Herding on Earnings Surprises: The Role of Institutional Investors in Post-Earnings Announcement Drift Linda H. Chen, Wei Huang and George J. Jiang☆ March 2015 ☆ Linda Chen is from the Department of Accounting, Carson College of Business, Washington State University, Pullman, WA 99164. Email address: linda.chen@wsu.edu. Wei Huang is from the Accounting and Finance Department, College of St. Benedict and St. John’s University, Collegeville, MN, 56321. Email address: whuang@csbsju.edu. George J. Jiang is the Gary P. Brinson Chair of Investment Management in the Department of Finance and Management Science, Carson College of Business, Washington State University, Pullman, WA 99164. Email address: george.jiang@wsu.edu. Tel: (509) 335-4474, Fax: (509) 335-3857. We wish to thank … for helpful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies. Herding on Earnings Surprises: The Role of Institutional Investors in PostEarnings Announcement Drift Abstract In this paper, we examine the role of institutional investors underlying post-earnings announcement drift. We provide evidence that transaction costs or limits to arbitrage do not fully explain why post-announcement abnormal stock returns are not arbitraged away by institutional investors. Instead, we find that the drift is only present in the stock sample where institutional trading herds in the same direction of earnings surprises. That is, institutional herding is likely a culprit of the stock price continuation. Nevertheless, we show that institutional herding in the same direction of earnings surprises does not push stock prices away from fundamental values but represents slow incorporation of information into stock prices. On the other hand, when institutional investors herd in the opposite direction of earnings surprises, there is an immediate destabilizing effect on stock prices. Key words: Post-earnings announcement drift; Transaction costs; Limits to arbitrage; Institutional herding; Stock price discovery. JEL Classification: 1 I. Introduction Existing literature documents a well-known post-earnings announcement drift (PEAD). That is, firms with positive earnings surprises subsequently outperform those with negative earnings surprises. Ball and Brown (1968) are the first to document the anomalous pattern in stock prices using a sample extending back to the 1950s. Subsequent studies confirm the postearnings announcement drift using different samples and methods, see, e.g., Foster, Olsen, and Shevlin (1984), Bernard and Thomas (1989, 1990), among others. While existing literature has proposed a number of explanations, from both rational and behavioral perspectives, of the postearnings announcement drift, one important question remains. That is, why are the anomalous returns not arbitraged away? In this paper, we examine the role of institutional investors underlying PEAD. Motivated by the arguments and empirical evidence documented in the existing literature, we are particularly interested in the following two questions. First, we examine to what extent transaction costs and limits to arbitrage prevent PEAD to be arbitraged away by institutional investors. Institutional investors are perceived as sophisticated and skilled. Several studies document that institutional investors exploit anomalous patterns in stock returns. For instance, Ke and Ramalingegowda (2005) show that active short-term institutional investors trade to exploit post-earnings announcement drift and earn positive abnormal returns. If institutional investors are indeed sophisticated and skilled, then the only reasons that prevent PEAD from being arbitraged away are transaction costs and limits to arbitrage. Second, we are interested in to what extent PEAD is associated with institutional herding. Existing literature documents that institutional investors have the tendency to engage in herding, that is, they buy or sell the same stocks during the same time period. While such herding behavior may be driven by access to common information set (Froot, Scharfstein, and 2 Stein (1992); Hirshleifer, Subrahmanyam, and Titman. (1994)), it is also likely that institutions may herd for reasons unrelated to information, such as the reputational risk of acting differently from others due to career concerns or preferences for specific stock characteristics due to investment styles (for detailed surveys of the herding literature, see Scharfstein and Stein (1990); Banerjee (1992); Devenow and Welch (1996); Falkenstein (1996); Bikhchandani and Sharma (2001); Gompers and Metrick (2001)). Following earnings announcement, institutions receive the same information about firm fundamentals. Thus, they may trade altogether on earnings surprises. If institutional herding incorporates information into stock prices, then price continuation or drift following earnings announcement represents a slow discovery process of stock prices. On the other hand, it is also possible that institutional herding drives stock prices away from their fundamental values if the trading of some institutions is not driven by information. We examine the effect of institutional herding on stock prices based on long-run stock returns. The main data used in our study includes CRSP for stock returns, Compustat for earnings announcements and other information on firm fundamentals, as well as the Thomason Financial 13F database for quarterly holdings of institutional investors. Our stock sample is restricted to common stocks traded on the NYSE, AMEX or NASDAQ. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. To examine whether transaction costs and limits to arbitrage prevent PEAD from being arbitraged away by institutional investors, we use two proxies of transaction costs, namely size and Amihud (2002) illiquidity ratio, and two proxies of limits to arbitrage, namely idiosyncratic volatility and short-sale constrain, in our empirical analysis. These measures have been used in existing studies, such as Bhushan (1994), Christophe, Ferri, and Angel (2004), Mendenhall (2004), Sadka (2006), Ng, Rusticus and Verdi (2008), Boehmer and Wu (2012), 3 etc. In particular, idiosyncratic volatility and short-sale constrain may explain not only why post-earnings announcement drift persists but also why it exists. Miller (1977) points out that stock prices reflect optimism in the presence of short-sale constraints. When investors’ beliefs are diverse and investors with pessimistic views are kept out of the market due to limits to arbitrage (as proxied by high idiosyncratic volatility or short-sale constraint), stocks tend to be over-valued and a future price reversal is likely. Our results show that consistent with findings in existing literature (Bhushan (1994) and Ng, Rusticus and Verdi (2008)), PEAD is more pronounced for small stocks and stocks with high illiquidity ratio. That is, transaction costs contribute to post-earnings announcement anomalous stock returns. Nevertheless, PEAD remains significant even among large cap stocks, i.e., those above the 20th percentile of the market cap of NYSE stocks. Similarly, consistent with findings in existing literature, PEAD is more pronounced for stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility and those with high short-sale constraint. That is, limits to arbitrage also contribute to postearnings announcement anomalous stock returns. Nevertheless, PEAD remains significant even among stocks below the 33rd percentile of idiosyncratic volatility or short-sale constraint of NYSE stocks. These findings suggest that while both transaction costs and limits to arbitrage attribute to PEAD, neither seems to fully explain why post-earnings announcement anomalous stock returns are not arbitraged sway by institutional investors. Next, we examine to what extent PEAD is associated with the herding behavior of institutional investors. Our results show that institutional investors in general herd in the direction of earnings surprises, namely institutional investors buy (sell) stocks with positive earnings surprises during the same time period. Nevertheless, we also note that institutional investors do not always herd in the same direction as that of earnings surprises. More than one third of stocks in the top (bottom) decile of earnings surprises are sold (bought) altogether by 4 institutional investors. This presents a nice setting to examine the extent to which post-earnings announcement drift is attributed by institutional herding and, more importantly, the effect of institutional herding on stock price discovery. Dividing stocks based on whether institutional investors herd in the same direction or opposite direction of earnings surprises, we show that drift following earnings announcement is significant only when institutional investors herd in the same direction of earnings surprises. When institutional investors herd in the opposite direction of earnings surprises, there is no longer significant drift after two weeks following earnings announcement. This is evidence that institutional herding against earnings surprises reverse market reaction to earnings surprises. We also use alternative measures of institutional herding in our analysis, namely the change of the number of institutional investors and the percentage change of the number of institutional investors. Both measures provide consistent results. In fact, when the percentage change of the number of institutional investors is used, the results are even stronger. Specifically, when the number of institutional investors decreases (increases) following positive (negative) earnings surprises, there is an immediate price reversal following earnings announcement. We confirm the results based on Fama-MacBeth regressions where we control for other firm characteristics that are known to be related to stock returns. Finally, we examine the effect of institutional herding on stock price discovery. As noted earlier, institutional herding driven by information helps stock price discovery as information is incorporated into stock prices gradually. On the other hand, institutional herding unrelated to information my push stock prices away from fundamental values and destabilize the price discovery process. We examine long-run stock returns up to 5 years following earnings announcements. Our results show that when institutions herd in the same direction of earnings surprises, we observe a slow price discovery process as information is slowly 5 incorporated into stock prices. On the other hand, when institutions herd in the opposite direction of earnings surprises, we observe an immediate short-term reversal following earnings announcement. This is evidence that institutional herding unrelated to information destabilizes stock prices and deters stock price discovery process. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section II describes data used in our analysis. Section III presents post-earnings announcement returns for subsamples of stocks based on size, illiquidity, idiosyncratic volatility, and short-sale constraint. In Section IV, we examine the effect of institutional herding on post-earnings announcement drift and stock price discovery. Section V concludes. II. Data and Methodology The main data used in our study include CRSP, Compustat, and Thomason Financial 13F. Firm characteristics are computed using information from the CRSP daily and monthly data as well as COMPUSTAT annual financial statements. We obtain quarterly institutional investors’ holdings from Thomason Financial 13F database. All institutions with greater than $100 million of securities under discretionary management are required to report their holdings to the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) within 45 days of the end of a calendar quarter. They must disclose all common-stock positions greater than $200,000 or 10,000 shares. Short interest data is obtained from NYSE and NASD (National Association of Securities Dealers) with monthly observations and from COMPUSTAT with semi-monthly observations. Our stock sample is restricted to common stocks traded on the NYSE, AMEX or NASDAQ. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. The key variable used in our empirical analysis is the standardized unexpected earnings (SUE). Following Foster (1977) and Foster, Olsen, and Shevlin (1984), we measure SUE as follows: 6 , , , , , where , , , 1 , 2 = quarterly earnings of the ith firm in period t, and are estimated using the most recent twenty quarters of data. Table I reports summary statistics of SUE. At the end of each quarter, we compute the mean, median, standard deviation, 25th and 75th percentiles of SUE and the number of observations of SUE in our sample. Table I reports these statistics for selected years in the sample period. Table I also reports summary statistics of other firm characteristics, including size, book to market ratio, momentum, Amihud (2002) illiquidity ratio, idiosyncratic volatility, and shortsale constraint. Following Fama and French (1993), market capitalization (SIZE) is calculated in the end of each June as stock price times the number of shares outstanding. Book-to-market ratio (BEME) is calculated as book value for the fiscal year ending in calendar year t-1 divided by market capitalization at the end of December of t-1. As defined in Fama and French (1993), book value is equal to book value of stockholders’ equity plus balance sheet deferred taxes and investment tax credits minus book value of preferred stocks. B/M are calculated at the end of each June, and used for the next four quarters. We exclude firms with negative book values. Momentum (MOM) is calculated as the cumulative 12-month return from Quarter t-2 to Quarter t-12. The Amihud illiquidity (ILLIQ) measure is calculated as the ratio of daily absolute return to dollar trading volume and averaged over the quarter (Amihud, 2002). Since trading volume in NASDAQ is double counted (Atkins and Dyl, 1997; Nagel, 2005), we adjust the turnover of NASDAQ stocks by a factor of 1/2. Following Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006), we measure idiosyncratic volatility relative to the Fama-French 3-factor model: ri ,t i i , MKT MKTt i , SMB SMBt i , HML HMLt i ,t . The model is estimated using daily 7 returns in the preceding quarter and idiosyncratic volatility (IVOLt) is obtained as var(i ,t ) . Relative short interest (RSI) is defined as monthly number of shares held short divided by the number of shares outstanding and averaged over the quarter. Following Asquith, Pathak and Ritter (2005), we use the difference between relative short interest, a proxy of short sale demand, and institutional ownership (IO), a proxy of short sale supply, as a measure of shortsale constraint (SSC). Institutional ownership is calculated as the number of shares held by institutional investors divided by total number of shares outstanding for each stock in the end of each quarter, i.e., IOt = # of shares held by institutional investors t total # of shares outstanding t III. Post-Earnings Announcement Drift: The Effect of Transaction Costs and Limits to Arbitrage A. Post-Earnings Announcement Drift In our empirical analysis, we first replicate post-earnings announcement drift (PEAD) in our sample period. Each quarter, stocks are sorted into decile portfolios based on SUE using previous quarter’s SUE breakpoints. For each decile portfolio, we compute equal-weighted cumulative abnormal returns over different horizons following earnings announcement. Following Bernard and Thomas (1989, 1990) and Foster, Olsen, and Shevlin (1984), we calculate the abnormal returns as follows: ARi ,t Ri ,t R p ,t where ARi ,t = abnormal return from firm i, day t; Ri ,t = raw return from firm i, day t; and R p ,t = equal-weighted average portfolio return for day t. To obtain equal-weighted average portfolio 8 return, we divide firms into deciles according to previous year December market capitalization and calculate average daily return for each portfolio. Table II reports the average abnormal stock returns of all SUE decile portfolios over different holding periods. It also reports return differentials and the associated Newey-West (1987) tstatistics between top and bottom SUE decides. To ensure that the return differentials are not just driven by the top and bottom deciles, we also compute and report return differentials between the average of top two and the average of bottom two SUE decides. Consistent with exiting studies (Ball and Brown (1968), Foster, Olsen, and Shevlin (1984), Bernard and Thomas (1989, 1990)), the results show clear and significant drift following earnings announcements. The return differentials between top and bottom SUE deciles are 0.774%, 1.556%, 2.374%, and 2.902%, respectively, over one-week, one-month, and one-quarter horizons following earnings announcements. All the differences are highly significant based on the Newey-West t-statistics. B. The Effect of Transaction Costs We use two variables as proxies of transaction costs: SIZE and Amihund illiquidity ratio (ILLIQ), as defined in Section II. Bhushan (1994) finds that transaction costs positively related to the magnitude of PEAD. Bhushan (1994) uses firm size as one of the proxies for transaction costs and shows that size is negatively related to transaction costs. Ng, Rusticus and Verdi (2008) also find that high transaction costs could weaken the return response to earnings announcement and enhance the PEAD. They find that transaction costs response for the existence and persistence of PEAD. Sadka (2006) also uses firm size and Amihud illiquidity ratio as proxy for liquidity and shows that liquidity risk can serve as an explanation of PEAD. 9 Follow the same procedure in the previous section, each quarter stocks are assigned to deciles using the SUE breakpoints of the previous quarter. As in Fama and French (2008), stocks in each decile are then divided into Big, Small, and Micro-cap subsamples using the 20th and 50th percentiles of the market cap for NYSE stocks. That is, we divide each SUE decile portfolio into three subgroups based on SIZE classification. This is equivalent to form SUE deciles for each size subgroup since the SUE breakpoints are based on the previous quarter. Table III reports the average equal-weighted cumulative abnormal returns of SUE decile portfolios of each size subgroup over different holding periods. As expected, the drift is most pronounced for micro-cap stocks. While the magnitude of drift for big stocks is much lower, it remains highly statistically significant. The return differentials between top and bottom SUE deciles are 0.533%, 1.047%, 0.896%, and 0.910%, respectively, over one-week, one-month, and one-quarter horizons following earnings announcements. The corresponding Newey-West t-statistics are 4.87, 5.33, 3.11, and 2.88. Note that this subsample contains stocks in the top 20th percentile of the market cap for NYSE stocks and there are on average only 32 stocks in the top and bottom deciles. Similarly, we divide stocks in each SUE decile into three subsamples according to the 33th and 67th percentiles of the ILLIQ of NYSE stocks. Again, this is equivalent to form SUE deciles for each ILLIQ subgroup since the SUE breakpoints are based on the previous quarter. Table IV reports the average equal-weighted cumulative abnormal returns of SUE decile portfolios of each ILLIQ subgroup over different holding periods. Similar to results based on SIZE subsamples, the drift is most pronounced for high ILLIQ stocks. While the magnitude of drift for low ILLIQ stocks is much lower, it remains highly statistically significant. The return differentials between top and bottom SUE deciles are 0.615%, 1.189%, 1.453%, and 1.490%, respectively, over one-week, one-month, and