Efficient Within Country Estimation of the Theories Brant Abbott May 11, 2008

advertisement
Efficient Within Country Estimation of the Theories
of Nominal Rigidity - Draft
Brant Abbott
May 11, 2008
Abstract
A fixed effects panel data approach is used to estimate the output gap solution
implied by theoretical models that attempt to explain the short run inflationoutput trade-off. This is accomplished by adopting the method of Defina (1991)
and Khan (2004), which overcomes the problematic aspects of the cross-country
framework, but viewing some coefficients as fixed across countries. The efficiency
gain from using the panel data method overcomes the multicollinearity problems that have plagued past studies of this nature. The results depend on what
measure of money is used. When the IMF’s money variable is used the results
support the Lucas imperfect information model, and when nominal GDP is used
as a proxy for money the results support the sticky price model.
1
–Draft–
1
Introduction
The source of the short-run trade-off between inflation and output observed in the data
is a longstanding and ongoing debate. The benchmark candidates to explain the tradeoff are the imperfect information model of Lucas (1972) and the sticky price model,
usually attributed to Calvo (1983). The empirical literature that tests the validity of
these models has traditionally used a problematic two-stage cross-country approach
to test the qualitative implications of the output gap solutions. To circumvent the
two-stage method’s problems recent contributions have embedded the second stage regression in the first stage and estimated a single equation for each country individually.
The results of these studies have been inconclusive and have suffered from a multicollinearity problem. The main contribution of the present study is to show that some
of the coefficients in the output gap solution can be considered fixed across countries,
allowing for more efficient fixed effects estimates. This is quite similar to some recent contributions to the exchange rate pass through literature that have shown that
the traditional two-stage method in that literature is better estimated in a panel data
framework (Goldfajn and Werlang, 2000; Frankel, Parsley, and Wei, 2005).
A secondary contribution of this paper is to demonstrate the impact that using log
nominal GDP as a proxy for log money supply may have on statistical results. To
justify the proxy variable, past studies have generally made the assumptions that the
aggregate demand curve is unit elastic, and that log nominal GDP is neither observable
or predictable. The substitution of nominal GDP for the money supply in past studies
was largely due to the lack of data availability. The two-stage method requires a large
cross-section of countries in order to have reasonable degrees of freedom in the secondstage, and comparable monetary data for such a set of countries did not exist. In this
study a smaller set of countries is used (n = 14) for which comparable quarterly data
from the IMF’s Monetary Survey exist. When log nominal GDP is used as a proxy the
1
–Draft–
results weakly support the sticky price model, but when the monetary variable is used
the results strongly support the Lucas imperfect information model.
The frictions that cause nominally driven real fluctuations in the benchmark models
operate in substantially different ways. In the imperfect information model agents must
adjust output in response to price shocks before they know whether the shock is nominal
or real. A rational expectations response is to adjust output by an amount based on
the relative volatilities of real and nominal disturbances, and thus output responds
regardless of what type the shock turns out to be. In the sticky price model, unlike
the Lucas model, firms have full information about the source of aggregate demand
disturbances, but if they choose to adjust their price they incur a cost. Firms will only
adjust their prices when the benefit of doing so exceeds the cost. If there is an increase
in the nominal money stock and prices are sticky due to adjustment costs there will be
an increase in aggregate demand resulting in a short-run increase in real output.
The question of which (if either) candidate best represents the true underlying
process behind the inflation-output trade-off has significant policy implications. The
Lucas model implies a New-Classical short-run Phillips Curve that maps predetermined expectations to current inflation, whereas the sticky price model implies a NewKeynesian Phillips curve that maps current expectations of future inflation to current inflation. Svensson (1999) shows that an optimal commitment monetary policy is inflation-targeting if the New-Classical Phillips Curve holds, and Clarida et al.
