LARD USE AND FARM ORGANIZATION Ot A NEW IflRIGATION PROJECT JFFERSOI COUNTI, OREGON by HOWARD A THESIS tibmitte4 to OREGON STATE COLLEGE in partial fn)fillment of the requiremmts for the degree of L&STER OF SCIENX June l9.l Redacted for privacy Redacted for privacy Rad at Department Agricultural &onoinic Redacted for privacy an of School Gr Redacted for privacy Dean of Graduate School is precented Mar 10) 191 Typed by Mary lawrence AClcNoWLDoMENT Thaiks are due Dr. C. V. Plath who has supervised this study since its inception. Iny helpful suggetiona have been received, although the author alone must bear the responsibility for their presentatiou, }e rould also gratefully a cooperation of the farmers, without which possible. The ctheerful assistance of the staff of Jefferson County Itura]. xtension Office deserves recognition, as does that of the Bureau of Reclv,*tton and the North Unit Deschutes Irrigation District. To *31 who have given help and encourages*nt in the preparation of this study, the author offers his t TABLE 0? C0rFTS INTRoDUcTION The Problem In Its Ora1l Setting The Problem In Its Lc-al Setting General Description of the Study Area ETHOD OF STUDY Sample Selection AND IAN!) USE Lend Classification Soils Lend Capability Classification Burau of Reclamation Irrigability Cisseification 2 14 7 8 12 12 13 18 Lnd Development 1 Leveling Costs 22 27 Irrigation of 'Nonirriab r*s Supply Water Delivery Water Cost Water Use 29 30 30 Land Uee FARM ORoANIZATION Aaount of Reeourcei Tot*1 Investment Land and Equipment Siss of Farm Ladino Acreage Use of R.sources 142 146 148 So OwnerBhip of Eseources Operatora Starting Net Worth Tenure and Tenancy Borrowed Capital suw.&Rr 61 67 L&N1) USE AND FARM OE1LNIZATION ON A NFW IRRIGATION PROJECT Ji?FgON COUNT!, OREGON INTDUCTION Recisnation of arid lands in the western states through irrigation will pr*vide an iaportant part of the future increase in food production in the United States. These lands will also pro- vide the last great frontier of eett]iaent in this country. It is expected that fedsr*l money will build the irrigation projects and that federal law will govern their settlemint, The Reelsastion ?roject Act, 1939 (12, p. 92) provides for the variation of onetruaa. tion charges in accordance with the productivity of the land. The COlumbia Basin Project Act, 193 (12, p. 700) provides for the variation of fare unit size in *000rdance with land productivity. In order to judge these proviian it is necessary to develop factual inforeation on the relationship of economic productivity to physical Land c]aeei!ication procedures, With this end in mind a research project was set up to study land use adjustment over a five-year per-. iod on a new irrigation project in Central Oregon. Thu paper sxaminse land use md farm organisation for the first two years of settlement. It is expected that th. study will continue for another three years, by which time fare dsvelope.nt and land use ad.justeent will be largely completed, blem In Its Overall Setting estimated that The Natural Resources Board tn 1936 (8, p. 9) there are more than $0 million acres pf potentially irrigable land in the 17 western states. Lass than 20 million acres of this were irrigated by 191.5. Projects under construction or under consider* tion by the Bureau of Reclamation at that time would provide water for another 20 million acres. "To provide for the creation of homes and of opportunities 1 living" is the "ultimate objactive of reclamation.. ). Successful settlement of irrigation projects has depended, to a considerable degree, on the ability of settlers to p. meet the repayment of construction charges (2, p. 1S3). These charges have been b*sed on the cost of project construction to the Federal Government, tempered, of necessity, by the settlers' ability to repay, and have been interest free. In recent contracts for repayment, the annual charge has been based upon the total annual returns (1, p. 31) of the project in relation to I annual returns over a period of years.1 In order to take advantage of th. greater benefits accruing to lands of higher productivity and their consequent greater repayment 1. "The term 'annual returns' shall mean the amount of annual gross returns per acre of the area in cultivation within the project contract unit involved, and the tern 'nornal returns' for any year shall mean the weighted average of the annual returns of those ten years, of the 13 year period covering said year and the twelve years preceding it, in which the annual returns are the highest." Reclamation Project Act of 1939, sec, 2(b) (12, p. $89). ability, contracts have varied repayrnent charges in accordance with land clasaification differences. St*mm of the Bureau of Reclamation (3, p, 107) stated that repaaent contracts would be varied by land clase if adequate information were available which could be used as the basis for establishing the range and level of i This study will help to fill that gap. The continued prosperity and increasing pulation in this have directed attention beyond the recent period of surplus agricultural production to the posibi1ity of a future limit to the domesticallyu-prodticed food supply. In an era of full employment consideration is given to the beet use of our resources to the end of full productiøn, "If the highest social gain highest productivity per person, we should hesitate to force by leg- islative means r.duotn in sise of farm in areaa of high productivity or an increase in etse of farm in areas of low productivity beyond that which would occur through competitive forces. Fare management studies ahoy that by so doing th. productivity per person is reduced in both types of areas' (, p. 7). This øhould be compared to the view expressed in the Columbia Basin Project Act of "farm units of sufficient acreage for the support of an average-sised family at a suitable level of living" (12, 700). If, in providing a desirable maximum number of farm homes, we are restricting the desirable maximum of fare production the Bupe*u of Reclamation attitude may need to be reconsidered It is expected that this study will indicate the presenc. or absence, b and th influenca, of economies of scal. on irrFated farms in this area. The principles observed here may also govern lend use on other pro jec The proble ed capital is ooiimon to most settlers on new irrigation projects. Of the fazns undar study-, operator. with low starting capital have approached thi problem of settlement in ltfl7 different Some of them are--.renting, borrowing heavily, part-. time farming, U units, crop sharing, and developing at a comparatively w rate, In time, a comparison of the relative uccoss of the methods should be possible, Any additioni to the available information on the rate and amount of capital development that is desirable, or necessary-, on a new irrigation project, will be welcomed by all planning and extension personnel connected with these levelopments. iv..year study will provide an increase in knowledge in these three areas, Thie present report may only fairly be judged in its relation to the overall study. Its task is to la the ground work and point out the direction of future investigation for the remaining years of the study. Some of its weaknesses may lie in that dirtio. ! Problem 2! Local Setting The locale of the study is the Worth Unit Deec}zutss irrigation District in Jefferson County, Oregon, cortonly known as the North Unit. It is a post-war development of the Bureau of Rselamation which has been rapidly settled under the ispetu of high prices. The juxtaposition of two areas of qujt dissimilar tpograpby, which were to come under irrigation at practically the ecme time, Invited their comparison. A research project was conceived which would permit study of the adjustment made to topographic and soil condition* by the farmers in thee. two areas, It was meant to be more of a guide to future action than * help to the present settlers in the district, The project wa et up with the following stated objectivee..