one-quarter horizons following earnings 10 announcements. The corresponding Newey-West t-statistics are 5.44, 5.79, 5.43, and 4.74. We interpret the results based on SIZE and ILLIQ as evidence that transaction costs unlikely fully explain why PEAD is not arbitraged away by institutional investors. C. The Effect of Limits to Arbitrage We use two variables as proxies of limits to arbitrage: idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL) and short sale constraint (SSC). Mendenhall (2004) uses idiosyncratic volatility to measure arbitrage risk and find that it is significantly positively related to the magnitude of PEAD. Boehmer and Wu (2012) find that short sales help reduce PEAD. Christophe, Ferri, and Angel (2004) find that short sales before earnings announcements are negatively related to stock returns after earnings announcement for NASDAQ firms. We divide stocks in each SUE decile in Table II into three subsamples according to the 33th and 67th percentiles of the IVOL for NYSE stocks. For each decile portfolio, we compute equal-weighted cumulative abnormal returns over different horizons following earnings announcement. Table V reports the average abnormal stock returns of SUE decile portfolios of each IVOL subgroup over different holding periods. Similarly, we divide stocks in each decile into three subsamples according to the 33th and 67th percentiles of the SSC for NYSE stocks. Table VI reports the average abnormal stock returns of SUE decile portfolios of different SSC groups over different holding period. Consistent with existing studies, our results show that stocks with high IVOL or SSC have higher drift following earnings announcement. Nevertheless, for both the subsample of stocks with the lowest IVOL and the subsample of stocks with the lowest SSC, there remains strong and significant post-earnings announcement drift. For the subsample of stocks with the lowest IVOL, the return differentials between top and bottom SUE deciles are 1.290%, 2.265%, 11 2.720%, and 3.141%, respectively, over one-week, one-month, and one-quarter horizons following earnings announcements. The corresponding Newey-West t-statistics are 12.42, 13.09, 12.82, and 14.04. For the subsample of stocks with the lowest SSC, the return differentials between top and bottom SUE deciles are 1.081%, 1.502%, 1.908%, and 2.076%, respectively, over one-week, one-month, and one-quarter horizons following earnings announcements. The corresponding Newey-West t-statistics are 6.65, 7.16, 5.63, and 4.95. We interpret these results as evidence that limits to arbitrage unlikely fully explain why PEAD is not arbitraged away by institutional investors. D. Fama-MacBeth Regressions We perform event-based Fama-MacBeth regressions of post-earnings announcement returns against SUE and other common firm characteristics. The main difference with the conventional Fama-MacBeth regression is that in our setting, stock returns and lagged variables are based on event dates instead of calendar dates. Specifically, we perform cross-sectional regression of post-earnings announcement returns against SUE with various firm characteristics included as control variables: RETi ,[ t 1,t T ] t 1t SUEi ,t k 1 kt X ki ,t i ,t T K where RETi ,[t 1,t T ] is post-earnings announcement returns of stock i from day t+1 to day t+τ with τ=5, 10, 21 and 63. The control variables include lagged market capitalization (SIZE), book to market ratio (B/M), previous month return (LRET), momentum (MOM), idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL), Amihund illiquidity ratio (ILLIQ) and relative short interest (RSI). The above regressions are estimated each quarter at the cross-section and Table VII reports time series averages of coefficient estimates as well as their Newey-West t-statistics. The results show that there is a significantly positive relation between SUE and post-earnings 12 announcement returns. More importantly, even after we control for common firm characteristics, such as SIZE, ILLIQ, IVOL, and ILLIQ, the relation remains positive and significant. IV. Post-Earnings Announcement Drift: The Effect of Institutional Herding A large body of empirical literature shows that institutional investors exhibit a tendency to herd, that is, they buy or sell the same stocks during the same time period. For example, Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1992), Nofsinger and Sias (1999), Wermers (1999), and Sias (2004) all provide evidence that institutional investors herd in buying or selling stocks. The theoretical literature offers two main reasons for why institutions might herd. First, they might receive similar information and trade based on the new information (Froot, Scharfstein, and Stein (1992); Hirshleifer, Subrahmanyam, and Titman. (1994)). Second, institutions may herd for reasons unrelated to information such as the reputational risk of acting differently from others or preferences for specific stock characteristics (for detailed surveys of the herding literature, see Scharfstein and Stein (1990); Banerjee (1992); Devenow and Welch (1996); Falkenstein (1996); Bikhchandani and Sharma (2001); Gompers and Metrick (2001)). In this paper, we examine institutional herding following earnings announcements. We are interested in whether institutional investors herd on earnings surprises. More importantly, what is the association between institutional herding and drift following earnings announcement? Moreover, what is the effect of institutional herding on the stock price discovery process? A. Earnings Announcements and Institutional Herding 13 We follow Lakonishok, Shleifer and Vishny (1992), Wermers (1999) and Sias (2004) and calculate the institutional herding (HERD) measure for each stock in our sample. Specifically, institutional herding is calculated as follows: HERDt pi ,t E pi ,t E NH [ pi ,t E pi ,t ] where pi ,t is the actual percentage of institutional investors that buy stock i. Those buyers are defined as institutional investors who increase their ownership over the quarter (IOt > lag IOt). E pi ,t is the expected value of pi ,t ,defined as the average buying percentage of all institutional investors trading at quarter t. E NH [ pi ,t E pi ,t ] is an adjustment factor which is the expected value of the first term under the null hypothesis that here is no herding. The theoretical distribution of pi ,t considering independent and random trades for each manager is a binomial distribution with mean E pi ,t We follow Brown, Wei and Wermers (2014) and further distinguish herding on the buy and sell sides by calculate buy-herding ( BHM i ,t ) and sell herding (SHMit): BHM i ,t HERDi ,t | pi ,t E[ pi ,t ] | SHM i ,t HERDi ,t | pi ,t E[ pi ,t ] | An “adjusted herding measure” is constructed to capture the direction of herding for a specific stock. Specifically, for each quarter and within each buy herding group (or sell herding group), the above measure is subtracted by the minimum value of BHM (or SHM) from each stock’s BHM (or SHM) to obtain a non-negative herding measure. Stocks that are traded by fewer than five institutional investors during the quarter are excluded in the calculation. We also use two additional measures of institutional herding in our analysis, namely the change of the number of institutional investors and the percentage change of the number of institutional investors. 14 Table VIII reports descriptive statistics of institutional ownership change (∆IO), institutional herding (INST HERD), the change of the number of institutional investors (∆#INST), and the percentage change of the number of institutional investors (%∆#INST ) each quarter in different SUE decile groups. For stocks in each decile, we compute the mean, median, 25th, 35th, 65th, and 75th percentiles of institutional ownership change (∆IO),institutional herding (INST HERD), change of the number of institutional investors (∆#INST), and the percentage change of the number of institutional investors (%∆#INST ) in each quarter. The table reports time series averages of these statistics for all SUE deciles. As shown in the table, institutional investors in general trade and herd in the same direction of earnings surprises. For example, as earnings surprise increases from SUE decile 1 (negative) to SUE decile 10 (positive), the average institutional herding increases, almost monotonically. The same patterns are observed for ∆IO, ∆#INST, and %∆#INST. We also note that there are variations in institutional herding among stocks within each decile. Specifically, in SUE decile 1 with negative earnings surprises, institutional investors herd in buying at least 35% of those stocks, whereas in SUE decile 10 with positive earnings surprises, institutional investors herd in selling at least 35% of those stocks. This cross-sectional variation presents an opportunity for us to examine the effect of institutional herding on post-earnings announcement stock returns. B. Institutional Herding and Post-Earnings Announcement Returns We divide stocks in each SUE decile into three subgroups based on the relation between institutional herding and earnings surprises, namely those with strongly positive, weakly positive, and negative relations between institutional herding and earnings surprises. For each decile portfolio, we compute equal-weighted cumulative abnormal returns over different horizons following earnings announcement. We perform similar analysis based on the change 15 of the number of institutional investors (∆#INST) and the percentage change in the number of institutional investors (%∆#INST). Table IX reports the average abnormal stock returns of SUE decile portfolios of each institutional herding (HERD) subgroup over different holding periods. The results show that when institutional investors herd strongly in the same direction of earnings surprises, there is a much stronger drift following earnings