DRAFT Reactions of Canadian Interest Rates to Bank of Canada Communications: What moves Markets? May 2008 Christine Fay1 and Toni Gravelle2 1 Financial Markets Department Bank of Canada Ottawa, Ontario, Canada K1A 0G9 cfay@bankofcanada.ca 2 Financial Markets Department Bank of Canada Ottawa, Ontario, Canada K1A 0G9 tgravelle@bankofcanada.ca Bank of Canada working papers are theoretical or empirical works-in-progress on subjects in economics and finance. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors. No responsibility for them should be attributed to the Bank of Canada. ISSN ####-#### © 200? Bank of Canada 1 Acknowledgement We wish to thank Scott Hendry, Christopher D’Souza, Rhys Mendes, Donna Howard, Carolyn Wilkins, and Grahame Johnson for their helpful comments. We would also like to thank Guy Mackenzie for his research assistance. 2 Reactions of Canadian Interest Rates to Bank of Canada Communications: What moves Markets? Abstract We empirically examine the reaction of Canadian financial markets to official Bank of Canada communication as well as their reaction to the recent use of “forward looking statements” (a.k.a. monetary policy inclination statements) included in these communications. This is done to investigate the extent to which Bank of Canada monetary policy transparency has improved. We find evidence that Fixed Announcement Date (FAD) press statements, and to a lesser extent speeches by Governing Council members, significantly affect near-term interest rate expectations indicating that central bank communication conveys important information to market participants. However, our results also show that FAD press statements and speeches do not significantly impact market rates over the more recent period when “forward looking statements” have been used on a regular basis. We investigate two explanations for this change in response. First, that market participants now better understand the Bank of Canada’s monetary policy reaction function and, as such, there is less new incremental information conveyed in these communications. Alternatively, that market participants have focused more on the forward looking statements themselves and less on the Banks’ discussion of the economic outlook (i.e., the Bank of Canada has become more predictable). As such the participants would respond less to new macroeconomic data releases than before. We find evidence to support the latter explanation. 3 1. Introduction How do markets react to central bank communications? This question is of interest because it helps assess central bank transparency, or more precisely, how well financial market participants understand and use the guidance communicated by central banks to effectively form their expectations for future inflation and asset market price movements more generally. As such, this paper’s goals are twofold. First, we investigate the extent to which Canadian interest rates respond to official Bank of Canada communication since late 2000, the time since the Fixed Announcement Dates (FADs) were introduced, using the same methodology as Reeves and Sawicki (2007). Specifically, based on a two stege regression methodology, we test the impact of official communication on the variance of interest rate using daily interest rate data. Following this, we study the impact of the Bank of Canada’s use of forward looking statements on market behaviour. In effect, we want to study whether the use of these statements have made the central bank more transparent with regards to their reaction function or simply more predictable in terms of their future policy rate actions. As is now well documented in most central banking handbooks, transparency is considered a key component of an effective monetary policy framework (see for example ECB 2004). Central bank transparency makes monetary policy more effective in three ways. First, in being clear about its mandate, how it goes about fulfilling it as well as its ability and willingness to do so, the central bank engenders greater credibility. Secondly, transparency, in regularly exposing the public to its views and understanding of current and future economic activity, imposes some degree of accountability by providing the means for the public to assess the consistency of the central bank’s actions and its monetary policy makers’ decision making process with its stated objective. Thirdly, and this is the main area of interest in this study, central bank transparency should help markets understand the monetary policy reaction function, allowing markets to anticipate the direction of future target interest rate movements. Monetary policy is more effective if markets participants correctly anticipate it. That is, given that short-term rates and long-term rates are linked via the expectations hypothesis, and the central bank only has control over short-term (or more precisely overnight) interest rates, the central bank can better influence longer-term interest rate expectations by communicating and shaping the 4 markets’ understanding of the factors driving the central banks reaction function and economic outlook. A better understanding of the central bank’s reaction function, it is thought, reduces market uncertainty about future rate movements (and implicitly market volatility) and also allows a shortening of, and an increase in the effectiveness of, the monetary transmission mechanism (the process by which expected changes in monetary policy are incorporated into the movement of other financial variables and, in the end, investment and consumption decisions). Aside from transparency initiatives aimed at clarifying the Bank of Canada’s objective (i.e., its inflation target) and monetary policy framework, the Bank of Canada has taken a number of measures over the years to increase transparency and to communicate to the public its views about the economic outlook. One significant step for enhancing transparency and increasing the effectiveness of monetary policy was taken on October 30th 2000, when the Bank of Canada announced its first eight pre-specified “fixed announcement dates” (FADs). The introduction of FADs virtually eliminated the market’s uncertainty regarding the exact timing of the Bank of Canada’s target rate announcements, thereby reducing interest volatility related to this uncertainty. It also, since the FAD schedule is known in advance, allowed market participant to focus more attention on Canadian macroeconomic news that accumulated between FADs and allowed them to speculate more precisely about the timing of target policy rate changes (see Appendix B for more on this). In addition, and more important for this study, it also gave the Bank an additional opportunity to increase the market’s information about the Bank of Canada’s views on the economic outlook. Previous empirical work undertaken at the Bank of Canada by Muller and Zelmer (1999), Gravelle and Moessner (2002), Parent (2002-2003), and Andreou (2005) has studied whether the move to FADs has increased central bank transparency. Parent (2002-2003), extending the work of Gravelle and Moessner (2002) shows empirically that Canadian market interest rates react to more Canadian macro announcement “surprises” and fewer US macro announcement “surprises” in the post FAD period than in the pre-FAD period. This work suggests that the introduction of the fixed announcement date regime has increased transparency by shifting the focus of markets to Canadian rather than U.S. economic conditions. As such it finds support for the idea that FADs have contributed 5 significantly to the improvement of the markets’ understanding of the Bank’s reaction function. Andreou (2005), following closely the work of Kuttner (2000), measures empirically the impact of policy surprises on Canadian government treasury bill and bond yields. He finds that the impact of a surprise action on the long end of the yield curve has diminished since the introduction of the FAD process suggesting that the Bank’s longterm policy goals are better understood and more credible. Like most other industrialized central banks, the Bank of Canada has, over the years, also increased its transparency by increasing the amount of information communicated to the public. Specifically, the Bank has, since 1995, regularly published its Monetary Policy Report (MPR) and update (MPRU). It has also, for sometime, published a press statement with changes in the policy rate. For many years speeches by Governing Council (the Governor and five Deputy Governors) have provided an opportunity to provide monetary policy information to the public. But like the press statements that accompany policy decisions, their potential to impact market expectations of future interest rates, were enhanced significantly with the introduction of FADs. As such, our study focuses on Bank of Canada communications for the period since FADs were introduced. Another more recent measure the Bank of Canada has taken to increase transparency is the inclusion of “forward looking statements” in FAD press releases and MPRs (and MPRUs). In the following section, we discuss in detail how the publication of policy rate guidance or a policy interest rate path might make a central bank more “predictable,” but does not necessarily increase the market’s understanding of the central bank’s monetary policy reaction function and as such does not necessarily make it more “transparent.” Any increase in transparency hindges on the central bank’s ability to sufficiently convey to market participants the conditionality embedded in the forward looking signal about the future policy actions or policy rate path. Empirical work measuring the impact of central bank communication is now quite extensive. Comparing the communication strategies of the Federal Reserve, the Bank of England and the ECB, Ehrmann & Fratzscher (2005 and 2007a) find that monetary policy communication generally has a significant effect on the short and medium-term horizons 6 of the yield curve.1 Using daily data, Kohn & Sack (2003) find that FOMC statements accompanying policy decisions and congressional testimony given by Chairman Greenspan have a significant effect on interest rates. Following the methodology of Kohn & Sack (2003), Reeves & Sawicki (2005) study the impact of official Bank of England (BoE) communications and find that only the publication of the Minutes of the Monetary Policy Committee meetings significantly impact market volatility when using daily data. However, when using intraday data, they find that both the Minutes and the Inflation Report have a significant impact on near-term interest rate expectations. Looking at a panel of six central banks including the Bank of Canada2, Connolly and Kohler (2007) find that across all countries, commentaries accompanying rate decisions have the largest impact. Among Bank of Canada communications, press releases accompanying FAD decisions, MPRs and MPRUs3, and speeches were the forms of official communication that they found to have a statistically significant impact on interest rates4. The results differ from ours in that we focus on the post-FAD period, while the Connolly and Kohler examine the January 1997 to August 2006 period. They also found that across countries, central bank communication had a small explanatory power for movements in interest rates overall relative to movement of global interests which is proxied by benchmark U.S rates. We find evidence that official Bank of Canada communication, in particular FAD press statements, have a significant effect on near- to medium-term yields suggesting that these communications convey important new information which impact the markets interest rate expectations. As mentioned, over our period of study there is a major shift in the Bank of Canada’s communication strategy that saw the inclusion of forward looking statements in FAD press statements and MPRs, which allows us to study the impact of these statements on Central Bank transparency. Reruning our tests on both a split sample (where these statements began being used in a consistent manner) as well as cross1 They also find that statements about the economic outlook only have a significant impact on the medium to long end of the yield curve in the US. They suggest this finding is related to differences in the stated monetary policy objectives of the three central banks. The Bank of England and the ECB focus on price stability whereas the Federal Reserve gives a stronger weight to the real economy. 