Reviews/Comptes rendus Reviews/Comptes rendus 459 BOOKS REVIEWED John B. Burbidge, James Cutt, Paul Dickinson, Newman Lam, Michael J. Prince, Christopher Ragan and William B.P. Robson When We’re 65: Reforming Canada’s Retirement Income System reviewed by Ellen M. Gee 466 Wallace Clement (ed.) Understanding Canada: Building on the New Canadian Political Economy reviewed by Barry Cooper 469 Michael Dorland (ed.) The Cultural Industries in Canada: Problems, Policies and Prospects reviewed by John D. Jackson 462 Richard G. Lipsey Economic Growth, Technological Change, and Canadian Economic Policy reviewed by Peter Howitt 467 Christopher McKee Treaty Talks in British Columbia: Negotiating a Mutually Beneficial Future reviewed by Gurston Dacks 460 Alex C. Michalos Good Taxes: The Case for Taxing Foreign Currency Exchange and Other Financial Transactions reviewed by Patrick Grady 461 C. Paraskevopoulos, R. Grinspun and T. Georgakopoulos (eds.) Economic Integration and Public Policy in the European Union reviewed by Thanasis Stengos 461 George Selgin Less Than Zero: The Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy reviewed by Ralph Kolinski 467 Carolyn Strange (ed.) Qualities of Mercy: Justice, Punishment, and Discretion reviewed by Vladislav (Victor) A. Tomovich 465 Peter Warrian Hard Bargain: Transforming Public Sector Labour-Management Relations reviewed by Greg McElligott 468 CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 460 Reviews/Comptes rendus Treaty Talks in British Columbia: Negotiating a Mutually Beneficial Future by Christopher McKee. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 1996. Pp. xvi, 126. Treaty Talks in British Columbia should be required reading for anyone interested in the process by which aboriginal rights in the province may well transform the relationship between its non-Native and Native inhabitants. Moreover, there should be a great many interested readers because this issue stirs powerful emotions, colours the province’s political process, carries with it hugh financial implications, raises profound issues of morality and justice, and promises to define relations between Natives and non-Natives for generations to come. Christopher McKee has achieved his goal of providing a lucid account of this process for lay readers. He begins by explaining the context of the BC treaty process — basic legal concepts and the history of Native-government relations in the province. The treatment of the latter topic is particularly important for readers sceptical of the claims process because it demonstrates that contemporary Native claims are far from a recent, groundless, and selfserving fabrication. Rather they reflect a history of governmental injustice that British Columbia’s First Nations have actively protested for more than a century. After laying the groundwork, McKee summarizes the treaty-making process that has been under way since 1993, focusing on the British Columbia Treaty Commission and the six stages of its negotiating process. He then outlines the major issues under negotiation and their politics. Because the BC claims process has provoked substantial opposition, McKee comments on some of its most contentious aspects. In particular, he correctly rejects the argument that total extinguishment of Aboriginal rights should accompany the settlement of Aboriginal claims. In his view, to do so would be to extinguish aboriginality, exactly the opposite of the purpose of the treaty process, which is to pave the way for an enduring future of respect and mutual recognition CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, between non-Aboriginal Canadians and First Nations. Treaty Talks in British Columbia closes by looking to the future of the treaty-making process and arguing forcefully about the behavioural and policy changes to which the participants must commit themselves if the process is to succeed. It is here that Treaty Talks in British Columbia makes its greatest contribution. McKee spares none of the participants. He argues that the provincial government must develop a more coherent policy process and involve third parties more meaningfully in the treaty process if they are to accept it as fair and legitimate. In his judgement, the Government of Canada should move more vigourously away from the band council provisions of the Indian Act in favour of more legitimate and effective forms of governance. At the same time, the Aboriginal leadership empowered by the Indian Act provisions must reform its often selfserving and elitist ways. Also, non-Aboriginal interests, such as the Council of Forest Industries, must accept both the morality and the cost effectiveness of the treaty process, particularly as compared to the unsatisfactory alternatives. The argument falters when it advocates turning over the implementation of the treaties, once they are ratified, to the federal Indian Claims Commission. Somebody must implement the treaties and help manage the resulting relationship between the First Nations and the federal and territorial governments. However, the lack of success that the Indian Claims Commission has enjoyed suggests looking elsewhere. This is a modest problem compared to the overall strength of this book. McKee deserves great credit for distilling the historical, legal, and political complexities of the treaty process into such a brief and readable work, and for demonstrating so persuasively the interest that all British Columbians — indeed all Canadians — have in the success of this process. GURSTON DACKS, Department of Political Science, University of Alberta VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus Economic Integration and Public Policy in the European Union edited by C. Paraskevopoulos, R. Grinspun and T. Georgakopoulos. Brookfield: Edward Elgar Publishers, 