(1999) and Vestin (2006) show that price-level-targeting is an optimal commitment if
the New-Keynesian Phillips Curve holds. The optimal policy when a ‘hybrid’ Phillips
Curve maps a weighted average of the New-Keynesian and New-Classical versions to
current inflation is inflation-targeting with some price-level consideration (Barnett and
Engineer 2001).1 Information as to the correct specification of the Phillips Curve would
1
These optimal policies are derived by maximizing a standard quadratic loss function subject to a
Phillips Curve. This is discussed by Barnett and Engineer (1999).
2
–Draft–
then be of great importance to monetary authorities when considering their policy
regime.
With few exceptions, a two stage cross-country methodology has been used to assess
the competing theories empirically (Lucas 1973; Ball et al., 1988; Kiley, 2000).2 Both
the sticky price and the imperfect information models imply that the output gap is
function of itself lagged and first differenced log money supply. The first stage of
the cross-country method is to fit regressions similar to equation (1) for a number of
countries individually:
yt = α + βyt−1 + τ ∆xt + vt .
(1)
The variables y and ∆x are the output gap and first differenced nominal GDP, respectively, and v is an error term. In these studies ∆x is used in lieu of ∆m, first
differenced money supply, for reasons discussed above. The parameter β is referred
to as the persistence coefficient and τ is referred to as the impact coefficient. In the
second stage the estimated impact coefficients from the first stage are regressed on some
specification of nominal variability, σ∆x , and/or mean inflation, π, calculated over the
entire sample period for each country.3 Both the sticky price and imperfect information
models imply that the impact coefficient should be decreasing in the standard deviation
of aggregate demand changes, σ∆x , and the sticky price model further implies that it
should be decreasing in trend inflation, π T . The model of Kiley (2000) has implications
similar to the sticky price model. When these variables are included individually their
coefficients are generally less than zero and significant, but results are less consistent
when both are included. Ball et al. (1988) report that when both are included the
coefficients on π terms are significant and the coefficients on σ∆x terms are not. They
argue that this implies mean inflation is the relevant variable and that the variability of
2
These three references are far from exhaustive, but are the three most instructive with regard to
this study. Kiley (2000) provides references to further examples.
3
Mean inflation is the sample average which is different from trend inflation, π T .
3
–Draft–
nominal GDP differences is significant in isolation only because it is highly correlated
with mean inflation.
The inability to distinguish between the effects of inflation and nominal volatility
volatility due to their strong correlation is only one of several problems with the two
stage cross-country method. The criticism by Akerlof et al. (1988) that the method
incorrectly assumes the second stage regressors are constant over time has been widely
cited. They argue that because in reality those variables are not constant over time the
value of the impact coefficient is not either, and also that average inflation may not be a
good approximation for trend inflation. A more subtle problem with the cross-country
method is that the estimated marginal effects of σ∆x and π on τ are strictly between
country effects and may not be reflective of within country relationships. The following
example clarifies this potential problem. Suppose that τ is entirely determined by how
autonomous the central bank is in each country, and that the less autonomous the
central bank is the higher inflation is on average. In figure 1, a scatter plot of this
hypothetical case for two countries, the large dots represent the means and the small
dots represent time series observations. Clearly a fit through the means would indicate
a negative relationship between τ and π, even though within each country there is no
relationship.
To address the problems pointed out by Akerlof et al. (1988), Defina (1991) moves
away from the two stage estimation framework. Defina’s method is to replace the
parameter τ in equation (1) with the functional form that was formerly fitted in the
second stage. If τ = f (σ∆x , π) then the following regression is fit for each country:
yt = α + βyt−1 + f (σ∆x,t , πtT )∆xt + vt .
(2)
The variables σ∆x,t and π t are calculated as the standard deviation of ∆x and average
4
–Draft–
Figure 1: Hypothetical τ vs π
3
2.5
2
τ
1.5
1
0.5
0
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
π
3
3.5
4
4.5
5
of π, respectively, over the five years t − 4 to t.4 In this framework the significance
is determined by formally considering what proportion of countries yield estimates of
coefficients on a particular variable that are significant. Defina reports that when f is
specified as a linear function 28/43 countries have negative coefficients on π and 35/43
countries have negative coefficients on σ∆x . However, only 13/43 π and 11/43 σ∆x
coefficients are significnatly less than zero at the 90% level, and for only 3/43 countries
were both coefficients significant.