2 This panel includes the central banks of Australia, Canada, the Euro Area, New Zealand, the UK and the US. 3 When Connolly & Kohler re-estimated their model over the post-FAD period (2000 – 2006), MPR(U)’s no longer had a significant impact on market rates. 4 Market rates used for Canada in this study included the front 8 BAX futures contracts. 7 dummies to account for dates prior to our split that include FLS’s, our results suggest that there has been a loss of conditionality surrounding Bank of Canada communications with the introduction of these forward looking statements, which is indicative of greater “predictability” but not of greater transparency measured in terms of the market having a better understanding of the monetary policy reaction function. 2. Issues Related with Publishing Policy Interest Rate Guidance or Paths: Predictability versus Transparency and Communicating Conditionality There are different aspects of monetary policy transparency. In this study we focus on one aspect of transparency by defining monetary policy as being transparent if market participants can anticipate the central banks’ official interest rate decisions correctly, based on their knowledge of the central banks’ reaction function. This definition is motivated by the view that central bank communication should be used to increase the effectiveness of monetary policy as described in the introduction. Under this definition then, in principal, central bank communication is put forward to help market participants update their understanding the central bank’s reaction function parameters, or more generally, the framework the central bank is currently relying upon to guide their decision making process. As such, communications about the central bank’s current view of how the economy is unfolding, typically summarised in projections of output or inflation that include, in some situations, some form of uncertainty bands (i.e., fan charts) help in this regard. In addition, communication regarding the macroeconomic variables that are particularly in focus in formulating policy, that summarizes how the central banks see certain alternative scenarios unfolding for the outlook, and that presents updates to the model or the modeling process, should enhance the markets understanding of the central bank’s reaction function and also cause a reaction in interest rates, both at the short end of the yield curve as well as in medium-, and in some cases, longer-term interest rates. Recently, a debate has unfolded around how much additional information central banks should release to the public with respect to their future policy rate intentions. 8 In particular, should central banks provide to the public their forecast of, or their intention for, the path of future target interest rates? Central banks see both pros and cons in providing policy rate inclination signals (including the publishing of the policy rate path).5 (Note that we focus only on the pros and cons as they relate to increasing the effectiveness of the monetary policy transmission mechanism, while Kahn (2007) and others also include those related to increasing monetary policy accountability and credibility.) One of the main advantages of providing policy rate guidance is that, in principal, it makes monetary policy, via the expectation hypothesis, more effective (i.e., more bang-for-buck)6 by better influencing medium- and long-term rates as these are likely to react more to policy actions that are accompanied by communication about the path of future policy rates. For example, if a central bank communicates that it will hold policy rates higher for a longer period of time than markets currently expect, then medium- and long-term rates would likely be higher than if the central bank simply communicated the current target for the policy rate (Kahn 2007)7. Another advantage of providing guidance is it reduces the degree of market uncertainty related to future monetary policy moves and thus reduces interest rate risk premia. Rudebush (2008) characterises policy inclination signals as falling into three categories: indirect signals; direct qualitative signals; and direct quantitative signals. The first, “indirect signals” provides implicit information about the policy path through the use of related information. Examples of indirect signals include balance of risk statements, the presentation of a risk scenario showing the extent that inflation would deviate from the target holding policy rates constant. According to Rudebusch (2008), examples of the second type of policy guidance, “direct qualitative” signals, include the policy “bias” statements used for a period by the Fed starting in the late 1990s, as well as phrases that signal the desired policy stance over an extended number of meeting dates, such as policy accommodation “can be maintained for a considerable period” or “can be removed at pace that is likely to be measured” also fall 5 See Kahn (2007) for a summary as well as Moessner and Nelson (2008). However, this hypothesis, to our knowledge, has not been directly tested empirically. 7 There is a third advantage put forward by theorists. When private agents are uncertain about the central bank’s inflation objective (particularly those central banks with new objectives or targeting regimes), it helps, in theory, align the private agents’ and the central bank’s expectations about future monetary policy and facilitating the economy’s adjustment back to the inflation objective after a shock. 6 9 in this category according to Rudebusch (2008). The final category, “direct quantitative” signals, best describe the explicit numerical projections provided by the central banks of New Zealand, Norway, Iceland, and Sweden The ECB’s use of “code words” such as “strong vigilance” would seem to fall into the indirect qualitative signal category. The Bank of Canada has provided direct qualitative signals to markets via its forward looking statements included in nearly all FAD (and/or MPR) press releases, since July 2004. These have typically included statements such as “some increase in the target for the overnight rate may be required in the medium (near) term” or “the current level of the target for the overnight rate is consistent with achieving the inflation target over the medium (near) term” or “… further reduction of monetary stimulus will be required ... over the next four to six quarters…” (see Table C.1 in Appendix C). The Bank of Canada also has recently introduced “balance of risk to the outlook statements” which would be categorized as “indirect guidance”. Moreover, the Bank has provided both indirect and direct qualitative signals in its other communications, particularly the MPRs and speeches that contained language consistent with the MPRs. Kohn (2005) and others, have highlighted that there are notable disadvantages to providing guidance. A major disadvantage of providing policy rate guidance is that markets might place too great a weight on the central banks guidance and as a consequence not fully understand or appreciate sufficiently the conditionality of this forecast or guidance. This can result in markets focusing less on their own private information (won’t do their homework). It may also reduce the information content of market prices (for information extraction purposes). A second disadvantage related to the perceived un-conditionality of the policy rate guidance is that it might cause policy makers to be less willing to change their policy intentions in light of new information, due to the following two concerns. First, frequent updating of the policy path might undermine the public’s confidence in the central bank’s forecasting ability. Second, policy markers may be concerned that financial markets will overreact to a shift in policy stance or guidance, leading to excess volatility. In other words, policy makers might be concerned that by “disappointing expectations” they will engender market volatility, even 10 though the change in circumstance justifies their reassessment of the appropriate policy action. A third problem with providing policy rate guidance is that it may in itself be difficult to provide forward guidance given the structure of the monetary policy decision making process and/or committee. For example, given its governance structure, the Bank of England’s Monetary Policy Committee’s basis for its decision is “renewed or refreshed” every month and as such is “very” conditional on the new information they’ve received since their last meeting (i.e., they don’t decide in advance what their decision will be at the next (few) MPC meeting(s) but instead meet with a relatively clean slate every time). They are thus averse to potentially fooling financial markets, via their communications, into thinking there are definite multi-meeting-date plans for the policy rate going forward. King (2006) notes that the added benefit of not providing forward guidance, is that there is no need to worry about how to wean markets off their “crutch of spoon fed expectations formation” without causing unintended volatility, when the central bank sees much greater uncertainty about the future path it will take, and is no longer able to provide relatively unconditional policy inclination statements.8 In considering the issue of providing policy guidance in official central bank communication, it is important to note that there is a subtle difference in a central bank’s communication strategy that is “transparent” and one that is “predictable” (see Moessner, Gravelle, and Sinclair (2005) and Jen 2007). Conceptually, a more “predictable” central bank can be thought of one that provides more policy “guidance” via, for example, “policy inclination statements” or their forecast/projection for future path of the policy rate, which explicitly includes information on the direction and perhaps timing of future interest rate changes. A more predictable central bank is one for which markets participants can more easily anticipate correctly the next policy decision (or the next set of policy decisions) without necessarily a better understanding of the reasons for the decision(s) and, as such, without a better understanding of the central bank’s reaction 8 This is roughly what happened to the FED at the April FOMC meeting, in which the press release no longer made it explicit that the FED will continue on this path. 11 function. On the other hand, a more transparent central bank is one that effectively conveys to the market their monetary policy reaction function (as described above).9 Although the aim of policy makers in providing policy guidance may be, in general, to enhance the markets’ understanding of the reaction function and ultimately the effectiveness of monetary policy, because of the market participants’ perverse (from the policymakers perspective at least) focus on the guidance communicated as described above, it turns out to reduce the markets’ reliance on their own private information, reduces their reaction to macro news, and reduces their incentives to update their understanding of the reaction function. As such, greater predictability might not necessarily imply greater monetary policy transparency, but greater transparency (in the sense that communication of information