Preliminary and incomplete Please do not quote without permission External Stability, Real Exchange Rate Adjustment, and the Exchange Rate Regime1 Olivier Gervais Bank of Canada Lena Suchanek Bank of Canada Larry Schembri Bank of Canada May 2009 Abstract Unsustainably large global current account imbalances are widely seen as an important contributing factor to the ongoing financial crisis. The lack of exchange rate adjustment to these imbalances is viewed as being partly responsible. Theories of external adjustment in open economies (e.g., Obstfeld and Rogoff, 1994) maintain that smooth adjustment to external imbalances can be most easily obtained via real exchange rate adjustment, rather than via income/output/expenditure adjustment. The purpose of this paper is to explore two related hypotheses: (i) that real exchange rate flexibility and adjustment is critical to maintaining external stability and (ii) that a flexible nominal exchange rate facilitates real exchange rate adjustment and the maintenance of external stability, if domestic wages and prices are sticky. Based on an event study analysis for a large set of emerging market economies over the 19752008 period, we find that real exchange rate adjustment has contributed significantly to current account adjustments. However, adjustment for fixed exchange rate regime countries with current account deficits does not occur through the classical adjustment process, but as a consequence of exchange rate crises, where the nominal exchange rate is forced to adjust and the costs in terms of foregone GDP growth is high. Preliminary results using vector error correction techniques support our finding in the event study; namely that the long run relationship between the current account and the real exchange rate is negative, which is consistent with theory. JEL classification codes: F31, F32, F41 1 We would like to thank Wei Dong, Sharon Kozicki, Michael Francis, Robert Lavigne, and Jeannine Baillu for helpful comments, and Firas Abu-Sneneh for excellent research assistance. The views in this paper are solely our responsibility and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Bank of Cananda. Email: lsuchanek@bankofcanada.ca 1 Introduction Unsustainably large global current account (CA) imbalances are widely seen as an important contributing factor to the ongoing financial crisis. The lack of exchange rate adjustment to these imbalances is viewed as being partly responsible.2 This concern about global imbalances helped instigate the reform of IMF surveillance activities that resulted in the recent 2007 Decision on Surveillance (IMF 2007). In this Decision, the IMF made the maintenance of “external stability” the focus of its surveillance activities over members’ exchange rate, fiscal, monetary and financial sector policies. The IMF refers to “external stability” as a balance of payments position that does not, and is not likely to, give rise to disruptive exchange rate movements. Although the concept of external stability encompasses both the current and the capital accounts of the balance of payments because CA imbalances may not cause disruptive exchange rate movements if they are complemented by sustainable capital inflows or outflows, the focus is primarily on CA imbalances and real exchange rate (RER) misalignment. However, the fear of labeling member country’s exchange rates as “misaligned” in Article IV reports has hampered the effective implementation of the 2007 Surveillance Decision. Lavigne and Schembri (2009) argue that the focus of IMF surveillance over exchange rates should, instead, be on permitting timely and effective RER adjustment to ensure that CA imbalances are restored to sustainable levels. Theories of external adjustment in open economies (e.g., Obstfeld and Rogoff, 1994) maintain that smooth adjustment to external imbalances can be most easily obtained via RER adjustment, rather than via income/output/expenditure adjustment. Relative price movements cause expenditure to switch between domestic and foreign-produced goods and can take place while the economy is operating at close-to-full employment. In contrast, income and expenditure adjustment have proven to be much more disruptive. In theory, market-driven RER adjustment will occur in response to a CA imbalance either via money supply and price level movements under a fixed nominal exchange rate (i.e., the classical adjustment process) or 2 For example, the IMF writes in the “People’s Republic of China: Staff Report for the 2006 Article IV Consultation”: “From a global perspective, exchange rate flexibility ... would also help contribute to an orderly process for resolving global CA imbalances.” In addition, Garcίa-Herrero et Koivu (2007) find that a more flexible nominal exchange rate would favour the adjustment of the trade balance. Page 2 of 45 via movements in a flexible nominal exchange rate (i.e., the [Meade-] Friedman adjustment process). Friedman (1953) and Borda (2005) maintain that because of the nominal stickiness of domestic wages and prices, a flexible exchange rate can facilitate RER adjustment. Numerous examples exist of the high cost of the classical adjustment process: the UK’s return to the gold standard in 1926, the West German boom of the 1960s, and the Argentine experience with a currency board in the 1990s. In practice, recent examples of the classical adjustment process are rare. Countries with a fixed nominal exchange rate and CA surpluses frustrate the RER adjustment process by sterilizing the impact on the domestic money supply. In countries with a deficit, RER adjustment under a fixed exchange rate occurs as a consequence of an exchange crisis in which the nominal rate is forced to adjust and economic activity is often disrupted. The purpose of this paper is to explore two related hypotheses: 1. that RER flexibility and adjustment is critical to maintaining external stability (main hypothesis) and 2. that a flexible nominal exchange rate facilitates RER adjustment and the maintenance of external stability because nominal wages and prices are sticky (corollary hypothesis). From a policy perspective, addressing these hypotheses and questions is important because they speak directly to exchange rate policy and the choice of exchange rate regimes. First, does a relatively flexible RER favor an adjustment of CA imbalances?3 And second, if this is so, does a flexible exchange rate regime allow external imbalances to adjust more smoothly? Although the existing literature has tended to focus on the second of our two hypotheses, that is the choice of the nominal exchange rate regime, we believe it is important to establish the validity of the first hypothesis, that is, the critical role of the RER in the adjustment process. To examine these questions and hypotheses we adopt two complementary empirical methodologies. We first examine the role of RER adjustments during periods of CA adjustments using an event study for 21 emerging market economies (EMEs) from 1975-2008, following the methodology of Freund and Warnock (2005). We also examine CA surplus 3 We measure external imbalances by the level of the CA. The literature has proposed alternative measures, such as the level of external debt to GDP, foreign assets, or reserves in terms of import months. Adjustment capacity has been measured by the change in imports following a shock (Igbar and Erbas, 1997) and the first order autocorrelation of the CA (Cheung and Lai, 2007). Page 3 of 45 reversals, and split the sample into crisis vs. non-crisis periods, and in fixed vs. floating exchange rate regimes. To our knowledge, the question of exchange rate regimes has not been addressed in the event study literature and this methodology seems to yield interesting results. Our preliminary empirical findings are consistent with the two hypotheses .First, we find that periods of CA reversals have been associated with sizeable RER depreciation. The larger the CA reversal, the larger the depreciation. Second, there seems to be a tradeoff between the adjustment that comes through the RER and through GDP. Put differently, if the RER can not adjust (potentially due to a fixed nominal exchange rate and slow adjustment of price levels), output/income has to take a larger burden in the adjustment. Third, the adjustment is more painful in terms of output loss for countries that had a fixed exchange rate regime at the time of the reversal, and the RER depreciates by more. Our results suggest that fast adjustment of external imbalances can come through a flexible nominal ER, or, a crisis. Given that a crisis comes along with higher cost in terms of output, this result suggests that a flexible ER allows a rapid but orderly adjustment of the CA, which is consistent with our second hypothesis. We then seek to examine the dynamic interaction of the CA, the RER, foreign and domestic income for the same sample of EMEs using vector error correction techniques. To our knowledge, there have been no attempts in literature to examine the long run relationship between the CA and the RER. We find that there exists a negative long run equilibrium cointegration relationship between the CA and the RER, which is consistent with theory. The results moreover support our first hypothesis that the RER is an important factor in determining the movement of the CA. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides some theoretical background and a brief literature review. Section 3 introduces the event study analysis and presents results. Section 4 specifies the VECM, and presents estimation results and analysis. Section 5 concludes. 