Case Study of Cape Wind: Identifying Success and Failure Modes of Offshore Wind Projects ARCHIVES By OFASC;VkOW Pierre Dennery JUN 24 2015 LIBRARIES Master of Science in Management LBRAR HEC Paris, 2015 _ES SUBMITTED TO THE MIT SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF SCIENCE IN MANAGEMENT STUDIES AT THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY JUNE 2015 2015 Pierre Dennery. All rights reserved. The author hereby grants to MIT permission to reproduce and to distribute publicly paper and electronic copies of this thesis document in whole or in part in any medium now known or hereafter created. Signature of Author: Signature redacted MIT Sloan School of Management May 8, 2015 Certified by: Signature redacted Henry Birdseye Weil Senior Lecturer Thesis Supervisor Accepted by: Signature redactedMichael A. Cusumano SMR Distinguished Professor of Management Program Director, M.S. in Management Studies Program MIT Sloan School of Management 1 [Page intentionally left blank] 2 Case Study of Cape Wind: Identifying Success and Failure Modes of Offshore Wind Projects By Pierre Dennery Submitted to MIT Sloan School of Management on May 8, 2015 in Partial Fulfillment of the requirements for the Degree of Master of Science in Management Studies. ABSTRACT Cape Wind was supposed to become the first offshore wind farm in the United States. In 2015, more than 10 years after its inception, a single turbine has yet to be produced and the project is at a dead end. Facing a strong local opposition, it has suffered numerous setbacks that eventually led to huge delays affecting its timeline. Understanding what happened in this particular project and what could have been done differently could help the industry go forward with new plans to develop offshore wind in the United States. In this paper, we have built a System Dynamics model to simulate the dynamics of support, opposition, financial certainty and technology that can affect an offshore wind farm during its approval process. We show that contrary to a common idea, the relatively lower environmental awareness fifteen years ago was not a major cause for the to date failure of Cape Wind. Rather, it is the level of advocacy against the project at its beginning that has the most impact on its overall timeline. Major efforts should therefore be devoted to defuse the most vehement opponents right from the beginning, rather than trying to convince more people to support it. We also show that changes in plans during the approval process to increase its NPV can have a strong impact on the project timeline. Lastly, contrary to our hypothesis, we see that a regulatory framework doesn't necessarily mean a faster approval process. Thesis Supervisor: Henry Birdseye Weil Title: Senior Lecturer 3 [Page intentionally left blank] 4 Acknowledgments This thesis wouldn't have been possible without the support and inspiration of the many people I have had the chance to meet here at MIT. First, I would like to sincerely thank my thesis advisor Professor Henry Birdseye Weil for his benevolent support throughout the year. Not only that, he has also been a great source of inspiration during my research. I would also like to appreciate Professor John Sterman for giving me guidance prior to the project and Katherine Dykes for sharing her expertise on wind energy. Lastly, my gratitude goes to MIT as an institution and a community for introducing me to the fascinating environmental, economic and social issues of Energy Transition through its classes, conferences, and club activities. 5 Table of Contents T he case for offshore w ind ....................................................................................................................8 Early developm ents ........................................................................................................................................... 8 The benefits of w ind ........................................................................................................................................11 Risks and criticism ..........................................................................................................................................14 The benefits of offshore w ind ........................................................................................................................17 Latest and future innovation ........................................................................................................................17 T he C ape W ind Project ......................................................................................................................18 Birth of the project ..........................................................................................................................................18 Initial Plan .........................................................................................................................................................19 H urdles ..............................................................................................................................................................19 Current state .....................................................................................................................................................22 Identifying success and failure modes of large energy projects ........................................ 23 Lack of regulatory fram ew ork .....................................................................................................................23 Failure to secure key local support ..............................................................................................................24 Location .............................................................................................................................................................24 M odel and D iscussion ..........................................................................................................................25 C ausal Loop diagram .....................................................................................................................................25 D efining variables ............................................................................................................................................27 M odel overview ................................................................................................................................................32 Sim ulations ........................................................................................................................................................35 D iscussion ..........................................................................................................................................................43 C onclusion .............................................................................................................................................45 A ppendix: E quations ...........................................................................................................................47 B ibliography ..........................................................................................................................................50 6 Figures and Tables Figure 1: Evolution of rotors sizes and power output from 1980 to 2010 .......................................... 9 Figure 2: Blade pitch control....................................................................................................................10 Figure 3: Market expansion self-reinforcement loops........................................................................11 Figure 4: Wind Resource Potential in the United States (Schwartz et al.)...................................... 12 Figure 5: Life-cycle emissions of different energy technologies (Schlomer et al.)...........................12 Figure 6: US Deployment & Cost for Land-based Wind: 1980-2013 (US DOE 1)..........................14 Figure 7: Turbine power curve (Wan).................................................................................................15 Figure 8: Causal loop diagram of support and financial dynamics ................................................. 26 Figure 9: TableA ........................................................................................................................................ 27 Figure 10: View 1 - Dynamics of support.......................................................................................... 32 Figure 11: View 2 - Dynamics of legislative process .......................................................................... 33 Figure 12: View 3 - Dynamics of technology and financing ............................................................. 33 Figure 13: View 4 - Dashboard ................................................................................................................ 34 Figure 14: "Base Case" Public Opinion...............................................................................................35 Figure 15: "Base Case" Lobbying ........................................................................................................ 36 Figure 16: "Base Case" Financing............................................................................................................36 Figure 17: "Base Case" Permits timeline.............................................................................................37 Figure 18: "Base Case" NPV and Technology cost.............................................................................37 Figure 19: "No Tech Change" Scenario Key Parameters................................................................. 38 Figure 20: "No Tech Change" Scenario Permits Timeline ............................................................... 38 Figure 21: "Eco-friendly" Scenario Key Parameters ........................................................................ 39 Figure 22: "Strong Advocacy" Scenario Permits Timeline ............................................................... 40 Figure 23: "Targeted Opposition Diffusion" Scenario Key Parameters ........................................ 