Khan (2004) adopts Defina’s method when assessing the theoretical work of Kiley
(2000), and follows Kiley’s own empirical work in dropping σ∆x terms from regressions.
This omission creates a strong potential for bias in the estimates of π T coefficients
because of the correlation between the variables. Kiley and Khan both argue that the
loss of efficiency when both variables are included justifies dropping one of the variables
and accepting some bias.
4
Defina uses actual inflation, π, rather than trend inflation.
5
–Draft–
The present paper estimates Kiley’s (2000) model in a fixed effects panel data framework, which vastly increases efficiency, eliminating the need to drop one of the variables.
This framework maintains Defina’s (1991) solution to the criticisms of Akerlof et al.
(1988), and ensures that slope estimates are based on within country variation. Estimation is carried out using ∆x in lieu of ∆m, as has traditionally been done, as well as an
actual measure of the money supply. The results vary substantially with the different
measures. When nominal GDP is used the persistence and impact coefficients are both
decreasing in π T and σ∆x , but the restriction that the relevant coefficients are constant
across countries is rejected. When money supply data is used the impact coefficient is
decreasing in σ∆x but not π T , and the persistence coefficient is not decreasing in either.
The restriction that coefficients are constant across countries cannot be rejected for any
of the relevant variables.
2
Theoretical and Empirical Frameworks
The theoretical foundation of the estimated model is exactly that of Kiley (2000).
The supply side of the economy follows Calvo (1983) by assuming a continuum of
monopolistically competitive price setting firms that choose a constant probability, γ,
that they will be able to adjust their price in any given period. Firms in this model
can choose a new γ in every period that they adjust their price, but because there is a
fixed cost of price adjustment, F , it is suboptimal to choose γ = 1. When firms adjust
their prices they choose their desired price p∗i,t , which depends on the money supply,
mt , and an idiosyncratic shock, ui,t :
p∗i,t = mt + ui,t .
6
–Draft–
Money growth and the idiosyncratic shock are assumed to follow simple non-stationary
processes,
∆mt = µ + m,t ,
ui,t = ui,t−1 + u,i,t ,
2
where m,t and u,i,t are mean zero disturbances with variances σm
and σu2 , respectively.
In periods that a firm does not adjust their price they incur a quadratic loss, L, due to
deviation of their actual price, pi,t , from their desired price: L = (1/2)K(pi,t − p∗i,t )2 .
A further cost per period is incurred by firms if they wish to maintain perfect
information about the state of the economy. Firms that pay this cost otherwise operate
in the same setting as the Calvo model, i.e. at time t they know the entire history of
shocks up to and including period t. If firms do not pay the information cost then at
time t they know the history of shocks only until time t − 1, and must make pricing
decisions in a manner similar to the Lucas model. The cost of perfect information,
α ∈ (0, ∞), is different for each firm and drawn from a distribution G.
Kiley shows that there is a threshold information cost, α, below which firms choose
to acquire perfect information and above which they choose not to. There is then a
fraction of the firms that has perfect information, Θ = G(α), and a fraction that does
not, 1 − Θ. Kiley further demonstrates the the optimal choice of γ is the same for
all firms regardless of whether or not they acquire perfect information. The solutions
imply the following relationships:
∂Θ
2
∂σm
> 0,
∂γ
2
∂σm
> 0,
∂γ
∂µ
> 0.
Quite simply, information and price adjustment are more desirable in a more volatile
environment, and optimal price adjustment becomes faster if trend inflation becomes
7
–Draft–
faster. A closed form solution for the output gap can be attained:
yt = (1 − γ)yt−1 + (1 − γΘ)∆mt + et ,
(3)
where et is a mean zero supply shock. Equation (3) is similar to equations (1) and (2)
where log nominal GDP (xt ) is a proxy for the money supply (mt ). The persistence
coefficient is (1 − γ) and the impact coefficient is (1 − γΘ). The estimation framework
calls for a functional form to be assigned to these coefficients. Here they are assumed
to be linear:
(1 − γ) = β0i + β1i πitT + β2i σ∆xit
(4)
(1 − γΘ) = τ0i + τ1i πitT + τ2i σ∆xit .
