Sound Policies or Good Fortune: What Drives Emerging Market Spreads? Philipp Maier and Garima Vasishtha∗ Draft Do not cite without permission February 2008 Abstract Since 2002, spreads on emerging market sovereign debt have fallen to historical lows. Given the close links between sovereign spreads, capital flows to emerging markets, and economic growth, understanding the factors driving sovereign spreads is very important. This paper uses factor analysis to study the extent to which emerging market bond spreads – measured by JP Morgan’s EMBI Global index – are driven by global factors, such as global liquidity or commodity prices, as opposed to country-specific macroeconomic fundamentals. Our results show that a common factor explains a substantial portion of the co-movements in emerging market spreads in the last decade. This factor is closely linked to global financial conditions, as well as to energy- and non-energy commodity prices. This factor, however, is not responsible for the reduction in EMBI spreads. Instead, emerging markets have benefited considerably from better macroeconomic policies. Therefore, a reversal of the benign global economic environment need not have a substantial negative impact on financing conditions for emerging markets. Bank index: Development economics, financial stability, international topics Keywords: Sovereign spreads, emerging markets, factor analysis JEL codes: E43, F34, F47, G12, G15 ∗ Corresponding author, Bank of Canada, International Department, 234 Wellington, Ottawa, ON, K1A0G9, Canada, email: gvasishtha@bankofcanada.ca. The views expressed are the authors’ and need not reflect those of the Bank of Canada. Helpful input from Carlos de Resende is acknowledged. Comments on earlier versions have also been given by Larry Schembri and Robert Lavigne. Research assistance has been provided by Brian DePratto, Andre Poudrier, and Christine Tse. All remaining errors are ours. 1 1 Introduction The role and importance of emerging markets have changed substantially over the recent years. Emerging markets are no longer recipients of capital inflows, as they were in the 1970s and 1980s. In the face of rising energy and non-energy commodity prices, emerging markets have accumulated large current account surpluses and, in many cases, substantial holdings of foreign reserves. This has brought important benefits: Many of the past problems of these economies were caused by their dependence on volatile capital flows from the developed world to finance current-account deficits, as exemplified by the Asian and the Russian crises. Today, however, the large importers of capital are industrialized countries, and capital is supplied by emerging markets. To understand this shift in the global economy, a thorough understanding of emerging markets is required. Perhaps the biggest sign of change has been in the emerging debt markets. The traditional gauge of risk of emerging market debt is JP Morgan’s ‘Emerging Market Bond Index Global’ (EMBI Global), which tracks the price of dollar-denominated emerging market debt since the early 1990s. In 2007, the EMBI Global yielded the thinnest spread ever recorded over riskless U.S. Treasury bonds. Two, not mutually exclusive, explanations for this are: first, many emerging markets have made improvements in macroeconomic fundamentals and have undertaken structural reforms. This has reduced the risk of default, and because investors demand a lower risk premium, spreads on emerging market debt have fallen. The second explanation acknowledges the improvements in macroeconomic frameworks, but also points to the fact that risk spreads have fallen for virtually all asset classes, not just for emerging market debt. This could indicate that other factors besides country fundamentals are responsible for the sharp fall in risk premia. Against this backdrop, we examine factors influencing movements in emerging market yield spreads. We use principal factor analysis to examine the degree to which spreads for different countries exhibit similar patterns. Our study is not the first to apply principal factor analysis on bond spreads. Slok and Kennedy (2004) use principal components analysis – a technique related to principal factor analysis – to identify a common trend in risk premia on stock and bond markets in developed and emerging market countries since the beginning of 1988. They find that their principal components are strongly correlated with the OECDs leading indicator of industrial production, and a measure of global liquidity. McGuire and Schrijvers (2003) use principal components 2 to study common developments in risk premia in 15 emerging market countries over the period 1997 to 2003. The first factor, which the authors call ‘investor risk aversion’, explains the bulk of the common variation.1 Hund and Lesmond (2007) show that liquidity is an important component of emerging market yield spreads. These authors look at both corporate and sovereign emerging market bonds, and use various regression techniques – although no principal factor analysis – to test for liquidity risk. Lastly, the study closest to ours is Ciarlone et al. (2007). These authors use factor analysis to examine emerging markets spreads, and find that the common factor is able to explain a substantial share of the reduction in emerging market spreads over the past few years. We improve upon their approach in a number of ways. First, our data set includes more countries. Second, we employ richer empirical specifications, using panel data, as well as country-specific regressions with instrumental variables and Seemingly Unrelated Regressions. Third, we also estimate principal factors and empirical models for different geographical regions. To preview the conclusions, we find evidence that emerging markets spreads can be explained by an exogenous common factor, which we can link to global financial developments and the evolution of energy- and non-energy commodity prices. These developments are typically outside the direct control of emerging markets. However, while the common factor has contributed to the fall in spreads, its contribution is relatively small. Instead, our results suggest that the most important elements driving the compression in spreads are better macroeconomic policies (primarily lower inflation and lower debt). These findings provide an explanation why emerging markets remained largely unaffected by the recent turmoil in global financial markets. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents stylized facts on emerging markets’ sovereign bond spreads during 1994-2007, and outlines possible explanations for the compression observed during this period. Section 3 outlines the empirical methodology. Section 4 presents the estimation results, and section 5 discusses the key findings. 1 We discuss ‘risk aversion’ in section 2.2. The Deutsche Bundesbank (2004) calculates a risk aversion indicator, employing principal component analysis using risk premia on investment and speculative grade corporate bonds in developed countries, and sovereign risk premia for some Asian and Latin American countries. 3 EMBI Global Composite EMBI Global Asia EMBI Global Europe EMBI Global Latin America 0 500 Basispoints 1000 1500 2000 2500 EMBI spreads 1997m7 2000m1 2002m7 2005m1 2007m7 Figure 1: EMBI spreads 2 Spreads on Emerging Market Bonds Spreads for emerging market countries have fallen considerably over the last 5 years. The most comprehensive measure of sovereign debt issued by emerging markets is JP Morgan’s EMBI Global (henceforth: EMBI).2 According to the EMBI, sovereign spreads have fallen for emerging market economies in virtually all regions of the world, be it Latin America, Europe or Asia (see figure 1). In 2007, the EMBI fell to the lowest level ever recorded. The compression in sovereign spreads has occurred in an environment characterized by structural changes in emerging market financing. A shift to longer maturities, lower external debt levels, and better debt management policies has led many EMs to reduce their debt servicing burdens. The consequences of these developments are impressive. Emerging markets were thought of suffering from ‘original sin’ less then 10 years ago, i.e. they were unable of borrowing in their own currency, because they had defaulted on their debt previously (Eichengreen et al., 2003b). Now, they are increasingly issuing debt in local currency (The Economist, February 24th, 2007). The ability to issue debt in local currency is a welcome shift, because if countries are only 2 The EMBI Global index, produced by JP Morgan-Chase, tracks total returns for US-dollar denominated debt instruments issued by EM sovereign and quasi-sovereign entities, like Brady bonds, loans, Eurobonds. The use of secondary market bond spreads is in line with the growing literature on sovereign spreads. It avoids the critique of Eichengreen and Mody (1998) that studies based on primary spreads suffer from selectivity bias, as the creditworthiness of primary issuers will vary with financing conditions. 