40 Figure 24: "Regulatory Framework" Scenario Permit Timeline......................................................42 7 The case for offshore wind Early developments The first electricity-generating wind turbines were designed concomitantly in Europe and the US in the late 1800s'. Soon, farmers across the United States adopted the technology, motivated by the lack of energy distribution systems. In the 1930s, wind turbines were a common sight in the Midwest, as attested by Dorothea Lange's iconic pictures of the Dust Bowl. Until the 1970s, most wind turbines remained very small with capacities of ranging from 10 to 100 kilowatts (Kammer), due to wind energy lack of competitiveness versus cheap fossil fuels. Even though a successful attempt was made to build the first megawatt turbine in 1941 with the Smith-Putnam Turbine, it broke less than 2 months after inauguration and was never repaired (McCaull). Troubled energy markets in the 1970s, nuclear incidents, as well as growing concerns for the protection of the environment under Nixon led to a renewed interest for wind energy in Europe and the US. In Denmark, the first 2 megawatts turbine was built in 19782. In the US, the federal government - through the Department of Energy - began funding NASA research for improving wind turbines efficiency. The program made considerable technological breakthroughs still in use today and achieved huge scaling: the first 4 megawatts turbine was developed in 1982 and held the record for 20 years (Linscott). In 1980, the World's first wind-farm project came out of . the ground in New Hampshire3 The 1980s and the 1990s saw further enhancement and up scaling of wind energy technology, making it ever more affordable: larger rotors to expand the area swept by the blades and higher towers to help reach areas of stronger and more constant wind (figure 1), improvement of blade pitch control including hydraulic systems and slewing drives (figure 2), product diversification 1Energy.gov, «History of wind energy ), n.d. Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://energy.gov/eere/wind/history-wind-energy 2 Frei, M., «Wind energy: Opportunities and Challenges >, n.d. Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.cas.umn.edu/assets/pdf/Wind%20Energy%200pportunities.pdf 3 UMass, «Wind Energy Center Alumni , n.d. Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.umass.edu/windenergy/about/history/alumni 8 with the advent of hot and cold air turbines, and early development of offshore wind were some of the factors contributing to this improvement. The common wind energy converter capacity rose from less than 100 kilowatts on average in the 1980s to close to 1 megawatt at the end of the 1990s (Kammer). Figure 1: Evolution of rotors sizes and power output from 1980 to 2010 140 120 - 0 100 0 2 A A 600 80- * Moss production APrototypes - 40 50kW 2001 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2 005 2010 Source: International Energy Agency (IEA) 9 Figure 2: Blade pitch control Being able to adjust the pitch angle of a turbine broadens the range of wind speeds at which the wind turbine can be operated. When the wind is low, a smallerpitch can be used to maximize the energy produced. When the wind is strong, adjustingto a largerpitch allows the turbine to turn without over speeding. This is referred to as 'furling". Above survival speed, a stalling system will ensure that the turbine doesn'tget damaged. Low Pitch High Pitch Full Feathered 90 Beside technological breakthroughs, market trends also had a great impact on the development of the industry in the late 90s. The sole expansion of the market created self-reinforcing loops (Figure 3) primarily leading to a decrease in costs. States such as California pioneered tax incentives for renewables energy with tax credits of up to 55% (Kammer). Finally, progressive grid integration offered more competitive returns for wind farm developers as it broadened the demand for such energy. 10 Figure 3: Market expansion self-reinforcement loops Suppliers Suppliers competition Cheaper supply Costs Incentive to develop + new projects Development of Wind Farn -.-- Installed Capacity + Learning Learning curve effect CR) ScalingP Economics of scale Manufacturing capacity The benefits of wind Wind is widely considered as one of the most promising renewable energy. Wind is ubiquitous, and can be found almost everywhere in the United States, with varying levels of intensity (figure 4). It is one of the cleanest: a study from the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (Schlkmer et al.) estimates its lifecycle greenhouse gas emissions (including direct emissions, infrastructure and supply chain emissions, biogenic C02 emissions and methane emissions) per kWh to range from 7 g to 56 g of C02 eq/kWh for onshore wind and 8 g to 35 g for offshore wind. The median estimate for onshore and offshore wind production ranges from 11 to 12 g of C02 eq/kWh. This is lower than any other energy source (figure 5). Solar power median estimates range from 27 g of C02 eq/kWh for concentrated Solar Power to 48 g of C02 eq/kWh for photovoltaic. Hydropower lifecycle emissions are double that of wind while geothermal's are more than three times higher. Nuclear is the only source of energy that can compare with 12 g of C02 eq/kWh. 11 Figure 4: Wind Resource Potential in the United States (Schwartz et al.) dI-sdIy uiD hos salid ecum p we wew PemIes Cis. S4m 4at 40 801 RNO 30-S M-1M sW1000 T 0111111is se WOa*$*"* $ON' wo, 60*0 TA- WT dI TA.64 74 $C3 -1 74 . 4 000 Gee as I uavka T 0s !1100 forow2t% VW *n46rOf VWi- 00a*nSf I.$- " "_ 2411. 1.7-54 ?A * = Mkakoaft! low "111. 11 S 1 a T't sib IWWI W by W00A1de asoru"WIC M 5? eewwwoneon fi ewtIvanmIs040 s folftsr #* seaon seasidn~sig mn4 IAI Figure 5: Life-cycle emissions of different energy technologies (Schl6mer et al.) Direct emssions Options Infrastructure &supply Dtrect ermssins Min/Median/Max Currently Commercially 0 9.6 670/760870 . i Geotheral 0 8.8/27/63 26/41 0 18148/180 0 15 0 0 7.0/11/56 8.0/12/35 0 0 Tenologies Pe-commercial 951120140 CrS-Coai-pC 100120f150 GCC Cyc-Comined 17 14!76,110 xyiUei CCS-Co0-a ocear 0 0 17 0 1.0/2 3.7/12/110 42 66 0 onshore Wind offshire 0 0 0 0 88 0 0 29 0 6.0/38179 0 18 0 Soiar PV-utity 130/230/420 450 Solar PV-rooftop CCS-G 0 27 19 Coinntrated Solar Power 620/74 - 210 Hydropower Nudeas 740/820/910 410/490/650 91 - Biomas-dedcaed (CS---C 47 0 1.6 350/370/490 Cyde Bioass-coifrsg n.. Wind Onhln ambes on Mm/Median/Ma Typical values Available Ti-chologies Coal-PC Gas-Combired Lifecyle emissions Metn essions Biogenic CO. emissions and albedo effect chain emissions Cyd 30/57/98 0 28 9.9 8.9 17 1001160/200 67 a 68 1901220/250 62 0 0 0 110 0 1701200/230 94/170/340 5.611728 12 Wind is also cheap relative to other renewable energies. Depending on the weighted average cost of capital used for the calculations, low/median/high estimates for onshore wind vary from 35/59/120 USD 2010/MWh to 92/160/300 USD 2010/MWh. It is significantly higher for offshore wind with estimates ranging from 80/120/180 USD 2010/MWh to 160/240/350 USD 2010/MWh but still lower than USD2010/MWh] rooftop photovoltaic [74/150/180 USD20l0/MWh, or concentrated solar power [110/150/220 USD20l0/MWh, 250/490/600 220/320/480 USD201O/MWh]. Accounting for a carbon tax of 100 USD 2010/tCO 2 eq, 10% WACC and a high capacity utilization, onshore wind is cheaper than coal, combined cycle gas (51/84/160 USD 2010/MWh vs. 97/150/210 USD 2010/MWh and 69/120/200 USD 201o/MWh) and comparable to nuclear (45/99/150 USD 201o/MWh). Without a carbon tax, offshore wind remains more expensive than coal but only by a slight margin (110/170/250 USD 2010/MWh vs 97/150/210 USD 20 1o/MWh) (Schlimer et al.). However, this is only a static vision of costs by energy sources. The cost of kWh from wind has steadily decreased over the past 35 years (figure 6) from 55 cents/kWh in 1980 to 6 cents/kWh in 2012. The slowdown in prices decrease around 2002 followed by a rebound is due to the upward fluctuations of oil prices that had an impact on installation and manufacturing cost for wind farm projects. 2012 prices for kWh are comparable to 2002 prices for kWh though oil prices are more than five times higher (1 10$/barrel in 2012 vs. 19$/barrel in 2002). This hints at large cost savings over the period to compensate for this increase. According to a recent study by investment bank Lazard (Lazard) on the US energy market, wind is now cheaper than any other source of energy with an unsubsidized levelized cost of 37 to 81 USD/MWh of electricity generated. With subsidies, the cost of wind energy ranges from 14 to 67 USD/MWh, compared to 61 to 87 USD/MWh for Gas Combined Cycle, the cheapest conventional energy source in the US. 13 Figure 6: US Deployment & Cost for Land-based Wind: 1980-2013 (US DOE 1) $70 ?f C U LU 40 $40 0- U 30 > LU 20 11111 11.1111 19 90 5 20k) ies Office LCOE: tdrd Rource ;Ced & Financing erms (Excudes PC) Wind Trhnot 201K * Wind Market LCQE in Good to Excellent Wind Resource Sites (Excludes PT() It is not yet clear today whether subsidies for renewable energies will be extended when they expire, but wind seems to have reached a point when it no longer needs them to be cost-efficient compared to conventional fossil fuels. Risks and criticism At the time Cape Wind was going through its approval process, the main argument against wind energy was its cost. In the early 2000s, the technological breakthroughs and the cost saving from operational efficiency were not yet sufficient for wind energy to compete with fossil fuels, let alone offshore wind. Today, offshore wind remains significantly more expensive than onshore wind and most fossil fuels. According to the Lazard's levelized costs of energy analysis (Lazard), offshore energy is twice as expensive as the highest estimate for onshore wind (162 USD/MWh). This is comparable to Integrated Gas combined cycle and cheaper than diesel generators and conventional gas only. The cost of capital is two to three times higher than onshore wind (4,300 USD/MWh to 1,200-1,800 USD/MWh). 