2 Theoretical Background and Literature Review The theory surrounding adjustment to CA imbalances in open economies has a long history, starting most notably with the price-specific-flow adjustment mechanism under the gold standard developed by David Hume in the 18th century. Since then there have been many developments including the work of Viner (1937), Meade (1951), Friedman (1953), Mundell Page 4 of 45 (1962) Dornbusch (1976), and Branson (1983), leading up to the Redux model of Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995). In all of these models, the RER moves to facilitate adjustment to a CA imbalance, regardless of whether the nominal exchange rate regime is permanently fixed, flexible or intermediate. For example, following a shock to external demand that creates a CA surplus, the RER will appreciate either through nominal exchange rate appreciation or through a rise in domestic inflation, thus reducing competitiveness and slowing exports, while favoring imports. The main channel through which RER helps bring about CA adjustment is through a relative price change that causes an “expenditure-switching” effect captured by the IS curve in the variations of the traditional Fleming-Mundell model. The “expenditure-switching” mechanism retains its validity in the Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995) model provided that nominal prices are fixed in the producer country and the exchange rate pass-through is complete.4 Milton Friedman (1953) argued in favor of flexible exchange rate regimes, based on the fact that, in a world with sticky prices, the nominal exchange rate would adjust in response to external real shocks and thus insulate the domestic economy. Friedman noted that in a world with sticky prices the speed at which relative prices adjust depends crucially on the exchange rate regime. Since then, a number of theories have confirmed his original intuition and it has become one of the least disputed arguments in favor of flexible exchange rate regimes (see Dornbusch (1980) for direct descendants of the open economy Mundell–Fleming models with sticky prices; see Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996) and Corsetti and Pesenti (2001) for dynamic general equilibrium models with nominal stickiness.) In the Mundell-Fleming-Dornbusch model, floating exchange rates are superior to fixed exchange rates when real shocks are the dominant source of disturbance to the economy.5 Under a fixed exchange rate regime, money demand shocks are fully and automatically eliminated by foreign exchange rate intervention, thus leaving the real economy unaffected. In contrast, following a real shock, domestic goods’ money prices have to bear the entire burden 4 Note that the J-curve implies that there might be an initial deterioration of the CA following a real depreciation because the Marshall-Lerner condition may not hold in the short run. A real depreciation initially causes imports to be more expensive and exports less expensive, and, if volumes are predetermined, will reduce the CA. After a while, though, the volume of exports will start to rise because of their lower more competitive prices, causing the demand for exports to pick up and domestic consumers to switch their expenditure to domestic products and away from expensive imported goods and services. Eventually, the CA should rise. 5 See Obstfeld and Rogoff (1997) Page 5 of 45 of downward adjustment. Because these are sticky, the economy reaches its new long-run equilibrium only gradually. The opposite is true for floating exchange rate regimes: following a real shock, the adjustment to a new equilibrium is immediate, reached by an appreciation of the nominal exchange rate, which eliminates the need for a change in the nominal price level. An empirical implication of these theories is that the adjustment of external imbalances across exchange rate regimes should differ. In particular, regimes that allow for faster movements in the RER should allow a faster adjustment to external imbalances such as large CA deficits. Under a flexible regime, the RER and relative prices can adjust immediately through changes in the nominal exchange rate, while under fixed regimes the changes happen at the rate permitted by the nominal stickiness, which is usually much slower and often more painful in terms of lost employment and output or much higher inflation (Dornbusch, 1980). Therefore, flexible regimes should allow quicker relative price adjustments and thus a faster resolution of CA imbalances. Although theoretical models are based on RERs, there is limited evidence on our first hypothesis. Only few researchers link the RER to the adjustment process of real variables (e.g. Lee and Chinn, 2002). Arghyrou and Chortareas (2008) address the question of CA adjustment and the role of the RER using a vector error correction model. In particular, the authors focus on the diverging CAs of the individual euro area countries, dynamics of CA adjustment, and the role of the RER. They find that the RER has a substantial impact on CA adjustment but that this relationship subject to nonlinear effects. Freund and Warnock (2005) use an event study approach to examine episodes of CA adjustment in industrial countries. They first determine periods of CA deficit reversals using criteria set up in Freund (2000), and then examine the behavior of key variables during the reversal. Among other results, they find that CA adjustment tends to be associated with slow income growth and a real depreciation. With respect to the second hypothesis, the literature has suggested methods to classify exchange rate regimes (e.g. Reinhart and Rogoff, 2004, and Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger, Page 6 of 45 2005)6 and the importance of exchange rate regimes for external stability. Chinn and Wei (2008), for instance, examine the importance of the nominal exchange rate regime for the adjustment process of the CA and find there is no robust relationship between the exchange rate regime and the rate of CA reversion.7 Moreover do not find a strong monotonic relationship between flexibility of a nominal exchange regime and the speed of convergence in RERs. However, these conclusions are somewhat misleading because they assume that speedier adjustment is in all cases associated with less costly adjustment. In practice, CA adjustment under fixed exchange rate regimes does not occur via the classical adjustment process. Most often countries running CA deficits adjust through exchange rate crises or forced devaluations which are associated with large employment and output losses. Moreover, their reduced form regressions mask a large endogeneity problem and omit important control variables, including the degree of wages and price flexibility and frequency and impact of exchange rate crises. Broda (2002) empirically assesses the Friedman hypothesis that a flexible nominal exchange rate will help insulate domestic output to external real shocks. He analyzes the responses of real GDP, RERs, and prices to terms of trade shocks and finds that responses are significantly different across exchange rate regimes. He finds that countries with more flexible regimes tend to have small real GDP losses and immediate large real depreciations. In contrast, countries with fixed regimes experience large and significant declines in real GDP, and the RER depreciates slowly by means of a fall in prices. Few authors even argue that the nominal exchange rate regime does not matter at all.8 3 Empirical Methodology To study the relationship between the CA and the RER, we first look at simple correlations. Then, following Freund and Warnock (2005), we use an event study approach to assess the 6 Reinhart and Rogoff (2004), for instance, question the IMF classification and develop a system of reclassifying historical exchange rate regimes, employing monthly data on market-determined parallel exchange rates. LevyYeyati and Sturzenegger (2002) construct a de facto classification based on data on exchange rates and international reserves. 7 The authors use the results of Reinhart and Rogoff (2004) to determine the importance of the exchange rate regime for the adjustment process of the CA. 8 For instance, Helpman (1981) Page 7 of 45 behavior of the RER in periods of CA reversions. Lastly, we use VECMs to examine the role of RER flexibility in CA adjustment. 3.1 Data and descriptive statistics We use data on the RER, CA, and a number of control variables from a variety of sources (listed in Table 1-3). Most data is quarterly.9 If only yearly data are available for a certain time period, we calculate missing quarterly data using linear interpolation for RER and the CA. We use the real effective exchange rate (REER) which is defined as the weighted average of the indexed bilateral exchange rates (trade weighted with main trading partners), adjusted by relative consumer prices.10 The RER is indexed to 100 for 2001:4, and an increase in the RER corresponds to a real appreciation. Data availability reduces our pool to 21 EMEs; from 1975 to 2008.11 For comparison, we also look at the G7 countries for which data availability allows a larger sample. Chart 1 provides an illustration of the CA and the RER for the countries included in our sample. Consistent with our theoretical priors, CA reversals have generally been associated with large exchange rate movements. For instance, Argentina’s CA reversed from a deficit of about 3% in 2001Q1 to a surplus of 10% by the end of 2002, which was accompanied by a RER depreciation of 60%. Likewise, the deterioration of Mexico’s CA from a surplus of about 1.5% in 1987 to a deficit of 6% in 2003 was accompanied by a RER appreciation of 78%. Table 4 shows that the correlations between the main variables with the RER have the expected sign. The correlation of the RER with the CA is negative – implying that an appreciation is generally associated with a deterioration of the CA. This result is also consistent with findings in the CA crisis literature. The correlation is more pronounced for EMEs – we interpret the low correlation in G7 countries due to the fact that G7 countries’ CA might be determined to a larger extent by other variables. The link between income growth and the CA is not clear. In simple open economy models (e.g. Mundell-Fleming), and increase in income is associated with higher spending on imported goods, and thus a deterioration of the CA. We should thus expect a negative sign, however, this is only so for G7 countries. For robustness, we also look at some control variables that have been used in the literature on CA 9 Quarterly data for the CA and the government balance has been seasonally adjusted. For simplicity, we will continue denoting the real exchange rate by RER, referring to the REER. 11 The sample period is smaller for some countries due to missing data. 10 Page 8 of 45 determination. The government balance is positively correlated with the CA – mirroring the fact that a fiscal expansion (i.e. a deterioration of the budget balance) could lead to higher interest rates and in the presence of capital inflows an appreciation of the domestic currency may occur which increases the CA deficit. Chart 2 plots volatility of the CA vs. volatility of the RER – there seems to be a positive relationship between the flexibility of the RER and the variability of the CA, suggesting some evidence for our first hypothesis. To address the question whether RER flexibility is associated with nominal exchange rate flexibility, we plot volatility of both in Chart 3. Nominal exchange rate flexibility seems to be associated, to a reasonable degree, with RER flexibility. However, the correlation between the two ranges from -.58 in Turkey to .99 in Malaysia (Chart 4). A negagive correlation between the nominal exchange rate and RER movements implies that nominal exchange rate movements are not trading closely differences in inflation rates as relative purchasing power parity would suggest. 