- (1) To determine the adjustments in land use made on conaarciml fsi.ily farms located on difforint grades of land as the farms bscome established under irrigation; (2) ?o examine causes for land use adjustments; (3) To assemble information which will be useful making recommendations i as to size of farms and land use on future irrigation projects. The first farm reoods were taken in November and Decber of ]$I9 and covered settler,' progress to that date. Second-year records were taken a year later. This study iø based upon an analysis of the two years' records. eri,tion of the Studr Area The North Unit contains O,000 irrigable acres. It lies to the east of the Cascade Nountsine, about 100 miles south of lun!bia at The Dallas. The climate is characteristic of the semi-arid intermountain region. Elevation of the area studied is 2200 00 feet above sea level. The growing season is about 130 frost free days.extending froa id Way to the first of October, The annual precipitation averages about nine inches. Six inches of this nor ua11y fall outside the growing suison making the area unsuited, without irrigation, to most cultivated crepe. The area tras produc ing winter wheat and range forage prior to the development of irri'gation, t of the land under study was already broken prior to the irrigation development. Ladras, the county seat, (l90 population 1, 20) is centrally located on the project. The area south of Madras was first provided with irrigation water in 19lj6 or 19I7. This study is lizited to the two areas north of Madras which received their first irrigation tsr in 1968 and l9L9. Agency Plains, lying north and northwest of Madras, covers about hO,00o acres (23,000 irrigable) and is a nearly1evel to gentlysloping plateau surrounded by an secarpsnt. Most of the irrigated land has a elope of las than 3 percent. The Mud Springs area covers just over 20,000 acres (6,3oo irrigable). It lies to the east of the Plains *nd about 200 feet law it in e1evtion. This area varies from level to strongly op breaking into rough topography along the boundaries of the pro jec The irrigated land has elopes ranging up to 6 percent or more. ontrasting nature of these two adjacent areas which inspired this stu METHOT) OF STUDY aimed at cataloging farm itwcutment in its none sep.ota and as to its 'various sources. In addition it wan necessary to get crop acreagee, ratee of production, and gross income. Wo attempt was made to get costs of production or net farm While such informatIon would have been useful it would have innensely complicated the work of collection and analysis of the data As e'very researcher knows, tin. *4 cost are factors limiting the quantity of data which can be collected and used. Efficiency in b requires value to be balanced with cost. In this study, a greater number of farms was considered to be of mere v*luø than greater deta.]. per farm. Since only 63 farm records were obtained for analysis this choice may be appreciated. Further justification for omitting oost of production, tar the resent, may be found in the following ststeTaents Peterson, of th* to College of iashtngton (, p. 147.18) recognized that "capital per farm is closely related to income per farm and income p.r person." Datm from the national census and from farm surveys were offered to Substantiate this claim. yment schedules for recent Buresu of Reclamation projects are based on erage gross income per irrigated acre (1, p. 314). Production costs and family living costs are kept to a minimum during the period of farm davelopment. Usually all surplus ineon. is invested in the tarn. The operator' a increasing equity in farm investment, throughout th. period, will show his economic progress. Great efficiency in farm production is not to be expected until farm investment is nearly complete. Relative efficiencies of different farm organisationa may be seem in the cospsrison of gross incomes irrigated acre and per dollar of investment. The extent to stiioh investment is devoted to the farm dwelling end family automo bUs wtU indicate relative levels of living, over tte or betceen farss These indicators promise to be sufficiently accurate to permi comparison of the various factors affecting farm organisstion and land us. They will serve to compare sSonmic progress under different amounts and 41 fferent organisations of farm resources, They wJ.0 also be used in an attempt to show the presence or absence, on this project, of a relationship between economic productivity and the various phystoal land classifications. Sample Selection 'At first the consideration in sample selection was to get farms fIrst year of irrigation. This limited the sample, for 1 purposes, to the area north of Wadxas. Water be available in Mud Springs May, l9149 arid on Agency Riains after mid' suar 191a8. Few farmers on the Plains raised an irrigated p in 19b.8; a considerable number irrigated oas fall seeding that year while a slightly amaller proportion irrigated no land in 19148. It was decided not to limit th. sample on the Plains to the latter group since it was felt this would bi*e the sample towards the farms with fewer resources or with les efficient operators, In relieving tht bias another was injected since all farms did riot ha comparable period of development. The second consideration in ampl. selection 'was to get a work- able group of farms representing the two irrigability land classes and the several land capability classes and soil types. It was also desirable to have these land classes represented In suitable blocks to permit comparison, Due to the limited area of each, the eurey included the greater part of the irrigability class 2 land on the Pl*ins aiid most of capability class I lands In ud Springs. An attempt was made to have a fair range of farm sises and to hA-re farms with varying amounts of nonirrigable land represented. the two sets of land classification maps and the Bureau ownership map and water delivery records were sufficient for selection of the sample. La a final check the county- agent was asked view the lists to guard against too heavy a weighting of atypi.- cal operators. He reported that, to his knowledge, the list contained a fair representation of operators' starting capital, further check on this was made as th records were taken. Initial contact was made by a letter from the county agent to rmer on the sampl. list, explaining what was desired of him oducing the two enumerators. This method was found to be and excellent cooperation was received. Only two farmers to give information. Three operators could not be reached and crop the share and expenses. t operate together tenant and landlord th, which in those are farms Share farms, large as fied classi'- were irrigated acres 16o over with Farm. 1. Table in shown is location crtd tenure by farms o distribution The brackets. in figures their anree, irrigated 2 (3) 6 3 3 10 160 over Farms 6 (3) (3) 8 Largs* Ptne Rented 12 Part-.tj Plains gency Springs Mud 1 DCHUTES UWIT NORTR LOC&TION AND TENURE BY SAMPLE IN FALULS OF NUMBER l90. in 1ze 3.. Table comparable a have to found were farms several s report present the in included is It (ti). report preliminary the in out came which 1919, for the in included not was eis its of beaiuse farm, One ana&ys unrepresentative. be to considered were they because taken was record the after dropp.d were farms Three harvest. their ing county the l.ft had they bec&use 10 Is the sample rpreeentative is did not include the southern half of the pro ject where farms are aefler and development has bean going on since l9L6, it is not representative or the whole of the North Unit. sample was chosen to represent certain conditions and The y not nec- ceessrfly be a fair representation of the northern half of the North Unit. as to It is believsd, however, that the sample is not too different se, investment and tenure, from the area from which it was taken. Furthermore, it Xe felt that many of the principles which govern the organization of farms and the developnont and use of the land in this project w&U also be effective on other new irrigation projects which may be settled in the Pacific Northwest in the near future. USE Land Cl*sification It will be generally recognised that th. nature of the land h*s a major influence on its use. Iow widely land must differ in order to bring about d.iffersnt uses is not so generally Within the Willanetts V*lley differences of soils and topography on individual farms are quite suffioint to bring out differences in land use under proper management. Peterson (, p. 6) states that only when the soil and tQpogr*phy combinations change drasti- cafly., ,do sufficient changes in intensity per acre and acres per farm occur to result in equivalent incomes per fsri tn neighboring areas that have similar marketing and climatic fssture., , tJ*u however, within the same type of farming area . . .only enough change occurs in land us so that faz,ere on the less productive land operat. about as many total acres per farm as their neighbors on the more productive land. Inhibiting factors like rolling topog p. or shallow, poorly drain.d soil usually handicap the 1arm oprstcr in the area of low productivity to such an extent that they prevent him crc. acres ;r man as his neighbor, who has mors level topography and deeper, better drained voile," Land under irr'i.gation in the area studied is classified into three major soil series and two major textures. There are two minor textures also represented, Three major land use capability classes and two irrigability caeses have been designated. None of these may be considered to indicate drastic changes. general type of tanning may be expcted to occur over the a Tb. soil survey (6, p. 12-23) rnarka actual differences in Boils end topography. Tab1 2 indIcate, the d1strbution of soils among ), Three soil series are important to the area under studyJLadras, Agency, snd Netoltue. the sample farms in 1919 Ts.bla 2, (1*. p. DISTRIBUTION OP 50118 OCCURRING ON/SAJfó FAR) N0T(PR UNIT DCRUTII 191*9 Matolius 9 Madrap 70 Agency 12 Era 33 76 14 16 14 monta narable 191*9 total 2 23]. 