14 The second most common argument' against wind energy is its variability and unreliability. Effectively, there are uncertainties regarding the generation of electricity by wind turbines: the strength of the wind blowing on a given day and the energy generation from a given turbine. Though we can predict quite accurately the amount of wind on a given day based on meteorological observations, it does not make it a reliable resource, as it is not correlated with the grid's load curve. Wind varies on day-to-day, month-to-month and year-to-year bases. Most inconveniently, wind is highly volatile on shorter time frames. It can change direction or strength within minutes. Because of the turbines capacity constraints, this has a great impact on the overall energy generation. Low winds as well as very strong winds will cause the turbines to stop working (figure 7). Changes in direction also lead to stark changes in efficiency. In order to maintain a sufficient quantity of electricity input into the grid throughout a day or a month, it is therefore required to keep a certain number of power generators that can ignite rapidly enough to respond to a sudden shortage of wind. These generators are usually conventional fossil fuel plants as nuclear plants are very expensive to shut down and hydropower isn't reactive enough for this purpose. Opponents to wind energy therefore argue that it is neither economical nor green because of its reliance on secondary fossil fuel plants. Figure 7: Turbine power curve (Wan) Bellow 3 m/sec, there is not enough windfor the turbine to produce energy. The output increases from 0 kW at 3 m/sec to 1500 kW at 15 m/sec and then stays constant up to 22.5 m/sec. Above 22.5 m/sec, the turbine is shut down to avoid damagesfrom strong winds. 15 1600 1400 1200 1000 B00 0 600 400 200 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 Wind Speed at 814 (m/s) As previously stated, wind is ubiquitous. However, states are unequally gifted with wind resources, and the best spots are usually located far from large areas of population. In the US, most of the wind is concentrated in the Midwest, far from both the East and the West Coast (figure 4). This entails large investments in transmission lines to move the electricity to where it is needed. Lastly, public perception of wind energy remains tainted by various concerns. There are some local environment concerns, as wind turbines need significant grid connection infrastructures that can affect the local environment during their construction. Residents have complained about the visual impact of the turbines, a growing concern proportional to that of the turbines size. They have also reported health issues related to the noise produced by the rotation of the blades. Combined together, these factors are believed to affect the property value of residents, which is why the strongest opposition to wind farm projects is often local. From an environmental point of view, wind turbines have caused bird deaths in the past, especially when they are located on avian migration routes. Lastly, military officials have raised a concern about the possible interference of turbines frequencies with airport radars (Zhang). 16 The benefits of offshore wind Offshore wind, despite its higher cost, addresses some of the issues that are raised with onshore wind. The best winds are to be found on coastal areas (Pacific, Atlantic and Great Lakes). Not only are they stronger and steadier than those of the Midwest, but also they are closer to the cities where electricity is consumed, given that nearly 40 percent of the US population lives in a . coastal county 4 Offshore wind also resolves most of the public perception problems linked with onshore wind. They are far enough from the coastline to not be heard by residents, making it easier to scale up. And they have little to no visual impact depending on their distance from the shore. Latest andfuture innovation While turbines design and electricity outputs are still following a learning curve, three secondary innovations could have even greater impact on the cost and reliability of wind energy. The first one is purely financial. The cost breakdown of wind farms indicates that maintenance costs are relatively small compared to cost of debt and cost of equity (20% vs. 80%)5. Moreover, cost of debt is substantially lower than cost of equity. Therefore, promoters try to raise as much debt as possible. However, banks are weary of lending money for projects with very high revenue volatility. Insurance policies - developed by start-ups such as Resurety 6 - that guarantee operators a floor revenue when weather conditions are adverse, diminish the overall risk of investments and make it possible to add debt during the construction phase, reducing the overall cost of the project. The development of smart grid technologies that collect instantaneous information on the demand and production of electricity throughout the day would also prove crucial to increase the value of wind energy, by reducing its downsides through better prediction and broader ' NOAA, «The U.S. Population living at the Coast >, n.d. Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://stateofthecoast.noaa.gov/population 5Milborrow (2013), «Turbine advances cut O&M costs , Wind Energy Monthly, Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://www.windpowermonthly.com/article/1183992/turbine-advances-cut-o-m-costs 6Resurety, Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http//www.resurety.com 17 integration. In Denmark (Kempener et al.), smart grid technologies have made it possible for wind to reach a 30% penetration rate, the world's highest. Lastly, a lot of research efforts have been put in developing large batteries that would enable to store energy when the wind is blowing and release it when needed. Boosted by the proliferation of smartphones and electric cars more recently, lithium ion batteries have been envisaged to play that role. But the raw material needed to make them remains expensive (Lazard). Researchers have therefore been trying to develop batteries using other more abundant elements. At MIT, professor Sadoway and his research team have been working on an aluminum-magnesium battery capable of storing energy at just a fraction of today's cost. The first real scale tests for these batteries are scheduled to be held in 20157. The Cape Wind Project Birth of the project At the turning of the millennium, Jim Gordon - a Boston entrepreneur who had founded Energy Management Inc. in the 1970s and had successfully developed the business thanks to its early adoption of natural gas-fired power plants - decided to sell all his existing assets. He would use the proceeds of the sale to finance what he viewed as a revolutionary project for New England and the United States: building the first ever offshore wind farm in the United States off the South coast of Cape Cod (Vietor). Offshore wind had just celebrated its tenth birthday anniversary in July 2001 (Rock) and was already widespread in Northern Europe. Denmark, Sweden and the Netherlands had completed several projects. The British Wind Energy Association had negotiated a set of guidelines with the Crown Estate for the future development of offshore farms (British Crown Estate). There was no such regulatory framework in the US, but Jim was confident he would quickly obtain approval and support. Massachusetts was a liberal state with an above average awareness for environmentrelated issues, and Cape Cod's taxpayers had been complaining about air pollution generated by 7 Chesto (2014), "Cambridge company's battery may give grid a boost", Boston Globe, Web. http://www.bostonglobe.com/business/2014/12/30/cambridge-based-battery-maker-charged-formanufacturing/Iz5kS7khBgBJ5 SolLSKHtI/story.html 18 coal and oil fueled power plants (Whitcomb et al.). In the summer, sanitary threshold were regularly passed. Initial Plan The initial project for Cape Wind was very ambitious at the time. Located in the Nantucket sound, off the south coast of Cape Cod near Mashpee, and north of Martha's Vineyard and Nantucket Island, it included 150 Siemens 2.8 megawatt wind turbines producing up to 420 megawatts (nameplate capacity) and an average of about 160 megawatts8 . Had it been completed before 2012, it would have been the largest offshore wind farm in the world. As a comparison, Middelgrunden (Larsen), completed in 2000 in Denmark, had a nameplate capacity of only 40 megawatts, more than 10 times lower than Cape Wind. Still in Denmark, Horns Rev, which was completed in 2002, set a new record with a nameplate capacity of 160 megawatts 9. Jim Gordon expected Cape Wind to start generating power in 20049. Hurdles By no means had Jim Gordon anticipated the battles that were awaiting him. Affluent residents of Cape Cod south shore and the islands quickly became aware of the project and objected to it. The farm was close enough to the islands for it to be seen from the shore (Whitcomb et al.). They feared it would ruin the views of Nantucket sound as well as hinder navigation in the area, which was at the time a good spot for yachting. By doing so, it would decrease their properties value. They also advanced historical arguments, stating that the "Nantucket Sound was a national treasure worthy of protection" (Whitcomb et al.). As early as 2001, they created the Alliance to Protect Nantucket Sound (The Alliance), comprising both Democrats such as Robert Kennedy and famous Republican supporters such as industry mogul Charles Koch 0 . Its stated purpose Wind (2001), «New England's EMI plans 420 MW Nantucket wind farm >, Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://www.capewind.org/article/2001/10/31/579-new-englands-emi-plans-420-mwnantucket-wind-farm 9 Hornsrev, Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://www.homsrev.dk/en 10 Seelye (2013), «Koch Brother Wages 12-Year Fight Over Wind Farm , NYT, Web. 2 Apr. 2015 http://www.nytimes.com/2013/10/23/us/koch-brother-wages-12-year-fight-over-windfarm.html 8 Cape 19 was to support the long-term preservation of Nantucket Sound". They would become Jim Gordon's fiercest opponents, filling more than 25 lawsuits and lobbying against Cape Wind. Because the farm was to be developed in federal waters, but at the same time needed near-shore infrastructures, Cape Wind had to get approval from both federal and state and local jurisdictions. At the federal level, the project needed approval from the US Army Corps of Engineers (USACE) (US DOE 2). A permit application was submitted right from the beginning in 2001. The USACE requested that an environmental impact study be conducted prior to giving its approval (US DOE 2). Starting in early 2002, data was collected and then discussed during heated public reviews, often opposing supporters of both sides. In November 2004 (US DOE 2), the USACE made available their draft Environmental Impact Statement (EIS). It seemed that Cape Wind had just obtained approval at the federal level. But, due to a change of legislation brought about by the 2005 Energy Policy Act and the amendments to the Outer Continental Shelf Lands Act, the Department of the Interior - and no longer the USACE - would have authority to issue permits and leases for this kind of project. Cape Wind would have to go through the whole process again, waiting for the newly competent Minerals Management Service (MMS) to issue its own EIS (US DOE 2). Being subject to its own rules - specifically the National Environmental Policy Act - the MMS determined that further investigations should be made and that an independent contractor should conduct the surveys. Concomitantly, Cape Wind was seeking approval from state legislators for its near-shore infrastructures. In May of 2005, the Massachusetts Energy Facility Siting Board (MEFSB) approved the transmission lines route project (MESFB). The Alliance challenged the decision but the Massachusetts Supreme Court upheld it in 200612. Though it secured approval from the Massachusetts secretary of Energy and Environmental Affairs (MEPA) in March of 200713 " Save our Sound, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.saveoursound.org/about us/mission/ 12 Cape Wind, n.d. «Litigation History of Cape Wind Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://www.capewind.org/sites/default/files/downloads/Litigation%20History%20of'%/2OCape%2 OWind%2OMay%202%202014.pdf 13 Cape Wind, n.d. «Cape Wind Timeline , Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.capewind.org/when/timeline 20 (contested by the Alliance and upheld in 2008), Cape Wind was then denied a Development of regional Impact (DRI) approval by the Cape Cod Commission (CCC) in October of 2007 (MESFB), asking for further environmental study. By that time, the Minerals Management Service had finally finished drafting its own EIS (the second after the USACE's). Once made public, the draft received more than 42,000 comments from opponents. Cape Wind would have to wait another year (January 2009) before the MMS made public its final EIS. As the final hurdles were being removed, Jim Gordon's efforts finally paid off at the State level in May 2009 when the MEFSB decided to overturn the CCC's decision by issuing a super permit (MESFB). The Alliance appealed but the Massachusetts Supreme Court upheld the decision in August 201013. During that period, opponents raised a new challenge asking the Department of Interior if Nantucket Sound was eligible to become a national park (11/18/09). The National Park Service ruled it out in January 2010 (US DOI). Approval from the Federal Aviation Association came in May 201014. There were fears that the wind turbines could interfere with the radio signals of a nearby military airbase but these concerns were dismissed. However, final approval was only granted in August of 201215 as a court of appeals for the District of Columbia had overruled the decision in October 2011 (Barnstablevs. FAA). In the aftermath of the first approval by the Federal Aviation Association, the Alliance filed a lawsuit on the basis of the Endangered Species Act. Environmental impact, including potential risk for migrating birds linked to the wind turbines blades, was a major concern during the approval process. The case would finally be settled four years later, with the DC Circuit affirming the FAA No Hazard Determination 16 Seelye (2010), «Massachusetts: FAA clears Wind Farm , New York Times, Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://www.nytimes.com/2010/05/18/us/18brfs-FAACLEARSWIN_BRF.html 15 FAA n.d. PressRelease, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 https://www.faa.gov/news/press _releases/news story.cfm?newsld= 13819 16 Brookes (2014), «Cape Wind wins long list of court decisions , Cape Cod Today, Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://www.capecodtoday.com/article/2014/03/15/24515-Cape-Wind-wins-long-listcourt-decisions 14 21 The lease was finally signed with Secretary of Interior Salazar in October 201017. In November, the Massachusetts Department of Public Utilities approved the Power Purchase Agreements made by Cape Wind with utility provider National Grid' 8 . In January 2011, the EPA gave its final green light to the project after the USACE issued a Section 10 permit (EPA). With the permitting process finally completed, the developers would be able to focus their efforts on securing project finance. They would have to go through other legal battles though, as opponents tried to contest the Power Purchase Agreements, arguing that they would raise electricity prices for customers. The Massachusetts Supreme Court upheld these agreements in December 201118 and May 201419. Where Jim Gordon's original plans were to start generating electricity by 2004, Cape Wind eventually had to wait 10 more years to be able to pass to the financing phase. Current state After years of litigation, the path for Cape Wind seemed to have been cleared. Jim Gordon had signed contracts with Utility companies National Grid and Eversource, which would have respectively bought 50%20 and 25% of Cape Wind's energy output. Expecting to raise the necessary funds by end of 2014, the production of wind turbines was supposed to start early 2015. But, as Energy Management Inc. failed to raise the money by the contract's deadline, and Cape Wind (2010), << First U.S. offshore wind farm lease is signed by Secretary Salazar, issued to Cape Wind , Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://www.capewind.org/article/2010/10/06/1090-first-usoffshore-wind-farm-lease-signed-secretary-salazar-issued-cape-wind 18 Reuters (2012), «Massachusetts OK's Cape Wind/NSTAR power purchase pact , Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/11/26/us-utilities-capewind-nstaridUSBRE8AP17P20121126 19 Cape Wind (2014), «Federal Judge Dismisses Lawsuit against Cape Wind , Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://www.capewind.org/node/1748 20 National Grid, n.d. «National Grid and Cape Wind Sign Power Purchase Contract , Web. 29 Apr. 2015, https://www.nationalgridus.com/aboutus/a3-1_news2.asp?document=5163 17 22 subsequently terminated construction contracts, National Grid and Eversource unilaterally terminated the contract. Until further negotiations, the project is suspended. But Jim Gordon has already pledged to keep on fighting, stating that the delays Cape Wind went through because of litigation were force majeure and therefore not valid reasons for termination 22 . Late February, he organized a rally in Boston and, with the help of a Cambridge's based organization 23 , gathered nearly 100,000 signatures for a petition asking Marcy Reed of National Grid to reinstate the contract. Meanwhile, the first offshore wind farm has started construction in Rhode Island. Because it went through so many obstacles, Cape Wind is a good example that can help us identify success and failure modes of renewable energy projects. We hypothesize that lack of regulatory framework, rallying national support at the expense of securing key local support, and controversial choice of location were the main shortcomings in the project. Identifying success and failure modes of large energy projects Lack of regulatory framework When looking at the litigation history of Cape Wind, it is striking to see the lack of regulatory framework for these kinds of projects. In some sense, Cape Wind made a precedent for the future. Two elements in particular have caught our attention: the fact that the competent Abel (2015), «More doubt is cast on Cape Wind plan , Boston Globe, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.bostonglobe.com/metro/2015/01/24/cape-wind-terminates-additional-contractscasting-more-doubts-project-viability/voEIRKmjXziMT5HAoM41KN/story.html 22 Abel (2015), «Cape Wind's future called into question , Boston Globe, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.bostonglobe.com/metro/2015/01/08/legal-wrangling-horizon-for-cape-wind-aftermajor-utilities-pull-out/kIEXaT5x4lkfUplijpdtsL/story.html 23 Crimaldi (2015) « Cape Wind vows to move project forward , Boston Globe, Web 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.bostonglobe.com/metro/2015/03/01/cape-wind-vows-continue-workproject/aeFotet5lyA5BSKgHqfngK/story.html 24 Kuffner (2015) «R.I. officials mark start of first offshore wind farm in U.S. , Providence Journal, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.providencejoumal.com/article/20150427/NEWS/150429334/13748http://www.provi dencejournal.com/article/20150427/NEWS/150429334/13748 21 23 administrations to give authorization evolved throughout the project (the EIS was first drafted by the USACE and ended having to be redone by the MMS) and that there was no public tender for the attribution of the construction sites. The latter weakened the reputation of the project, giving its opponents the opportunity to denounce cronyism and suspicious contracts. The former might have been a source of delay for the approval process by giving additional time for opponents to file lawsuits. Though this cannot be imputed to Jim Gordon, he might have derisked the project by starting with a smaller scale wind farm, laying the regulatory foundations for a future extension. Failure to secure key local support From the beginning of the project, it seems that Jim Gordon abandoned efforts to convince local residents of Cape Wind south shores and the islands to rally his project. Instead, Cape Wind's communication's strategy was more targeted at the general public. In August 2007 for example, Cape Wind was featured in Jason Jones' daily show2 5 . The show was heavily pro-Cape Wind, picturing its opponents as super-rich - not-in-my-backyard - WASP coveting their privileges. It also made fun at the allegation of visual impact of the project. Though these efforts might have helped raise awareness of the project on a national scale, we believe it did little more than antagonize the existing sides. Another possible path would have been to secure local support first; targeting key influencers with aligned political agenda and turning them into heralds for the project. Most of the containment efforts against the project came from the people who would have been most affected by the project. We hypothesize that the marginal benefit of convincing one of them largely exceeded that of rallying support from Californian residents. Location The choice of location for the project was driven by a rigorous analysis of estimated costs, revenues and environmental impacts of the project (DOE 2). Installing the wind turbines farther from the shore was not a viable economic option, as it induced increased costs from installing turbines in deeper grounds and longer expansive High Voltage Direct Current transmission lines. Cape Wind, n.d., «Daily Show, Jason Jones 180 - Nantucket , Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.capewind.org/video/daily-show-j ason-j ones- 180-nantucket 25 24 However, Jim Gordon assumed that he would encounter less resistance for his project in a liberal state rather than in a more