that effectively enhances the markets’ understanding of the reaction function) does in general imply greater predictability. However, it is not clear that those central banks that publish their target rate paths or some other form of policy rate guidance are necessarily “predictable”, as predictability is dependent on the degree of perceived conditionality (or in particular the lack thereof) embedded in the central banks communications, including in any one of the three types of policy guidance. It is possible that central banks that provide a direct quantitative guidance (i.e., that publish future target rate paths) can be less predictable (and more transparent) than those that simply offering direct qualitative guidance (i.e., that publish policy inclination statements), if the inclination statement is explicitly presented to, or is implicitly perceived by, financial markets as less conditional than the policy path. Specifically, central banks could provide “error,” “risks,” or “uncertainty” bands around their forecast of key economic variables, including the policy rate, and explicitly indicate 9 Strictly trying to increasing the markets’ understanding of the monetary policy reaction function (i.e., increasing transparency as defined above) on the other hand does not lead to the same problems of perceived un-conditionality and yet still allows for enhanced monetary policy effectiveness. If markets had a perfect understanding of the reaction function, they could correctly anticipate the path of future policy rates to, in principal, the same degree as if the policy guidance was provided. By not stating explicitly the implications of its economic outlook for the future stance of monetary policy, a central bank would force market participants to draw their own conclusions for future policy stances. Market participants could do this by focusing on the implications of economic and financial developments, rather than by simply speculating on whether and when the Bank will follow through with its previously announced “guidance” for monetary conditions. 12 that the timing of policy changes could occur anytime over a lengthy period (i.e., anytime within the projection period). Moreover, central banks that publish a target rate path could in principal use this as a tool to aid their (conditionality laden) communication about the economic outlook, providing in-depth alternative scenarios and/or risks to their base case policy rate projections. Central banks could indicate that the path is simply the mean/mode of a series of, or probability distribution of, scenarios. In addition, Moessner and Nelson (2008) argue that the regular appearance of a forecast policy rate path in central bank communications may in itself make these more conditional in nature relative to those central banks that irregularly communicate guidance, as the latter may be viewed as doing so for the tactical reason of “massaging” market expectations. The latter central banks’ communication guidance strategy may thus look more like unconditional commitments in this case. Nonetheless, it would seem that central banks that provide direct qualitative or quantitative guidance in the form of a forward looking statement or publishing a policy rate path, have more “work” to do in terms of making clear the high degree of conditionally embedded in their communications. In sum, what is important in terms of measuring central bank predictability is one: to what extent the central bank conveys the timing and direction of future rate changes; and two: how much conditionality there is explicitly embedded in, or implicitly perceived by the market in, its communications. As highlighted by Kahn (2007), central banks that restrict themselves to use only “balance of risks” statements leave “the markets to interpret any possible implication of these risks for the (future) policy rates.” In contrast, policy statements like the forward looking statements used by the Bank of Canada or the “measured paced” guidance provided by the Fed over an extended period of time, seem more unconditional in nature. Empirically, central banks that are increasingly predictable should see a decrease in the financial markets reliance on macroeconomic news to anticipate near-term monetary policy changes. The relatively unconditional nature of the forward guidance provided, would negate the need for markets to do their homework in terms of formulating their “shadow” monetary reaction functions and in turn using this to calculate the timing of the 13 next, or the next few, target rate changes. As mentioned in the introduction, this is in fact what Ehrmann and Fratzscher (2007b) find when studying changes in U.S. Federal Reserve communications. They find that since the Fed introduced its policy inclination statement in 1999, interest rate reactions to macro news were generally smaller and there were fewer macro releases that were statistically significant. Moreover, they find that inter-meeting communications about the future course/timing of monetary policy, rather than that about the economic outlook, garnered smaller interest rate reactions after the Fed introduced its policy inclination statement. In this study, we investigate whether or not the inclusion of forward looking statements in Bank of Canada communication has caused markets to react less to macroeconomic releases. 3. Types of Central Bank Communications In our paper we focus on three main types of official Bank of Canada communications These include: Fixed announcement date (FAD) press statements; the Monetary Policy Report and Update; and, Speeches and other communications comprising press conferences and interviews. Given that FAD press releases are one of the communication items, we begin our sample on October 30, 2000. This is the date the Bank of Canada published the first schedule of FADs, making it the first date on which market participants could trade based on this knowledge. Our sample ends on May 31, 2007. 3.1. FAD Press Statements On September 19, 2000 in an effort to increase transparency, the Bank of Canada announced that it would move to a FAD regime, changing (or not) its’ target for the overnight policy rate on eight pre-specified dates each year (except in exceptional circumstances). The first of these FADs occurred on December 5, 2000. On each fixed announcement date, a press statement is released at 9:00 am (eastern time) announcing the policy decision. The statement includes the reasons underlying the policy decision, an update of the governing council’s view of the economic outlook, and, more recently, forward looking policy guidance and a discussion about the balance of risks to the outlook. As such, it is an important form of communication and receives intense scrutiny by market participants. 14 Between October 30, 2000 and May 31, 2007 ( our sample period) there were 53 FADs with accompanying press releases. There was also one intra-meeting policy change with a press release on September 17, 2001, shortly after the September 11, 2001 terrorist attacks. For most of this paper we do not include the period following and including September 11, 2001 (3 month window) as this period is not representative of the normal market dynamics or normal reactions to communication. 3.2 Monetary Policy Reports (MPRs) and MPR Updates (MPRUs) The MPR and its update are released four times a year, two days following every second FAD at 10:30 am (Eastern Time).10 The Governing Council (GC) uses this document as its main method of communicating and updating its detailed views on the current state and likely evolution of the economy. Although the main messages of the MPR(U) have been summarized in the FAD press statement, the MPR(U) elaborates in greater detail the Governing Council’s assessment of the factors that have shaped the interest rate decision, and puts into context recent developments in terms of the underlying trends over the medium term. Prior to the release of the MPR, the GC, with substantial input from the Bank of Canada staff, comes to a consensus view on the future path of the Canadian economy, taking into account any new information since the previous MPR. It is therefore the main vehicle for the GC to communicate in detail, any significant changes in its view of the economic outlook. As such, it plays a role akin to some central banks’ “minutes” in discussing the factors underlying the Bank of Canada’s economic and inflation outlook. However, given Governing Council’s monetary policy decision making process is consensus-based, the MPR (as opposed to certain central bank minutes) does not provide individual GC member views on the outlook. 10 Since the inception of Fixed announcement dates, the MPR(U) release has always followed the FAD press release. The time lag between these two releases has shortened over time (although the content and consistency between the two has not changed materially). The MPR(U) was initially released two weeks following the FAD. In mid-2001 the Bank began releasing the MPR(U) within the same week as the FAD, and currently, the MPR(U) is released two days following the FAD. 15 Our sample contains 14 MPRs and 13 MPRUs for a total of 2711. 3.3. Speeches All governing council members give speeches and interviews. The views expressed in BoC speeches are representative of, and consistent across, all governing council members, rather than the views of individual members. This is a function of the fact that the underlying monetary policy decision structure at the BoC is by consensus. Governing council members speak on a number of topics, which may or may not be of interest to market participants. However, many speeches contain an economic conjuncture as well as a question and answer period following the speech. In general, the economic outlook section in a speech is used to reinforce and elaborate on the key messages in the MPR(U) and FAD press statement, and it is only when there are developments that lead governing council to significantly change their views from what was most recently laid out, that they would seek to provide a clear signal of this change in view. In addition, there is a black out period the week preceding the FAD in which the BoC does not comment on either the economy or the direction of monetary policy. In order to include only those speeches relevant to monetary policy or the economic outlook, as well as capture information that the market actually receives, we include only those speeches, interviews and news conferences that generate at least one story headline in Bloomberg related to either monetary policy or the economic outlook. Over our sample period GC members made 153 speeches, of which we include 98. 3.4 Forward Looking Statements (FLSs) and Balance of Risks Discussions The Bank of Canada began using FLSs in April 2002, where they appeared in both FAD press statements as well as MPRs.12 See Table 1 in Appendix B which outlines the 11 The main difference between the MPR and MPRU is it’s length and the depth of analysis of factors outside the domestic economy. We do not believe that this difference has a significant impact on market reaction. As such, we will treat the MPR and MPRU as the same event. 