6 8,333 100 190 net inareau. 0 08 Madras and the related Agency series are composed of a bosslike volcanic ash of moderate depth on oonglomeratio lava mud or basalt. wThese developed under grse and sagebrush cover with an average rainfall of between 8 and 10 inches. They show some accumulation of Liner materl*ls in the upper subsoil," Madras "soil, to a depth of 8 to 10 inches is a brownish gray, friabl, sandy loam containing some pumice. It is underlain by olive brown compact silty prismatic clay loam 'with colloidal etaininge and soil aggregates. This grades into yellowish gray, highly calcareous clay loam or clay with lime coated fragments of rhyolite anc basalt." "At an average depth of about 21i thckE e the eubeoil rests rn gray conglomeratic.]ike cali abs hardp*n of variable hicknese which grades into samicemented basalt fragments, then into ba*alt rock. Th topography is nearly level to moderately sloping. Internal drainage is impeded by the hardp*n" (6, p. IS). The Agency series di! f.rs from th. Madras In having a heavier. textured subsoil and no hardpan, t)nis better internal drainage. (One or two farmers mentioned the appearance of some drainage prob lem on the Plains). i1t and sandy loam were the common textures found for the two series. The lighter texture combined with earns slope permitted earlier field work in th. spring of l91 (one reported that he had been leveling right through the winter). Metolius soil is of alluvia], origin and is found along drainage ways in the Mud Springs area, Practically none of it exists on the Elaine. Metolius sandy loam (the only texture mapped) is described as a "light brown light textured subsoil on permeable aatril (drainage fair)" (6, p. 16). Several farms on this soil 'were troubled with flooding in the spring of 19b9 and 19S0. Sinc, that time the drainag, way has been deepened and straightened and the trouble should be eliminated. Almost all Metolius soil (and only Mstolius soil) is ippd as being in land capability class I with no major restrictions on its use. It is possible, however, that dr sues some trouble. h of Powers (6, these soils as follows foot )Letoliug sandy loam Madras sandy loam Agency loam 1.9 inches 1.6 inches 1.5 inches foot 1.6 inches 3.9 inches Third foot 1.7 inches The infiltration rate for Madras sin in about an hour and forty ainntern. Compared to the texture, loam is listed as having a slightly greater limit, and a longr length of run. It can take slightly more w*ter per application and thus requires less frequent irrigation. corrugation method of irrigation, which Ii in general use, requires however, a considerably slower rate of application on the loam then on th sandy loam coil. These comparisons are according to approximate" irrigation practices and methods given bi Powers (6, p. h6). is too early to draw any conclusione regarding th, influence aoila on land use but it is evident that come differences wiU show u in time. land Capabiltt, Classification The Soil Conservation Service (6, p. 232) has est up eight land capability classes "based on physical characteristic, of the landecu, slope, erosion.. .In this classification, irrigation is 16 assumed feaib].,... ,Claseiftc*tion not based on land productivity. "Class It Very good land with little or no limitation in Use. It is nearly level, deep and without appreciable erosion, Some of it may need ,nditioning treatment, such as clearing, leveling, or minor drainage improvement, "Class Iii Good land with minor phyeical limitations, such as gentle slopes or slight erosion. Choice in use. is reduced or special practices are needed, such as careful water management, contour operations, cover c1'oppinP, or longer rotations. s,class III: Moderately good land 'with major physical limitations, such as relatively steep slopes, shallow soils or severe eroRiob. Choice in use is further reduced and more protective measures are required, such as terracing, strip cropping, and very careful water management. "Class IV: Fairly good land that is beet suited to pasture and hey but may be used occasionally for a culti.vated crop.-'.'in 1 to 6 years. Has major limitations such as very sandy soils or unfavorable climatic conditions, When plowed, erosion revention measures must be used carefully." The four remaining classoa of land are not suitable for oulti.vation and will not be described hers. Since water supply was limited, water rights were given only to the better lands which includes mainly c&pability classes I and IX and some Ill. Table 3 indicates the relative frequency of these three classes he irrigable acreage of the sample farms (b, p. 10), and Table 1 shows their distribution in the entire study area (6, p 28). Classes I, II, and III ar, important in the Springs; class II is important on the Plains. The differences exhibited in these two tables between the sample farms and tb whole area are due partly to ehoics.-d.liberate - Table 3. RENTAGE OF 62 SLMP Capability class GABLE LAND BY IAN!) CAPABILITY CLASS R NOIHUIITBcHUT 114 All farns Mad Springs (62 faras) (20 farms) 07 ?lai (142 t Percent trace 140 33 6 99 27 Tot*l Table 14. 00 PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION 07 IAN!) CAPABILITY CIASS III IN THE SAMPLE AREA NORTH UNIT DCHUT Capability class Both areas acres 0 Mud Springs bacree Percent Percent Percent 7 0 3. 63 22 83 III Total I I, 16 100 (6, table 5, p. 28). selection of class I 1andssnd partly to the fact that Table 3 3i.sl* only the irrigable land Table l lists all class I, II, and III land. Some capability class III land was not considered irrigable under the Bureau' a olasification. Bureau of Reclamation Irrigability Classification tton was madi prior to project construction an was revised after construction. In addition to separating the irrigable frou the nonirrigable land, it sets up different grades of iz'rigable land. On this project only two classes of land were designated 'irrigable .1 The definition of the irrigability classes fol].owsi Class I The best land in the project, nearly levl (o. 14.0 percent slopi), moderately deep (214 inches or over). The same as class 1 land except that it may have up to a 6 percent elope. Class 3 Shallower (20 - 214 inches), steeper slope (up to 10 percent), while it i generally considered irrigsb].e, on this project no water is guaranted for class 3 land. Class 6 - Nonarable, shallow, rocky, steep. Classes 1 and 2 nonirrigable are the seas a. 1 and 2 irrigabl. ezospt that they are too high for irrigation by gravity metheds. rigability classes are the bases for *raisal values for the purchase of the land and for repa7ment of project construction charges, 4ppratsal prices, based on dry l*nd values on this proj.ct, were as followsi struction charges have been assess 1 should be n pr , on land re the same In all cept Is set, class I and class 2 ope and moothnees. TION ON 63 8AMPL ?&R, II DO1UTE5 lI Sprin ia farmi 63 firma 2169 srss 8do acres 871 acreS Percent of farm Irrigable 83 Glass 1 66 lii 72 214 ii o4 Reclamation Irrigability Classification s, October, 191.i9. ition of land on th sample farms according to the Bureau' a irrigability classification. Class 2 land is of more frequent occurrence in the Sprin area th&n on tbe Plains, 1atnining only the 31 omnsr-operated farms, the difference 2 Igability class 2 land per farm between Mud Spr Acre Plaths in 19O was as follows i enoy Plains Mud Springs 2( farn) (11 farms irrigable acres per farm 7 acres Class 2 acres per farm 20 sores Class 2 as percent of irrigable 27 percent 102 acres Ths fact that owner-operated farms in the Sprin 13 acres 12 percent 'were on the 27 acres smal]ar than on the Plains and had more class 2 land, led to thø expectation that farms 'with c2ae.a 2 land would be a11er then fsrma with wholly e3au 3. lands. This was trite of the 9 farms having 70 to 100 percent class 2 land. They averaged 100 irrigable acres compared to lllj for the entire 63 farms. However, only I of these 9 farms were in Mud Springs. Th* 1 farms with percent or more class 2 land, or the 22 farms with 2 percent or more class 2 land, when compared to the reixzing farms are the same average use, 110 irrigated sores1 (Table 7 shows farm sisee 1, (uitting, in this average only, farm no. 8 which has 2? percent claus 2 land and l02 irrigated acres and seriously weighted any average in which it was included. land Deve1osent If there is price competition in the purchase of land we expect a purchaser to consider not only th. productivity of the land but also the comparative cost of developing it and of operating it after it is developed, Reclamation laws and the Bureau's contract with the irrigation district sought to curtail price competition and speculation in project lands, Maximum prices were set on land cla*ees according to their dry land value and penalties were inoiudsd to prevent higher prices being paid, Ths actual purchaser, however, )*s ot always agreed exactly with these values nor with the relative difference in value between various land classes, The owners of class 2 lands apparently regarded thea nor. highly those