conservative state. This however was not necessarily true. Wind energy has seen most of its development in conservative Midwest states, where large energy production sites such as oil and shale gas rigs as well as refineries are commonly sighted in the landscape. Southern Atlantic coal dependant coastal states could have been an easier first target. Model and Discussion Causal Loop diagram The goal of our model is to identify the drivers of success or failure of gaining approval and raising funds for a large offshore wind project. In order to do so, we started by building a simple causal loop diagram to evidence the reinforcing loops that exist between public support and the financing process of a large clean energy project (figure 8). It excludes the particular dynamics of public support and the details of the financing process. We can identify two powerful reinforcing loops: the "follow the tide" and "abandon ship" loops. As the project gathers ever more regulatory support, investors have more financial certainty and start comitting capital to the project. These investments are a signal that the project will eventually be completed and is inevitable. To be on the winning side, some former opponents rally the project. Regulators then consciously or inconsciously follow the tide of public opinion. "Abandon the ship" is the exact opposite loop, where opposition manages to slow the regulatory process, leading to less financial certainty for potential investors. Because of that, they withdraw from negotiations or make public statements against investing in the project, sending a negative signal to the general public. As the project future looms, former advocates start questioning it and support further wanes. 25 NEW--- L- - - - - - - - - --- - - - - -- Figure 8: Causal loop diagram of support and financial dynamics Support Opposition Follow the tide Reguoaco Abandon ship sfp4r PrOmohtiOnl 01f renewable energies + crtaie AdTcanical Adasageou s pa Market a Technical concerns / Change of t techn o logy Cheap money conditions Financial certainty Costs Availability of financing Secondary but no less powerfull loops are the "Promotion of Renewable Energies", "Cheap money" and "Technical concerns". As support grows for the project, so does regulatory support like in the previous loops. This leads to more legislation in favor of renewable energies, such as subsidies or obligation for grid operators to favor green energies over conventional ones. The result of that is more advantegeous Power Purchase Agreements; therefore better expected revenues and more financial certainty. This then feeds back into more support. More financial certainty also leads to better availability and cost of financing, as more institutions are willing to fund the project and therefore compete for it. By reducing the cost of capital, it then feeds back into the financial certainty of the project thanks to increased Net Present Value. On the other side, if technical certainty for the project decreases because of exposed misestimates or increased constraints on the project, financial certainty decreases, fostering more opposition, and raising new regulatory barriers that will further increase constraints on the project and ask for more reviews its technical aspects. It is interesting to note that while the adoption of a new technology for cost purposes increases the financial certainty of the project, it can also reduce it by forcing the promoter to conduct new studies and impact estimates, triggering the technical uncertainty loop. 26 This simple causal loop diagram gives us a sense of the dynamics around the project. In order to be able to simulate different paths to securing approval and financing, we need to define input variables and build a working System Dynamics model. Defining variables Output variables Final Approval: a 0/1 variable indicating if the project has gained regulatory approval Financial certainty: a variable indicating if the project is able to secure financing. Financing is considered secured when Financial certainty equals 1. We stop running the model when both variables reach 1. The final outcome is the Time it took from Design to Construction. We want to test for a set of input variables to see which ones affect Time of the project the most. Input variables Each of these 4 variables is set with an initial value and evolves during the simulation. TableA, TableF: tables representing the marginal intensity of a 1% change in voicing opposition or support Figure 9: TableA A very small minority of vehement opposition can suffice to generate a strong lobbying movement. This is what we have tried to incorporateinto our model with a diminishing marginal lobbying curve. With 1% "Voice Against", the intensity of the lobbying is 50% of its theoretic maximum. With 2%, this increases to 75%, etc. Above 10%, we consider that additional opponents have no impact on lobbying. 100% 75% ...... ... ---- -------- - -------... 50% 0% 1% 2% 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% 8% 9% 10% % of people "voicing against" the project 27 Init Strongly Against, Init Strongly in Favor: The initial proportion of residents actively advocating against or for the project Initial percentage in favor: The initial proportion of residents in favor of the project including "Voice in favor", "In favor" and "Lean in favor" (see below). Initial percentage against is equal to 100 - Initial percentage in favor. We start with 0 "In favor" and 0 "Against" Legislation in place: a 0/1 variable indicating if the legislation is already in place. When equal 0, the three approval processes occur in sequence, indicating a trial and error approach. When equal to 1, the legislator already knows the extent of the approvals needed and several processes can start at the same time. The overall theoretical procedure time is the same in both cases though (27 months, or 3 times 9 months) Change technology: a 0/1 variable indicating if we choose to change technology after the second one becomes more profitable. Ramp end time against, Ramp end time for: the time it takes for opponents and advocates of the project to reach 100% of their respective lobbying efficiency. Computation variables The next set of variables is variable that change during the simulation and are used to calculate our output variables. Voice against, Voice in favor: a dimensionless variable indicating the percentage of the local population who advocate against or for the project. Against, In favor: a dimensionless variable indicating the percentage of the local population who have a strong opinion against or for the project, but who do not actively participate in the debates. Lean in Against, Lean in favor: a dimensionless variable indicating the percentage of the local population without a definitive opinion against or for the project Become against, become in favor: the rate at which people "leaning in favor" / "leaning against" change to "leaning against" / "leaning in favor" 28 CA, CF: the rate at which people "leaning against" / "leaning in favor" change to "Against" / "In favor" CVA, CVF: the rate at which people "Against" or "In Favor" become advocates for their cause, in percentage/Month. Both can be positive or negative. IntensityA, IntensityF: a dimensionless value between 0 and 1 indicating the strength of public opposition or public support for the project. IntensityA is 0 if nobody is strongly opposed to the project and 1 if everybody is. LobbyingA, LobbyingF: a dimensionless value between 0 and 1 indicating the overall strength of lobbying against / in favor of the project. Time remaining to get permit i: the number of months remaining to get permit i. Procedure i slowing rate: the speed at which opposition manages to delay the approval process. Adoption of new Technology: 3 extra months added at time t =50 to each procedure if we decide to adopt the new technology. Expected remaining time for approval: the theoretical remaining time for approval at a given moment, taking into account the procedure slowing rate. Expressed in Months. Net Present Value of project: a financial indicator of the value of the project, in USD. Availability of financing: a dimensionless variable between 0 and 1 indicating the attractiveness of the project. It is also called Financial certainty. Investment cost: the investment cost for the wind farm, in USD. It is based on the desired capacity and the technology adopted at time t. EfficiencyA and EfficiencyF: a dimensionless variable indicating the level of organization of each camp from 0 to 1 that affects the power of their lobbying efforts. Settings variables These are variables that we don't test during our simulation. We try to calibrate them to make the model as close to reality as possible. 29 WACC: the weighted average cost of capital -used as our discount factor in our NPV calculation. We have set it to 0.009 per month for an annualized 11% (Kopp). Change time: the average time in months it takes for someone leaning on one side to change to the other side when lobbying is at its maximum. The stock of people leaning on one side is depleted following a first order delay. We have set it to 6 months. Change time strong: the average time in months it takes for someone "against" or "in favor" one side to become and advocate when lobbying is at its maximum. We have set it to 12 months SPT and SPT all: standard procedure time of one procedure and standard procedure time of the whole approval process. "SPT" is 9 months when there is no regulatory framework and 27 months otherwise. "SPT all" is always 27 months. Procedure i completion rate: the speed it takes for a procedure to be completed. As we have defined the procedure as a number of months, this variable is dimensionless and equal to 1. Cost of tech 1 and 2: we simulate a scenario with 2 available technologies. The first one is cheaper than the other one in the beginning but its cost reduction potential is lower than the other one. They are expressed in USD/MW. Tech 1 starts at 6,000,000 USD/MW and Tech 2 starts at 8,000,000 USD/MW. Ti and T2 min cost: the minimum theoritical costs for technology 1 and technology 2. They are expressed in USD/MW. 5,000,000 USD/MW and 4,000,000 USD/MW. (Lazard) Cost reduc pot 1 and 2: the cost reduction potentials of technology 1 and 2, corresponding to the difference between the cost of technology and the minimum cost of technology for each one. They are expressed in USD/MW. Speed 1 and 2: the speed of cost reduction for each technology. T1 and T2 cost reduction: the cost reduction of each technology every month, determined by the cost reduction potential and the speed of cost reduction. It follows a first order delay function. Expressed in USD/MW/Month. 