4 CA/GDPa Debtb /GDP Reserves/ST debt Fiscal balance/GDP GDP growth Inflation Average -1.80 32.20 145.90 -3.10 7.50 23.50 Year 1996 Min -26.80 14.20 10.00 -20.20 -8.00 0.20 Max 12.70 133.20 763.20 7.20 12.20 123.00 Average 1.70 28.80 400.10 -2.40 5.20 5.90 Year 2005 Min -16.90 15.90 23.40 -8.10 1.80 Max 15.90 176.70 1353.50 10.00 9.00 16.60 Source: International Monetary Fund (2007) a Current account-to-GDP ratio; b Total debt (i.e. public + private debt) Table 1: Macroeconomic fundamentals in Emerging Markets able to borrow in foreign currency, a currency crisis almost automatically becomes a dollar-denominated debt crisis (Eichengreen et al., 2003a).3 Does this mean that emerging markets have entered a virtuous circle, in which lower credit spreads lead to lower debt servicing costs, which lower the probability of sovereign default, hence improving country ratings, leading to lower spreads and, consequently, lowering debt servicing costs etc.? To answer this question, an understanding of the factors driving the reduction in emerging market spreads is required. The literature has identified two main, not mutually exclusive, explanations for the decline in emerging market spreads: improvements in country fundamentals, and beneficial global (financing) conditions. Each of these is briefly discussed below. 2.1 Improvements in macroeconomic fundamentals Since the Asian crisis, many emerging markets have made improvements in macroeconomic fundamentals and undertaken growth-enhancing structural reforms. Key economic policy changes include the switch to more flexible exchange rate regimes, lower inflation through the adoption of inflation targeting (and the associated increased antiinflationary credibility), strong current account performance, stronger fiscal performance, and – in many cases – accumulation of foreign exchange reserves (see table 1). Also, some countries have benefited from better managing the fiscal impact of volatile commodity prices. 3 Issuing debt in local currency has the additional advantage that it increases liquidity and resilience of local debt markets. Government securities are often viewed as benchmarks for corporate bonds, and by issuing local currency debt and developing local financial markets, governments can help allow local companies to borrow for longer periods and at better terms. 5 In addition, these improvements of macroeconomic fundamentals are often accompanied by better and more timely data provision (International Monetary Fund, 2007). This allows investors to better evaluate a country’s riskiness. Taken together, improved country ratings reflect better economic policies, and have thus contributed to the compression in sovereign spreads. 2.2 Favourable global (financial) conditions The second explanation argues that emerging markets benefit from low spreads not (primarily) because of better economic policies, but because global and cyclical factors have been favourable. More specifically, it has been argued that high prices for energy- and non-energy commodities (figure 2), and favourable global financial conditions – characterized by low interest rates and low stock market volatility in advanced economies (figure 3), as well as an abundant supply of liquidity – have fuelled the compression of spreads. Hence, it has been argued that the compression in emerging market spreads is primarily driven by exogenous factors, such as changes in risk appetite of international investors.4 Global financial conditions can effect emerging market spreads, because they capture two elements: first, the risk stemming from the risk of default; second, the degree of willingness or ability of investors to accept a risky asset. The latter may be unrelated to the actual default risk of that country, and may reflect factors like the financial position of investors or liquidity risk in financial markets at that time. Put differently, even if investors’ degree of risk aversion and their expectations about countries’ default risks are constant, the share of risky emerging market assets in an investor’s portfolio is not likely to be constant, due e.g. to portfolio constraints.5 4 See e.g. Herrera and Perry (2002); Grandes (2003); Garcia Herrero and Ortiz (2004); Calvo and Talvi (2004); and Rozada and Yeyati (2006). 5 In our view, there is a distinction between investors’ ability or willingness to hold risk and ‘risk aversion’. Risk aversion is a coefficient in the consumers utility function. This parameter is part of the intrinsic profile of economic agents, and we assume that it is unchanged over time. For a given risk aversion, the willingness or the ability to hold a risky asset can change, reflecting – for instance – changes in the composition of an investor’s balance sheet, which make holding risky assets more or less attractive at different points in time (see also Gai and Vause, 2004; Coudert and Gex, 2006). As an aside, note that improvements in country fundamentals and external developments, such as prices for commodities, are easy to measure. Measuring changes in investors’ ability and willingness to hold risk is not straightforward. Ciarlone et al. (2007) propose to use the VIX as a proxy for uncertainty on financial markets. In our empirical analysis we follow their approach. Alternatively, various third-party sources have developed indicators, notably: the Deutsche Bank Currency Risk Appetite Index, the Lehman Brothers’ Risk Aversion Index, and JP Morgan’s Liquidity and Risk Premia Index. There is also JP Morgan’s Liquidity, Credit and Volatility Index, which aggregates two series capturing liquidity, two risk premia indicators, and three measures of market volatility (Coudert and Gex, 2006). This last index has also been used to study changes in risk aversion during financial crises 6 1997q1 7 35 6 5 4 15 1999q3 2002q1 2004q3 1997q1 2007q1 1999q3 10Y US Treasury Bond(right axis) 2002q1 2004q3 2007q1 Figure 3: Financial conditions (US long-term interest rates, VIX) Figure 2: Oil and commodity price index 2.3 VIX (left axis) 3 10 0 50 20 100 20 40 150 25 60 200 30 Commodity price index (right axis) 250 80 Oil price (left axis) Implications These two explanations have very different implications for policymakers. Firstly, if global financial developments caused the compression in emerging markets spreads, they could fall below levels that would adequately cover risk.6 Secondly, a high sensitivity of emerging market spreads to developments in advanced economies could imply that in the event of an upturn in these rates, the cost of financing for emerging markets can rise substantially. To distinguish between those two explanations we employ the largest, most diverse data set for emerging countries for which consistent data on internationally traded sovereign bonds is available (the EMBI Global). By covering different geographical regions, as well as a mix of commodity-exporting and commodity-importing countries, we can isolate global factors from country-specific developments. The key tool we use is factor analysis. 3 Methodology: Factor analysis Factor analysis is a statistical technique used to reduce the dimensionality of data, and to detect structure in relationships between variables. Its aim is to identify factors that account for most of the variations in the covariance or correlation matrix of the data. Underlying this technique is the premise that unobservable internal characteristics in emerging markets (see Dungey et al, 2003). 6 A similar development may have occurred prior to the Asian financial crisis of the 1990s, see Kamin and Kleist (1999). 