who set the appraised prices. These prices were U nt less for farms on class 2 land than for farms en dais 1 Purchasers paid practically the same price on each for farms Ing 109 irrigable acrsss praised price 36 farms on class 1 land 15 fares on class 2 land difference $2,690 2,39 $ Price pa: $3,20S 3,180 295 25 land on Agency Plains was considered to be more desirab land in Mud Springs. The new owners bought it two years before they began to fare it, and it was bought, on the average, a year and a half earlier than the land in Mud Springs. A comparison of the length of ties which land owners on Agency P1ais and in Mud 3pringe hays owned and operated their lend up to January 1, l9l is as follows: 16 Owners Mud Springs 32 Owners Agency Plains 10 monthi 28 months Owned Operated 8 months 3 months Difference Appraised prices for land on I quite eimi1r, however, purchasers paid about *6 more pe acre for land on the Plain Appraised pric. Prics: 20 Owners, Agency Plains U Owners, Mud Springs $2 $$ per acre per acre $35 per acre per acre Difference $ 0 per acre $6 per acre Owner operators on ths Plains had; net worth at start of 60 percent greater than owner operators in Mud Springs. Apparently thoø who could afford it bought lend on Agency R1a.ins. caste Only about 60 psrosnt of the leveling work was hired. Costa ranged from *7 per' hour for a small "cat" on a scraper to $114 per hour for a "cat" and l2'-1 yard carryall. It was difficult to get accurate costs on land leveling done by the operators themselves; a wide variety of tractors and dirt moving equipment were used and many operators had only a general idea of how much time they had spent at this job. Unless more specific information was available this work was valued at $3J0 an hour and a hO-hour week was 23 asauiied. This was taicen to ixxlw1e operating costs at labor at $1 and depreciation at i3. per hour of operation. A conparison of leveling costs by land class is shown in Table Contraxr to expectations1 farms with class 1 land have had higher ng costs than those on dais 2 land. Thiø could be due to able IVELING COSTS }T1R ItRIGATiD ACRE BY iBFtIOA}3ILITY ClASSES NOTH UNIr 63 FA?JI scnTjrrs l9O Percent class 2 Range i6lOO Levelin cost, dollars er acre No. of farms Average red Own rork Total $9 69 26 12 17 28 0 36 8 27 several possible reasons. (a) Class 1 lands :wy need more leveling in order to make theri really levol thilc class 2 lands are irrigated the contour and thus require less leveling, (b) It m 1. In an earlier study on the southern half of projects Van Mi*le (13, p. 22), Lowid leveling costs to be higher on the poorer land. Leveling costs per irrigated acres by class of 1*4 were given as follows a Class I-fl0.8, Class II-.$13, Class III42l.18 and averaged l6.b2. This included land clearing operations which, however, were slight. Another 2,2O was spent on the "irrigation systn" including "ditching, pipe, fluuee, check boxes and other irrigatlon structures" brin the total land developnént cost found in the earlier study to 16,62 per irrigated acre. $220 $156 27 250 181 28 2i5 161 22 170 23 2 Class Total of rcent 11J4 136 109 22 $ acre irrigated per Dollars incoae ment p thvest. Total C-ross 109 0 75 far* per Acres 15 farms Al]. 2 and Claes 2 Class Unit c1&s Leveling Irrigated Irrigable 2 Class Faznis Irrigability l0 DLCHUT1 UNIT }ORTH CL&SSF IEIUGABILITY 131 COST8 LEVELING AND INCOME, INVESTM}NT, IZE, 7. Table significantly cheaper for an operator to do his own leveling than for him to hire it done. (c) Hired leveling may be significantly better than the work that the operator doea for himself. (d) Per- haps costs which we have assigned to the operator' a own work are too ice (they would have to be doubled, however, before total costs would be equal in the two groups). (.) Possibly the group of 15 farms is not large enough to truly represent costs on class 2 lands. The two groups of farms average just about the same development period, class 1, 29 monthsj class 2, 28 months. Table 7 compares the groups as to size, investment, and income both in acres and as a percent of the total size, investment, and income on all farms. There is a greater percentage variation in leveling costs than in any of the other measures compared0 Income per dollar of invest- ment in the two groups is comparable at 71 cents and 72 cents. (An interesting difference between class 1 land and cl*s 2 land is that 67 percent of class 2 land is owner-operated while only 56 percent of class I land is owner-operated). It is blieved that, while the amount of the difference in leveling costs may not be exact, the direction of the difference ii reasonably certain at this time. Aa these farms become completely developed, however, this diffrsnce in total leveling colts y change. In comparing leveling costs beb rr-operatore on the Plains and in Mud Springs neither the amount nor direction of the unit. acr, 95 a on $2250 or acre irrigable per $25 averaged farms sampl. the on land for prices Appraised refinancing. and purchase land for necessary sa $2250 estimated .TLA, acre per what approximately 7 is (which consider were they labo own farmers' the for allowance no includes This prices. l919 at unit farm famtly typical a for $3510 require will irrigation and treainent land acre per impr. Own HirIU Total acre per coat Iaeling Aliland farms of No. 1950 DCHUTE5 UNIT NORTH PIAI) AGENCY AZi) SPRIUC Mtll) MS l9O I1IGATFJ) ACRE PER O1ER-0PER&T!D 31 work. own a operator' th. to attributed values the upon extent certain & to depends however, differences, the of anunt the as well as direction The charged. was depreciation when Springs ud in higher slightly were coats leveling thst shows 8 T&ble areas. both in acre per $30 was irproveinents land acre per 22 at $ operator' Before same the were area each in all of cot value the and leveling work, own the of coat the into calculated were charges depreciation certainty. reasonable with ascertained be could difference 26 favorably with the 3L per acre for all land iw&pro' ts Tibia 8 considering the changing price level and the fact .ts are not, as yet, complete Irrigation of 'Nontrx'igable' Lands Twenty-one finns irrigated * total o acres more thin their rights specified in l90; another 21 fauna :ated 260 acres I.e. than their water right; the ree*ining 21 finns irrigat.d within or We of their full irrigabi, acreage. This difference bet*sen irrigated acres and irrigable acres is closely associated with class 2 land. On the whole, farmers with class 2 land irrigated 10 acres more than their irrigable acreage while those with only class 1 lands irrigated 122 acres less than irrigable acreage. Some of the farmers with class 2 lands, of uris, irrigated less than their irrigable acreage and some of those with no class 2 land irrigatd mere thin their irrigable acreage. It 2 75 The 12 a nbered that the 12 farms averaging 36 acres of ( as Table 7) were not comparable with the farms aver- of class 2 nor with those having only class I. land. larger fauna. They irrigated o average, seven for which thy held no water right. Their income per 1 but their in compared to 70 cents per doUar of investment we low (66 cents all C srms irrigating a total of $ a Based on l919 calculations, about 250 acres on the 63 farms class I or 2 land which the bureau of ec1smation considered to be too high for gravity irrigation metiods, and which were given no water right. This "nonirrigable" land occurred on only 2]. of the 63 sample farms and ua, on the average, nearly 12 acres per term. Quite frequently it was in hummocks which could be leveled and spread over low spots, thus permitting irrigation. (One farmer irrigated 25 acres of clase 1 and 2 nonirrigable land with a sprinkler system and without major leveling). Class 3 land on the project was usually irrigable by gravity due to the limitation of the water supply it wee not given a water right. Ths eight operators in th. study with c]ass 3 land had, on the average, 28 acres of it per farm. lass 1, 2, and 3 nonirrigable lands, however, accounted for only slightly more f th. extra acres irrigated by the farmers on class 2 i's 110 acres of thIs hatter 1nonirrlgabl&' land ted while 95 crea of class 6 lands wsr also irrigated. vii bi remembered that el*aa 6 lands were described as It nonarable, hallow, rocky and steep (see page 18). Irrigating extra acres was more important on farms with over irrigable acres than on farms with lees than that arnmt. There were two operators, however, with an average of 38 irrigabls acres, rho irrigated 6J acres saab in 1950. Their water rights were increasto 55 acres in 1951 which was still nine acres less than the 0. &noth.r operator pith 77 irrigabi. acres was irriga d in rigating 130 acres and was trying to get his water right increased. like37 that the operators of small farms, especially, will seek to increase their irrigable acreage by irrl.gat irrigableN land. Nany farrs will, at relatively great expense, improve small areas of nonirrigable land that complicates their ield work. Water Supp] , of course, is a factor in water uee Tater