30 Desired Capacity: the desired actual capacity (by opposition to nameplate capacity) of the wind farm, in MW. We set it to 160 MW, the desired capacity of Cape Wind. Cost of MWh and MWMonth: the costs associated with operating and maintening 1MW of power during one hour or one month. Monthly OM: the costs associated with operating and maintening the wind farm. Price of MWh and MWMonth: the price the wind farm can expect to sell its MWh or MWMonth to the utility grid. Subsidies per MWh or MWMonth: the additional revenues the farm can expect for 1 MWh or MWMonth of power sold. Monthly expected returns: the overall revenues the farm can expect during one month, in USD/Month. Base NPV: a base NPV to which the actual NPV is compared in order to give an indication of the financial attractiveness of the project. 31 W_ Model overview Our model is made of 4 different views. Equations for each variable can be found in appendix. Figure 10: View I - Dynamics of support * niy Against ,Change 2t Voice.Against i tableA rCA time Strong t LobbyingA / Lean Against Ramp End Time For Z EfficicyA Initial per B cntage in fav orin Become again.t aor Ramp End Time Againkst EfficiencvF RD Lean In Favor I LobbyingF tabeF + CFu --- Lob ingA IntensityF In Favor Voice in Favor Cie Finacialcert nty Cbhange time Strong> 32 Figure 11: View 2 Dynamics of legislative process - Proced. 2 rProcedure Io in g s slowing rate Procedure 3 loing rate te Time remaining to get pennit 3 ime reann to gperritrI Tiermiigt *Final Approval Procdure 3 cop ompletion rate Procedure 2 otrt rate Procedure 1 rocomptetion - Icompetio rat Figure 12: View 3 - Dynamics of technology and financing Expected remaining time for approval Al> Availability of financiny Financial certainty Cost of NVh Base NPV cost reduc pot 1 4V-- tI min cost speed Cost of MWMonth I Monthly OM costs Cost of tech 1 ii cost reduction a Prsent Value of Project + N htinvestment cost Desired capacity -- WACC Cost of tech 2 t2 cost reduction Monthly expected return. Subsidies per Price of MWmonth Subsidies per MWh Price of MN% speed 2 cost reduct pot 2 - t2 min cost 33 II ETm Permits t l 12 " Lobbying a- 5 .5 0 0 0 Cu 0 ,0 0 Intensity of lobbying 36 72 108 0 0 144 36 Time (Month) p lx .n.A: C LN nr. tC Cu ntinA : nnrnt IntnsjynJ am On " nt Itt t JC MWi-- 0 36 72 108 144 Time (Month) Fcam Crt -L n Ti. -me (Monh) Cur= 1" ir------Lwm:c ra -----~-Apnecra m MlWl, Climm. 20 36 72 108 Time (Month) 144 4M 450 M 3M 48 96 Time (Month) Ne prrnn Valhne dnpr -n: (%r% In'nvm a-t : C-n -----. 144 36 Time72 (Mont 108 144 Financial certainty .5 2 M 0 0 Cost of technology 900 M 0 (o Su xdispr Curu Decided ~ NPV if i Fppavc' rmn-g rs lwpp,,At Fral Appnv': Curmia s 0 V Cfst ~ - ~~~ 0 ic aslat-A ~~- 72 108 Time (Month) 40 2 ." !R ~ 36 1=4 rn n N nnk tcurvea Tt-u rcsnartn V) rz 'aruit 2: Curni'WZA in rnin 60 u i wl, - ~~ 144 Lean 9 t 72 108 Time (Month) -- ~~ Voice C en 0 Month dmn 0 - A, - ap C1 0 36 72 108 Time (Month) CO ast 1-gh I : Cunrm Ct nina C-h 2: OC-n-nt 0 144 0 Fitnncial cuainy 36 72 108 Time (Month) Dw m 144 144 Simulations Base case scenario: our base case scenario is not supposed to reflect the exact dynamics of the actual project but tries to approximate them. In this scenario, we assume that advocates of the project had a head start compared to opponents and managed to organize their lobbying structure in 6 months, compared to 12 for opponents. We estimate a conservative first split of 2% "Voice against", 48% "Lean Against", 48% "Lean In Favor" and 2% "Voice in favor". Legislation is not in place but a change in technology occurs during the project. Figure 14: "Base Case" Public Opinion Voice Lean Decided 60 9 0 36 72 108 Time (Month) 144 0 36 108 72 Time (Month) 144 0 36 72 08 44 Evolution of public opinion: overall, as time goes on, opinions get more polarized. There is a decrease in people leaning on one side and an increase in both decided and advocates. The rapid increase in people leaning in favor of the project is related to the difference in time to organize for both parties (6 months vs. 12 months). After that period, they both reach cruise mode and the gap is reduced. It takes more than seven years for the population of residents voicing against the project to start decreasing. The change in technology after month 50 gives a new boost to opposition, as the financial certainty of the project is reduced due to new studies having to be conducted. 35 Figure 15: "Base Case" Lobbying Lobbying Intensity of lobbying 0 0 0 36 72 108 Time (Month) 0 144 36 72 108 Time (Month) 144 Lobbying: Lobbying rapidly increases for both advocates and opponents in the beginning as efficacy reaches 100% for each. It then stabilizes over the whole period, with a slight boost for opponents when technology is changed. Both lobbying against and intensity of lobbying against start to decline quickly after year 10, when few regulatory obstacles remain for the project to be granted approval (follow the tide loop). Figure 16: "Base Case" Financing Financial certainty S.5 36 0 S 36 72 2(M4108 Time (Month) 14 Financial cranty : Curent Financial certainty: financial certainty progressively increases as the project is advancing through its regulatory process and NPV of the project is decreasing from declining technology costs. It increases faster in the first year because opposition lobbying is not yet in place to slow the process. After month 50, financial certainty drops abruptly because of the added time the new technology adds on the regulatory process. In the end, as the voicing opposition vanishes, financial certainty increases more rapidly (follow the tide loop). It should be noted that we haven't incorporated PPA in our model for simplicity purposes. Loosing the PPA is what finished Cape Wind, but it is not represented here as financial certainty doesn't drop at the end. 36 Figure 17: "Base Case" Permits timeline Permits 30 Month I dnn O Month, 0 dtnin _____________L_____ 0 T--e renA~g Cr dnl pe.-rm -nt iL Aph 36 :- 108 72 Time (Month) 144 CurventM I Permits and approval: The overall process takes more than 14 years. Permit 1 is obtained faster than Permit 2 as some of it is processed at a time when the opposition is not yet organized. The technology change largely increases the overall delay. Permit 3 is obtained rapidly at the end as the opposition is vanishing. There is a flexion point in the Process of obtaining permit 2: when the proportion of people voicing against the project starts decreasing, lobbying against the project decreases and Permit 2 processing speed starts increasing again. The marginal importance of people stopping to voice against the project increases as the proportion diminishes because of the intensity table. Figure 18: "Base Case" NPV and Technology cost NPV Cost of technology 4M 900 M 2M 600 M 0 36 72 108 144 Time (Month) Time (Month) c 1e:ca' NPV: the NPV of the project increases because of the declining cost of technology. When the project leaders adopt the new technology, they make a significant gain in NPV When the project gains approval, NPV stands around $850 million. 37 No technology change scenario: in this scenario, we only assume that we stick with technology one throughout the project. Figure 19: "No Tech Change" Scenario Key Parameters Decided Lean Voice 50 60 20 25 0 0 0 36 108 0Time72 (Month) 36 0 144 144 108 72 Time (Month)0 80D M 4M 700 M 3 .M Nv Pram ue xrq 0 0 96 144 48 Time (Month) 36 108 72 Time (Month) 144 Cca a I cu C-z-n-. 14 Financial certainty 2M 600 M 10 (Month) Cost of technology NPV 0 3 T1 (L T4 47 366 M2 ~Time ~W ____- 0 36 108 72 Time (Month) 144 Financial ce.ainy :Cami Evolution of public opinion: compared to the previous scenario, the overall trends in public opinion are similar but opposition decreases more rapidly. Around month 50, voicing opinion is already declining and the absence of a boost from technology change accelerates its fall. Similarly, lobbying against decreases well before and financial certainty reaches 100 just after 96 months. The NPV of the project at approval is significantly lower than in our base case scenario though (~$ 750 M) because the cheaper technology has not been adopted. Figure 20: "No Tech Change" Scenario Permits Timeline Pennits 30 I Month dmnl 0 0 Month dmnl mit I 1: Tile rrai Te prmit EX e d rA Final Appr0v .. 108 72 Time (Month) 36 0 rrl: 144 Curent Current C vr :Currerl 38 Overall, permits are obtained almost twice as fast as in our base case scenario (around 8.5 years), even though only a third of the theoretical time (9 months) is removed. The project is at a tipping point around month 50, about to accelerate. In this case we let the acceleration take place whereas we delay it in the base case. Eco-friendly scenario: in this scenario, we start with a greater proportion of people leaning in favor of the project (60% compared to 50% in the base case) Figure 21: "Eco-friendly" Scenario Key Parameters Permits 30 Month dmn 0 0 Month dmnI 7-,-N- 0 lxrnp'F:n, Lrrrt i't 36 72 108 Time (Mornb) 144 ps1Crm\< CU mma Lean K 0 0 36 108 72 Time (Month) 144 With a 20% gap between people originally leaning in favor of the project and people originally leaning against the project, the overall duration of the project is only reduced by 20 months. As we can see on this graph, that is because the original gap is rapidly closed because lobbying against the project has a greater impact than lobbying in favor as the pool from which it can move people is higher. This is the balancing loop represented in figure 8. 39 Strong advocacy scenario: in this scenario, we increase the proportion of people advocating for the project by 25% from 2% to 2.5% in the beginning Figure 22: "Strong Advocacy" Scenario Permits Timeline Permits 30 Month 0 dmnI 0 Month dmnI 144 108 72 36 0 Time (Monh) Tim rmmz i T11e r permit Iur: . n . Firal A-prav,-: - - - - - - - Tme k permit 2 Cur prmit 3 Curzew. -emiras n.g Imn r : n al : CarL -- Current d:-n Similarly, the overall duration of the project is only reduced by around 2 years. The reason behind it is that the additional advocates have a much smaller marginal contribution to lobbying than the base ones, and therefore don't impact public opinion as much. Targeted opposition diffusion scenario: in this scenario, we decrease the proportion of people advocating against the project by 25% from 2% to 1.5% in the beginning Figure 23: "Targeted Opposition Diffusion" Scenario Key Parameters Permits 30 Month I dmnl 0 0 Month dml 0 EpI r r. 108 72 Time (Month) 144 I Currin1 prm \ . o Timreaing ageFpemit I Currmn Th. 