1996. Pp. xvii, 310. This volume brings together a number of papers that try to shed some light on the basic issues surrounding the economic integration drive in the European Union under the Maastricht treaty. This debate is especially relevant after the recent French election results which brought to the forefront serious questions about the feasibility as well as the desirability of the monetary union. It has become quite clear that problems of convergence of domestic inflation rates come with a price of relatively high unemployment, and the sacrifice of domestic monetary policy is recently receiving more skeptical scrutiny in member countries than it did earlier. The volume covers a number of important aspects in the area of economic integration that do not feature prominently in the current debate as it takes place in the media but are as important and perhaps more so if the experiment of the EU Maastricht treaty is to be successful. These include the politics of union, implications for national fiscal policies and associated social and labour policies as well. Since some of the most difficult problems of integration are sectoral, questions of agricultural policy and the conflicts among member states as well as foreign investment and technological guidelines are among the most prominent issues that need to be addressed. Many of the general issues of convergence mentioned above are investigated in the context of Greece, the focus of most papers in the volume. The first of six parts considers a number of general issues of European integration, including recent challenges to the convergence criteria. The second part presents certain empirical and theoretical aspects of the monetary union. Part III deals with social policy reform and the structuring of a social union. Part IV deals with fiscal policy and public 461 finance issues. Part V presents an analysis of such European Union policies as agriculture, foreign investment, and technology. Finally, the last part looks at Greece as it tries to meet the convergence criteria. It is in this context that the volume adds to the debate about European integration in that it considers a process of integrating unequal partners and looks at the issues that arise from the point of view of one of the members least prepared to satisfy these convergence criteria. To that end, the set of articles presented here constitutes an interesting and valuable collection of papers that shed considerable light on the complex phenomenon of European integration as it unfolds. THANASIS STENGOS, Department of Economics, University of Guelph Good Taxes: The Case for Taxing Foreign Currency Exchange and Other Financial Transactions by Alex C. Michalos. Toronto: Dundurn Press, Science for Peace Series, 1997. Pp. viii, 87. This book is called Good Taxes because its author strongly believes that financial taxes in general and the Tobin tax in particular are good taxes. By this he means they generate enough revenue to pay for public goods including the social safety net, they are levied in proportion to ability to pay, and they are administratively manageable and cost effective. The author claims to construct a reasonable sort of benefit-cost analysis of financial transaction taxes, but his analysis is literary not quantitative. The meat of this book is contained in two chapters: the first presents 19 arguments in favour of financial transactions taxes and the second offers rebuttals for 20 arguments against financial transaction taxes. While the underlying literature review is thorough, the point of view is, not surprisingly, relatively one-sided. The book does, however, present a handy survey of the estimates of the amount of revenue that might be raised by a Tobin tax. CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 462 Reviews/Comptes rendus A drawback of the book is its very academic style; it is filled with many long quotes that make for choppy reading. a coherent primer on financial transaction taxes, you might not find this book very enlightening. PATRICK GRADY, Global Economics Ltd. Strangely, the book does not systematically offer the author’s own argument in favour of a Tobin tax. Instead, the reader is left to infer this from the views the author expresses about the arguments of others. Consequently, readers looking for a strong coherent case for a Tobin tax are likely to be disappointed. Rather all they will find is a smorgasbord of supporting arguments. The author never clearly reveals if he prefers a Tobin tax or would settle for any kind of financial transaction tax. The answer to this question of course depends on what you want the tax to do, and the author is not very clear on this. His fondness for financial transaction taxes appears to stem from his belief that any type of financial transaction tax is good because it takes money from the rich to spend on the poor. In other words, he believes that financial transactions constitute a good proxy for ability to pay. Unfortunately, no empirical analysis is presented in the book to demonstrate that this is indeed the case. The reader is left with nothing more than the author’s assertion. The author also never really satisfactorily addresses the efficiency arguments against the taxation of financial transactions. The theory of optimal taxation suggests that from the point of view of allocative efficiency it is best to tax transactions where supply and/or demand are most inelastic, thereby approximating the impact of a lump sum tax and minimizing distortions. On this criterion, financial transactions are not the obvious candidates for excise taxation. If you are already familiar with the pros and cons of financial transaction taxes and want a convenient list of all the arguments on both sides or alternatively if you wish to see how one knowledgeable supporter of