holding capacity, elope, permeability and texture are important variables in irrigation practices. Water is undoubtedly a factor in land use between irrigated end dry land farms. Even on irrigated farms, water is an important variable factor, depending upon its availability, quality, and cost. Water Delivery later d.liver on the North Unit is on an order basis, Th Dsschutes River is the source of water. Storage is in Wiokiup Reservoir 16 miles southsast of Bend. Diversion is made Into the North Unit )In 'nal just north of the Bend city limits The rrigation District offic. and the boll Reclamation office are ted at the sir base just north of Nadras and 16 miles north of water, little relatively require Grains grown. crops of type the with water' of 'duty or requirement ion Irriga amount. less use of ue would otherwise who farmer a by minimum the encourage would this consideration worth was that than to up water watr rpm. on premium the If allotment. minimum his ueed ha he until r eurp for eligible not was farmer A tranuctioi the in part his for premium some demend cou3d therefore, seller, The another. to farmer one from allowance water surplus of transfer the p.rmitted for $2.O two us This district The District. Irrigation the by sold limit he acre. irrigabi. per sore-foot one to up acr-foot * at that above available was water Surplus aore.feet, project the on acre irrigable per cost water was ooneequencc. a as luffered crop their and water for wait to had operators several l9O, July, in spell & not is This order. hot sudden a during but occurrence con their of priority the it on rely must users wat.z' deliver, to canals the of capacity the beyond order on is water When required. is before days three or two user water the by ordered be must Water Bureau. the of ice off Bend the with contact radio has turn in which office local the with radio by contact In are riders Ditch 31. legumes considerable and row crops only moderate applications of waters Among other things, $ farmer must bl*nee the acreage of these crops with the amount of water which he ia obtain. The weighted duty of water is computed by rniltiplying the depth of water required for each crop during the season by the percentage of the irrigated acreage in such a crop and adding the results, POwers (6, p. 15) offers as an examples 65 percent in slZalt!a x 36 inch duty 25 percent in grain z 12 inch duty 10 percent in row crops x 2I Inch duty Weighted duty of water per irrigated acre 23.I inches 3.0 inchea 2.lj inches - 28.8 nahi. When water is in abundant supply and free, then, according to elementary economic thee it is used to th. point where its margi.- mel return is zero, When water is abundant and has coat it will theoretically be used to the point where its marginal return is equal to its merginal cost, When the unit cost of water decreases as the quantity used increases, lavish use is encouraged. When uni cost increases as the quantity need increases, more careful use is encouraged. This latter is the noswal situation for the project. When the water supply Is limited, not by pric, but by decr'ee, wa mey not be used to its beet economic advantage. All these theoretical suppositions have practical application he water supply on the irrigation project. Two or three farms byond the end of the project ar, using eat waste water to irrigate non'.projeat lands at no coat for delivery. U*ny farmers on the project also are able to use fsee waste water. 32 the firs yea of irrigation, farmers were charged only for the actual amount of water delivered, With only a portion of their land irrigated this often meant less than the minimum 'rater charge. The second year all farms were assessed the minimum water charge. The charge for the second year was $2.50 per irrigabl acre hether or not they used the water, This encouragod the use of water up to the minimum since it cost no 'nore. Th final supposition of a supply of water not liiit.d by price but by decree has not yet occurred. In a dry year it is possible that the total water supply would be i c rore than enough to supply the 50,000 'irrigable' acres with 2 acre feet per irrigeble acre. This is the riinimum amount which the darn was constructed to rrovide. The number of sample fares using various rates of water in 19b9 and 1950 according to Bureau of Reclamation figures was as foflowss tcreu.feet per iz'rigabl. acre 0.1 - 1.0 Li - 2.0 2.1 - 3.0 34 el 5.0 1919 1950 1 21 27 7 0 8 38 15 1 59 63 t of water used has definit, economic Implica some doubt, however, whether th Dursau' a figures on official water use per irrigable acr, 'ill he sufficient to uncover these implications. On many- fares, as we have seen, the irrigated 33 icr.age is not too olo8aly related to irrigable acreage. A further qualification is that a significant number of ?Pator5 lave waste available for irrigation in amounts unknown to us. problem deserves further coneidsrstion. Land Use Practicafl aLl of the irrigated land on the study farms was producing winter wheat prior to irrigation development. Several of operators came to the area a year or two before irrigation was due and carried on dry farming, meanwhile developing their farms fo irrigation, They leased lands from other new owners who were not yet ready to operate their farms. These farmers were in a ?osition to raise an irrigated crop in 19146 when water first became available on the Plains, Gross in from irrigated crops averaged $14, 2SO for he eight farmers who irrigated crop in i9I8. the land was sold with the provis owner would retain possession until irrigation wat the original e available. n water became availabla in the suer of 19148 the new owners could not take over th. fern until after the crop of winter wheat bad bean harvested. By then it was too late to get the land leveled and crop raised. The main aim of these farmers then, was to get a crop ladino, alfalfa or red olover established, Sixteen such operators able to get some of their land irrigated .n 19148 but received no irrigated crop average of 1 Altogether 214 farmers on the Plains got an percent of their irrigable land irrigated in 19148, Eighteen of the Plains farmers took possession of their land too late to get any of it leveled and irrigated in 19148. No water was available for irrigation in the Mud Springs area until the spring of 19149 but all operators irrigated some land that yeai 35 Table 9. IA1 US B! LOCATION AN!) IRRIGABILIT! CMSSI?ICATION 63 FAJOH UNT D1CHt1T1, 19Q Class 1 Class 2 Class 1&2 Agency Number o' tarns Plain. llud Springs 142 Percent class 2 69% 26% (acree per' fa Crops Ladino 145 Rd cloyar 56 146 58 114 20 11 A]!alfa 18 20 15 Pesture 2 2 5 3 1 Fieldp.as 6 14 14 7 Potatoes S 0 15 20 15 18 105 lU I!t3 320 Grain Total irrigated acres 58 6 Gross irrigated crop income Per farm 19,095 $17,330 *22,950 *21,130 $114,770 156$ 160$ 1145 6 lye percent of the. irrigable land on the study fazms was in 19ti9 and about 96 percent in 1950. The actua irrigated in 1950 was slightly more than the total irrigabis creage It will be remembered that about 3.5 percent of the land irrigated in 1950 was classed wnonirrigableW by the Bureau. Table 9 (p 35) shows land use in 1950 in the o areas end also according to the differert land classes. Table 10 (p. 37) compares land use, crop income and approximate prices received in l99 and Land use has been complicated by unusual prices and price 1950. changes. It became apparent 'when the area was first developed in 19b6 that it was adapted to the production of clover seeds. Alaike, ladino and red clover were all grown in the southern part of the project By the time the northern half of the project was developed it was evident that a]aike could not compete with the other two crops because of its lower price. area There is no a3aik. grown in the studied. The price for £en].and red clover seed was good in 19I8 and l9I9 but fell to less than halt in 1950. Thus in the Mud Springs area, which was developed only s1ight2y later than Agency Plains, there is a larger proportion of ]adino and a mealier propor' tion of red clover than on the Plains. The ladino seed price was supported at $1.25 per pound in 1950. Gross income per acre of 2adino was 275 compared to $108 per acre for red clover on which the support price was L3 cents p.r pound. Most cl the seed was sold at a few cents above support price. Table 10. LARD USE ANI) GROSS CROP fl4003LE - 19149 ANT) 395() 6 F443 NORTH UNiT DCHUT Crop acres per farI!a I149 i95O Gross crop income per farm Gross crop Income Approximat. price received per acre 19149 1950 19149 1950 50 $2,037 $13,782 $211 *275 1'149 1950 1.30 $ 1.27 Crops tadino 10 $ Red clover 5 17 367 1,8142 78 108 3.00 0.145 Alfalfa 5 18 233 148 71 25.00 2o.00 Pasture 2 3 - 1,310 Field pas 14 5 219 1402 146 77 .05 Potatoes 3 14 1,202 1,090 332 269 1.50 1.00 Grain* 65 16 2,14145 835 38 51 1.95 2.00 Other * 1 21. 