American University Research Outputs and Local Housing Prices* Qing Hong Abigail Payne April 2003 Abstract The goal of this paper is to examine the effects of local housing prices on university research outputs. The underlying hypothesis is that increases in housing prices lower faculty members’ utilities, and then lead faculty members to re-allocate labor supply, which is reflected as changes in university research outputs. We set up a simple model of the behavior patterns of two kinds of agents: faculty members and universities, and the interactions between the two patterns in the procedure of research production. A faculty member maximizes utility, which is a function of job components (salary and effort) and location components (local housing prices and amenities) by choosing where to work and, simultaneously, where to live. Universities maximize profit (calculated using shadow prices of research outputs) by picking the optimal salary and effort level. This model predicts that housing prices have positive effects on both salaries and research outputs. Using the data of 227 American universities over the period of 15 years, 19851999, our empirical findings suggest: (1) the overall effects of housing prices are significantly positive on both published articles and salaries; (2) housing prices have a larger positive impact on research outputs for more highly ranked universities; and (3) the competition from outside offers has negative effects on research outputs and positive effects on faculty salaries. * We are grateful to Aloysius Siow for very helpful and precise guidance. We thank William Strange, Philip Oreopoulos, Michelle Alexopoulos and Robert McMillan for many constructive comments and discussions. I. Introduction “I know of no greater possible threat to the academic vitality of Stanford than our current housing market,” Provost Condoleezza Rice wrote in a May 7 letter to the president of the campus homeowners’ group. “Our future depends on our ability to attract outstanding faculty, students and staff to Stanford, but the lack of affordable housing has made that effort far more difficult.” …… “The housing market in the area has been bad forever, but by last year it had become a problem,” Cox [the vice provost for institutional planning] says. “Faculty, graduate students, medical residents and postdocs, every category of person, find themselves in a completely untenable housing market. I’ve heard around the country that [due to housing price] coming to Stanford is just a joke.” From Stanford Report [on line], issue of May 13, 1998 The study is motivated by the concern about high local housing prices and tight housing markets in the real world. As shown in the above citation, at least one American university is concerned that its ability to attract good quality faculty is being menaced by high housing prices and tight housing markets. As shown in Panel A of Figure 1, the trend of the index of median housing prices in San Francisco, CA (PMSA), where Stanford University is located, is steeper than that of the annual salaries per faculty member at Stanford since 1995, though salaries keep increasing during the whole sample period. The median housing prices in San Francisco raise fast even relative to that averaged across all the MSA areas since 1995. In the case of facing increasing housing prices, faculty members may react by making new joint job- and residence-location decision, or labor supply decision, or both. As a result, universities’ educational outputs may change. Of these outputs, the research outputs are of most interest since research outputs are one of the most important bases on which universities build up their academic and educational prestige. 1 In this paper, we explore the net effects of local housing prices on university research outputs. We start by setting up a simple theoretical model of two kinds of agents: faculty members and universities. In the model, a faculty member maximizes utility, which is a function of job components (salary and effort) and location components (local housing prices and amenities) by choosing where to work and, simultaneously, where to live. Universities maximize profit (calculated using shadow prices of research outputs) by picking the optimal salary and effort level. The underlying logic for the interactions between the behavior patterns of the two agents is that: (1) given that increased housing prices lower faculty members’ utilities, and that the more able faculty members have more alternative job opportunities than the less able members, universities faced with high local housing prices are forced to offering higher salaries2 to attract faculty members, or accepting lower research outputs; (2) if universities do not offer higher salaries, then outstanding faculty member will choose to accept an offer from another university, or may choose to exert less research. With some standard restrictions on parameters restricted in the model, and using the results, from previous studies, of positive effects of housing prices on personal earnings, our predictions are that the effects of housing prices on both research outputs and salaries are positive; and the effects of amenities are negative. The prediction that the effects of housing prices on research outputs and salaries have the same signs implies that facing increasing local housing prices, universities’ optimal reaction rules are, theoretically, to offer higher salaries and to obtain higher effort levels at the same time. After setting up the theoretical model, we estimate the empirical model to examine the effects predicted in the theoretical analysis, using the data on 227 universities over the period of 1985-19993. We have two measures of research outputs: the number of published articles and citations per article. 1 Someone may argue that some universities exert very few research activities. It is not an issue in this study since our analysis focuses on Research and Doctoral Universities under Carnegie Classifications. See section III of Data for the definitions of the two university categories of by Carnegie Classifications. 2 In reality, except for increasing salaries, universities may increase compensations in alternative forms, such as providing low-interest-rate mortgage and building houses and then selling (or renting) to faculty at low price. In this paper, we mainly focus on the channel of increasing faculty salaries. 3 Some universities have missing data in one year or several years in this period. Our empirical results suggest that, first, the overall effects of housing prices are significantly positive on both salaries and research outputs; second, the estimated effects of housing prices on research outputs are ranked from high to low as we move from the top ranked universities to the lowest ranked ones. Finally, we found that the value of potential job opportunities has negative effects on research outputs and positive effects on salaries, which verify the effect of competition from outside offers. The analysis proceeds as follows. In section II, we set up the theoretical framework. In section III we summarize the data sources and some statistics of main variables. In sections IV and V, the explanation of the empirical strategies and the estimate results are given out, respectively. And, the concluding remarks appear in section VI. II. Theoretical framework To detect the relation between local housing prices and university research outputs, we develop a theoretical model, in which simplified behavior patterns of two kinds of agents – university and faculty members – and their interactions are considered. There are three assumptions for the model: (1) labor is mobile; (2) there is no asymmetric information between a given university and its faculty members – in other words, here is no principle-agent problem; and (3) there is no commuting, that is, faculty members live in the same MSA in which their universities are located. (1) The faculty member’s problem We assume that each faculty member has a utility function over two components: the job component and location component, U lsi = U ( J lsi , Lil ) , with superscript representing individual i and the subscripts location l and school s , respectively. Each component plays a nonnegative role on faculty member utility, that is, U J > 0 and U L > 0 . Valuation of the job component is formed over salary ( S ) and effort ( E ), J lsi = J ( S lsi , Elsi ) , with J S > 0 and J E < 0 (job valuation rises with increased salary and falls with increased effort). ( S lsi , Elsi ) is set by each university; each faculty member makes a take-it-or-leave-it decision. Each individual is endowed with a unit of time, which could be allocated to leisure and/or effort. Let E denote the