the concept deals with the arguments, this book might be for you. On the other hand, if you are not already familiar with the issue and want CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, The Cultural Industries in Canada: Problems, Policies and Prospects edited by Michael Dorland. Toronto: James Lorimer & Company, Publishers, 1996. Pp. xiii, 376. $24.95. There is no shortage of published collections in the culture and communications field. There is a shortage of solid analytical reports or monographs on the issues and debates facing policymakers. Nevertheless, some collections are superior to others and some do make a contribution. This collection has a certain uniqueness. All essays are original, there are no reprints. There is a very high level of topical integration (many collections do not quite make it in this respect). The essays address the private as well as the public sector and they (at last!) go beyond a preoccupation with content, thus probing marketing issues in addition to the more commonly analyzed industrial structures. The Cultural Industries in Canada is a collection of 13 essays by recognized scholars and consultants, many of whom readers will have met before in other collections and research monographs and in the press. According to Michael Dorland the “essays ... trace out what the effect of state policy has been, evaluate its often ambiguous legacy, and examine the implications for the future in an increasing global market ...” According to Dorland, the text as a whole revolves around the argument “that the way one approaches the cultural industries and policies affecting them, as well as the language one uses, is as important as the reality one imagines one is talking about, or making policy for.” Although this implies an analysis of the language (or discourse) of policy statements, such is not the case. The essays which, for the most part, are of good quality and evenly balanced throughout the text, are descriptive and historical. The focus is on specific industries and the consequences of policies implemented. VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus The selections are grouped into the following production domains: Print (books, periodicals, and newspapers); Sound (recording and radio); Image/ data (film and video, public and private television, cable, home video and DBS); and Policy. In turn, each writer deals with the assigned topic by describing its background, analyzing the market accompanied with production statistics, describing the related industrial structure, and considering related policy formulation and implementation. It is much to the credit of the editor that the writers were held to a common framework, thereby giving the collection the quality of a single monograph (not an easy task as those who have edited collections well know). Though evenly balanced, readers will undoubtedly dwell more on essays related to their specific interests and quibbles. The fact that I too have selected certain articles over others for comment in no way reflects negatively on those passed by. Rowland Lorimer’s extensive research on books and reading makes him an excellent choice to write on book publishing history. How many of us are aware that the “book publishing industry ... generates yearly sales of over $1.5 billion in publisher’s receipts and $3 billion in retail sales.” This is the lead essay; if the value of production and sales for each industry in the business of producing and reproducing representations were calculated and added for the field as a whole, the amount would be very impressive indeed. Not surprising then that the federal ministries of Canadian Heritage and Industry find themselves frequently at odds and frequently cooperating. This common distinction between the “symbolic environment” and the “industry environment,” as Professor Dorland puts it, seems to present the writers and, perhaps, the readers, with a conundrum. Lorimer chooses to introduce the distinction as one between certain markets (trade books and, “in a more limited fashion,” mass-market paperbacks and textbooks), “if the focus is on ... culture” and a broader market, “if the focus is on industrial development.” There is too a hint here that mass-market paperbacks are not quite “culture.” The riddle is, how 463 does one conceptually distinguish between industry and culture as separate objects of discourse? I will return to this issue, one which pervades the collection. Both Lorimer and Lon Dubinsky, in his article on periodical publishing, note that their discussions are limited, in the main, to English Canada, a point that is all too often missed in analyses of and presentations on “Canadian Culture.” Dubinsky specifies that his material focusses on English Canada. Having made this distinction, these and other essays give very little attention to the presence of strong regional cultures (although Dubinsky does point to the development of regional periodicals) and the fact that the Canadian cultural enterprise is and has been principally devoted to the creation of a national culture, in some cases undermining local or regional cultures. (This can certainly be demonstrated in the broadcasting field). In contrast, the cultural enterprise in Quebec has been and is devoted to the preservation of a national culture. Christopher Doran and Will Straws’ articles introduce the reader to two areas infrequently addressed in the field, namely, the press and the recording industry, both doing quite well as “Canadian cultural industries.” It is of some significance that Straw asks the reader to seriously consider the contradictions and paradoxes inherent in the recording industry, significant because all commercial and public enterprises in the business of representation contain contradictions and paradoxes and it is only