1149 So 3149 Total irrigated 914 1314 *6,5214 19,h10 $ 70 $3.70 irrigable acres 110 1114 se than 0.5 acre .0145 Weather conditions seriously interfered with the clover harvest 950. SoRi rain is nornal for the area in the fall but in 1950 s earlier and of greater duration than could reasonably have e7pected, The harvest was not yet coirpleted 1i the area in March, 1951. came. I3arvesting continued at reat expense after the mine Many farmers invested in crop driers and combines that they could not afford to own and yet could rot afford not to own under the circumstances. Yield. of clover were only 1I*1.t as great after the ..t spell began. Thus, gross crop income does not give biolute evaluation of land use in that year nor is it a safe mdiastor of net farm income. Gross crop income per farm is, however, fairly closely related to th. acreage of ladino per farm since ladino seed contributed 70 percent of this income. The effect of the wet fal.1 wee felt more keenly in the Mud Springs area than on Agency Plains lThile Mud Springs farms had 25 percent mere ].adino acreage they had bS percent less gross crop income per farm (see Tible 9). Thie is due partly to the nal1ar inv.etesnt per acre in sachineir and equipment on Mud Springs farms. Harvest on the Plains was more complete when the wet weather started). However, the deeper eo Mud Spring. which refused to dry out and stop clover growth- were also a factor. This would account for the equally poor harvest reported on the farms south of Madrae which were located on .t1. similar to those in Mud Springs. continued the late r and ids it harvest the seed even when the weather iras fair. These farms had been in op on a year or two longer than those in Mud Springs arid should have been better equipped for the emergency. An early, deep frost, occurring before the potato harvest was completed in 191&9, damaged * considerable portion of the potatoes In the study area in that year. Many of the potatoes failed to mak. grade and later brok. down in storage In l90, of course, it was th, pric, which was damaging. There were 2 acres of potatoes on the sample farms in 19S0, about iS percent mor then in 19149. Gross income on potatoes, in 1950, was only 80 percent of the 19I9 Income while harvesting and marketing costs were higher. To dat, potatoes have contrIbuted very little to farm dvslopment on the farms studied. While the prospects for the coming year are uncertain, potatoes appear to have a definite place in land use on the project. Alfalfa, too, has been disappointing. Yields have not been high and. some farmers plowed up their alfalfa in 1950. The 1950 was damaged by summer rains and ire of poor quality. Alfalfa bee littl. chance of competing successfully with ladino clover under present conditions. Its importance will increase as livestock duction increases on the project. To d*ts, however, surplus potatoes and clover chaff havø been abundant and have furnished mere of the livestock feed in the area. Cracked grain from volunteer growth in the clover has also been a good feed source. Livestock on most farms has been limited to a cow and chickens The abundance of fe.deble wast.e and the current high 10 prices have been an Incentive for thos with sufficient capital for livestock f.ding operations. 'ost operators, however, require all of thir investment 'or squipnent and ioprevemsnte. There is also * probl.m of water eupp]y for livestock during the winter. There is on. grade A dairy and there are teo creamery prodac.ra area being studied. Lack of buildings and poor market deterents to daizying. In addition, higher incomes can be realised from clover seed production. When th. project was first conceived, dairying was expected to play an Important part in ite success. It may yet do so. Indications so far are Inconclusive dairy development will be naturallr slow consid.ring the amoun investment required and the lack of maz*.ting facilities at present, ii FARM ORGANX7ATION organization refers to the manner or factors of in 'which farm production are combined or organized by the farmer into a producti'e unit. The settler on a new irrigation proeet gener. fly has united capital resources1, He must organize his resources to bring his farm into production as to pay current living expenses quickly as possible in order and production costs. To do this he must acquire the use of additional resources through renting, sharing, or borrowing. The problem of farm organization for the new settler is one of the amount of total resources, the way th.y are *it to use, and their ownership. Amount of Resources the farm records ar sorted on die of income (Table U), income is seen to be associated with investment, with irrigated acreage and with the acreage of ladino per farm. ship was shown when farms were groupd by and by size of investment. au. A similar relation in irrigated acres The question arises, important is each of these to total incone, at this early stage of deeloent Farmers Home Administration (9, p.3) .stimat.d that $2,000 was necessary to develop a family sized farm on the North Unit. H&lf of the operators of the farms studied began operations with a net worth of less than $10,000. Thtal lnveejaent Tnccmie per doflnr of tots]. investient varied widely between individual farms It appeared to be higher on fans with higher incoiw (Table 12). ifowever, when farnw were placed in broad groups according to the size of their investment (Table 13) inc.one per dollar of total investment was consistent]y close to O.70 as the foUoLng tabulation shows, Averac total inveetcnt per fann per acre $ 23 22,S00 Average Incone per dollar of inveatmnen 0.66 000 207 203 0.73 2?,00 2L2 $0.70 (In ccmiparing fanne on clasa I and class 2 laM the sane conBia toncy was noticed. Income was O.72 and O,7l per dollar of investment respective3y, It would appear fran this that while total inccine is rather closely related to total investanen the relative amounts of capita]. used had little relationship to Its efficiency. Investment roduced the same relative amount of gross income 'whether used in large or small amounts. There is pezthaps a hint that it is more efficient The 19 fai,s in this group had percent of the tccbal investment on all farms in the stixty and about the same proportion of gross crop income. Tsbl. 11. COME COMPARED TO FARM SUIC, INV1ENT AND IADINO ACRZAGE 63 FAR1. NORTH UNIT DC1!UTF, 1950 Gross crop incom Average p014 Investeent per farm Acres per farm Number of Total land and Irrigated farm farms $58,000 6 $60,000 $38,000 $7 $IO,OoO 35,000 7 140,000 22,000 139 20- $30,000 214,000 12 29,000 19,000 128 48 0- 20,000 15,000 17 23,000 13,000 99 37 0- 10,O00 5,000 21,000 12,000 Rang. Over $bO,OOO 30- *41 Four part-time and three first year equipment Table 32 Gross GROSS CROP INCOME PER ACRE Art) INCOME PER DOIJAR OF ThVESTMENT COM?M(1) NORTi UNIT PESCHU, 1y50 C Wuntber come Average of Gross crop thoome per irrigated per fara farms acre Over $140,000 $58,000 6. $227 $3o- $140,000 35,000 $20- $30,000 214,00 $10- $2o,ocO 15,000 $ 0- $10,000 5,000 o45,000 AU farms per acre Inccrne per dollar of investnent Total land and equipment $4D .97 250 160 o.88 1.57 12 188 151 o.814 1.214 17 153 135 o.66 66 157 0,25 $1148 $0.73 $119 0.28 56* Average* Land and equipment investment $ir 2,000 7 32 US o.i5 $19,000 63 $170 $1147 $0.70 aras in second year of irrigation. Tabi. 13. cAPITAL R0UR 01 FA ota 6-1& 000 berof farms fa: al irvestment d and equipment investment operator's equity, November, 19S0 net worth at start others ahare total loans owed November, 1950, 1950 gross crop income 19149 gross crop im the of de'velopmen irrigeble a IT DCHU vestment per arm l8 0 000 0'ir 30 000 20 $13,000 19 $22,500 All f 63 3.5,000 $149,000 2fl, 000 *27,500 16,500 $ 7,500 6,000 $13,000 8,Soo $33,500 19,500 *17,500 11,000 1,500 $ 3,500 $ 6,50o 3,500 $ 6,500 8, Soc $13,000 14,000 6, Son $20,500 9,000 $13,000 6,500 $ 9,500 2,000 $16, Soc 14*000 $33,Sno son $19,500 6,500 207 135 285 163 8 113 $ a total investment land and equipment investment net worth at start 1950 gross crop income Income per dollar total investment Income per dollar land and equipment investment Percent of investment in land and eqiips 1.12 97 151 $ 196 0,73 1.12 $ 0.68 1.20 $ 0.70 57% 61% 65% 116 146 when used in medium amounts but at present this can be considered a. no more tban suggestive, Total gross income, i related rather closeir to total investment, Land and uzent Investment vestment in land and equipment an being clone to th. actual productive investment per farm * e far an crop production is concerned, This avoids th. problem of differing wkotmte invested in homes, care, and livestock1 which are net so closely related to producing crop income. Land end equipment investment averaged 61 percent of total investment, In comparing land and equipment mi ment with income in Table 13 there appears to be a correlation betwen investment in land and equipment per acre and income per acre. Total investment per farm J49,000 Lind and equipment Investment per acre Income per dollar of land and equipment Income investnt per sex'. *196 151 22,5oo 13 000 $163 135 129 $1.20 1.12 Average $27,500 $1147 $1.16 142 1145 p170 1. While livestock is an important source of Income on eertain farms it is not important enough in the whole study to warrant individual treatment at present, $0.73. reaches only investment equipment and land of dollar per income while $137 at law still is acre iricoii removed, are they When tenant. the under yeer first small one and farms pert-time 2 contains group This p.r its tr farr increasa. investment as increase does the in Efficiency risee. acre per investment as decrease) even (*od increase to Efficiency acre. per income appear not does capital of use and acre per investment t a quite be to seems there acre. per efficiency capital greater f between relationship definite aberration, one from Apart moderate in invested i. it when a perhaps, again, is There equipment Income investment acre per 116 137 161 188 $218 1.22 o.68 $1.08 1.140 162 191 196 1281 $23 81 1.08 87 $1147 $1.16 l7O i.bo Average $100 Under 1214 ]J49 iy1 :i. $100.