3.2 Event study approach As mentioned above, theory suggests that CA improvements are associated with a RER depreciation, and CA deterioration with RER appreciation. To examine the validity of this hypothesis empirically, we first apply Freund and Warnock’s (2005) event study to our set of EMEs. This kind of analysis is not new – for instance, Algieri and Bracke (2007) apply Freund and Warnock’s methodology to a larger set of countries, including some EMEs. However, we repeat and extend this exercise here for our set of countries to yield new insights about the role of RER adjustment for CA adjustments for different groups of EMEs. In particular, we distinguish between crisis and non crisis periods, and between fixed exchange rate regimes and floating regimes at the time of the reversal. Moreover, we also analyze CA surplus reversals. We then evaluate the behavior of output growth and RER movements, the two main contributors to CA adjustment according to the existing literature (see Algieri and Bracke, 2007, for a summary) in periods of CA reversion. In a first step, we determine CA reversal periods for our sample. The criteria for a CA reversal are: 1) The CA deficit (surplus)-GDP ratio exceeded two percent before the reversal. Page 9 of 45 2) The average deficit (surplus)-GDP ratio was reduced by at least two percentage points over three years (from the minimum to the centered three year average). 3) The CA deficit (surplus)-GDP ratio was reduced by at least one third. 4) The maximum deficit (surplus)-GDP ratio in the five years after the reversal was not larger than the minimum in the three years before the reversal. The first three criteria ensure that large CA reversals are captured, whereas the fourth ensures that the reversal was sustained, i.e. the change in the data was not only due to some heightened volatility. 3.2.1 CA deficit reversals Using these criteria on data for our set of EME countries from 1975-2008, we identify 55 episodes of CA deficit adjustment in 21 countries, listed in Table 5. Chart 5 documents the pattern of adjustment across the CA, the RER, and GDP growth, with event time 0 corresponding to the year the CA balance is most negative. On average, the CA deficit stood at -6.6% of GDP at the time of reversal, which is very close to the average reported by Freund and Warnock (2005), although their sample only includes industrialized countries. In our sample, there is considerable variation across episodes, ranging from relatively small deficits (e.g. Argentina with 2% in 1980) to over 13% in Ecuador in 1998. During these periods, the CA improved by an average of 6.2 percentage points within the 3 years following the start of the episode. In the majority of cases, patterns of real GDP growth and the RER movements are consistent with theory and other findings of the literature: in 70% of the cases, the RER depreciated in the three years following the start of the reversal. On average (for all identified periods), the RER depreciated by 6.35%. However, in all 60 cases, countries experienced a total depreciation12 around the time of the CA reversal, of, on average, 31%. These results provide ample proof that CA deficit reversals have been accompanied by currency depreciation, and that this depreciation is large. This result is consistent with findings in the literature, although the adjustment of the RER for EMEs seems to be more pronounced. Freund (2005) for instance 12 Total depreciation is defined as the percentage change between the maximum value of the RER in the three years leading up to the reversal minus the minimum value of the RER in the three years following the reversal. Page 10 of 45 finds that, in industrialized countries, CA deficit reversals are accompanied by a real depreciation of about 10 to 20 percent. Moreover, there seems to be a positive correlation between the size of the CA reversal (within 3 years) and the size of the total depreciation in that period (Chart 6). Further, in 70% of all episodes, CA reversals have been accompanied by a decrease in real GDP growth, by an average of 1.6 percentage points. The fall seems to be in line with previous findings (Algieri and Bracke, 2007), and is consistent with theoretical priors. We examine whether there is evidence of a trade off between adjustment though GDP or through depreciation. Freund and Warnock (2005) argue that, restricted exchange rate adjustment leads to lower income growth during CA recovery. In particular, income growth is forced to accommodate CA adjustment precisely because RER depreciation is not sufficiently large to facilitate the CA adjustment. Indeed, we also find an inverse correlation between the extent of exchange rate adjustment and the slowdown in GDP growth (Chart 7). There is a clear tradeoff: adjustment comes through either RER movements or GDP growth. If exchange rates movements are limited, the CA position worsens further and the GDP reduction is more extreme. Thus RER flexibility is critical to low-cost (in terms of output cost) CA adjustment. Most of the countries in our sample have experienced currency and/or debt crises; these may magnify the results.13 We therefore split the sample into crisis (26) and non-crisis (32) periods (Chart 8).14 Not surprisingly, during crisis periods, the CA reverts faster and by more (7.9 pp within 3 years), and is accompanied by a much stronger currency depreciation (15% in 3 years, and 34% over the period as a whole). Also, GDP contracts substantially more during crisis periods (2.54 pp). To yield insight on our second hypothesis, we split the sample of CA deficit reversals into floating and fixed exchange rate regimes at the time of the reversal. To classify episodes, we use the classification compiled by Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger (2005) for the specific countries at the time of the CA reversal. Their classification seems to better capture de facto ER regimes compared to de jure regime classification such as in the IMF’s official ER 13 Note that the periods determined in table 5 include crisis periods as well as periods of “normal” reversion of CA imbalances. 14 To determine crisis periods, we have to rely on several studies to determine crisis periods for all countries in our sample: Frankel and Cavallo (2004) and Kaminsky (2003), Calvo and Reinhart (2000), and Calvo, Izquierdo, and Mejía (2004). Crisis periods determined in different papers for the same country overlap significantly. Page 11 of 45 classification, published annually in its Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions.15 Some interesting results emerge (Chart 9): First, CA reversals occur earlier in countries with fixed ER regimes, at a CA deficit to GDP ratio of 5.2% compared to 6.5% for floaters. Despite the deeper trough, the adjustment of the CA in floating ER regimes occurs faster, suggesting that flexible ER regimes allow for faster resolution of external imbalances. Second, significant RER depreciation precedes CA reversal in fixed exchange rate regimes, with continuing sizeable depreciation during the reversal. This suggests that despite the fixed nominal rate, adjustment has to come through the RER – in most cases through a crisis and the collapse of the fixed ER regime. This adjustment through the RER is larger than in the case for floaters. And most importantly, the cost in terms of GDP is significantly larger in countries with fixed exchange rate regimes: GDP drops from an average of 8.2% two quarters before the reversal to -.2% a year after the reversal, compared to a drop from 5.8 to 0.7% in floating regimes. This suggests that adjustment of external imbalances is more painful given limited nominal ER flexibility. The results support our second hypothesis that flexible ER regimes facilitate the maintenance of external stability through a rapid adjustment of external imbalances. Moreover, countries with fixed exchange rate regimes only allow CA adjustment through large depreciation and large losses in GDP growth, thus through much more painful adjustment. 3.2.2 CA surplus reversals Using the above mentioned criteria we determine 30 CA surplus reversal periods (Table 6). The results are broadly symmetric to the analysis of CA deficit reversals. On average, the surplus stood at 7.8% and fell by 8.9pp within 3 years (Chart 5). During these periods, the CA improved by an average of 6.2 percentage points within the 3 years following the start of the episode. Again, there is considerable variation across episodes, ranging from relatively small surpluses (e.g. Bolivia with 2% in 1990Q4) to 20% in Russia in 2002Q2. Within 3 years following the peak, the RER appreciated in 80% of the periods determined. The average appreciation (including all periods) was large: 20% on average. In all episodes, the RER appreciated in the 6 years around the reversal, by an average of 64%. Again, these results 15 For a discussion of de facto and de jure exchange rate regime classification, please refer to Bailliu, Lafrance and Perrault (2003). Page 12 of 45 provide ample evidence for our first hypothesis (that CA adjustments are facilitated by RER movements), and that RER movements are quite large. Consistent with theory, GDP growth increased during these periods (in 80% of all periods), by an average of 1.7pp (average over all periods). We can again split our sample into countries that followed a fixed exchange rate regime at the time of the reversal, and those that let their currency float (Chart 10). 16 On average, CA surpluses revert earlier in floating regimes (at 7% of GDP compared to 9% for fixers), suggesting that fixed ER regime countries retard the adjustment of the CA. The major contributing factor to CA reversion in fixed ER regime countries is rapid output growth – suggesting that nominal ER rigidity impedes an adjustment through the RER. As for floaters, both RER appreciation and GDP growth contribute to the adjustment process. The results seem to again provide some evidence for our second hypothesis: the RER does not adjust in fixed ER regimes; the adjustment has thus to come through GDP growth, and to a much larger extent than for floaters. 