fraction of the time endowment spent in exerting effort, then (1 − E ) denotes the fraction of leisure time. Next, the location component is a function of local housing prices ( HP ) and amenity conditions ( A ), Lil = L( HPl i , Ali ) , with LHP < 0 and L A > 0 (faculty members value housing prices negatively, and amenities positively). It is assumed that local housing prices ( HP ) and amenity conditions ( A ) are exogenous to faculty member and university decisions – in other words, the faculty group is too small relative to the local housing market and residence environment to affect housing prices and amenities.4 In a reduced form, the utility function can be written as U lsi = U (S lsi , Elsi , HPli , Ali ) (1) We also make the assumptions that all faculty members have some outside offer(s)5, are mobile and able to move without costs. The optimization problem for a faculty is to maximize utility, by making the decision about where to work and, simultaneously, where to live. Specifically, university s brings up a job offer, ( S lsi , Elsi ) , to faculty i ; faculty i makes a take-it-or-leave-it decision, taking the location valuation into accounts.6 With the above assumptions of labor mobility and zero moving cost, in equilibrium, all faculty members obtain the unique level of utility from any university-location combinations, U = U ( J lsi 1 , HPli , Ali ) ∀i,l , and s . (2) Equation (2) implies that, in equilibrium, there is no incentive for a faculty member to move to another university, and location as well. Totally differentiating equation (2) we derive how the changes in the job valuation is affected by changes in housing prices and amenities, dJ lsi = − 4 U U HP dHPli − A dAli UJ UJ (3) This assumption may be violated when a relative big university is located in a small town, with its university size constituting a notable fraction of the local population. We will get back to this discussion in the section of Robustness test. 5 This assumption is made to simplify analysis. One extension could be made by dividing the faculty members into two groups: the tenured professors and the non-tenured ones, the two groups being supposed to have great disparity between their abilities of on-job searching. However, being restricted by the available data, we are not able to implement this method. 6 This assumes away the agent-principle problem. From equation (3), we develop the empirical model of the reservation job valuation,7 i ln J ls = ρ1 ln HPl + ρ 2 ln Al + ε lsi (4) The implication of equation (4) includes two points. First, ρ1 and ρ 2 are the simplified expression of the coefficients on housing prices and amenity conditions, respectively, in equation (3). Using the first order derivatives given previously, we get that ρ1 > 0 and ρ 2 < 0 , which implies that the reservation job valuation increases when the housing prices increase and the amenities decrease. So, changes in job valuation are required to balance the changes in housing prices and amenities to reach the fixed utility level, U , in equilibrium. Second, equation (4) shows the formation of the reservation job valuation, that is, in equilibrium, given any level of housing price and amenity, a faculty forms a reservation job valuation, J , which guarantee him/her the equilibrium utility level, U . If the actual job valuation is lower than J , which means the utility is lower than U , then the faculty member would be better off by quitting the current position and moving to another job giving utility U . (2) The university’s problem In the general sense, universities are non-profit agents. For expository simplicity, however, we model universities to maximize profits of research production, which are calculated using the shadow price. In addition, in order to get the closed forms of the solutions of optimal effort and salary, we assume that the job valuation is a CobbDouglas function, J ( S lsi , Elsi ) = ( S lsi ) µ (1 − Elsi )θ , and µ ,θ > 0 . Recall that (1 − E ) denotes the fraction of leisure time of the time endowment. Then, the university’s maximization problem is, i i max P ⋅ Qls − S ls {S , E } i ls s.t. i ls i J ls ≤ ( S lsi ) µ (1 − Elsi )θ , µ , θ > 0 and Elsi ∈ [0,1] Qlsi = ( RlL ) γ 1 ( RsS ) γ 2 (1 − Elsi ) −γ 3 , γ 1 , γ 2 , γ 3 > 0 7 (5) We take logarithm on each variable because, with large disparities in the units of different variables, it makes interpretation for the coefficients of variables easier. where P is interpreted as the shadow price of research productivity, Qlsi . Considering that universities sell research productivity on an international higher-education market, P is not affected by university- or location-related factors. The first constraint is an individual rationality constraint discussed in the proceeding subsection. The second constraint gives the production technology. Qlsi , the research produced by individual i at school s in location l , is a function increasing in a set of location-specific resources in l , RlL , and a set of university-specific resources of s , RsS , and decreasing in individual’s leisure (or, inversely, increasing in effort exerted in research).8 To maximize profits, universities choose optimally the pair of contractual variables – salaries and effort levels, subject to the binding constraint that faculty’s job valuation is no less than the reservation level. We solve this maximization problem and get the optimal solutions to S lsi and Elsi . And, using the optimal effort level, we write the optimal research outputs, γ 3µ γ 1θ γ 2θ −γ 3 µ θ −γ 3µ L θ −γ 3µ S θ −γ 3µ i θ −γ 3µ Qlsi = Pγ 3 ( Rl ) ( Rs ) ( J ls ) θ (6) The variable of salary in the theory does, precisely, refer to the research-related T remuneration, which differs from the total remuneration, S lsi , and is not separately T = k ( S lsi )η , observable in practice.9 By setting up a simplified transformation function, S lsi k > 0 , and η > 1 , we get the expression of the optimal total salaries, θη T S lsi γ 1θη γ 2θη −γ 3η µ θ −γ 3µ L θ −γ 3µ S θ −γ 3µ i θ −γ 3µ ( Rl ) ( Rs ) ( J ls ) = k Pγ 3 θ (7) Taking logarithm on both sides of equations (6) and (7), and combining with equation (4), we obtain, 8 L In this study, Rl includes three variables of location-specific resources, MSA population density, the value of potential job opportunities in a given MSA, and a dummy variable which is set to equal to one if S the number of universities, which are in our sample, is greater than one in a given MSA; Rs includes two variables of university-specific resources, university size and university total research funding per faculty member. Different combinations of these variables are used in different specifications of estimation. 9 The idea comes from Graves, Marchand and Thompson (1982). ln Qlsi = γ 3µ − γ 3ρ2 µ − γ 3 ρ1 ln Pγ 3 + ln HPli + ln Ali θ − γ 3µ θ θ − γ 3µ θ − γ 3µ + −γ3 γ 2θ γ 1θ ln RsS + ln RlL + ε lsi θ − γ 3µ θ − γ 3µ θ − γ 3µ Q = α 0 + α 1 ln HPli + α 2 ln Ali + α 3 ln RsS + α 4 ln RlL + ε lsi T = ln k + ln S lsi − γ 3ηρ 2 θη µ − γ ηρ ln Pγ 3 + 3 1 ln HPli + ln Ali θ − γ 3µ θ θ − γ 3µ θ − γ 3µ + − γ 3η i γ 2θη γ θη ln RsS + 1 ln RlL + ε ls θ − γ 3µ θ − γ 3µ θ − γ 3µ S = β 0 + β1 ln HPli + β 2 ln Ali + β 3 ln RsS + β 4 ln RlL + ε lsi (8) The two equations in (8) is the basis for our empirical model. We estimate the two equations simultaneously in that their error terms are correlated. To predict the signs of the coefficients on variables, we need to conjecture the sign of (θ − γ 3 µ ) . As learned from previous studies, the sign of the effects of housing prices on salary (or wage) is always positive, which implies, θ − γ 3 µ < 0 . Studying Great Britain in 1972-1995, Cameron and Muellbauer (2001) found a long-run coefficient of around 0.075 for full-time men and around 0.10 for full-time women of relative regional house prices on relative regional earnings. So, Orazem, and Otto (2001) used the U.S. census data to examine the effects of housing prices, wages, and commuting time on joint residential and job location choices. The data confirm that the higher metropolitan housing costs require that wages be higher in the metropolitan market. Taking as given that θ − γ 3 µ < 0 and using the given conditions of parameters, ρ1 > 0 , ρ 2 < 0 , µ ,θ > 0 , and γ 1 , γ 2 , γ 3 > 0 , we are allowed to predict the signs of the coefficients on housing prices and amenities in the two equations, respectively. In the output equation, α 1 > 0 , α 2 < 0 ; and in salary equation, β 1 > 0 , β 2 < 0 . In words, the predictions are, • Prediction1: The effects of local housing prices on research outputs are positive; the effects of amenity conditions on research outputs are negative. • Prediction2: The effects of local housing prices on faculty salaries are positive; the