hortacsu and Syverson (2012) look at the introduction of individual savings accounts in Mexico and show that firms that invested more heavily in advertising had both high prices and larger market shares, since customers seem to not be sufficiently price sensitive. Similarly, Gurun, Matvos and Seru (2014) show that areas with large house price increases and expansion of mortgage originations, saw an increase in marketing expenses and amounts of marketing solicitations being sent out. These results suggest that firms seem to compete on nonfinancial dimensions such as advertising to substitute for price competition. A paper that uses a very similar data set is Han, Keys and Li (2013), but focus on a complementary topic. The authors use Mintel data between 2007 and 2011 to document the large expansion in the supply of credit card debt in the time period leading up to the financial crisis and after the crisis. The results show that the expansion prior to crisis was particularly large for consumers with medium credit scores as supposed to sub-prime customers. In addition they show that even customers who had previously gone through a bankruptcy still have a high likelihood of receiving offers, but that these offers are more restrictive. 2.3 2.3.1 Data and Summary Statistics Data Description We use a comprehensive dataset from Mintel Comperemedia that contains comprehensive information on the types of credit card offers that customer with different characteristics receive in the US. This data is based on panel conduced with more than 4000 households monthly where the household collects all mailings of direct (preapproved) credit mailing and send this original information to Mintel. For this data collection effort Mintel selects the households based on their demographic and 5Hastings and Mitchell (2011) use a large-scale, nationally representative field survey from Chile to directly relate impatience and financial literacy relate to poor financial decisions within a savings context. The results show that impatience is a strong predictor of wealth. Financial literacy is also correlated with wealth though it appears to be a weaker predictor of sensitivity to framing in investment decisions. 83 economic characteristics in order to be representative of the distribution of the US credit card owning population. For each household, Mintel collects detailed demographic information including the age and education of household head, and household income, composition, races, zip code, etc. Each month, Mintel receives from the household all credit solicitation mails, such as credit card, home equity loan and mortgage offers that these selected households received during the month. We only observe offers to the entire households usually to the head of the household. After gathering the physical credit card offers from the households, Mintel manually scans the actual mailers in PDF format and electronically enters some key information which usually are contained in the Schumer box: regular purchasing APRs, balance transfer APRs, cash advantage APRs, default APRs, maximum credit limits, annual fees, late fees (penalty fees), over limit fees and so on. We manually check the quality of the dataset and find that all the variables are very well collected except default APRs which has many missing values. The data sample ranges from March 1999 to February 2011. For each month, there are about 4,000 households and 7,000 credit card mail campaigns on average. In total, there are 1,014,768 mail campaigns which consist of 168,312 different credit card offers. This is because credit card companies usually issue the same offer to many households at the same time. Our second data resource from Mintel is the scanned images of all pages of the credit card offers. However, Mintel only keeps scanned images of about 80% of the credit card offers. Therefore, 803,285 out of the total 1,014,768 credit card offers have complete scanned images of each page. We extract information of reward programs and any soft information about the design of the mailer itself from these scanned images. First, we use OCR (Optical character recognition) software to transfer all the images into Word documents. The OCR software we use is OmniPage Professional version 18.0. It is one of the leading document imaging software which is accurate and fast. The OCR software separates the characters and graphics/background patterns from the original documents (scanned credit card offers), recombines them together based on original digital documents' design and turns it into editable Word documents. After that, we use keyword searching algorithm to search the reward programs in each offer. We are able to identify 8 commonly used reward programs: cash back, point reward, flight mileage, car rental insurance, purchase protection, warranty protection, travel insurance and zero introductory APRs. Moreover, because we keep format information of each character in the offers, we can also get the format design of these reward programs. By using Word application in VBA, we are able to identify the font of the characters. We collect the size and color of each reward program when they were mentioned in the offer as well as whether they were highlighted with bold or italic. Also, we count the number and size of pictures on each page. To check the quality of the OCR and keyword searching algorithm, we randomly select some offers to manually check the accuracy which turns out to be over 90%. As we mention before, there are some missing values for default APRs from Mintel's hand collect database. To deal with it, we also use keyword searching algorithm to search the default APRs stated in the offers. Usually, the Schumer box contains default APRs which sometimes called penalty APRs. We extract default 84 APRs for all credit card offers with scanned images by using our algorithm and compare them with the ones collected by Mintel. The accuracy of our algorithm is about 98%. In this way, we are able to add back some of the missing values to almost complete the default APRs data. Because we only have 80% samples with scanned offers, our variables for reward programs and format are limited to these 80% sample. 2.3.2 Descriptive Statistics Table 2.1 is the summary statistics. FFR is the monthly average federal fund rate from January 1999 to December 2011. We merge FFR into our credit card dataset by month. In Table 2.1, variables from APR to Intro APR-cash are based on our entire 1,014,768 mail campaigns from Mintel. APR is the regular purchasing APRs in the credit card offers. Sometimes, regular APR is a range and we pick the middle point as the APR. The mean of APR is 12.64% among 982,796 total mailings received by consumers. The APRs for balance transfer has a mean of 11.33% and standard deviation of 3.34%. The cash advance APR has a mean of 19.88% and the standard deviation is 4.28%. For default APRs, the mean is much 26.51% which is higher than all other APRs. The credit card companies charge very high default APRs which may be applied to all outstanding balances of a credit card if a consumer pays the monthly bill late (usually in 60 days). All these APRs are monthly couponed. IntroAPRregular, IntroAPRbalance and IntroAPRcash are the dummies of whether the offer has 0% introductory APR for regular purchase, balance transfer and cash advance respectively. "Max Card limit" is the nature log of the maximum credit card limit stated in the offers. We only have 526,949 observations for "Max Card limit" since many credit card offers don't have it, especially during later years. Credit cards also have a number of different fee types, the dimensions that we observe in the data are annual fee, late fee and over limit fee in our sample. Annual fee on average are $12.28 with a standard deviation of 31.99. The distribution of annual fee in our sample is pretty skewed. 81.5% of the mailing offers have zero annual fee and the maximum annual fee is $500. Typically the types of cards that have annual fees associated with them, offer mileage programs and other expensive value added services. Late fee is the one-time payment if the consumer misses paying at least their minimum monthly payment by the due date. In our sample, late fee has a mean of $33.83 and a standard deviation of 6.17. It is much less skewed than annual fee. About 90% of the credit card offers have late fee from $29 to $39. Since this is a fixed monthly fee that comes due if the minimum payment has not been, one can imagine that the cost of this fee structure can be very high especially when customers carry small balances. Finally, over limit fee is the fee charged when consumers' credit card balance goes over the card limit. The mean of over limit fee is $29.7 with a standard deviation of 10.16. The distribution of over limit fee is also concentrated: about 87% of the cards has over limit fee from $29 to $39. Although credit card companies usually charge zero annual fee, they do charge much more from late payment and over borrowing. In Table 2.1, variables from "Size" to "Purchaseprct" are from 80% of 1,014,768 total mail campaigns which have scanned images of credit card offers. "Size" is the 85 maximum size of the reward programs minus the average size of all characters in every pages of each credit card offer. For example, if the letters "cash back" appear 3 times in the offer, we pick the largest one. "Size" equals this largest number minus the average size of all characters on the same page. The unit of size is directly from Word document. The variable "Size" has 4.71 mean and 5.49 standard deviation. The maximum value of Size is 143.6 because some offers will print very large characters to highlight reward programs. The 90th percentile of variable Size is 10.99. We use this relative size measurement because credit card companies tend to enlarge the reward program characters' size relatively to the paragraphs nearby in order to highlight the reward programs. The size differences between them should be the measure of highlight. Moreover, "Color" is the dummy of whether reward programs in the offer use color other than black/white. We only focus on the characters of reward programs rather than the entire offer since almost every credit card offers use some colors, especially during later years. 6 "Bold" is the dummy of whether the offer use bold to highlight reward programs. "Picture" is the file size of each page of the offer which is the measurement of how many or how "fancy" the pictures are in the offer. We don't use actual count of the pictures nor the size of the pictures because our algorithm considers the background of the page as a big picture as well (usually it is just a big plain color picture). Using storage size of each Word document, we can approximate how complicated the design of the page is. Other information such as characters also use some storage. However, Pictures in Word documents usually take most of the storage room. We think that file storage size is a good measurement of the pictures in the credit card offers. The variable "Picture" is the file storage size and the unit is megabyte (MB). The mean of "Picture" is 0.23MB with 0.26MB standard deviation. In the appendix, we plot two samples of the credit card offers. Figure 2-7 is the sample of simple visual offer, which doesn't use big font, flashy colors, or pictures to highlight the reward programs. Figure 2-8 is the sample of high visual offer with many fancy designs. Moreover, we define "Reward" as the number of reward programs of CASH, POINT and Car rental insurance in each offer. We choose these three reward programs because they are similar and most commonly used. CASH, POINT, MILE, Carrental, Purchaseprct are dummies of whether the offer has these reward programs respectively. Table 2.2 summarize the design of the credit card offers. All credit card offers state late fees, default APRs, over-limit fees, and annual fees. Only 5.8% of the credit card offers mention late fees in the first page of the offers. 4.97% of the credit card offers mention default APRs in the first page of the offers. 6.96% of the credit card offers mention over-limit fees in the first page of the offers. Basically, credit card offers usually don't mention backward loaded terms in the first page of the offer. On the other hand, 79.28% of the credit card offers put annual fees information on the first page which is considered to be the front loaded term. Moreover, reward programs 6To construct the format variables such as Size, Color, and Bold, we only focus on the reward programs fonts which include cash back, point rewards, mileage, car rental insurance, purchase protection, and low intro APR programs. 86 are usually mentioned in the first page of the offers; 100% of the cash back program and mileage programs are mentioned in the first page. For point reward, car rental insurance, and 0 introductory APRs, the changes to be put on the first pages are 93.51%, 80.48%, and 91.04% respectively. Panel B of Table 2.2 compares the credit card terms when they are mentioned on the first page or not. It is clear that late fee, over-limit fee, and annual fee are much lower in the offers when they are mentioned on the first page than in the offers when they are mentioned in the back. Timetrend: In figure 2-1 to figure 2-4, we plot the monthly time trend of reward programs and variables of credit card design from March 1999 to February 2011. As we can see, the number of reward programs increases overtime and appears cyclical. For example, there is a drop of reward program numbers during the recent crisis. The uses of size, color and pictures in credit card offers also increase overtime and have cyclical patterns. 2.4 2.4.1 Results Customer Characteristics and credit card features We start by analyzing how the features of offers vary with the characteristics of the customers. The analysis allows us to understand whether specific credit card features are used to target different client groups. But the exercise also allows us to see if the relationships in the data are intuitive. For that purpose in Table 2.3 we run a simple regression model of card features, such as card APR, late fees or reward program on customer characteristics. The characteristics of interest for us are the education levels of customers, which are measured as six distinct educational achievement dummies ranging from some high school to graduate school. And nine different income groups ranging from the lowest income group of less than $15,000 to the highest of over $200,000. In these regressions we also control for the age group fixed effects of the customer, the state fixed effect, dummies for household composition and credit card company fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at the month level. It is important to note that these customer characteristics are also the same ones that credit card companies observe when they send out mailing campaigns. In column 1 of Table 2.3 we start with the mean APR as the dependent variable and report the coefficients on the education and income bins. The results show that regular APR decreases significantly for higher income groups and the results are relatively monotonically going up with increasing income. The magnitude of the effect is quite large. Between the lowest and the third highest income groups there is a difference in mean APR of almost 0.561 percentage points which is a significant difference. The relationship between APR and income levels off a little for the highest two income groups, but we will show that these groups also have different product features. In contrast there is no significant relationship between the regular APR and education. The estimated coefficients are all close to zero and insignificant. We repeat the same regression for APR on balance transfers and APR on cash withdrawals and get very similar results. The regressions are not reported but can be obtained from 87 the authors. These results intuitively suggest that higher income customers are better credit risk and as a result enjoy a lower cost of capital. Interestingly the same is not true for more educated customers. We now use the logarithm of the maximum credit balance as the left hand side variable and repeat the same regression set up as in column (1). We see that limits increase with higher education bins, but the increase is even steeper with income categories. It is intuitive to think that credit card companies are more comfortable increasing their exposure to customers with higher income and better educational attainment since this might be correlated with increased future earnings potential. Interestingly in columns (3) and (4) these results reverse when we look at Default APR and late fee. These are backward loaded fees which become due when the customer is either 30 days late or becomes more than 90 days delinquent. Very surprisingly we find that late fees and default APR increase significantly with customer income, but drop with higher educational attainment. For example the difference in default APR between the lowest and the highest income group is about 0.543 percentage points. So customers with higher income actually face higher default interest rates than those with lower income. The same pattern holds true for late fees. In contrast, customers with higher education receive card offers that have smaller late fees and lower default APR. This result is very puzzling: If default APR or late fees are a means to manage customer default risk, it is not clear why customers with higher income would be a higher default risk conditional on falling late, compared to customers with lower income. These results might be a first indication that these interest rates are set with a different set of considerations in mind. In a next step we look at how reward programs are offered to customers. In column (5) the dependent variable is a dummy equal one if the credit card offer contains a cash back program. We see that there is a strong positive correlation with income, between the highest and lowest income group there is a 4 percent difference that a card has cash back program. This is economically very substantive since only 21 percent of card offers contain a cash back program. In contrast we do not see any relationship between educational levels and the likelihood of receiving a credit card offer with a cash back program. In column (6) we see a very similar result for points programs. Again there is a statistically and economically significant increase in the likelihood of receiving an offer with a points program for households that have higher income levels. But there is no relationship with educational levels. We observe a very different relationship when looking at miles programs. In column (7) we show that the likelihood of receiving a card offer with a miles program increases significantly with the education level of the household. Households in the second to last highest income group are more than percent more likely to receive an offer with a miles program compared to a household in a the lowest educational bin. Since only eight percent of credit card offers include a miles program in the first place, education seems to be a very important dimension in receiving miles programs. We also see that miles programs increase with the income level of the customer. The final reward program we look at are low introductory APR offers. These usually expire after a few months (customarily between six to 12 months) and then a higher interest rate kicks in. In column (8) we see that introductory APR 88 programs are predominantly offered to less educated and lower income customers. A similar relationship holds for introductory APR rates on balance transfers. Moreover, in Table 2.3 Column 9, "Format" is the first principal component of reward programs' size, color, bold and the picture sizes on the credit card offers. We show that more educated households or high income households can get fancier designed credit card offers which usually use bigger font size, more colors, more bold, and more pictures to emphasize the reward programs. As discussed above, the detailed customer information in the Mintel data allows us to analyze how credit card issuers target customers with different characteristics, for example across the income and educational attainment distribution. However, one dimension that we do not have in our data, are the FICO scores for individual borrowers. To analyze if the lack of FICO scores in our data is a significant limitation, we obtained Mintel data via the CFPB. While the data covers a shorter time period than ours, starting only from 2007, it has the advantage of containing also FICO scores. The idea it to see if credit card features differ significantly by FICO scores, after controlling for all the other observable characteristics of the customer. This is equivalent to asking whether card issuers use FICO scores to screen a different dimension of the borrowers from all the other characteristics. For that purpose we repeat our waterfall regressions where we regress card features on the different customer characteristics and then add FICO scores as an additional explanatory variable. Adding the customers' FICO scores does not add any additional explanatory power to the regression. The adjusted R-squared of the regressions are unchanged and none of the coefficients on other RHS variables change when including the FICO scores. So, overall it appears that the dimensions spanned by the FICO scores are jointly spanned by the other observable characteristics. These results reduce the concern that we are missing an important, and separate screening dimension. Taken together these results suggest that different reward programs are used to target different customers groups. Introductory APR offers are primarily offered to less educated and poor clients. In contrast points and cash back programs are offered to richer customers but independent of their educational level. Finally, miles is the only reward program that are predominately targeted to richer and importantly to more educated customers. We plot the coefficients from Table 2.3 in Figure 2-5 and 2-6 to make the patterns more clear. Figure 2-5 plots the estimated coefficients of the education on credit card terms and reward programs. Figure 2-6 plots the estimated coefficients of the income level on credit card terms and reward programs. 