(5)
Defina (1991) and Khan (2004) make similar substitutions and add a constant term,
then fit a regression of equation (6) for each country i:
yit = αi + β0i yit−1 + β1i (yit−1 πitT ) + β2i (yit−1 σ∆xit ) +
τ0i ∆xit + τ1i (∆xit πitT ) + τ2i (∆xit σ∆xit ) + vt .
(6)
Defina’s model differs from (6) in that (1 − γ) is replaced by a single coefficient, and
Kahn’s model does not include σ∆xit terms in the substitutions.
The present study tests whether restrictions that the coefficients can be fixed across
countries are valid. To do this a single panel regression, rather than several independent
regressions, is fit. Two variations of this approach are taken. In the first nominal GDP
is used as a proxy for money, and in the second an actual measure of money is used.
The T × n matrices ∆M and YL are constructed as follows, where n is the number
8
–Draft–
of countries and T =

∆m1





∆M = 





0
..
.
..
.
0
0
Pn
i=1
Ti is the total length of the stacked data:
...
∆m2 . . .
..
.
0
...
...
0
...
0
..
.
∆mn−1
0
0
∆mn












 YL = 










yL1
0
..
.
..
.
0
0
...
yL2 . . .
..
.
0
...
...
0
...
0
..
.
yLn−1
0
0
yLn
Each ∆mi is a vector of length Ti containing the change in money (or log nominal
GDP) for country i, and each yLi is a similar vector containing the lagged output
gap. A matrix of dummy variables is denoted by D, and stacked variables are denoted
by boldface characters without subscripts. A ‘period’ between two vectors indicates
“element-by-element” multiplication, as opposed to matrix multiplication. Using this
notation, a model in which the restrictions that β1 , β2 , τ1 and τ2 are constant across
countries in equation (6) can be written as follows:
y=
D YL yL.π T yL.σ∆m ∆M ∆m.π T ∆m.σ∆m
Ω1 + v,
(7)
where
Ω1 0 = [ α1 . . . αn β0,1 . . . β0,n β1 β2 τ0,1 . . . τ0,n τ1 τ2 ].
The αi parameters are country specific intercept terms; the β0,i and τ0,i are the country
specific constant terms of equations (4) and (5); and the τ1 , τ2 , β1 and β2 parameters
are the country-invariant slope terms of equations (4) and (5). This is equivalent to the
usual fixed-effects estimator. In total 3n + 4 coefficients are estimated in this version
of the model, however, that is 4n − 4 less coefficients than were estimated by Defina
9






.





–Draft–
(1991) or Khan (2004).
If the restriction that the constant terms in equations (4) and (5) are fixed across
countries the matrices YL and ∆X are replaced by vectors yL and ∆x containing
stacked data. This version of the estimator can be written as
y=
D yL yL.π T yL.σ∆m ∆m ∆m.π T ∆m.σ∆m
Ω2 + v,
(8)
where
Ω2 0 = [ α1 . . . αn β0 β1 β2 τ0 τ1 τ2 ].
In this case only n + 6 coefficients are estimated, a substantial increase in degrees
of freedom. If the restrictions that equation (8) imposes on equation (6) cannot be
rejected, a test for the suitability of a random effects model can be carried out. Random
effects would be the most efficient estimator, but if some of the restrictions are rejected
the fixed effects estimator is efficient.