'raermit E 36 aCrirni, ~rimi ~..un~gtiM 40 Lobbying Intensity of lobbying 0 0 36 0 0 72 108 Time (Month) 72 108 Time (Month) 44 Intenity . CUm t latenuityY : CI> n .... A.. :... . . L 36 Voice Lean Decided 60 60 20 30 0 00 0 36 72 108 Time (MonhM ) 0 144 36 72 108 Time (Month) 144 Ti Financial certainty Cost of technology NPV 900 M 4 4M 3M S750 M .5 2M 600 M 0 48 R6 Time (Mon.th) 144 0 36 72 108 144 Time (Month) 0 36 72 08 Time (Month) 44 The overall duration of the project is reduced by more than 8 years. Compared to the base case scenario, intensity of lobbying against the project starts significantly lower ( 25%). Compared to the "more advocates scenario", the impact of the change is stronger because the marginal contribution of advocates between 1.5% and 2% is greater than that of advocates between 2% and 2.5%. This strong decrease in lobbying affects all other key variables, leading to faster rallying of public opinion and greater financial certainty. Regulatory framework scenario: in this scenario, we introduce a regulatory framework, avoiding trial and error type of process. The technology changes after month 50. The results of the simulation are counter-intuitive. Introducing a regulatory framework can impact a project by increasing its overall timeline. Introducing a regulatory framework in our base case scenario eventually leads to the project never completing. 41 haft--_ __ ---. - - - -- - - __n Figure 24: "Regulatory Framework" Scenario Permit Timeline Pennits 30 I Month dmnl 0 0 Month dmnI in ge :1 .t permit I:Curnew Sund mn,gt at parmit 2: Cur=et - - - -- - - ~t re ing emit spe -: Curm t -ExI,oaa stieS ap val : Curt TiM e Tm Tim Firal 144 108 72 Tune (Month) 36 0 :Lro aCrn..mn -- - -- - enh -- The reason is simple: after the technology change, only one legislator is working on the permit process when the legislative framework exists whereas two legislators (one for Permit 1 and one for Permit 2) are working without framework. The completion rate is therefore slightly faster in our base case scenario. This however doesn't necessarily mean that having a pre-existing regulatory framework negatively impacts the project. More reasonably, the framework also comes with an overall shortened approval process, which we haven't modeled. PPA scenarios: in these scenarios, we simulate the effects of signing a power purchase agreement with the utilities. Signing the PPA significantly decreases the WACC of the project and therefore increases its NPV and financial certainty. However, if approval is not granted within two years of signing the contract, the PPA can be revoked, leading to a higher increase in WACC due to the bad publicity generated. Figure 25: "PPA scenarios" Scenario Permit Timeline PPA Signed in year 6,10 and 14 Permits 30 Month 30 30 Month .1 dnnI I dmn 0 MonthL 0 0 dmnl 48 144 96 Timeremig 0 0 l'matd ran Fi pr; v Tvx r mim 7 ui ft zie fon zppvnl: Cwrr urn h - W1= ai Tume r-mn F',x7<ved re Finml Ape Month dmnI 0 Month Month Time (Month) I% I [ 0 dmni 0 et rmn 2 Carren - mh Permits Permits r.,- perrl 2 Curnnr - %tn\ ;v prmit 2 Curenw - K appwoal ; Cwrrr-. - Mvwh iru: x ,-f ur dmni 96 144 48 Time (Month) ri 0 Tore r Tim inga re 1inal AppMvn : 144 96 48 Time (Month) miga emit Curew .pemit3, C.ram Larrent ---- - MI rh d 42 It appears from these simulations that there is a right time to sign Power Purchase Agreements: doing so too early (first graph) can affect the project negatively as it exposes it to a greater risk of failure from not getting approval on time. If that happens, then the project looses financial credibility and this can be a burden for the remaining of the process. Signing the agreements late avoids the risk of not getting approval within the 2 years interval, but it doesn't benefit the overall progress of the project as everything is already settled. The right time to sign the contract is somewhere between the two, where it leaves enough time to gain approval on time while also significantly accelerating the process during this 2 years period. Discussion Improving the model Our model has several shortcomings that need to be improved if we wanted to make it more accurate: - Financial certainty strongly depends on Time remaining to get approval, meaning that when Time remaining to get approval is zero, financial certainty is equal to 1. However, the real Cape Wind project would not fit in our model, as financial certainty never reached 1, even though it had gained all necessary regulatory approvals. In order to improve the model, financial certainty could also be made a function of time. As time goes by and the project doesn't come out of the ground, debt and equity provider can become wary that the project is "cursed" and refuse to invest even though the project has been approved. - Our model is sensitive to the assumptions we make for the additional PPA: the duration of the offer as well as its effects on the WACC of the project. Longer offer periods and steeper drops in WACC make it more favorable to sign the agreements early, whereas short offer periods and smaller drops in WACC make it more favorable to sign the agreements when the project is nearing its end. - The overall delays in our model are sensitive to our intensity tables. However, even though the delays can be greatly affected when we change our assumptions on the 43 marginal lobbying intensity of a 1% increase in support or opposition, our conclusion regarding the relative efficacy of project approaches remains the same. Randomness should also be added in the project: in the public opinion variables as well - as for WACC (because it depends on interest rates) and for the expected price of MW. Our intuition is that adding randomness would increase the duration of our simulation. Interpreting our results The first insight from our simulations is that changing technology is a trade off: doing so can improve the NPV of the project significantly but it also delays its approval. When facing a strong opposition, it can be advantageous to keep the same technology so as to not give a boost to opposition. However, when opposition is weaker as in the "Targeted Opposition Diffusion" scenario, the delay is very small (around one year) and the NPV gains are important (-$50 million). Secondly, the best public relation's strategy is to target and try to reduce opposition rather than choosing an eco-friendly environment or recruiting advocacy champions. Reducing opposition can be done either by reducing opponents' aversion or by choosing a project site where the initial opposition is already weak. This suggests that developing large renewable energy projects in more conservative states could be easier than doing so in liberal states where residents are not used to living next to large energy plants and are therefore more averse to changing their immediate area. Also, shrinking the size of the project, and using it as a proof of concept for an extension can reduce opponent's aversion quite significantly. This is what seems to be the strategy of Deepwater in Rhode Island, where the first offshore wind farm in the USA will only start with 5 turbines. There is a right timing for signing Power Purchase Agreements: doing so too early exposes the project to not obtaining permits on time and loosing those PPA after the offer period. Doing so at the end of the project is a safe bet but doesn't help accelerate the approval project. Our simulations suggest that the best time to sign the PPA is once the developers are certain that they wi1 -4-ain permits witAin the P-A *he er peiod. T-is accelerates the end vf the project by giving it more financial certainty towards the end while not exposing it to the risk of contract 44 termination. Of course this is purely theoretical and developers should evaluate their level of certainty. Nevertheless the suggestion to not sign those contracts too early remains valid. Lastly, having a regulatory framework in place can only be a time-saver if it goes with a significant reduction in the overall process. Having one single entity approving the project focuses opposition's attacks and can result in the deciding body being overwhelmed, which is not the case when several deciding bodies are working at the same time. Looking forward to Cape Wind Cape Wind is stalled at the moment. But is it too late to turn it around? What would make it possible? Evidently, the termination of the Power Purchase Agreements was a major blow to Cape Wind that abruptly ended its "follow the tide" reinforcing loop that seemed to inevitably lead to the launch of the project. The tide has suddenly reversed and rapid changes are needed for the project to survive: opponents are regaining strength and will likely undermine any new attempt to revive Cape Wind. Only a series of events could potentially reverse the strong negative reinforcing loop: major regulatory support for Wind Energy in the form of large subsidies making the project attractive for both investors and Utilities, a sudden energy shock reversing the downward trend of fossil fuel prices, as well as a psychological trigger for advocates of the project such as a spill or a contamination scandal seem necessary. Likely, the project will never be developed, at least in its current state. Meanwhile, Block Island wind farm will serve as a test. If successful, it will benefit the rest of the industry by giving it financial credentials and Rhode Island's Request for Proposal framework could be extended to other states. Conclusion System Dynamics have been extensively used to better understand the dynamics of project implementation after approval. In this paper, our goal was to better understand the dynamics of pre-approval process for a large offshore wind project. Our model suggests that the key factors that impact the overall duration of a project are opponents rather than proponents, and the 45 decision to adopt a new technology while going through the approval process. On the contrary, the overall level of environmental awareness barely affects its timeline, suggesting that no renewable project is too early for its time. Rather, it is the developers' duty to find places where local opposition from residents is minimal; and we suggest these places could be found in more conservative states rather than liberal states. Moreover, if their goal is to advance a "green" agenda, massive projects will likely be more counterproductive as they crystallize opposition. Starting with less ambitious projects can clear the path for larger extensions and be a more