2.4.2 Pricing of Credit Cards In a next step we now want to understand how the pricing of credit card offers changes with reward programs. The idea is to test if these reward programs are used in combination with more backward loaded credit card features or different pricing levels. If indeed rewards are used to attract customers who are more prone to shrouding we would expect more pricing of hidden features and more backward loading. For that purpose we will investigate the different reward programs separately. 89 We follow the general idea pioneered in Ausubel (1991) to assume that APR should be very sensitive to the Fedfundrate since this is the rate at which the banks can raise capital. Parallel to Ausubel (1991) we will interpret any elasticity between the APR and FFR that is much below 1 as an indication that credit card issuers are insulated from competition. But in our case we want to understand whether the use of reward programs allows issuers to react less strongly to changes in the FFR and also use more backward loaded fee structures. Our first regression specification is Yi,jt = #1 x FFRM + /2 x RPj,t + FEi,jt + cij,t, (2.1) where Yi,jt indexes the dependent variables we are interested in such as regular purchasing APRs, default APRs, late fee and over limit fee. For example, APRi,j,t is the regular purchasing APR of the credit card offer issued by company i to consumer j at time t. FFRM indexes the federal fund rate at month M. RPjt indexes the dummy of certain reward program in the credit card offer such as cash back, point reward, flight mileage and zero introductory APRs. We also control the fixed effects such state fixed effects, bank fixed effects, and household demographic fixed effects. 7 t is at daily frequent. Also, we explore the sensitivity between APRs and FFR by adding interaction terms of FFR and reward programs: Yi,j,t = #1 x FFR + 02 x RPjt + /3 x RPi,jt x FFR + FEi,jt + (i,j,t, (2.2) We cluster the standard errors at the cell level. Points Program In Table 2.4 Panel A, we focus on the use points programs. Ex ante there is no obvious reason why a credit card offer should even be linked with a points program, since the credit card company could rather offer a lower interest rate. In column (1) we regress the regular APR on the FFR and an indicator for whether the credit card contains a points program. In this first column we only control for state fixed effects but no person specific characteristics. We see that the coefficient on FFR is only 0.326, while the coefficient is highly significant it indicates that there is less than perfect pass through of the cost of capital to customers. We also see that those cards that have a points program have lower APR. But in this baseline specification the negative coefficient could be driven by a composition effect, since was we saw in the prior Table only higher income customers receive credit cards with points. Therefore, in column (2) we include cell fixed effects in the regression. This means we control for every consumer cell, which is a unique combination of the customers' income bin, educational attainment, household composition, age and the state that she lives in. This specification allows us to test how credit card offers that have points programs are priced compared to those without a points program holding constant 'We construct the household demographic cells by age, education, income, household composition, and the states. 90 the customer characteristics. As we see in column (2) the coefficient on Points stays negative and only drops by about 10 percent, which means that it cannot be driven by the customer's observable credit type but has to be specific to the pricing strategy of a given card. In column (3) of Table 2.4 Panel A we now add bank fixed effects to the regression. This allows us to control for the differences in pricing strategies between banks. We see that with bank fixed effect the coefficient on Points drops by a huge factor, almost ten! This result suggests that banks differ significantly in their use of point programs and those issuers which use point programs extensively are also those that charge lower APR rates. However, in this most stringent specification, we still find a negative and significant coefficient on the POINT dummy. This means that when two credit cards are sent to the same person by the same bank, but one card offers a reward program with points to the customer and the other does not, the one with the points program has a lower APR affiliated with it. This is very surprising since the production of points is most likely not costless and thus we need to ask how the card company will break even on the production of such points. In the remaining columns of the table we now analyze how this relationship correlates with other card features. First in column (4) we follow Ausubel (1991) and interact Points x FFR to test if credit cards that offer points are less sensitive to changes in the FFR. The results suggest that this is indeed true, since the coefficient on the interaction term is minus 0.244 and significant at the one percent level. This means that credit cards that have points programs do not need to adjust as quickly to changes in the FFR. However, maybe more interestingly in the context of our analysis in column (5) we now use the Default APR as a dependent variable. We repeat the same regression as in columns (2) regressing Default APR on FFR and Points controlling for cell fixed effects. We show that Default APR increases significantly with Points, again keep in mind that this is holding constant all the characteristics of the recipient of the offer. When we now interact Points x FFR in column (6) we again find that the there is a large and significantly negative coefficient suggesting that Points programs allow credit card issuers to maintain higher default APRs and not pass on any changes in their cost of capital to consumers. And finally we repeat the same regression specifications in columns (8) to (10) but using late fees as the dependent variable. Again we see a very strong increase in late fees for cards that have a point program. But in this case the reward program is associated with higher sensitivity of late fees to underlying changes in the FFR. This could indicate that late fees are an important way to make adjustments for the banks changing cost of capital. Cash Back Program In Table 2.4 Panel B, we focus on the use cash back programs. In column (1) we regress the regular APR on the FFR and an indicator for whether the credit card contains a cash back program. As before, we first only control for state fixed effects but no person specific characteristics. We see that the coefficient on FFR is only 0.312, while the coefficient is highly significant it indicates that there is less than perfect pass through of the cost of capital to customers. We also see that those cards 91 that have a cash back program have lower APR. Parallel to before, in column (2) we include cell fixed effects in the regression. This specification allows us to test how credit card offers that have cash back programs are priced compared to those without a cash back program holding constant the customer characteristics. As we see in column (2) the coefficient on cash back stays negative and only drops by about 8 percent. In column (3) of Table 2.4 Panel B we now add bank fixed effects to the regression. This allows us to control for the differences in pricing strategies between banks. We see that with bank fixed effect the coefficient on cash back drops by a factor of three. This result suggests that banks differ significantly in their use of cash back programs and those issuers which use cash back programs extensively are also those that charge lower APR rates. We now analyze how this relationship correlates with other card features. First in column (4) as before we follow Ausubel (1991) and interact cash back x FFR to test if credit cards that offer cash back are less sensitive to changes in the FFR. The results suggest that this is indeed true, since the coefficient on the interaction term is minus 0.363 and significant at the one percent level. However, maybe more interestingly in the context of our analysis in column (5) and (6) we now use the Default APR as a dependent variable. When we interact cash back x FFR in column (6) we again find that the there is a large and significantly negative coefficient suggesting that cash back programs allow credit card issuers to maintain higher default APRs and not pass on any changes in their cost of capital to consumers. And finally we repeat the same regression specifications in columns (8) to (10) but using late fees as the dependent variable. Again we see a very strong increase in late fees for cards that have a cash back program. But in this case the reward program is associated with higher sensitivity of late fees to underlying changes in the FFR. This could indicate that late fees are an important way to make adjustments for the banks changing cost of capital. Mileage Programs In Table 2.5 Panel A, we focus on the use of mileage programs. In column (1) we regress the regular APR on the FFR and an indicator for whether the credit card contains a mileage program. Again, we only control for state fixed effects but no person specific characteristics. Moreover, we see a very strong increase in APR for cards that have a mileage program. The coefficient on MILE is 1.698, significant at one percent level. In column (2) we again include cell fixed effects in the regression. As we see in column (2) the coefficient on mileage stays significantly positive and increases by about 24 percent. In column (3) of Table 2.5 Panel A, we now add bank fixed effects to the regression. This allows us to control for the differences in pricing strategies between banks. We see that with bank fixed effect the coefficient on mileage stays almost the same. This result suggests that banks don't differ significantly in their use of mileage programs. In the remaining columns of the table we now analyze how this relationship correlates with other card features. First in column (4) we follow Ausubel (1991) and interact mileage x FFR to test if credit cards that offer mileage are less sensitive to 92 changes in the FFR. The results suggest that this is indeed true, since the coefficient on the interaction term is minus 0.363 and significant at the one percent level. In column (5) and (6) we now use the Default APR as a dependent variable. We find similar results as regular APRs in column (1) and (2). Finally we repeat the same regression specifications in columns (8) to (10) but using late fees as the dependent variable. Again we see a very strong increase in late fees for cards that have a mileage program. But in this case the reward program is associated with higher sensitivity of late fees to underlying changes in the FFR. This could indicate that late fees are an important way to make adjustments for the banks changing cost of capital. Zero Introductory APR In Table 2.5 Panel B, we focus on the use zero introductory APRs programs. In column (1) we regress the regular APR on the FFR and an indicator for whether the credit card contains a zero introductory APRs program. Again, we only control for state fixed effects but no person specific characteristics. We see that the coefficient on FFR is only 0.397, while the coefficient is highly significant it indicates that there is less than perfect pass through of the cost of capital to customers. We also see that those cards that have a zero introductory APRs program have lower APR. But in this baseline specification the negative coefficient could be driven by a composition effect, since was we saw in the prior Table only higher income customers receive credit cards with zero introductory APRs. Therefore, in column (2) we include cell fixed effects in the regression. This specification allows us to test how credit card offers that have zero introductory APRs programs are priced compared to those without a zero introductory APRs program holding constant the customer characteristics. As we see in column (2) the coefficient on zero introductory APRs stays negative and only drops by about 4 percent, which means that it cannot be driven by the customer's observable credit type but has to be specific to the pricing strategy of a given card. In the remaining columns of the table we now analyze how this relationship correlates with other card features. First in column (3) we follow Ausubel (1991) and interact zero introductory APRs x FFR to test if credit cards that offer zero introductory APRs are less sensitive to changes in the FFR. The results suggest that this is indeed true, since the coefficient on the interaction term is minus 0.566 and significant at the one percent level. However, maybe more interestingly in the context of our analysis in column (4) and (5) we now use the Default APR as a dependent variable. When we interact zero introductory APRs x FFR in column (6) we again find that the there is a large and significantly negative coefficient suggesting that zero introductory APRs programs allow credit card issuers to maintain higher default APRs and not pass on any changes in their cost of capital to consumers. And finally we repeat the same regression specifications in columns (8) to (10) but using late fees as the dependent variable. Again we see a very strong increase in late fees for cards that have a zero introductory APRs program. But in this case the reward program is associated with higher sensitivity of late fees to underlying changes in the FFR. This could indicate that late fees are an important way to make adjustments for the banks changing cost of capital. 93 Format of the Reward Programs In Table 2.6, we focus on the design of the credit card offers. We use the font size, color, and bold of the reward programs on the offers. We also use the picture sizes to measure the design of the credit card offers. "Format" is the first principal component of reward programs' size, color, bold and the picture sizes on the credit card offers. In column (1) we regress the regular APR on the FFR and Format. Again, we only control for state fixed effects but no person specific characteristics. We see a very strong increase in APR for cards with fancier design. The coefficient on Format is 0.374, significant at one percent level. In column (2) we again include cell fixed effects in the regression. As we see in column (2) the coefficient on Format stays significantly positive and increases by about 2 percent. In column (3) of Table 2.6, we now add bank fixed effects to the regression. This allows us to control for the differences in pricing strategies between banks. We see that with bank fixed effect the coefficient on Format stays almost the same. This result suggests that banks don't differ significantly in their use of mileage programs. In the remaining columns of the table we now analyze how this relationship correlates with other card features. First in column (4) we follow Ausubel (1991) and interact Format x FFR to test if credit cards with fancier design are less sensitive to changes in the FFR. The results suggest that the sensitivity doesn't change significantly with Format. In column (5), (6) and (7) we now use the Default APR as a dependent variable. We find similar results as regular APRs in column (1) and (3). However, in column (7), we find that default APRs of credit cards with fancier design are significantly less sensitive to changes in the FFR. Finally we repeat the same regression specifications in columns (8) to (10) but using late fees as the dependent variable. Again we see a very strong increase in late fees for cards with fancier design. Format again is associated with lower sensitivity of late fees to underlying changes in the FFR. This could indicate that fancy designs such as big colorful font, can make back loaded terms less sensitive to banks cost of capital. In sum these results suggest that the majority of reward programs are designed to allow the company to backward load a lot credit card payments to a later time period when credit terms are very expensive. For example through the use of late fees and default APRs. At the same time credit cards with point programs are even in the current time less sensitive to the ups and downs of the FFR. A similar relationship holds for cash back program. It is interesting that both of these programs are used in combination with backward loading of payments, since schemes like points or cashback are not inherently depending on the time factor. This might point to the idea that these reward programs are used to shroud the more expensive aspects of a card program. Similarly cards with introductory APR offers have almost by definition more backward loaded payment features. The one big exemption are cards with mileage programs. These cards seem to be predominately targeted at more educated customers. These cards are associated with a higher mean APR rate but much lower late fees and default APR. 94 2.4.3 Trade-off between Regular APRs and Late Fees From above, we see that credit card companies use different reward programs with different pricing strategies and target different consumer groups. We explore the pricing trade-offs between font loaded terms such as regular APR and back loaded terms such as late fees. In Table 2.7 column (1), we first look at the trade-offs between regular APRs and late fees by regressing regular APRs on late fees. We only control state fixed effects in column (1). We find that a $1 increase in late fee is associated with a 0.06% increase in regular APRs. When we control for cell fixed effects and bank fixed effects in column (2) and (3), we still find that regular APRs are negatively associated with late fees. This suggests that credit card companies usually choose to decrease regular APRs and increase late fees to make the terms more backward loaded or choose to increase regular APRs and decrease late fees to make the terms front loaded. Moreover, we interact the reward programs (cash back, point, and car rental insurance programs) with late fees in column (4) and find significantly negative coefficient on the interaction term. This suggests that more reward programs led to significantly more trade-offs between late fees and regular APRs. Then, we compare the heterogeneous effects of mileage program and intro APR program on credit card pricing strategy. In Table 2.7 column (5) and (6), we find that intro APR programs led to significantly more trade-offs between late fees and regular APRs. Interestingly, in Table 2.7 column (7) and (8), we find that mileage programs led to significantly fewer trade-offs between late fees and regular APRs. This is consistent with our previous findings; Intro APR programs led to more backward loaded terms but not the mileage program which usually targets the well-educated consumers. 