12 Forward looking policy statements began appearing in the highlights section of some of the MPR(U)’s and their accompanying press release with the April 2002 MPR and were included in all MPR(U)’s beginning with the July 22, 2004 MPRU. 16 wording of each FLS. It was not until July 2004 that a FLS was issued with nearly each FAD and/or MPR. It is important to note that over our sample, there have only been either positive or neutral FLSs. There are two reasons for this. First, the period since July 2004 where the Bank of Canada has more consistently included FLSs, had also been a period where there has been a sustained economic growth period and as such where the policy rate was on a relatively consistent upward march (see Chart 1). It is also worth noting that in general, subsequent monetary policy actions have, in general, been consistent with these statements as outlined in Table 2, Appendix B. There also have been the more qualitative “balance of risk” statements issued with FAD and MPR releases. Although we do not examine these specifically in our study, we thought it useful to provide a brief summary of their characteristics. Although a few balance of risk statements were issued earlier in the FAD period, the consistent inclusion of these in all FAD/MPR press releases started in July of 2005. These statements are presented in Table 1 in the Appendix B. Note that the earlier set of balance of risk statements were split between short-term (or near-term) risks to the projection and those “later on” in the projection (or over the medium term). The near-term risks were always balanced and those later on were generally tilted downwards. Starting in September 2006, the Bank no longer split the timing of the risks and simply referred, in general, to “the risk to its inflation projection”. After several press releases which stated risk were balanced, the first balance of risk statement to indicate unbalanced risks over the projection period occurred in April 2007, when Bank said “risks are roughly balanced, but with a slight tilt to the upside.” However, this “composite” balance of risk statement might not provide a very clear signal of the Bank’s view of the balance of risk. The first unequivocal message occurred in December 2007, roughly two and half years after the balance of risk statements began to be consistently included in the press statements, when the Bank saw “a shift to the down side in the balance of risks around … the projection for inflation through 2009.” 4. Methodology 4.1 Measuring Market Reaction to Communications 17 Four problems arise when trying to measure the market impact of communications. The first is that it is difficult to quantify and characterise systematically the content of Central Bank communications, making it hard to benchmark the “strength/importance” or “direction” of what is announced. Specifically, it would be useful to quantify the direction or implied stance of all that is communicated by the Bank, by for example categorizing it into dovish, neutral, or hawkish statements. But this is at best a possibility only for a subset of FAD/MPR press releases that included a forward looking statement, rather than the complete set of communications. Secondly, we cannot easily measure what markets had expected these communications to say, therefore adding to the difficulty in assessing the strength or sign of the signal. To address these two problems we follow the methodology of Kohn & Sack (2003) and Reeves & Sawicki (2005) in which we focus on the volatility of interest rates on days of official Bank of Canada Communication. Since any change in the mean should also effect the variance of the asset price, this is a good proxy for analysing the overall importance of the communication event for financial markets without needing to quantify the strength or direction of the event itself. Thus, we would expect to see the volatility of these instruments rise on communication days if this communication is passing along new relevant information as this news is incorporated into market rates. Another issue when measuring market reaction to communications is that the content of communications or the communication event itself may be endogenous, that is, the central bank may choose to communicate new information, or increase the frequency of its communication because of a sudden change in the economic conjuncture or some other news. In this case, asset prices would probably be more volatile on the days of communication, possibly in reaction to other factors we are unable to control for, thus possibly overstating the impact of the communication. With respect to the endogeneity of communication event, outside of speeches, the Bank of Canada sets and announces its communication dates well in advance, therefore ruling this out to a large extent as an issue in our study. The final complication that occurs when attempting to measure the impact of communications on interest rates is that other events taking place on the same day as 18 these communications may also be relevant to market participants and therefore move interest rates. These factors include macroeconomic news in both Canada and the U.S., U.S. and Canadian policy rate surprises, and U.S. monetary policy communications. We control for U.S. news variables due to the close economic links between Canada and the U.S. and the fact that that changes in U.S. benchmark interest rates tend to move other industrialized country rates. As such, in order to isolate the asset price movements linked to official Bank communications, we must first take into account all other relevant information that could move interest rates on communications days. Our analysis therefore takes on two distinct parts. 4.2 Regression equations To control for the effect of macroeconomic announcements, policy surprises and U.S. communications on asset prices, we estimate equation (1) using OLS13, following Kohn & Sack (2003), and Ehrmann & Fratzscher (2005) among others, with modifications for the Canadian economy. The first stage regression model is as follows: n m i =1 j =1 Δy t = β 0 + β 1 ΔON tu + β 2 Δff t u + β 3 Δef t + β 4 ΔT 2 t + ∑ α i cmaciu,t + ∑ α j usmaciu,t + ε t (1) where the one-day change in the interest rate of interest, Δy , are regressed on the surprise component of Canadian policy announcements, ΔON tu ; the surprise component of U.S. policy announcements, Δff u ; FOMC communication control variables, Δef and ΔT 2 ; and the surprise component of macroeconomic announcements in Canada and the U.S.; cmacu and usmacu respectively. We then relate the unexplained variance of market prices from this regression to communications variables as described below in Section 4.3. Please see Appendix A, where we describe in detail each of these controls. 4.3 Measuring the Impact of Communications on Market Rates 13 We use the Newey-West estimator which “provides a way to calculate consistent covariance matrices in the presence of both serial correlation and heteroscedasticity.” (Johnson & Dinardo,1997, p.333). 19 Once we have controlled for “other news”, we measure the impact of official Bank communications on markets by relating the unexplained variance to these communications using the following equation. ε 2 i ,t n = δ 0 + δ 2Vixt + ∑ γ j comm j ,t + η i ,t (2) j =1 Where ε t2 is the squared residual of from equation (1) for interest rate i. Commj,t represents the jth type of communication, which in our study are the FAD press releases, MPR releases, or speeches. We will set this variable equal 1 on communication days and 0 otherwise. We will compare the variance of these market rates on communication against the average variance on all non-communication days controlling for the gradual decline in market volatility over our period of study by including the VIX index.14 Specifically, if Bank communications in fact convey important ``market moving`` information then we expect that γj,t to be positive and statistically significant. Section 5: Data Our data consists of daily observations over the post-FAD period: October 30, 2000 to May 31, 2007.15 We exclude the three months following the September 11, 2001 terrorist attacks, in line with the methodology of Kohn & Sack, due to the disruption in financial markets around that period that may lead to distortions. This makes our sample size 2313 days for each regression. In order to study the impact of communications on both short as well as longer term interest rate expectations we use yields of different maturities as the dependent variables. At the short end we use the 3 month CDOR16 interest rate as this is the rate to which the 14 Kohn & Sack (2003) argue that a comparison of the volatility on FOMC statement days against the level of volatility observed over the week preceding each statement is a superior measure as it better controls for patterns of volatility over the sample. We find however, that including a dummy for the week prior to a communication event has little impact on our results. As well, we find, as in Kohn & Sack, and Reeves and Sawicki, that estimating equation (5) using GARCH (without including the VIX) does not change our results. 15 October 30, 2000 is the date the Bank of Canada issued a press release stating the 2000-2001 dates for the FAD 16 The CDOR rate is tabulated by Reuters at 10:00 and is a survey of the 9 major Canadian dealers. The top and bottom rates are dropped and the rest are averaged. The CDOR is announced at 10:25. 20 BAX futures contracts settle and was found by Johnson (2003) to be a good measure of market expectations. As well, we include the front BAX contracts17 and 2-, 5-, & 10-year Government of Canada benchmark bond yields; however, we first needed to make an adjustment to these yields as there were issues with duration and rollover with both series. That is, for these series, the actual duration of the instrument changes on a daily basis, with big jumps when the contract changes or rolls over. We therefore calculated a 90 day, 180 day and 270 day constant maturity futures-based interest rate by linearly interpolating between the rates on the front four BAX futures contracts. We will refer to these contracts as BAX1, BAX2, and BAX3 respectively. Next, consistent with Reeves and Sawicki, we calculated 2, 5 and 10 year constant maturity bond yields using the zero coupon curve, available on the Bank of Canada website. These yields were used in a number of Canadian studies looking at market reaction including Gravelle & Moessner (2002) and Parent (2002-2003). For a more detail description of the control variables including the macroeconomic surprise variables see Appendix A 5.2 Macroeconomic announcements data Using OLS to estimate equation (1), we include in our study the subset of independent macro surprise variables that were significant at the 5 per cent levels over our sample (see appendix C). Among For Canada, this includes both the core and headline consumer price index releases, the employment & GDP releases, housing starts, the Ivey purchasing managers index, leading indicator, manufacturing shipments and retail sales. The U.S. macro surprise variables we find significant include, core CPI, GDP, hourly earnings, industrial production, ISM, non-farm payrolls, the core and headline producer price indices, the trade balance and the unemployment release18. 