7 (or attributes) exist, in which the sample elements differ. These characteristics are commonly referred to as ‘latent factors’ or ‘internal variables’, and are assumed to account for the variation and co-variation (or correlation) across a range of observed phenomena. A reason why emerging markets spreads could contain a common factor is found in the immunization theory (Macauley, 1938; Fisher and Weil, 1971), which claims that there exists only one factor of uncertainty in the economy (and that this factor has the same impact on all rates in the economy, irrespective of their maturity). This concept should hold for different interest rates within one economy, but also between economies, provided that we can sufficiently quantify factors such as currency risk.7 Formally, factor analysis stipulates that p observed random variables can be expressed as linear functions of m hypothetical common factors (m < p), plus an error term. Consider x1 , x2 , .....x p random variables and f1 , f2 , ..... fm factors, then x1 = λ11 f1 + λ12 f2 + ....... + λ1m fm + e1 x2 = λ21 f1 + λ22 f2 + ....... + λ2m fm + e2 . . x p = λ p1 f1 + λ p2 f2 + ....... + λ pm fm + e p (1) where λ jk are called factor loadings, and e j are error terms, also referred to as specific factors ( j = 1, 2, ....p; k = 1, 2, .....m). In this paper, the x0 s represent quarterly series of the levels of EMBI Global spreads, and the sample elements are given by twenty emerging markets. Our sample runs from 1998Q1 to 2007Q2. 8 In matrix form, equation (1) is given by: X = ΛF + E. 7 Perignon (2) et al. (2007) outline the limitations of analyzing the common factor structure in variables such as bond returns. Their argument is that a multi-country dataset of bond returns captures both local and common influences, and therefore tends to pick ‘too many’ factors. In our case, however, this concerns does not seem to hold, since we only identify two common factors. 8 Our sample comprises: Argentina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Columbia, Ecuador, Hungary, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Panama, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Russia, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, and Venezuela. 8 The following assumptions are underlying the factor model: E[e] = 0, E[ f ] = 0, E[x] = 0 (3) The first assumption is standard for error terms in most statistical models. The second assumption is generally made for convenience, without loss of generality. The third may or may not be true, and if it is not, then equation (2) can be modified to x = µ + Λ f + e, where E[x] = µ. Additional assumptions underlying the model are: E[ee0 ] = Ψ (diagonal) (4) 0 E[ f e ] = 0 (a matrix of zeros) (5) E[ f f 0 ] = Im (an identity matrix) (6) The first assumption states that the error terms e j , ek , j 6= k are uncorrelated. Thus, all of x which is due to common factors is contained in Λ f . The second assumption states that the common factors are uncorrelated with the specific factors, and the third assumption postulates that common factors are orthogonal. 4 Results We proceed as follows: The first step is to estimate a principal factor model. Having identified common factors, we employ regression analysis to identify their main drivers, and we compare the principal factor in emerging market spreads to principal factors found in other bond classes and to spreads for OECD countries to examine whether emerging market spreads follows similar or different patterns. In a second step, we use the principal factors in a panel setting. We start by pooling all countries together, then disaggregate the data into different geographical regions. Lastly, we check the robustness of our findings with country-specific regression analysis. 9 4.1 1 Principal factor analysis Estimating a principal factor model The first step of our analysis is to estimate a principal factor model. To determine how many principal factors should be retained, a common methodology is to plot the eigenvalues of the principal factors, starting with the largest ones (a so-called ‘screeplot’). This shows the relative importance of the principal factors. Typically, principal factors with an eigenvalue < 1 are discarded, as they contain little common information (the Kaiser-Guttman criterion). We start by estimating the principal factor model for all countries in our sample. The corresponding screeplot is given in the top left panel of figure 4. As can be seen, the Kaiser-Guttman criterion suggests that we should retain the first two principal factors. While our results indicate two principal factors, most previous studies suggest that one principal factor is enough to describe the co-movement in spreads series for emerging markets (see e.g. Ciarlone et al., 2007). To examine why our findings differ, we first estimate principal factor models for different regions separately. We split our sample into Latin American, European, and Rest-of-the-World countries.9 The remaining panels of figure 4 show screeplots for each region individually. We see that comovements in EMBI spreads within each of the geographical regions seem to be sufficiently captured by the first principal factor. Figure 5 shows the first and second principal factors for all countries, and each region estimated separately. While the first principal factor indicates a clear downward movement in all EMBI series, the second principal factor does not show a clear trend during the period under consideration. Before we proceed, note that data availability constrains the estimation of the principal factor model. For a number of countries, we have limited observations, as the EMBI data is not available for all countries during the period 1997-2006. Principal factor models are, however, restricted by the shortest sample available. This means that the principal factor for all countries can only be estimated for the period 1999Q2-2006Q1. By leaving out three countries (Chile, Hungary, and Thailand), we can increase the sample period to 1998Q1-2006Q4. As figure 6 reveals, the differences between the 9 The group ‘Rest of the World’ comprises the countries China, Malaysia, Morocco, the Philippines, Russia, South Africa, and Thailand. This means that we analyze all countries consistently covered by the EMBI Global, for which data is available for 1998-2007. 10 Screeplots Latin America Eigenvalues 2 4 0 0 Eigenvalues 5 10 6 15 All regions 0 5 10 Number 15 20 0 2 8 10 Eigenvalues 1 2 3 0 0 Eigenvalues 1 2 3 4 Rest of the world 4 Europe 4 6 Number 1 2 3 Number 4 5 1 2 3 Number 4 5 Figure 4: Screeplots by geographic region Principal factors by region Second factor 1997q1 All LA All LA Europe ROW Europe ROW 1999q3 2002q1 2004q3 -2 -2 -1 -1 0 Scores for factor 1 0 1 1 2 2 3 First factor 2007q1 1997q1 1999q3 2002q1 Figure 5: The first two principal factors per region 11 2004q3 2007q1 Principal factors Second principal factor 1997q1 Full sample 1999q3 Restricted sample 2002q1 2004q3 -2 -2 -1 -1 Scores for factor 1 0 1 Scores for factor 2 0 1 2 2 First principal factor 2007q1 1997q1 Full sample 1999q3 Restricted sample 2002q1 2004q3 2007q1 Restricted sample excludes Chile, Hungary, Thailand Figure 6: Full sample vs. restricted sample long and the short series are relatively small (correlation between the series is 0.995 for the first principal factor and 0.983 for the second principal factor). In light of the relatively small size of our sample, we therefore use the longer principal factor series for the estimations below. 2 What drives principal factors? Figure 4 indicates that EMBI spreads contain one, possibly two principal factors. Is it useful to retain the second principal factor? Although it is not always straightforward to interpret principal factors economically, it would be desirable if we had an intuition of what drives them. Table 2 provides correlations of the principal factors with key economic indicators. These correlations suggest that the first and second principal factor are driven by relatively similar variables. For a more formal analysis we employ a statistical model, considering each principal factor individually. Given that – by construction – the common factor reflects covariation in all emerging market economies in our sample, they should be related to global economic conditions, not regional variables. Key global economic indicators include prices for energy and non-energy commodities, global monetary conditions, 12 First principal factor Global LA E ROW Equity indices Nasdaq FTSE SP500 Interest rates 3M bond 10Y bond Yield curve Others Oil prices Commodity prices VIX Second principal factor Global LA E ROW -0.86 -0.64 -0.82 -0.88 -0.71 -0.86 0.42 0.78 0.58 -0.52 -0.09 -0.36 -0.90 -0.92 -0.95 -0.76 -0.91 -0.83 -0.81 -0.62 -0.77 -0.84 -0.81 -0.88 -0.68 -0.16 0.71 -0.72 -0.26 0.71 0.65 0.85 -0.45 -0.22 0.38 0.37 -0.87 -0.56 0.79 -0.86 -0.62 0.76 -0.68 -0.16 0.71 -0.83 -0.40 0.80 -0.89 -0.89 0.95 -0.87 -0.87 0.96 0.36 0.37 -0.22 -0.61 -0.59 0.72 -0.82 -0.83 0.83 -0.67 -0.69 0.56 -0.90 -0.89 0.91 -0.88 -0.89 0.84 Note: “Global” is the principal factor estimated over all countries (restricted sample); LA, E, and ROW denote principal factors for the regions Latin America, Europe, and the rest of the world, respectively. Table 2: Correlations of principal factors with key economic variables and stock market variables. We estimate: PFi,t = β1 + ∑ βk Xk,t + εi,t , i=1,2 (7) k whereby PFi,t denotes the first and second principal factor. Xk,t are a set of k exogenous variables which – according to other studies – have predictive power in explaining common factors. We use the following variables: • Financial indicators: the S&P 500, short- and long-term U.S. bonds (the 3 monthand 10 year-yield, respectively), and the VIX; • Natural resources: oil prices (in USD), and the IMF commodity price index. We check the stationarity of the principal factors, as well as the explanatory variables, using unit root tests (for all unit root tests, the alternative is a covariance-stationary autoregression with both a constant and a deterministic trend). The results of Augmented Dickey-Fuller tests are reported in table 3. As can be seen, presence of a unit root can be rejected for the first, but not for the second factor (and not for most of the regional principal factors). Also, presence of a unit root cannot be rejected for the explanatory 13 PF1 PF2 PF1LA PF1E PF1ROW PF2LA PF2E PF2ROW Oil SP500 10Y US 3M US VIX ADF -4.24 -0.88 -3.21 -1.28 -2.80 -0.78 -2.19 -2.53 -1.91 -1.67 -2.03 -1.74 -3.53 p-value 0.01 0.95 0.10 0.87 0.21 0.96 0.48 0.31 0.63 0.75 0.57 0.72 0.05 Lags 0 0 0 2 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 1 0 Obs. 35 35 31 30 35 31 31 34 40 40 40 39 40 PF1LA , PF1E , PF1ROW denote the first principal factor for Latin America, Europe, and the rest of the world, respectively; PF2LA , PF2E , PF2ROW are the second principal factors. Table 3: Unit root tests: principal factors and explanatory variables variables (possibly with the exception of the VIX). In order to ensure stationarity, we therefore carry out all estimates in first differences (year-over-year).10 We estimate equation (7) by OLS for the global and the regional principal factors separately.11 Consider the left part of table 4 first. The second and third column report regression results using the exogenous variables outlined above. We see that commodity prices, as well as financial variables,12 affect the principal factor. Qualitatively similar results are obtained for the oil price, instead of commodity prices. The fourth column reports the effects of a one-standard deviation shock of the explanatory variables on the first principal factor. As can be seen, financial variables dominate the effect of strong commodity prices. The interpretation of the second common factor is more complex. Factors related to 10 An alternative way is to test for cointegration between the principal factors and the explanatory variables (Engle and Granger, 1987). Following the procedure outlined in Johansen (1995), we find that the first principal factor is cointegrated with oil prices, the VIX, and short- and long-term U.S. interest rates. Hence, we could, in priciple, estimate e.g. an error-correction model (ECM). However, one of the assumptions underlying ECM’s is that a variable is fluctuating around a long-run trend. In our view, there is no sound economic basis why emerging market spreads should follow such a long-run trend. 11 We also estimated equation (7) using GMM, and obtained qualitatively similar results. LM tests for serial correlation of the residuals and White heteroskedasticity tests were passed. 12 Note that the literature does not find consistent results for the effects of U.S. interest rates or the slope of the U.S. yield curve on emerging market spreads. For example, Dooley at al. (1996) find that higher U.S. interest rates lead to higher emerging market spreads, while Eichengreen and Mody (1998) and McGuire and Schrijvers (2003) find a negative effect. 14 Constant Commodities SP500 10Y US VIX Obs. R2 PF1 -0.03 -0.01*** 0.00*** -0.52** 0.10*** 32 0.72 PF2 0.38** -0.01** 0.00 -0.10 0.08*** 32 0.62 Effect of 1 StDev shock on PF1 0.26 0.58 0.40 0.56 PF1 and PF2 denote the first and second global principal factor, respectively. Table 4: Regressions of the global principal factors uncertainty on the stock market do not seem to have large explanatory power. Overall, it is not clear that we can easily interpret the second factor, nor that including the second factor adds to our understanding. Given that the second factor barely passed the Kaiser-Guttman criterion, we decided to omit the second principal factor from most estimations. Note that this does not change the estimation results qualitatively, as we show in appendix A. 3 Comparing emerging markets spreads to other countries or assets classes To compare the degree of covariation in emerging markets spreads to movements in sovereign bonds of other countries or asset classes, we estimate principal factor models for (i) different U.S. asset classes, and (ii) sovereign bond interest rates for OECD countries. First, consider the principal factor in EMBI spreads to principal factors found in other asset classes. Figure 7 plots the two factors we found in EMBI spreads, and a factor found in different U.S. asset classes. To compute the latter, we included indices for the following asset classes: • Investment Grade bonds, • High Yield bonds, • and bonds rated AAA, AA, A, and BBB (all bond-equivalent yields-to-maturity). Given that these indices all cover U.S. indices – and, hence, U.S. denominated assets – we can compare the principal factors directly. We see that while spreads in 15 all asset classes have fallen, differences exist between emerging market bonds and U.S. asset classes, in particular in timing: the first principal factor in emerging market spreads seems to lag the development in U.S. asset classes by about a year. Second, we compare the principal factor for emerging market spreads to interest rates for sovereign bonds for OECD countries. We consider principal factors in shortand long-term interest rates (the 3-month and 10-year yields, respectively). If the compression in spreads is driven by benign global factors – such as high global liquidity – the fall should also be visible in interest rates of OECD economies.13 Data constraints – and the restriction that we do not want to include emerging market countries in our OECD sample to avoid ‘double counting’14 – leaves us with the following group of OECD countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom. We approximate the spread between OECD interest rates and U.S. rates by taking the difference of the 3-month and 10-year yields for each OECD countries, relative to the corresponding U.S. interest rate. As can be seen in figure 8, neither short-term, nor long-term interest rates in OECD countries follow the pattern found in emerging market economies, as the compression of interest rates did not coincide with the fall in interest rates of emerging markets. Taken together, the comparison of the emerging market factor with developments in U.S. asset markets, as well as for sovereign bond spreads in OECD countries, suggests that there are ‘distinct developments’ found in spreads for emerging markets. This provides a first indication that emerging markets’ spreads may not (only) be driven by global factors, but that improvements in macroeconomic fundamentals may matter. 4 Distinguishing between different classes of risk Additional insights can be gained from comparing principal factors in EMBI spreads across different degrees of risk.15 We divide the sample into countries that have – on average over the entire sample – a rating of BBB or better, and countries whose ratings 13 Ideally, all bonds would be denominated in U.S. dollars. However, most OECD countries issue debt in their own currency. This means that factors related to the stability of their currency could potentially affect these interest rates. However, we believe that this potential bias is small, because the principal factor methodology identifies covariation in all series, i.e. movements that prevail in all countries. 14 Poland, for instance, would be part of both the OECD sample and the emerging market group. 15 We thank Patrick McGuire for this suggestion. 