2.4.4 Unemployment Insurance We now analyze the effect of changes in the unemployment insurance's effects on credit card terms and reward programs. The idea is to use an exogenous shock to the credit worthiness of customers, in particular their risk of default. UI was increased in staggered fashion across several US states over the last decade. These changes all went in the direction of providing higher levels of unemployment insurance as well as longer time period. By buffering consumer cash flow in the case of negative shocks, it reduces also a lender's exposure to one of the largest negative economic shock that customers might suffer. We obtain data on the level of unemployment insurance (UI) from the U.S. Department of Labor for each state. Based on this information we calculate annual changes in UI at the beginning of each year from 1999 to 2012 and match them into our credit card dataset. Following, Hsu, Matsa and Melzer (2012) we use the maximum UI benefits as the measure of unemployment protection. We define the maximum Ul benefits as the product of the maximum weekly benefit amounts (WBA) and the maximum number of weeks allowed. For example, in January 2000, Alabama allows a maximum of 26 weeks unemployment insurance during 52 week period and the maximum weekly benefit amounts (WBA) is $190. We use $4,940 (26 weeks times $190 WBA) as the level of 95 UI. For each state, we then calculate the annual percentage increase of UI. We use 10% annual growth as the cut-off and define a UI "jump" if it increases more or equal to 10% within a year. This allows us to run a standard Difference in Difference estimator to regress changes in card features on UI changes across states and across time. We use one year before and after the UI jumps to perform the Difference in Difference regressions. The reason to use this short cut off is that some states have a large increase in UI in one year and then small changes in follow on year. So we did not want to confound the impact of the UI change with small subsequent changes. Table 2.8 Panel A is the one year Diff-in-Diff regression results across our entire sample period (1999 to 2011). In column 1, the coefficient of UI jump is not significant. This suggests that an increase in the UI doesn't have significant effects on regular APRs. But in column (2) and (3) we see a greater reliance on backward-loaded payment features such as a very strong increase in the late fees and balance transfer APRs. Column 4 is for annual fees. UI doesn't have significant effects on annual fees. In the last column, we also look at whether credit card issuers use more intro APR programs when UI increases. For that purpose we build a dummy variable "Intro_APR_ All" for whether the credit card offer has either zero intro APR for regular purchases, balance transfer, or cash advance. We see in column (5) that indeed card issuers use more intro APR programs after UI increases have been implemented. We control year fixed effects, cell fixed effects, and bank fixed effects. We also repeated this regression set up using other time windows, e.g., two year windows around the change and the results are qualitatively and quantitatively very similar. We now repeat the same analysis in Table 2.8 Panel B but from 1999 to 2007. A lot of UI increases happened between 2008 and 2010. Since many other things also happened during this crisis period, there is a concern that other hidden variables drive our results. In order to mitigate this concern, we drop years after 2007 and only focus the period from 1999 to 2007 in Panel B. The regression results in Panel B are very similar with Panel A; Balance transfer APR, late fee, and zero intro APR increase after the UI jump. Moreover, when we drop the bank fixed effects, the regression results are quite similar with Table 2.8. This means that the results are not driven by banks differentially selecting to offer credit cards in states with UI changes. Our results are driven by the variation within bank decisions to change pricing policies based on the UI changes. Taken together these results suggest that credit card companies realize that there is an inherent trade off in the use of backward loaded or shrouded features of credit card offers: They might help in inducing customers to take on more (expensive) credit, but at the same time they expose the lender to people who pose a greater risk. Therefore we observe a greater reliance on these features when the customer pool has an (exogenous) improvement in credit quality. 96 2.5 Conclusion The paper shows that credit card issuers use different card features to separate customer groups with higher or lower propensity for behavioral biases. We show that less educated and poorer customers receive more card offers with backward loaded payment features, and they are also less likely to receive rewards programs that are targeted at richer and more educated people, especially miles but also points and cash back programs. In contrast, richer and more educated people receive more card offers with miles, cash back and points, but are much less likely to receive offers with low intro APR. This latter customer group gets on average better terms: lower interest rate and fees. Interestingly we find that cards with rewards that are predominantly offered to richer and more educated people do not show backward-loaded pricing structures. These results are in line with the insight of Gabaix and Laibson (2006) that suppliers will not offer shrouded terms on products which are mainly demanded by sophisticated consumers, since they can undo the shrouding and as a result hurt the profits of the firm. Finally our analysis highlights and important dimension of the use of shrouding and backward loading that has previously been ignored in the literature. It is beneficial for banks to maximize shrouding and backward loading of payments if this does not change the credit risk of customers. However, at an extreme these pricing strategies could attract customers who cannot afford the products that are offered. Using shocks to unemployment insurance, which reduce the credit risk of especially poorer customers, we show that banks are well aware of this trade off. They are willing to extend more backward loaded or "shrouded" credit to these customers when their overall credit risk is lower. The results in this paper provide evidence that credit card companies do screen for behavioral biases via the type of reward programs and low introductory APRs that are offered to customers. However, the interaction between behavioral screening and classic adverse selection is much more complex than the prior theory literature has taken into account. There appears to be an inbuilt trade off between the immediate benefits from using shrouded terms to charge higher cost of capital (via a combination of interest rates and fees) and their impact on increasing the credit risk of the customer pool by drawing in customers who do not understand the credit terms that they are offered and thus have a higher chance that they can ultimately not afford them. 97 2.6 Bibliography Agarwal, Sumit, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson. "Learning in the credit card market", NBER Working Paper (2008). Agarwal, Sumit, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson. "The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions over the Lifecycle with Implications for Regulation", Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. Fall,(2009):51-117. Agarwal, Sumit, Souphala Chomsisengphet, and Chunlin Liu. "The Importance of Adverse Selection in the Credit Card Market: Evidence from Randomized Trials of Credit Card Solicitations, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 42.4 (2010): 743-754. Agrawal, Ashwini K., and David A. Matsa."Labor unemployment risk and corporate financing decisions." Journal of FinancialEconomics 108.2 (2013): 449-470. Ausubel, Lawrence M. "The failure of competition in the credit card market." The American Economic Review (1991): 50-81. Bergstresser, Daniel, John MR Chalmers, and Peter Tufano. "Assessing the costs and benefits of brokers in the mutual fund industry." Review of FinancialStudies 22, no. 10 (2009): 4129-4156. Bertrand, Marianne, Dean S. Karlan, Sendhil Mullainathan, Eldar Shafir, and Jonathan Zinman. "What's advertising content worth? Evidence from a consumer credit marketing field experiment." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(1) (2010): 263-306. Beshears, John, James J. Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian. "Simplification and saving." Journal of economic behavior & organization 95 (2013): 130- 145. Campbell, John Y., Howell E. Jackson, Brigitte C. Madrian, and Peter Tufano. "Consumer financial protection." The journal of economic perspectives, 25.1 (2011): 91-114. Carlin, Bruce I. "Strategic price complexity in retail financial markets." Journal of FinancialEconomics, 91.3 (2009): 278-287. Cochrane, John H. "Finance: Function matters, not Size." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27 (2013): 29-50. Vigna, Stefano Della, and Ulrike Malmendier. "Contract design and self-control: Theory and evidence." The Quarterly Journal of Economics (2004): 353-402. DellaVigna, Stefano. "Psychology and economics: Evidence from the field." Journal of Economic Literature 47.2 (2009): 315-372. Gabaix, Xavier, and David Laibson. "Shrouded attributes, consumer myopia, and information suppression in competitive markets." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 121.2 (2006): 505-540. Greenwood, Robin M., and David S. Scharfstein. "The growth of modern finance." Journal of Economic Perspectives. (2012). Gross, David B., and Nicholas Souleles. "consumer response to changes in credit supply: evidence from credit card data." Center for Financial Institutions Working Papers 00-04, Wharton School Center for Financial Institutions, University of Pennsylvania (2000). 98 Grubb, Michael D. "Selling to overconfident consumers." The American Economic Review, 99.5 (2009): 1770-1807. Gurun, Umit G., Gregor Matvos, and Amit Seru. "Advertising expensive mortgages." National Bureau of Economic Research working paper (2013). Han, Song, Benjamin J. Keys, and Geng Li. "Unsecured Credit Supply over the Credit Cycle: Evidence from Credit Card Mailings." unpublished working paper (2013). Hastings, Justine S., and Olivia S. Mitchell. "How financial literacy and impatience shape retirement wealth and investment behaviors.", National Bureau of Economic Research (2011). Hastings, Justine S., Ali HortaAgsu, and Chad Syverson. "Advertising and competition in privatized social security: The case of Mexico.", National Bureau of Economic Research (2013). Heidhues, Paul, and Botond Koszegi. "Exploiting naivete about self-control in the credit market." The American Economic Review (2010): 2279-2303. Heitmann, M., Johnson, E. J., Herrmann, A. and Goldstein D. G. "Pricing Add-Ons as Totals: How Changing Price Display can Influence Consumer Choice." Working Paper (2014). Hortacsu, Ali, and Chad Syverson. "Product differentiation, search costs, and competition in the mutual fund industry: a case study of the S&P 500 Index Funds." Quarterly Journal of Economics,119 (2004): 403-456. Hsu, Joanne W., David A. Matsa, and Brian T. Melzer. "Unemployment Insurance and Consumer Credit." Unpublished Working Paper (2013). Koszegi, Botond. "Behavioral contract theory." Journal of Economic Literature. Forthcoming (2013). Lohse, Gerald L. "Consumer eye movement patterns on yellow pages advertising." Journal of Advertising, 26. 1 (1997): 61-73. Lohse, Gerald L., and Dennis L. Rosen. "Signaling quality and credibility in yellow pages advertising: the influence of color and graphics on choice." Journal of advertising, 30.2 (2001): 73-83. Maskin, Eric, and John Riley. "Monopoly with incomplete information." The RAND Journal of Economics, 15.2 (1984): 171-196. Merton, Robert C. "Financial innovation and economic performance." Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 4.4 (1992): 12-22. Miller, Merton H. "Financial innovation: The last twenty years and the next." Journal of Financialand Quantitative Analysis, 21.4 (1986): 459-471. Mussa, Michael, and Sherwin Rosen. "Monopoly and product quality." Journal of Economic theory, 18.2 (1978): 301-317. Shui, Haiyan, and Lawrence M. Ausubel. "Time inconsistency in the credit card market." In 14th Annual Utah Winter Finance Conference (2004). Thaler, Richard H., and Cass R. Sunstein. "Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness." Yale University Press (2008). Tufano, Peter. "Securities innovations: a historical and functional perspective." Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 7.4 (1995): 90-104. 99 Tufano, Peter. "Financial innovation." Handbook of the Economics of Finance 1 (2003): 307-335. 100 Figure 2-1: Monthly Time Trend of Reward 14 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 OA 0.2 0 -oe-Raward Figure 2-1 is the plot of monthly time trend of variable "Reward". Reward equals to how many reward programs the offer has out of Cash back, point and car rental insurance program. For each month, we calculate the average "Reward" of the credit card offers. 101 Figure 2-2: Monthly Time Trend of Size 9 8 7 6 5 4 S 2 1 0 -v-Ske Figure 2-2 is the plot of monthly time trend of variable "Size". Size is the maximum size of the reward programs minus the average size of all characters in every pages of each credit card offer. For each month, we calculate the average "Size" of the credit card offers. 102 . ..... .. -.: . ....... .... Figure 2-3: Monthly Time Trend of Color 0.7 0.6 0.4 OA 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 -.- Cobr Figure 2-3 is the plot of monthly time trend of variable "Color". "Color" is the dummy of whether reward programs in the offer use color other than black/white. For each month, we calculate the average "Color" of the credit card offers. 103 Figure 2-4: Monthly Time Trend of Picture 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 --. Picture Figure 2-4 is the plot of monthly time trend of variable "Picture". "Picture" is the file storage size of scanned images of credit card offers. The unit is megabyte (MB). For each month, we calculate the average "Picture" of the credit card offers. 104 Figure 2-5: Waterfall Regression Coefficients APRs and Fees by Education 0.10 0.00 High ?ol Some College Post Colege ate -0.10 -0.20 -0.30 -040 -0.50 -0.60 -@-APR -- +-ARPDefault -4--LateFee Reward Programs by Education 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00 High School e College -0.02 Post College Graduate -0.04 -0.06 -"-CASH -- &-POINT --- MILE -*--IntroAPR Figure 2-5 plot the estimated coefficients on the education from a regression where we regress individual card features on dummies for different education levels (as provided by Mintel). The regression results are reported in table 2.3. We omitted the highest education bin (graduate school) since it is very rare and noisy. 105 Figure 2-6: Waterfall Regression Coefficients APRs and Fees by Income 0.80 0.60 OAO 0.20 0.00 -020 -0.40 -0.60 -0.80 -*-APR -- o-ARP_Default -- a-LateFee Reward Programs by Income 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 -0.05 -0.10 -- e-CASH -- e-POINT -- e-MILE --- IntroAPR Figure 2-6 plot the estimated coefficients on the income from a regression where we regress individual card features on dummies for different income levels (as provided by Mintel). The regression results are reported in table 2.3. 106 ....... .... Figure 2-7: Simple Visual Credit Card Offer XYZ Bank Credit Card 0intro APR The new standardof excellence. Dear Sir/Madam, Congratulations! You're Pre-Approved for this Credit Card! It is time to get the card you deserve! And you pay $0 Annual Fee. Get Rewards on Every Purchase. Your Credit Card rewards you more by earning: * 2% reward points for every dollar spent on restaurants, airfare and gas * 1% reward points on all other purchases Points add up fast - make your purchases work for you. Get the Privileges. Save the Fee. With no annual fee, the value keeps coming. You will also receive a 0% introductory APR on purchases and balance transfers for the first 12 months. Additionally, we offer a Balance Transfer Fee that is only 3% of the amount. The Credit Card is designed for people who are smart with their money, and want to enjoy the benefits. Once you have the card, you can: - Get 24/7 online account access - Ask for e-alerts to make sure you don't forget when payment is due - Call us anytime with questions or concerns Request your card today, and let the rewards begin. Sincerely, David Hughes Senior Vice President Figure 2-7 is the sample of simple visual credit card offers. It has relatively small font size to emphasis the reward programs. It doesn't have many colors or flashy pictures. 107 lire 2-8: Higrh Visual Crpdit Crd Offer Dear Sir/Madam, You're Pre-Approvedfor a MisterGold Cardwith a Credit Line up to $3,000. Isn't it time you get the credit you deserve? Your credit history shows that you're a perfect match for this card. We offer you unmatched convenience, an exclusive rewards program, no annual fee and superb client service. Enjoy Premium0% Intro APR for the First12 Months. Enjoy a 0% introductory APR for 12 months on purchases and balance transfers after your account is opened - after that, a variable APR, currently 18.99%. That's a year of savingsl Enjoy the Benefits of Being a MisterGoldCard Member. Earn one point for every dollar you spend on purchases. You can redeem points for a statement credit towards any travel purchase you have made on the Card. It gets better. With the MisterGold card, there is no annual fee and you have the flexibility to pay for your purchases over time. Act Now and Get Your MisterGoldCard. Don't miss out on this exceptional opportunity to enjoy the benefits and buying power of your MisterGold card with a credit line up to $3,000. We look forward to welcoming you as a new XYZ Bank member. Sincerely, Julia Squire Senior Vice President Figure 2-8 is the sample of high visual credit card offers. It has relatively big font size to emphasis the reward programs. It also has many colors and flashy pictures to draw consumers' attention. 