In terms of past literature there is a subtle interpretation of the difference between
equations (7) and (8). The traditional two stage cross-country method requires that the
second stage be estimated with a fixed intercept term. The country-invariant τ0 and β0
terms in equation (8) make this same restriction, while it is relaxed in equation (7). This
restriction is related to the question of within and between country variation discussed in
the introduction. Fitting equation (8) would result in the bold line illustrated in figure
1, whereas fitting equation (7) would fit a different regression line for each country that
is indicative of the within country variation. Because equation (8) is nested in equation
(7), formal testing is straightforward. The methodology of Defina (1991) and Khan
(2004) captures within country variation, however it does not allow for formal testing
of such restrictions.
10
–Draft–
Table 1: Data Sample
3
Country
Time Period
Country
Time Period
Australia
Canada
France
Germany
Italy
Japan
Mexico
1971Q1-2007Q2
1971Q1-2007Q1
1976Q1-1998Q2
1960Q4-1989Q2
1976Q1-1998Q4
1961Q1-2006Q4
1977Q1-2007Q1
Netherlands
1973Q1-1997Q1
New Zealand
1982Q2-2007Q1
South Africa
1968Q1-1992Q3
Spain
1970Q1-1999Q1
Switzerland
1977Q4-2007Q2
United Kingdom 1961Q1-2007Q2
United States
1960Q4-2007Q2
Data
Quarterly seasonally adjusted nominal GDP, GDP deflator and percent change in
money data for 14 countries spanning the years 1956-2007 were retrieved from the
IMF’s International Financial Statistics. The definition of money in the series used is
narrow and includes transferable deposits and currency outside banks. A list of included
countries and time periods is provided in table 1.
The raw data were used to calculate log real GDP and log nominal GDP in the usual
way. The output gap is formulated as the cyclical component of Hodrick-Prescott (HP)
filtered log real GDP as in Kiley (2000) and Khan (2004). Inflation was computed
as percentage changes in the GDP deflator, and trend inflation is computed as the
trend component of HP filtered inflation. Because the data was quarterly the filtering
parameter was set to 1600. The time varying measures of the standard deviation of the
percent change in money and first-differenced log nominal GDP were calculated using
using three years of data as:
# 21
t
X
1
=
(∆mi,s − ∆mi,s ) ,
4 s=t−11
"
σ∆m,i,t
11
–Draft–
where ∆mi,s is the mean of ∆mi,s over the period t − 11 to t.
4
Results
To create a basis for testing nested restrictions equation (6) was estimated as a single
panel regression, in which none of the slope coefficients were restricted to be constant
across countries. This is equivalent to fitting a separate regression for each country, like
Defina (1991) did. Table 2(a) presents these results for the case of using nominal GDP
as a proxy, and Table 2(b) presents the the results for the case of using the IMF’s money
variable. Standard errors are given in parentheses below slope coefficients. When the
nominal GDP data is used the majority of coefficients have the sign implied by the
sticky price theory, however these coefficients are seldom significant. Even less common
that significant coefficient with the correct sign are significant coefficients with the
wrong sign, the presence of which is troubling. These results for the nominal GDP case
are very similar to those of Defina (1991) and Khan (2004). The results for the case
of using IMF money data are similar, however correctly signed coefficients are in the
majority only for τ2 , τ0 and β0 .
Tables 3(a) and 3(b) presents a subset of the results from fitting equation (7) by
OLS when nominal GDP and IMF money data are used, respectively. In equation (7)
coefficients τ1 , τ2 , β1 and β2 are fixed across countries. If the restrictions cannot be
rejected, the results of these regressions are quite different depending on which variable
is used. In the case of nominal GDP as a proxy the results highly support sticky price
models. In that case the persistence and impact coefficients are decreasing in both
trend inflation and nominal volatility, with highly significant coefficients. On the other
hand, if IMF money is used the only significantly negative coefficient is on the nominal
volatility term in the impact coefficient. This result is highly supportive of the Lucas
12
–Draft–
Table 2(a): No coefficient restrictions, Nominal GDP data.