16 2 2 1 0 Basispoints -1 1 Basispoints 0 -1 2 1 0 -1 2 1 0 -1 Factor 1 Emerging Markets (left axis) Factor 1 OECD 3M interest rates (left axis) 1997q1 1999q3 2002q1 2004q3 1997q1 2007q1 Figure 7: Principal factors for emerging markets and U.S. asset classes Constant Commodities SP500 10Y US VIX Obs. R2 1999q3 2002q1 -2 Factor 1 OECD 10Y interest rates (left axis) -2 Factor 1 U.S. bond classes (right axis) -2 -2 Factor 1 Emerging Markets (left axis) 2004q3 2007q1 Figure 8: Principal factor for emerging markets and OECD interest rates PF1 All countries -0.03 -0.01*** 0.00*** -0.52** 0.10*** 32 0.72 PF1 High risk 0.01 -0.01*** -0.51*** -0.51*** 0.11*** 32 0.74 PF 1 Low risk -0.23 0.00 -0.09 -0.09 0.07** 24 0.50 Table 5: Regression of the first principal factor by risk class is below BBB. We call them ‘Low risk’ and ‘High risk’ countries, respectively.16 Figure 9 shows the first principal factor estimated over all countries in our sample, and the low- and high-risk countries. As can be seen, the differences are small. Table 5 reports regressions of equation (7) by emerging market risk class. The second column shows the results for the principal factor estimated over all countries in our sample, and columns three and four show regressions for the principal factors for high- and low-risk countries, respectively. Differentiating between high- and lowrisk countries reveals differences: the principal factor for low-risk countries is only affected by volatility in U.S. equity markets (as measured by the VIX), whereas highrisk countries are also affected by commodity prices or the stance of U.S. monetary policy. This suggests that high-risk countries are more susceptible to foreign shocks than low-risk countries. 16 The low-risk group comprises Chile, Hungary, Malaysia, Poland, and Thailand; the high-risk group comprises Argentina, Brazil, Bulgaria, China, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Morocco, Panama, Peru, the Philippines, Russia, South Africa, Turkey, and Venezuela. 17 -2 -1 0 1 2 Principal factors by riskiness First principal factor All countries -3 First principal factor Low-risk countries First principal factor High-risk countries 1997q1 1999q3 2002q1 2004q3 2007q1 Figure 9: Principal factors for all countries, and low- and high-risk countries 5 Interpretation Taken together, the evidence from the principal factor model suggests that EMBI spreads contain a common factor, affected by financial market variables, as well as commodity prices. We found differences among emerging economies of different risk classes, and differences seem to exist between the common factor in emerging markets and other (U.S.) asset classes or OECD economies. This suggests that the principal factor in emerging markets reflects a common development in emerging markets, which is likely to be different than developments in other asset classes. Having estimated the principal factor model, table 6 reports factor loadings – the partial correlation of the EMBI series for each country with the principal component – and a measure of the uniqueness, i.e. the percentage of the variance in EMBI series in a country that can not be explained by the common factor (the flipside of uniqueness is communality, i.e. the share of variation that can be explained by the common factor) for the first factor. We see that the factor loadings are > 0.8 for most countries. This is an indication that the first factor could be a statistically important element in explaining EMBI spreads. In what follows, we test for this notion in a statistical model. 4.2 Panel regressions Having examined the factors driving the principal factor, we now turn to the question how important the principal factor is in explaining the compression of emerging market spreads. We first examine all countries in our sample jointly using panel estimation 18 Argentina Brazil Bulgaria Chile China Columbia Ecuador Hungary Malaysia Mexico Morocco Panama Peru Philippines Poland Russia S. Africa Thailand Turkey Venezuela Global principal factor Factor loadinga Uniquenessa -0.16 0.98 0.82 0.32 0.96 0.07 0.96 0.08 0.85 0.28 0.90 0.19 0.83 0.30 0.58 0.66 0.98 0.03 0.96 0.07 0.98 0.04 0.94 0.12 0.94 0.12 0.44 0.81 0.96 0.07 0.90 0.19 0.99 0.03 0.95 0.10 0.84 0.29 0.87 0.25 Regional principal factor Factor loadingb Uniquenessb 0.40 0.84 0.95 0.09 0.99 0.02 0.87 0.24 0.92 0.16 0.97 0.06 0.81 0.34 0.54 0.71 0.98 0.04 0.93 0.14 0.96 0.09 0.98 0.03 0.97 0.05 0.45 0.79 0.97 0.05 0.93 0.13 0.98 0.05 0.93 0.13 0.79 0.37 0.96 0.08 Table 6: Factor loadings and uniqueness, using global and regional principal factors techniques. Panel estimation has the advantage of pooling the data, which increases the size of the sample, and allows more precise estimation of common coefficients. 1 Unit root tests An assumption underlying conventional panel estimation techniques is that the data series are stationary. We evaluate stationarity based on the following four types of panel unit root tests: Levin, Lin and Chu (2002), Breitung (2000), Im, Pesaran and Shin (2003), and the two Fisher-type tests using ADF and PP tests presented in Maddala and Wu (1999) and Choi (2001). All tests have as null hypothesis the presence of a unit root. The alternative hypothesis for the Levin, Lin and Chu (2002) and Breitung (2000) tests is that the series does not contain a unit root; the alternative hypothesis for Im, Pesaran and Shin (2003) and Fisher-ADF and Fisher-PP is that some cross-sections are without unit root. We run all tests on the levels, and allow for intercept and trend. The results from the panel unit root tests are reported in table 7. As can be seen, 19 Common unit root Levin, Lin, Chu (2002) p-value Breitung (2000) p-value Levin, Lin, Chu (2002) p-value Breitung (2000) p-value Individual unit root Im, Pesaran, Shin (2003) p-value ADF - Fisher χ 2 p-value PP - Fisher χ 2 p-value Im, Pesaran, Shin (2003) p-value ADF - Fisher χ 2 p-value PP - Fisher χ 2 p-value a b EMBI 1.88 0.97 -0.01 0.50 GDP -1.65 0.05 2.00 0.98 EMBI -3.53 0.00 76.58 0.00 49.34 0.15 GDP -7.49 0.00 154.67 0.00 79.43 0.00 Budgeta 0.58 0.80 -1.32 0.09 ST debt -1.81 0.04 -4.13 0.00 Budgeta -6.29 0.00 215.32 0.00 835.70 0.00 ST debt -1.59 0.06 65.67 0.01 33.21 0.77 CPI -0.62 0.27 0.81 0.79 LT debt -2.80 0.00 -0.99 0.16 CPI -4.11 0.00 85.29 0.00 68.62 0.00 LT debt -2.51 0.01 200.32 0.00 67.97 0.00 Exports -3.01 0.00 -2.50 0.01 Reserves -1.08 0.14 0.22 0.59 Exports -2.78 0.00 293.20 0.00 261.48 0.00 Reserves -0.66 0.25 50.28 0.13 54.31 0.07 Fin. Dev.b -0.18 0.43 -1.29 0.10 XR -6.07 0.00 -5.28 0.00 Fin. Dev.b -1.12 0.13 58.46 0.03 75.45 0.00 XR -0.67 0.25 257.26 0.00 28.45 0.87 Budget deficit Financial development (bank credit-over-GDP Table 7: Panel unit root tests tests on levels, allowing for trends and intercepts for most series the results are not conclusive. Consider, for instance, the GDP growth series: while Levin, Lin and Chu (2002) is able to reject presence of a unit root at the 5 percent level, the Breitung (2000) test strongly indicates that the panel series contain a unit root. Given these mixed results, we decide to take first differences (year-over-year) of all series to ensure that all series are stationary. 2 Panel estimation: All countries Since our focus is on a specific set of countries, rather than drawing the countries randomly from a large population, econometric theory suggests that a fixed effects model is the appropriate specification.17 In the most general form, we estimate the 17 See Baltagi (1995). We also estimated a random effects model, but it was rejected by the Hausman test. 20 following specification: EMBIi,t = β1 + β2,i PFt + ∑ βk Xk,i,t + ∑ βl Yl,t + εi,t , k (8) l where EMBIi,t denotes the EMBI series for country i, and the first global principal factor is given by PFt . Xk,i,t are k country-specific exogenous variables, and Yl,t denotes l global variables – i.e. variables that are identical for all countries, such as the price of oil. εi,t is a normally-distributed error term. Note that equation (8) allows the intercept to vary between countries. This captures time-invariant country-specific effects, such as institutional features of the political system or the rule of law, which have not changed during our sample period. We ran regressions with the following country-specific and global variables (note that not all of them are included in all regressions). • Country-specific variables: Country ratings, GDP growth, inflation, the exchange rate against the U.S. dollar, and the ratios of short- and long-term debt-to-GDP, exports-to-GDP, reserves-to-GDP, the fiscal balance-to-GDP, and the ratio of bank credit-to-GDP as a proxy for financial development; in addition, we add two variables proxying structural policies: a dummy variable IT taking the value 1 when a country introduces inflation targeting, and to proxy the overall economic structure, we use the 2008 regulation index from the Heritage Foundation;18 • Global variables: Prices for natural resources (oil and non-energy commodity prices), the S & P500, the VIX, and world GDP growth.19 Lastly, we add a variable indicating when a country experienced a currency or banking crisis. This variable is defined as one during currency or banking or sovereign debt crises, and zero otherwise.20 Note that estimating the panel by ordinary least squares yields inconsistent estimates, if EMBI spreads and some of the macroeconomic variables are simultaneously determined. To test whether instrumental variables estimation 18 We also experimented with local stock market indices and variables proxying financial integration with the United States, but these did not have a significant impact. 