108 Table 2.1: Summary Statistics Data Variable FFR APR Max Card limit APRBalance APRCASH DefAPR Annualfee Latefee overlimitfee IntroAPR regular IntroAPRbalance IntroAPRcash Size Color Bold Picture Reward CASH POINT MILE Carrental Purchaseprct N 156 982767 526949 749264 942430 721393 1003977 1001221 898636 1014768 1014768 1014768 644865 644865 644865 803285 803285 803285 803285 803285 803285 803285 Mean 2.676708 12.64551 10.05231 11.33406 19.88759 26.51097 12.28505 33.8348 29.74222 0.4674211 0.4739418 0.0562621 4.709489 0.3210936 0.355845 0.229046 0.6762071 0.2105218 0.2382828 0.0878804 0.2274025 0.2340713 S.D. 2.137708 4.180521 1.366279 3.341435 4.282504 3.970656 31.99156 6.165273 10.15561 0.4989377 0.4993208 0.2304273 5.491711 0.466897 0.4787689 0.2638539 0.767116 0.4076795 0.4260333 0.283121 0.4191549 0.4234173 Min 0.0706452 0 6.214608 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.001715 0 0 0 0 0 0 Max 6.544516 79.9 15.42495 29.9 79.9 41 500 85 79 1 1 1 143.6293 1 1 4.10319 3 1 1 1 1 1 Note: FFR is the federal fund rate at monthly frequency. Other variables are based on Mintel's credit card's direct mail campaigns from March 1999 to February 2011. Variables from "Size" to "Purchaseprct" are from 80% of 1,014,768 total mail campaigns which have scanned images of credit card offers. Size is the maximum size of the reward programs minus the average size of the whole page in credit card offer. Color is the dummy of whether reward programs in the offer use color other than black/white in the offer. Bold is the dummy of whether the offer use bold to highlight reward programs. If there is no reward programs in the offer, we put missing value to Size, Color, and Bold. Picture is the file size of each page of the offer which is the measurement of how many or how large are pictures in the offer. Reward is the number of reward programs of CASH POINT and Car rental insurance in each offer. CASH, POINT, MILE, Carrental, Purchaseprct are dummies of whether the offer has these reward programs respectively. Intro APRregular, Intro_APRbalance and IntroAPRcash are the dummies of whether the offer has 0% introductory APR for regular purchase, balance transfer and cash advance respectively. APR is the regular purchase APR of the credit card offer which is the middle point if APR is a range in the offer. Card Limit is the log of maximum credit card limit stated in the offer. Annual fee, late fee and over limit fee are fees charged by credit card company which usually are in shumerbox. 109 Table 2.2: Descriptive Statistics for Format Design of Credit Card Offers Penal A Percentage of cards that have this term Term mentioned on 1st page Font size of term if mentioned on 1st page Font size of CC term if NOT mentioned on first page Font color of CC term if mentioned on first page Font color of CC term if NOT mentioned on first page Font bold of CC term if mentioned on first page Font bold of CC term if NOT mentioned on first page # Obs Late fee DefAPR 100.00% MILE 100.00% Over Annual CASH POINT limit fee fee 100.00% 100.00% 21.05% 23.83% 8.79% Carrental Intro APR 51.64% 22.74% 5.80% 4.97% 6.96% 79.28% 100% 93.51% 100% 80.48% 91.04% 9.49 9.28 9.80 13.24 11.16 11.47 14.12 10.27 11.27 9.57 9.63 9.50 13.76 10.62 10.80 9.91 10.04 10.62 33.98% 37.88% 27.73% 66.86% 40.13% 42.84% 47.12% 24.34% 32.28% 24.67% 26.19% 27.73% 44.35% 37.24% 38.45% 29.47% 23.31% 32.29% 38.59% 27.77% 35.07% 79.01% 47.24% 43.90% 56.34% 10.56% 53.15% 49.00% 19.59% 34.53% 53.20% 29.97% 18.08% 13.08% 39.99% 776,624 776,624 776,624 776,624 803,285 803,285 803,285 803,285 776,624 Late fee Default APR 28.20% 27.01% Over Annual limit fee fee 27.58632 7.691491 30.11493 33.22181 36.58% Penal B if term is on first page 29.38247 if term is in the back 35.10307 (schumer box) Note: The dataset is based on Mintel's credit card's direct mail campaigns from March 1999 to February 2011. Descriptive statistics are based on 80% of 1,014,768 total mail campaigns which have scanned images of credit card offers. Penal A is the descriptive statistics of format information of credit card terms and reward programs. In Penal A, late fee, default APR. over limit fee and annual fee appears in 776,624 offers since we have missing pages of Schumer box where these terms usually appear. IntroAPRs contains all introductory APR programs: regular intro APR, balance transfer Intro APR and cash advance Intro APR. Size is the maximum size of the reward programs in credit card offer. Color is the dummy of whether reward programs in the offer use color other than black/white in the offer. Bold is the dummy of whether the offer use bold to highlight reward programs. Picture is the file size of each page of the offer which is the measurement of how many or how large are pictures in the offer. Penal B is the descriptive statistics of credit card terms when they mentioned on the first page or not. "First page" includes the envelop and the first page letter of credit card offers. 110 Table 2.3: Credit Card Features and Demographics Variable FFR Education_2 Education_3 Education_4 Education_5 Education_6 Income_2 Income_3 Income_4 Income_5 Income_6 Income_7 Income_8 Income_9 Age FE State FE HH Compo FE Bank FE Observations R-squared (1) APR (3) (2) CardLimit DefAPR (4) Late Fee (5) CASH (6) POINT (7) MILE 0.352*** (0.076) -0.039 (0.029) 0.033 (0.037) -0.067 (0.045) 0.003 (0.047) 0.043 (0.047) -0.227*** (0.036) -0.348*** (0.050) -0.451*** (0.056) -0.530*** (0.070) -0.606*** (0.078) -0.561*** (0.084) -0.419*** (0.095) -0.390*** (0.096) 0.005 (0.010) 0.095*** (0.008) 0.103*** (0.011) 0.206*** (0.013) 0.242*** (0.015) 0.003 (0.013) 0.118*** (0.011) 0.178*** (0.013) 0.228*** (0.014) 0.301*** (0.015) 0.361*** (0.016) 0.380*** (0.017) 0.405*** (0.018) 0.419*** (0.018) 0.882*** (0.096) -0.009 (0.030) -0.031 (0.031) -0.026 (0.040) -0.111*** (0.039) -0.009 (0.047) 0.092*** (0.029) 0.149*** (0.035) 0.132*** (0.040) 0.225*** (0.048) 0.263*** (0.060) 0.356*** (0.070) 0.431*** (0.081) 0.543*** (0.087) -0.242* (0.133) -0.104** (0.041) -0.310*** (0.051) -0.264*** (0.055) -0.528*** (0.078) 0.086 (0.067) 0.133* (0.074) 0.135** (0.066) 0.322*** (0.077) 0.431*** (0.088) 0.462*** (0.098) 0.581*** (0.110) 0.612*** (0.131) 0.556*** (0.139) -0.012*** (0.004) 0.015*** (0.002) 0.010*** (0.002) 0.018*** (0.003) 0.011*** (0.003) 0.003 (0.004) 0.020*** (0.003) 0.026*** (0.003) 0.030*** (0.003) 0.044*** (0.004) 0.048*** (0.005) 0.048*** (0.005) 0.047*** (0.006) 0.040*** (0.006) 0.010*** (0.003) 0.008*** (0.002) 0.004 (0.003) 0.009*** (0.003) 0.004 (0.004) 0.005 (0.005) 0.013*** (0.002) 0.022*** (0.003) 0.026*** (0.003) 0.035*** (0.003) 0.042*** (0.003) 0.047*** (0.004) 0.049*** (0.005) 0.051*** (0.005) 0.008*** -0.026*** (0.002) (0.005) 0.013*** -0.002 (0.002) (0.002) 0.019*** -0.015*** (0.001) (0.003) 0.046*** -0.026*** (0.003) (0.004) 0.064*** -0.049*** (0.004) (0.004) 0.003 -0.003 (0.003) (0.005) 0.015*** 0.002 (0.002) (0.004) 0.022*** -0.002 (0.002) (0.004) 0.028*** -0.006 (0.002) (0.005) 0.045*** -0.014*** (0.003) (0.005) 0.059*** -0.021*** (0.003) (0.006) 0.076*** -0.035*** (0.004) (0.006) 0.100*** -0.051*** (0.006) (0.008) 0.117*** -0.066*** (0.008) (0.006) -0.014 (0.014) 0.069*** (0.007) 0.075*** (0.008) 0.159*** (0.011) 0.190*** (0.014) -0.003 (0.013) 0.079*** (0.010) 0.111*** (0.011) 0.137*** (0.011) 0.200*** (0.013) 0.247*** (0.014) 0.291*** (0.016) 0.336*** (0.020) 0.380*** (0.022) Y Y Y Y 942,397 0.253 Y Y Y Y 496,063 0.607 Y Y Y Y 713,882 0.310 Y Y Y Y 961,247 0.157 Y Y Y Y 777,192 0.248 Y Y Y Y 777,192 0.262 Y Y Y Y 777,192 0.075 Y Y Y Y 629,637 0.080 (8) (9) IntroAPR Format Y Y Y Y 972,260 0.159 Note: OLS regressions to estimate relationship between credit card features and consumer's demographics. Data is restricted to offers we have scanned pictures from column 5,6,7, and 9. Format is the first principal component of reward programs' size, color, bold and the picture sizes on the credit card offers.Income_ 2 is the dummy for households whose annual income is from 15k to 25K. Income_3 is for 25k to 35k. Income.Income_4 is for 35k to 50k. Income_5 is for 50k to 75k. Income_6 is for 75k to 100k. Income_7 is for 100k to 150k. Inocme_8 is for 150k to 200k. Income_9 is for over 200k. Education_2 is dummy for household head whoes highest education is high school. Education_3 is for some college. Education 4 is for graduated college. Education_5 is for post college graduate. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by month. Regressions are controlled by age fixed effects, household composition fixed effects, state fixed effects and bank fixed effects. 111 Table 2.4: Relationship Between APRs/Fees and Reward Program Panel A Variable FFR POINT (1) APR (2) APR (3) APR (4) APR (5) DefAPR (6) (7) DefAPR DefAPR (8) Late Fee (9) Late Fee (10) Late Fee 0.326*** (0.004) -0.844*** (0.013) 0.314*** (0.005) -0.671*** (0.013) 0.258*** (0.005) -0.062*** (0.012) 0.759*** (0.005) 0.750*** (0.013) -0.160*** (0.007) 2.063*** (0.018) No Yes Yes 753,690 0.214 No Yes No 616,957 0.116 No Yes Yes 616,957 0.313 No Yes No 769,923 0.0226 -0.277*** (0.009) 0.869*** (0.024) 0.434*** (0.010) No Yes No 769,923 0.0258 -0.133*** (0.007) 1.510*** (0.015) No Yes No 753,690 0.0218 0.808*** (0.006) 1.341*** (0.025) -0.197*** (0.007) No Yes No 616,957 0.118 0.733*** (0.005) 0.429*** (0.012) Yes No No 778,497 0.0282 0.373*** (0.005) 0.007 (0.023) -0.244*** (0.007) No Yes No 753,690 0.0241 (1) APR (2) APR (3) APR (4) APR (5) DefAPR (6) DefAPR (7) DefAPR (9) (10) (8) Late Fee Late Fee Late Fee 0.312*** (0.004) -0.528*** (0.012) 0.301*** (0.005) -0.451*** (0.013) 0.255*** (0.005) -0.165*** (0.012) 0.784*** (0.005) 0.002 (0.015) -0.120*** (0.008) 1.573*** (0.019) No Yes No 753,690 0.0189 No Yes Yes 753,690 0.214 0.846*** (0.006) 0.621*** (0.027) -0.238*** (0.008) No Yes No 616,957 0.111 0.748*** (0.005) 0.587*** (0.015) Yes No No 778,497 0.0236 0.395*** (0.006) 0.472*** (0.020) -0.363*** (0.006) No Yes No 753,690 0.0242 No Yes Yes 616,957 0.315 No Yes No 769,923 0.0127 POINT*FFR State FE Cell FE Bank FE Observations R-squared No Yes Yes 769,923 0.227 Panel B Variable FFR CASH CASH*FFR State FE Cell FE Bank FE Observations R-squared No Yes No 616,957 0.109 -0.139*** (0.008) 1.381*** (0.026) 0.076*** (0.011) No Yes No 769,923 0.0128 -0.109*** (0.007) 0.845*** (0.022) No Yes Yes 769,923 0.221 Note: Panel A shows OLS regressions to estimate relationship between point reward programs and credit card APRs and fees. Panel B shows OLS regressions to estimate relationship between cash back reward programs and credit card APRs and fees. Data is restricted to offers we have scanned pictures. Regressions in column 1 is controlled by state fixed effects. Regression 2 to 8 are controlled by demographic cell fixed effects based on states, age, income, education and household composition. Regressions in column 3,7 and 10 are controlled by bank fixed effects. POINT is the dummy of whether the credit card offer has point reward program or not. CASH is the dummy of whether the credit card offer has cash back reward program or not. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by cells. 112 Table 2.5: Mileage Program vs. Zero Introductory APR Program Panel A Variable FFR (1) APR (2) APR (3) APR 0.314*** 0.294*** 0.241*** (0.004) (0.005) (0.005) 1.698*** 1.938*** 1.971*** (0.018) (0.019) (0.020) (4) APR (5) DefAPR (6) DefAPR (7) DefAPR (9) (10) (8) Late Fee Late Fee Late Fee 0.783*** (0.005) 0.332*** (0.024) 0.742*** (0.005) 0.317*** (0.017) No Yes No 616,957 0.110 0.774*** (0.005) 0.058 (0.044) 0.100*** (0.012) No Yes No 616,957 0.110 No Yes Yes 616,957 0.312 -0.125*** -0.028*** -0.107*** (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) -2.724*** 0.128 -1.507*** (0.063) (0.090) (0.051) -0.992*** (0.034) No No No Yes Yes Yes No No Yes 769,923 769,923 769,923 0.0176 0.0249 0.223 Yes No No 778,497 0.0350 No Yes No 753,690 0.0368 No Yes Yes 753,690 0.234 0.278*** (0.005) 1.448*** (0.028) 0.170*** (0.010) No Yes No 753,690 0.0373 (1) APR (2) APR (3) APR (4) APR (5) DefAPR (6) DefAPR (10) (9) (8) (7) DefAPR Late Fee Late Fee Late Fee 0.397*** (0.004) IntroAPR -0.950*** (0.012) IntroAPR*FFR 0.391*** (0.005) -0.990*** (0.012) 0.326*** (0.004) -0.740*** (0.013) 0.891*** (0.005) 0.183*** (0.011) No Yes No 942,397 0.0452 No Yes Yes 942,397 0.238 0.774*** (0.005) 0.058 (0.044) 0.100*** (0.012) No Yes No 713,882 0.127 0.859*** (0.005) State FE Cell FE Bank FE Observations R-squared 0.664*** (0.006) 0.560*** (0.022) -0.566*** (0.006) No Yes No 942,397 0.0613 MILE MILE*FFR State FE Cell FE Bank FE Observations R-squared Panel B Variable FFR Yes No No 982,736 0.0486 No Yes No 713,882 0.126 (0.011) -0.286*** (0.007) 1.035*** (0.016) No Yes Yes 713,882 0.300 No Yes No 961,247 0.0148 0.571*** -0.479*** (0.009) -0.082*** (0.025) 0.411*** (0.010) No Yes No 961,247 0.0185 -0.239*** (0.007) 1.105*** (0.017) No Yes Yes 961,247 0.209 Note: Panel A shows OLS regressions to estimate relationship between mileage reward programs and credit card APRs and fees. Panel B shows OLS regressions to estimate relationship between zero intro APR reward programs reward programs and credit card APRs and fees. Data is restricted to offers we have scanned pictures in Panel A. Panel B includes the entire credit card offer sample with and without scanned pictures. Regressions in column 1 is controlled by state fixed effects. Regression 2 to 8 are controlled by demographic cell fixed effects based on states, age, income, education and household composition. Regressions in column 3,7 and 10 are controlled by bank fixed effects. MILE is the dummy of whether the credit card offer has mileage reward program or not. IntroAPR is the dummy of whether the credit card offer has 0 intro APR for regular purchase or not. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by cells. 113 Table 2.6: Relationship Between APRs/Fees and Credit Card Offer Design Variable FFR Format (1) APR (2) APR (3) APR (4) APR (5) DefAPR (7) (6) DefAPR DefAPR (10) (9) (8) Late Fee Late Fee Late Fee 0.229*** (0.004) 0.374*** (0.004) 0.232*** (0.005) 0.393*** (0.005) 0.198*** (0.005) 0.426*** (0.004) 0.797*** (0.006) 0.274*** (0.005) 0.738*** (0.005) 0.208*** (0.005) -0.087*** (0.008) 0.160*** (0.009) -0.060*** (0.007) 0.009 (0.009) Yes No No 623,476 0.0297 No Yes No 608,946 0.0321 No Yes Yes 608,946 0.177 0.198*** (0.005) 0.420*** (0.007) 0.002 (0.002) No Yes No 608,946 0.177 No Yes No 510,788 0.131 No Yes No 510,788 0.310 No Yes No 627,119 0.00176 No Yes No 627,119 0.186 FormatFFR State FE Cell FE Bank FE Observations R-squared 0.743*** (0.005) 0.333*** (0.008) -0.048*** (0.002) No Yes Yes 510,788 0.311 -0.057*** (0.007) 0.077*** (0.010) -0.026*** (0.005) No Yes Yes 627,119 0.186 Note: OLS regressions to estimate relationship between credit card offer design and credit card APRs and fees. Data is restricted to offers we have scanned pictures and reward programs. Regressions in column 1 is controlled by state fixed effects. Regression 2 to 8 are controlled by demographic cell fixed effects based on states, age, income, education and household composition. Regressions in column 3,7 and 10 are controlled by bank fixed effects. Format is the first principal component of reward programs' size, color, bold and the picture sizes on the credit card offers. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by cells. 114 Table 2.7: Regular APR vs. Late Fees Variable FFR LateFee (1) APR (2) APR (3) APR (4) APR (5) APR (6) APR (7) APR (8) APR 0.571*** (0.015) -0.066*** (0.001) 0.568*** (0.013) -0.057*** (0.001) 0.459*** (0.011) -0.016*** (0.001) 0.809*** (0.010) -0.024*** (0.002) 1.945*** (0.056) -0.065*** (0.002) 0.493*** (0.013) -0.029*** (0.002) 0.424*** (0.011) 0.030*** (0.002) 0.761*** (0.011) -0.077*** (0.002) 0.666*** (0.009) -0.017*** (0.002) 0.837*** (0.073) -0.059*** (0.002) 2.278*** (0.071) -0.094*** (0.002) -2.193*** (0.092) 0.115*** (0.003) Yes No Yes No 749,983 0.168 -0.906*** (0.086) 0.080*** (0.002) Yes No Yes Yes 749,983 0.347 Reward LateFee*Reward IntroAPR LateFee*IntroAPR MILE LateFee*MILE Year FE State FE Cell FE Bank FE Observations R-squared Yes Yes No No 975,486 0.165 Yes No Yes No 936,641 0.150 Yes No Yes Yes 936,641 0.332 Yes Yes No No 773,694 0.172 Yes No Yes No 936,641 0.173 Yes No Yes Yes 936,641 0.348 Note: OLS regressions to estimate relationship between regular APR and late fees in credit card offers. Data is restricted to offers we have scanned pictures in column 2, 7 and 8. Regressions in column 1 and 2 are controlled by state fixed effects. Regression in column 3 to 8 are controlled by demographic cell fixed effects based on states, age, income, education and household composition. Regressions in column 5, 6 and 8 are controlled by bank fixed effects. Reward is the number of reward programs of CASH POINT and Car rental insurance in each offer. MILE is the dummy of whether the credit card offer has mileage reward program or not. IntroAPR is the dummy of whether the credit card offer has 0 intro APR for regular purchase or not. All regressions are controlled by year fixed effects. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by cells. 115 Table 2.8: Unemployment Insurance and Credit Card Features Panel A Variable (1) APR (2) APRBalance (3) Late Fee (4) AnnualFee (5) IntroAPRAll FFR 0.237*** UI (0.029) 0.030 (0.047) 0.160* (0.088) Yes Yes Yes 128,778 0.265 0.169 (0.266) 0.292 0.459*** (0.104) 0.107*** (0.039) Yes Yes Yes 63,134 0.190 129,344 0.237 0.005* (0.003) Yes Yes Yes 131,025 0.133 Variable (1) APR (2) APRBalance (3) Late Fee (4) AnnualFee (5) IntroAPRAll FFR 0.223*** UI (0.028) -0.014 (0.036) 0.537*** (0.148) 0.102** (0.043) Yes Yes Yes 57,510 0.197 0.179* (0.092) Yes Yes Yes 122,439 0.258 -0.016 (0.347) 0.008*** Yes Yes Yes 122,965 0.245 Yes Yes Yes 124,616 0.132 Year FE Cell FE Bank FE Observations R-squared Yes Yes Yes 127,697 Yes Yes Yes Panel B Year FE Cell FE Bank FE Observations R-squared Yes Yes Yes 121,467 0.297 (0.003) Note. OLS regressions to estimate unemployment insurance effects on credit card features. Panel A includes the credit card offers from 1999 to 2011. Panel B is from 1999 to 2007. All regressions are controlled by year fixed effects, bank fixed effects and cell fixed effects based on states, age, income, education and household composition. UI is the dummy which equals 1 if unemployment insurance increases by more than 10% in this year and 0 in the year before the increase. IntroAPRAll is the dummy for whether the credit card offers have any of introductory APRs for regular purchase, balance transfer or cash advance. Standard errors are clustered at the state level. 116 Chapter 3 Privatization, Politics, and Corruption 3.1 Introduction In the 1990s, a huge wave of privatization swept across the world, especially in such countries as Mexico, Central Europe, the Soviet Union, and China. In 1978, SOEs in China controlled 99% of the production. Thirty years later, in 2008, this figure had decreased dramatically to 32%.1 There has been much debate around the reasons why governments want to privatize state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and what the effects of such privatization are? On the theory side, there has been a long debate why SOEs exist. There are three main views about SOEs: social view, agency view and political view. The social view claims that government's object is to maximize social welfare and private firms can't internalize the positive externalities (e.g., Stiglitz (1993)). Agency view argues that managers of SOEs have less incentives (Tirole(1994)), because SOEs have more objectives than private firms and need to serve multiple masters (Dixit(1997)). Political view assumes that politicians have their personal goals which are conflicted with social welfare maximization (Shleifer and Vishny(1994)). SOEs are captured by politicians and pursue their self-interested objects. I provide the suggestive evidence of political view in this paper. I investigate the impacts of privatization on SOEs and private firms in order to understand the influence of privatization on the economy. I use detailed firmlevel data on the Chinese manufacturing sector that include both SOEs and private firms from 1998 to 2005 (The Chinese Industry Census Dataset (CIC)). This dataset contains detailed financial information as well as other firms' variables such as their registration type, percentage state ownership, number of workers, average wages and so on. That allows me to study both partial privatization (selling part of the assets to private owners) and full privatization (changing registration types). 