through a recognition of these that public policy has a chance of meeting reality halfway. Michel Filion’s essay on radio concludes the section on the “Sound Industries.” Interestingly enough, of all the essayists, Filion discusses the interests differentially attached to public and private broadcasting as nationalism versus commerce rather than in terms of the more usual culture versus economics dichotomy: “... national radio, from its very beginning was a compromise between nationalism and commerce.” I have often puzzled over the fact that most writers in the culture and communications CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 464 Reviews/Comptes rendus field resist acknowledging that the discourse of Canadian “culturists” carries English-Canadian nationalism as a sub-text. Good for Filion! Though I would argue that he neglects to come to terms with the regionalization/centralization axis in broadcasting. The fate of CKUA, Edmonton at the hands of the CRBC during its earlier years and the forced closing of CKY, Winnipeg (the first commercial public radio station in Canada) during the 1940s are two examples of this process. Marc Raboy picks up the case of public television. Quite rightly, and again not too often referred to in the field, Professor Raboy points out that no broadcaster is void of public purpose nor of regulation. The difference between the CBC and private television is a matter of degree, with the former becoming more and more like a private broadcaster combined with a kind of “publicization” of the private sector. This is a provocative analysis, all the more so because Raboy, like Filion is not taken in by the “culturists.” Public broadcasting, as we have it, emerged as the instrument of a particular vision of the state. There are four essays on policy, all interesting in their historical coverage of policy formulation and implementation, but not overly productive in debating the key problems facing politicians and bureaucrats who must make policy within the context of a political-economy where very little consensus is to be found. Robert Babe’s contribution does present a useful conceptual framework for the evaluation of policy in his use of the categories of technical, functional, and corporate convergence and the historical emergence of divergence in the communication industry. To return to the distinction between culture and economy, a comment, directed more to the field in general, than to the authors of this book in particular: culture may be taken to refer to dominant, traditional, or emerging systems of meaning; the latter two challenging the dominant. If one adopts this manner of conceptualizing culture, one cannot op- CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, pose culture to marketplace economics; or keep culture out of or put culture into trade negotiations; or have cultural and non-cultural industries. Marketplace economics is a culture — a set of meanings and prescriptions for action — as are anti-market public policy objectives. Culture can only be “put into” or “taken out” of trade agreements or industry if one specifies just what cultural configuration is at issue. In Canadian/US trade negotiations and in the split between culture and economy adopted in this book, the references are not to culture tout court but specifically to industrial complexes (public and private) producing and distributing particular types of discourse. An important point if one is to address public policy regarding instruments of communication. We cannot oppose cultural development per se to marketplace thinking or to technology for that matter; we can oppose only a specified and particular set of goals for cultural development to the marketplace, keeping in mind that the proponents of marketplace thinking will have their own agenda for cultural development. Both Filion and Raboy are more tuned in to this way of thinking than most of the other essayists. Public policy supporting Canadian industry producing and distributing symbolic representations is in the aid of a particular vision of the state and the nation, not culture per se. It would be far more useful from a policy point of view to articulate the particular national vision behind cultural policies; that is, to be honest regarding the ideological base upon which cultural and communications policies stand. The culture/economy dichotomy is deeply buried in this collection as it is in most publications in the field. Nevertheless, the collection is exceptionally informative and up to date with respect to those industries engaged in the production of representations. It is a must for the shelf of anyone, scholar or consultant, working in the field. JOHN D. JACKSON, Centre for Broadcasting Studies, Concordia University VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus Qualities of Mercy: Justice, Punishment, and Discretion edited by Carolyn Strange. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 1996. Pp. xii, 186. $24.95. In this collection of scholarly essays, readers will find five mutually complementary and yet separate topics on the issues of state punishment for law breakers. It covers more than a single society and therefore is both comparative and historical. Each author presents his/her study in clear and eloquent style. Greg T. Smith writes about the decline of physical punishment in London, 1760-1840, and Simon Devereaux, covering almost the same time period (1770-1830), explains some alternatives to death in the English State, such as transportation and other penal practices. Barry Wright takes the case of Canada with his penetrating “‘Harshness and Forbearance’: The Politics of Pardon and the Upper Canada Rebellion.” This essay explains the role of the pardon in the dynamic period of early nineteenthcentury Upper Canada. According to