3.3 Vector Error Correction Model approach To analyze the long run relationship between the CA and the RER, we use a VECM approach because the series are integrated, and the VECM allows the estimation of a cointegrating relationship without imposing a causal relationship between two endogenous variables. The main advantage of a VECM specification in the context of our research is that it allows empirical estimation of the long run relationship between the CA and the RER, as well as to 16 Note that the sample size for this table is very small (4 fixed ER regimes and 10 floating ER regimes), and drawing conclusions should be treated with respective caution. Page 13 of 45 determine the reversion speed of the CA.17 A second advantage of the VEC model framework is that it allows feedback effects between the variables.18 3.3.1 Integration and cointegration A first step is to test for the stationary of the individual variables. In this paper, we apply the standard Augmented Dickey-Fuller test to determine the level of integration. The results (Tables 1-3) reject the hypothesis that the series are stationary, thereby implying that the variables are, in general, I (1). In Bolivia, China, and Israel the RER is stationary. The presence of unit roots leads us to test for cointegration. We use both the λ-max and the Trace statistic to determine the number of cointegration relationships. Table 7 shows test results. In 11 out of 22 cases we find evidence for one cointegration relationship. The observation that the CA and the RER do not cointegrate for a number of countries can be explained by several factors. First, for some countries, this might be due to the omitted variable problem, an issue which we address in section 3.3.4. Second, the CA and RER might not adjust as expected in theory because policies impede an adjustment of either variable. For instance, in countries with fixed exchange regimes and sticky and/or regulated prices, the RER is likely to be inflexible, and therefore would impede an adjustment of the RER to its long run equilibrium value. This is likely the reason why China’s CA and RER do not cointegrate. Similarly, we find no cointegration for Malaysia, India, and Thailand, all of which heavily intervene in their currency markets. Sterilization may also be a reason why the CA does not adjust, as policies in these countries do not allow a full adjustment of their RER.19 Given our theoretical priors, we accept the evidence of one cointegrating vector for all our countries. 17 An alternative measure of the adjustment speed of the CA could be the size of the mean reverting coefficient (e.g. Chinn and Wei 2008). However, the autoregressive coefficient on the CA might be influenced by the number of shocks that a country experiences and therefore seems to fail to distinguish between rapid adjustments that result from flexible policies as opposed to low persistence which results from the absence of shocks. 18 Note that a reduced form regression would estimate the effect of a depreciation of the exchange rate on the CA, given by the partial derivative derivative 19 ∂CA . The VECM allows to capture feedback effects, represented by the total ∂REER dCA . dREER See Lavigne (2008) “Sterilized Intervention in Emerging-Market Economies: Trends, Costs, and Risks”, Bank of Canada Discussion Paper 2008-04. Page 14 of 45 3.3.2 Specifying a Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) We now specify a vector error correction model (VECM). A VEC model is a restricted VAR designed for use with non-stationary series that are known to be cointegrated. The VECM has cointegrating relations built into the specification so that it restricts the long-run behavior of the endogenous variables to converge to their cointegrating relationships while allowing for short-run adjustment dynamics. Given that the data is quarterly, the model is estimated with three lags of each variable: Equation 1 2 2 ΔCAt = α CA (CAt −1 − β RERt −1 ) + ∑ λ1,i ΔCAt −i + ∑ λ2,i ΔRERt −i + ε 1, t i =1 i =1 2 2 i =1 i =1 ΔRERt = α RER (CAt −1 − β RERt −1 ) + ∑ λ3,i ΔRERt −i + ∑ λ 4,i ΔCAt −i + ε 1, t . β specifies the long-run equilibrium relationship between the CA and the RER, whereas αCA and αRER measure the speed of adjustment of the CA and the RER, respectively. In the long run, the CA should return to the level compatible with the level of the RER: CAt = β RERt The cointegrating relationship is stationary and can be interpreted as an equation for the longterm relationship of the CA and the RER. We should expect β to be negative. A real depreciation (a decrease in the RER) increases exports because of their lower more competitive prices, causing the demand for exports to pick up and domestic consumers to switch their expenditure to domestic products and away from expensive imported goods and services. Table 8 gives the estimated cointegrating vectors for the countries, normalized on CAt.20 A negative value for αCA indicates that disequilibrium between the observed values for the CA and its equilibrium moves observed CA toward the equilibrium value implied by the cointegration relationship. The CA short-term variations can be more or less persistent depending upon the value of αCA. For instance, a value of αCA near 0 will lead to very persistent adjustment dynamics. 20 Given that the order of the variables in the VECM does not matter, we put the CA first, meaning that the coefficient on in the cointegrating vector on the CA is 1. Page 15 of 45 3.3.3 Results We first examine the long-run relationship between the CA and the RER. The CA and the RER are negatively cointegrated for 18 out of 22 cases (Table 7), and thus β has the expected sign (Chart 11). The β coefficient on the RER is highly statistically significant in 13 out of 18 of these cases. The results provide some evidence for the negative long term relation between the CA and the RER, and thus support our hypothesis that RER movements are associated with CA adjustment. The result is moreover consistent with findings by Arghyrou and Chortareas (2008), although these authors focus only on European countries. This result holds despite the fact that our sample includes periods of crisis – an interpretation of the negative coefficient is that adjustment of the CA takes place through RER depreciation, whether it is as a result of financial crisis or through a smooth adjustment. There is a wide dispersion in the size of the coefficient: it ranges from 0.06 Brazil to 0.41 in Malaysia. In few cases, the sign of the coefficient is counterintuitive: for instance, for China, the long term relation between the RER and the CA is positive and statistically significant – which might be attributed to factors mentioned above. This finding might also capture important aspects of China’s development strategy of export-led growth. The lack of significance of the long run parameter for some countries might be attributed to the fact that the RER on its own can not explain the reversion of the CA – such as in Mexico. The inclusion of additional variables addresses this problem in most cases (see next section). Moreover, there might be a lag in the volume adjustment in response to a change in exchange rate, as stipulated by the J-curve, suggesting that the contemporaneous relationship between the RER and the CA is small, but that the RER affects the CA over time. We now turn to the short run dynamics of our regression. Deviations from the CI relationship can be corrected through the adjustment of the CA, and/or the adjustment of the RER. We concentrate here only on the speed of adjustment of the CA, αCA:21 it is negative and statistically significant in 20 out of 22 countries, indicating that the CA responds significantly to the past deviations (Table 8, Chart 12). For the remaining two cases (Russia and China), the 21 The error-correction term in the RER equation, αRER, is not statistically significant for half of the countries, and even positive in some cases, meaning that there is little evidence for an adjustment of the REER towards its longterm equilibrium value. This implies that for most countries, it is the CA that adjusts to the long run equilibrium, whereas the REER is the trend variable. Page 16 of 45 coefficient is not statistically significant. The fact that the coefficient is statistically significant also implies that the RER Granger causes the CA in the long run, supporting our first hypothesis.22 The level of the adjustment speed varies considerably across countries, ranging from 0.005 in Bolivia to 0.295 in Korea. An α of 0.136 for Argentina, for instance, suggests that 13.6% of the difference between the equilibrium and observed CA is eliminated within one quarter. This corresponds to a half life of the CA of 4.74 quarters, or one year and 2 month. The average adjustment speed of 0.134 is comparable to Arghyrou and Chortareas’ (2008) findings, who find an average CA adjustment speed of 0.18 for 11 European countries, ranging from 0.058 in France to 0.490 in Greece. The interpretation of the size of this coefficient is not straightforward. Ignoring crisis periods, a higher adjustment speed would speak to the ability of a country to adjust to external imbalances. However, the adjustment of external imbalances can, and has in a large part of the cases, come through crises. Therefore, the result that the CA adjusts rapidly might be driven by the fact that these countries experienced CA crises with rapid movements in the RER and the CA (such as in the case of Korea). For other countries the adjustment speed of the CA is quite low. This observation could have several possible explanations. First, some countries have limited nominal exchange rate flexibility. Thus, the absence of nominal exchange rate adjustment may be depriving the country from a potent channel of CA adjustment. For these countries, adjustment has to come through reducing relative unit labor costs taking the form of competitive disinflations. If prices are rigid in the short run, convergence of the CA has to come through other variables than the RER, such as higher income levels. These countries may face significant CA imbalances in the event of demand shocks. Second, we may attribute slow reversion of the CA to the fact that the CA adjusts through other variables not taken account, which are more important in the reversion of the CA than the RER. The adjustment speed of the CA does not seem to be positively correlated with the flexibility of the de facto exchange rate regime. We compare the estimated error correction terms with the 