6. Results 6.1 Market Impact of Official Bank of Canada Communications 17 Johnson (2003) shows empirically that the front three BAX contracts are among the rates that are most representative of expectations in Canada (under 1 year) and Harvey (1996) shows that changes in futures prices tend to respond more quickly than (or lead) other money market rates in their reaction to economic news. 18 The Ivey Purchasing managers index begins in January 2001 21 As can be seen in Table 1, FAD press statements and speeches have a significant impact on the volatility of market rates over the full sample, October 2000 to May 2007. The FAD press statements are significant for all BAX interest rates and the 2-year yield and have the largest impact in the 2nd and 3rd BAX. This implies that market participants, on average over the sample, find that press releases provide important information for the short to medium term outlook. Yields longer than 2 years are not significantly impacted by any type of communication. Interestingly, the MPR was not significant in any of our tests. This could be due to one of two things. First, in the post-FAD period, MPR(U)s closely follow FAD press statements. It is possible, then, that these FAD press statements are “scooping” the new information in the MPR. As discussed earlier, Connolly & Kohler (2006) found that the MPR was significant, however, their sample covers the 1997 to 2004 period. When they run their test over the shorter post FAD-only period, they find that the MPR is no longer significant. This is consistent with the fact that in the pre-FAD period, the MPR did not follow the rate decision announcement by any pre-specified time period, as these decisions were made on an as needed basis. Another possible explanation is that there is an impact but as we are using daily data and are unable to control sufficiently for other news that day, this other news is drowning out the impact of the communication event. This theory is supported by the findings of Reeves and Sawicki who found that the BoE Inflation Report was not significant at a daily frequency, but significant when they used intraday data. Table 1: Full sample results n ε i2,t = δ 0 + δ 2Vixt + ∑ γ j comm j ,t + η i ,t j =1 Increase in Var(ε) due to: Interest Rates Var(ε) noncomm days 3.116 90D CDOR (0.000) 13.367 BAX1 (0.000) Fad Press Release 0.772 (0.392) 14.761 (0.001) 22 MPR(U) Speeches 5.944 (0.289) 17.014 (0.295) 0.261 (0.776) 6.431 (0.060) BAX2 BAX3 2Y Bond` 5Y Bond 10Y Bond 23.701 (0.000) 28.621 (0.000) 17.882 (0.000) 16.990 (0.000) 14.634 (0.000) 24.463 (0.212) 23.963 (0.234) 14.333 (0.249) 4.547 (0.519) -0.833 (0.863) 24.930 (0.004) 26.570 (0.010) 14.975 (0.023) 5.146 (0.283) -0.251 (0.934) 15.586 (0.021) 16.241 (0.037) 5.236 (0.177) 2.121 (0.460) 0.432 (0.844) Given that speeches rarely, as discussed above, deviate from the discussion presented in the published MPR, the finding that speeches had an impact on markets, over the full sample, while the MPR did not, was a bit of a puzzle at first. However, as can be seen in Graph 1 below, which displays our volatility measure (the squared residuals from the estimated equation 1) for the BAX2 rate over our sample (the red bars) we see that there are two clusters of high volatility days that help explain this result (note that the green line in this graph is the average volatility on non-communication days). Both of these high volatility periods are marked by higher uncertainty in markets due to either financial headwinds from accounting scandals such as Enron and Worldcom in the earlier period or SARs, the East Coast Blackout and a rapidly appreciating Canadian Dollar in the second period. These periods are also significant in that a number of speeches included inter FAD updates to the Bank’s views about the future direction of monetary policy (which would cause significant volatility in market prices as “new” information is incorporated into market prices), and that during these periods FLSs were not used in FAD press statements or MPR(U)’s. To test this hypothesis empirically, we conducted a sensitivity analysis by removing one by one, the speeches that had the largest impact on our market rates. By removing only two speeches (2 per cent of our sample), our results were no longer significant at the 5 per cent level, thus providing support to our theory that it is only a handful of speeches that impact market rates. 23 Graph 1 400 7 350 6 Enron Worldcom Financial Headwinds 300 250 5 SARS East Coast Blackout Strong appreciation of Canadian Dollar 4 200 ON Rate Target 3 150 100 2 Var BAX2 on nonCommunication Days: 23.7 BAX2 50 0 O ct -0 0 M ar -0 1 Ju l-0 1 N ov -0 1 M ar -0 2 Ju l-0 2 N ov -0 2 A pr -0 3 A ug -0 3 D ec -0 3 A pr -0 4 A ug -0 4 D ec -0 4 A pr -0 5 A ug -0 5 Ja n06 M ay -0 6 Se p06 Ja n07 M ay -0 7 0 1 7. Impact of forward looking Statements on Asset Prices: Are Markets viewing these as unconditional commitments Johnson, Johnson & Fay (2006) define FLSs as communications that explicitly state Governing council’s view of the likely future path for policy rates. In this section we are interested in how these statements have impacted market behaviour. More specifically, we examine empirically whether these statements have helped markets in their understanding of the Bank of Canada’s monetary policy reaction function or instead have only made the monetary policy actions of the central bank more predictable. If the latter is true, this would cause market participants to react less to information that is relevant in calculating the reaction function in the near term, and in turn reduce the information content embodied in rates. As previously mentioned, some argue that FLSs improve transparency about the future direction of monetary policy and as such could reduce volatility in interest rates and possibly increase the central banks’ influence over the full range of the yield curve, potentially enhancing the effectiveness of monetary policy actions. On the flip side of the 24 debate, the main concerns are that this policy guidance could be taken as a precommitment as it is difficult to condition the statements, and that it may lead to less independent analysis of the economy by the market. If market participants do in fact view FLSs as a rough pre-commitment and the consistent presence of a FLS makes the Bank of Canada predictable, then outside of the information provided in unanticipated changes in the FLS, the information about the Bank’s view of the economic outlook would be less in focus and thus longer-dated BAX rates and bond yields should move less on FAD days. In addition, market participants should react less to macroeconomic news given the consistent inclusion of FLSs. We first examine the hypothesis that interest rates will react less during the period when the FLS is included on a regular basis in the FAD and MPR statements. This is done in two ways. We first split our sample in two at July 22, 2004, the point at which the BoC began using FLSs in a consistent manner, and examine the communication coefficient estimates over this July 2004 to May 2007 sample period. Tables 2a and 2b provides estimates of the communications coefficients over the first and second sample respectively. In the first sample, a period where the FLS was used inconsistently and sparingly, the FAD and speeches are significant for various maturities of interest rates. In Table 2b we can see that there are, for all but one interest rate, no longer any communication events that are significant.19 Table 2a: First Subsample Results Increase in Var(ε) due to: Interest rate 90D CDOR BAX1 BAX2 Var(ε) on non-comm days 4.608 (0.000) 17.291 (0.000) 29.561 (0.000) Fad Press Release 1.137 (0.442) 18.345 0.004 31.538 (0.013) 19 MPR(U) Speeches 11.486 (0.278) 30.053 (0.297) 37.011 (0.270) -0.010 (0.995) 11.264 (0.079) 27.197 (0.036) Although the MPR has a significant impact on 10 year Bond, the coefficient is negative, which seemed a bit strange at first, however, the BoC attemps to set MPR dates when there are not other major economic events, therefore it is possible that if the MPR has no impact on the volatility of 10 year yields, on average MPR dates may have a lower variance than other non-communication dates. 25 BAX3 2Y Bond 5Y Bond 10Y Bond 35.703 (0.000) 23.929 (0.000) 22.129 (0.000) 18.452 (0.000) 34.532 (0.304) 23.584 (0.280) 12.222 (0.336) 3.955 (0.651) 34.880 (0.026) 19.596 (0.058) 5.942 (0.448) -1.299 (0.775) 27.055 (0.071) 4.779 (0.491) 0.392 (0.933) -0.799 (0.827) Table 2b: Second Subsample Results Increase in Var(ε) due to: Interest rate 90D CDOR BAX1 BAX2 BAX3 2Y Bond 5Y Bond 10Y Bond Var(ε) on non-comm days 0.923 (0.000) 8.012 (0.000) 15.889 (0.000) 19.110 (0.000) 9.906 (0.000) 10.054 (0.000) 9.376 (0.000) Fad Press Release 0.308 (0.441) 8.423 0.070 13.509 (0.121) 13.798 (0.175) 7.956 (0.161) 3.007 (0.415) 0.113 (0.969) MPR(U) Speeches -0.124 (0.733) 1.348 (0.760) 9.329 (0.485) 12.077 (0.462) 4.607 (0.528) -2.803 (0.193) -4.942 (0.001) 1.100 (0.199) 1.417 (0.581) 1.597 (0.680) 1.389 (0.753) 3.020 (0.409) 2.814 (0.450) 0.952 (0.727) These findings seem to support the idea that markets focus nearly solely on the FLS and view it as a rough pre-commitment in that, in contrast to our earlier results, FAD press statements are no longer significant. However, it could also be the case that markets reduced reaction to FAD press releases is due to their better or increased understanding of the reaction function of the Bank, as markets became accustomed to the new FAD regime. That is, there are fewer information asymmetries between the central bank and markets about the reaction function and therefore less ‘new’ information in central bank communication. We will look at each of these explanations in turn. 26 One caveat before we continue is that there are two factors that may reduce the robustness of these results somewhat. The first is that because we are splitting our sample, our sample size is halved, reducing the statistical strength of the test. The second is that there are significantly fewer periods of uncertainty in the second half (and fewer macroeconomic turning points in monetary policy) and as such market participants perhaps have less “new” or less “important” information to react to, relative to the earlier sample. 7.1 Testing Possible Explanations To test whether central has become more transparent or just more predictable over the second half of our sample we conduct two tests. In the first, we conduct a test using a cross dummies which are first set to one on FAD press release dates that contain a FLS, and, separately, the cross dummies are set to one on the subsequent FAD date (the FAD date following one that has a FAD press release with a FLS). An additional explanatory variable, the variable that cross-multiplies the original FAD dummy with one of the two FLS dummy, is added to the second stage regression. If markets are ignoring information surrounding the FLS we would expect the coefficient on our cross-dummy variables to be large and negative. Table 3 provides the coefficients and their significance level for the full sample and cross dummy for both the current FAD press statement and the subsequent FAD press statement scenarios. As can be seen below, the coefficients on the cross dummies are in general negative and, at least in the first scenario significant at the 10 per cent level for all but one of the yields. This supports our hypothesis that the Bank of Canada has become more predictable over the second half of our sample. Table 3: FAD FLS Cross Dummy Regressions Interest rate 90D CDOR Testing the impact of the FLS on FAD Testing the impact of FLS on Press Statement Days Subsequent FAD Press Statement Days FAD Press Release Fad Press Release FAD Press Subsequent FAD Full Sample Cross Dummy Release Full Press Release Sample Cross Dummy 2.741 (0.084) 2.482 (0.102) -3.865 (0.021) 27 -3.491 (0.035) BAX1 BAX2 BAX3 2Y Bond 5Y Bond 10Y Bond 22.607 (0.001) 42.049 (0.003) 50.078 (0.003) 26.968 (0.028) 13.705 (0.101) 3.888 (0.437) -15.406 0.065 -33.610 (0.040) -46.150 (0.018) -23.083 (0.073) -16.474 (0.079) -7.967 (0.180) 14.155 (0.022) 26.461 (0.034) 35.355 (0.070) 19.728 (0.058) 9.062 (0.279) 1.385 (0.776) 1.237 (0.886) -3.127 (0.854) -17.934 (0.375) -9.513 (0.463) -7.837 (0.405) -3.274 (0.582) In the second test we create a 2nd half Canadian and US macro surprise cross dummy by creating a set of dummy variables for macro releases in the second half only, and rerun regression 1 with the inclusion of this new dummy. If markets understand the central bank’s reaction function better, Canadian macro surprise cross dummy test should yield significant positive coefficients as market participants react more fully to new domestic economic information as it arrives. We find however, that for all yields, the majority of the macro surprise dummies were negative20, suggesting that markets reacted less to Canadian macro releases in the second half of our sample. Thus lending further support to our increased predictability hypothesis. 