announcement. More importantly, when institutional investors herd in the opposite direction of earnings surprises, the drift following earnings announcement is only short-lived. As shown in Panel C of Table IX, there is a significant drift over the one-week horizon following earnings announcement. The drift is no longer significant beyond one-week horizon. Table X reports the average abnormal stock returns of SUE decile portfolios of different percentage change in the number of institutional investors (%∆#INST) groups over different holding period. Results based on the change in the number of institutional investors (∆#INST) are similar and thus not reported for brevity. Consistent with the result sin Table IX, the results in Table X show that when there is a high increase (decrease) in the percentage of the number of institutional investors for stocks with positive (negative) earnings surprises, the drift following earnings announcement is much stronger in both magnitude and statistical significance. On the other hand, when there is a high decrease (increase) in the percentage of the number of institutional investors for stocks with positive (negative) earnings surprises, we observe an immediate reversal in stock returns following earnings announcement. While announcement day returns for stocks with positive surprises are significantly higher than for those with negative surprises, the post-earnings announcement stock returns are quickly reversed. The return differentials between top and bottom SUE deciles are negative and 16 statistically insignificant over one-week horizon, but negative and highly significant beyond one-week horizons. To further control for the effect of other firm characteristics on post-earnings announcement returns, we perform event-based Fama-MacBeth regressions of post-earnings announcement returns. Specifically, we regress post-earnings announcement returns against SUE, interactions of SUE with dummies for institutional herding and percentage change in the number of institutional investors, and various firm characteristics included as control variables: RETi ,[ t 1,t T ] t 1t SUEi ,t 2 t DHERD * SUEi ,t 3t DIO * SUEi ,t k 1 kt X ki ,t i ,t T K where RETi ,[t 1,t T ] is post-earnings announcement returns of stock i from day t+1 to day t+τ with τ=5, 10, 21 and 63. DHERD * SUEi ,t is the interaction term of interactions of SUE with dummies for institutional herding. The institutional herding dummy is set equal to 1 if there is strongly positive or weakly positive correlations between institutional herding and SUE and otherwise 0. DIO * SUEi ,t is the interaction term of interactions of SUE with dummies for percentage change in the number of institutional investors. The percentage change in the number of institutional investors dummy is set equal to 1 if there is strongly positive or weakly positive correlations between percentage change in the number of institutional investors and SUE and otherwise 0. The control variables include lagged market capitalization (SIZE), book to market ratio (B/M), previous month return (LRET), momentum (MOM), idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL), Amihund illiquidity ratio (ILLIQ) and relative short interest (RSI). The above regressions are estimated each quarter at the cross-section and Table XI reports time series averages of coefficient estimates as well as their Newey-West t-statistics. The results confirm that the relation between SUE and post-earnings announcement returns is significantly 17 positive only for stock samples where institutional investors herd in the same direction of earnings surprises. V. Post-Earnings Announcement Returns Over Long-Run The finding that post-earnings announcement drift is significant only when institutional investors herd in the same direction of earnings surprises suggests tow possible roles of institutional investors. One interpretation of the finding is that institutional investors may be slow in reacting to earnings information and in incorporating information into stock prices. This represents a slow process of stock price discovery. The other interpretation of the finding is that institutional investors may herd beyond the effect of earnings information and as such drive stock prices away from fundamental values. We examine long run stock returns following earnings announcement to distinguish the above two hypotheses. Our main premise is that if institutional herding drives stock prices away from fundamental values, we should observe return reversals over long run. Figure I plots post-earnings announcement abnormal stock returns of all stocks in the SUE deciles. Panel A plots the average abnormal stock returns up to 60 months during the postearnings announcement period for each decile portfolio formed on SUE. Panel B plots return differentials between the top and bottom deciles (D10-D1) and the average of top two and bottom two deciles (D10|9-D1|2). The reason to examine returns up to 60 months or 5 years is that as documented in De Bondt and Thaler (1985), stock returns on average tend to revers over 3- to 5-year horizons. As shown in Figure I, returns of both top and bottom SUE deciles tend to be persistent. The differences between D1 and D10 as well as the difference between the average of D1 and D2 and the average of D10 and D9, as plotted in Panel B, show that 18 there is no obvious reversal of stock returns following earnings announcements even up to 60month horizon. Figure II plots post-earnings announcement abnormal stock returns for the subsample of stocks with strongly positive relation between the percentage change of the number of institutional investors (%∆#INST) and SUE. Panel A plots the average abnormal stock returns up to 60 months during the post-earnings announcement period for all SUE decile portfolios. Panel B plots return differentials between top and bottom deciles (D10-D1) and the average of top two and the average of bottom two deciles (D10|9-D1|2). The results show similar patterns as the full sample results as plotted in Figure I. That is, there is no obvious reversal of stock returns following earnings announcements even up to 60-month horizon. This is evidence that institutional herding in the direction of earnings surprises do not destabilize stock prices but represents a slow process of stock price discovery. Finally, Figure III plots post-earnings announcement abnormal stock returns for the subsample of stocks with negative relation between the percentage change of the number of institutional investors (%∆#INST) and SUE. Panel A plots the average abnormal stock returns up to 60 months during the post-earnings announcement period for all SUE deciles. Panel B plots return differentials between top and bottom deciles (D10-D1) and the average of top two and the average of bottom two deciles (D10|9-D1|2). The plots confirm the results in Table X that there is an immediate return reversal following earnings announcement when institutional investors herd in the opposite direction of earnings surprises. However, as illustrated in Panel B of Figure III, these reversals are soon corrected over longer horizons. VI. Conclusion 19 In this paper, we examine the role of institutional investors underlying post-earnings announcement drift. We are mainly interested in the following two questions. First, to what extent transaction costs and limits to arbitrage prevent institutional investors from arbitraging away anomalous stock returns following earnings announcement? Second, to what extent the drift following earnings announcement is associated with the herding behavior of institutional investors. We provide evidence that transaction costs or limits to arbitrage do not fully explain why post-announcement abnormal stock returns are not arbitraged away by institutional investors. In addition, we find that while institutional investors in general herd in the same direction of earnings surprises, there are more than one third of stocks in the top (bottom) decile with positive (negative) earnings surprises where institutional investors herd in selling these stocks. We use these two subsamples to examine how the drift following earnings announcement is associated with herding behavior of institutional investors and, moreover, the effect of institutional herding on long-run stock price discovery. Our results show that the drift is only present in the stock sample where institutional trading herds in the same direction of earnings surprises. That is, institutional herding following earnings announcements is likely a culprit of the stock price continuation. Nevertheless, we show that such herding behavior does not push stock prices away from fundamental values but represents slow incorporation of information into stock prices. On the other hand, when institutional investors herd in the opposite direction of earnings surprises, there is clear evidence of immediate price reversal following earnings announcement. 