22 Engle and Granger (1987) demonstrate that the results from the VECM model in Equation 1 can be used to test causation from the RER to the CA – (that is, the RER does not Granger-cause the CA if all λ2,i and αCA = 0). Besides, the VECM approach allows to distinguish between short-run and long-run Granger-causality. Long-run Granger causality can be evaluated by testing whether the coefficient of the error-correction term (i.e. αCA) is statistically different from zero by a t-test. The short run Granger causality can be evaluated by testing whether the estimated coefficients on lagged values of ΔRERt in equation 1 are jointly statistically significant. However, we are interested in the long run behaviour here and thus concentrate on the short run Granger causality test. Page 17 of 45 exchange rate classification developed by Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger (2005) (Chart 13). The average regime flexibility for a country is captured by the average over the estimation period. Whereas Korea’s CA adjusts fairly quickly according to the estimated error correction term, Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger classify this country as “intermediate” over the estimation horizon. On the other hand, CA adjustment speed in Turkey is relatively slow when estimated by the error correction term, although it has been classified as a floater for almost the whole sample period. This is potentially due to the fact that the estimated coefficient αCA does not distinguish rapid adjustment through crises or via a flexible nominal and real exchange rate. Moreover, for some countries, the RER might not be the most important contributing factor to CA adjustment, with other factors such as domestic GDP playing an important role. 3.3.4 Accounting for income growth differentials23 Theoretically, income growth differentials across countries should play an important role in the determination of the CA. On the empirical side, Arghyrou and Chortareas (2008) estimate the cointegrating relationship between the CA, the RER, and income growth differences. Following Arghyrou and Chortareas (2008), we use G7 national income as a proxy for foreign income. This measure certainly raises some concerns, as G7 national income might be better suited as a variable of foreign demand for some countries more than others. However, we think that it allows a preliminary assessment of the importance of foreign demand. We find that the GDP, GDP* (foreign demand, i.e. G7 income), CA and the RER are cointegrated in 18 out of 21 countries (the exeptions being Brazil, Russia, and Thailand).24 In some cases, we can now find a cointegration relationship where there was none when testing cointegration between the CA and the RER, which suggests that the level of income growth is an important determinant of CA reversion in these countries. Given our theoretical priors, we impose one cointegration vector in the VECM.25 23 The literature has suggested a list of variables that could be cointegrated with the RER. We test for the budget balance (cf. Afonso and Rault, 2008), terms of trade, and account for periods of crises using dummy variables. 24 Test results are not shown in order to save space. 25 Note that the log of GDP is stationary. However, Hansen and Juselius (1995) have noted that not all individual variables included in the CI regression need be I (1). To find cointegration, between non-stationary variables, only two of the variables have to be I(1). The system of variables should be chosen because of their economic relevance, and not merely for their time series properties. Page 18 of 45 Regarding the estimated cointegrating vectors (Table 9), in 13 out of 21 EMEs, the coefficients on domestic national income have the expected sign and are statistically significant in most of these cases.26 Evidence on the importance of foreign income is less evident: only in 12 out of 21 cases, the variable has the expected sign, of which only 7 are statistically significant. Interestingly, with the exception of South Africa, the absolute values of the coefficients of GDP and GDP* are lower than those of the RER, which is opposite to Arghyrou and Chortareas’ (2008) findings. This suggests that for the EMEs under analysis, RERs have been playing a more prominent role than relative incomes in long-run CA determination, whereas for European countries, relative incomes seemed to have had a bigger impact on CA determination. This result is moreover somewhat consistent with the findings in the event study analysis, which suggests that the currency depreciates more significantly in EMEs than in industrialized countries in order to facilitate CA adjustment. 4 Conclusion The lack of exchange rate adjustment is widely seen as an important contributing factor to unsustainably large global CA imbalances. In this paper we explore two related hypotheses: (i) that RER flexibility and adjustment is critical to maintaining external stability (main hypothesis) and (ii) that a flexible nominal exchange rate facilitates RER adjustment and the maintenance of external stability (corollary hypothesis). We adopt two complementary empirical methodologies. Using an event study analysis for a large set of EMEs over the 19752008 period, we find ample evidence in favor of our first hypothesis: RER adjustment is critical to reducing CA imbalances and maintaining external stability. CA revisions are accompanied by large RER movements, regardless of the exchange rate regime. However, the crucial distinction becomes how countries adjust to large CA deficits - the adjustment may come through an “orderly process” of gradual RER depreciation, or, through a crisis. Second, we find evidence for our second hypothesis that a flexible nominal ER facilitates RER adjustment and the maintenance of external stability. We find that 1) the adjustment is more painful in terms of output loss in crisis periods and for countries that had a fixed exchange rate regime at the time of the reversal, 2) the RER depreciates by more in crisis periods and for 26 The cointegrating relation coefficient on the RER remains relatively robust in most cases with respect to the specification with two variables. Page 19 of 45 countries with fixed exchange rate regimes, and 3) the CA reverts faster in crises and for floating regimes. The results suggest that fast adjustment of external imbalances can come through a flexible nominal ER, or, a crisis. Given that crises come along with higher cost in terms of output, this result suggests that a flexible ER allows a rapid but orderly adjustment of the CA which is comparatively less harmful in terms of output cost. Similarly, for CA surplus reversals, the adjustment of the CA in fixed exchange rate regimes has to come through large GDP growth movements, due to limited RER movement, whereas in floating exchange rate regimes both real GDP growth and RER depreciation contribute to the adjustment process. The result is again in line with our second hypothesis: a flexible ER regime facilitates the adjustment of the RER, and thus of the CA. Of course, these empirical findings must be interpreted with caution, as the CA, GDP, and the RER might be affected through other variables that are omitted from the analysis and could explain the differences between adjustments in fixed and flexible ER regime countries. Our vector error correction modeling confirms that the negative relationship between the RER and the CA holds in the long run. The result is consistent with our first hypothesis that CA adjustment is correlated with RER movements, regardless of the ER regime. Deviations from the long run relationships are moreover important drivers of CA reversion. In sum, our findings support recent arguments that EMEs should permit their RERs to adjust to external imbalances by eschewing efforts to sterilize the impact of these imbalances on the domestic money supply and on domestic prices and wages. EMEs could allow more nominal exchange rate flexibility in order to promote adjustment to external imbalances, thus avoiding crises and large costs in terms of output. Going forward, it would be interesting to separately identify the contribution of nominal exchange rate and price adjustment to RER flexibility, and thus CA reversion. (…). Second, our VECM analysis is based on a list of assumptions: For example, we assume exchange rate regimes to be constant over the estimation period, which is arguably too simple. It would be interesting to test for structural breaks in the estimated cointegration relationships to account for the fact that estimated coefficients change pre- and post-crisis, or before and after a country changes nominal exchange rate regime. Fujii (2002) studies a related question on PPP and argues that long run parameters in the cointegration relation do not change, but that the Page 20 of 45 adjustment speed of some Asian countries changed after the respective crisis. We could follow his methodology to allow for a shift of alpha in crisis periods. Also, it could be insightful to construct panel VECMs for our sample, grouping countries according to region and other similarities (commodity exporters/importers, EME versus G7 countries, etc.). Panels allow a more robust estimation of relevant coefficients, as the number of observation increases.27 References Afonso, António and Christophe Rault. 2008. “Budgetary and External Imbalances Relationship – A Panel Data Diagnostic.”ECB Working Paper No. 961 / November 2008 Algieri, Bernardina and Thierry Bracke. 2007. “Patterns of CA Adjustment – Insights from Past Experience.” European Central Bank Working Paper Series No 762 / June 2007 Arghyrou, Michael G. and Georgios Chortareas. 2008. “CA Imbalances and Real Exchange Rates in the Euro Area.” Review of international economics 9(5) 747-764. Bailliu, Jeannine, Robert Lafrance and Jean-Francois Perrault. 2003. "Does Exchange Rate Policy Matter for Growth?" International Finance, Winter 2003, 6 (3), p. 381-414 Broda, Christian. 2004. “Terms of Trade and Exchange Rate Regimes in Developing Countries” Journal of International Economics 63 31–58 Calderon, Cesar Augusto, Alberto Chong and Norman V Loayza. 2002. “Determinants of CA Deficits in Developing Countries”. In: Contributions to Macroeconomics Volume 2, Issue 1 2002 Article 2. Calvo, Guillermo A. and Carmen M. Reinhart. 2002. “Fixing for your Life”. NBER Working Paper 8006. Calvo, Guillermo A., Alejandro Izquierdo, and Luis-Fernando Mejía. 