'Thirty Years of Phenomenal Achievements, National Bureau of Statistics, China Statistics Press, 2008. 117 It is well known that decisions regarding privatization are not random. 2 Government usually picks some SOEs for privatization in preference to others based on firms' financial characteristics or other reasons. To deal with this selection bias, I use political turnover timing as an instrument variable for privatization. Politics has a big influence on government-owned firms. Shleifer and Vishny (1994) argue that politicians capture SOEs to derive their own benefit from them. Dinc and Gupta (2011) find evidence that government's decision to privatization in India also depends on political costs and benefits. To investigate the role of politicians in China, I hand-collected every city mayor's profile from 1990 to 2011. Combined with CIC firm data, I find that politicians delay privatization during turnover years. The number of privatized SOEs and the amount of privatized assets are significantly lower when a city changes mayors. This evidence is consistent with the argument that negative effects of privatization, such as layoffs, may cost government the political supports of its people3 . It is a similar story in China. When new mayors take over the city, they want to build their reputation and gain support from citizens or their superiors. Doing a lot of privatizations may hurt them. Another story could be that mayors have greater incentives to privatize SOEs before turnover since they can usually gain extra rents from privatization. There are many cases that state-owned assets were sold at significantly lower prices and politicians got their cuts from the deal. Based on these instances, I use political turnover timing as an instrumental variable for privatization. To verify this instrumental variable's quality, first I use the Cox proportional hazard model to study the turnover of mayors. The only variable that shows a significant effect on turnover is age. In China, the retirement age is 60 for males and 55 for females. Moreover, age is a constraint on promotion. For example, city mayors are usually between 40 and 50 years old. Those who are too young or too old cannot be promoted as city mayors. This mitigates the concern that provincial politicians might select younger/older mayors in cities where they want less/more privatizations. More importantly, cities' economic performance, such as average ROA and total net profits from firms, don't have significant effects on the hazard ratio either. It turns out that the length that a mayor has been in a city has strong predictive powers on turnover. I also use the probit model to double check these results and find that turnover again is not dependent on economic conditions. This result can mitigate the concern that the timing of turnover might be endogenous, since politicians are assigned by government instead of voted for in China. Second, for the exclusion condition, turnover should affect SOEs' performance only through privatization. To examine this, I pick a sub-sample of SOEs who are 100% state-owned during my entire sample period and estimate whether turnover has effects on these SOEs. The results show that turnover doesn't have significant effects on 100% state-owned SOEs. To study privatization's effect on SOEs, I use both actual political turnover and years the mayors have been in the cities to instrument privatizations and perform 2Gupta, Ham and Svejnar (2008) argues that more profitable firms got privatized first in Czech. Government's decision of privatization is endogenous and there is selection bias of using privatization directly to study its effects. 3Lindbeck and Weibull(1987), Dixit and Londregan (1996) 118 2SLS. For privatization's effects on private firms, I employ difference-in-differences identification by estimating the difference between the industry in a certain province that has privatized SOEs and the ones that have not. I found that privatization can increase SOEs' efficiency by 50% and increase private firms' efficiency by 100%. Moreover, SOEs cut 64% of their workers after being privatized. Private firms increase 16.3% employment if there are privatizations around. Overall, every 100 workers got fired by SOEs come with an 169 increase in private sector hiring in the same industry and same province. I also look at the politicians' individual effects on firm performance and other activities by estimating politicians' fixed effect. In my dataset, 60% of the politicians have been mayors in more than two cities. I am able to catch this part of the variations and find that politicians have a large influence on SOEs under their jurisdiction. But they have less influence on SOEs that have higher political hierarchies (provincial level and central government level). Moreover, to study the heterogeneity of politicians' individual effects further, I identify "bad" politicians if they have been in jail because of corruption. The results show that SOEs performed worse if there were corrupt politicians in the city. Also, SOEs under "bad" politicians tend to have more market power, an effect that is not significant for private firms. This evidence can be explained best by the political view of SOEs. 4 Overall, this paper documents the evidence of privatization's effect on China's economy. The results also support the political view of SOEs and suggest that politicians are motivated by self-interested benefits and capture SOEs to achieve their own goals. The paper is organized as follows. The next section presents the literature review and history of economic reform in China. Section 3.3 describes the data. Section 3.4 presents the empirical methodology, and Section 3.5 shows the results. Section 3.6 examines politicians' individual effects and corruption. Section 3.7 concludes. 3.2 3.2.1 Literature review and economic reform in China Literature review There are three main views about SOEs: social view, agency view and political view. The social view claims that government's object is to maximize social welfare. Private firms have different goals: maximize their own profits which sometimes has negative externalities and we call them market failures. Government can cure market failures by intervening in the case of negative externalities such as pollution, regulating natural monopolies and providing public goods. One way of doing it is to set up SOEs. For example, Stiglitz (1993) argues that private banks may not give money to high social returns projects and we need state owned banks to do it instead. Sappington and 4Shleilfer and Vishny (1994) argues that politicians' are self-interested and they are able to capture SOEs to achieve their personal goals. And the only way to fix it is to fully privatize SOEs. 119 Stiglitz (1987) argues that SOEs can reduce government intervention transaction cost to do social optimal projects. Agency view is based on the same assumption as social view that government wants to maximize social welfare. However, managers of SOEs have less incentives (Tirole (1994)), because SOEs have more objectives than private firms and need to serve multiple masters (Dixit(1997)). Moreover, there is no owner with strong incentives to monitor managers because they bear all the monitoring costs but only benefit a fraction (Alchian(1965)). Vickers and Yarrow(1988, 1991) also point out that asymmetric information can give managers bargaining power to oversees. Under this view, SOEs intend to do socially beneficial projects but managers would put less efforts. Government needs to strike the balance between social welfare gains and internal inefficiencies. Political view assumes that politicians have their personal goals which are conflicted with social welfare maximization (Shleifer and Vishny (1994)). SOEs are captured by politicians and pursue their self-interested objects such as political supports from people, direct benefits to friends or even putting money into their own pockets. In return, politicians give privileges to SOEs via government subsidy, tax treatment and market power. Under this view, politicians use tax payers money to capture SOEs and force them to achieve their own goals. Shleifer and Vishny (1994) and Boycko, Shleifer , and Vishny (1996b) argue that full privatization is the only sure way to solve this political inefficiency because privatizations increases the intervention costs to politicians. Social and agency view share the same key assumption that government's goal is to maximize the social welfare. Political view assumes that politicians are selfinterested. Under all these three views, privatization would increase the SOEs' efficiency. However, the first two views predict that private firms around privatized SOEs will suffer since after privatization, SOEs' goal become the same as private firms(e.g. stop provide public goods) and there are more competition in the market. Under political view, privatization of SOEs will benefit private firms because politicians will "bribe" SOEs less(e.g. less protection from competition) and give more opportunities to private firms. On empirical side, efficiency improvement during privatization is well documented. La Porta and Les-de-Silanes (1999) study Mexico privatizations between 1983 and 1991 which suggests that privatizations have an average of 54 percent gain in output, half worker being laid off with increased wage, and productivity surge by 64 percent after privatization. Frydman, Gary, Hessel and Rapaczynski (1999) consider the similar objective on central Europe countries' privatization tide around 1994. They argue that privatized SOEs perform better than before, but the performance improvement is only significant on the revenue measure for the firms sold to outside owners. No obvious sign of productivity jump if SOEs were privatized to inside owners, for example, the former managers. There are many recent empirical works have been done on political view of SOEs. Dinc and Gupta (2011) look at Indian political election voting shares of different parties to define the political competition and use it as IV of privatization. The evidence suggest that government delays privatization where the political party faces more competition and privatizations improve SOEs' efficiency. 120 To my knowledge, it is probably the most similar work with this paper. 3.2.2 History of Chinese SEOs' reform Economic reform and the privatization of SOEs in China started in 1978. This reform and opening-up policy was initiated by Xiaoping Deng, the successor of Chairman Mao Zedong. There were three main stages of privatization. The first period was from 1978 to 1984, when SOEs started to pay tax instead of giving profits directly to the government. This was not successful because the tax rate was too high (around 55%) and many SOEs were unable to pay. The second period was from 1986 to 1993, when SOEs could be contracted out, which gave the managers and contractors more incentives. However, since ownership did not change and the regulations were not good, contractors extracted rents as much as possible, which harmed state owned assets. The third stage was from 1993 to 2005. During this stage, SOEs have sold to other investors, such as institution investors, private investors and so on. In this paper, I focus only on the third stage because it is true "privatization" and is also the most influential reform among SOEs. After 2005, State-owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission put more strict rules of privatization which lowered down the privatization process significantly. A competitive market is one of the main forces that has accelerated the privatization of Chinese SOEs. Yao (2005) uses survey data of 800 SOEs from 1995 to 2001 to show that insolvency was the big problem among many SOEs, and government and state banks did not want to support these firms anymore, so privatization became the most efficient way out. By 1988, more than 40,000 SOEs had been privatized or reorganized. Yao's study shows that the new reform between 1997 and 1998 improved SOEs' efficiency a lot. In China, SOEs, especially the big ones, have many privileges and resources from their political connections. For example, SOEs control a large variety of industries including oil, electricity, telecommunications, finance, and so on. The big names among China's SOEs include China National Petroleum Corporation, China Mobile, and China Telecom. Moreover, banks are more willing to loan money to SOEs because of their state backing. In a few cases, the state has allowed SOEs to go bankrupt and has bailed out some that have been in trouble. Many top managers of these big SOEs end up being government officials at either central or state government level. More interestingly, there is a party committee in each SOE that exerts considerable influence over a firm's daily activities and big decisions. Accordingly, Chinese SOEs are very closely connected with politicians and government. SOEs also comprise a big part of the Chinese economy. The CIC dataset reveals that in 1998 SOEs controlled 42% of assets in the economy. This had dropped to 18% by 2005. 121 3.3 3.3.1 Data Description Data The data for this paper come from two sources: (1) The Chinese Industry Census (CIC) from 1998 to 2005 , (2) the Zechen Database and (3) the Baidu Encyclopaedia Database. The CIC dataset, which is collected by the Chinese National Bureau of Statistics (NBS), includes any manufacturing firm in China with annual sales of more than RMB 5 million (around US$700,000). It has detailed annual accounting data and firm characteristics such as the number of workers, industry category, location, registration type, political hierarchy, government subsidy, wages, and so on. In total, there are about 380,000 firms comprising about 40% of industrial output in China. To my knowledge, CIC is the most detailed database on Chinese manufacturing firms and the content and quality are very good. One potential concern is that SOEs might over report their performance to impress the government. SOEs' managers' promotions depend on firms' economic performance. This could lead to a downward bias of privatization's effects, and the real effects should be more positive. Using firm registration type from the CIC dataset, I can classify a firm as an SOE or a private firm. Moreover, I also have the shareholders' data, which has enabled me to calculate the percentage share-holdings by the state and other investors. This is the main measurement used this paper since many privatizations in China are partial, which means the state sells part of the SOEs to private firms, and it usually takes several years to fully privatize a SOE. The location data in the CIC dataset is an 11-digit number that can locate the firm at street level. I cut the first four digits to identify the city and use it to match the politician dataset. My second data source is the Zechen Database, which provides the names of all the mayors and secretaries of municipal committee in each city from 1949 to 2011. I manually collected the list of mayors' and secretaries' names as well as their terms of office on a monthly basis. I also collected data for members of the provincial committees of the Communist Party of China. In sum, this dataset covers all 334 cities and 31 provinces in China. Based on the lists constructed from the Zechen Database, I also hand collect these politicians' profiles from the Baidu Encyclopaedia database, a Chinese language collaborative Web-based encyclopaedia provided by the Chinese search engine Baidu. Baidu Encyclopaedia is the number 1 online Chinese encyclopaedia and generally provides very good profiles of famous people (better than the public official profile for politicians). However, the quality of politicians' profile still varies among different cities, especially small ones. In order to fix this, I also use the Xinhua News Website as a supplementary source to cross check the data from the Baidu Encyclopaedia. Xinhua News is the official press agency of the People's Republic of China and the biggest center for collecting information and press conferences in China. It is also the largest news agency in China, and has complied profile files for some politicians. The final 5 This dataset has been used in many other papers such as Chang and Klenow(2009), Huang, Jin and Qian(2012), Dougherty and Herd (2005), Geng (2006) 122 profile dataset includes 2,227 city-level politicians (both city mayors and secretaries) and 574 provincial-level politicians. Among them, I am able to get about 1,674 city level politicians' profiles. Each profile has the politician's gender, age, education, and place of birth. For education, I have used a dummy variable of whether the politician has a college degree (or a higher qualification) or not. Place of birth is a four-digit city ID. Moreover, we have some politicians with the same name (very common in China). In order to fix this, I double-checked the politicians who have the same name and distinguished by their different ID numbers. 3.3.2 Matching Politicians to Firms The CIC data include names and addresses of all firms. I use the first four-digit city code to identify the firm's location. For the politicians' data, I also have the same four-digit city code for each one. Based on this location information, I merge the CIC dataset with the politicians' dataset at city level. As a result, 95% of the CIC data matches up with the politicians' dataset. Table 3.1 presents the summary statistics of key variables in these datasets. In China, there are several political hierarchy levels headed by the central government in Beijing. Under the central government are 31 provinces and four municipalities: Beijing, Tianjing, Shanghai, and Chongqing. Beneath those are about 300 cities, which are what this paper looks at. There are also thousands of counties in China controlled by cities. Since the firms in the CIC dataset are the biggest in China, many are located in cities. In case where they are located in small counties, they still fall under the jurisdiction of the city. Moreover, the CIC dataset also contains information about firms' political hierarchy level. In China, each firm needs to answer to a certain level of government. From this information, I can determine a politician's influence on a firm. For example, firms whose hierarchy is at central government level need to listen to the central government and may not need to answer to the city government where they are actually located. 3.3.3 Summary Statistics Table 3.1 presents summary statistics for variables of interest for the CIC dataset and the data relating to politicians. To analyze privatization's effects on SOEs and its externalities on private firms, I mainly use percentage of private share to measure privatization. In China, most of the SOEs' privatizations are partial, which means government usually sells part of the assets to private owners. I also use the changes in firms' registration types to construct the dummy to capture whether the firm was transferred from a SOE to private ownership. The top panel of Figure 3-2 plot the number of SOEs' privatization from 1999 to 2005 in China. It shows that, generally, privatization increased over time except during 2005. Moreover, 2002 was a "quiet" year and there were only about 65% volume compared with 2003 and 2004. On the political side, the top panel of Figure 3-2 is the time trend of political turnover. There are two spikes in 1998 and 2002/2003. This is mainly because in China, we have the National Congress of the Communist Party of China (CPC) every five years and there was one in September 1997 and another in November 2002. 