19 U.S. short-and long-term interest rates were not significant at conventional levels. 20 Our dating of crisis periods is taken from Kaminsky (2003), Table 4. For countries that are not included in her sample, we created our own crises dummies based on information contained in IMF country reports. 21 Constant PF (global) Rating GDP CPI LT debt ST debt Exports Reserves XR Deficit Fin. Dev. Crisis Regulation IT SP500 VIX Oil World GDP Obs. Countries R2 j-test (p-value) Exogeneity (p-value)a Model 1 0.69*** 2.21*** 3.56*** Model 2 1.39*** 2.05*** 0.06*** 0.11*** 19.28*** 12.59* -165.69*** 0.77 0.00 1.00 6.08** 8.00*** Model 3 3.43 2.05*** 0.06*** 0.13*** 17.81*** 13.68** -162.31*** 0.24 0.00 1.00 6.14** 7.20*** -0.03 -2.18** 599 20 0.45 0.00 0.21 448 19 0.43 0.01 0.61 448 19 0.44 0.00 0.84 Model 4 -0.82 1.42* 0.07*** 0.13*** 17.44*** 11.25 -170.31*** 0.67 0.00 1.31** 5.08* 7.65*** 0.04 -2.19** -0.01* -0.22 0.07 6.87 448 19 0.46 0.00 0.85 */**/*** denotes significance at the 10/5/1 percent level a Davidson-MacKinnon test of exogeneity Table 8: Panel regressions using a global principal factor, dependent variable: EMBI spreads was necessary, we ran a Davidson-MacKinnon (1993) test. The results indicate that instrumental variables techniques are required. We therefore use two-stage least-squares, and instrument GDP growth, inflation, the exchange rate, ratings, the ratios of the budget deficit, bank credit, long- and short-term debt, exports- and reserves to GDP by their lagged values (2 lags). The results of the instrumental variable estimations are given in table 8. We estimate models with different sets of country-specific variables. Model 1 in the second column uses the principal factor and country ratings, which proxy country fundamentals.21 We see that a better rating – which translates into a lower value of the rating 21 The ratings are from Standard and Poor’s. A lower value indicates a better rating, i.e. an AAA-rating 22 variable – is associated with a larger fall in EMBI spreads. Model 2 uses more detailed country-specific exogenous variables. Changes in emerging market spreads are positively related to GDP, inflation, short- and long-term debt, the degree of financial developments, and macroeconomic crises – loosely speaking, higher volatility in macroeconomic fundamentals translates into higher spreads. The size of the budget deficit and reserve holdings – both as ratios to GDP – are insigificant. Lastly, the negative coefficient on the export-to-GDP ratio suggests that large falls in exports can drive up EMBI spreads. Model 3 adds two variables that signal structural macroeconomic policy changes: a variable indicating the introduction of inflation targeting (IT ), and the regulation index from the Heritage Foundation (in our instrumental variables estimation, we use the property rights and corruption indices from the Heritage Foundation as instruments for the regulation index). A higher value of the regulation index indicates less government interference, which is traditionally believed to be beneficial for economic development. According to model 3, introduction of inflation targeting lowers EMBI spreads, whereas the proxy for regulation is insignificant. Lastly, model 4 adds global variables, such as the VIX, the S&P500, oil prices, and world GDP growth. These variables are added as a robustness check, but we would not expect them to be significant at conventional levels, given that the effects of global developments should be captured by our principal factor (at the same time, significance for the principal factor can be expected to weaken, because of multicollinearity). As expected, they are largely insignificant. 3 Panel estimation: Data disaggregated by region An alternative way to estimate equation (8) is to use the regional principal factors derived above, i.e. to estimate: EMBIi,t = β1 + β2,i PFj,t + ∑ βk Xk,i,t + ∑ βl Yl,t + εi,t , k (9) l whereby the principal factor for region j is given by PFj,t . We report estimates for variations of models 3 and 4 in columns 2-3 (table 9). Comparing these results to table 8 we see that by and large, both give relatively similar results qualitatively. Next, we escorresponds to a value of 1; a D-rating is given by a value of 23. 23 Constant PF (regional) GDP CPI LT debt ST debt Exports Reserves XR Deficit Fin. Dev. Crisis Regulation IT SP500 VIX Oil World GDP Obs. Countries R2 j-test (p-value) Exogeneity (p-value)a All regions pooled Model 3a Model 4a 0.34 1.86 1.03* 1.00 0.08*** 0.08*** 0.17*** 0.16*** 18.39*** 18.88*** 10.73 9.63 -104.38* -141.81** -0.42 -1.07 -0.00** 0.00 0.61 0.96 5.82* 4.82 7.57*** 7.88*** 0.05 0.01 -3.49*** -3.24*** -0.01 -0.11 0.03 -12.10 422 418 19 19 0.43 0.44 0.00 0.00 0.59 0.67 Estimation by region (Model 3b) LA Europe ROW 9.95* -9.66*** 2.80 0.73 -0.93 0.88*** 0.08** 0.05 -0.09** 0.03 0.20*** 0.03 46.90*** 3.18 -0.69 96.23* 11.03 1.51 -896.57** 133.72* -44.05 -47.23** -0.85 0.27 0.00 -0.13 0.36*** 3.09 0.59 6.66 3.26 15.85*** 1.63 10.98** 13.74*** 0.94 -0.13 0.17** -0.06 0.10 -3.76 -0.55 189 8 0.56 0.00 0.58 96 5 0.73 0.02 0.00 137 6 0.56 0.00 0.38 */**/*** denotes significance at the 10/5/1 percent level a Davidson-MacKinnon test of exogeneity Table 9: Panel regressions using regional principal factors, dependent variable: EMBI spreads timate equation (8) for each region separately. These estimates are reported in columns 5-7 of table 9. Keeping in mind that the sample size drops considerably when using regional principal factors, which increases the standard errors and makes it harder to find statistically significant estimates, our results are reasonably robust across specifications. Lastly, we use the distinction between ‘low risk’ and ‘high risk’ countries introduced above, and estimate model 3 and 4 for each group of countries separately (table 10). The key difference between different risk classes is that ‘high risk’ countries seem to be more susceptible to global economic developments: whereas the principal factor is significant for high-risk countries, emerging market spreads for low-risk countries 24 seem to be driven by economic fundamentals. Including the global variables separately (right part of table 10) does not change this. 4.3 Country-specific regressions A potential drawback of panel regressions is the implicit assumption that countries behave in a sufficiently similar way. By estimating a single coefficient for each independent variable for all countries, panel estimations cannot account for heterogeneous effects of, say, inflation or debt-to-GDP ratios between countries. By running countryspecific regressions, we can examine whether the key conclusions from the panel regressions hold for all countries alike. We start with the following specification: EMBIt = β1 + β2 PFt + ∑ β j X j,t + ∑ βkYk,t + εt . j (10) k As before, each country’s EMBI is given by EMBIt ; X j,t denote j country-specific variables, Yk,t indicate k global variables, and εt is a normally-distributed error term. We estimate this regression for each country separately. To avoid endogeneity, we estimate equation (10) with instrumental variables, whereby we instrument all country-specific variables using lagged values (for the results we report we included two lags, but we also ran separate regressions with one lag). Results are reported in table 11. At first glance, it is apparent that considerable heterogeneity exists between countries. Also, due to the short sample size, it is not straightforward to get significant estimates (this issue is shared with other studies, see e.g. Ciarlone et al., 2007). Broadly speaking, we find that the first principal factor is statistically significant. Debt variables continue to be important, and it is also apparent that the effects of reserve accumulation or higher export-to-GDP ratios seem to differ between countries. 