Barry Wright, pardons were not granted simply on compassionate grounds but rather according to political and tactical needs, agendas and the circumstances of an individual case. Tina Loo’s contribution is a summary of her research entitled “Savage Mercy: Native Culture and the Modification of Capital Punishment in Nineteenth-Century British Columbia.” The central theme in Loo’s essay is the question of cultural diversity and how organized societies can govern it, especially concerning the question of jurisprudence. As well as editing the book, Carolyn Strange wrote about comparative justice by contrasting political culture and the death penalty in New South Wales and Ontario, 1890-1920. Readers will enjoy her summary about British justice and cultural values as she compares Canadian and Australian laws and their adaption to local conditions of justice administration. And the last contribution to this valuable anthology is an “Afterward” about punishment in late twentieth-century Canada by Anthony N. Doob. 465 Doob suggests that the Canadian Parliament has given the country’s judges very little guidance about how sentences should be handed down, thus leaving to judges opportunities to exercise personal discretion and to apply a degree of mercy. This collection treats mercy not as a theological concern but rather as a judicial aspect of organized societies and their law-enforcing institutions. By using the history of predominantly Protestant countries (Australia, Canada, and England), the editor convincingly shows that scholars, like the policymakers of the present time, know very little about the various qualities of mercy. Many misconceptions exist about its quality and applications. For this reason alone, one may wish that someone will complement this book with similar research on a set of predominantly Roman Catholic countries of the same period in Europe, for example, France, Spain, and Italy. It would be a fair matching for the three countries used in this book. In general, this volume is a welcome addition to the criminological and legal library of important books. It can be used by both professionals and students alike. The essays are well written and each topic is primarily based on historical data along with statistical evidence. With the type of historical facts used and other archival evidence, a scientific explanation for the history of the quality of mercy is unquestionably achieved. The contributors to this volume, including the editor, have enriched legal and sociological literature. Sociologists of correction or/ and sociology of punishment, criminologists, law professionals, parliamentarians, and other policymakers, and of course students, need to be made aware of the content of this anthology. VLADISLAV (VICTOR) A. TOMOVICH, Department of Sociology, Brock University CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 466 Reviews/Comptes rendus When We’re 65: Reforming Canada’s Retirement Income System by John B. Burbidge, James Cutt, Paul Dickinson, Newman Lam, Michael J. Prince, Christopher Ragan and William B.P. Robson. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute, 1996. Pp. vii, 224. $16.95. This book, thirteenth in the C.D. Howe Institute’s “Social Policy Challenge” series co-editored by John Richards and William G. Watson, consists of five papers: the first two present specific pension policy proposals while the other three more general papers provide background to the pension policy debate. Of the specific proposal papers, the first, by William Robson, is entitled “Ponzi’s Pawns: Young Canadians and the Canada Pension Plan.” Here, the CPP is likened to a pyramid scheme, purportedly invented by American con man Charles Ponzi in the early decades of this century. Obviously, Robson is no fan of pay-as-you-go systems in which retirement benefits are paid out of current payroll taxes and not out of a pre-existing fund. Fearing the changing age structure and wishing to be fair to younger generations of Canadians, he advocates “beefing up” the CPP fund in the short-run — through higher contribution rates and lower benefits — and then replacing the CPP (probably around 2030) with a private pension system. In the second paper, Christopher Ragan focuses on tax-deferred savings plans (TDSPs) such as Registered Retirement Savings Plans (RRSPs), proposing that they be abolished and replaced by increased consumption taxes. He argues that TDSPs do not increase savings and that they redistribute wealth in favour of upperincome persons. To encourage savings and to eliminate such wealth redistribution, he proposes eliminating all tax (i.e., public) support for all TDSPs and establishing a consumption tax system by reducing income tax rates and increasing the GST rate. Burbidge’s paper, the first of the more general contributions in this volume, has two major themes: one, over the long run, it will not be feasible to maintain current levels of intergenerational transCANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, fers to elders and, two, public assistance for the aged must be tied more closely to the well-being of the generation whose taxes provide public pensions. He views the CPP as the logical place for cuts, suggesting that it could be phased out over ten years or altered so that payment levels are tied to growth in the real earnings of workers. Lam, Prince, and Cutt focus on ways to restore the CPP, a program whose repair they view as important to reviving a Canadian collective identity. Noting that population aging is only one of many factors affecting the feasibility of the CPP, they sift through a number of options for reform and for each option consider its rationale, effect on contributors, socio-legal implications, and financial impact. They then recommend the following five measures to reform the CPP: (i) quickly raise the contribution rate to 8 percent; (ii) invest contributions through the capital market, with investments regulated by an independent authority; (iii) gradually raise the age for full pension entitlement to 79; (iv) freeze the retirement pension at its current level of purchasing power; and (v) remove survivor and disability benefits from the CPP and provide them through another program such as Worker’s Compensation, Old Age Security, or the Guaranteed Annual Supplement. The volume concludes with Paul Dickinson’s paper on six common misperceptions/myths about the CPP as presently constituted. These misperceptions are: (i) few of today’s seniors are poor, and a large portion of federal benefits goes to high-income seniors; (ii) the CPP is regressive because low-income workers contribute a larger share of their earnings than high-income earners; (iii) the CPP does little to help low-income elderly persons; (iv) future generations of workers will have less disposable income than today’s workers because CPP contribution rates must increase to finance the plan when the baby boomers retire; (v) today’s younger workers will earn no interest on their CPP retirement contributions, and future generations will receive less in benefits than they pay in contributions; and (vi) the CPP is approaching bankruptcy. He points out the danger that these misperceptions, VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus if left unchallenged, could be accepted without question and could even lead to the demise of the CPP through self-fulfilling prophecy. When We’re 65 is somewhat mistitled — it is not really about reforming the Canadian retirement income system. While the paper by Dickinson, and to a lesser extent that by Burbidge, explicitly recognize the inter-connectedness of our pension system, the other papers discuss reforms to one part of the system only, without considering the implications of changing that part on the other parts and/or on the whole. The papers are ordered in an odd way — from the specific to the general — with background papers preceding specific policy-proposal papers. On the other hand, there is a clear, albeit implicit, “right to left” ordering of the papers. While there is much for thought provided in this volume, there is one major disappointment. I am truly amazed that a book dealing with pension reform in the 1990s fails to deal with women, and ignores gender differences in a discussion of the effects of public policy and public policy changes. ELLEN M. G EE, Department of Sociology and Anthropology, Simon Fraser University Less Than Zero: The Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy by George Selgin. London, UK: The Institute of Economic Affairs, #132, 1997. Pp. 81. In this brief monograph, Professor Selgin makes the case for a “productivity norm” as the operating rule for a central bank. With rising productivity, there would have to be falling prices, hence the title of the book. Selgin eloquently makes the case for a falling price level, both theoretically and empirically, and points out repeatedly how this “productivity norm” and accompanying deflation are to be preferred to zero inflation. In Selgin’s world, “change in velocity would be prevented ... from influencing the price level through offsetting adjustments in the supply of money” (p. 10). While those who agree that “... unemployment is a nonmonetary or natural economic condition ...” (p. 9) will probably find much to like in Selgin’s arguments, 467 Selgin also strongly posits the argument that “Monetary disturbances have real effects” (p. 19). In this statement of the argument “... it is assumed that there is a fiat-money-issuing central monetary authority capable of insulating the price level from the effects of innovations to the velocity of money or real output” (p. 21). The most interesting question is thus done away with: How and when does the central bank know that there have been “innovations to the velocity of money or real output?” The central bank has gone from being a preprogrammed dispenser of money to an omniscient corrector of “innovation.” Selgin also sides with those “revisionists” who now deny that there was a depression in England in the last quarter of the nineteenth century contravening the testimony of those who lived through it now that they are not here, in terms which are quite similar to those who are praising the Bank of Canada’s current deflationary policy in the face of 10 percent unemployment because it is “natural,” and ignoring the voices of those who decry the high and persistent unemployment of the 1990s in Canada. Although he concedes there was a depression in the 1930s, I suspect that that will be eliminated by his followers in another couple of decades when those who experienced it are also conveniently gone. Whether you agree with its thesis or not, this book is an interesting and useful addition to the debate on central bank policy which will certainly generate much further discussion and research. RALPH KOLINSKI, Department of Economics, University of Windsor Economic Growth, Technological Change, and Canadian Economic Policy by Richard G. Lipsey. C.D. Howe Institute Benefactors Lecture. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute, 1996. Pp. 87. No one in Canada has done more to foster public understanding and academic study of economic CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 468 Reviews/Comptes rendus growth than Richard Lipsey. The views he has put forth in numerous publications, meetings, and public speeches have helped shape Canadian policy discussions. Through the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research he has been a leader in new growth theory at the highest level. These lectures summarize his views on growth and sketch their implications for Canadian public policy. Lipsey advocates a radical break from mainstream economics, which he argues cannot deal properly with the origins and consequences of technological change, the mainspring of growth. Technological change, which in neoclassical theory is purely exogenous, is in fact endogenous to economic life, and especially to economic policy, which influences the level and direction of research and development, patterns of technological diffusion, sectoral and regional adjustments, and the ability of private individuals and firms to coordinate their decisions in an ever changing world. The lectures illustrate some of the policy implications of endogenous technology, with examples running from the regulation of monopoly, which he argues, following Schumpeter, should be geared more to preserving incentives to innovate and less to fostering static efficiency, through to federal science and technology policy, which he argues must not be blinded by either protectionist or laissez-faire dogmas. Lipsey maintains that technological change takes place not just through the continuous accumulation of new ideas in the form of new and better goods, but through a punctuated succession of “general purpose” technologies that pervade the economy and transform society. These radical structural changes raise our welfare in ways that can’t be captured by standard growth accounting methods, which assume an invariant underlying technological structure, or even by existing endogenous growth theories, which also assume a constant underlying structure, although at a deeper level than does neoclassical growth theory. The deep structural adjustments that often accompany new general purpose technologies are the CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, source not only of long-run prosperity but also of much short-run hardship. Lipsey recognizes the costs imposed on displaced workers and bankrupt businesses, but argues that society typically places too much emphasis on the costs and not enough on the long-run benefits. He uses historical examples going back to the bronze age to emphasize the enormity of the benefits attributable to new general purpose technologies. He also applies his insights repeatedly to the particular example of the information and communication revolution that is currently transforming the world. Committed neoclassicists will probably not be persuaded to abandon their research programs by this or any other historical argument. Nor will those of us who are pushing Schumpeterian endogenous growth theories. Economic theory, like technology, has a habit of producing trajectories that no one had thought possible. But all of us would be well advised to push our theories as far as possible to accommodate the discontinuous structural changes that Lipsey argues have sustained economic growth for millennia. And policymakers who want to help Canada prosper in the new economy cannot afford to ignore Lipsey’s message. PETER HOWITT, Department of Economics, Ohio State University Hard Bargain: Transforming Public Sector Labour-Management Relations by Peter Warrian. Toronto: McGilligan, 1996. Pp. 205. $18.95. Peter Warrian’s Hard Bargain sweeps readers in with the verve of a management bestseller. The New Public Management is “disaggregating” service delivery everywhere. Public sector Wagnerism is obsolete, and unions that resist multi-skilling and cooperation court disaster. Impelled by restraint, and informed by Reinventing Government, local managers can now plausibly threaten “political exit” from practically every field. GM may always make cars, but “Premiers like Ralph Klein ... and Mike VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus Harris ... have no such base commitment to government services” (p. 19). Yet service and productivity gains ultimately require enthusiastic workers, and excessive contracting out “means putting yourself out of business” (p. 128). Ignoring these realities means deadlock, or “a downward spiral of bloody-mindedness,” layoffs, and cuts (p. 102-3). Only flexible, participative workplaces can survive restraint more or less intact. So Warrian offers a post-Wagner compromise. In exchange for accepting multi-skilling, with wages and job security tied to productivity, state unions would be consulted on performance standards, and workers would be retrained for a wider variety of jobs, via “sector councils,” etc. Warrian suggests that new bargaining strategies might allow for “completely autonomous working arrangements,” and perhaps co-management (at Ontario Hydro!) (p. 33). But both depend on friendly governments and enlightened (or desperate) managers. He cites unions in Indianapolis that successfully bid for city contracts. But the city included overhead costs in all bids, and even here, “some work has been lost” (p. 129). Given the threat of political exit and the paucity of consistently friendly governments, this is hardly reassuring. And how can the value of democratic workplaces be quantified in a competitive bid? Despite the air of inevitability he creates, Warrian is curiously ambivalent about the forces propelling public sector change. The Harris/Klein approach will produce deadlock, he says, but it is the crest of the wave sweeping Wagnerism away. Trends in the private sector compel change in the public sector, but so far convergence has not occurred. More seriously, Warrian simply presumes a common interest in service. He notes that managers have helped define the “client” needs which drive TQM, and that similar efforts often produce more staff reductions than quality gains. Yet he never raises the 469 obvious questions: Is management really committed to service? Has service ever been more than an incidental concern of the state itself? He chides public sector unions for assuming that the welfare