123 Most of the politicians' turnover, such as transfer to another city with the same level of promotion and retirement, would have been accomplished during these periods. City mayors are usually replaced every five years, which is the same cycle served as members of the Congress of the Communist Party. In turnover, politicians would either get promoted, be transferred to another city, or retire. There is a very clear cycle of political turnover in China. 3.4 3.4.1 Empirical Analysis Privatization's effect on SOE itself First, I want to study the effects of privatization on SOEs. In this analysis, I use both percentage private share of SOEs and the registration type change(from state owned to private owned) as independent variables to measure privatization. For dependent variables, I use ROA, OROA, sales per worker(labor productivity) to measure the firm's efficiency. I also study privatization's effect on firm's market share, government subsidy, average workers' wage and number of workers. The basic specification I use to test is based on panel data: Yt= a + at + aj +,31 - private_sharejt+ y1 - Xi,t + Eit (3.1) where Yi,t is one of the measures of efficiency or other independent variables I discussed above. a, is the firm fixed effect (84,661 categories), at is the year fixed effect (8 categories) and aj is the industry fixed effect (40 categories). In total, I have 84,706 dummies to control these fixed effects. The reason I add industry fixed effect is that some firms changed industry in the sample and it is not collinear with firm fixed effect. private_sharei,t is the percentage share of private owners of firm i at time t. #1 in (1) is the coefficient of interest that captures privatization's effect. Xjt are controls for firms' characteristics such as total sales, total assets and so on. Moreover, I also use the registration type to create the dummy private which equals 1 if the SOE is registered as a private firm and 0 otherwise. It is a before/after privatization dummy. The regression becomes: Yi,t= ai + at + a + #1 -privatej,t + 7y - Xi,t + Eit (3.2) Equation 3.1 studies efffects of 1% increase of SOE's private share while 3.2 estimates the effects of changing registration type from SOE to private firm. On average, private share will increase around 40% when SOE changes its registration type. Two specifications above should give the similar results on privatization's effect because most of the state-owned shares are sold when change registration type. There are several concerns about this basic identification. First, as I mentioned before, the decision of privatization is endogenous. Gupta, Ham, and Svejnar(2008) looks at SOEs' privatization in Czech and find evidence that government chose to privatize more profitable SOEs first. Including firm fixed effect can alleviate the problem since it controls firms' time invariant part of selection bias. However, the 124 government may determine the privatization on time varying variables such as firms' economic performance, market share and so on. Second, their might be an omitted variable bias if there is any missing depended variables which are correlated with both privatization and firm's performance. Based on these concerns, I use political turnover timing as instrumental variable to privatization. Dinc and Gupta(2011) looked at Indian political election voting shares of different parties to define the political competition and use it as IV of privatization. The main idea behind it is that politicians may lose votes if they privatize SOEs which would come with lay-offs and temporary unemployment. In more competitive area, the government are more reluctant to do privatizations. In China, there is no voting system and I use the political turnover as IV instead. In Figure 3-1 Panel C and D , privatization decreased a lot in 2002 and in Panel E, it is clear that political turnover mainly happens during National Congress of CPC (1998 and 2002). In aggregate level, during turnover years, there were less privatizations. One story can be that the government doesn't want to have many changes and negative side-effects of privatizations during these "sensitive" times and new mayors want to build good reputations and gain support from citizens. Another possibility is that during these turnover periods, politicians are busy with other things such as their promotions and moves. SOEs' privatizations may be not on top of their lists. About exogenous condition of this IV, National Congress of CPC happens exactly every 5 years and the tenure of city mayor is between 3 to 5 years. In another word, mayors are "forced" to change cities every 5 years. In order to test the exogeneity of political turnover, I use the Cox proportional hazard model since it incorporates both turnover of the politicians' demographic and the time of turnover. The hazard rate of turnover is given by: h(t) = ho(t) exp( 1 zxi + 2 x 2 + - - + #Xik), (3.3) where Xi ... Xk are politician's demographic (age, gender, education and place of birth) and average ROA and total net profits from the firms under the mayors' jurisdiction. I have both time-varying and time-invariant variables and I assume that time-varing variables are constant during one year. I followed Wooldridge(2001) to do this proportional hazard model and report the coefficients as well as hazard ratios from the estimation. I included the economic performance variables: average ROA and total net profits to test whether the turnovers are determined by politicians' performance. Li and Zhou(2005) found that the likelihood of promotion of provincial leaders increases with their economic performance in China between 1979 and 1995. Moreover, it is well known that the city mayors' promotion in China are heavily depend on local GDP. The variation I am using here is from the timing of turnover rather than the turnover's type which can be promotions, transfer to another city or retirement. However, it is still a concern that economic performance can also affect the timing of the turnover. Using (3), I can test whether it is the case or not. I use both contemporaneous average ROA and total profits as well as lagged average ROA and total profits to make sure that past economic performance are also counted here. In section 6, I will also use probit model to study the politician's promotion, retirement and corruption. 125 After the verification of IV, I use 2SLS to perform the IV regressions. I use how many years have the politicians(mayors and party leaders) stayed at the city as IV rather than the actual turnover. Although, from hazard ratio analysis and probit analysis, it shows that turnover doesn't depend on politicians' demographic and the economic performance, it is still hard believe that political turnover is totally exogenous. Moreover, the length that the politicians have stayed has significant predictability of turnover and it is more exogenous. The first stage regression is: private_shareit= ai + at + a j + F1 -Politician1lt+F2 - Politician2,t+ Y -Xi,t + Ei,t (3.4) where F, is the coefficient vector of Politicianl,t which are the dummies of the years the mayor of the city I stayed at time t: D11 ,t, D2,,,...,D9,, since the longest year is 9 in my sample. And F2 is the coefficient vector of Politician2,t which are for secretary of municipal committee. It also includes 9 dummies as mayors. The second stage is: Yt = ai + at + a, + 1 private sharei,t + 'y - Xi,t + Ei,t (3.5) Then, I also use the actual turnover in the first stage regressions first to double check the results. private_sharei,t= ai + at + a, + A - TurnoveriT, + Yi,t = ai + at + a +)31 'Y1 - Xi,t + Ei,t - private sharei,t + yi - Xi,t + Ei,t (3.6) (3.7) where Turnoverl,t is how many turnovers in city 1 at year t. In order to test the weak instrument variable problem, I also calculate the F-stats of IVs in first stage regression. 3.4.2 Privatization's effect on private firms After study privatization's effects on SOEs which has a lot of well documented evidence, it is more interesting to look at the effects on private firms surround privatized SOEs. It would give us the whole picture of the effects from privatizations on entire economy. I estimate this effect by looking at the differences between the industry in a certain province who has privatized SOEs and the ones who don't have. The hypothesis is that SOEs have a lot of privileges and government protections over private firms. Privatized SOEs suppose to lose these benefits and the private firms would gain from it because they can compete with SOEs more fairly. Many Chinese SOEs have artificial monopoly powers. Here, I employ the difference in difference model: Yi,t = ai + at + a, + ak + 01 - privatizedSOEj,k,t +-1 - Xi,t + Ei,t (3.8) where Yi,t is as the same as in equation 3.1 which is the efficiency measures and other independent variables of private firms. Again, ai is the firm fixed effect , at is the year fixed effect, a, is the industry fixed effect and ak is the province fixed effect. privatizedSOEj,k,t is the dummy whether there was any privatization in province k and industry j at time t. Xi,t are controls for firms' characteristics. The assumption 126 of this DID specification is that the trends after taking out these fixed effects are the same for all private firms. In another word, all the other effects are level effects. Under this assumption, I can compare the private firms who have privatized SOEs in the same province and industry with private firms without any privatized SOEs. One concern is that the assumption of same trend may be not valid. I add 2 year and 3 year pre-trend dummies privatizedSOEj,k,t+rin equation 3.8. Moreover, I also analyse the long-term effects of privatized SOEs on private firms by adding lagged dummies(post trend) privatizedSOEj,k,et-. T = 2, 3. the specification becomes: yi,t ~ + Ct + a3 + ak + 01 -privatizedSOEj,k,t +32 +3 privatizedSOEj,k,t+ + 7h - Xi,t + Ei,t i - privatizedSOE,k,, (3.9) All the regressions above only show the correlations between the SOE's privatizations and the private firms surround them. In order to estimate the causality between them, I use political turnover again to instrument privatization. The 2SLS are: 1 privatizedSOEj,k,t - ai+at+aj+ak+Fl.Politician p,t +F 2 .Politician2p,t+-i1-Xit+Ei (3.10) = Cti ai,t +t + 'j + &k + s1 - privatizedSOEj,k,t + Y1 - Xi,t + Eit (3.11) where F 1 is the coefficient vector of Politicianlp,t which are the dummies of the average years the city mayors have stayed in cities under province p at time t: D1 ,t, 1 D21,t,...,D9,,t since the longest year is 9 in my sample. And F 2 is the coefficient vector of Politician2pt which are for secretary of municipal committee. It includes 7 dummies because the longest average tenure of secretaries of municipal committee in a province is 7 years. The difference in difference specifications above don't consider the magnitude of privatization. Bigger privatizations suppose to have bigger impacts on private firms. To verify it, I use privatized Assets to replace dummy of whether there is privatized SOE or not in (8). And I use the sample condition on existence of privatization. The specification becomes: ,t ai + at - aj + ak + /1 - privatizedAssetsj,k,t + 71 - Xi,t + Ei,t (3.12) where privatizedAssetsj,k,t is the log of total asset got privatized in province k and industry j at time t. And the sample size is conditioned on the province and industry who has privatization happened. It can give us the sense whether bigger firms' privatization has bigger effects to further test my hypothesis. To further verify my story that private firms gain from privatizations because they can compete more fairly with privatized SOEs, I use number of firms in each province and industry to measure the competitiveness. The hypothesis is that privatization's effects on private firms should be smaller in more competitive market. It is because that if the market is already very competitive, one more privatization should have less effect. I interact privatizedSOEj,k,t with FirmNumberjk,t-1 which is the number of 127 firms in industry Yi, = j province k at time t - 1. ai + at + a3 + ak + +32 /1 - privatizedSOEj,k,t privatizedSOEj,k,t * FirmNumber,k,t_1 + Y1 - Xi,t -+Ei,t (3.13) The prediction should be that more firms in a certain industry and province (more competitions) should lead to less impact of privatization. 3.5 3.5.1 Results Privatization's effects for SOEs Before doing 2SLS regressions, it would be good to see the validity of instrument variable. Table 3.2 shows the results of estimating equation 3.3. The results for Cox proportional hazard model are in column (1) and (2). In column (1), except age has significantly positive effects on hazard ratio(turnover), other things don't have effects including average ROA and total profit from the firms under this politicians' jurisdiction. Column (2) uses lagged ROA and total profit. Again, there is no significant results for them. Column (3) and (4) use Weibull distribution to double check the results and there is no significant coefficients at all. Two hazard ratio specifications have pretty consistent results. I also plot the hazard functions in Figure 3-2 and it is clear that probability of turnover increases when politicians stay longer. Table 3.3 panel A shows the results of estimating equation 3.1 for all efficiency measures and other key variables. It is OLS regression and the standard errors are clustered by firm. Column (1) to (3) presents evidence for efficiency gain of SOEs via privatization. ROA and OROA significantly increase 0.3% when the SOEs are fully privatized(private share changes from 0% to 100%). Average SOEs' ROA is around 5% so that SOEs' gains efficiency by 6% after privatization. At the same time, sales per worker increase by 4.1% after privatization. Moreover, the coefficient of privatized share on market share is significantly positive because that privatized SOEs become more competitive. Column (6) and (7) analyse the privatization's effects on employment. Both number of workers and wages increase after privatization by 1.5% and 1.1% after full privatization. For government subsidy, I don't find any significant result in this specification. In Panel B, I use registration type change from state-owned to private-owned to measure privatization. Use before/after dummy Privatize, I get the similar results as in Panel A except OROA which doesn't have significant effect. Table 3.4 panel A shows the results from 2SLS for equation 3.4 and 3.5. First stage is strong, F-stats for excluded instruments(dummies for politicians' tenure) is 28.14 and privatizations are less when politicians stayed longer time which predicts higher turnover probability. In the second stage, from column (1) to (3), coefficients are still positive and larger than panel A. ROA significantly increases 2.3% when the SOEs are fully privatized which is about 50% efficiency gain. For subsidy in column (5), coefficient is now significantly negative and SOEs' probability of getting government 128 subsidy decreases about 10% after privatization. For employment in column (6) and (7), the coefficients are all negative now. It makes more sense because one of the SOEs social object is to increase employment and usually over pay workers in China. In Table 3.4 panel B, I use actual turnover as IV. First stage is very strong and there are less privatizations when the city is under political turnover. Coefficient of turnover is -0.007. The results on seven variables are consistent with Panel A. In sum, privatizations increases SOEs profitability and efficiency and government can subsidize them less. 3.5.2 Privatization's effect on private firms In order to understand the total effects of SOEs, we turned to private sectors here. Table 3.5 panel A are the results of estimating equation 3.8. Column (1) indicates that ROA of private firms increase significantly when there are SOE privatizations in the same industry same province. The magnitude is 0.1% increase of ROA which is about 2% efficiency gain. From column (3), labour productivity also increase by 0.7%. For employment part, private firms will hire 0.5% more workers and decrease wages by 0.4%. Combined with the results from Table 3.3, it seems that workers who were lay-off by SOEs transfer to private firms instead. Bigger supply of labour decreases the wages. In panel B, by adding 2 year or 3 year pre-trend dummies and lagged dummies, private firms who have privatized SOEs around them did slightly worse before privatizations. The coefficient for 2 year pre-trend at column (1) to (3) are insignificant. In column (4), there is a slightly negative pre-trend for ROA 3 years before. It could be that these private firms were doing worse because of the SOEs in the neighbour. For example, SOEs have priory or unique access to the market, funding and government projects. For the lagged dummies, effects seems to last during couple of years after privatizations. Table 3.6 panel A are the results from equation 3.12 to check whether bigger privatizations have bigger effects. All the samples in panel A are private firms who have privatized SOEs around them. For measures of profitability, Column (1) and (3) have significantly positive coefficients. It means that bigger privatizations increase private firms' efficiency more. And bigger privatizations make private firms to hire more workers. These results has the same direction as Table 3.5 panel A and it verifies the results in panel A as well. To further verify my story here that private firms gain from privatizations because that they can compete with privatized SOEs more fairly, I put interaction term between dummy privatizedSOE and number of firms in this industry and province. In Table 3.6 panel B, privatizedSOE still have significantly positive effect on productivity measurement. The coefficient of privatizedSOE * FirmNumber is significantly negative. It means that when there were more firms in this industry(more competitions), privatization has less effect because private firms can gain less from the market that was already competitive. Table 3.7 are the results from 2SLS in equation 3.10 and 3.11. Again, first stage is very strong with F-stats 124.3. In the second stage, ROA of private firms will increase 6.3% if there are SOEs in the same province same industry get privatized. The magnitude is big which double the efficiency. From Column (2) to (4), all other 129 profitability measures have big and significantly positive coefficients. For subsidy, coefficient is also significantly positive and bigger than OLS regression. Number of workers increases as well. The only different thing here is wages and benefits. Column(6) tells that wage significantly increases for private firm after SOEs' privatization. Moreover, I calculated the overall effects of the privatization on employment. Based on the coefficients I estimate in Table 3.4 and 3.7, SOEs cut 64% of their workers after being privatized. Private firms increase 16.3% employment if there are privatizations around. Overall, every 100 workers got fired by SOEs come with an 169 increase in private sector hiring in the same industry and same province. The privatization may also affect the firms in the related industries such as downstream industries. In Chapter one, I find that the government credit from CDB has positive spillover effects on downstream industries. Again, I use the input-output matrix to define the industry supply chain. However, I don't find any significant effects of privatizations on downstream industries. The reason could be that privatizations in China from 1998 to 2005 were mainly focus on the manufacturing industry such as textile. State still controls the strategic industries such as energy and mining sector which are usually at the upstream level in the supply chain. In the CIC data, only 2.7% of the privatizations are in the upstream industries and 97.3% of the privatizations are in the downstream industries. This could explain why I couldn't find significant impacts of privatizations on downstream industries. Based on these results, private firms benefit from SOEs privatizations as well and hire the workers lay-offed by privatized SOEs. It could be the case that private firms now can compete with SOEs on more fair basis. Politicians stop or do less "bribe" to privatized SOEs because it is more costly to do so. However, to direct test this channel, the evidence above is not enough. In the following sector, I will estimate politicians' effects on both private and state owned firms. 