5 Discussion Since 2002, emerging market spreads have fallen to historically low levels. This has prompted academics and policymakers to investigate the sustainability of these favourable developments. In theory, spreads could fall because of ‘push’ or ‘pull’ factors, reflecting benign developments in global financial and commodity markets, and/or 25 Constant PFa GDP CPI LT debt ST debt Exports Reserves XR Deficit Fin. Dev. Crisis Regulation IT SP500 VIX Oil World GDP Obs. Countries R2 j-test (p-value) Exogeneity (p-value)b Model 3 High risk Low risk 4.85** 4.57 0.82*** 0.00 -0.06** 0.05* -0.02 0.13*** -0.27 24.92*** 1.04 13.72 1.27 -238.59** -2.37* -13.66 0.00** 0.00 0.09 3.72 -0.27 21.82*** 0.40 16.65*** -0.10** -0.06 0.62 -2.15 113 5 0.45 0.00 0.25 278 14 0.54 0.01 0.56 Model 4 High risk Low risk 2.83 4.91 0.85*** 0.00 -0.11*** 0.05* 0.00 0.13*** -0.44 23.86*** 1.33 17.74 3.35 -259.93** -0.88 -14.01 0.00*** 0.00 -0.03 3.27 1.10 22.67** 0.08 16.09*** -0.06* -0.08 0.10 -1.88 0.00 -0.01 0.04 -0.08 0.02 -0.01 22.25 29.93 113 278 5 14 0.60 0.55 0.00 0.01 0.16 0.47 */**/*** denotes significance at the 10/5/1 percent level a The principal factor reflects the group of countries, i.e. we use the principal factor derived for high-risk (low-risk) countries for the group of high-risk (low-risk) countries. b Davidson-MacKinnon test of exogeneity Table 10: Panel regressions using regional principal factors, dependent variable: EMBI spreads 26 Table 11: Country-specific regressions 27 Argentina 1.44 6.03 0.06 -0.11 137.40** -901.79*** 8254.69 197.29 -45.24 30 0.81 Morocco -0.86 1.89*** 0.11 -0.05 -1.44 7.63 246.73 3.08 -1.33 30 0.84 Coefficient Constant PF GDP CPI LT debt ST debt Exports Reserves XR Obs. R2 Coefficient Constant PF GDP CPI LT debt ST debt Exports Reserves XR Obs. R2 Panama 0.04 1.04*** 0.49** 0.55*** -46.49** 549.85* 5413.71 -24.75*** 0.00 28 0.75 Brazil 0.18 4.01** -0.07 -0.06 3.39 17.45 622.57 -10.82 -5.97 30 0.77 Peru 0.30 2.75*** -0.07 0.15* -1.91 -19.97 -67.87 2.61 3.84** 30 0.86 Bulgaria 1.16* 0.54 -0.04 -0.20* 5.36*** 15.99*** -128.75** -11.09*** 4.79* 30 0.4 Philippines 0.04 0.67 0.09 -0.11 -6.40*** -1.19 258.55** -12.21*** -0.08 29 0.86 Chile 0.44* 0.65*** 0.01 0.06* 1.21 1.60 -37.74** -0.28 0.00 27 0.76 Poland 0.99** 0.82* -0.03 0.05 -0.43 -6.84 -29.93 1.86 1.85 18 0.88 China -0.20 0.26*** 0.05 0.05 -8.96 36.17 -56.84 -1.41 -1.51 30 0.8 Russia 0.23 -1.29 0.05 0.12* 10.04 -55.85* 469.88 6.66 -1.83* 30 0.93 Columbia -1.00* 3.40*** -0.13* -0.15 -3.66 -103.15** 25.83 -9.95 0.00 30 0.87 S. Africa 0.31 1.55*** -0.28** -0.09** 82.21*** -80.65* 78.45 61.59* -1.08** 30 0.79 Ecuador 0.62 9.17** 0.28* -1.16 -268.84 1369.67 19758.34 -1018.57 -0.01 12 0.99 Thailand -0.65 0.01 -0.03 0.17** -1.90*** 2.75* -12.90 -0.76 0.15 27 0.94 Hungary -0.39*** 0.12 0.04 -0.03 -0.01 1.14 32.81*** -1.18** -0.01** 27 0.55 Turkey 0.91 2.79*** -0.15*** 0.00 5.93 5.03 -378.64* 0.80 8.19* 28 0.77 Malaysia -1.15*** 0.60*** -0.16*** -0.22 -10.46*** 7.40*** 29.50*** -0.17 -1.84 30 0.92 Venezuela 1.11 2.22*** -0.01 0.08 19.60 179.06 -102.56 -47.64*** 0.00 29 0.8 Mexico -0.48 1.50*** -0.01 0.02 28.14*** -210.87** 533.49** 19.43 -0.63*** 30 0.95 sound country fundamentals, driven by structural reforms and better macroeconomic policies. Which of the two factors have been more important? While benign conditions in global financial and commodity markets can reverse very quickly, country fundamentals typically do not deteriorate ‘over night’. Thus, it is important to understand the reasons for the compression in spreads, as this can provide information about the sustainability of benign financing conditions for emerging markets. We have conducted a principal factors analysis to study EMBI spreads. By extracting principal factors from EMBI spreads, we estimate the degree of co-movement between all countries in our sample. As countries differ in economic developments, the principal factor captures global conditions, as opposed to country-specific economic fundamentals. We find that commodity prices, as well as conditions on financial markets are key variables driving the principal factor (these factors drive the global, as well as the regional, principal factors). We use this principal factor in panel and country-specific regressions to analyze the degree to which the fall in EMBI spreads is driven by better macroeconomic policies. Our results indicate that the principal factor is statistically important in explaining the compression in spreads. But how important is the principal factor economically? The second column of table 12 summarizes the results of panel model 3b in terms of the effects of a one-standard deviation shock to the exogenous variables. The reductions in inflation and long-term debt have the biggest effect, followed by higher export-to-GDP ratios. All three can be thought of as better macroeconomic fundamentals, as all three reduce vulnerability to external shocks. In contrast, the benefits from global conditions – proxied by the principal factor – seem relatively small. This suggests that the principal factor has been a less important element in the reduction in EMBI spreads, or put differently: our results lend support to the hypothesis that better policies were a key factor in allowing emerging markets to finance themselves at favourable rates. If emerging market spreads are primarily driven by macroeconomic fundamentals, these results could provide an explanation why emerging markets have hardly been affected by recent turmoil in the financial sector. Note, however, two caveats. Firstly, as the country-specific results have shown, the benefits from better macroeconomic policies vary considerably between countries. Secondly, while we find a clear link between the principal factor and benign global conditions – i.e. high energy- and non-energy commodity prices, low volatility in stock markets, and low (U.S.) interest rates – it is not entirely clear that the impact of 28 All regions Model 3 Model 4 Global conditions PF (global) 1.38 0.96 SP500 2.14 VIX 1.19 Oil 0.53 World GDP 0.09 Macroeconomic fundamentals GDP 1.15 1.22 CPI 11.82 12.46 LT debt 5.18 5.07 ST debt 0.99 0.81 Exports 2.56 2.68 Reservesa 0.02 0.06 XRa 0.36 0.25 Deficita 0.51 0.67 Fin. Dev. 1.33 1.10 Crisis 1.91 2.02 Regulation 0.34 0.56 IT 1.00 1.01 a Effect not statistically significant Table 12: Effects of a one-standard deviation shock to global and country-specific factors on EMBI spreads these benign conditions occurs only through the principal factor. To some extent, such additional effects were captured in our specification 4b, when we added the S&P 500, the VIX and oil prices as additional exogenous variables. The third column of table 12 shows the effects of a one-standard deviation shock to the exogenous variables using panel model 4b. The magnitude of the (additional) effect of, say, oil seems small (and is not even statistically significant). Still, it is probably easier for emerging markets to reduce and restructure their debt, if fiscal revenues are high because of high oil prices. How likely is it that these benign global conditions for emerging economies will prevail? Should the world economy slow down in response to the recent trouble in credit markets, commodity prices are likely to come under pressure, too. It remains to be seen how EMBI spreads would react, if emerging economies had to deal with the (fiscal) impact of lower commodity prices. 29 Constant PF1 PF2 GDP CPI LT debt ST debt Exports Reserves XR Deficit Fin. Dev. Crisis Regulation IT SP500 VIX Oil World GDP Obs. Countries R2 Model 3 3.43 2.05*** 0.06*** 0.13*** 17.81*** 13.68** -162.31*** 0.24 0.00 1.00 6.14** 7.20*** -0.03 -2.18** Model 3c 5.80 1.92** 0.15 0.06*** 0.12*** 18.11*** 14.13** -169.38*** -0.89 0.00 1.07 6.01** 7.35*** -0.08 -2.10* 448 19 0.44 448 19 0.43 Model 4 -0.82 1.42* 0.07*** 0.13*** 17.44*** 11.25 -170.31*** 0.67 0.00 1.31** 5.08* 7.65*** 0.04 -2.19** -0.01* -0.22 0.07 6.87 448 19 0.46 Model 4b 0.94 1.67** -0.42 0.07*** 0.13*** 17.89*** 11.33 -171.70*** 0.20 0.00 1.32** 4.81* 7.62*** 0.01 -2.48** -0.01* -0.17 0.05 14.07 448 19 0.45 Table 13: Panel regressions with one or two principal factors (estimated by IV) A A.1 Additional robustness checks Adding a second principal factor As explained in section 4.1, the results of the factor analysis are not entirely clear on whether we should use one or two principal factors. Given that there is no straightforward interpretation for the second principal factor, the estimates reported only included the first factor. We have also estimated equation (10) with two principal factors, i.e. EMBIt = β1 + β2 PF1,t + β3 PF2,t + ∑ β j X j,t + ∑ βkYk,t + εt . j (11) k We estimate equation (11) without and with global variables (models 3d and 4d, respectively). Adding the second factor does not change our results qualitatively, as can be seen in table 13. 