state has popular support, and that state workers and clients share similar economic interests. Yet he claims confidently that the bad old days of unregulated management tyranny are over. So what restrains managers, and supports government regulation of the workplace, if not some public support for the welfare state’s “social wage”? And is this not precisely the economic interest shared by state workers and clients? Warrian’s strategy would have state workers settle for minimal gains at a time when cracks are appearing in the neoconservative facade, and coalitions with clients are creating new forms of accountability. Workers can achieve greater control of their workplaces, and better service to clients, but progress here will come despite state managers and outside market mechanisms. Hard Bargain remains a valuable guide to the mechanics of restructuring in bargaining, hospitals, Hydro, and local government. It provides a concise, accessible, and wide-ranging account from the standpoint of a veteran negotiator who, perhaps, sees too much as non-negotiable. GREG MCELLIGOTT, Division of Social Science, York University Understanding Canada: Building on the New Canadian Political Economy edited by Wallace Clement. Montreal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press, 1997. Pp. x , 408. $22.95. This volume may be seen as a sequel to the 1989 publication, edited by Wallace Clement and Glen Williams, The New Canadian Political Economy. Many of the same authors appear in both volumes, though the confident moralism of the earlier book CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 470 Reviews/Comptes rendus is more soberly and indirectly presented here. There is still talk of social democratic (and even Marxist!) “solutions” to various economic, cultural, and environmental problems. Clever postmodern titles employing parentheses to make puns are both used and cited. Many of the essays have bibliographies as well as endnotes, so readers looking for an extensive collection of materials, all of which are ideologically compatible, not to say homogeneous, will be well served. If a note of criticism may be permitted, it was (to this Westerner) amazing to read about the National Energy Program in terms of Canadian economic nationalism. It was odd as well in a book written from the “tradition” of political economy to read an analysis of aboriginal self-government that never mentioned the more basic problem of aboriginal self-sufficiency. Finally, the discussion of “social forces” in Quebec that led to an “emerging francophone bourgeoisie and ... labour movement” CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, neglected to attend to the fact that these “forces” amounted to the most rapid and thorough secularization of a people in Western history. Nor did it mention the possibility that these new francophone organizations might usefully be seen as heirs to a previously existing francophone organization, the Church. Using language favoured by many of the contributors, this collection exhibits many fine examples of the aspiring hegemonic discourse of an English-speaking central Canadian intellectual class, located primarily in Ottawa and Toronto, and strategically sited at York and Carleton universities. If you liked the perspective presented in The New Canadian Political Economy, you will like Understanding Canada. B ARRY C OOPER , Department of Political Science, University of Calgary VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997 Reviews/Comptes rendus 471 NEW BOOKS Canada-Japan Trade Council. The Japanese Market for Quebec Software. Ottawa: Canada-Japan Trade Council, 1996. Pp. 27. Richard E. Feinberg. Summitry in the Americas: A Progress Report. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 1997. Pp. xvi, 261. $20.00. James Gwartney and Robert Lawson. Economic Freedom of the World 1997. Vancouver, BC: The Fraser Institute, 1997. Pp. xxi, 287. Wolfgang Hoffmann-Riem. Regulating Media: The Licensing and Supervision of Broadcasting in Six Countries. New York, NY: Guilford Press, 1996. Pp. xxi, 424. $49.50. Isabella Horry, Filip Palda and Michael Walker with Joel Emes. Tax Facts Ten. Vancouver, BC: The Fraser Institute, 1997. Pp. xvi, 155. Mark Janis, Richard Kay and Anthony Bradley. European Human Rights Law: Text and Materials. Don Mills, ON: Oxford University Press, 1995. Pp. xxxvi, 516. $59.50. George Macesich. Transformation and Emerging Markets. Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers, 1996. Pp. ix, 128. $52.95. National Council of Welfare. Healthy Parents, Healthy Babies. Ottawa, ON: Minister of Supply and Services Canada, 1997. Pp. 42. National Council of Welfare. Child Benefits: A Small Step Forward. Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services Canada, 1997. Pp. 22. National Council of Welfare. Poverty Profile 1995. Ottawa, ON: Minister of Supply and Services Canada, 1997. Pp. 94. National Council of Welfare. Welfare Incomes 1995. Ottawa, ON: Minister of Supply and Services Canada, 1996. Pp. ii, 44. Willis J. Nordlund. The Quest for a Living Wage: The History of the Federal Minimum Wage Program. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1997. Pp. xviii, 283. $57.95. E. Rico Sabatini with Sandra Nightingale. Welfare-No Fair: A Critical Analysis of Ontario’s Welfare System (1985-1994). Vancouver, BC: The Fraser Institute, 1996. Pp. x, 292. Philippe R. Scholtès (ed.). Industrial Economics for Countries in Transition: Evidence from Eastern Europe and Asia Pacific. Brookfield, US: Edward Elgar Publishers, 1996. Pp. xviii, 192. Thomas T. Schweitzer, Robert K. Crocker and Geraldine Gilliss. The State of Education in Canada. Montreal, PQ: The Institute for Research on Public Policy, 1995. Pp. 141. CANADIAN PUBLIC POLICY – ANALYSE DE POLITIQUES, VOL . XXIII, NO . 4 1997