- $12.- $)So- $l7- $200 Over range average acre per investment and land of dollar per Income equipment and Land investment. of dollar per income and acre per investment between observed be can correlation definite no acre per equipment and land in investment their to according grouped are farms when r, acre. per investment smaller thosswi' than capital this had acre per equipment and land use the in lency investment higher the that appear would ttb it this in From 17 148 d invested EL&,730 in land and equipment. What income could it have produced if the aet of relationships between investment per acre and income per cc noted in the foregoing tabulation, held true under other conditions? Income per dollar of investment $1.08 .68 1.22 $218 188 77 89 $18,068 11,376 2o,110 1.08 161 137 116 81 !97 18o68 $1.16 $1147 13)4 $19,1400 1.140 1.140 Average Land and equipa.nt 5iae of farm Gross crop investment per acre acres income 1014 122 11414 23,1422 23,1422 For instance, at an income per dollar of investment of $1.16, $16,730 invested at the rate of $1147 per acre on 1114 acres produced a gross crop income o *19,1400. Thie wee the average for all farms. At an income per dollar of investment of $1.14o, *16,73 st.ed at the rate of $137 p.r acr, on 122 acres would suppoiedly produce a gross crop income of 123,1422. It would. appear that the average operator could have produced a larger gross income by spreading his capital over more acres than he has dons, Thi. is an interesting and entirely possible relationship. Our data, however, do not warrant any definite conclusions being drawn from them. It is likely that on some of the analler acresges, (below 60 acres) capital cannot bø used as efficiently as on larger acreage.. 149 is even possible that on somerhit lax acreagss (around 80 as) capital investment in some equipment I.e greater than the farm can efficiently use. Most farms have * combine aM many- have two tractors. Thse are considered to be necessities bit their capacity is greater than can be efficiently used on a small acreage. From the operator's point of view than, a larger acreage would be advisable, Thus far in this diecuagion we have been ignoring the fact that the Bureau of Reclamation has invested about $200 of reimbursable public funds per acre of irrigable land. After the first of farm development the settler will become fully aware o: extent of this investment whi he beins to repay it. If we consider the Reclamation investment at 200 per acre *bov the operator'. investment the following relationship results. Investment per acre come per dollar of investment Income per acre $23 $1418 388 361 337 316 281 Average $3147 0.33 O7 0. 1 128 I6 192. 0.31 162 87 0.149 $170 Viewing the total social investment, capital efficiency is not noticeably diminished as investment per acrS increases. Land sffi- ciency is greatly increased. By limiting the farm acreage, society would appear to gain to the extent that the limitation increases investment per con. Nevertheless, en individual farmer, at least i ue short run, gains by increasing his a oreage and preading his investmerkt over a greater acreage up to a practical ti.1t depending upon available capital. Again it must be emphasised that p&'t of the foregoing reasoning rests upon supposition and furthermore, that the figures which are given are merely the product of research on the first two years of farm development. The fact remains that certain farmers have mad. unusually larg. incomes with large resources ome or both of these years. This is not only the result of the system oi land reclA1tion. It is also the result of an unusual adaptation of a crop to a mew area at a critical time, both in the development of this projeot and of that crop, The results are partly, at least, fortuitous and may not be expected to continue indefinitely nor to necessarily recur on futur. reclamation projects. ladino Acreage ii. ladime clover accounted for 70 percent of gross crop income in 1950 on the farms studied, me definite correlation could be found between acreage of ladino and income. Ladino was grown universally and the proportion of ladino acreage to total irrigated acreage was practically constant in most groupiflga of farms. The poor harvest helped to disrupt any poaible oo: ion b rsdw on the large acreages that took longez to haryest. The operator with elatively small acreage often finished harvesting before the bad r set in. The acreage of 3adino, however, may be regarded as important to th. size of farm income since income per acre of ladino was ignificantly greater than that of other crops grown on the pro jeot (Table 10). Table iL ETBt&TEI) C&PITAL R!UI USED ON NORTH UNIT DCHUT! AND ACTUAL C&PITAL PROJECT 1950 1950 actual 31 owner 19Li9 ?.H.A. 1950 operated actual ktiaat.d farms 63 farms Land acquisition and do,.].ome Land purchase and refinancing Basic land tz.staent and irrigation Pare dwelling Other building. and finoss Farmetead water $ 2,250 $ 2,3003 $ 2,80O 3,500 3,510 2,800 5,000 5,000 5,000 1,850 1,700 Li3O00 1,200 Lie 350 $12, 20 $13,500 TOTAL quipmsnt and livest ry and .quipaent Aitosobil. and/or truck 6,000 1,000 Home equipment 1,500 Livestock 900 1,Li0O -. 1,60 - 25210 *2Li.100 $27050 Total required investment $ 7,000 $11,550 tU,000 Nit worth at s land a 10,500 1,5002 9,250 *11,900 *13,550 TOTAL Loans 750 9,500 n and developmint Equipmen $ 6,087 $ 1,250 $ 3,300 Li,2?8 6,5o Operating home and farm 2,600 6,oSo 3,150 6,700 $16,915 $12,800 $13,150 TOTAL LOANS Farmers Home Administration, Credit needs in the Columbia River drainage area 1950 through 1955 (9, p. 3). Automobile on]y. 3. Appraised price. 53 f at some length in the previous eøction. It will be sufficient he to point ant that the use of resources differs according to the ire of those resources. Ths proportion of total inveetaent going p production decreased as the amount of total investment increased (Table 13). ?ot&l inyestment per fari 000 22,500 1300O Aver $27,500 per acre $28 207 f total invoatnent in land and equipment 57% 65% 20) $2I2 6: Thie is natural. When his capital is limited, a farm operator eseks to invest it in crop production where it will bring quii returns. When he has an abundance of capital the operator will invest it in buildings and livestock, which bring returns after a greater length of time, and in a home, automobile or other evidences of good living. The disposition of fare capital in its various meat mazy bt compared in Tables lh and 35 for the 31 fuU-.time owner-v operated farms and for sU the farms in the study. In Table 3J these also may be compared with Partners Homs Administration estimates of capital needs. It would appear from the latter comparison that farm investment is nearly- complete in many respects. Many farmers on the project today, however, are without adequate hones. Investment in homes, other buildings and livestock may be expected to increase considerably in coming years. Operators ol' the farms studi.d averaged 6 percent greater net Worth when starting than was expected in the Farmers Home Adininistra- tion estimate. It seems that the farmer, are also expecting a higher standard of living than the Farmers Home Administration estimate provided. Investment in automobiles already te above the astima whil, housing investment is squal to the estimated amount. Only half the expect.d period of development has passed. Table 17, how- ever, Ihows that many farmers ar, still below both the average and the ssttmatd amount of tnveatient. It wiU be remembered that 19 farms bad over half the tot*l investment on the 63 study farms and thus have * buoyant effect on the average. Table 15. INVTMENT PER ACRE AND PERC4T FOR ALL FARMS ANT) FOR GYNER.'OPERLTZO FARMS NORTH UNIT DCHUTES 1950 Percent of Investment total tnestinent per acre S 8 10 2 31 30 13 II 53 18 21 16 18 7 7 3 b Equipnent 91 101 Livestock 12 9 S Automobile 15 16 6 $ 25 Buildings - house Other buildinga later Total $21i2 Operator's equity $152 Irrigated acr.s 100 $181 63 9 6 nsre1dp of Resources d as to the re tion in n Tables 16, 17, and these tables, but an atteapt is being made to bring out differert relationships aocording to tenure, ownership, and operator' e starting net worth. Opertor' s Starting Net Worth Farm