8. Conclusion We find evidence that official Bank of Canada communication, in particular FAD press statements have a significant effect on near to medium term yields suggesting that these communications convey important new information which impact the markets interest rate expectations. The lack of significance in longer term yields may suggest a high level of credibility surrounding the Bank of Canada’s single inflation target objective of 2 per cent over our period of study. As well, the observation that MPR(U)’s were not significant did not come as surprise for two reasons. Over this period, the MPR(U)’s closely followed FAD press statements and by construction conveyed a consistent message for the near to medium term economic outlook, and as mentioned above, longterm yields appear to be well anchored over this period in Canada. 20 A number of these negative cross dummies were also significant at the 5 per cent level. As well, none of the cross dummies with positive coefficients were significant at the 5 per cent level. 28 Over our period of study, in an effort to increase the level of transparency, there was a major shift in the Bank of Canada’s communication strategy, the inclusion of forward looking statements in FAD press statements and MPR(U)’s, which allows us to study the impact of these statements on Central Bank transparency. Reruning our tests on both a split sample (where these statements began being used in a consistent manner) as well as cross-dummies macro-variables to account for dates prior to our split that include FLS’s, our results suggest that there has been a loss of conditionality surrounding forward looking monetary policy assumptions with the introduction of these forward looking statements. Care must be taken, however, when interpreting results of empirical work studying the effects of forward looking language. There are a number of issues related to the small sample size as well as lack of different economic environments. For instance, there are only a few policy turning points over our full sample and none in the second half of sample, the period when forward looking statements were consistently used. As such, there is less uncertainty as well as fewer macroeconomic shocks and/or news to react to, possibly contributing to some of our second half results. As well, empirical work suggests that the pre-existing shape of the yield curve at the time of the communication will impact how markets react to news along the yield curve. Another caveat is that the Bank of Canada has stressed in its communications that it does not react to any one macroeconomic shock or surprise. The smaller reaction of market rates in the second half of our sample to macroeconomic news may in part be a reflection of the market’s better understanding how the Bank of Canada reacts to these shocks. Consequently, instead of reacting to one off shocks, there is more of a gradual shift in policy rate expectations with the accumulation of data that we are unable to pick up in our tests. Finally, using data at a daily frequency may also affect our results as it is not possible to control for all other shocks hitting the market the same day, and further study at an intraday trading frequency might yield different answers. 29 That said, there is a general agreement amongst central bankers that in general, there remain issues surrounding the incorporation of conditionality and uncertainty around this form of guidance, the debate surrounds the weighting of the risks versus the benefits, and the various views on how conditionality can be incorporated into the communications strategy. As such, each central bank has its own view of both the risks and benefits, as well as how to overcome the lack of conditionality surrounding these statements (projections). Consequently, there exists a full spectrum of communication strategies surrounding how much of the policy outlook to reveal, from not saying anything (except in extreme circumstances), to publishing regularly a policy rate forecast. There may also be no one “ideal” communications strategy for mitigating risks to conditionality and uncertainty surrounding these statements. 30 Bibliography Andreou, J. 2005. “Estimating the Impact of Monetary Policy Surprises on Fixed-Income Markets.” Bank of Canada Review (Summer): 11-19. Connolly, E and M. Kohler. 2007. “News and Interest Rate Expectations: A Study of Six Central Banks”. In The analysis of the money market: role, challenges and implications from the monetary policy perspective. Proceedings of a conference held by the European Central Bank. November 2007. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. Ehrmann, M. and M. Fratzscher. 2005. “How Should Central Banks Communicate?” European Central Bank Working Paper No. 557. Ehrmann, M. and M Fratzscher. 2007a. “Communication and Decision-Making by Central Bank Committees: Different Strategies, Same Effectiveness?” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 39(2–3): 509-41. Ehrmann, M. and M. Fratzscher. 2007b. “Transparency, disclosure and the Federal Reserve.” International Journal of Central Banking 3(1): 179-225. Gravelle, T. and R. Moessner. 2002. “Reactions of Canadian Interest Rates to Macroeconomic Announcements: Implications for Monetary Policy Transparency.” Journal of Bond Trading and Management (1) 1: 27-43. Harvey, N. 1996. “The Market for Futures Contracts on Canadian Bankers’ Acceptances.” Bank of Canada Review (Autumn): 19-36. Jen, S. “Currency Economics: My Thoughts on Currencies.” Morgan Stanley, 26 February, 2007. Johnson, G. 2003. “Measuring Interest Rate Expectations in Canada.” Bank of Canada Review (Summer): 17-27. Johnson, M., G. Johnson, and C. Fay. 2006. “Communicating with Financial Markets.” MPRC Discussion Note. Johnston, J., and J DiNardo.1997. Econometric Methods, Fourth Edition. The McGrawHill Companies, Inc. Kahn, G. 2007. Communicating a Policy Path: The Next Frontier in Central Bank Transparency? Kansas City Economic Review, First quarter 2007. King, M. 2006. Speech at the Lord Mayor’s Banquet for Bankers and Merchants of the City of London at the Mansion House, London, England, 21 June. Kohn, D. and B. Sack. 2003. “Central Bank Talk: Does it Matter and Why?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 31 Kohn, D. 2005. “Central Bank Communication.” Speech at the Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania. January 9. Federal Reserve Board of Governors. Kuttner, K. 2000. “Monetary Policy Surprises and Interest Rates: Evidence from the Fed Funds Futures Market.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No.99. Moessner R., T. Gravelle, and P. Sinclair. 2005. “Measures of Monetary Policy Transparency and the Transmission Mechanism”. In Mahadeva, L. & P. Sinclair (eds.). How Monetary Policy Works. Routledge. Moessner, R. and W. Nelson. 2008. "Central Bank Policy Rate Guidance and Financial Market Functioning" . BIS Working Paper No. 246 Muller, P. and M. Zelmer. 1999. “Greater Transparency in Monetary Policy: Impact on Financial Markets.” Bank of Canada Technical Report No. 86. Parent, N. 2002-2003. “Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data” Bank of Canada Review (Winter): 29-34. Reeves, R. and M. Sawicki. 2007. “Do Financial Markets React to Bank of England Communication?” European Journal of Political Economy 23: 207-227. Reinhart, V. and B. Sack. 2006. “Grading the Federal Open Market Committee’s Communications.” Paper presented at the 2006 AEA meetings, Boston. Rudebusch, Glenn D. 2008. “Publishing Central Bank Interest Rate Forecasts.” FRBSF Economic Letter No. 2008-02. 32 Appendix A: Control Variables A.1 Macroeconomic Surprises Gravelle & Moessner (2002) and Parent (2002-2003), among others, found that the surprise component of macroeconomic announcement has a statistically significant impact on a number of Canadian market rates. Following Gravelle & Moessner (2002) and Reeves & Sawicki (2005), we calculate standardized21 macroeconomic surprises as: mac = u i ,t ( X i ,t − X ie,t ) Ω iX (A1) Where X i ,t − X ie,t is the actual minus the market expected value of the ith macroeconomic release on day t, and Ω iX is the sample standard deviation of surprises for the ith macroeconomic release. This is set to zero on days where no announcements are made.22 Financial market expectations or forecast of the macroeconomic data release used in calculating the surprise component are provided by Bloomberg surveys conducted prior to each announcement. We use Bloomberg market poll surveys as our market expectations instead of Money Market Services International as this latter source has data limitations in the more recent period; however, both polls survey a similar group of economists2324. 21 We standardize the macroeconomic surprises in order to make the coefficients comparable across indicators. 22 Another factor that would influence yields would be revisions to macroeconomic releases. However, we do not have a full sample of data for this, and so will not include it in our study. Given that the macro revision is released at the same time as the current period macro release, not including the revisions if anything may make the result marginally noisier. 23 Although Gravelle & Moessner (2002) and Parent (2002-2003) use S&P MMS survey data for their full sample, we were unable to do this as the survey becomes inconsistent after mid. 2003 Recent empirical work has faced this same challenge and has found that where the two surveys overlap, the two data sources agree very closely. Comparison of our data confirm this. 24 Reeves & Sawicki also split their macroeconomic survey data sample between MMS & Bloomberg due to data limitations. Other papers that have dealt with this issue include Robitaille & Roush (2005), Gurkaynak, Levin, & Swanson (2006), and Gurkaynak & Wolfers (2005). 33 A.2 Policy Surprises As pointed out in Kohn & Sack (2003) and empirically shown through factor analysis in Gurkaynak, Sack and Swanson (2004), the market response to a policy announcement consists of two distinct factors: The first is the difference between where markets expect the central bank to set its policy rate and the action the Central Bank actually takes on one particular policy date. This is the “surprise” component. The second is linked to the press statement accompanying the policy action and is the perceived change in the future path of policy. As we want to focus on the communications aspect, the press statement, we will need to control for any impact the “surprise” component of the policy action by the Bank of Canada has on our key rates. Given our close link with the US, we will also test for Canadian market reaction to US policy surprises. A.2.1 Canadian Policy Surprises Following the methodology of Andreou (2005) we will take the one day difference in the 1 month bankers acceptance (BA) rate25 on Canadian monetary policy decision days. ΔON tu = bat − bat −1 (A2) Where bat- bat-1 is the surprise component of policy. We set this equal to zero on nonpolicy days. A.2.2 US Policy Surprises Consistent with the work of Kuttner (2000) we measure US policy surprises as: Δff t u = [D /( D − d )] ⋅ Δff 1t 25 (A3) Johnson (2003) shows empirically, by testing the expectations hypothesis, that 1 month Bankers Acceptances are the best proxy for market expectations (over our period of study). A number of studies use the Reuters survey of market economists as their proxy for market expectations. We find this measure in Canada to not be statistically significantly different from our measure, however we chose our measure for a number of reasons including the time lag between the survey and the actual announcement. 