3.5.3 Examination of exclusion condition and robustness check To examine the exclusion condition of IV, I selected the SOEs who are 100% owned by state during the entire sample period(1998-2005). The hypothesis is that the only channel for political turnover to affect firms is through privatization. For SOEs who have never been privatized should not be affected by political turnover. There are 2,711 SOEs in this sub sample and I simply regress actual turnover on firms' performance measurement and employment and control firm fixed effect, year fixed effect, industry fixed effect and other firms' characteristics. Table 3.8 Panel A are the regression results. There is no significant effect from political turnover to 100% owned SOEs. This evidence also support the exclusion assumption of the instrumental variable. People may argue that government may privatize SOEs based on their industry performance or prospectives. To check the robustness of the results in Table 3.3, 3.4 and 3.7, I re-run the regressions in Table 3.3 Panel A, Table 3.4 Panel A and 130 Table 3.7, adding industry trend control(interaction between industry dummies and year dummies). Table 3.8 panel B and Table 3.9 are the results and it is almost the same as Table 3.3, 3.4 and 3.7. It means that privatization's effects are not driven by industry specific trends. 3.6 Influence of Politician in China A natural question followed is whether politicians have real influence on firms? If yes, How do politicians put influence? Bertrand and Schoar (2003) studies the managers fixed effects matter for many firms' operations and performance. Here, I use the politicians fixed effects to study how much do individual politicians matter for firms performance. Then, I also classify politicians' "type" into two groups: Good one and Bad one. I use politicians' profile data which contains whether the politician has been to jail or not. I pick the politicians who went to jail because of the corruptions such as taking bribe and I mark them as "Bad guys". From my database, 95% of politicians who went to jail are due to corruption. It is also the most common reason to charge politicians in China. I can then estimate the bad politicians' effect on economy. 3.6.1 Policitian's fixed effects In order to estimate politicians' individual effects on the firms, I controlled firm fixed effect, time fixed effect, industry fixed effect and city fixed effect. I also controlled firms' other characteristics. By controlling these variations, I can estimate whether politicians can have their own effects on the firms. The variation of politicians' fixed effect comes from that there are 60% politicians in the sample have been to different cities as mayors or party leaders at different times. In provincial level, 30% in the sample have been to different provinces. Firm fixed effect and city or province fixed effect can't capture this part of variation. Moreover, the CIC dataset has each firm's political hierarchy and the hypothesis is that politicians should have more effects on the firms under their jurisdiction and less effect on the firms above their levels even these firms are located in their city or province. Then, I repeat the same specification in equation 3.14 on different political levels of the firm. The specification is: yi,t = ai + at + a3 + ah + -Y1 - Xi,t + Apoliticians + Ei't (3.14) where Yi,t again stands for one of the firm economic variables, a, is the firm fixed effect , at is the year fixed effect, a3 is the industry fixed effec and ah is the city fixed effect. Apoliticians are fixed effects for 1,116 politicians and it is a group of dummies of whether the firm is under the each politician's jurisdiction or not. It is the same for provincial level politicians and I have 171 of them. The results are in Table 3.10. It is clear that generally politicians' fixed effects are significant. For provincial level SOEs, city level politicians don't have effect on firms' performance(ROA) but they have significant effect on market shares and employment. On the other hand, provincial politicians have effects on ROA, market 131 shares and number of workers. For the city level SOEs, both city level and provincial level politicians have significant effects as well as on county level SOEs. 3.6.2 Corruptions and firm's performance To further examining the channel of political influence, I classify the politicians into good or bad ones. It allows me to study the differences between firms under good politicians' jurisdictions and bad ones. Again, I look at firm's performance, market share, government subsidy, employment, wages and so on. The specification is: Y,t = ai + at + a3 + yi - Xi,t + Jaili,t + ej,t (3.15) where Jaili,t is the dummy whether the firms i is under bad politicians' jurisdiction at time t. Other independent variables are the same as before. And I only use the sample of SOEs since it is easier for bad politicians to extract rents from SOEs. I also use the sample of private firms to check this hypothesis. One of the concerns here is that politicians' corruption is endogenous and it is highly depended on the economic performance of the city. The politicians in rich areas suppose to have more opportunities to take bribe and easier to become corrupted. By controlling firm fixed effect and city fixed effect, I can mitigate this concern. Another concern is that in China, the corrupted politicians may not end up in Jail. There is a saying in China that most corrupted politicians are usually most powerful ones and they can always avoid prisons. This problem may be less severe since I am using city level politicians and usually they are not so powerful compared with provincial and central level politicians. Moreover, communist party passed a rule to regulate the politicians and fight corruptions at 1997. After that, there has been couple of thousand politicians sentenced to jail during last two decades. Based on that, my measurement here has less selection bias. The results in Table 3.11 panel A show that corrupted politicians will significantly decrease the economic performance of SOEs. ROA decreases by 0.4% that is about 10% efficiency loss. OROA and labour productivity also decrease significantly(column(2) and (3)). However, market share of these SOEs increases which means that although these SOEs becomes less competitive but they gain more market powers from the government. Moreover, number of workers significantly increases by 4.7% and wages decreases by 1.8%. These results are consistent with Shilefer and Vishny(1994) that politicians extract the rents from SOEs and force SOEs to hire more workers to gain more political support. In return, they give SOEs more privileges such as market power. In panel B Table 3.11, it is the same specification in equation 3.15 and use private firms instead. From Column(1) to (4), corrupted politicians have no or less effect on private firms performance except labour productivity. The interesting thing is that employment increases and wage decrease like SOEs do but with smaller magnitude.The decrease in labour productivity is probably because of the increase of number of workers. With all the concerns I discussed before, based on these results in Table 3.11, it 132 seems the case that corrupted politicians extract the rents or personal interests from SOEs and force them to hire more workers and pay less wages while they compensate SOEs with more market powers. This effect is less or insignificant for private firms since it is more costly for politicians to do that on private firms. 3.6.3 Politicians' career path Although the timing of political turnover is exogenous based on the evidence I showed. It is interesting to study where do politician go when they leave the old positions. It is well documented that politicians' promotion is highly depend on economic performance. I have the politicians' profile data which can help me to test it. I classify the politicians' turnover into 5 categories: promoted, go to jail, retire, die and move to another city. I only look at the first 4 categories and focus on city level politicians here. First, I want to re-test the exogeneity of political turnover. I use probit model to test: T urnoveri,t = at + F - StayedYeari,t + yi - Xi,t + Eit (3.16) where at is the year fixed effect, StayedYeari,t is the group of dummies of the years the Politician i stayed at his or her positions at time t. Again, the longest year is 9 years. Xi,t are the politicians' demographics such as age, gender, education, place of born and the economic performance in his or her jurisdiction such as average ROA and net profit of the firms in that city. Then, I control politicians' personal effects to double check the results. Condition on turnover, I use probit model again to study the career path of politicians, the specification is: Careeri = 1 ROAi + /2 - profiti + Y1 - Xi + Ei (3.17) where Careeri is the dummy of 4 categories I mentioned before: promotion, Jail, Retire and Death of politician i. ROAi and profiti are the average ROA and net profit of the firms under politician i's jurisdiction. They are the measurement of politicians' economic performance. The results are in Table 3.12. In column (1) and (2), again, turnover does not depend on economic performance and politicians' demographics. And the longer the politician stayed, the higher probability of turnover. It is consistent with the results from hazard ratio estimation. In column (3) to (6), promotions are highly positively correlated with economic performance as well as Jail. It shows again that corruptions are highly correlated with economic environment. Also, retirement is positively depended on age and death is totally random. In column (4), I also find that the probability of going to jail is higher if the politicians were born in rural area. It might be the case that these politicians don't have as many connections as the one born in cities. It is difficult for them to avoid jail. It also might be that these politicians grew up in relatively poor area and this early life experience affects their behaviours later on. 133 3.7 Conclusion The main objective of this chapter is to document privatization's effects on the Chinese economy, which is the second-largest economy in the world. Using a detailed manufacturing firms' dataset (CIC) and the politician profile dataset in China, I find that more political turnovers lead to fewer privatizations. I use political turnover as an instrumental variable and find that privatization significantly increases the efficiencies of both SOEs and private firms in the same industry and area. Bigger privatizations have larger impacts. Privatization benefits all firms in the economy due to more market competitions and fewer government interventions. For employment, SOEs cut 64% of their workers after being privatized. Private firms increase 16.3% employment if there are privatizations around. Overall, every 100 workers got fired by SOEs come with an 169 increase in private sector hiring in the same industry and same province. The aggregate effect of privatization on employment is positive. While the timing of political turnover is exogenous from my tests, the heterogeneity across politicians is a very important factor for the economy. I find that the fixed-effect of politicians can affect SOEs' economic performance and employment significantly. Moreover, I also use politicians' profiles to find that politicians who are more corrupt will extract more rents from SOEs and give them more market power in return. Corrupt politicians have smaller effects on private firms. This evidence mainly supports the political view of SOEs (Shilefer and Vishny (1994)). After all, privatization is one of the most important factors in the future growth of China. In the World Bank "China 2030" report, it writes: "China's rapid growth, particularly since 2003, benefited from SOE restructuring and expansion of the private sector.. .Relative to the private sector, state-owned enterprises (SOEs) consume a large proportion of capital, raw materials and intermediate inputs to produce relatively small shares of gross output and value added. A large share of state enterprise profits comes from a few state enterprises where profitability is often related to limits on competition and access to cheaper capital, land, and natural resources.. .Privatization and market reform generated vibrant competition in most manufacturing sectors." 134 3.8 Bibliography Alchian, Armen Albert. "Some economics of property rights." IL Politico 30 (1965): 816-829. Bertrand, Marianne, and Antoinette Schoar. "Managing with Style: The Effect of Managers on Firm Policies." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118.4 (2003): 1169-1208. Boycko, Maxim, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. "A theory of privatisation." The Economic Journal 106 (1996): 309-319. Dinc, Serdar, and Nandini Gupta. "The Decision to Privatize: Finance, Politics and Patronage." The Journal of Finance LXVI (2011): 241-270. Dixit, Avinash, and John Londregan. "The Determinants of Success of Special Interests in Redistributive Politics." The Journal of Politics 58.4 (1996): 1132-1155. Dixit, Avinash. "Power of Incentives in Private versus Public Organizations." The American Economic Review 87.2 (1997): 378-382. Frydman, Roman, Cheryl W. Gray, Marek Hessel, and Andrzej Rapaczynski. "When Does Privatization Work? The Impact of PrivateOwnership on Corporate Performance in Transition Economies" The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(4) (1999): 1153-1191. Gupta, Nandini. "Partial Privatization and Firm Performance." The Journalof Finance 60.2 (2005): 987-1015. Gupta, Nandini, Jhon C. Ham, and Jan Svejnar. "Priorities and Sequencing in Privatization: Theory and Evidence from the Czech Republic." The European Economic Review 52 (2008): 183-208. Khwaja, Asim, and Atif Mian. "Do Lenders Favor Politically Connected Firms? Rent Provision in an Emerging Financial Market." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 120.4 (2005): 1371-1411. Lindbeck, Assar, and Jorgen W. Weibull. "Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition." Public Choice 52.3 (1987): 273-297. Megginson, William, and Jeffry Netter. "From State to Market: A Survey of Empirical Studies on Privatization." Journal of Economic Literature 39.2 (2001): 321-389. Megginson, William L. "The financial economics of privatization." New York: Oxford University Press, 2005. Porta, Rafael La, and Florencio de Silanes. "The Benefits of Privatization: Evidence from Mexico." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114.4 (1999): 11931242. Sapienza, Paola. "The Effects of Government Ownership on Bank Lending." Journal of FinancialEconomics 72(2) (2004): 357-384. Sappington, David E. M., and Joseph E. Stiglitz. "Privatization, information and incentives." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 6.4 (1987): 567-585. Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny. "Corruption." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108.3 (1993): 599-617. Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny. "Politicians and Firms." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109.4 (1994): 995-1025. 135 Silanes, Florencio, and Andrei Shleifer. "Privatization in the United States." Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1995. Tirole, Jean. "The Internal Organization of Government." Oxford Economic Papers 46.1 (1994): 1-29. Vickers, John, and George K. Yarrow. "Privatization: an economic analysis." Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 1988. Vickers, John, and George Yarrow. "Economic Perspectives on Privatization." The Journal of Economic Perspectives 5.2 (1991): 111-132. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. "Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data." Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2002. Yao, Yang. "Chinese Privatization: Causes and Outcomes." China and World Economy 13 (2005): 66-80. 136 Figure 3-1: Manufacturing Firms in China Number of Firms in Chinese Manufacturing Sector 00 C% Q 0 - LO z 1998 2000 1999 2001 SOEs Number S Year 2003 2002 2004 2005 Private Firm Number ---- Aggregate Assets in Chinese Manufacturing Sector - CO 0 1998 2000 1999 - 2001 SOEs Asset Year - 2003 2002 2004 2005 Private Firm Asset In Figure 3-1, the top Panel is the plot for numbers of SOEs and private firms in China from 1998 to 2005. The bottom Panel is the total asset value of SOEs and private firms. Units in the bottom Panel is 1 trillion RMB which is about 142 billion US dollars. 137 Figure 3-2: Turnover and Privatization Privatization Number 5000 4500 4000 , 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 Em M m 1000 500 -- 0 1999 -i 2000 2001 2002 2003 2005 2004 Year Pliticians' Turnover %Turnover 70 60 50 +40 30 20 10 0 1998 In Figure 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Year 3-2, the top Panel is the number of total SOEs who were privatized each year. The bottom Panel the percentage turnover of city level politicians each year from 1998 to 2005. 138 Figure 3-3: Estimated Hazard Functions Cox proportional hazards regression Weibull regression - N4 U, C ..I - a 2 4 6 8 10 0 5 Swfiw 10 Figure 3-2 is the estimated hazard functions from estimating equation 3.3. Left side panel is from Cox proportional hazard regression and right side panel is from Weibull distribution hazard regression. The horizontal line is in years. 139 Table 3.1: Summary Statistics Data Panel A: CIC Variables Variable ROA OROA Log(Sales/Worker) Subsidy Market share Log(Wage) Log(Worker) Log(Assets) Log(Sale) Leverage Obs 1,041,841 1,041,841 1,036,390 1,041,841 1,041,841 1,033,384 1,036,390 1,041,841 1,041,841 1,041,841 Mean 0.06 0.06 5.05 0.10 0.01 2.23 4.71 9.59 9.76 0.54 S.D. 0.10 0.23 1.07 0.30 0.04 0.69 1.11 1.42 1.33 0.25 Obs 1,420 1,674 1,674 1,343 1,674 1,674 1,674 1,674 Mean 46.16 0.81 0.03 0.25 0.30 0.06 0.01 0.03 S.D. 6.05 0.39 0.16 0.43 0.46 0.24 0.12 0.17 Panel B: Politicians' profile Variables Variable Age Education Gender Born at rural Promotion Jail Dead Retire Variable ROA= NneT TotalWage Wage= W of t NumberofWorkers, R , Worker is the total number of employees, Leverae TotalLiability. Age is the politiTotalAsset r NumberofWorkers' Operati rofit TotalBenefit cian's age in 1998, Education is a dummy of whether politician has college degree or above. Born at rural is a dummy of whether politician was born in a rural area(not city). Promotion is a dummy of whether the politician has ever been promoted in turnover. Jail is a dummy of whether the politician has ever been in Jail. Dead is a dummy of whether the politician was dead during turnover or not. Retire is a dummy of whether the politician retired in turnover. In total, there is 1674 politicians and for some of them, age and place of born are missing. 