2004. On the Empirics of Sudden Stops: The Relevance of Balance-Sheet Effects”. NBER Working Paper 10520. Cheung, Yin-wong and Kon S. Lai. 2007. “Nominal exchange rate flexibility and RER adjustment : new evidence from dual exchange rates in developing countries.” Hong Kont Institute for monetary research. Working Paper No.9/2007 Chinn, Menzie D. and Shang-Jin Wei. 2008. “A Faith-based Initiative: Does a Flexible Exchange Rate Regime Really Facilitate CA Adjustment?” University of Wisconsin, Madison, and NBER. Chinn, Menzie D. Eswar and S. Prasad. 2003. “Medium-term determinants of CAs in industrial and developing countries: an empirical exploration.” Journal of International Economics 59 (2003) 47–76 27 However, Arghyrou and Chortareas (2008) argue that panel regressions can hide important differences in the links between RERs and CA balances across individual countries, because the structures of the economies are often very different. Page 21 of 45 Clarida, Richard, 2007, “G7 CA Imbalances: Sustainability and Adjustment?” University of Chicago Press. Dornbusch, R., 1980. Open Economy Macroeconomics Basic Books, New York. Engle, R. F. and Granger, C. W. J. 1987. “Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing. Econometrica”, Vol. 55, pp. 251-276. Frankel, Jeffrey A. and Eduardo A. Cavallo. 2004. “Does Openness to Trade Make Countries More Vulnerable to Sudden Stops, or Less? Using Gravity to Establish Causality” NBER Working Paper 10957 Freund, Caroline and Frank Warnock. 2005. “CA deficits in industrial countries: the bigger they are, the harder they fall?” NBER Working Paper 11823. Freund, Caroline. 2005. “CA Adjustment in Industrialized Countries”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 24, No. 8, pp. 1278-1298, December. Friedman. 1953. “The case for flexible exchange rates. Essays in Positive Economics” University of Chicago Press, Chicago 157–203 Fujii, Eiji. 2002. “Exchange Rate and Price Adjustments in the Aftermath of the Asian Crisis. International Journal of Finance and Economics 7: 1–14 (2002) Garcίa-Herrero, Alicia and Tuuli Koivu. 2007. “Can the Chinese trade surplus be reduced through exchange rate policy?” Bank of Finland, Institute for Economies in Transition. Discussion Papers 6/2007 Hansen, Henrik and Juselius, Katarina. 1995. “CATS in RATS: Cointegration Analysis of Time Series” Evanston: Estima. Helpman, Elhanan. 1981. “An Exploration in the Theory of Exchange Rate Regimes.” Journal of Political Economy, October 1981, 89(5), pp. 865–90. International Monetary Fund. 2007. “Bilateral Surveillance over Members' Policies Executive Board Decision” June 15, 2007. Kaminsky, Graciela L. 2003. “Varieties of Currency Crises” NBER Working Paper 10193. Lavigne, Robert, and Larry Schembri. 2009. “Strengthening IMF Surveillance: An Assessment of Recent Reforms” Bank of Canada Discussion Paper. Forthcoming Lee, Jaewoo and Menzie D. Chinn. 2002. “CA and RER dynamics in the G7 countries”’ International Monetary Fund, Working paper 02/130 Levy-Yeyati, Eduardo and Federico Sturzenegger. 2005. “Classifying Exchange Rate Regimes: Deeds vs. Words” European Economic Review, European Economic Review 49 1603 – 1635 Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff. 1994. “Exchange rate dynamics redux“ Journal of Political Economy (1995) 103, 624-60. --------1996. Foundations of international macroeconomics MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Obstfeld, Maurice. 2001. “Mundell-Fleming Lecture- International Macroeconomics: Beyond the Mundell-Fleming Model”. IMF Staff Papers Vol. 47, Special Issue. Page 22 of 45 Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2004. “The modern history of exchange rate arrangements: a reinterpretation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. CXIX February 2004 Issue 1 Ricci, Luca Antonio, Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, and Jaewoo Lee. 2008. “Real Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A Cross-Country Perspective” IMF Working Paper 08/13. Page 23 of 45 Annex 4.1 Tables Table 1 CA Data Country Argentina Bolivia Brazil Canada Chile China Columbia Czech Republic Germany Ecuador France United Kingdom Hungary Indonesia India Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source 1976-1992 Annual World Bank 1977-1994 Annual World Bank 1975-1990 Annual World Bank 1970-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1975-1995 Annual World Bank 1980-2005 Annual IIF 1970-1995 Annual World Bank 1990-1992 Annual IIF 1971-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-1992, 20032008 Annual IIF 1975-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1970-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-1994 Annual IIF 1980-1989 Annual IIF 1975-1995 Annual World Bank Page 24 of 45 1992-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1995-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1991-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS Integration I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% 1996-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 2006-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1996-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1993-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 5% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% 1993-2002 I(0) at 1% Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(0) at 5% 1995-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1990-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1996-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(0) at 1% Israel Italy Japan Korea Malaysia Mexico Peru Philippines Poland Russia Thailand Turkey United States South Africa Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source 1970-1971 Annual World Bank 1971-2008 Quarterly OECD 1977-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1976-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1975-1998 Annual World Bank 1981-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1977 Annual World Bank 1977-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-1999 Annual IIF 1992-1996 Annual IIF 1975-1992 Annual World Bank 1974-1986 Annual World Bank 1973-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1970-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS Page 25 of 45 1972-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(0) at 5% I(0) at 5% 1999-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(0) at 5% 1978-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% 2000-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1997-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1993-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1987-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(0) at 5% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 5% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% Table 2: RER data Country Argentina Bolivia Brazil Canada Chile China Columbia Czech Republic Germany Ecuador France United Kingdom Hungary Indonesia India Israel Italy Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source 1980-1993 Annual IIF 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-1993 Annual IIF 1975-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-1989 Annual IIF 1975-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1975-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-1993 Annual IIF 1980-1993 Annual IIF 1975-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS Page 26 of 45 1994-2008 Quarterly BIS Integration I(1) at 1% I(0) at 1% 1994-2008 Quarterly BIS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(0) at 5% I(1) at 1% 1990-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(0) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(0) at 10% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% 1994-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1994-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(0) at 1% I(1) at 1% Japan Korea Malaysia Mexico Morocco Peru Philippines Poland Russia Thailand Turkey United States South Africa Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-1993 Annual IIF 1975-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-1993 Annual IIF 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1970-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1975-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1981-1993 Annual IIF 1994-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1994-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1975-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% 1994-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% 1994-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(0) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% 1994-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% Table 3 : GDP by Country Country Argentina Bolivia Brazil Time Frame 1981-1990 Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Annual IMF IFS 1970-2008 Annual IMF IFS 1970-1990 Annual IMF IFS Page 27 of 45 1970-1980, 19912008 Quarterly IMF IFS Integration I(1) at 1% I(0) at 1% 1991-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% Canada Chile China Columbia Czech Republic Germany Ecuador France United Kingdom Hungary Indonesia India Israel Italy Japan Korea Malaysia Mexico Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency 1970-2008 Quarterly OECD 1970-1979 Annual IMF IFS 1970-2008 Annual IMF IFS 1970-2008 Annual IMF IFS 1995-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1970-2008 Quarterly OECD 1970-2008 Annual IMF IFS 1970-2008 Quarterly OECD 1970-2008 Quarterly OECD 1970-1995 Annual IMF IFS 19700-1993 Annual IMF IFS 1970-2000 Annual IIF 1970-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1970-2008 Quarterly OECD 1970-2008 Quarterly OECD 1970-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1970-1988 Annual IMF IFS 1970-1980 Annual Page 28 of 45 I(1) at 1% 1980-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(0) at 5% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(0) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(0) at 10% I(1) at 1% 1996-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1994-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 2001-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(0) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% 1989-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1981-2008 Quarterly I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Time Frame Frequency Source Morocco Peru Philippines Poland Russia Thailand Turkey United States South Africa IMF IFS 1970-2008 Annual IMF IFS 1970-2008 Annual IMF IFS 1970-1981 Annual IMF IFS 1981-1995 Annual IMF IFS 