Country
β0
β1
β2
τ0
Australia
0.98
(0.16)
0.98
(0.14)
0.87
(0.18)
1.33
(0.36)
1.09
(0.09)
0.84
(0.13)
1.27
(0.13)
1.14
(0.09)
1.03
(0.32)
1.20
(0.19)
0.90
(0.27)
0.94
(0.19)
0.88
(0.12)
0.88
(0.17)
-6.23
(6.37)
3.23
(8.19)
3.04
(7.31)
-35.59
(24.41)
-7.87
(2.97)
-0.37
(4.69)
-2.81
(0.64)
16.90
(4.76)
-10.83
(53.23)
-5.07
(6.45)
-6.76
(6.04)
-7.47
(24.65)
-5.35
(5.47)
2.17
(7.94)
-9.74
(29.24)
-38.44
(38.57)
-7.27
(10.33)
-22.99
(33.76)
-4.69
(4.64)
-9.05
(16.59)
-17.62
(4.44)
-70.23
(16.73)
-18.65
(44.18)
-11.44
(8.03)
12.04
(40.37)
-4.03
(16.18)
-6.62
(23.93)
-3.36
(33.64)
2.78
(0.36)
2.78
(0.44)
3.14
(0.42)
3.25
(0.70)
2.67
(0.27)
1.59
(0.29)
2.59
(0.14)
2.47
(0.39)
2.21
(0.93)
2.70
(0.34)
1.88
(0.40)
2.31
(0.59)
2.83
(0.30)
2.86
(0.47)
Canada
France
Germany
Italy
Japan
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
South Africa
Spain
Switzerland
United Kingdom
United States
R2 = 0.785
13
τ1
τ2
-42.86
-48.47
(9.93)
(49.53)
-40.99
-162.91
(12.33) (82.85)
-75.42
-26.28
(13.71) (16.39)
-82.94
-61.67
(36.28) (64.45)
-39.68
-13.80
(4.98)
(10.45)
-28.93
-33.98
(9.22)
(25.66)
-11.25
-17.67
(0.57)
(3.78)
19.84
-102.04
(27.45) (35.52)
-37.98
14.12
(132.89) (101.72)
-26.27
9.97
(8.02)
(15.47)
-31.97
81.31
(6.77)
(45.03)
-111.03
56.25
(71.32) (44.59)
-33.50
-67.31
(9.74)
(31.46)
-53.97
-45.85
(17.29) (83.29)
–Draft–
Table 2(b): No coefficient restrictions, IMF Money data.
Country
β0
β1
β2
τ0
τ1
τ2
Australia
0.81
(0.20)
0.83
(0.19)
-0.05
(0.20)
0.53
(0.38)
0.78
(0.14)
0.71
(0.18)
-0.08
(0.10)
0.31
(0.13)
0.76
(0.23)
0.88
(0.30)
0.62
(0.39)
0.63
(0.43)
0.62
(0.27)
0.75
(0.30)
-1.29
(8.57)
-0.07
(10.36)
8.04
(13.66)
-14.24
(40.87)
0.12
(4.48)
-1.47
(7.01)
3.31
(0.81)
13.12
(4.33)
-24.81
(37.92)
-3.52
(12.03)
-0.32
(8.89)
2.65
(36.76)
-1.32
(6.64)
3.79
(12.39)
-0.01
(0.04)
0.01
(0.03)
0.07
(0.03)
0.07
(0.08)
-0.02
(0.02)
0.01
(0.03)
0.00
(0.00)
0.07
(0.02)
0.01
(0.04)
-0.01
(0.02)
0.02
(0.07)
0.00
(0.04)
0.02
(0.05)
0.03
(0.07)
0.08
(0.04)
0.02
(0.05)
0.00
(0.06)
0.05
(0.08)
0.09
(0.04)
0.07
(0.04)
-0.01
(0.02)
-0.23
(0.09)
0.04
(0.06)
0.14
(0.05)
0.05
(0.05)
0.03
(0.10)
0.00
(0.04)
0.07
(0.10)
0.76
(1.17)
0.81
(2.00)
-2.63
(2.97)
4.14
(6.13)
0.31
(0.75)
0.16
(1.00)
-0.02
(0.07)
-13.31
(4.73)
0.08
(3.35)
-2.58
(1.61)
-0.56
(0.87)
-12.64
(6.06)
0.25
(0.92)
-1.02
(3.65)
-0.006
(0.004)
-0.003
(0.004)
-0.002
(0.008)
-0.021
(0.016)
-0.011
(0.004)
-0.008
(0.004)
0.000
(0.000)
0.048
(0.016)
0.001
(0.007)
0.000
(0.002)
0.000
(0.006)
-0.002
(0.009)
0.003
(0.007)
-0.009
(0.020)
Canada
France
Germany
Italy
Japan
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
South Africa
Spain
Switzerland
United Kingdom
United States
R2 = 0.539
14
–Draft–
Table 3(a): Coefficients τ1 , τ2 , β1 and β2 fixed, Nominal GDP data
Coefficient
Estimate
Standard Error
p(H0 = 0; Ha < 0)
β1
-2.86
0.60
0.00
β2
-11.46
2.55
0.00
τ1
-12.26
0.57
0.00
τ2
-11.91
3.22
0.00
R2 = 0.762
imperfect information model, which has no implications for the other terms.