34 Where D is the total # of days in the month, d is the day of the month of the FOMC decision, and Δff 1t is the change in the futures rate on the day of the policy decision (including inter-meeting actions). We set this equal to zero on non-policy days. A.3 U.S. Communications As pointed out in Gravelle & Moessner (2002) and shown empirically in Connolly & Kohler (2004), “Because Canada is a small open economy, with direct links to the US economy in terms of trade and capital flows, it should be of no surprise to find that Canadian Debt instruments are significantly influenced by US interest rates, which are in turn affected by various US economic announcements”. Although we have already included US macro announcements and policy surprises, we have not controlled for another major factor that influences US interest rates (and in turn Canadian rates), FOMC communications. To control for the impact of FOMC communications on Canadian rates we will include the one day change in the second Eurodollar futures contract26 as well as the one day change in the on the run 2 year Treasury on dates of FOMC press releases, testimonies and minutes27. 26 The second Eurodollar futures contract is tied to the three-month LIBOR rate on the date of expiration – a rate that is primarily influenced by the expected fed funds rate over the subsequent three months. 27 Reinhart & Sack (2005) test both short and medium term expectations using these rates and find FOMC press releases, testimonies and minutes (following the change in release time) to be significant. We will therefore only include these Fed communications into our regression. 35 Appendix B: The Role of Fixed Announcement Dates in Enhancing Monetary Policy Reaction Function Understanding As argued in Gravelle and Moessner (2002) and Moessner, Gravelle, and Sinclair (2005) a key ingredient to greater monetary policy reaction function understanding by market participants is fixed pre-announced policy rate action dates. Without, fixed action dates market participants find it difficult accumulate and distil the macroeconomic data in a fashion that roughly simulates the way the Bank uses it for its economic outlook and as such properly understand a central banks monetary policy reaction function. The transparency advantages of fixed action dates are brought out in stark relief when one thinks about fixed dates on which a central bank does not change the policy rate. In a regime without fixed dates, a day that bank does not change rates looks the same as any other day. However, when fixed dates are in place the fact the central bank did not change its policy rate on the designated date is news. In addition to information generated by the action itself (of moving the target rate or not on fixed action dates), fixed action dates also provide the central bank with an additional opportunity to communicate to the public, via a press release that accompanies the monetary policy decision point, its views about its economic outlook and what drives any revision to it as well as its policy stance or guidance that results from this outlook. 36 Appendix C Table C.1: Use of Forward Looking Policy Language in Bank of Canada FAD Press Statements and MPR(U)’s Date Event Change in the Target ON Rate Near Term Direction of ON Rate Implied by FLS Balance of Risk Forward-Looking Policy Statement (FLS) Balance of Risks Statement May 29, 2007 FAD 0 Higher ON rate Slight tilt to upside … some increase in the target for the overnight rate may be required in the near term… On balance, the Bank judges that there is an increased risk that future inflation will persist above the 2 per cent inflation target… Apr 26, 2007 MPR Unchanged ON rate Slight tilt to upside The current level of the target for the overnight rate is judged, at this time, to be consistent with achieving the inflation target over the medium term. The Bank continues to judge that the risks to its inflation projection are roughly balanced, although there is now a slight tilt to the upside. Apr 24, 2007 FAD 0 Unchanged ON rate Slight tilt to upside Mar 6, 2007 FAD 0 Unchanged ON rate Balanced The Bank continues to judge that the risks to its inflation projection are roughly balanced, although there is now a slight tilt to the upside. Despite recent volatility in global financial markets, the Bank continues to judge that the risks to its inflation projection are roughly balanced Jan 18, 2007 MPRU Unchanged ON rate Balanced The current level of the target for the overnight rate is judged, at this time, to be consistent with achieving the inflation target over the medium term. In line with the Bank's outlook, the current level of the target for the overnight rate is judged, at this time, to be consistent with achieving the inflation target over the medium term. The current level of the policy interest rate is judged, at this time, to be consistent with achieving the inflation target. Jan 16, 2007 FAD 0 Unchanged ON rate Balanced In line with the Bank’s outlook, the current level of the target for the overnight rate is judged, at this time, to be consistent with achieving the inflation target over the medium term. Dec 5, FAD 0 Unchanged Balanced In line with the Bank's 37 The risks around the Bank's inflation projection continue to be judged to be roughly balanced, but the main upside and downside risks have diminished somewhat since the October MPR. The Bank continues to judge that the risks to the inflation projection are roughly balanced, but the main upside and downside risks outlined in the October MPR have diminished somewhat The Bank judges that, 2006 ON rate Oct 19, 2006 MPR Oct 17, 2006 FAD Sep 6, 2006 FAD Jul 13, 2006 MPRU July 11, 2006 FAD May 24, 2006 FAD Apr 27, 2006 MPR Unchanged ON rate Balanced 0 Unchanged ON rate Balanced 0 Unchanged ON rate Balanced Unchanged ON rate Small tilt to downside later in projection 0 Unchanged ON rate Small tilt to downside later in projection +25bp Unchanged ON rate Short term risks balanced. Small tilt to downside later in projection Higher ON Rate Short term risks balanced. Small tilt 38 outlook, the current level of the target for the overnight rate is judged at this time to be consistent with achieving the inflation target over the medium term. The current level of the policy interest rate is judged, at this time, to be consistent with achieving the inflation target. In line with this updated outlook, the current level of the target for the overnight rate is judged at this time to be consistent with achieving the inflation target over the medium term. In line with this outlook, the current level of the target for the overnight rate is judged at this time to be consistent with achieving the inflation target over the medium term. The current level of the policy interest rate is judged at this time to be consistent with achieving the inflation target In line with the Bank's largely unchanged outlook, the current level of the target for the overnight rate is judged at this time to be consistent with achieving the inflation target over the medium term. With today's increase, the target for the overnight rate is now at a level that is expected to keep the Canadian economy on the base-case path projected in the April Monetary Policy Report (MPR) and to return inflation to the 2 per cent target. In line with the Bank's outlook, some modest further increase in the policy interest rate may be overall, risks around the inflation projection are roughly balanced. The Bank judges that the risks to its inflation projection are roughly balanced. It is the Bank's judgment that, overall, risks around the inflation projection are roughly balanced. While both these risks appear to be a little greater than they were in July, the Bank continues to judge that, overall, risks are roughly balanced. the Bank continues to judge that these risks are roughly balanced, with a small tilt to the downside later in the projection period because of the possibility of a disorderly resolution of global imbalances. Risks to the projection remain roughly balanced, with a small tilt to the downside later in the projection period related to global imbalances. The Bank continues to assess the risks to this projection to be as presented in the MPR. The Bank judges that these risks are roughly balanced, with a small tilt to the downside to downside later in projection Short term risks balanced. Small tilt to downside later in projection Apr 25, 2006 FAD +25bp Higher ON Rate Mar 7, 2006 FAD +25bp Higher ON Rate Jan 26, 2006 MPRU Jan 24, 2006 FAD +25bp Higher ON rate Short term risks balanced. Risks tilted to downside later in projection Dec 6, 2005 FAD +25bp Higher ON rate Oct 20, 2005 MPR Short term risks balanced. Risks tilted to downside later in projection Short term risks balanced. Risks tilted to Higher ON Rate Higher ON rate Short term risks balanced. Risks tilted to downside later in projection Short term risks balanced. Risks tilted to downside later in projection 39 required. later in the projection period. In line with the Bank's outlook for the Canadian economy, some modest further increase in the policy interest rate may be required to keep aggregate supply and demand in balance and inflation on target over the medium term. Consistent with this view, some modest further increase in the policy interest rate may be required to keep aggregate supply and demand in balance and inflation on target over the medium term In line with the Bank's outlook, some modest further increase in the policy interest rate would be required. The Bank judges that the risks to its projection are roughly balanced, with a small tilt to the downside later in the projection period. In line with the Bank's basecase projection and current assessment of risks, some modest further increase in the policy interest rate would be required to keep aggregate supply and demand in balance and inflation on target over the medium term. In line with the outlook, some further reduction in monetary stimulus will be required to maintain a balance between aggregate supply and demand over the next four to six quarters and keep inflation on target. In line with the Bank's outlook, some further reduction of monetary stimulus will be required. Risks to the Bank's projection remain balanced for 2006 and tilted to the downside through 2007 and beyond. Recent data do not alter the Bank's outlook for growth and inflation, including its assessment of risks, as set out in the January Update Risks to the Bank's projection remain balanced for 2006. Through 2007 and beyond, risks are tilted to the downside, as the unwinding of global imbalances could involve a slowdown in world economic activity. The Bank continues to judge that the risks to the outlook are balanced over the short term, but are tilted to the downside through 2007 and beyond. Short-term risks to this projection appear to be balanced. But looking further out to 2007 and beyond, there are downside later in projection Oct 18, 2005 FAD +25bp Sep 7, 2005 FAD +25bp Jul 14, 2005 MPRU Jul 12, 2005 FAD May 25, 2005 FAD Higher ON rate Short term risks balanced. Risks tilted to downside later in projection Short term risks balanced. Risks tilted to downside later in projection In line with the Bank's outlook, and given that the Canadian economy now appears to be operating at capacity, some further reduction of monetary stimulus will be required to maintain a balance between aggregate supply and demand over the next four to six quarters, and to keep inflation on target. None increasing risks that the unwinding of global economic imbalances could involve a period of weak world economic growth. Short-term risks to this projection appear to be balanced. But as we look further out to 2007 and beyond, there are increasing risks that the unwinding of global economic imbalances could involve a period of weak global growth. Despite developments associated with higher energy prices, risks to the Bank's outlook for the Canadian economy through 2006 still appear to be reasonably balanced. Over the medium term, however, there is increasing risk that the correction of global current account imbalances could involve a period of weakness in world aggregate demand. These risks appear to be balanced. Over the medium term, however, there is increasing risk that the correction of global current account imbalances could involve a period of weakness in world aggregate demand. Higher ON rate Tilted to downside later in projection In line with this outlook, some reduction of monetary stimulus will be required in the near term. 0 Higher ON rate Tilted to downside later in projection However, in line with the Bank's outlook, some reduction in the amount of monetary stimulus will be required in the near term to keep aggregate demand and supply in balance and inflation on target. The risks to the outlook through 2006 appear balanced, but over the medium term risks related to global imbalances are increasing. 