20 References Amihud, Y., 2002, Illiquidity and Stock Returns, Journal of Financial Markets 5: 31–56. Ang, A.; R. Hodrick; Y. Xing; and X. Zhang. “The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns.” Journal of Finance, 51 (2006a), 259-299. Asquith, P., P. A. Pathak, and J. R. Ritter, 2005, Short interest, institutional ownership, and stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics 78, 243–276. Atkins, A.B., and E. A. Dyl, 1997, Transactions costs and holding periods for common stocks, Journal of Finance 52, 309-325. Ball, R., and P. Brown, 1968, An Empirical Evaluation of Accounting Income Numbers, Journal of Accounting Research 6: 159-178. Bernard, V. L., and J. K. Thomas, 1989, Post-earnings-announcement drift: Delayed price response or risk premium, Journal of Accounting Research, 27(3), 1-36. Banerjee, A., 1992, A simple model of herd behavior, Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 797–817. Bernard, V. L., and J. K. Thomas, 1990, Evidence that stock prices do not fully reflect the implications of current earnings for future earnings, Journal of Accounting and Economics 13.4: 305-340. Bhushan, R., 1994, An Informational Efficiency Perspective on the Post-Earnings Announcement Drift, Journal of Accounting & Economics 18: 45–65. Bikhchandani, S., Sharma, S., 2001, Herd behavior in financial markets, IMF Staff Papers 49: 279–310. Boehmer, E. and J. Wu, 2013, Short selling and the price discovery process, Review of Financial Studies 26, 287–322. Christophe, S. E., M. G. Ferri, and J. J. Angel, 2004, Short-selling prior to earnings announcements, Journal of Finance 59, 1845-1876. De Bondt, W. F., & Thaler, R. (1985). Does the stock market overreact?. The Journal of finance, 40(3), 793-805. Devenow, A. and I. Welch, 1996. Rational herding in financial economics, European Economic Review 40: 603–615. Fama, E. F. and K. R. French, 1993, Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56. Falkenstein, E. G., 1996, Preferences for stock characteristics as revealed by mutual fund portfolio holdings, Journal of Finance 51, 111–135. Foster, G., 1977, Quarterly Accounting Data: Time-Series Properties and Predictive-Ability Results, The Accounting Review, January, pp. 1-21. Foster, G., C. Olsen, and T. Shevlin, 1984, Earnings releases, anomalies, and the behavior of security returns, Accounting Review, 574-603. Froot, K., D. Scharfstein and J. Stein, 1992, Herd on the street: Informational inefficiencies in a market with short-term speculation, Journal of Finance 47: 1461–1484. Gompers, P.A., Metrick, A., 2001, Institutional investors and equity prices, Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, 229–259. Hirsheifer, David, A. Subrahmanyam, and S. Titman, 1994, Security analysis and trading patterns when some investors receive information before other, Journal of Finance 49, 16651698. Hirshleifer, D., A. Subrahmanyam, and S. Titman, 1994, Security analysis and trading patterns when some investors receive information before others, Journal of Finance 49, 1665-1698. Ke, B. and S. Ramalingegowda, 2005, Do institutional investors exploit the post-earnings announcement drift? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39(1), 25-53. 21 Lakonishok, J., A. Shleifer and Vishny, R., 1992. The impact of institutional trading on stock prices, Journal of Financial Economics 32: 23–43. Miller, E. “Risk, Uncertainty, and Divergence of Opinion.” Journal of Finance, 32 (1977), 1151- 1168. Nagel, S., 2005, Short sales, institutional investors and the cross-section of stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics 78, 277–309. Ng, J., T. O. Rusticus, and R. S. Verdi, 2008, Implications of transaction costs for the post– earnings announcement drift, Journal of Accounting Research, 46(3), 661-696. Nofsinger, J. and R.W. Sias, 1999. Herding and feedback trading by institutional and individual investors, Journal of Finance 54: 2263–2295. Sadka, R., 2006, Momentum and post-earnings-announcement drift anomalies: The role of liquidity risk, Journal of Financial Economics 80, 309-349. Scharfstein, D.S. and J.C. Stein, 1990, Herd behavior and investment, American Economic Review 80: 465–479. Sias, R.W., 2004, Institutional herding, Review of Financial Studies 17: 165–206. Wermers, R., 1999, Mutual fund herding and the impact on stock prices, Journal of Finance 54, 581-622. 22 Table I. Summary Statistics of Firm Characteristics This table reports summary statistics of firm characteristics of the stock sample at the end of selected years during our sample period: 1980, 1990, 2000, 2013. Each year, we compute the mean, median, standard deviation (StDev), 5th, 25th, 75th and 95th percentiles and the number of observations of each variable. The variables include market capitalization (SIZE), book to market ratio (B/M), momentum (MOM), Amihud illiquidity ratio (ILLIQ), idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL), and relative short interest (RSI). SIZE is calculated at the end of each June as market capitalization. B/M is calculated at the end of each June using book value for the fiscal year ending in calendar year t-1 divided by market capitalization at the end of December of year t-1. MOM is the skip one month cumulative 12month return preceding the month. ILLIQ is calculated as the ratio of absolute daily return to dollar trading volume and averaged over the quarter. IVOL is the standard error of the residual of the Fama-French 3-factor model estimated for daily return over the quarter. RSI is calculated each month as the number of shares held short divided by the total number of shares outstanding and averaged over the quarter. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. Year 1980 Variable SIZE B/M MOM ILLIQ IVOL RSI N 2097 1658 2103 1910 2108 2109 5% 55.07 0.0299 -0.3081 0.0049 0.8973 0.00% 25% 251.86 0.0632 -0.0790 0.0360 1.4642 0.00% Mean 3993.25 0.1170 0.1562 2.9447 2.3168 79.31% Median 865.62 0.1010 0.0708 0.1994 2.0492 1.43% 75% 3071.98 0.1480 0.2916 1.1624 2.8479 27.36% 95% 14182.53 0.2580 0.8980 12.7410 4.5668 287.94% StDev 16249.34 0.0845 0.3928 11.2994 1.2276 376.44% 1990 SIZE B/M MOM ILLIQ IVOL RSI 3285 2584 3305 3318 3318 3318 54.26 0.0140 -0.6188 0.0018 1.0916 0.00% 233.66 0.0362 -0.3125 0.0349 1.8416 2.64% 7794.01 0.0784 -0.0351 16.7970 3.6304 160.19% 819.26 0.0619 -0.0987 0.5252 2.8433 17.29% 3955.08 0.0964 0.1275 4.8222 4.3385 101.85% 34449.17 0.1896 0.7391 56.9030 9.0274 681.45% 28639.09 0.0870 0.4917 139.5041 2.8618 651.58% 2000 SIZE B/M MOM ILLIQ IVOL RSI 4713 3611 4779 4820 4817 4820 88.08 0.0049 -0.6170 0.0005 1.5029 0.15% 409.44 0.0203 -0.2857 0.0085 2.4450 4.05% 25929.36 0.0738 0.2388 3.3921 4.2380 171.96% 1478.28 0.0492 -0.0459 0.1166 3.7097 45.05% 6958.06 0.0966 0.3469 1.4421 5.4594 181.48% 84264.44 0.2171 2.0083 16.7587 8.7359 758.62% 152370.39 0.0849 1.1410 13.5646 2.4163 376.68% 2013 SIZE B/M MOM ILLIQ IVOL RSI 2922 2146 2947 2979 2976 2979 205.56 0.0094 -0.3516 0.0001 0.7277 0.00% 1241.99 0.0299 0.0622 0.0006 1.1059 0.00% 44581.81 0.0833 0.3433 4.3723 2.1322 0.00% 5162.70 0.0528 0.2648 0.0046 1.6453 0.00% 21233.08 0.0888 0.4989 0.0576 2.5415 0.00% 174616.54 0.2061 1.1337 10.1769 4.9221 0.00% 182971.60 0.3829 0.8144 41.6818 1.8836 0.00% 23 Table II. Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns This table reports the average abnormal stock returns of all SUE decile portfolios over different holding periods. Each quarter, stocks are assigned to deciles using the SUE breakpoints of the previous quarter. D1 includes firms with the lowest SUE rank, and D10 includes firms with the highest SUE rank. The average return differentials between top and bottom deciles (top and bottom two deciles), as well as their Newey-West t-statistics, are also reported. N is the average number of stocks in each decile. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 348 341 345 347 346 345 344 342 344 346 -1.240 -0.817 -0.537 -0.223 0.071 0.419 0.752 1.084 1.394 1.824 -0.776 -0.592 -0.470 -0.288 -0.189 0.093 0.175 0.303 0.485 0.607 -0.897 -0.768 -0.612 -0.423 -0.327 0.026 0.217 0.362 0.591 0.774 -0.906 -0.906 -0.572 -0.404 -0.337 0.096 0.400 0.528 0.830 0.965 -0.918 -0.863 -0.524 -0.365 -0.293 0.306 0.542 0.714 1.048 1.256 -1.055 -0.858 -0.502 -0.351 -0.162 0.456 0.666 0.895 1.272 1.556 -1.335 -1.019 -0.692 -0.374 0.018 0.828 1.047 1.230 1.787 2.374 -1.424 -1.245 -0.861 -0.357 0.123 1.103 1.255 1.522 2.264 2.902 3.064 (31.32) 2.637 (32.29) 1.383 (12.34) 1.230 (12.80) 1.671 (10.04) 1.515 (11.52) 1.871 (9.39) 1.804 (11.75) 2.175 (9.88) 2.043 (12.41) 2.611 (10.95) 2.370 (13.09) 3.708 (14.74) 3.257 (17.53) 4.326 (16.58) 3.918 (20.93) D10–D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 NW-t 24 Table III. Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns – Size Subsamples Each quarter, stocks are assigned to deciles using the SUE breakpoints of the previous quarter. Stocks in each decile are then divided into big, small, and micro-cap subsamples using the 20th and 50th percentiles of the market cap for NYSE stocks. The average abnormal returns for all SUE deciles in each size subsample are calculated and reported. The average return differentials between top and bottom deciles (top and bottom two deciles) in each size subsample, as well as their Newey-West t-statistics, are also reported. N is the average number of stocks in each decile. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. Panel A: Micro-cap Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 260 257 264 266 264 259 251 249 256 260 -1.514 -0.969 -0.629 -0.275 0.112 0.488 0.920 1.324 1.646 2.212 -0.933 -0.723 -0.570 -0.370 -0.231 0.101 0.202 0.345 0.546 0.713 -1.050 -0.959 -0.739 -0.516 -0.392 0.023 0.256 0.399 0.663 0.903 -1.070 -1.148 -0.693 -0.500 -0.411 0.083 0.471 0.584 0.928 1.094 -1.067 -1.116 -0.635 -0.468 -0.342 0.333 0.659 0.823 1.173 1.424 -1.196 -1.095 -0.618 -0.419 -0.174 0.543 0.825 1.065 1.470 1.759 -1.511 -1.249 -0.823 -0.383 0.133 1.020 1.321 1.545 2.173 2.834 -1.667 -1.514 -0.989 -0.368 0.285 1.444 1.658 1.897 2.806 3.498 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 3.726 (28.94) 3.171 1.646 (12.37) 1.458 1.953 (9.81) 1.788 2.163 (9.12) 2.120 2.491 (9.60) 2.390 2.956 (10.26) 2.760 4.345 (14.18) 3.884 5.165 (16.17) 4.742 NW-t (29.85) (12.78) (11.44) (11.53) (12.27) (12.72) (17.25) (20.86) 25 Panel B: Small Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 56 53 52 52 52 53 57 57 56 54 -0.568 -0.395 -0.274 -0.082 -0.068 0.237 0.352 0.520 0.761 0.801 -0.264 -0.164 -0.170 0.039 0.006 0.132 0.115 0.211 0.373 0.312 -0.469 -0.185 -0.268 -0.045 -0.010 0.104 0.099 0.264 0.511 0.419 -0.431 -0.209 -0.266 -0.009 -0.007 0.244 0.254 0.376 0.759 0.611 -0.432 -0.161 -0.273 0.047 -0.083 0.398 0.267 0.426 0.953 0.853 -0.551 -0.237 -0.277 -0.083 -0.118 0.364 0.204 0.475 0.961 1.083 -0.790 -0.351 -0.414 -0.246 -0.407 0.503 0.275 0.448 0.984 1.212 -0.711 -0.494 -0.507 -0.164 -0.351 0.323 0.206 0.643 0.994 1.369 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 1.369 (12.87) 1.262 0.576 (7.20) 0.557 0.888 (7.62) 0.792 1.043 (6.80) 1.005 1.285 (6.88) 1.199 1.635 (7.55) 1.416 2.002 (7.26) 1.669 2.079 (5.91) 1.783 NW-t (16.31) (3.14) (7.69) (9.01) (8.84) (9.61) (7.70) (6.56) Panel C: Big Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 32 31 28 29 29 33 36 36 32 31 -0.293 -0.394 -0.254 -0.102 -0.070 0.104 0.298 0.414 0.577 0.516 -0.251 -0.127 0.019 -0.063 -0.051 0.015 0.092 0.150 0.160 0.223 -0.263 -0.127 0.043 -0.078 -0.170 -0.015 0.155 0.256 0.208 0.270 -0.279 -0.125 0.114 -0.118 -0.139 -0.048 0.120 0.326 0.239 0.444 -0.424 -0.075 0.176 -0.079 -0.153 -0.013 0.115 0.385 0.328 0.500 -0.521 -0.042 0.212 -0.039 -0.048 -0.018 0.272 0.373 0.373 0.526 -0.460 -0.225 0.066 -0.215 -0.166 -0.064 0.330 0.424 0.312 0.436 -0.463 -0.278 -0.180 -0.297 -0.301 -0.206 0.165 0.440 0.520 0.447 0.810 (8.01) 0.891 (11.07) 0.474 (5.70) 0.381 (6.90) 0.533 (4.87) 0.434 (5.36) 0.722 (4.69) 0.543 (5.33) 0.924 (5.30) 0.664 (5.03) 1.047 (5.33) 0.731 (4.48) 0.896 (3.11) 0.717 (3.30) 0.910 (2.88) 0.854 (3.30) D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 NW-t 26 Table IV. Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns – Illiquidity Subsamples Each quarter, stocks are assigned to deciles using the SUE breakpoints of the previous quarter. Stocks in each decile are then divided into three subsamples according to the 33th and 67th percentiles of the Amihund illiquidity ratio (ILLIQ) for NYSE stocks. The average abnormal returns for all SUE deciles in each illiquidity subsample are calculated and reported. The average return differentials between top and bottom deciles (top and bottom two deciles) in each illiquidity subsample, as well as their Newey-West t-statistics, are also reported. N is the average number of stocks in each decile. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. Panel A: High ILLIQ Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 208 208 217 221 221 216 208 207 212 217 -1.648 -1.037 -0.653 -0.297 0.142 0.556 1.003 1.417 1.811 2.446 -1.003 -0.787 -0.596 -0.388 -0.270 0.086 0.195 0.374 0.606 0.774 -1.162 -1.030 -0.786 -0.561 -0.446 0.007 0.255 0.410 0.713 0.950 -1.213 -1.267 -0.751 -0.543 -0.489 0.025 0.463 0.588 1.010 1.143 -1.249 -1.268 -0.692 -0.520 -0.441 0.321 0.651 0.827 1.232 1.499 -1.381 -1.217 -0.681 -0.452 -0.229 0.570 0.817 1.084 1.532 1.860 -1.513 -1.244 -0.770 -0.288 0.196 1.174 1.479 1.743 2.398 3.132 -1.681 -1.585 -0.954 -0.240 0.428 1.632 1.913 2.175 3.132 3.881 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 4.095 (26.98) 3.472 1.777 (12.61) 1.585 2.112 (9.89) 1.928 2.356 (9.25) 2.317 2.748 (9.79) 2.624 3.241 (10.30) 2.995 4.645 (13.57) 4.144 5.562 (15.09) 5.139 NW-t (28.74) (13.13) (11.31) (11.59) (12.19) (12.32) (16.46) (19.13) 27 Panel B: Medium ILLIQ Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 79 76 74 72 71 72 73 73 73 70 -0.893 -0.577 -0.417 -0.150 -0.021 0.164 0.457 0.721 0.868 1.021 -0.530 -0.379 -0.316 -0.156 0.026 0.195 0.185 0.249 0.311 0.385 -0.563 -0.543 -0.399 -0.254 -0.088 0.114 0.220 0.369 0.456 0.609 -0.523 -0.560 -0.387 -0.257 -0.009 0.269 0.460 0.509 0.654 0.894 -0.438 -0.436 -0.363 -0.168 0.057 0.376 0.577 0.697 0.951 1.123 -0.516 -0.528 -0.335 -0.316 0.003 0.363 0.652 0.835 1.148 1.309 -1.103 -0.910 -0.904 -0.757 -0.266 0.331 0.582 0.787 1.249 1.499 -1.145 -0.954 -0.992 -0.748 -0.426 0.410 0.392 0.826 1.338 1.772 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 1.914 (16.01) 1.679 0.915 (8.60) 0.803 1.172 (8.18) 1.086 1.417 (8.30) 1.316 1.561 (8.70) 1.474 1.824 (9.31) 1.751 2.602 (9.39) 2.380 2.917 (8.26) 2.604 NW-t (17.98) (9.90) (10.47) (10.70) (10.41) (11.90) (11.06) (9.61) Panel C: Low ILLIQ Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 61 58 54 54 54 58 62 62 59 58 -0.416 -0.394 -0.330 -0.113 -0.087 0.219 0.341 0.491 0.655 0.675 -0.252 -0.131 -0.102 -0.003 -0.086 0.054 0.136 0.155 0.248 0.220 -0.381 -0.094 -0.128 0.009 -0.150 0.058 0.156 0.229 0.341 0.234 -0.310 -0.072 -0.055 0.041 -0.116 0.142 0.184 0.355 0.474 0.369 -0.343 0.003 0.017 0.090 -0.144 0.235 0.223 0.386 0.598 0.522 -0.522 0.008 0.046 0.099 -0.095 0.225 0.289 0.340 0.587 0.667 -0.814 -0.255 -0.062 -0.089 -0.263 0.307 0.279 0.186 0.416 0.639 -0.695 -0.383 -0.219 -0.165 -0.237 0.125 0.257 0.373 0.614 0.795 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 1.091 (12.35) 1.070 0.471 (5.94) 0.425 0.615 (5.44) 0.525 0.679 (5.02) 0.612 0.865 (4.77) 0.730 1.189 (5.79) 0.884 1.453 (5.43) 1.062 1.490 (4.74) 1.243 NW-t (15.48) (7.44) (5.86) (5.91) (5.81) (6.13) (5.71) (5.68) 28 Table V. Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns – IVOL Subsamples Each quarter, stocks are assigned to deciles using the SUE breakpoints of the previous quarter. Stocks in each decile are then divided into three subsamples according to the 33th and 67th percentiles of the idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL) for NYSE stocks. The average abnormal returns for all SUE deciles in each IVOL subsample are calculated and reported. The average return differentials between top and bottom deciles (top and bottom two deciles) in each IVOL subsample, as well as their Newey-West t-statistics, are also reported. N is the average number of stocks in each decile. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. Panel A: High IVOL Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 208 200 205 208 204 196 187 185 195 206 -1.576 -1.028 -0.653 -0.277 0.113 0.538 1.015 1.476 1.778 2.330 -1.026 -0.810 -0.642 -0.443 -0.337 0.098 0.179 0.332 0.509 0.712 -1.146 -1.037 -0.799 -0.651 -0.559 -0.053 0.164 0.293 0.532 0.782 -1.052 -1.193 -0.716 -0.621 -0.581 0.014 0.395 0.515 0.818 0.973 -1.004 -1.124 -0.628 -0.588 -0.523 0.297 0.629 0.804 1.084 1.370 -1.153 -1.087 -0.589 -0.536 -0.327 0.524 0.793 1.064 1.403 1.699 -1.437 -1.246 -0.743 -0.503 0.065 1.079 1.324 1.633 2.131 2.862 -1.426 -1.399 -0.849 -0.325 0.433 1.632 1.859 2.157 2.857 3.706 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 3.908 (28.76) 3.356 1.738 (11.43) 1.529 1.928 (8.60) 1.749 2.032 (7.58) 2.018 2.379 (7.86) 2.291 2.870 (8.41) 2.671 4.305 (11.92) 3.838 5.471 (13.54) 4.694 NW-t (32.41) (12.14) (9.88) (9.73) (10.24) (10.76) (14.63) (17.82) 29 Panel B: Median IVOL Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 80 81 82 80 81 82 85 85 83 77 -0.889 -0.632 -0.397 -0.208 0.026 0.331 0.528 0.807 1.042 1.367 -0.397 -0.295 -0.240 -0.040 0.074 0.118 0.200 0.332 0.511 0.526 -0.542 -0.421 -0.370 -0.063 0.087 0.144 0.337 0.527 0.752 0.787 -0.626 -0.521 -0.372 -0.068 0.118 0.236 0.493 0.637 0.969 1.050 -0.715 -0.539 -0.405 0.002 0.137 0.408 0.553 0.741 1.157 1.228 -0.807 -0.644 -0.394 -0.003 0.195 0.524 0.625 0.852 1.346 1.489 -1.197 -0.770 -0.626 -0.192 0.063 0.680 0.695 0.964 1.638 1.787 -1.468 -1.111 -0.881 -0.505 -0.129 0.616 0.616 1.008 1.755 1.920 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 2.256 (20.65) 1.965 0.923 (9.85) 0.864 1.329 (8.78) 1.251 1.676 (10.15) 1.583 1.943 (10.55) 1.820 2.297 (11.79) 2.143 2.984 (12.21) 2.696 3.388 (12.16) 3.127 NW-t (21.47) (10.51) (10.51) (12.30) (12.97) (13.49) (15.12) (14.87) Panel C: Low IVOL Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 60 61 58 60 62 66 71 72 66 63 -0.611 -0.433 -0.358 -0.177 -0.047 0.129 0.313 0.420 0.672 0.839 -0.395 -0.258 -0.130 -0.069 -0.034 0.065 0.116 0.217 0.325 0.359 -0.572 -0.310 -0.251 -0.079 -0.071 0.141 0.221 0.388 0.600 0.717 -0.800 -0.447 -0.287 -0.046 -0.057 0.192 0.335 0.492 0.790 0.907 -0.971 -0.481 -0.292 -0.077 -0.047 0.249 0.313 0.539 0.901 0.985 -1.095 -0.462 -0.322 -0.108 -0.024 0.232 0.355 0.605 0.926 1.170 -1.246 -0.609 -0.453 -0.100 -0.020 0.369 0.628 0.764 1.104 1.474 -1.653 -0.906 -0.851 -0.312 -0.269 0.141 0.398 0.738 1.128 1.488 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 1.450 (16.64) 1.277 0.754 (11.15) 0.668 1.290 (12.42) 1.100 1.707 (11.75) 1.472 1.956 (12.36) 1.669 2.265 (13.09) 1.826 2.720 (12.82) 2.217 3.141 (14.04) 2.588 NW-t (18.69) (11.42) (13.80) (13.81) (13.88) (14.55) (15.20) (15.58) 30 Table VI. Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns – Subsamples of Short Sale Constraint Each quarter, stocks are assigned to deciles using the SUE breakpoints of the previous quarter. Stocks in each decile are then divided into three subsamples according to the 33th and 67th percentiles of the short sale constraint (SSC) for NYSE stocks. SSC is defined as relative short interest minus institutional ownership. The average abnormal returns for all SUE deciles in each SSC subsample are calculated and reported. The average return differentials between top and bottom deciles (top and bottom two deciles) in each SSC subsample, as well as their Newey-West t-statistics, are also reported. N is the average number of stocks in each decile. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. Panel A: High Short Sale Constraint Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 192 190 194 195 193 188 187 188 194 197 -1.557 -0.965 -0.628 -0.239 0.151 0.510 0.917 1.323 1.694 2.265 -0.966 -0.758 -0.621 -0.430 -0.298 -0.004 0.082 0.274 0.501 0.680 -1.140 -1.036 -0.805 -0.670 -0.474 -0.105 0.080 0.276 0.584 0.791 -1.193 -1.203 -0.786 -0.612 -0.555 -0.053 0.278 0.435 0.836 1.006 -1.240 -1.223 -0.762 -0.641 -0.480 0.222 0.515 0.669 1.075 1.364 -1.428 -1.175 -0.802 -0.654 -0.360 0.460 0.595 0.836 1.326 1.676 -1.854 -1.339 -0.942 -0.556 -0.067 0.995 1.192 1.399 2.076 2.735 -2.046 -1.632 -1.118 -0.451 0.239 1.524 1.507 1.823 2.768 3.433 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 3.821 (27.56) 3.240 1.647 (12.40) 1.453 1.931 (9.35) 1.776 2.199 (8.86) 2.119 2.605 (9.47) 2.451 3.104 (9.98) 2.803 4.589 (13.83) 4.002 5.479 (16.05) 4.939 NW-t (30.03) (13.13) (11.20) (11.23) (12.06) (11.82) (15.89) (19.06) 31 Panel B: Median Short Sale Constraint Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 1] [2, 2] [2, 5] [2, 10] [2, 15] [2, 21] [2, 42] [2, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 86 83 83 83 84 85 86 86 83 83 -0.964 -0.703 -0.441 -0.244 -0.114 0.266 0.589 0.934 1.060 1.383 -0.642 -0.398 -0.286 -0.088 -0.068 0.176 0.256 0.368 0.426 0.559 -0.648 -0.436 -0.421 -0.094 -0.147 0.136 0.451 0.497 0.594 0.825 -0.667 -0.554 -0.324 -0.069 -0.065 0.198 0.628 0.743 0.856 1.031 -0.680 -0.463 -0.293 0.087 -0.049 0.380 0.677 0.910 1.097 1.288 -0.707 -0.460 -0.219 0.127 0.103 0.356 0.947 1.220 1.241 1.653 -0.719 -0.480 -0.457 -0.083 0.180 0.568 1.180 1.432 1.652 2.311 -0.651 -0.582 -0.541 -0.040 0.093 0.534 1.401 1.621 1.989 2.669 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 2.347 (17.40) 2.055 1.200 (10.80) 1.012 1.473 (9.14) 1.251 1.698 (8.43) 1.554 1.968 (9.33) 1.764 2.360 (10.20) 2.030 3.029 (10.67) 2.581 3.320 (8.66) 2.946 NW-t (18.83) (11.06) (9.72) (10.20) (10.79) (11.53) (12.24) (10.70) Panel C: Low Short Sale Constraint Stocks Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 70 67 68 70 69 72 72 69 67 65 -0.679 -0.483 -0.405 -0.133 0.037 0.289 0.520 0.573 0.865 0.966 -0.386 -0.286 -0.188 -0.080 0.050 0.273 0.337 0.338 0.512 0.450 -0.461 -0.314 -0.230 -0.129 -0.018 0.281 0.368 0.551 0.678 0.621 -0.367 -0.351 -0.168 -0.137 0.064 0.412 0.526 0.645 0.863 0.821 -0.292 -0.215 -0.053 -0.017 0.081 0.490 0.537 0.698 1.023 1.003 -0.330 -0.317 0.014 0.008 0.159 0.597 0.626 0.789 1.200 1.173 -0.524 -0.644 -0.279 -0.154 0.087 0.656 0.636 0.615 1.143 1.384 -0.540 -0.739 -0.524 -0.478 -0.116 0.597 0.446 0.704 1.202 1.536 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 1.645 (17.31) 1.496 0.836 (7.36) 0.817 1.081 (6.65) 1.037 1.188 (6.05) 1.201 1.294 (6.60) 1.266 1.502 (7.16) 1.510 1.908 (5.63) 1.848 2.076 (4.95) 2.009 NW-t (17.40) (8.80) (8.28) (8.18) (8.64) (9.66) (8.06) (7.07) 32 Table VII. Fama-MacBeth Regressions of Post-Earnings Announcement Returns Each quarter, we perform cross-sectional regressions of post-earnings announcement stock returns over different holding periods on SUE with various control variables. The control variables include lagged market capitalization (SIZE), book to market ratio (B/M), previous month return (LRET), momentum (MOM), Amihund illiquidity ratio (ILLIQ), idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL), and relative short interest (RSI). For details on variable definitions, please refer to Table I. The table reports time series average of coefficient estimates and their Newey-West t-statistics. *** and ** indicate significance at the 1% and 5% level, respectively. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 21] 0.561*** (11.15) 0.000 (0.861) 0.503 (1.83) -0.130 (-0.60) -0.350*** (-4.74) 0.016*** (3.95) -0.168*** (-6.40) 0.008** (2.09) 0.611*** (12.25) 0.658*** (12.16) 0.000 (0.96) 0.231 (0.55) -0.330 (-1.06) -0.525*** (-4.27) 0.016*** (3.84) -0.189*** (-4.74) 0.013** (2.35) 0.858*** (14.27) 0.920*** (14.47) 0.000 (0.19) 0.368 (0.54) -0.691 (-1.46) -0.475** (-2.18) 0.012** (2.05) -0.161** (-2.30) 0.021*** (2.78) 1.595*** (21.25) 1.663*** (18.76) -0.000 (-0.94) 3.844** (2.22) -0.153 (-0.15) -0.255 (-0.46) 0.046*** (4.59) -0.121 (-0.66) 0.032** (2.11) N 0.131 (1.27) 3534 0.494*** (4.91) 2643 0.454** (2.31) 3534 0.882*** (4.65) 2643 1.218*** (3.46) 3534 1.473*** (4.59) 2643 3.917*** (4.22) 3534 3.210*** (4.46) 2643 Adj. R2 (%) 0.42% 1.37% 0.38% 1.55% 0.41% 2.11% 0.50% 3.16% SIZE B/M LRET MOM ILLIQ IVOL RSI Intercept 33 [1, 63] 0.517*** (11.39) SUE Table VIII . Institutional Ownership Changes and Institutional Herding Across SUE Deciles Each quarter, stocks are assigned to deciles using the SUE breakpoints of the previous quarter. For stocks in each decile, we compute the mean, median, 25th, 35th, 65th, and 75th percentiles of institutional ownership change (∆IO),institutional herding (INST HERD), change of the number of institutional investors (∆#INST), and the percentage change of the number of institutional investors (%∆#INST ) each quarter. The table reports time series averages of these statistics for all SUE deciles. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. ∆IO INST. HERD SUE Decile 25% 35% Mean Median 65% 75% 25% 35% Mean Median 65% 75% D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 -1.450 -1.261 -1.175 -1.085 -1.078 -1.078 -1.012 -0.975 -0.990 -0.998 -0.676 -0.574 -0.538 -0.485 -0.484 -0.478 -0.441 -0.417 -0.433 -0.422 -0.346 -0.018 0.190 0.267 0.360 0.385 0.482 0.539 0.472 0.516 -0.021 0.019 0.043 0.066 0.098 0.100 0.120 0.149 0.119 0.132 0.623 0.676 0.722 0.762 0.828 0.834 0.835 0.878 0.814 0.860 1.334 1.429 1.480 1.552 1.626 1.594 1.601 1.640 1.592 1.667 -32.920 -31.446 -30.095 -29.764 -29.532 -29.189 -28.862 -29.036 -29.026 -28.442 -21.521 -20.553 -19.678 -18.848 -18.903 -17.933 -18.199 -17.846 -17.262 -16.540 -3.506 -2.476 -2.403 -1.734 -1.568 -0.542 -0.256 0.127 -0.186 0.295 -6.291 -4.704 -5.031 -4.361 -4.486 -3.333 -3.013 -2.504 -2.797 -1.258 7.391 9.671 9.512 10.968 10.859 14.060 15.145 14.658 14.207 14.181 25.233 25.700 24.929 25.979 26.718 27.330 28.728 28.719 28.300 28.347 SUE Decile t 25 % 35% Mean Median 65% 75% 25% 35% Mean Median 65% 75% D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 -3.890 -3.438 -3.077 -2.813 -2.669 -2.438 -2.482 -2.265 -2.055 -1.941 -2.015 -1.691 -1.456 -1.324 -1.184 -0.993 -0.989 -0.846 -0.699 -0.574 2.007 2.485 2.527 3.063 3.304 3.803 4.231 4.583 4.499 4.724 -0.202 0.037 0.136 0.371 0.507 0.717 0.805 0.930 1.007 1.107 1.787 2.063 2.096 2.485 2.610 2.982 3.206 3.515 3.522 3.735 4.048 4.301 4.423 4.779 4.963 5.717 6.022 6.566 6.445 6.717 -6.835 -5.720 -5.601 -5.256 -4.873 -4.215 -4.001 -3.826 -3.767 -3.752 -3.669 -2.874 -2.747 -2.298 -2.137 -1.738 -1.551 -1.448 -1.235 -1.210 2.655 3.487 4.443 4.699 5.032 5.422 5.650 5.943 8.623 7.002 -0.391 0.070 0.333 0.581 0.868 1.295 1.426 1.608 1.878 1.925 3.065 3.531 3.974 4.559 4.640 5.097 5.331 5.631 5.940 6.021 6.354 7.225 7.560 8.472 8.408 9.093 8.973 9.854 9.957 10.510 ∆#INST %∆#INST 34 Table IX. Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns – Subsamples of Institutional Herding Each quarter, stocks are assigned to deciles using the SUE breakpoints of the previous quarter. Stocks in each decile are then divided into three subsamples: as those with strongly positive, weakly positive, and negative correlations between institutional herding (HERD) and SUE. The average abnormal returns for all SUE deciles in each subsample are calculated and reported. The average return differentials between top and bottom deciles (top and bottom two deciles), as well as their Newey-West t-statistics, are also reported. N is the average number of stocks in each decile. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. Panel A: Strong Positive Correlation between HERD and SUE Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 111 105 104 103 102 106 107 107 104 105 -1.287 -0.834 -0.637 -0.315 -0.166 0.580 0.729 1.161 1.445 1.803 -1.008 -0.825 -0.772 -0.543 -0.432 0.265 0.424 0.526 0.692 0.816 -1.216 -1.144 -1.099 -0.913 -0.735 0.502 0.700 0.913 1.076 1.410 -1.362 -1.265 -1.179 -1.018 -0.877 0.870 1.121 1.341 1.590 1.908 -1.499 -1.194 -1.177 -1.081 -0.921 1.290 1.350 1.674 1.986 2.465 -1.750 -1.376 -1.284 -1.202 -0.910 1.583 1.703 2.059 2.477 3.008 -2.294 -1.846 -1.764 -1.414 -1.084 2.307 2.416 2.767 3.372 4.104 -2.193 -2.099 -1.981 -1.356 -1.070 2.464 2.643 3.078 4.001 4.681 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 3.090 (30.62) 2.685 1.824 (9.99) 1.671 2.626 (9.57) 2.423 3.270 (10.01) 3.062 3.963 (11.30) 3.572 4.758 (12.40) 4.306 6.398 (15.01) 5.808 6.874 (13.85) 6.487 NW-t (32.26) (10.34) (10.33) (11.13) (11.82) (12.87) (14.79) (15.29) 35 Panel B: Weak Positive Correlation between HERD and SUE Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 143 141 144 146 143 140 139 139 145 147 -1.371 -0.912 -0.493 -0.202 0.207 0.540 1.025 1.205 1.612 2.207 -0.787 -0.579 -0.483 -0.278 -0.178 0.166 0.227 0.441 0.596 0.720 -0.967 -0.795 -0.694 -0.405 -0.237 0.073 0.323 0.385 0.760 0.810 -0.996 -1.046 -0.677 -0.338 -0.314 0.059 0.448 0.488 0.892 0.896 -0.948 -0.994 -0.715 -0.316 -0.353 0.168 0.633 0.584 1.078 1.192 -1.153 -0.938 -0.633 -0.293 -0.254 0.438 0.690 0.777 1.244 1.436 -1.430 -1.243 -1.085 -0.367 -0.133 0.766 1.260 1.104 1.751 2.496 -1.675 -1.455 -1.331 -0.307 0.029 1.137 1.491 1.193 2.260 2.752 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 3.578 (26.50) 3.051 1.506 (11.10) 1.340 1.777 (8.77) 1.666 1.892 (7.41) 1.916 2.140 (7.63) 2.106 2.589 (8.56) 2.386 3.926 (10.41) 3.460 4.426 (10.81) 4.071 NW-t (26.81) (12.36) (11.13) (10.48) (10.86) (11.03) (13.76) (14.21) Panel C: Negative Correlation between HERD and SUE Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 93 95 97 99 100 99 98 96 95 93 -0.837 -0.527 -0.389 -0.106 0.199 0.100 0.419 0.704 0.954 1.111 -0.428 -0.324 -0.097 0.012 0.093 -0.161 -0.190 -0.021 0.109 0.158 -0.367 -0.297 0.013 0.171 0.132 -0.508 -0.433 -0.187 -0.052 0.028 -0.114 -0.291 0.232 0.400 0.353 -0.537 -0.327 -0.159 0.058 0.018 -0.059 -0.149 0.503 0.583 0.598 -0.386 -0.252 -0.042 0.185 0.078 0.015 0.089 0.724 0.786 0.879 -0.468 -0.256 -0.083 0.217 0.247 0.198 0.320 1.036 1.110 1.578 -0.336 -0.387 -0.155 0.193 0.427 0.232 0.223 0.998 1.087 1.650 -0.068 -0.255 0.205 0.473 0.979 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 1.948 (17.55) 1.715 0.586 (6.36) 0.509 0.395 (2.55) 0.320 0.132 (0.62) 0.241 0.137 (0.52) 0.236 0.232 (0.70) 0.180 0.228 (0.50) 0.051 0.747 (1.61) 0.498 NW-t (18.28) (7.52) (2.99) (1.51) (1.21) (0.72) (0.13) (1.35) 36 Table X. Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns – Subsamples of Percentage Change in the Number of Institutional Investors Each quarter, stocks are assigned to deciles using the SUE breakpoints of the previous quarter. Stocks in each decile are then divided into three subsamples: as those with strongly positive, weakly positive, and negative correlations between percentage change in the number of institutional investors (%∆#INST) and SUE. The average abnormal returns for all SUE deciles in each subsample are calculated and reported. The average return differentials between top and bottom deciles (top and bottom two deciles), as well as their Newey-West t-statistics, are also reported. N is the average number of stocks in each decile. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. Panel A: Strong Positive Correlation between %∆#INST and SUE Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 136 127 125 120 116 155 156 159 163 167 -1.602 -1.286 -1.014 -0.643 -0.313 0.798 1.185 1.618 1.857 2.326 -1.280 -1.054 -0.983 -0.700 -0.638 0.473 0.624 0.735 0.971 1.173 -1.507 -1.449 -1.372 -1.114 -1.040 0.693 0.913 1.151 1.412 1.691 -1.768 -1.885 -1.554 -1.429 -1.259 1.014 1.311 1.599 1.960 2.249 -1.988 -2.031 -1.599 -1.624 -1.433 1.495 1.693 2.047 2.397 2.861 -2.352 -2.246 -1.881 -1.887 -1.560 1.951 2.028 2.592 2.986 3.472 -3.142 -3.062 -2.900 -2.657 -2.066 3.031 3.057 3.643 4.206 5.050 -3.028 -3.240 -3.271 -2.723 -2.216 3.306 3.371 4.165 4.799 5.717 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 3.929 (35.74) 3.535 2.452 (10.97) 2.238 3.198 (10.02) 3.030 4.017 (10.70) 3.931 4.849 (11.81) 4.639 5.824 (13.06) 5.528 8.193 (15.87) 7.730 8.745 (14.95) 8.392 NW-t (39.49) (11.07) (11.12) (12.61) (14.05) (15.25) (17.35) (17.24) 37 Panel B: Weak Positive Correlation between %∆#INST and SUE Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 78 79 79 80 80 81 83 80 78 77 -0.886 -0.577 -0.351 -0.142 0.035 0.417 0.598 0.845 1.140 1.316 -0.455 -0.371 -0.323 -0.211 -0.150 0.102 0.125 0.304 0.360 0.458 -0.541 -0.541 -0.418 -0.334 -0.353 0.095 0.123 0.258 0.354 0.524 -0.430 -0.588 -0.334 -0.369 -0.337 0.050 0.245 0.389 0.349 0.555 -0.521 -0.588 -0.304 -0.416 -0.391 0.201 0.346 0.448 0.482 0.771 -0.652 -0.608 -0.178 -0.516 -0.394 0.327 0.360 0.471 0.489 0.996 -0.723 -0.765 -0.432 -0.651 -0.360 0.461 0.552 0.358 0.642 1.295 -0.629 -0.916 -0.719 -0.873 -0.439 0.655 0.546 0.482 0.854 1.639 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 2.202 (14.81) 1.959 0.913 (9.28) 0.822 1.066 (6.94) 0.980 0.985 (5.46) 0.961 1.292 (6.81) 1.181 1.648 (7.10) 1.372 2.019 (5.84) 1.712 2.268 (5.75) 2.019 NW-t (15.20) (11.13) (8.76) (7.29) (8.43) (8.23) (6.69) (7.90) Panel C: Negative Correlation between %∆#INST and SUE Holding Period SUE Decile N [-1, 0] [1, 1] [1, 5] [1, 10] [1, 15] [1, 21] [1, 42] [1, 63] D1 D2 D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 D8 D9 D10 133 136 142 147 150 109 106 103 102 101 -0.803 -0.399 -0.054 0.238 0.465 -0.002 0.334 0.414 0.700 1.155 -0.321 -0.203 -0.013 0.105 0.230 -0.353 -0.314 -0.219 -0.039 -0.099 -0.260 -0.209 0.037 0.205 0.337 -0.780 -0.633 -0.602 -0.307 -0.342 -0.055 -0.119 0.336 0.540 0.512 -0.981 -0.759 -0.829 -0.435 -0.570 0.185 0.156 0.542 0.866 0.872 -1.120 -0.869 -0.915 -0.474 -0.665 0.324 0.422 0.844 1.148 1.357 -1.297 -0.949 -1.062 -0.621 -0.732 0.543 0.927 1.441 1.848 2.201 -1.591 -1.433 -1.580 -0.811 -0.925 0.321 0.603 1.428 1.991 2.574 -1.304 -1.218 -1.542 -0.449 -0.692 D10 –D1 NW-t D10|9–D1|2 1.958 (14.07) 1.529 0.222 (2.46) 0.193 -0.082 (-0.51) -0.090 -0.515 (-2.52) -0.416 -0.850 (-3.71) -0.740 -1.057 (-3.76) -1.049 -1.468 (-3.15) -1.603 -1.013 (-2.09) -1.032 NW-t (15.61) (2.93) (-0.79) (-2.75) (-4.03) (-4.55) (-4.04) (-2.40) 38 Table XI. Fama-MacBeth Regressions of Post-Earnings Announcement Returns on Institutional Herding Each quarter, we perform cross-sectional regressions of post earnings announcement stock returns over different holding period on SUE, interactions of SUE with dummies for institutional herding and percentage change in the number of institutional investors (dHERD and d%∆#INST), and various control variables. The institutional herding dummy is set equal to 1 if there is strongly positive or weakly positive correlations between institutional herding (or percentage change in the number of institutional investors) and SUE and otherwise 0. The control variables include market capitalization (SIZE), book to market ratio (B/M), previous month return (LRET), momentum (MOM), Amihund illiquidity ratio (ILLIQ), idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL), and relative short interest (RSI). For details on variable definitions, please refer to Table I. The table reports time series average of coefficient estimates and their Newey-West t-statistics. *** and ** indicate significance at the 1% and 5% level, respectively. The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. SUE dHERD *SUE *** 0.254 (6.40) 0.480*** (8.38) d%∆#INST *SUE SIZE B/M LRET MOM ILLIQ IVOL RSI Intercept N Adj. R2 (%) 0.000 (0.83) 0.543** (1.97) -0.180 (-0.84) 0.363*** (-4.88) 0.017*** (4.02) 0.158*** (-6.17) 0.008** (2.20) 0.479*** (4.77) 2641 1.429 [1, 5] 0.182*** (3.54) *** 0.166 (3.08) 0.735*** (10.36) 0.547*** (8.61) 0.000 (1.01) 0.551** (2.01) -0.176 (-0.82) -0.053 (-1.00) 0.395*** (7.63) 0.505*** (8.36) 0.000 (0.98) 0.579** (2.10) -0.215 (-1.00) -0.364*** [1, 10] 0.143** (2.16) *** [1, 21] 0.090 (1.01) -0.000 (-0.96) 4.005** (2.34) -0.298 (-0.30) 1.908*** (9.26) -0.000 (-0.87) 3.903** (2.26) -0.294 (-0.30) -0.530** -0.299 -0.294 -0.326 (-2.30) 0.012** (2.02) (-2.40) 0.013** (2.23) (-0.54) 0.048*** (4.82) (-0.53) 0.045*** (4.58) (-0.59) -0.047*** (4.78) -0.136 -0.153** -0.133 -0.084 -0.110 -0.082 (-4.32) 0.014** (2.52) (-1.94) 0.022*** (2.86) (-2.19) 0.022*** (2.91) (-1.90) 0.023*** (2.98) (-0.46) 0.032** (2.15) (-0.61) 0.033** (2.20) (-0.45) 0.034** (2.23) 0.834*** (4.42) 2641 1.727 1.427*** (4.46) 2641 2.230 1.437*** (4.49) 2641 2.264 1.400*** (4.38) 2641 2.352 3.136*** (4.36) 2643 3.258 3.151*** (4.38) 2641 3.311 3.093*** (4.30) 2641 3.386 0.171 (2.20) 1.116*** (9.92) 0.000 (0.88) 0.307 (0.73) -0.405 (-1.30) 0.749*** (8.91) 0.000 (1.04) 0.281 (0.67) -0.388 (-1.25) -0.374*** -0.546*** -0.543*** (-4.91) 0.016*** (3.93) (-5.01) 0.017*** (3.99) (-4.40) 0.017*** (3.94) -0.164*** -0.156*** (-6.29) 0.008** (2.19) 0.477*** (4.76) 2641 1.458 *** *** [1, 63] 0.345** (2.22) -0.479** (-2.36) 1.394*** (7.18) 1.727*** (9.08) -0.000 (-0.89) 4.029** (2.35) -0.403 (-0.41) -0.241 (-3.12) 0.648*** (9.98) 0.674*** (8.50) 0.000 (0.96) 0.342 (0.81) -0.448 (-1.45) 0.564 (4.29) 1.619*** (7.78) 0.000 (0.13) 0.487 (0.72) -0.800 (-1.70) 1.202*** (10.26) 0.000 (0.25) 0.432 (0.633) -0.788 (-1.67) -0.487 (-4.26) 0.976*** (9.48) 1.083*** (10.07) 0.000 (0.20) 0.528 (0.78) -0.873 (-1.86) -0.559*** -0.510** -0.504** (-4.39) 0.016*** (3.81) (-4.49) 0.016*** (3.90) (-2.32) 0.014** (2.29) -0.172*** -0.183*** -0.169*** (-6.12) 0.009** (2.29) (-4.38) 0.014** (2.42) (-4.61) 0.014** (2.45) 0.465*** (4.64) 2641 1.501 0.854*** (4.53) 2641 1.640 0.856*** (4.52) 2641 1.663 39 ** Figure I. Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns Panel A plots the average abnormal stock returns up to 60 months following earnings announcement for each decile portfolio formed on SUE. Panel B plots return differentials between top and bottom deciles (D10-D1) and top and bottom two deciles (D10|9-D1|2). The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. CAR(%) Panel A: Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 -10 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 Month Decile 1 Decile 2 Decile 3 Decile 4 Decile 5 Decile 6 Decile 7 Decile 8 Decile 9 Decile 10 Panel B: Return Differentials between D10 and D1 and (D10+D9)/2 and (D1+D2)/2 20.000 18.000 16.000 CAR(%) 14.000 12.000 10.000 8.000 6.000 4.000 2.000 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 Month D10|9-D1|2 D10 –D1 40 Figure II. Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns – Strong Positive Correlation between Percentage Change in the Number of Institutional Investors and SUE Panel A plots the average abnormal stock returns up to 60 months following earnings announcement for stocks in each decile portfolio formed on SUE with strongly positive correlations between percentage change in the number of institutional investors and SUE. Panel B plots return differentials between the top and bottom deciles (D10-D1) and top and bottom two deciles (D10|9-D1|2). The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. CAR (%) Panel A: Post-earnings announcement abnormal stock returns 20.00 18.00 16.00 14.00 12.00 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 -2.00 -4.00 -6.00 -8.00 -10.00 -12.00 -14.00 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 Month Decile 1 Decile 2 Decile 3 Decile 4 Decile 5 Decile 6 Decile 7 Decile 8 Decile 9 Decile 10 CAR(%) Panel B: Return differentials between (D10+D9)/2 and (D1+D2)/2 26.000 24.000 22.000 20.000 18.000 16.000 14.000 12.000 10.000 8.000 6.000 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 Month D10|9-D1|2 D10 –D1 41 Figure III. Post-Earnings Announcement Abnormal Stock Returns – Negative Correlation between Percentage Change in the Number of Institutional Investors and SUE Panel A plots the average abnormal stock returns up to 60 months following earnings announcement for stocks in each decile portfolio formed on SUE with negative correlations between percentage change in the number of institutional investors and SUE. Panel B plots return differentials between the top and bottom deciles (D10-D1) and top and bottom two deciles (D10|9-D1|2). The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2013. Panel A: Post-earnings announcement abnormal stock returns 10.000 8.000 CAR(%) 6.000 4.000 2.000 0.000 -2.000 -4.000 -6.000 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 Month Decile 1 Decile 2 Decile 3 Decile 4 Decile 5 Decile 6 Decile 7 Decile 8 Decile 9 Decile 10 Panel B: Return differentials between (D10+D9)/2 and (D1+D2)/2 6.000 CAR(%) 4.000 2.000 0.000 -2.000 -4.000 -6.000 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 Month D10|9-D1|2 D10 –D1 42