For the results presented in Table 3 to be meaningful the restrictions imposed on
the regression must be accurate. To check this a simple F -test of the null hypothesis
that the restrictions are true was performed, the results of which are presented in Table
4. In the case of nominal GDP data the null is strongly rejected, but in the case of the
IMF money data it cannot be rejected. This implies that the results presented in Table
3(a) are not likely to be accurate, and the best results for the case of the nominal GDP
data are those in table 2(a). However, for the IMF money variable the results presented
in Table 3(a) can be considered, and are more efficient than those in Table 2(a). More
efficiency could be gained if the coefficients β0 and τ0 are fixed across countries. The
last line of Table 4 gives results for testing the null hypothesis that those coefficients
are fixed for the IMF money data case. This is in essence testing the restrictions that
are imposed on equation (7) to arrive at equation (8). The restrictions are strongly
rejected.
The last result in Table 4 implies that each country should have a unique τ0,i , which
15
–Draft–
Table 3(b): Coefficients τ1 , τ2 , β1 and β2 fixed, IMF Money data
Coefficient
Estimate
Standard Error
p(H0 = 0; Ha < 0)
β1
3.18
0.75
1.00
β2
0.0025
0.0029
0.85
τ1
-0.0433
0.0725
0.29
τ2
-0.0005
0.0003
0.07
R2 = 0.525
Table 4: Hypothesis Testing
Restrictions
F -value
p-value
3.64
0.00
β1,i = β1 , β2,i = β2 , τ1,i = τ1 , τ2,i = τ2 , ∀i
1.17
0.19
β0,i = β1 , τ0,i = τ0 , ∀i
3.10
0.00
Nominal GDP data
β1,i = β1 , β2,i = β2 , τ1,i = τ1 , τ2,i = τ2 , ∀i
IMF Money data
16
–Draft–
Figure 2: Predicted τ vs. σ∆ m (Money Data)
0.035
CAN
USA
UK
0.03
0.025
τ
0.02
0.015
0.01
0.005
0
2
4
6
σ∆ m
8
10
12
14
further implies that each country has a unique intercept in τ σ∆x space. Here τ is defined
as the total impact coefficient, that is τit = τ0,i + τ1 πitT + τ2 σ∆xit . Figure 2 provides a
scatter plot of τ̂ vs. σ∆x , for Canada, the United States and the United Kingdom,
where τ̂t is the predicted impact coefficient from equation (7) fit with IMF money data.
The subtle negative marginal effects of nominal volatility on the impact coefficient is
apparent in this scatter plots, however, it is clear that the difference between countries
has far more to do with the intercept than the slope. One can imagine a line fit through
the means of the plotted data as having an almost vertical slope, whereas the within
country slopes are closer to horizontal.