profitable strategy in the end. During the process approval, developers are faced with a number of decisions, including redesigning the project to incorporate new and cheaper technologies and choosing when to sign Power Purchase Agreements. Changing technology is a trade off between greater NPV and shorter approval process. Depending on the extra time and procedure cost that can arise from changing technology, keeping the same technology throughout the project is often the better strategy. As for the Power Purchase Agreements, we find that pushing to sign them early in the process can ultimately hurt the project. It should be done when developers have enough confidence that they will gain approval before the offer ends. 46 Appendix: Equations Stocks Lean Against: Become against-Become in Favor-CA ; Initial Value = 100-Initial percentage in favor-Init Strongly Against Against: CA-CVA ; Initial Value = 0 Voice Against: CVA ; Initial Value = Init Strongly Against Lean in Favor: Become in Favor -Become in For -CF ; Initial Value = Initial percentage in favor-Init Strongly in Favor In Favor: CF - CVF ; Initial value = 0 Voice Against: CVF ; Initial Value = Init Strongly in Favor Time remaining to get permit 1: Procedure 1 slowing rate-Procedure 1 completion rate ; Initial Value SPT Time remaining to get permit 2: Procedure 2 slowing rate-Procedure 2 completion rate ; Initial value SPT = Time remaining to get permit 3: Procedure 3 slowing rate-Procedure 3 completion rate ; Initial value SPT = Cost of tech 1: -tl cost reduction ; Initial value = 3,000,000 Cost of tech 2: -t2 cost reduction ; Initial value = 4,000,000 Variables CVA: max(0,DELAY3( CA/5 , Change time Strong ))+Voice Against*MIN(0,0.5-Financial certainty)/5 CA: max(0,DELAY3( CA/5 , Change time Strong ))+Voice Against*MIN(0,0.5-Financial certainty)/5 Become Against: Lean In Favor*(LobbyingA/Change time) CVF: max(0,DELAY3( CA/5 , Change time Strong ))+Voice Against*MIN(0,0.5-Financial certainty)/5 47 CF: max(O,DELAY3( CA/5 , Change time Strong ))+Voice Against*MIN(0,0.5-Financial certainty)/5 Become In Favor: Lean Against*(LobbyingF/Change time) IntensityA: tableA(Voice Against)/100 EfficiencyA: IF THEN ELSE( Ramp End Time Against =0 , 0 , MIN (1,RAMP(1/Ramp End Time Against, 0,Ramp End Time Against))) LobbyingA: EfficiencyA*IntensityA IntensityF: tableF(Voice in Favor)/100 EfficiencyF: IF THEN ELSE( Ramp End Time For =0 , 0 , MIN(1,RAMP(1/Ramp End Time For, 0,Ramp End Time For ))) LobbyingF: IF THEN ELSE( Ramp End Time For =0 , 0 , MIN(1,RAMP(1/Ramp End Time For, 0,Ramp End Time For ))) Procedure 1 slowing rate: IF THEN ELSE( Time remaining to get permit 1<=0 , 0 , LobbyingA* 1.1 )+Adoption of New Technology , Procedure 2 slowing rate: IF THEN ELSE( Time remaining to get permit 2<=0, 0, IF THEN ELSE( Legislation in place= 1 , LobbyingA* 1.1 , IF THEN ELSE( Time remaining to get permit 1 <=0 LobbyingA*1.1 , IF THEN ELSE (Time>50:AND:Time remaining to get permit 1<=3,LobbyingA*1.1,0) )))+Adoption of New Technology Procedure 3 slowing rate: IF THEN ELSE( Time remaining to get permit 3<=O, 0, IF THEN ELSE( Legislation in place= 1 , LobbyingA* 1.1 , IF THEN ELSE( Time remaining to get permit 2<=0, LobbyingA* 1.1 , LobbyingA* 1.1,0) ))+Adoption of New Technology Adoption of New Technology: Change technology*3*PULSE( 50, 1) Procedure 1 completion rate: IF THEN ELSE(Time remaining to get permit 1<=0, 0,1) Procedure 2 completion rate: IF THEN ELSE (Time remaining to get permit 2<=0,0,IF THEN ELSE( Legislation in place= 1,1,IF THEN ELSE( Time remaining to get permit 1 <=0 , 1 , IF THEN ELSE (Time>50:AND:Time remaining to get permit 1<=3,1,0) ))) Procedure 3 completion rate: IF THEN ELSE(Time remaining to get permit 3<=0,0,IF THEN ELSE( Legislation in place= 1,1 ,IF THEN ELSE( Time remaining to get permit 2<=0 , 1, 0) )) Expected remaining time for 2nproval: IF THEN ELSE(Legislation in place=1, max(0,Time remaining to get permit 1),max(0,Time remaining to get permit 1)+ max(0 ,Time remaining to get permit 2)+max(0,Time remaining to get permit 3)) 48 Final Approval: IF THEN ELSE (Time remaining to get permit 3<=0, 1,0) Cost reduc pot 1: max(0,Cost of tech 1-tl min cost) Cost reduc pot 2: max(O,Cost of tech 2-t2 min cost) T1 cost reduction: cost reduc pot 1*speed 1 T2 cost reduction: cost reduc pot 2*speed 2 Investment cost: IF THEN ELSE(Change technology=1,IF THEN ELSE(Time<=50,Cost of tech 1 *Desired capacity,Cost of tech 2*Desired capacity),Cost of tech 1 *Desired capacity) Availability of financing: MIN(i,exp(ln(0.4)*(1+(Expected remaining time for approval/100-(SPT All/i 00))/(SPT All/100))) *Net Present Value of Project/Base NPV) Financial certainty: Availability of financing Cost of MWMonth: 30*24*Cost of MWh Monthly OM costs: Desired capacity*Cost of MWMonth Price of MWMonth: 30*24*Price of MWh Subsidies per MWMonth: Subsidies per MWh*30*24 Monthly Expected Returns: Desired capacity*(Price of MWmonth+Subsidies per MWMonth) Net Present Value of Project: -Investment cost+(Monthly expected returns-Monthly OM costs)/WACC 49 Bibliography Barnstable vs. FAA. United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit. 28 Oct. 2011 British Crown Estate (2010). A Guide to an Offshore Wind Farm, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http-//www.thecrownestate.co.uk/media/5408/ei-a-guide-to-an-offshore-wind-farm EPA (2011). Outer ContinentalShelfAir Permit issued to Cape Wind Associates, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://epa.gv/regionl /communities/p df/CapeWind/CapeWindFinalPermit-1-7-201 .pdf Firestone J. & Kempton W. (2005). Public Opinion about Large Offshore Wind Power: Underlying Factors, University of Delaware, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://wind.nrel.gov/public/SeaCon/Proceedings/Copenhagen.Offshore.Wind.2005/documents/pa pers/Poster/Firestone Kempton PublicOpinionaboutlargeoffshorewin.pdf Gunturu, U. B., & Schlosser, C. A. (2012). Characterization of wind power resource in the United States. Atmospheric Chemistry and Physics, 12(20), 9687-9702. Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http_://www.atmos-chem-phys.net/12/9687/2012/acp-.12-9687-2012.pdf Kammer, J. (2012). «Wind Energy Encyclopedia ofEnergy. Salem Press Kempener R., Komor P., Anderson, H. (2010). Smart Grids and Renewables, A guidefor effective deployment, IRENA, Web. 29 Apr. 2015, https://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/smart grids.pdf Kopp D.R. (2010). Foundationsforan Offshore Wind Turbine, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://dspace.mit.edu/handle/1_721.1/60766 Larsen H.L. (2001). The World's Largest Offshore Windfarm, Middelgrunden, 40 MW, Copenhagen Environment and Energy Office, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 50 http://www.middelgrunden.dk/middelgrunden/sites/default/files/public/file/ArtikelWORL 0%2 OSUSTAINABLE%20ENERGY%20DAY%202001.pdf Lazard (2014) Lazard'sLevelized Cost ofEnergy Analysis - Version 8.0, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.lazard.com/PDF/Levelized%/o2OCost%/o20of%/20Energy%/o20-%/ 20Version%/o208.0.pdf Linscott, B.S. (1983). DOE Large HorizontalAxis Wind Turbine Development at NASA Lewis Research Center, NASA, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://ntrs.nasa.gov/archive/nasa/casi.ntrs.nasa.gov/1 9830022836.pdf Massachusetts Energy Facilities Sitting Board (2009). FinalDecision in the Matter of the Petition of Cape Windfor a Certificate ofEnvironmentalImpact andPublic Interest, Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http://www.env.state.ma.us/dpu/docs/siting/efsb07-8/52709cwford.pdf McCaull, J. (1973). Windmills. Environment: Science andPolicyfor SustainableDevelopment, 15(1), 6-17. Nanopoulos A. (2012). Valuation of Wind Energy Projectsand StatisticalAnalysis of Wind Power. Web. 29 Apr. 2015, http:_/dspace.mit.edu/handle/1721.1/74932 Rausch S. & Karplus V. (2014). Markets versus Regulation : The Efficiency andDistributional Impacts of U.S. Climate Policy Proposals, MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change, Report n'263, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://globalchange.mit.edu/files/document/MITJPSPGC Rpt263.pdf Rock M., Parsons L. (2010). Offshore Wind Energy, Environmental and Energy Study Institute, Washington, USA, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.eesi.org/files/offshore wind 101310.pdf Santen N.R. (2012). Technology Investment Decisions under Uncertainty: A New Modeling Frameworkforthe Electric Sector, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://dspace.mit.edu/handle/ 1721.1/92656 51 Schlkmer S., T. Bruckner, L. Fulton, E. Hertwich, A. McKinnon, D. Perczyk, J. Roy, R. Schaeffer, R. Sims, P. Smith, and R. Wiser (2014). Annex III: Technology-specific cost and performance parameters. In: Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the IntergovernmentalPanelon Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 https://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar5/wg3/ipccwg3 ar5 annex-iii.pdf Schwartz, MN., Heimiller, D., Haymes, S., & Musial, W. (2010). Assessment of offshore wind energy resourcesfor the United States. Golden: National Renewable Energy Laboratory, Web 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.nrel.gov/docs/f1-0.osti/45889.pdf US Department of Energy (2014), Revolution Now, The FutureArrivesfor Four Clean Energy Technologies - 2014 Update, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://energy.gov/sites/prod/files/2014/1 0/fl 8/revolution now updated charts and text october 2014.pdf US Department of Interior (2010). DeterminationofEligibility Notification, National Park Service, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://www.nps.gpv/nr/publications/guidance/NantucketSoundDOE.pdf Vietor R. (2008). Cape Wind: Offshore Wind Energy in the USA, Harvard Business School, Cambridge, USA Wan, Yih-Huei, Ela E. & Orwig K., 2014, National Renewable Energy Laboratory, Development of an equivalent Wind PlantPower-Curve, NREL, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http;//www.nrel.ov/docs/f 1 Oosti/48146.pdf Whitcomb R., Williams W. (2010). Cape Wind, PublicAffairs Weil, H.B. & Dalton W.J. (1992). Risk Management in Complex Projects. In System Dynamics 1992, University of Utrecht, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 htt://www.systemndynamics.or/conferences/992/roceed/dfs/supweil39.pdf 52 Zhang Q. (2008), Feasibilityanalysis of coordinatedoffshore windproject development in the US, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Web. 29 Apr. 2015 http://dspace.mit.edu/handle/1721.1/45762 53