140 Table 3.2: Hazard Ratio Analysis of Politicians' Turnover Dependent Variable Age Education Gender Born at rural Average ROA Average Total Profit Hazard Ratio (1) Cox (2) Cox (3) Weibull (4) Weibull 0.015** (0.006) 0.206 (0.447) 0.181 (0.193) -0.038 (0.085) -1.223 (1.109) 0.000 (0.000) 0.017** (0.007) 0.352 (0.488) 0.175 (0.193) -0.020 (0.090) -0.002 (0.007) 0.466 (0.538) 0.224 (0.222) -0.058 (0.100) -0.509 (1.215) 0.000 (0.000) -0.000 (0.007) 0.665 (0.574) 0.189 (0.222) -0.037 (0.105) Lagged Average ROA -0.309 (1.208) 0.000 (0.000) Lagged Average Total Profit Constant Observations Chi squared 2,914 7.900 2,587 7.286 -3.925*** (0.641) 0.331 (1.366) 0.000 (0.000) -4.339*** (0.664) 2,914 3.596 2,587 2.966 Data restricted to city level mayors and secretary municipal committee of the CPC(party leaders). Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. Column (1) and (2) are the results from Cox proportional hazard regression. Column (3) and (4) are from Weibull distribution hazard regressions. AverageROA AverageTotalProfit are the means of ROA and net profit from firms which are under the politicians' jurisdiction each year. 141 Table 3.3: Does Privatization Improve SOEs' Efficiency? (OLS) Panel A: OLS Regressions use privatized share (1) ROA Variable (2) OROA (3) (4) (6) (5) (7) Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker Privatized Share 0.003*** 0.003*** (0.001) (0.001) LogSale 0.029*** 0.036*** (0.000) (0.001) LogAsset 0.041*** (0.005) 0.001*** (0.000) 0.216*** (0.007) Constant 2.246*** 0.031*** (0.002) 0.019*** -0.251*** 1.982*** (0.007) (0.046) (0.109) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 228,230 228,230 224,037 0.057 0.009 0.104 Firm FE Time FE Industry FE Observations R-squared -0.235*** -0.293*** (0.014) (0.016) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 228,230 228,230 0.067 0.030 (0.174) Yes Yes Yes 225,471 0.132 -0.001 (0.002) 0.011** (0.005) 0.015*** (0.004) 5.012*** (0.121) Yes Yes Yes 225,471 0.004 Panel B: OLS Regressions use registration type change Variable Privatize Logsale (1) (2) ROA OROA 0.003*** -0.001 (0.001) (0.003) 0.028*** 0.035*** (0.000) (0.001) Logasset (3) (4) 0.025*** (0.006) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.228*** -0.222*** -0.274*** (6) (7) 0.006 (0.004) 0.012*** (0.005) 0.059*** (0.005) 0.022*** (0.007) Constant (5) Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker (0.002) 2.208*** 0.014** -0.139*** 1.940*** 4.976*** (0.011) (0.014) (0.149) (0.007) (0.034) (0.086) (0.096) Firm FE Time FE Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations R-squared 262,622 0.064 262,622 0.012 259,796 0.122 262,622 0.056 262,622 0.054 258,169 0.093 259,796 0.005 Data restricted to SOEs both got privatized and remain state-owned. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by firm. All the regressions control firm fixed effect, year fixed effect, industry fixed effect. Panel A are OLS regression results from estimating equation 3.1 using the share owned by private firms as right hand side variable to measure privatization. Panel B are OLS regression results from estimating equation 3.2 using Privatize which is the dummy of registration type change from state-owned to private-owned. 142 Table 3.4: Effects of Privatization on SOEs' Efficiency (Using Political Turnover Timing as Instruments) Panel A: 2SLS Regressions (IV: mayor's Tenure) Dependent Variable Privatized Share LogSale (7) (6) (5) (4) (3) (2) OROA LogSales/worker Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker (1) ROA 0.023** 0.009 (0.009) (0.013) 0.030*** 0.037*** (0.001) (0.001) LogAsset Firm fixed effect Yes Time fixed effect Yes Industry fixed effect Yes Observations 184,203 R-squared 0.058 F-stats of first stage 28.14 Yes Yes Yes 184,203 0.031 28.14 0.148* (0.080) 0.010*** (0.003) -0.105*** -0.227*** (0.036) (0.069) -0.041 (0.063) Yes Yes Yes 184,203 0.044 20.68 0.033*** (0.002) Yes Yes Yes 184,203 0.01 28.23 Yes Yes Yes 181,913 0.002 28.39 0.212*** (0.007) Yes Yes Yes 181,913 0.127 28.23 Yes Yes Yes 180,615 0.082 28.14 Panel B: 2SLS Regressions (IV: mayor's Turnover Dummy) First Stage Dependent Variable Privatized Share Turnover (1) ROA (2) OROA (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) LogSales/worker Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker -0.007*** (0.001) Privatized Share 0.078** 0.115 (0.040) (0.072) 0.028*** 0.034*** (0.001) (0.002) Logsale Logasset Firm fixed effect Time fixed effect Industry fixed effect Observations R-squared Yes Yes Yes 200,827 0.087 Yes Yes Yes 200,827 0.077 Yes Yes Yes 200,827 0.057 1.276*** (0.418) 0.203*** (0.009) Yes Yes Yes 198,246 0.307 0.025 (0.015) -0.255* (0.155) 0.094 (0.325) -0.640** (0.280) Yes Yes Yes 200,827 0.043 0.034*** (0.003) Yes Yes Yes 200,827 0.101 Yes Yes Yes 196,843 0.101 Yes Yes Yes 198,246 0.245 Data restricted to SOEs both got privatized and remain state-owned. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by firm. All the regressions control firm fixed effect, year fixed effect, industry fixed effect. Panel A are results of second stage regression of 2SLS described in equation 3.4 and 3.5. Instrument variables are the length of how many years have politicians stayed in a city. Weak instrumental variable test statistics(F-test) from first stage regressions are reported as well. Panel B are are results of second stage regression of 2SLS use actual political turnover as IV. Turnover is the dummy whether the city is in the turnover year or not. First stage regression result is in Panel B as well. 143 Table 3.5: Does Privatization Improve Private Firms' Efficiency? (OLS) Dependent Variable Privatized SOE Logsale Panel A: Before and After Privatization Analysis and After Privatization Analvsis (2) (3) (4) (1) (5) (6) (7) ROA OROA Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker 0.001*** (0.000) -0.000 (0.001) 0.042*** 0.049*** (0.000) (0.001) Logasset 0.007*** (0.002) 0.000 (0.001) 0.209*** 0.029*** (0.004) 2.444*** (0.387) -0.000 (0.000) -0.004** (0.002) 0.005** (0.002) Privatized SOE LogSale - 0.001*** -0.000 (0.000) (0.001) 0.042*** 0.049*** (0.000) (0.001) LogAsset 2 year pre trend 2 year post trend -0.001 (0.000) 0.001*** (0.000) -0.001 (0.001) 0.002*** (0.001) 3 year pre trend 0.007*** (0.002) -0.332*** -0.332*** (0.050) (0.125) Firm fixed effect Yes Yes Time fixed effect Yes Yes State fixed effect Yes Yes Industry fixed effect Yes Yes Observations 485,452 485,452 R-squared 0.094 0.050 0.001*** -0.000 (0.000) (0.001) 0.042*** 0.049*** (0.000) (0.001) 0.209*** (0.004) 0.004 (0.003) -0.007*** (0.003) 3 year post trend Constant ( (0.001) -0.333*** 0.333*** -0.383*** -0 .060** 1.713*** 4.830*** (0.050) (0.125) ).028) (0.291) (0.136) (0.259) Firm fixed effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Time fixed effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes State fixed effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Industry fixed effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 485,452 485,452 484,255 485,452 4 85,452 483,423 484,255 R-squared 0.094 0.050 0.124 0.053 .101 0.090 0.028 Panel Before and After Privatization Analysis (2) (3) (4) (1) (5) (6) VARIABLES ROA OROA Log(Sales/worker) ROA 0 ROA Log(Sales/worker) Constant 2.437*** (0.387) Yes Yes Yes Yes 484,255 0.124 0.008*** (0.002) 0.209*** (0.004) -0.001** -0.001 (0.001) (0.001) 0.001* 0.002*** (0.000) (0.001) -0.332*** -0.331*** (0.050) (0.125) 0.019*** (0.005) -0.007** (0.003) 2.420*** (0.388) 485,452 485,452 484,255 0.094 0.050 0.124 Data restricted to private firms who are not converted from SOEs. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by firm. Panel A is the DID regression in equation 3.8. PrivatizedSOEis the dummy of whether the private firm has any privatized SOEs in the same industry and same province. Panel B is the results from equation 3.9 by adding 2 and 3 year pre/post trend dummies. 144 Table 3.6: Does Bigger Privatization Have Bigger Effects? Panel A: Privatization's Effects on Private Firms Close-by Variable (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (2) OROA Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker (1) ROA LogPrivatizedAsset 0.001** -0.000 (0.000) (0.000) Logsale 0.043*** 0.051*** (0.001) (0.001) Logasset 0.003*** (0.001) 0.002*** -0.000** (0.001) (0.000) 0.202*** (0.005) Constant 0.029*** (0.002) -0.220*** (0.064) Firm FE Time FE State FE Industry FE Observations R-squared -0.378*** (0.024) Yes Yes Yes Yes 269,376 0.096 -0.170 3.178*** (0.256) Yes Yes Yes Yes 269,376 (0.215) Yes Yes Yes Yes 269,312 0.055 0.135 -0.001 (0.001) 0.002 2.147*** (0.005) (0.104) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 269,376 0.051 269,376 0.025 Yes Yes Yes Yes 269,023 0.100 0.001* (0.001) 4.500*** (0.123) Yes Yes Yes Yes 269,312 0.025 Panel B: Heterogeneous Effects of Different Market Competitiveness Variable (1) ROA (2) OROA PrivatizedSOE 0.001*** 0.000 (0.000) (0.001) PrivatizedSOE -0.002** -0.006*** Firm# (0.001) (0.001) Logsale 0.043*** 0.051*** (0.000) (0.001) Logasset Constant Firm FE Time FE State FE Industry FE Observations R-squared -0.299*** -0.310** (0.128) (0.032) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 433,052 433,052 0.096 0.052 (6) (7) (3) (4) (5) Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker 0.015*** (0.003) -0.048*** (0.006) -0.015*** (0.000) 0.012*** (0.001) -0.002 0.003 (0.002) (0.001) 0.005 -0.058*** (0.004) (0.004) 0.000 (0.002) 0.015*** (0.005) 0.202*** (0.004) 1.901*** (0.169) 0.031*** (0.001) -0.380*** -0.398*** 1.750*** (0.072) (0.085) (0.106) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 433,052 433,052 432,169 0.042 0.034 0.101 5.288*** (0.121) Yes Yes Yes Yes 432,907 0.024 Yes Yes Yes Yes 432,907 0.135 Data restricted to private firms who are not converted from SOEs. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by firm. Panel A is the results from equation 3.12 and the sample is restricted to the private firms who have privatized SOEs around. Panel B is is the results from equation 3.13 with interactions between PrivatizedSOEand the number of firms in the industry and province. Firm# are in unit of 1,000. 145 Table 3.7: DID Regressions Results(Estimated Privatization) Dependent Variable PrivatizedSOE Logsale (1) ROA 0.063*** (0.005) 0.041*** (0.000) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (2) OROA Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker 0.104*** (0.007) 0.048*** (0.001) Logasset Firm fixed effect Yes Time fixed effect Yes State fixed effect Yes Industry fixed effect Yes Observations 408,348 R-squared -0.042 F test of first stage 124.3 0.323*** (0.034) 0.000 (0.001) 0.142*** 0.087*** (0.016) (0.030) Yes Yes Yes Yes 408,348 0.101 125.1 0.030*** (0.001) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 408,348 406,451 0.005 0.084 125.1 126.5 0.209*** (0.004) Yes Yes Yes Yes 408,348 -0.088 124.3 Yes Yes Yes Yes 407,254 0.065 126.6 0.163*** (0.026) Yes Yes Yes Yes 407,254 0.002 126.6 Data restricted to private firms who are not converted from SOEs. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by firm. The results are from second stage regressions by estimating equation 3.10 and 3.11. The instrumental variables are group of dummies of years the mayors stayed and F-statistics from first stage regression are reported. 146 Table 3.8: Exclusion Examination and Robustness Check Panel A: Exclusion Examination (1) ROA Variable Turnover (2) OROA (7) (6) (3) (4) (5) Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker 0.001 -0.000 (0.001) (0.001) 0.021*** 0.023*** (0.002) (0.003) Logsale Logasset, Constant -0.203*** -0.232*** (0.036) Firm FE Time FE Industry FE Observations R-squared Yes Yes Yes 16,263 0.062 (0.044) Yes Yes Yes 16,263 0.038 0.000 -0.001 (0.010) 0.007 (0.009) -0.004 (0.007) 0.354*** (0.134) 0.043*** 1.087 1.125*** (1.516) (0.017) (0.235) 5.681*** (0.424) (0.001) 0.390*** (0.031) 0.010 (1.305) Yes Yes Yes 15,997 0.105 -0.026 (0.053) Yes Yes Yes 16,263 Yes Yes Yes 16,263 0.097 0.064 Yes Yes Yes 15,812 0.071 Yes Yes Yes 15,997 0.037 Panel B: OLS industry trend robustness check Variable (1) ROA (2) OROA PrivatizedShare 0.002*** 0.003** (0.001) (0.001) Logsale 0.029*** 0.036*** (0.000) (0.001) Logasset Constant Firm FE Time FE Industry FE Industry trend Observations R-squared -0.253*** -0.296*** (0.013) (0.016) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 228,230 228,230 0.077 0.035 (7) (6) (5) (4) (3) Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker 0.042*** (0.005) 0.001*** 0.015*** (0.005) 0.017*** (0.004) 0.214*** (0.007) 2.164*** (0.171) Yes Yes Yes Yes 225,471 0.142 0.031*** (0.002) 0.022*** -0.207*** 2.009*** (0.007) (0.047) (0.109) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 228,230 228,230 224,037 0.148 0.014 0.111 5.057*** (0.124) Yes Yes Yes Yes 225,471 0.010 (0.000) -0.001 (0.002) Panel A use SOEs who are 100% state-owned from 1998 to 2005 and use actual political turnover as independent variable to exam the exclusion condition of using political turnover as IV. Panel B is the robustness check by re-estimating the results in Table 3.3 Panel A and add interactions between industry dummies and time dummies. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by firm. 147 Table 3.9: 2SLS Robustness Check Panel A: Industry trend robustness check Dependent Variable Privatized Share (6) (7) (4) (5) (3) (2) OROA Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker (1) F OA 0.026*** (0.010) 0.173** (0.082) Firm fixed effect Yes Time fixed effect Yes Industry fixed effect Yes Industry time trend Yes Observations 184,203 R-squared 0.064 F-stat of first stage 27.07 0.210*** (0.007) Yes Yes Yes Yes 181,913 0.136 27.27 Logsale 0.012 (0.014) 0.029*** 0.036*** (0.001) (0.001) Logasset Yes Yes Yes Yes 184,203 0.035 27.07 0.007*** (0.003) -0.095*** -0.209*** (0.037) (0.070) -0.052 (0.064) Yes Yes Yes Yes 184,203 0.164 27.31 0.033*** (0.002) Yes Yes Yes Yes 184,203 -0.000 27.34 Yes Yes Yes Yes 181,913 0.008 27.22 Yes Yes Yes Yes 180,615 0.092 26.55 Panel B: Industry trend robustness check Dependent Variable Privatized SOEs Logsale (1) ROA (7) (5) (6) (4) (3) (2) OROA Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker 0.063*** 0.103*** (0.005) (0.008) 0.041*** 0.048*** (0.000) (0.001) Logasset Firm fixed effect Yes Yes Time fixed effect Yes Yes Industry fixed effect Yes Yes Industry time trend Yes Yes Observations 408,348 408,348 R-squared -0.035 -0.078 F-stat of first stage 105.9 105.9 0.317*** (0.036) 0.206*** (0.004) Yes Yes Yes Yes 407,254 0.079 107.8 0.000 (0.001) 0.134*** 0.079** (0.017) (0.032) 0.160*** (0.028) Yes Yes Yes Yes 408,348 0.134 106.5 0.030*** (0.001) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 408,348 406,451 0.015 0.090 106.5 107.6 Yes Yes Yes Yes 407,254 0.010 107.8 Table 3.9 is the robustness check of privatization's effect on SOEs and private firms using years that mayor stayed as IV. Panel A is the results from re-do Table 3.4 Panel A and add interactions between industry dummies and time dummies. Panel B is the results from re-do Table 3.7 and add interactions between industry dummies and time dummies. All standard errors are clustered by firm. 148 Table 3.10: Do Politicians' Individual Fixed Effects Matter? Panel A: Province level firm City level politicians Variable F-stat P-value Constraints ROA 0.9238 0.9425 Provincial level politicians N F-stat P-value Constraints N 863 18,503 1.5242 <0.0001 171 19,202 Market Share 3.8817 <0.0001 863 18,503 7.3476 <0.0001 171 19,202 LogWorker 857 18,257 2.0118 <0.0001 169 18,951 1.4655 <0.0001 Panel B: City level firm City level politicians Variable Provincial level politicians F-stat P-value Constraints ROA 1.1230 0.0030 Market Share 3.8185 <0.0001 2.5496 <0.0001 LogWorker 1,098 1,098 1,090 N F-stat P-value Constraints 41,623 2.0445 <0.0001 41,623 7.9435 <0.0001 41,106 4.6190 <0.0001 168 168 166 N 42,533 42,533 42,010 Panel C: County level firm City level politicians Variable Provincial level politicians F-stat P-value Constraints ROA 1.8432 <0.0001 Market Share 2.7664 <0.0001 4.4848 <0.0001 LogWorker 1,116 1,116 1,109 N F-stat P-value Constraints 71,588 4.4796 <0.0001 71,588 6.4467 <0.0001 70,649 9.1727 <0.0001 166 166 164 N 72,514 72,514 71,570 Data restricted to state-owned firms. Reported in the table are the results from fixed effects panel regressions in equation 3.14. Standard errors are clustered by firm. Panel A is sample of SOEs at provincial political hierarchy. Panel B is sample of SOEs at city level political hierarchy. Panel C is sample of SOEs at county level political hierarchy. F-statistic and P-value in the table are calculated from politicians' fixed effects and N is the number of observations. In total, there are 1,116 city level politicians and 171 provincial level politicians who changed the job during sample period. 149 Table 3.11: Do Bad Politicians Extract Rents From Firms? Panel A: OLS regressions on SOEs Variable Jail Logsale (1) (2) ROA OROA -0.004*** -0.003*** (0.001) (0.001) 0.028*** 0.035*** (0.000) (0.001) Logasset (4) (3) (5) (6) (7) Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker -0.027*** (0.006) 0.001*** (0.000) -0.031*** -0.019*** (0.003) (0.005) 0.014* (0.007) Yes Yes Yes 260,871 0.056 0.022*** (0.002) -0.139*** 1.941*** (0.034) (0.086) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 260,871 256,419 0.056 0.093 0.231*** Constant -0.223*** -0.274*** (0.011) (0.014) Firm FE Yes Yes Time FE Yes Yes Industry FE Yes Yes Observations 260,871 260,871 R-squared 0.064 0.012 (0.007) 2.186*** (0.149) Yes Yes Yes 258,045 0.122 0.029*** (0.005) 4.964*** (0.095) Yes Yes Yes 258,045 0.004 Panel B: OLS regressions on private firms Variable Jail Logsale (1) (2) ROA OROA -0.001 -0.000 (0.001) (0.001) 0.040*** 0.050*** (0.000) (0.001) (3) (4) -0.027*** (0.007) 0.000 (0.000) Logasset 0.180*** Constant -0.002 (0.012) Firm FE Time FE Industry FE Observations R-squared (5) (6) (7) Log(Sales/worker) Mkt share Subsidy LogWage LogWorker -0.012*** -0.026*** (0.003) (0.006) 0.017*** (0.006) 0.023*** -0.253*** (0.017) -0.179 (0.132) (0.005) 3.357*** (0.154) Yes Yes Yes 319,506 Yes Yes Yes 319,506 Yes Yes Yes 319,248 Yes Yes Yes 319,506 Yes Yes Yes 319,506 Yes Yes Yes 318,803 Yes Yes Yes 319,248 0.088 0.049 0.138 0.118 0.051 0.099 0.032 (0.001) -0.208*** 2.128*** (0.050) (0.099) 4.030*** (0.121) Data restricted to SOEs in panel A and private firms in panel B. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by firm. The results are from estimating equation 3.15. Jail is the dummy of whether the politicians are bad or good."bad" means he or she went to Jail eventually. 150 Table 3.12: Politician Career Path Dependent Variable Average ROA Total Profit Age Education Gender Born at rural area Year_2 Year_3 Year_4 Year_5 Year_6 Year 7 Year_8 Year_9 Constant Person fixed effect Observations (1) Turnover -1.298 (2.334) -0.000 (0.000) 0.010 (0.007) -0.931** (0.453) -0.237 (0.199) 0.003 (0.081) 1.125*** (0.126) 1.851*** (0.125) 2.247*** (0.129) 2.567*** (0.136) 3.204*** (0.145) 3.424*** (0.163) 3.815*** (0.191) 3.984*** (0.246) -1.011 (1.459) NO 6,509 (2) Turnover (3) (4) Promotion Jail -5.137 (5.485) 0.000 (0.000) 4.428*** (1.317) (5) Retire (6) Dead 1.186 (2.677) -0.003 (0.025) 0.033** (0.015) -1.701 (3.901) -0.047 (0.071) 0.026 (0.028) 0.226* (0.130) -0.172 (0.192) 0.595 (0.474) -0.023 (0.249) -2.517** -3.652*** (0.763) NO (0.998) NO NO -3.504** (1.440) NO 1,167 1,140 1,130 1,157 0.026** (0.011) -0.063*** (0.009) 0.308 (0.467) 5.078*** (1.911) 0.027* (0.014) 0.018 (0.015) -0.304 (0.581) 0.252 (0.250) -0.064 (0.089) 1.445*** (0.143) 2.625*** (0.155) 3.543*** (0.172) 4.508*** (0.194) 5.925*** (0.225) 7.079*** (0.268) 8.276*** (0.328) 9.466*** (0.424) -1.021 (1.294) YES 7,446 2.377*** (0.664) Data in column (1) and (2) is panel data for each politicians' turnover. In total, there are 1,167 politicians and 7 years. Column (3) to (6) are the politicians' career path condition on turnover. Promotion is the dummy of whether the politicians got promoted or not. Jail is the dummy of whether the politicians went to jail or not. Retire and Dead are for retirement and death respectively. All regressions are probit model and robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. 151