effects of amenity conditions on faculty salaries are negative. The fact, that the coefficients on housing prices have the same signs in output and salary equations, indicates that, when local housing prices increase, universities’ optimal reactions are to increase salary payments enough to induce higher effort levels. In equilibrium, the increases in faculty member’s utility caused by increasing salary are balanced by the decreases in utility caused by increasing effort level. III. Data. (1) Data sources: A. Research outputs We have two measures for universities’ research outputs: the published articles per faculty and the citations per article, which are constructed by Payne and Siow (2001) (PS later on), using the Institute for Scientific Information (ISI) dataset. Data on articles published and citations to articles are available annually for the period from 1981 through 1998, being collected from approximately 4,800 journals. PS use data at the institutional level for papers published during that year for all disciplines. They construct the citations per articles by dividing the total number of citations to articles published in a particular year, accumulated to 1998, by the number of articles published in that year. “Thus, the number of citations per article in earlier years will be higher on average than the number of citations per article near the end of the sample period; the year fixed effects should control for this difference.” (PS, p.15) The trend of the index of published articles per faculty member averaged for the whole sample universities (1990=100) is shown in Figure 2. We see that, basically, the number of published articles per faculty member keeps increasing over time, and that the line for the whole sample universities is smoother than that for Stanford. B. Local housing prices The measure for local housing prices is the median price of single-family homes at MSA level, excluding the effect of the sale price of condominiums and the rental rate. The median home price is an important indicator widely used in housing markets reports and analysis, the data on which come from the National Association of Realtors10. The sale price of single-family homes may vary dramatically due to the structure, area, and other physical characteristics of houses. Changes in the median price reflect the changes in purchasing costs, but not the building costs. C. School characteristics The measures of school characteristics used in this study include faculty salary, university size11, research funding12, public university or private university, and the Carnegie classifications: Research University I (R1), Research University II (R2), Doctoral University I (D1), or Doctoral University II (D2).13 Data on these variables come from CASPAR data, which is a compendium of data sources on higher educational institutions and funded by the National Science Foundation (NSF).14 D. Value of potential job opportunities and outside-offer competition The measure for the value of potential job opportunities ( VPO ) to faculty is constructed by averaging the per capita private earnings in two sectors, the sector of Finance, Investment and Real Estate and the sector of Services, at the MSA level. Data come from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), an agency of the Department of Commerce.15 10 Web page of the National Association of Realtors is: http://www.realtor.org. University size is defined regarding to the number of faculty members, not of students. 12 There are two kinds of data regarding to research funding in this data source, total research funding and federal research funding. For the purposes of this study, we use total research funding data and name it simply as research funding. 13 The Carnegie Classification of Institutions of Higher Education is the leading typology of American colleges and universities. It is the framework in which institutional diversity in U.S. higher education is commonly described. We use its 1994 edition, in which all American universities and colleges are classified into Doctoral-Granting Institutions and other 5 categories. Doctoral-Granting Institutions, which we are interested in this study, comprises 4 sub-categories: Research University I, Research University II, Doctoral University I, and Doctoral University II. “Research universities are defined as those that offer a full range of baccalaureate programs, are committed to graduate education through the doctorate, and give high priority to research, awarding at least 50 doctoral degrees each year. Doctoral schools differ from Research schools in that they do not meet minimum requirements with respect to federal support and they may award fewer doctorate degrees. The Research and Doctoral schools are further divided into classes II and I. Research I differs from Research II in that Research I schools receive more than $40 million annually in federal support. Doctoral I differs from Doctoral II in that Doctoral I schools must offer at least 40 doctoral degrees in at least five disciplines; Doctoral II schools must award 20 or more doctorate degrees in at least one discipline or more than 1-0 degrees in at least three disciplines.” (PS, P.14) 11 14 Website for this data source is http://caspar.nsf.gov. Data from this source are at the institutional and academic discipline level and are available on a yearly basis from as far back as 1972. 15 The website is: http://www.bea.gov/bea/regional/reis/. The underlying reason for picking the two sectors is that we do not have the perfect proxy of VPO to faculty members, and people who work in the two sectors have the characteristics close to those of university faculty members in terms of education background and income level. Therefore, we choose the private earnings in the two sectors to construct VPO . There are two inherent limitations of this measure for VPO . First of all, it is not a comprehensive measurement, without covering all the possible potential opportunities to university faculty members. On the other hand, it does not capture the value of the potential job opportunities from other MSA areas. However, how important this disadvantage is depends on how mobile the faculty members are. Specifically, in an extreme case, if a professor is perfectly immobile, then this disadvantage of the measure for VPO does not decrease the accuracy of our estimations. Aggregately, we need to be cautious when interpreting the estimate results when we use the variable of VPO . The measure of VPO is one of the two measures we use to indicate the competition from outside offers faced by universities. The higher the degree of outside-offer competition, the more difficult it is for universities keeping their faculty members, especially those more able ones.16 The other one is a school number dummy, SCHN l . SCHN l is set equal to one if the number of universities in MSA l is greater than one and is zero otherwise. The coefficients on school number dummy provide us the relative effects of competition for the group facing more universities, equivalently, higher degree of competition, to the group facing no local competition. E. University ranking The data on university ranking come from the Top American Research Universities (TARU) reported by TheCenter at the University of Florida.17 There are 3 annual reports available on-line for the years 2000, 2001, and 2002. We chose the 2000 report, which is 16 Note that we assume perfect mobility in the model. In reality, mobility, other than ability, should be taken into account. 