0 Higher ON rate In line with this outlook, a reduction of monetary stimulus will be required None 40 over time. Apr 14, 2005 MPR Apr 12, 2005 FAD Mar 1, 2005 FAD Jan 27, 2005 MPRU Higher ON rate In line with this outlook, a reduction of monetary stimulus will be required over time. None 0 Higher ON rate None 0 Higher ON rate In line with this outlook, a reduction of monetary stimulus will be required over time. …the implications for the pace of reduction in monetary stimulus are essentially unchanged from those that the Bank presented in January's Update The pace of reduction in monetary stimulus is likely to be slower than envisioned in the October Report. Higher ON rate (but at a slower rate than anticipated at the time of the MPR) None None Jan 25, 2005 Dec 7, 2004 Oct 21, 2004 FAD 0 None – refers to MPRU None FAD 0 None None None Oct 19, 2004 FAD +25bp Higher ON rate Sep 8, 2004 Jul 22, 2004 FAD +25bp Higher ON rate Higher ON rate This base-case projection assumes further reduction of monetary stimulus over time to keep the economy near its production capacity and achieve the inflation target. Further reduction of monetary stimulus will be required over time to keep inflation on target, with the pace depending on the Bank's continuing assessment of the prospects for factors that affect pressures on capacity and, hence, inflation. None None Jul 20, 2004 Jun 8, 2004 Apr 15, FAD 0 Monetary stimulus will have to be removed to avoid a buildup of inflation pressures. The pace of the withdrawal will depend on the evolving prospects for inflation and for capacity pressures None – refers to MPRU FAD 0 None None None Overall, the risks to the MPR Higher ON rate MPRU MPR Balanced 41 None None None 2004 Apr 13, 2004 Mar 2, 2004 Jan 22, 2004 Jan 20, 2004 Dec 2, 2003 Oct 22, 2003 Oct 15, 2003 Sep 3, 2003 Jul 17, 2003 July 15, 2003 June 3, 2003 Apr 23, 2003 FAD -25bp Balanced FAD -25bp Apr 15, 2003 Mar 4, 2003 FAD +25bp FAD +25bp Jan 23, 2003 MPRU Jan 21, 2003 FAD 0 Higher ON rate Dec 3, FAD 0 Higher ON MPRU None outlook appear balanced. The risks to the outlook now appear balanced None None None None FAD -25bp None None FAD 0 None None None None MPR FAD 0 None None FAD -25bp None None None None MPRU FAD -25bp None None FAD 0 None None The Bank believes that further reductions in monetary stimulus over time will be necessary, but the timing and pace will depend on the evolution of inflation expectations and the strength of domestic and external demand. None None As indicated in the MPR Update, further reductions in monetary stimulus will be required to return inflation to the target over the medium term. With the stance of monetary policy currently very stimulative, a reduction of stimulus will be required in order to return inflation to the 2 per cent target over the medium term. However, with the stance of monetary policy currently very stimulative, a reduction of stimulus will be required in order to return inflation to the 2 per cent target over the medium term. timely removal of monetary None MPR Higher ON rate Higher ON rate Higher ON rate 42 None None None None 2002 rate Oct 23, 2002 MPR Higher ON rate Oct 16, 2002 FAD 0 Higher ON rate Sep 4, 2002 FAD 0 Higher ON rate Jul 24, 2002 MPRU Jul 16, 2002 Jun 4, 2002 Apr 24, 2002 FAD +25bp FAD +25bp Apr 16, 2002 Mar 5, 2002 Jan 23, 2002 Jan 15, FAD FAD Higher ON rate Balanced None None At this time, the risks to our projected rate of growth of 3 to 4 per cent growth appear to be balanced. (PR) None None None +25bp As the economy approaches its capacity, the task for monetary policy is to gauge economic strength and the implications for future inflation. This means reducing the substantial amount of stimulus in place in a timely and measured manner. None 0 None None None None None None MPRU FAD None None MPR Higher ON rate Higher ON rate stimulus will be required to achieve the inflation target over the medium term Going forward, further removal of monetary stimulus will be required, with the pace and extent of the tightening depending on unfolding developments and on their implications for pressures on capacity and inflation in Canada. It remains the Bank's view, going forward, that timely removal of monetary stimulus will be required to achieve the inflation target over the medium term. Looking forward, it remains the Bank's view that, as the Canadian economy continues to expand and to approach its production capacity, further measured reductions in monetary stimulus will be necessary in order to achieve the inflation control target of 2 per cent over the medium term. It remains the Bank's view that the underlying economic situation will require further reductions in the amount of monetary stimulus (PR) None -25bp 43 None 2002 Nov 27, 2001 Nov 7, 2001 Oct 23, 2001 Sep 17, 2001 Aug 28, 2001 Aug 1, 2001 Jul 27, 2001 May 29, 2001 May 1, 2001 April 17, 2001 Mar 6, 2001 Feb 6, 2001 Jan 23, 2001 Dec 5, 2000 Nov 9, 2000 FAD -50bp MPR None None None None FAD -75bp None None Intermeeting FAD -50bp None None -25bp None None None None MPRU FAD -25bp None None FAD -25bp None None None None MPR FAD -25bp None None FAD -50bp None None None None MPRU FAD -25bp None None FAD 0 None None None None MPR Table C.2a: Consistency of BOC forward looking policy statements and monetary policy decisions: Post-FAD full sample excld. 3 months following September 11 Monetary Policy Decision (following meeting) Direction of Forward looking Policy Statement Easing No Change Tightening All in Press Release or MPR(U) 0 0 0 0 Easing 0 8 0 8 Neutral 0 10* 12 22 Tightening 12 6 2 20 No Forward Looking Statement 12 25 14 50 All 44 *on one occasion there was no change in the following meeting but an ease in the next meeting Table C.2b: Consistency of BOC forward looking policy statements and monetary policy decisions: Post-FAD 2nd half Monetary Policy Decision (following meeting) Direction of Forward looking Policy Statement Easing No Change Tightening All in Press Release or MPR(U) 0 0 0 0 Easing 0 8 0 8 Neutral 0 5 10 15 Tightening 0 0 0 0 No Forward Looking Statement 0 13 10 23 All 45 Table C.3: Canadian interest rate response to surprises: pre and post FAD subsamples Rate Front BAX Significant surprises, Post-FAD (Oct.31/00May 31/07); c_cpixfe (2.2660, 0.0000); c_emp (2.2210, 0.0006); c_gdp (0.8430, 0.0110); c_ivey (0.8356, 0.0224); c_rtl_sls (1.6918, 0.0022) 2 R 0.3024 0.2694 us_cpixfe (1.0142, 0.0292); us_gdp (1.8894, 0.0054); us_mich (0.8012, 0.0389); us_nfp (5.1355, 0.0000); us_unemp (-1.7781, 0.0073) us_cpixfe (1.4655, 0.0074); us_gdp (2.2557, 0.0039); us_hr_earn (2.1960, 0.0179); us_ism (2.3627, 0.0376); us_nfp (6.4945, 0.0000); us_unemp (-1.9770, 0.0111) 0.2568 c_cpixfe (2.5352, 0.0009); c_emp (3.2099, 0.0004); c_gdp (1.6745, 0.0048); c_rtl_sls (2.3064, 0.0041) 2-year Bond 5-year Bond us_cpixfe (1.1361, 0.0171); us_gdp (1.6855, 0.0151); us_hr_earn (1.9372, 0.0079); us_ind_prod (0.9930, 0.193); us_ism (2.2035, 0.0131); us_nfp (5.4516, 0.0000); us_unemp (-1.8403, 0.0066) c_cpixfe (1.8511, 0.0055); c_emp (2.4162, 0.0027); c_hsg_sts (-0.9512, 0.0149); c_ivey (1.2873, 0.0474); c_rtl_sls (1.6627, 0.0195) 0.3585 0.2634 0.2056 us_cpixfe (1.6574, 0.0260); us_gdp (2.5225, 0.0009); us_hr_earn (2.0707, 0.0469); us_ind_prod (1.9635, 0.0218); us_ism (2.6915, 0.0440); us_mich (1.3477, 0.0163); us_nfp (5.6011, 0.0000) c_cpixfe (3.0472, 0.0194); c_emp (4.6898, 0.0062); c_rtl_sls (3.8159, 0.0083) us_cpixfe (2.4493, 0.0034); us_gdp (2.7636, 0.0059); us_hr_earn (2.8730, 0.0178); us_ind_prod (2.1186, 0.0276); us_ism (3.1486, 0.0277); us_mich (1.5479, 0.0252); us_nfp (6.9083, 0.0000) c_cpixfe (2.4617, 0.0257); c_emp (3.1078, 0.0311); c_ivey (2.0236, 0.0400); c_rtl_sls (2.7872, 0.0332) us_cpixfe (1.6800, 0.0147); us_gdp (2.0822, 0.0190); us_hr_earn (2.5396, 0.0147); us_ind_prod (2.2551, 0.0004); us_ism (3.6300, 0.0079); us_nfp (5.6645, 0.0000); us_unemp (-1.6721, 0.0421) c_cpixfe (1.9462, 0.0419); c_curr_acct (-1.9733, 0.0144); c_hsg_sts (-1.3573, 0.0185); c_ivey (2.4559, 0.0084) Significant surprises, Post-FAD 2nd Half (July 22/04-May31/07) c_cpixfe (1.4575, 0.0080); c_gdp (1.4019, 0.0002); c_ivey (0.7757, 0.0373); c_raw_mat (-0.4882, 0.0429) 0.3091 c_cpixfe (2.6606, 0.0063); c_emp (2.7756, 0.0049); c_gdp (2.3579, 0.0005); c_rtl_sls (1.6396, 0.0405) 0.2899 c_cpixfe (2.6648, 0.0103); c_emp (3.9098, 0.0001); c_gdp (2.9563, 0.0006); c_rtl_sls (1.7852, 0.0196) 0.2394 0.2500 us_nfp (7.6713, 0.0000); us_ppixfe (2.0647, 0.0000); us_unemp (-4.8649, 0.0093) 0.2909 c_cpixfe (2.5743, 0.0036); c_emp (3.3618, 0.0000); c_gdp (2.2952, 0.0024); c_rtl_sls (1.6200, 0.0106) 0.2706 us_nfp (6.1859, 0.0000); us_ppixfe (0.8722, 0.0437); us_unemp (-3.2702, 0.0167) 0.2234 c_curr_acct (3.0674, 0.0187); c_emp (3.0067, 0.0000); c_rtl_sls (1.2659, 0.0380) The first number in parentheses is the coefficient; the second number represents the significance level. Estimated using a Newey-West adjusted covariance matrix. 46 0.2199 us_nfp (6.1014, 0.0000); us_ppixfe (1.5567, 0.0002); us_unemp (-4.0079, 0.0075) us_nfp (5.3438, 0.0000); 28 R2 us_nfp (3.1476, 0.0000); us_ppixfe (0.4860, 0.0421); us_unemp (-2.2254, 0.0050) c_cpixfe (2.4025, 0.0123); c_cpi (1.8341, 0.0318); c_emp (4.8005, 0.0010); c_rtl_sls (3.5724, 0.0079); c_cpixfe (2.5208, 0.0008); c_emp (3.9619, 0.0000); c_gdp (1.7439, 0.0080); c_ivey (1.2418, 0.0384); c_rtl_sls (2.7664, 0.0014) c_cpixfe (2.8916, 0.0023); c_emp (4.3766, 0.0000); c_gdp (1.7828, 0.0182); c_rtl_sls (3.0025, 0.0010) 3rd BAX c_cpixfe (2.8758, 0.0002); c_emp (3.0365, 0.0016); c_rtl_sls (2.4350, 0.0035) R2 us_gdp (1.5311, 0.0001); us_nfp (3.2642, 0.0000); us_gdp (1.0231, 0.0058); us_nfp (2.7792, 0.0000) 2nd BAX Significant surprises28, Post-FAD 1st Half (Oct.31/00-July 21/04) 0.2251 us_cpixfe (1.4323, 0.0053); us_gdp (1.4152, 0.0414); us_hr_earn (1.6987, 0.0268); us_ind_prod (0.8430, 0.0433); us_ism (1.5801, 0.0218); us_nfp (5.0138, 0.0000); us_ppixfe (0.9790, 0.0108); us_unemp (-1.2933, 0.0409) c_cpixfe (1.3067, 0.0255); c_emp (1.6305, 0.0224); c_hsg_sts (-0.8984, 0.0231) 10year Bond CADUS excha nge rate us_cpixfe (1.0933, 0.0304); us_ism (1.2955, 0.0099); us_nfp (3.8224, 0.0000); us_ppi (-0.8034, 0.0283); us_ppixfe (0.9975, 0.0072) c_emp (0.2264, 0.0000); c_lead_ind (0.0785, , 0.0026); c_manu_ship (0.0870, 0.0395); c_rtl_sls (0.1672, 0.0007) us_cpixfe (1.9551, 0.0163); us_ind_prod (1.8255, 0.0034); us_ism (2.5423, 0.0327); us_nfp (5.1961, 0.0000) 0.1579 c_curr_acct (-2.6186, 0.0018); c_hsg_sts (-1.5156, 0.0063); c_ivey (2.2252, 0.0084) us_ppixfe (1.2387, 0.0045) c_curr_acct (3.3261, 0.0256); c_emp (2.5218, 0.0000) 0.1692 us_ism (1.8670, 0.0387); us_nfp (3.8319, 0.0003) c_emp (0.1716, 0.0108); c_lead_ind (0.0857, 0.0019); c_rtl_sls (0.1733, 0.0085) 0.0944 us_ism (1.0035, 0.0186); us_nfp (4.1649, 0.0000); us_ppi (-0.8990. 0.0087); us_ppixfe (1.4020, 0.0031) c_cpixfe (0.1636, 0.0116); c_emp (0.3016, 0.0000); c_manu_ship (0.1671, 0.0353); c_mrch_trade (0.1315, 0.0245); c_rtl_sls (0.1614, 0.0357) us_hr_earn (-0.1204, 0.0206); us_ppi (0.1135, 0.0148); us_trd_bal (-0.0941, 0.0355) us_ppi (0.0717, 0.0496); us_trd_bal (-0.1123, 0.0025) 47 0.1982 0.1160