17
–Draft–
5
Discussion and Conclusion
The framework presented above successfully deals with many of the complications that
have plagued the empirical literature on nominal rigidities. The method makes use
of the suggestion by Defina (1991) that allows measures of nominal variability and
trend inflation to vary over time, but increases efficiency to circumvent the problematic
multicollinearity that has made inference in previous studies difficult. Because this
method estimates the marginal effects using only within country variation, it provides
more compelling evidence that the theoretical relationships exist at the country level
than estimates based on cross-country variation.
This paper has also provided evidence that the use of nominal GDP as a proxy for
the money supply effects the statistical results. When the IMF’s measure of money
was used the results strongly supported the Lucas imperfect information theory. The
coefficient for which Lucases theory has implications had the was significant in the
hypothesized direction, and the coefficients that have implications unique to the sticky
price theory were not. When nominal GDP was used a proxy for money, estimated
coefficients from equation (7) were all as predicted by the sticky price theory, however
the restrictions were strongly rejected. Without the restrictions imposed the results
gave weak evidence in favor of the sticky price theory (Table 2(a)).
The result that τ0 and β0 cannot be restricted to be constant across countries indicates a further problem with past uses of the two-stage method. The two stage method
the assumption that those parameters are fixed across countries is being made. This
is related to the difference between measuring within and between country variation.
Because the impact and persistence parameters have different intercepts in each country, fitting a regression with the restriction of non-unique intercepts will bias estimated
marginal effects.
The empirical specification used in the present study posits that the persistence
18
–Draft–
and impact coefficients are simple linear functions. The results of this study would be
strengthened by considering non-linear specifications. Many past authors have considered quadratic specifications, however such specifications have little more theoretical
grounding than do linear ones. Akerlof et al. pointed out that the impact parameter
should be a hyperbolic function of mean inflation and nominal volatility. Implementation of such a specification in the panel data framework would be beneficial. Furthermore, the route to distinguishing between hybrid and pure sticky price models may
be through the implied functional forms. These forms are likely to be non-linear and
rely on asymptotic properties for inference. The substantial improvement in degrees of
freedom offered by the panel data framework will be of great benefit in such a study.
It would be prudent for replications and extensions of this study to be done using
monetary data. This study has indicated that the results when nominal GDP is used as
a proxy may be misleading. However, further studies using different measures of money
and different samples would be helpful in determining how generalizable this result is.
References
Akerlof, George, Andrew Rose, and Janet Yellen (1988) ‘The New-Keynesian
economics and the inflation-output trade-off: comments and discussion.’ Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity 1, 66–75
Ball, Laurence, Gregory Mankiw, and David Romer (1988) ‘The New-Keynesian
economics and the inflation-output trade-off.’ Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 1, 1–65
Barnett, Richard, and Merwan Engineer (2001) ‘When is price-level targeting a good
idea?’ In ‘Price Stability and the Long-Run Target for Monetary Policy’ (Bank of
Canada) pp. 101–149
19
–Draft–
Calvo, Guillermo (1983) ‘Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework.’ Journal
of Monetary Economics 12, 383–398
Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler (1999) ‘The science of monetary
policy: A new keynesian perspective.’ Journal of Economic Literature
73(4), 1661–1707
DeFina, Robert H. (1991) ‘International evidence on a new keynesian theory of the
inflation-output trade-off.’ Journal of Money Credit and Banking 23, 410–422
Frankel, Jeffrey, David Parsley, and Shang-Jin Wei (2005) ‘Slow passthrough around
the world: A new import for developing countries?’ NBER working paper No. 11199
Goldfajn, Ilan, and Srgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang (2000) ‘The pass-through from
depreciation to inflation: A panel study.’ Banco Central do Brasil working paper 5
Lucas, Robert (1972) ‘Expectations and the neutrality of money.’ Journal of
Economic Theory 4, 103–124
(1973) ‘Some international evidence on output-inflation trade-offs.’ American
Economic Review 63, 326–334
Svensson, Lars (1999) ‘Price-level targeting versus inflation targeting: A free lunch?’
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 31(3), 277–295
Vestin, David (2006) ‘Price-level versus inflation targeting.’ Journal of Monetary
Economics
20
Download