17 An overview of TheCenter and the Top American Research Universities annual report can be found at the website: http://thecenter.ufl.edu. TheCenter determines the Top American Research Universities by their rank on nine different measures: Total Research, Federal Research, Endowment Assets, Annual Giving, National Academy Members, Faculty Awards, Doctorates Granted, Postdoctoral Appointees, and Median SAT Scores. The Top American Research Universities (1-25) identifies the institutions that rank in the top 25 nationally on at least one of the nine measures. The Top American Research Universities (2650) identifies the institutions that rank 26 through 50 nationally on at least one of the nine measures. based on the universities’ performance in 9 measures in 1998-1999, because its reported period is also the closest to the studied period in our article, 1988-1998. The TARU reports the universities ranked 1-25, and 26-50, which are defined as the Rank1 and Rank2, respectively, in our study. We define all the remaining research universities, which also are classified as Research Universities under Carnegie (1994) classifications scheme, as Rank3.18 Finally, Rank4 includes all the doctoral universities under Carnegie (1994) classifications. The major advantage of this rank grouping is that it performs better in reflecting the gaps in schools’ research capabilities among subgroups than Carnegie classification groupings – R1, R2, D1, and D2 universities, which is obvious in Tables 3 and 4. F. Local amenity index Blomquist, Berger, and Hoehn (1988) provide a ranking of life quality for 253 urban counties using 1980 Census data. We use their ranking of counties to construct the measure for local amenity conditions of universities. To give the county with better amenity conditions a higher amenity index, we calculate the amenity index by subtracting 254 by county’s ranking order number. Then we get a descending amenity index system corresponding to the descending ranking of life quality for the 253 counties, with the highest value of 254 and the lowest value of 1. In our original data, we have local variables at MSA level, while Blomquist, et al (1988) rank counties. In the first step, we match a county to a MSA. There are two possibilities: some MSA areas have one or more than one matched county, while some MSA areas have none. In the second step, in the former group of MSA areas, if we have the rank of the county in which the school is located, we simply match the country’s amenity index to the school; otherwise, we match the nearest matched county in the MSA to the school. For the schools in the MSA areas with no matched counties, however, we report their amenity index as missing data. After merging the new data on amenity index into our original dataset, 268 observations are missing in the estimated sample (900 observations are missing in the full 18 We are allowed to define it in this way because the research universities referred by TheCenter and the research universities defined by Carnegie classifications are of great overlap. In our dataset, all the universities ranked 1-50 in the TARU report fall into the body of research universities under Carnegie classifications, which is the combination of Research 1 and Research 2 universities. sample) in the Article Case19. The distributions of missing observations over ranking groups in two different samples are shown in Table 1. It is apparent that the observations are missing more frequently among the lower ranked schools. This will bias our estimates to towards higher ranked schools. Table 1: The distributions of missing observations across subgroups in different samples (in the Article Case): University ranks In the full sample In the estimated sample Rank1 120 45 Rank2 180 63 Rank3 240 68 Rank4 360 92 Total 900 268 Another disadvantage of the amenity index data is that the Blomquist, et al (1988)’s county ranking is estimated using 1980 Census data, but 1980 does not fall into the period studied in the paper, 1990-1998. So, the accuracy of our estimate results is influenced by how much the ranking of quality of life for urban counties changes over time. (2) Data sample Separate data sources are matched at two levels: schools and MSA areas. By school, we merged university research outputs measures, university characteristic measures, and university ranking. And then, by MSA, we match MSA median housing prices and VPO with all these school data. There are 3323 observations in the data sample. Since we have missing data in different years for different variables, eventually, in estimated sample of the benchmark specification, we have 1241 observations of 143 universities in the Article Case (1238 19 We have two sets of estimates. In the first set, we use published articles per faculty as the quantity measure of university research outputs. In the second set, we use citations per article as the quality measure of research outputs. We call them Article Case and Citation Case, respectively. In the part of empirical analysis of this paper, we mainly discuss the Article Case. We discuss the Citation Case briefly in comparison to the Article Case. observations of 143 universities in the Citation Case) over an 8-year period, 1991-1998.20 In the whole sample, the 227 universities are scattered in 40 states of the total 51.21 (3) Variable summary statistics In Panel A of Table 2, we summarize descriptive statistics of two dependent variables and two main explanatory variables, not only for the entire estimated sample, but also for subgroups of estimated samples, separately by Carnegie classifications and by university ranking as well. Panel B of Table 2 summarizes additional four explanatory variables – MSA population density, MSA private earnings in two selected sectors, university size, and total research funding per faculty member. All variable summaries in Tables 2 are for the Article Case. As reported in Panel A of Table 2, the means of published articles per faculty member, annual salaries per faculty member, median housing prices, and amenity index, are 1.45, $57890, $125670, and 121.46, respectively. Together with Panel B, we have 4 school characteristic variables: published articles per faculty member, annual salaries per faculty member, university size, and total research funding per faculty. There are three issues worth noting. First, by both the Carnegie Order, ranked as R1, R2, D1, and D2, and the Rank Order, ranked from Rank1 through Rank4, the means of the four school characteristic variables decrease as you move down the rankings. Second, the decreases under the Rank Order are smoother than under the Carnegie Order. For example, the means of published articles per faculty are, under the Carnegie Order, 2.62, 0.95, 0.56, and 0.69. Under the Rank Order, the same statistics are 3.05, 1.66, 0.95, and 0.62. Third, we do not observe the same decreasing patterns in the non-school-characteristic variables under any order. IV. Empirical strategy We develop two empirical strategies to detect the effects of housing prices on research outputs. (1) Strategy I Based on the expressions in (8), Strategy I models are 20 The list of the university names is available on requests. In our estimated sample, the 11 states with no observations are: Alabama, Arkansas, Maine, Montana, New Hampshire, Vermont, West Virginia, and Wyoming, and Alaska, District of Columbia and Hawaii. 21 ln Qls ,t = α 0 + Yt + α 1 ln HPl ,t −1 + α 2 ln Al ,t −1 + α 3 ln RsS,t −1 + α 4 ln RlL,t −1 + ε lsQ,t (12) ln S lsT ,t = β 0 + Yt + β 1 ln HPl ,t −1 + β 2 ln Al ,t −1 + β 3 ln RsS,t −1 + β 4 ln RlL,t −1 + ε lsS ,t (13) The two equations are estimated simultaneously, with the assumption that the two error terms, ε lsQ,t and ε lsS ,t , are jointly normally distributed. The model using the number of published articles (citations to article) as the proxy of research outputs is called the Article Case (the Citation Case). α 1 and β 1 are of most interest. If α 1 ( β 1 ) is not equal to zero, then it is suggested that there are impact of local median housing prices on both research outputs (salaries). Considering the time lag effects of information about local median housing prices and amenities on individual utility expectation and of university decision-making, we take one period lag on explanatory variables. Year fixed effects are included in all specifications. (2) Strategy II The underlying assumption for Strategy I, that the effects of housing prices on research outputs are identical across all universities, is untenable since universities differ dramatically in some characteristics, for example, research productivity. This assumption can be relaxed in different ways. Our Strategy II model demonstrates one of the ways. In Strategy II, first, we define four university ranking groups: Rank1 through Rank4, with Rank1 referring to the top ranked universities and Rank4 the lowest ranked universities. Then, in both research output and salary equations, we incorporate a full set of interaction terms with ranking groups for the variables of housing prices and the two university-specific resources, university size and total research funding per faculty member. But we do not include the interaction terms for the variables of amenities and the location-specific resources, MSA population density, VPO , and SCHN l .22 By doing so, we are permitted to look into subgroups to explore the effects of housing prices and compare the differences. This kind of nonlinearity is the only difference between Strategy I and Strategy II. Strategy II models are, 22 We estimated different specifications, both including and excluding the interaction terms for amenity index and the location-specific resource variables. However, we decide to use the latter model in that its results are more significant and more consistent with the predicted signs of the coefficients than the results from the former model. ln Qls ,t = α 0 + Yt + RANK k + α 11 ln HPl ,t −1 + α 12 ln HPl ,t −1 ∗ Rank 2 + α 13 ln HPl ,t −1 ∗ Rank 3 + α 14 ln HPl ,t −1 ∗ Rank 4 + α 2 ln Als ,t −1 + α 31 ln RsS,t −1 + α 32 ln RsS,t −1 ∗ Rank 2 + α 33 ln RsS,t −1 ∗ Rank 3 + α 34 ln RsS,t −1 ∗ Rank 4 α 4 ln RlL,t −1 + ε lsQ,t (14) ln S lsT ,t = β 0 + Yt + RANK k + β11 ln HPl ,t −1 + β12 ln HPl ,t −1 ∗ Rank 2 + β13 ln HPl ,t −1 ∗ Rank 3 + β14 ln HPl ,t −1 ∗ Rank 4 + β 2 ln Als ,t −1 + β 31 ln RsS,t −1 + β 32 ln RsS,t −1 ∗ Rank 2 + β 33 ln RsS,t −1 ∗ Rank 3 + β 34 ln RsS,t −1 ∗ Rank 4 α 4 ln RlL,t −1 + ε lsS ,t (15) Ranking group dummies, RANK k , are introduced to control for each group’s fixed effect. Here, the key coefficients are two sets of parameters, {α 1k } and {β 1k }, with k = 1, 2, 3, and 4, corresponding to 4 ranking groups. The estimate of α 11 ( β 11 ) indicates the housing price effects on research outputs (faculty salaries) for Rank1 universities; the estimated coefficients on interaction terms, α 1k ( β 1k ), k = 2, 3, and 4, test whether housing prices affect research outputs (faculty salaries) more for Rank k than for Rank1. V. Estimate results In this section, we interpret the results for Strategy I and II sequentially, focusing on the Article Case, while briefly discussing the Citation Case. (1) Strategy I A. The Article Case Table 3 reports the estimates of Strategy I for the Article Case in two panels, with the top panel being for the article equation, and the lower panel for the salary equation. The results shown in the top panel indicate that housing prices have a significant positive impact on research outputs, with the range of value from 0.28~0.72. This is consistent with Prediction1 that the effects of local housing prices on research outputs are positive. On the other hand, the coefficients on amenity index are significantly positive, which is inconsistent with Prediction1. A 1% increase in amenity index leads the number of published articles to increase 8~10%. In the lower panel, being consistent with Prediction2, the effects of housing prices on salary are positive. The effects of amenity index are positive, which is inconsistent with Prediction2, while they are not statistically significant. The estimated results suggest that salaries increase 14~23% if median housing prices increase 1%. There are some issues regarding the other explanatory variables worth noting. First, the variable of VPO plays a negative role on the numbers of published articles and a positive role on salaries. It is consistent with the hypothesis that in the region with more competition, the universities need to pay higher salaries to prevent faculty members from dropping their current positions, while professors, taking advantage of the competition, tend to make less effort in academic activities.23 When we introduce the variable of MSA population density in column (2), the effect of VPO becomes insignificant in both the article and salary equations. This demonstrates that the variable of MSA population density acts as a measure of outside competition in research production. The fact that the two variables of VPO and MSA population density have a correlation of 0.8 at the 5% level of significance confirms the proceeding interpretation. However, the estimated effects of SCHN are not consistent with the hypothesis of outside-offer competition, even being significantly positive in columns (3) in the top panel. Additionally, the effects of university sizes and average research funding are strongly significant and positive on both the published articles and salaries. A 1% increase in research funding per faculty member leads to a 63% increase in the number of published articles, and 6% increase in salaries per faculty member. B. The Citation Case The estimate results of the Citation Case are reported in Table 4. Overall, the estimates from the Citation Case are qualitatively similar to the Article Case. Except for the estimates of school number dummy, the values of all the other estimates are smaller compared to their counterparts in the Article Case reported. This result suggests that 23 In the situation with more than one alternative job opportunities, faculty members have various possible choices. Basically, there are two categories, either picking up a new job or keeping the current job and also having a second job at the same time. In either case, we will observe the drop in the research outputs at the university the faculty member are currently serving for. local housing market prices and amenity conditions outputs affect the quality measure of research outputs less than the quantity measure. Besides, we also see that the effects of amenity index in article equations become insignificant and, compared to their counterparts in the Article Case, the estimated coefficients of salary equations change very little. (2) Strategy II A. The Article Case In Table 5, the estimates of Strategy II for the Article Case are reported in two panels, the top one being for article equations and the lower one for salary equations.24 Most of all, there is a great disparity in the effects of housing prices across the four ranking groups. The coefficients on housing prices within Rank1, being positive and, in most cases, statistically significant, are close to the coefficients on housing prices within Rank2. In column (2), the effects of housing prices are high in Rank1 and Rank2, and then go down dramatically through Rank3, while still being positive, and become negative for universities in Rank4. The net effects of housing price on the number of published articles are 79%, 90%, 12%, and –31% for Rank1 through Rank4s, respectively. There are two important points relevant to these results. First, they provide the evidence to reject the validity of the underlying assumption for Strategy I that the effects of housing prices on research outputs are identical across all universities. Second, the effects of housing prices keep being significant even after the quality of universities’ research, represented by the university ranking, is controlled for. This reflects that the significance of the effects of housing prices we observed in Table 3 is not the result of the correlation between the university quality and the local housing prices, or put in another way, the fact that the universities of higher quality always locate in the regions with higher amenity conditions and higher housing prices.25 Our hypothesis is two-folded. First, universities faced with high local housing prices are forced to offering higher salaries to attract faculty members, or accepting lower research outputs. Higher ranked universities may have more room to increase salaries, 24 The estimates of university size and average total research funding and their complete set of interaction terms with ranking groups are not reported in the table, which are available on requests. 25 The statement is also supported by the low degree of correlation between the two variables, school rank and local amenity index in the dataset studies. being more influential and powerful to get extra funding, relative to the lowest ranked universities. If research funding per faculty member is a proxy for the ability to get extra funding to increase salaries, then we do see that, with including the variable of research funding, the coefficient on housing prices on research outputs becomes positive, though non-significant. This guess is supported by the comparison of the relative salaries to local housing prices among the four ranking groups shown in Figure 3. During the years 1995-1998, in which all the four groups experienced increases in local housing prices and salaries26, the relative salaries of Rank4 universities drop fast relative to the other three groups. And, the level of relative salaries goes down when we move from Rank1 group through Rank3. The differences in the coefficients on housing prices on articles among the four ranking groups can be explained by the differences in level and speed of the changes in relative salaries. However, the remaining puzzle is that even the relative salaries kept decreasing since 1995, the outputs of articles increased. In the second fold, we hypothesize that faculty members may behave heterogeneously given the same changes in relative salaries. When housing prices increase, professors those have better paid outside offers would, with higher possibility, get promotions. The professors in higher ranked universities are prone to process in the way in that they have relative advantage in research in terms either of less teaching and more time in research, or better colleague environment, or higher IQ. On the contrary, for the professors in lower ranked universities, it is harder to get better paid outside offers to compete with the current job. Corresponding to the relative advantages of professors