1996-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1970-1983 Annual IMF IFS 1970-1987 Annual IMF IFS 1970-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1970-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS IMF IFS I(0) at 1% I(1) at 1% 1982-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1996-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% 1984-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS 1988-2008 Quarterly IMF IFS I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% I(1) at 1% Table 4: Correlations CA RER GG GDP All countries -0.1026 0.132059 0.022486 G7 -0.01851 0.172019 -0.01768 EMEs -0.0969 0.130847 0.052265 CA stands for CA, RER for the real effective exchange rate, and GG for government balance. Table 5 : List of CA deficit adjustment episodes and main characteristics Country Date Started Argentina Argentina Bolivia Bolivia Bolivia Brazil Brazil 1980Q4 1998Q1 1981Q4 1987Q4 1998Q2 1982Q4 2001Q1 CA Deficit At Beginning -2.05 -5.16 -7.92 -9.29 -9.81 -5.77 -4.71 Change in CA (3 Years) Change in RER from t0 to t3 2.51 1.95 5.75 11.34 5.81 5.57 6.03 Page 29 of 45 -66.34 8.70 99.65 -20.27 0.77 -35.00 -16.72 Change in ER (Max to Min) Change in Average GDP Growth -66.34 -16.02 -69.47 -88.51 -15.04 -35.00 -57.05 -3.79 -3.84 -3.99 4.60 -1.95 -0.50 0.45 Chile Chile China Columbia Columbia Czech Rep. Czech Rep. Ecuador Ecuador Ecuador Ecuador Hungary Hungary Hungary Indonesia Indonesia Indonesia India India Israel Israel Israel S. Korea S. Korea S. Korea Malaysia Malaysia Mexico Mexico Mexico Peru Peru Peru Philippines Philippines Poland Poland Poland Russia Thailand Thailand Thailand Turkey Turkey Turkey S. Africa S. Africa S. Africa 1984Q2 1997Q4 1985Q4 1983Q1 1997Q4 1997Q1 2003Q4 1980Q4 1987Q4 1998Q3 2001Q2 1978Q4 1987Q1 1994Q3 1983Q4 1995Q4 2004Q1 1990Q4 1998Q1 1985Q1 1994Q2 2000Q4 1980Q1 1991Q1 1997Q1 1982Q4 1995Q4 1981Q4 1994Q4 2001Q1 1981Q4 1995Q4 1997Q3 1982Q4 1997Q4 1978Q4 1993Q4 1999Q4 1998Q1 1983Q2 1995Q3 2005Q2 1980Q4 1986Q1 1993Q4 1976Q1 1982Q1 1997Q1 -7.90 -7.91 -4.10 -7.85 -5.45 -8.19 -7.89 -5.43 -10.68 -13.89 -4.25 -7.55 -5.56 -10.50 -8.36 -2.68 -3.21 -3.02 -2.79 -5.41 -7.69 -3.31 -10.99 -3.67 -5.20 -13.24 -9.56 -6.44 -7.06 -3.13 -6.69 -8.84 -6.29 -8.64 -6.13 -10.84 -4.70 -7.38 -4.56 -4.99 -10.06 -8.34 -6.03 -2.06 -3.26 -8.72 -9.53 -2.34 3.26 5.20 2.87 4.44 6.52 3.93 4.46 4.51 7.19 11.70 2.91 4.37 1.97 6.62 4.19 6.46 5.56 2.60 2.54 5.47 4.06 4.80 5.50 2.87 7.07 11.22 23.42 8.85 5.15 2.45 7.07 5.40 4.93 8.49 2.20 4.85 2.58 4.79 20.25 3.30 20.85 12.45 2.25 3.56 2.25 15.15 11.52 1.59 Page 30 of 45 -38.90 -11.53 -14.42 -35.22 -17.09 4.62 14.35 2.46 0.30 -6.44 15.33 -9.18 -0.71 4.75 -22.25 -34.91 13.81 -8.00 0.89 -2.08 10.19 -17.95 -1.82 -5.23 -12.36 -4.09 -20.63 -27.93 -4.60 -8.15 2.34 -1.49 -7.74 -15.02 -17.73 -15.66 22.76 15.33 -26.43 -16.14 -12.72 19.34 -10.83 -15.95 10.40 17.27 -19.82 -11.21 -56.07 -14.20 -53.39 -37.13 -27.93 -22.60 -24.04 -19.37 -57.38 -50.34 -54.17 -3.31 -22.73 -14.59 -25.39 -64.43 -38.14 -12.09 -11.09 -18.66 -11.91 -20.79 -4.60 -19.20 -39.96 -17.30 -27.81 -38.15 -47.55 -29.48 -26.66 -16.05 -12.99 -29.15 -32.76 -38.28 -47.73 -27.55 -44.89 -17.00 -34.74 -18.30 -11.62 -25.78 -27.50 -19.91 -27.93 -24.27 7.00 -5.24 -1.47 4.33 -5.22 -8.98 2.53 -3.99 0.13 -2.64 4.81 -3.31 1.83 6.73 -1.17 -6.59 0.87 -2.34 -1.18 3.27 -0.20 -4.13 -4.60 -1.67 -5.01 -2.22 -5.79 -8.40 -1.06 -4.21 -6.42 -2.41 -5.49 -7.82 -2.60 0.05 10.94 -2.21 4.90 0.76 -0.45 -4.17 2.45 -0.17 -9.48 -2.16 -4.23 -1.68 Average Crisis Non crisis -6.67 -6.62 -6.74 6.26 7.90 5.44 -6.35 -15.24 1.32 -31.17 -34.27 -28.15 -1.58 -2.54 -0.86 Table 6: List of CA surplus adjustment episodes and main characteristics Arg Bol Bra Chn Col Cze Ecu Idn Ind Isr Kor Mal Mex Per Phl Pol Rus Thl Zaf Average 28 28 1989Q4 2002Q3 1990Q4 2004Q2 1991Q1 1997Q4 1991Q4 1991Q4 2000Q1 2001Q1 2004Q2 1985Q3 1989Q3 1976Q3 1988Q1 1998Q1 2004Q1 1987Q4 1999Q3 1983Q4 1987Q4 1979Q4 1986Q4 1990Q4 2000Q2 2005Q2 1998Q1 2001Q2 1980Q1 1987Q3 Identified CA 6.56 11.25 2.05 2.06 3.29 3.91 5.21 5.29 14.55 4.78 3.08 16.63 2.59 6.96 9.15 15.72 4.68 7.94 17.68 3.96 3.06 4.61 3.13 5.66 20.25 12.49 14.35 5.56 11.90 6.78 0.08 Deterioration Over 3 Years in CA -8.38 -7.04 -9.12 -1.30 -4.40 -2.19 -9.81 -8.29 -19.22 -7.99 -4.62 -20.62 -6.01 -19.96 -12.82 -12.88 -4.05 -9.95 -10.89 -5.00 -5.89 -10.83 -6.61 -10.36 -12.20 -5.91 -11.68 -2.82 -10.13 -6.70 -0.09 Percent Appreciation from peak to Year 3 143.11 14.99 5.34 54.56 -23.38 -1.23 41.75 25.24 117.52 29.62 9.07 9.60 2.99 -36.54 21.61 32.36 23.69 -11.90 3.99 -14.36 38.34 9.00 1.12 54.43 33.47 23.29 9.13 2.15 12.82 -3.44 19.79 Excluding the Poland 1990 period which significantly amplifies the averages. Page 31 of 45 Total appreciation around 6 year range 143.11 169.66 28.61 89.17 108.70 33.02 46.99 74.50 118.20 113.67 14.23 22.94 24.87 104.63 28.38 66.56 30.15 55.65 38.53 88.78 49.59 41.68 49.30 1277.67 81.44 51.97 53.23 14.00 52.77 58.17 63.88 Change in Growth Rates (Before/After) 3.68 11.33 0.51 2.52 3.96 -2.70 0.84 1.85 6.64 3.52 1.80 1.48 -17.42 -0.53 -3.25 0.05 6.51 3.62 -1.61 3.52 3.75 9.82 -3.28 4.37 0.92 0.01 6.07 0.90 1.68 1.92 Table 7: Cointegration test (CA and RER)29 Trace Test Hypothesized Trace No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue ARG Statistic Maximum Eigenvalue Test 0.05 Hypothesized Critical Value Prob.** No. of CE(s) Max-Eigen Eigenvalue Statistic 0.05 Critical Value Prob.** None * 0.108162 16.59607 15.49471 0.0340 None 0.108162 12.24831 14.26460 0.1017 At most 1 * 0.039819 4.347752 3.841466 0.0371 At most 1 * 0.039819 4.347752 3.841466 0.0371 BOL None 0.086803 9.814474 15.49471 0.2953 None 0.086803 9.715976 14.26460 0.2313 BRA None * 0.107752 18.63310 15.49471 0.0163 None 0.107752 12.19915 14.26460 0.1034 At most 1 * 0.058358 6.433942 3.841466 0.0112 At most 1 * 0.058358 6.433942 3.841466 0.0112 None * 0.080075 16.37675 15.49471 0.0368 None 0.080075 9.097476 14.26460 0.2781 At most 1 * 0.064601 7.279275 3.841466 0.0070 At most 1 * 0.064601 7.279275 3.841466 0.0070 None 0.051787 7.888151 15.49471 0.4774 None 0.051787 5.796187 14.26460 0.6395 At most 1 0.019009 2.091964 3.841466 0.1481 At most 1 0.019009 2.091964 3.841466 0.1481 CHL CHN COL None * 0.151617 24.32501 15.49471 0.0018 None * 0.151617 17.92208 14.26460 0.0126 At most 1 * 0.057050 6.402937 3.841466 0.0114 At most 1 * 0.057050 6.402937 3.841466 0.0114 CZE None 0.077627 10.02835 15.49471 0.2786 0.077627 8.565447 14.26460 0.3241 ECU None * 0.141142 21.35864 15.49471 0.0058 None * 0.141142 16.58448 14.26460 0.0211 At most 1 * 0.042854 4.774161 3.841466 0.0289 At most 1 * 0.042854 4.774161 3.841466 0.0289 None * 0.117021 15.81189 15.49471 0.0448 None 0.117021 13.56549 14.26460 0.0642 At most 1 0.020398 2.246394 3.841466 0.1339 At most 1 0.020398 2.246394 3.841466 0.1339 None 0.094882 15.11987 15.49471 0.0569 None 0.094882 10.66685 14.26460 0.1717 At most 1 * 0.040763 4.453027 3.841466 0.0348 At most 1 * 0.040763 4.453027 3.841466 0.0348 IND None 0.080748 13.87162 15.49471 0.0865 None 0.080748 9.008911 14.26460 0.2854 ISR None * 0.147005 25.53496 15.49471 0.0011 None * 0.147005 20.51125 14.26460 0.0045 At most 1 * 0.038195 5.023714 3.841466 0.0250 At most 1 * 0.038195 5.023714 3.841466 0.0250 None * 0.118933 18.85853 15.49471 0.0150 None 0.118933 13.54848 14.26460 0.0646 At most 1 * 0.048415 5.310043 3.841466 0.0212 At most 1 * 0.048415 5.310043 3.841466 0.0212 None 0.045854 7.524112 15.49471 0.5176 None 0.045854 5.257178 14.26460 0.7091 HUN IDN KOR MAL MEX PER None * 0.201539 28.14199 15.49471 0.0004 None * 0.201539 24.08243 14.26460 0.0011 At most 1 * 0.037229 4.059562 3.841466 0.0439 At most 1 * 0.037229 4.059562 3.841466 0.0439 None 0.095776 14.03171 15.49471 0.0821 None 0.095776 11.57799 14.26460 0.1275 At most 1 0.021111 2.453717 3.841466 0.1172 At most 1 0.021111 2.453717 3.841466 0.1172 PHL None 0.058825 8.907372 15.49471 0.3740 None 0.058825 6.911344 14.26460 0.4997 POL None 0.067944 11.88509 15.49471 0.1625 None 0.067944 7.669508 14.26460 0.4133 RUS None * 0.237985 22.18319 15.49471 0.0042 None * 0.237985 17.93810 14.26460 0.0126 At most 1 * 0.062295 4.245087 3.841466 0.0394 At most 1 * 0.062295 4.245087 3.841466 0.0394 THL None 0.094292 14.36123 15.49471 0.0735 None 0.094292 10.59712 14.26460 0.1756 TUR None 0.087939 9.850046 15.49471 0.2924 None 0.087939 9.849138 14.26460 0.2220 ZAF None 0.093926 14.42595 15.49471 0.0720 None 0.093926 12.72384 14.26460 0.0863 29 Shaded areas indicate evidence of a cointegration relationship. Page 32 of 45 Table 8: Cointegration results (CA and log(RER))30 Arg Bol bra chl chn col cze ecu Hun idn ind isr kor mal α_ca -0.13607*** -0.04617 [-2.94695] -0.0054* -0.00348 [-1.54968] -0.08221*** -0.02776 [-2.96081] -0.13516*** -0.04924 [-2.74500] 0.000782 -0.00196 [ 0.39895] -0.16395*** -0.0347 [-4.72445] -0.10082** -0.0509 [-1.98075] -0.23211*** -0.05937 [-3.90935] -0.19155*** -0.05261 [-3.64089] -0.15597*** -0.03966 [-3.93306] -0.20918*** -0.07712 [-2.71235] -0.128* -0.06737 [-1.89986] -0.2953*** -0.07751 [-3.80983] -0.07547*** -0.02894 [-2.60796] β_ca 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 β_log(RER) 0.080371*** -0.01768 [ 4.54541] 1.40817** -0.55394 [ 2.54211] 0.061217** -0.027 [ 2.26715] 0.093885** -0.03748 [ 2.50483] -4.46E-01*** -0.17145 [-2.60161] 0.090283*** -0.01604 [ 5.63032] 0.021827 -0.04741 [ 0.46035] 0.006394 -0.03857 [ 0.16578] 0.110034*** -0.02668 [ 4.12421] 0.119155*** -0.01832 [ 6.50290] 0.004418 -0.00759 [ 0.58196] 0.351295*** -0.10412 [ 3.37410] 0.188198*** -0.05434 [ 3.46311] 0.412068*** -0.0987 [ 4.17507] 30 In Table 6 column RER, given the indirect definition used for the RER, positive signs correspond to negative coefficients for the RER. Shaded areas represent coefficients which have the expected sign. Page 33 of 45 mex per phl pol rus thl tur zaf -0.03694*** -0.01423 [-2.59578] -0.1061*** -0.03577 [-2.96635] -0.08823** -0.04245 [-2.07853] -0.141*** -0.03813 [-3.69769] 0.009315 -0.01097 [ 0.84902] -0.09502** -0.04258 [-2.23120] -0.06378** -0.02305 [-2.76761] -0.11733** -0.04859 [-2.41479] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 -0.0907 -0.06847 [-1.32468] 0.009982 -0.03892 [ 0.25648] 0.263906*** -0.08568 [ 3.07998] 0.003651 -0.00497 [ 0.73432] -0.76808*** -0.20494 [-3.74775] 0.252644*** -0.09244 [ 2.73295] 0.052112** -0.02415 [ 2.15811] -0.05629 -0.05595 [-1.00602] Table 9: Cointegrating Vectors (GDP, GDP*, CA, RER) 31 ARG BOL BRA CHL CHN COL α_ca -0.05973 -0.04786 [-1.24812] 0.004615* -0.00277 [ 1.66350] 0.011257 -0.00808 [ 1.39242] -0.08197*** -0.02313 [-3.54292] -0.00284* -0.00184 [-1.54592] -0.16534*** -0.03265 β_log(RER) 0.118565*** -0.00944 [ 12.5583] -3.47959*** -0.51902 [-6.70420] -0.05048 -0.05966 [-0.84609] 0.324874*** -0.05335 [ 6.08898] 0.031873 -0.10123 [ 0.31487] 0.13589*** -0.01853 β_GDP 0.004501*** -0.0007 [ 6.44475] -0.43812*** -0.07005 [-6.25425] -0.03833*** -0.00688 [-5.57383] 0.021174*** -0.00333 [ 6.35164] 0.010044 -0.01733 [ 0.57973] 0.004343*** -0.00126 β_GDP* 0.027921*** -0.00324 [ 8.61392] 0.384645*** -0.10032 [ 3.83404] 0.007973 -0.01496 [ 0.53281] -0.01262 -0.00982 [-1.28453] 0.159871*** -0.03566 [ 4.48314] -0.00022 -0.00369 31 For Column RER, GDP, and GDP*, given the indirect definition used for the RER, positive signs correspond to negative coefficients for the RER. Shaded areas represent coefficients which have the expected sign. Page 34 of 45 CZE ECU Hun IDN IND ISR KOR PER MEX MAL RUS Pol PHL TUR ZAF [-5.06386] -0.38782*** -0.09215 [-4.20849] -0.27374*** -0.06302 [-4.34370] 0.002332 -0.00832 [ 0.28040] -0.12751*** -0.03692 [-3.45327] -0.14473*** -0.0442 [-3.27454] 0.005181 -0.00699 [ 0.74108] -0.11268*** -0.05707 [-1.97427] 0.005553 -0.00568 [ 0.97842] -0.00381* -0.00207 [-1.84200] -0.0553*** -0.01837 [-3.00999] -0.15815 -0.15009 [-1.05367] 0.000571 -0.00132 [ 0.43446] -0.05896 -0.06084 [-0.96907] -0.00122 -0.00266 [-0.46001] -0.23509*** -0.04399 [-5.34386] [ 7.33325] -0.14227*** -0.03277 [-4.34146] 0.003393 -0.03351 [ 0.10126] -0.18634 -0.17635 [-1.05664] 0.075465*** -0.01745 [ 4.32587] 0.012647* -0.00767 [ 1.64837] 1.398577 -0.73304 [ 1.90791] 0.079948 -0.06269 [ 1.27522] 0.31372** -0.15102 [ 2.07739] 0.633948** -0.3104 [ 2.04234] 0.345256*** -0.07646 [ 4.51579] 0.14093*** -0.02747 [ 5.13111] 0.361692*** -0.11015 [ 3.28357] -0.00594*** -0.00154 [-3.86653] 0.239051** -0.11219 [ 2.13081] 0.00705 -0.02714 [ 0.25975] [ 3.45463] 0.002373* -0.00149 [ 1.59733] 0.00479 -0.00475 [ 1.00926] 0.016465 -0.01188 [ 1.38609] 0.006866*** -0.00145 [ 4.75101] 0.009922*** -0.00243 [ 4.07996] 0.084679 -0.01159*** [ 7.30801] 0.010693*** -0.00217 [ 4.92926] -0.0102 -0.00815 [-1.25189] 0.098975*** -0.016 [ 6.18426] 0.038091*** -0.00585 [ 6.51268] -0.0109*** -0.00157 [-6.94274] -0.04053* -0.0252 [-1.60836] -0.00594*** -0.00154 [-3.86653] -0.01768*** -0.00325 [-5.44339] 0.012143*** -0.00263 [ 4.62329] [-0.05883] -0.03072*** -0.00511 [-6.00841] 0.019591** -0.00985 [ 1.98828] -0.16866*** -0.0334 [-5.04985] -0.00406 -0.00546 [-0.74396] 0.008732** -0.00353 [ 2.47355] -0.0858 -0.06474 [-1.32531] -0.03142*** -0.00636 [-4.94160] 0.198875*** -0.04007 [ 4.96280] 0.117877*** -0.04364 [ 2.70108] -0.00019 -0.01491 [-0.01276] -0.01381** -0.00707 [-1.95393] -0.62862*** -0.12568 [-5.00187] -0.00887** -0.00444 [-1.99659] 0.075712*** -0.0249 [ 3.04105] -0.03005*** -0.0047 [-6.39049] Page 35 of 45 4.2 Charts Chart 1: CA and Real effective Exchange Rate 140 800 100 .08 60 400 .04 20 .12 0 .04 .00 -.04 -.08 1970 1980 1990 CA_ARG_SA .10 .05 .00 -.05 -.10 -.15 1970 1980 1990 CA_CHL_SA .2 .1 .0 -.1 -.2 1970 REER2_ARG 240 200 2000 1980 1990 CA_BOL_SA 160 120 .12 80 .08 .04 .00 -.04 -.08 1970 REER2_CHL 200 160 120 80 .04 40 .02 2000 REER2_BOL 300 250 200 150 100 .08 50 .04 1990 1990 CA_CHN_SA 2000 REER2_CHN 125 1980 .00 1990 CA_IDN_SA -.04 1970 2000 REER2_IDN 1990 2000 140 1980 REER2_IND 120 100 80 .04 .02 60 .12 .04 .00 -.04 -.02 1970 1980 1990 CA_JAP_SA -.12 1970 2000 REER2_JPN 1980 1990 CA_KOR_SA 120 80 .050 .000 -.050 -.100 1970 1980 1990 CA_PER_SA 2000 .08 40 .04 .00 -.04 -.08 -.12 1970 REER2_PER 2000 1980 1990 CA_PHL_SA REER2_PHI 1980 1990 CA_THA_SA 2000 REER2_THL 1980 1990 2000 REER2_CAN 160 120 1990 2000 REER2_COL 120 110 100 90 .04 80 .00 70 -.04 80 40 1980 1990 CA_CZE_SA 2000 REER2_CZE 140 120 100 80 60 40 -.08 1980 1990 REER2_ISR -.12 1970 2000 1980 1990 2000 1980 1990 CA_MAL_SA 1980 1990 CA_TUR_SA2 2000 CA_ITA_SA 120 100 80 60 40 -.08 1970 2000 REER2_MAL 1,200 1980 1990 CA_MEX_SA 2000 REER2_MEX 400 300 200 400 0 100 .20 0 .10 .00 -.12 1970 1980 1990 2000 -.10 1970 1980 1990 2000 CA_POL_SA 180 .02 60 .00 -.02 -.04 -.06 -.08 1970 REER2_TUR REER2_ITA 180 160 140 120 .08 100 .04 80 .00 800 100 -.08 1970 CA_ISR_SA -.04 140 .04 -.04 -.05 -.15 1970 140 120 100 80 .3 60 .2 .1 .0 -.1 -.2 1970 2000 .00 .05 80 CA_CAN_SA 100 .08 60 .04 .00 -.04 -.08 -.12 1970 -.04 120 80 1980 CA_COL_SA 105 .04 .02 95 .00 -.02 -.04 -.06 1970 REER2_KOR 180 160 140 120 100 80 .04 160 .15 REER2_BRA 100 REER2_FRA CA_GBR_SA REER2_GBR CA_HUN_SA REER2_HUN 500 .2 .04 400 .02 .1 300 .00 .0 200 -.02 -.1 130 100160 140 -.04 0 -.2 120 120 110 100 100 80 90 60 80 1990 2000 1970 1980 1990 2000 1970 1980 1990 2000 CA_IND_SA .06 120 .04 80 .02 40 .00 -.02 -.04 -.06 1970 140 -.08 1970 2000 140 120 CA_FRA_SA -.02 1980 2000 160 160 180 115 -.04 1970 REER2_ECU 300 250 200 150 100 .04 50 .02 1990 -.04 1980 .00 1980 1980 CA_BRA_SA .00 -.02 CA_ECU_SA .08 .04 .00 -.04 -.08 -.12 1970 -.12 1970 2000 .02 .00 -.02 -.04 -.06 1970 200 1980 REER2_POL CA_RUS_SA REER2_RUS 120 280 110 240 100 200 90 .15 160 80 .10 120 70 .05 80 .00 -.05 -.10 -.15 1990 2000 1970 1980 1990 2000 CA_USA_SA Page 36 of 45 REER2_USA CA_ZAF_SA REER2_ZAF Chart 2 Standard deviation of CA and REER compared 120 Standard deviation of REER 100 RUS BOL 80 60 CHN IDN 40 BRA 20 CHL COL TUR ECU ARG MAL THL JAP GBR USA FRA 0 0 MEX KOR ISR DEU 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 Standard deviation of CA Chart 3 Real and Nominal Exchange Rate Volatility (Standard Deviation, 1994-2008) 20 18 CZE 16 JAP REER 14 HUN ZAF POL 12 ISR 10 CHN CAN CHL USA GBR 8 6 DEU 4 FRA PER ITA PHL THL MAL KOR IND 2 0 0 5 10 15 20 NEER Page 37 of 45 25 30 35 40 Source: BIS -0.05 -0.06 -0.07 Average Median -0.02 -0.04 Page 38 of 45 t t+12 t+10 0.06 t+8 t+6 t+4 -0.04 t+2 -0.03 t-2 -0.02 t-4 Current Account t-6 0 t-8 Current Accout Deficit Reversals t-10 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 -0.6 Turkey Venezuela Hungary Russia India Poland Mexico Germany France Brazil Japan Indonesia Peru Philippines Israel China South Africa United Kingdom Italy Korea Thailand Chile Argentina United States Czech Republic Canada Malaysia -0.4 t-10 -0.2 t-12 -0.01 t-12 Chart 4 Correlation between the NEER and the REER 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 -0.8 Chart 5 CA Surplus reversals 0.08 Current Account Average Median 0.04 0.02 0 REER REER 130 120 120 110 110 100 90 Average Median Growth t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-12 t-8 80 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 90 t-10 100 Average Median GDP 7 8 6 7 5 6 5 4 4 3 3 2 Average Median 2 Average Median 1 1 0 Chart 6 Total depreciation versus size of CA adjustment Size of depreciation -100.00 -90.00 -80.00 -70.00 -60.00 -50.00 -40.00 -30.00 -20.00 -10.00 0.00 5.00 10.00 15.00 0.00 20.00 25.00 Size of CA adjustment Page 39 of 45 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 0 Diff in GDP growth pre and post criris Chart 7 Change in GDP growth versus size of total REER adjustment -15 -10 -5 0 -20 -40 -60 -80 -100 0 5 10 15 Size of REER adjustment Chart 8 : CA deficit reversals : Comparison of crisis vs. Non-crisis periods Crises periods Non-crisis periods Page 40 of 45 Average Median t+12 t+8 t+10 t+6 t+4 t t+2 t-2 t-4 t-8 t-10 t-12 t+12 t+10 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 t+8 Average Median 0.02 0.01 0 -0.01 -0.02 -0.03 -0.04 -0.05 -0.06 -0.07 -0.08 t-6 Current Account Current Account 0.02 0.01 0 -0.01 -0.02 -0.03 -0.04 -0.05 -0.06 -0.07 -0.08 REER REER 150 150 140 140 130 130 120 120 Average Median 110 110 Average Median 100 100 90 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t t+2 t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 90 Growth Growth 7 7 6 6 5 5 4 4 3 3 2 2 Average Median 1 Average Median 1 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 t-12 0 0 Chart 9 CA deficit reversals: Comparison of Fixers vs. Floaters Fixers Floaters Current Account Current Account -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.03 -0.06 -0.07 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 -0.04 -0.04 -0.05 t-8 -0.01 t-10 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 -0.01 t-12 0 t-12 0 -0.05 Average Median -0.06 -0.07 Page 41 of 45 Average Median REER REER 160 160 Average Median 150 140 Average Median 150 140 130 130 120 120 110 110 100 100 90 90 10 8 8 6 6 4 4 2 2 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t Average Median t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 0 t+12 t+10 Average Median t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 0 t-12 t+2 Growth Growth 10 -2 t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 t-12 80 80 Chart 10 CA surplus reversals : Fixers versus floaters32 Fixers Floaters Current Account Current Account 0.1 -0.04 -0.04 32 Note that the sample size for this table is very small (4 fixed ER regimes and 10 floating ER regimes), and drawing conclusions should be treated with respective caution. Page 42 of 45 t+12 t+10 Average Median t+8 t+6 t+4 t t+2 t-2 -0.02 t-4 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t t+2 -0.02 t-2 0 t-4 0 t-6 0.02 t-8 0.02 t-10 0.04 t-12 0.04 t-6 0.06 t-8 0.06 0.08 t-10 Average Median 0.08 t-12 0.1 6 6 0 4 2 Page 43 of 45 t+12 8 t+10 8 t+8 10 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 t+4 t+2 t 140 t+6 10 t-2 150 t+4 12 t+2 GDP t 12 t-4 REER t-2 80 t-6 90 80 t-4 100 90 t-8 110 100 t-6 120 110 t-10 130 120 t-8 Average Median t-12 130 t-10 t+12 t+10 t+8 t+6 Average Median t-12 t+12 2 t+10 4 t+8 t+4 140 t+6 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 150 t+4 t+2 t t-2 t-4 t-6 t-8 t-10 t-12 160 160 REER Average Median GDP Average Median 0 Chart 11 Long run cointegration relation REER and CA 1.0000 β_log(reer) 0.8000 0.6000 0.4000 0.2000 Mal Isr Phl Thl Kor Idn Hun Chl Col Arg Bra Tur Cze Per Ecu Ind Pol Zaf Mex Chn -0.2000 Rus 0.0000 -0.4000 -0.6000 Chart 12 Short run adjustment of CA to cointegration relation 0.05 -0.1 -0.15 -0.2 -0.25 α_ca -0.3 -0.35 Page 44 of 45 Rus Chn Mex Tur Mal Bra Phl Thl Cze Per Zaf Chl Arg Pol Idn Col Hun Ind Ecu -0.05 Kor 0 Chart 13 Adjustment Speed of Current Account versus LevyYeyati and Sturzenegger (2002) classification 0.4 α_ca 0.3 0.2 0.1 Float Float Float Float Float Float Interim Interim Interim Interim Interim Interim Interim 0 IDN KOR ARG BRA MEX PER ECU RUS ISR COL CHL CAN JPN Note: Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger (2002) classify countries into floaters, intermediate, and fixed regimes from 1975 to 2000. We average the indicator over the period 1980-2000 to evaluate the "average" de facto exchange rate regime. Countries are ranked according to this average here. We only consider statistically significant error-correction terms. Page 45 of 45