30 A.2 Robustness checks for country-specific regressions For the country-specific regressions, we checked the robustness of our results by adding a crisis variable (estimations are done using instrumental variables). The results are qualitatively comparable. Also, during crises, EMBI series might exhibit structural breaks. Despite adding a crisis variable, it could be that non-linear effects are inadequately captured in our specification. To test the robustness of our estimations and to account for the fact that a few outliers might bias the results, we also estimated the equation by quantile regression. The differences between the two methodologies are small (detailed results available upon request), leading us to believe that our findings are not substantially impacted by outliers. Lastly, figure 10 shows the difference between actual and predicted values of equation (10), when estimated using instrumental values. We see that the fit of the countryspecific regressions is, by and large, very good. B Data sources Our analysis covers 20 emerging market economies: Argentina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Columbia, Ecuador, Hungary, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Panama, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Russia, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, and Venezuela. These are all countries for which the EMBI Global provides consistent data between 1998Q1 and 2007Q2. For some tests, we group the countries into the following regions: Latin America, Europe, and Rest of the World (ROW). The country-specific components of JP Morgan’s EMBI Global index is our measure of sovereign spreads. We use monthly and quarterly data of the following data sources: EMBI Global series are taken from JP Morgan, macroeconomic data on reserves, inflation, exports, GDP in local currency, and the exchange rate are from the IMF’s IFS database, and ratings are from Standard and Poor’s. Ratings data were transformed into numbers (an AAA rating equals 1; an AA ratings equals 2 etc.). Note that we use annual GDP data for China, Ecuador, Panama, and Venezuela, due to data availability, and interpolated the series using a linear conversion. U.S. bond data for the 3 month and the 10 year Treasury are from Datastream, and the U.S. yield curve is proxied by the difference in the two series. 31 32 Fitted values Fitted values Fitted values Morocco Russia Fitted values Columbia Argentina South Africa Panama Ecuador Brasil Thailand Peru Hungary Bulgaria Fitted values Fitted values Fitted values Fitted values Figure 10: Actual vs. fitted values Fitted values Fitted values Fitted values Fitted values Turkey Philippines Malaysia Chile Fitted values Fitted values Fitted values Fitted values Venezuela Poland Mexico China Country-specific estimation by instrumental variables Fitted values Fitted values Fitted values Fitted values As regards data transformation, we use nominal GDP in local currency and convert it to real GDP using the GDP deflator (except for Brazil, Bulgaria, China, Columbia, Panama, Russia, and Venezuela, where only CPI data was available to deflate the series). Short-and long-term debt-to-GDP ratios, reserves-to-GDP ratio, and exports-toGDP ratios are computed using nominal values in U.S. dollar. References Baltagi, B. H.: 1995, Econometric analysis of panel data, John Wiley, Chichester. Breitung, J.: 2000, The local power of some unit root tests for panel data, in B. H. Baltagi (ed.), Advances in Econometrics, Vol. 15: Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration, and Dynamic Panels, JAI Press, Amsterdam, pp. 161–178. Calvo, G. and Talvi, E.: 2004, Sudden stops, financial factors and economic collapse in latin america: Learning from argentina and chile, NBER Working Paper No. 11153 . Choi, I.: 2001, Unit root tests for panel data, Journal of International Money and Finance 20, 249–272. Ciarlone, A., Piselli, P. and Trebeschi, G.: 2007, Emerging markets spreads and global financial conditions, Banca d’Italia Temi di discussione 637. Coudert, V. and Gex, M.: 2006, Can risk aversion indicators anticipate financial crises?, Banque de France Financial Stability Review 9, 67–87. Davidson, R. and MacKinnon, J.: 1993, Estimation and Inference in Econometrics, Oxford University Press, New York. Deutsche Bundesbank: 2004, Indicators of internatioanl investors’ risk aversion, Monthly Bulletin 56(10), 69–73. Dooley, M., Fernandex-Arias, E. and Kletzer, K. M.: 1996, Is the debt crisis history? recent private capital inflows to developing countries, World Bank Economic Review 10, 27–50. Dungey, M., Fry, R., Gonzalez-Hermosillo, B. and Martin, V.: 2003, Characterizing global risk aversion for emerging markets during financial crises, IMF Working Paper WP/03/251. 33 Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R. and Panizza, U.: 2003a, Currency mismatches, debt intolerance and original sin: Why they are not the same and why it matters, NBER Working Paper 10036. Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R. and Panizza, U.: 2003b, The pain of original sin, in B. Eichengreen and R. Hausmann (eds), Other People’s Money: Debt Denomination and Financial Instability in Emerging Market Economies, University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Eichengreen, B. and Mody, A.: 1998, What explains changing spreads on emergingmarket debt: Fundamentals or market sentiment?, NBER Working Paper 6408. Engle, R. F. and Granger, C. W. J.: 1987, Co-integration and error correction: Representation, estimation, and testing, Econometrica 55, 251–276. Fisher, L. and Weil, R. L.: 1971, Coping with the risk of interest rate fluctuations: Returns to bondholders from naive and optimal strategies, Journal of Business 44, 408–431. Gai, P. and Vause, N.: 2004, Risk appetite: concept and measurement, Bank of England Financial Stability Review December, 127–136. Grandes, M.: 2003, Convergence and divergence of sovereign bond spreads: Theory and facts from latin america, Paris, France: Delta, ENS/EHESS . Herrera, S. and Perry, G.: 2002, Determinants of latin spreads in the new economy era: The role of us interest rates and other external variables, Mimeo, World Bank . Herrero, A. G. and Ortiz, A.: 2004, The role of global risk aversion in explaining latin american soveriegn spreads, Mimeo, Bank of Spain . Hund, J. and Lesmond, D. A.: 2007, Liquidity and credit risk in emerging market debt, Journal of Finance forthcoming. Im, K., Peseran, M. H. and Shin, Y.: 2003, Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels, Journal of Econometrics 115, 53–74. International Monetary Fund: 2007, Global Financial Stability Report, Washington. Johansen, S.: 1995, Likelihood-based Inference in Cointegrated Vector Autoregressive Models, Oxford University Press, Oxford. 34 Kamin, S. B. and Von Kleist, K.: 1999, The evolution and determinants of emerging market credit spreads in the 1990s, BIS Working Paper 68. Kaminsky, G.: 2003, Varieties of currency crises, NBER Working Paper No. 10193 . Levin, A., Lin, C. F. and Chu, C.: 2002, Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic and finite-sample properties, Journal of Econometrics 108, 1–24. Macauley, F. R.: 1938, Some theoretical problems suggested by the movements of interest rates, bond yields, and stock prices in the United States since 1856, Columbia University Press, New York. Maddala, G. and Wu, S.: 1999, A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and a new simple test, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 61, 631–652. McGuire, P. and Schrijvers, M. A.: 2003, Common factors in emerging market spreads, BIS Quarterly Review December, 6578. Prignon, C., Smith, D. R. and Villa, C.: 2007, Why common factors in international bond returns are not so common, Journal of International Money and Finance 26, 284–304. Rozada, M. G. and Yeyati, E.: 2006, Global factors and emerging market spreads, Inter-American Development Bank, Research Department Working Paper 552. Slok, T. and Kennedy, M.: 2004, Factors driving risk premia, OECD Economics Department Working Papers 385. 35