in higher ranked universities, the disadvantages of professors in low ranked universities may be too much teaching, less inspiring colleague environment, or low IQ. Seeing that the possibility to get promoted on current positions is very low, they may decide decrease effort level exerted in research or other academic activities and switch part or all of time and effort to another job, a second job or a new job. In either way, these professors could get better off. When there is an increase in local housing prices, and given the same changes in relative salaries, it seems possible that professors in higher ranked universities work harder to be more productive, higher valued, and higher paid in the future, while professor in lower ranked universities show less career concerns. To go in this way, 26 See Appendix Figure 4. however, we need to extend the theory to a dynamic model, simply, a two-period model, to allow individuals to value future salaries. So, the great disparities of the effects of local housing prices across the four ranking groups may be the net results for both reasons. Second, row (5) reports the elasticities of the number of published articles with respect to housing prices. They are statistically significant in columns (2)-(4), with the value of 21~28%, which implies that local housing prices increasing 1% will result in a 21~28% increase in published articles. Just the result in column (1) is not significant. Third, the effects of amenity index on the number of published articles are positive and statistically significant in all the four specifications. It is inconsistent with the theoretical predictions that amenity conditions play a negative role on research outputs. The estimates of amenity index fall into the range of [0.09, 0.16], which means that 1% improvement on amenity index will lead to 9 ~ 16% increase in the quantity measure of universities’ research outputs. In the specification in column (4), we introduce the variable of research funding per faculty member. In the first panel, the coefficients on the variable, which are not reported in Table 5, are significantly positive. As a result, there is a sharp drop in most of the estimates in column (4) relative to their counterparts in the previous specifications. For an instance, the effects of housing prices within Rank1 decrease from 63% and 83% in columns (1) and (3), respectively, to 36%. Within Rank2, it drops from 63% and 101% to 58%. The only exception happens to the effects of housing prices within Rank4 shown in row (4). Within Rank4, the effects of housing prices raise from –48% and –23% to 17%, while being insignificant in columns (3) and (4). If the amount of total research funding per faculty member at a university captures school ranking to some extent in that top research universities always have more research funding than those lower ranked, then, consistently, we would expect that, after taking into account the research funding effects, the gaps between the coefficients of different ranking groups are weakened relative to those in columns (1) and (3). Finally, the effects of MSA population density and SCHN on the number of published articles are of the expected signs and, in most cases, significant. The variable of VPO plays a similar impact as the variable of population density on articles when the variable of population density is excluded in estimation model. The results provide a strong support for the existence of negative effects from outside-offer competition on articles. B. The Citation Case In Table 6, the estimates of Strategy II for the Citation Case are reported. They are broadly consistent with the Article Case, except for several differences worthy of notice. First, the estimates of all explanatory variables are smaller in terms of absolute value than their counterparts in the Article Case. For instance, the effects of housing prices within Rank1 are in the range of 36~83% in the Article Case, while they are in the range of 27~34% in the Citation Case. It suggests that the quality of research outputs is less influenced by the exogenous housing prices than the quantity of research outputs. Second, in the first panel, the effects of housing prices within Rank1 and Rank2 are still significant, while those within Rank4 become insignificant. Lastly, the coefficients of housing prices, amenity index, VPO, and SCHN on salaries in Citation Case are of few difference from their counterparts in Table 5 for the Article Case, which implies that, maximizing profits under either form of research outputs, universities adjust salary offers with respect to exogenous changes in local housing markets to the similar extent. VI. Concluding remarks In this study, we set up a simple two-agent model to examine the effects of housing prices on university research outputs, taking the rational reaction forms of both university and faculty into account. With some standard restrictions on parameters restricted in the model, and taking as given the conclusion from previous studies that the effects of housing prices on personal earnings are positive, the theory predicts that the effects of housing prices on both research outputs and salaries are positive; and the effects of amenities are negative. Our empirical results are a mixture of consistency and inconsistency with the theoretical predictions. First, in the specifications without looking into ranking subgroups, the effects of housing prices are significantly positive on both of published articles and salaries. Next, when looking into ranking subgroups, the estimated effects of housing prices on research outputs are ranked from high to low as we move from the top ranked universities to the Rank4. This diminishing pattern is observed in both Article Case and Citation Case. The effects of housing prices are high in Rank1 and Rank2s, and then go down dramatically through Rank3, while still being positive, and become negative for universities in Rank4. Finally, the set of variables capturing local outside-offer competition – the MSA population density, the value of potential job opportunities, and a school number dummy – play a negative role on university research outputs, and a positive role on salaries per faculty member. There are two interesting issues we leave for future research. First, how to incorporate the heterogeneity among faculty members? One way to implement this idea is to break faculty members into two groups of tenured and non-tenured professors. Since the two groups differ substantially in terms of research ability and labor mobility, it will be interesting to detect the effects of housing prices and amenity on the professors’ research outputs in each group. Restricted by available data, we cannot implement this idea in the current study. Second, as we mention briefly in Footnote 3, in practice, except for adjusting salaries and effort levels, universities may have alternative options to reduce the passive impact of housing prices increasing on research outputs. These alternative options include providing low-interest-rate mortgage and building houses and then selling (or renting) to faculty at low price. Stanford University is using the latter scheme. It is worth serious thinking that why some universities choose salary-effort scheme, while other choose building or mortgage scheme favorable to faculty members. How to integrate these different schemes into one model and apply the benefit-cost analysis? And, how do housing prices affect research outputs differently under different schemes? Reference: Bacolod, Marigee P. (2001). “The Role of Alternative Opportunities in the Female Labor Market In Teacher Supply and Quality: 1940-1990”, Balderston, Frederick E. (1995). Managing Today’s University: Strategies for Viability, Change, and Excellence, Jossey-Bass: Jossey-Bass Publishers. Cameron, Gavin, and John Muellbauer (2001). “Earnings, Unemployment, and Housing in Britain”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, vol.16, pp 203-220 (2001). Case, Karl E. and Christopher J. Mayer (1996). “Housing price dynamics within a metropolitan area”. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 26 (1996), 387-407. Chay, Kenneth Y. (1998). “Does Air Quality Matter? Evidence from the Housing Market.” NBER Working Paper 6826. De Groot, Hans, Walter W. McMahon, and J. Fredericks Volkwein (1991). “ The Cost Structure of American Research Universities.” Review of Economics and Statistics, vol.73, no. 3, August 1991, pp.424-31. Dundar, Halil and Darrell R. Lewis (1995). “Departmental Productivity in American Universities: Economics of Scale and Scope”. Economics of Education Review, vol.14, no.2, pp.119-144. Gayer, Ted and W. Kip Viscusi (2002). “Housing price responses to newspaper publicity of hazardous waste sites”. Resource an Energy Economics, 24 (2002), 33-51. Glass, J. C., D. G. McKillop, and G. O’Rourke (2002). “Evaluating the productive performance of UK universities as cost-constrained revenue maximizers: an empirical analysis”. Applied Economics, 2002, 34, 1097-1108. Glass, J. C., D. G. McKillop, and N. Hyndman (1995). “Efficiency in the Provision of University Teaching and Research: an Empirical Analysis of UK Universities”. Journal of Applied Econometrics, vol.10, 61-72. Graves, Philip E., James R. Marchand, Randall Thompson (1982). “Economics Departmental Rankings: Research Incentives, Constraints, and Efficiency”, American Economic Review, vol.72, issue 5, Dec. 1982, pp1131-1141. Johnes, Geraint, and Thomas Hyclak (1999). “House Prices and Regional Labor Markes”, the Annuals of Regional Science (1999) 33: 33-49. Olmo, Jorge Chica (1995). “Spatial Esimation of Housing Prices and Locational Rents”, Urban Studies, vol. 32, no. 8, 1331-1344. Payne, A. Abigail and Aloysius Siow (2001). “Does Federal Research Funding Increase University Research outputs?” Department of Economics, University of Toronto, working paper. Roback, Jennifer (1982). “Wage, Rents, and the Quality of Life”, Journal of Political Economy, vol.90, issue 6, Dec. 1982, pp 1257-1278. Siow, Aloysius (1998). “Tenure and Other Unusual Personnel Practices in Academia”, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 14(1): 152-173. So, Kim S., Peter F. Orazem, and Daniel M. Otto (2001). “The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 83(4), November 2001: 1036-1048. Zucker, Lynne G., Michael R. Darby, and Maximo Toreto (1997). “Labor Mobility from Academe to Commerce.” NBER Working Paper 6050. Figure 1 Changes in the Indexes of Local Median Housing Prices and Annual Salaries per Faculty Member* (1990=100) Panel A: Stanford University Index of Median Price of Single-Family Homes in San Francisco, CA (PMSA) Index of Annual Salaries per Faculty Member at Stanford University 120 110 100 90 80 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Panel B: Universities in the Whole Sample Index of Averaged Local Median Prices of Single-Family Homes for the Whole Sample Index of Averaged Annual Salaries per Faculty Member for the Whole Sample 120 110 100 90 80 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Note: * Both local median housing prices and annual salaries per faculty member are in 1996 dollars. Figure 2 Changes in the Index of the Annual Number of Published Articles per Faculty Member the Whole Sample Universities Stanford University 130 120 110 100 90 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Note: There are missing data on the number of published articles per faculty member in the years 1987-89 for the whole sample, and in the years 1985-89 for Stanford University. Figure 3 Relative Changes in Salary: The ratio of the index of annual salaries per faculty member over the index of local median housing prices (1991=100) Rank1 Universities Rank3 Universities Rank2 Universities Rank4 Universities 1.15 1.1 1.05 1 0.95 0.9 0.85 0.8 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Appendix: Figure 4 Panel A: Rank1 Universities Index of Annual Salaries per Faculty Member for Rank1 Universities Index of Local Median Price of Single-Family Homes for Rank1 Universities 110 100 90 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Panel B: Rank2 Universities Index of Annual Salaries per Faculty Member for Rank2 Universities Index of Local Median Price of Single-Family Homes for Rank2 Universities 110 105 100 95 90 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Panel C: Rank3 Universities Index of Annual Salaries per Faculty Member for Rank3 Universities Index of Local Median Price of Single-Family Homes for Rank3 Universities 130 120 110 100 90 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Panel D: Rank4 Universities Index of Annual Salaries per Faculty Member for Rank4 Universities Index of Local Median Price of Single-Family Homes for Rank4 Universities 110 105 100 95 90 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Table 2 Variable summary statistics for the Article Case. Panel A: The dependent variables and two main explanatory variables (Standard deviations are in parenthesis) Number of published articles per faculty member Annual salaries per faculty member ($thousands † ) Median price of single-family homes ($thousands † ) Amenity index Observations* (School numbers) 1.45 (1.94) 57.89 (10.46) 125.67 (47.86) 121.46 (73.90) 1103 (142) 2.62 (2.42) 64.85 (9.87) 133.13 (53.30) 124.45 (73.96) 433 (56) Research II 0.95 (0.39) 54.93 (7.06) 94.20 (16.98) 118.47 (63.99) 152 (19) Doctoral I 0.56 (1.24) 52.63 (7.93) 121.09 (37.78) 120.40 (81.46) 260 (34) Doctoral II 0.69 (0.95) 53.24 (8.71) 136.31 (51.24) 119.27 (71.46) 258 (33) 3.05 (2.78) 68.39 (9.76) 139.37 (59.08) 110.90 (68.97) 285 (37) Rank2 1.66 (1.03) 59.79 (5.86) 115.20 (37.45) 134.78 (75.08) 172 (22) Rank3 0.95 (0.41) 51.99 (4.43) 97.09 (17.11) 133.63 (68.16) 128 (16) Rank4 0.62 (1.11) 52.93 (8.33) 128.67 (45.59) 119.84 (76.57) 518 (67) Variables Estimated sample By Carnegie classifications Research I By school ranking group Rank1 (To be continued) Note: † All dollars are constant ($1996). * The observations in the specifications without the variable of research funding per faculty member. The period studied is 1991-1998. Table 2 (continued) Panel B: The variables of location- and university-specific resources (Standard deviations are in parenthesis) MSA population density (persons per square mile) MSA private earnings in two selected sectors ‡ ($thousands † ) University size (number of faculty members) Total research funding per faculty member ($thousands † ) Observations* (School numbers) 1397.68 (2216.20) 28.82 (11.64) 744.53 (482.64) 118.83 (166.28) 1026 (134) By Carnegie classifications Research I 1412.57 (2062.40) 29.15 (11.19) 1064.89 (537.09) 229.57 (205.79) 433 (56) Variables Estimated sample Research II 422.20 (247.24) 23.06 (4.77) 711.34 (230.13) 66.61 (35.95) 152 (19) Doctoral I 1973.35 (2809.79) 31.44 (14.15) 462.07 (236.85) 21.67 (20.97) 249 (34) Doctoral II 1391.09 (2291.21) 29.27 (11.40) 414.62 (189.61) 36.45 (43.60) 192 (25) 1391.30 (1965.59) 29.69 (10.89) 1123.66 (610.77) 262.44 (237.17) 285 (37) Rank2 1131.61 (2108.62) 27.87 (10.87) 900.28 (355.55) 141.19 (101.35) 172 (22) Rank3 419.54 (282.86) 22.41 (4.92) 735.41 (188.50) 81.63 (51.91) 128 (16) Rank4 1719.29 (2609.97) 30.49 13.06) 441.41 (218.59) 28.11 (33.57) 441 (59) By school ranking group Rank1 Note: † All dollars are constant ($1996). ‡ The two sectors are the Sector of Finance, Investment, and Real Estate and the Sector of Services. Please see Section III for the explanation in detail. * The observations in the specifications with the variable of research funding per faculty member. The period studied is 1991-1998. Table 3 Strategy I: the Article Case. (Standard errors are in parenthesis) Specifications (1) (2) Article Equation: Dependent variable =ln(published articles per faculty member) Main explanatory variables: ln(local median housing prices) ln(amenity index) 0.660*** (0.156) 0.095** (0.042) University-specific resource variables: ln(university size) 0.785*** (0.051) ln(research funding per faculty member) Location-specific resource variables: ln(MSA population density) ln(value of potential job -0.427** opportunities) (0.182) SCHN (=1, if the # of 0.101 schools in a given MSA (0.089) >1) (3) 0.716*** (0.157) 0.084** (0.042) 0.283** (0.097) 0.080*** (0.024) 0.800*** (0.051) 0.149*** (0.034) 0.633*** (0.015) -0.181*** (0.066) 0.141 (0.274) 0.130 (0.089) -0.058 (0.039) 0.069 (0.166) 0.159*** (0.052) Salary Equation: Dependent variable =ln(annual salaries per faculty member) Main explanatory variables: ln(local median housing prices) ln(amenity index) 0.188*** (0.020) 0.002 (0.005) University-specific resource variables: ln(university size) 0.086*** (0.006) ln(research funding per faculty member) Location-specific resource variables: ln(MSA population density) ln(value of potential job 0.071*** opportunities) (0.023) SCHN (=1, if the # of 0.007 schools in a given MSA (0.011) >1) Observations 1103 0.180*** (0.020) 0.004 (0.005) 0.133*** (0.018) 0.004 (0.004) 0.083*** (0.006) 0.028*** (0.006) 0.055*** (0.003) 0.025*** (0.008) -0.008 (0.035) 0.002 (0.011) 0.034*** (0.007) -0.017 (0.030) 0.004 (0.009) 1103 1026 Note: *** (**, and *) represents statistically significant at the 1% (5%, and 10%) level. Year fixed effects are included in all specifications. One period lag is taken on all the explanatory variables. Table 4 Strategy I: the Citation Case. (Standard errors are in parenthesis) Specifications (1) (2) Citation Equation: Dependent variable =ln(citations per article) Main explanatory variables: ln(local median housing prices) ln(amenity index) 0.344*** (0.069) 0.021 (0.018) University-specific resource variables: ln(university size) 0.361*** (0.023) ln(research funding per faculty member) Location-specific resource variables: ln(MSA population density) ln(value of potential job -0.117 opportunities) (0.081) SCHN (=1, if the # of 0.132*** schools in a given MSA (0.039) >1) (3) 0.360*** (0.070) 0.018 (0.019) 0.168*** (0.052) 0.009 (0.013) 0.365*** (0.023) 0.147*** (0.018) 0.231*** (0.008) -0.050* (0.029) 0.039 (0.122) 0.140*** (0.039) -0.033 (0.021) 0.123 (0.089) 0.165*** (0.028) Salary Equation: Dependent variable =ln(annual salaries per faculty member) Main explanatory variables: ln(local median housing prices) ln(amenity index) 0.191*** (0.020) 0.003 (0.005) University-specific resource variables: ln(university size) 0.087*** (0.006) ln(research funding per faculty member) Location-specific resource variables: ln(MSA population density) ln(value of potential job 0.070*** opportunities) (0.023) SCHN (=1, if the # of 0.006 schools in a given MSA (0.011) >1) Observations 1100 0.183*** (0.020) 0.004 (0.005) 0.133*** (0.018) 0.004 (0.004) 0.084*** (0.006) 0.028*** (0.006) 0.055*** (0.003) 0.026*** (0.008) -0.010 (0.035) 0.002 (0.011) 0.034*** (0.007) -0.017 (0.030) 0.004 (0.009) 1100 1025 Note: *** (**, and *) represents statistically significant at the 1% (5%, and 10%) level. Year fixed effects are included in all specifications. One period lag is taken on all the explanatory variables. Table 5 Strategy II: the Article Case. (Standard errors are in parenthesis) (1) Specifications (3) (2) (4) Article Equation: Dependent variable =ln(published articles per faculty member) Main explanatory variables: ln(local median housing prices)*Rank1 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank2 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank3 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank4 Elasticity of published articles w.r.t. Housing prices ln(local amenity index) 0.627*** (0.129) 0.630*** (0.228) -0.010 (0.471) -0.484*** (0.115) 0.789*** (0.148) 0.900*** (0.250) 0.117 (0.472) -0.306** (0.151) 0.830*** (0.148) 1.005*** (0.251) 0.029 (0.471) -0.229 (0.152) 0.358*** (0.127) 0.584*** (0.198) 0.055 (0.355) 0.170 (0.127) 0.036 (0.091) 0.214* (0.124) 0.267** (0.124) 0.277*** (0.102) 0.122*** (0.030) 0.122*** (0.030) 0.113*** (0.030) 0.089*** (0.023) / -0.172*** (0.137) -0.195** (0.066) -0.152*** (0.049) 0.283 (0.199) -0.169** (0.066) -0.091** (0.038) 0.029 (0.159) 0.053 (0.052) YES YES YES YES NO NO NO YES 1111 1103 1103 Location-specific resource variables: ln(MSA population / density) ln(value of potential job / opportunities) SCHN (=1, if the # of / schools in a given MSA >1) University-specific resource variables: ln(university size) & interactions with ranking groups ln(research funding per faculty member) & interactions with ranking groups Observations 1026 (To be continued) Note: *** (**, and *) represents statistically significant at the 1% (5%, and 10%) level. Year fixed effects are included in all specifications. One period lag is taken on all the explanatory variables. The estimated coefficients on both ln(university size) and its interaction terms, and ln(research funding per faculty member) and its interaction terms, with ranking groups respectively, are not reported in the table. Table 5 (continued) (Standard errors are in parenthesis) (1) Specifications (3) (2) (4) Salary Equation: Dependent Variable = ln(annual salaries per faculty member) Main explanatory variables: ln(local median housing prices)*Rank1 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank2 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank3 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank4 0.122*** (0.018) 0.104** (0.031) 0.162** (0.065) 0.228*** (0.016) 0.086*** (0.020) 0.051 (0.034) 0.152** (0.065) 0.176*** (0.021) 0.078*** (0.020) 0.030 (0.034) 0.169*** (0.065) 0.160*** (0.021) 0.116*** (0.021) 0.015 (0.032) 0.163*** (0.058) 0.203*** (0.021) Elasticity of salaries w.r.t. Housing prices 0.173*** (0.013) 0.130*** (0.017) 0.120*** (0.017) 0.143*** (0.017) ln(local amenity index) 0.0001 (0.004) 0.007 (0.004) 0.008** (0.004) 0.009** (0.004) / 0.077*** (0.019) -0.004 (0.009) 0.030*** (0.007) -0.013 (0.027) -0.009 (0.009) 0.030*** (0.006) -0.071*** (0.026) 0.011 (0.008) YES YES YES YES NO NO NO YES 1111 1103 1103 1026 Location-specific resource variables: ln(MSA population / density) ln(value of potential job / opportunities) SCHN (=1, if the # of / schools in a given MSA >1) University-specific resource variables: ln(university size) & interactions with ranking groups ln(research funding per faculty member) & interactions with ranking groups Observations Note: *** (**, and *) represents statistically significant at the 1% (5%, and 10%) level. Year fixed effects are included in all specifications. One period lag is taken on all the explanatory variables. The estimated coefficients on both ln(university size) and its interaction terms, and ln(research funding per faculty member) and its interaction terms, with ranking groups respectively, are not reported in the table. Table 6 Strategy II: the Citation Case. (Standard errors are in parenthesis) (1) Specifications (3) (2) (4) Citation Equation: Dependent variable =ln(citations per article) Main explanatory variables: ln(local median housing prices)*Rank1 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank2 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank3 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank4 0.329*** (0.061) 0.315** (0.107) 0.270 (0.221) -0.031 (0.054) 0.330*** (0.070) 0.321*** (0.118) 0.263 (0.223) -0.025 (0.072) 0.340*** (0.070) 0.347*** (0.119) 0.241 (0.223) -0.006 (0.073) 0.269*** (0.066) 0.278*** (0.102) 0.252 (0.183) 0.081 (0.065) Elasticity of citations w.r.t. Housing prices 0.153*** (0.043) 0.155*** (0.059) 0.168*** (0.059) 0.187*** (0.052) ln(local amenity index) 0.036*** (0.013) 0.035** (0.014) 0.033** (0.014) 0.020* (0.012) / -0.017 (0.065) 0.020 (0.031) -0.037 (0.023) 0.094 (0.095) 0.026 (0.032) -0.051*** (0.020) 0.105 (0.082) 0.103*** (0.027) YES YES YES YES NO NO NO YES 1108 1100 1100 1025 Location-specific resource variables: ln(MSA population / density) ln(value of potential job / opportunities) SCHN (=1, if the # of / schools in a given MSA >1) University-specific resource variables: ln(university size) & interactions with ranking groups ln(research funding per faculty member) & interactions with ranking groups Observations (To be continued) Note: *** (**, and *) represents statistically significant at the 1% (5%, and 10%) level. Year fixed effects are included in all specifications. One period lag is taken on all the explanatory variables. The estimated coefficients on both ln(university size) and its interaction terms, and ln(research funding per faculty member) and its interaction terms, with ranking groups respectively, are not reported in the table. Table 6 (continued) (Standard errors are in parenthesis) (1) Specifications (3) (2) (4) Salary Equation: Dependent Variable = ln(annual salaries per faculty member) Main explanatory variables: ln(local median housing prices)*Rank1 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank2 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank3 ln(local median housing prices)*Rank4 0.122*** (0.018) 0.104*** (0.031) 0.161** (0.065) 0.235*** (0.016) 0.088*** (0.020) 0.052 (0.034) 0.151** (0.065) 0.184*** (0.021) 0.079*** (0.020) 0.032 (0.034) 0.169*** (0.064) 0.168*** (0.021) 0.116*** (0.021) 0.015 (0.032) 0.163*** (0.058) 0.203*** (0.021) Elasticity of salaries w.r.t. Housing prices 0.176*** (0.013) 0.135*** (0.017) 0.124*** (0.017) 0.142*** (0.017) ln(local amenity index) 0.0003 (0.004) 0.007* (0.004) 0.008** (0.004) 0.009** (0.004) / 0.074*** (0.019) -0.004 (0.009) 0.030*** (0.007) -0.017 (0.027) -0.010 (0.009) 0.031*** (0.006) -0.072*** (0.026) 0.011 (0.008) YES YES YES YES NO NO NO YES 1108 1100 1100 1025 Location-specific resource variables: ln(MSA population / density) ln(value of potential job / opportunities) SCHN (=1, if the # of / schools in a given MSA >1) University-specific resource variables: ln(university size) & interactions with ranking groups ln(research funding per faculty member) & interactions with ranking groups Observations Note: *** (**, and *) represents statistically significant at the 1% (5%, and 10%) level. Year fixed effects are included in all specifications. One period lag is taken on all the explanatory variables. The estimated coefficients on both ln(university size) and its interaction terms, and ln(research funding per faculty member) and its interaction terms, with ranking groups respectively, are not reported in the table.