investment averaged about $27,500 per farm on the study farms. Operators owned about t0 percent of this amount when they started farm development on the project. In December, 1950, after about two and a half years of farm development, their equity was 63 percent of total farm investasent. Examination of Table 13 would seen to indicate that net worth was directly related to the increase in the operator' s equity in farm investment. Investment er farm Operators Net worth Percentage increase equity 195o1 at start2 Over $30,000 $33,500 in equity 13,000 $19,500 8,500 72% 53% $27,000 $17,500 $11,000 59% $18- 30,000 6- 18,000 7500 6000 Operators equity in 1950 wu the total farm inveitment lees th* amount of debts outstanding and the amount of other' s equity In land, equipment, and buildings. It does not include cash or bink balance. Net worth at start includes the value of land, equin nt, livestock, and cash aseets that the operator owned when he started farm develonent less the wnouiit of his debts at the start. M'D FARM 0P1'R&TO1 Number CMEARTi) B! TENURE 63 FAB N0ITh JNIT DEcCHUTF 1950 of farm onthe on farm 0erator' a age h at start p11,000 $ 7,500 $11,500 $ 5,500 $ 5,000 $25,500 Operators equity $ 9,000 $17,000 $1J,SOO $ 7,500 h1,00O Total investment $11,500 $2,0OO $26,000 $18,500 $61,500 $27,500 Lend and equipment $ 6,Soo $15,500 $17,000 $]3,000 $36,500 $17,000 Total loans 4 3,500 *l3000 $16,500 $ 8,Soo (wed November, 1950 $ 2,500 $ 7,000 $ 9,000 3,000 $22,000 $17,00ö p income $ 1,0 Table 17. NET WOIflil AT START COMPA'i:, TO SIZE, IVTMEtT AXJ) ThCOME NORTH UNIT DICHUT 1 Net worth at start Average per farm S Per Irrigable Numoer of acre farms $200 14 Irrigable acres per fare Total investment Operators 1950 1950 equity Gross crop income 1950 Oen.r-operatedfarms Over $18,000 $25,500 *37,000 22, 500 *12- 818, 000 15,500 161 16,500 15,Soo 6- 812,000 9,500 1214 13,500 11,000 6,000 3,500 145 U, 1},000 $11,000 $127 88 $23,500 $16, noc 000 149 102 18,500 7,500 17,000 $ All farms £11 owner. operators Renters 0wrer-rerter 5,5on 142 8 127 26,000 114,Sno large & share 25,500 110 8 229 61,500 141,000 00 ].7 500 All farms 811 C 827 Table 18. FA ThVT E, AS PEfICENT OF TOTAL INVTME};T, BY TENURE G:aU II UNIT 0 . CHUTPS 19O Itenters O.ner-rentere AU fartus Number of farms Total investment $23,00 Operator' s .quity ed AU loans as percent Starting net worth Increase in equity 28% $18,00 $26,000 141% % 17% 3% 146% 27,0O 63% 214 Those operators with *tor investment also had a larger net wwx-th at ths start and made greater gain, in their equtt farm invsetnsnt, both in term. of percentage. and in terms of dollari. When owner-operators were grouped according to th. net worth, however, the opposite affect was evident for all groups except the one with the largest starting net worth (Table 17). th at start Average Increase in equity Percentage equity of total investment Over $18,000 $2,o0 $12- 18,000 3$,Soo $ 6.. 12,000 9,0O 0- $ 6,000 )Soo $U,OO Ii3O00 88% 71% 68% Average $ ,oOo 69% $11,000 1,000 70O These groups had comparabl. periods of developeent. It app then, that the amount of his starting net worth did not nes.arily d.termine a farmer's progress. The fact that only fixed capital and no operating capital is considered under operator' a equity may leave oms doubt as to the ueefulneas of these figures. Confidence in the.. figures nay be increased by the fact that farm size, total farm invs.ta.nt and boi-row.d operating capital are quite comparable for own.r-operat.d farms in th. three lower groups of starting net worth. 6]. Net worth at start Over $18,000 Irrigabi. acres p.r fare Total investment jer farm Operating capital borrowed per fare $1i2, 000 5,000 $6- 12,000 127 96 77 8o 23,000 19, Sao 21.000 6, 00 00 ge 88 $23, Soo $, 00 $12- 18,000 o-$ 6,000 There i.e a possible .zplsnation for the apparent anomaly of the increase in operator' $ equity being greater where his starting net worth was lees. Operators with little net worth at start mey have had to rely more heavily upon their own labor in their farm invest.. ment (landleveling and building) and thus have earned their increase in .quity. Operators with a greater starting capital were rob.b]y more Inclined to hire work such as leveling and construction. This would not increas, their equity in the farm business, but would only transfer cash assets to fixed assets. Table 16 shows that the period of farm development and the increass in operator' equity were somewhat lees on rented fare. and somewhat more on part-owned farms than on the average owneroperat.d farm. Starting net worth, however, was low in both these tenure groups. Tenure and Tenancy !iftysight percent of the land on the study farms was owner operated. Forty-two percent wae partly in units which were wholly r.ntd and partly in rented tracts that were operated in conjunction with scm. owned land. Unite containing rented land were larger, the average, than thoes which were wholly ewnar-oparated. This could be xpected. Rented land must not only provide for the opera tor, but also must make some return to the landlord. A furbher reason is that an operator may not r.uelve water for more than 160 irrlgaJ3le acres in the ownership of one person or of a fiity including children under 18 year's old, (i3, esotion 30â, amsnded An operator is permitted to lease 3and in sxeeaa of 160 irrigabis acres provided 'that the terms and conditions of the Isase are rtie factory and in keeping with the purpose of the Federal R*clamatlon Laws, and that the operation under the lease would b. beneficial to the lands' (13, section 30B, amended). Operators of units over trrigab].e acres are required to have their cropping program approved by the county agent and by a local board. This must be done each year before the contract for water delivery may be signed. Six op.r*tors of the sample farms irrigated over' 160 acres in l90. One of these contained lees than 160 'irrigable' acres, th. operator irrigated about 2 acres of nonirrigabi. land. A number of these large operations were soma eort of partnership arrangement. Three of them were wholly rented and three were partly owned and partly rented. The large unite also had large investments and At lust five of them were generefly found in the top grouping wbsn farms were arranged en else, income, or investment. Large farms may be compared to other farms in certain aspects in Table 16. 63 tel procedure, among the sample farms iiake all improvements In th. land. No rent was due for years. Thi.. would permit the operator to have at least on. complete crop to pay for his leveling costs. Usually little crop income was produced the first year. Rentel shares to the owner in succeeding year. averaged one-third of the crop. A mimber of these leases contained purchase options. A veriety of other rental contracts were also used which ua amounts of th. landlord's investhent in improve- sent. and in crop production, (*i the tao share farms the landlord provided most of the investment and such of the operating expenses and took tmothfrds of the crop, Thee. farms had large investmentS and were not strictly comparable to any of th. major groups, least of all, perhaps to the rented farms. They were often grouped with large farms in the analysis which tended to sle dam the 3*rg There is some i on moat rented farms. Both renters and landlords are seeking an acceptable share lease for crop and livsstoak enterprise.. There were four part-tims owrn.zop.rstora among the sampl. farms On. operator had a full-time job oft the tarn. T others worked at construction mtenever possible. The fourth tarni.r spent most of his tine on another farm and only a fraction of it en hi. own pisee. Tb. av.rg. else income and inveetaent for thee farms js l seen in Table 16. as nay be evera]. of the sample farms have changed hands a continuing the cooperation that their began, predecessors began. One of th. owned farms changed hands ear]) early in l9l. In neither case was operator, both ta this due to failure of the first production and had above average improvements, Two ranted farms have also chs.ngod hands, leased by the oner of an 80 acre tract, One was orig He could no developeent of both places and had to drop th. lease, farm also changed hands due to Inadequacie Due to poor topography and li-mi-ted capital it original operator. The second original operator. $ too large for the The lease was taken up by two operators who divided the farm. Those three farmers began operations in 191 with limited capital on farms that income in l9O was small. x'e largely undeveloped. In several groupings in the analysie thes. three first-year operators and the four operator. were placed in a separate group (see Tables U and I Tenure is already çroviding some inter. promises to be of some importance to this stud of the 'value of total investment per Borrowed funds wez'e used as folloirs: and buildings 2 percent Uachinery and equipment 2 percent Production end household expenses 50 percent AU loans ($]3,i$o) 100 percent of the coat of land ad buildings had been borrowed 0 percent of the total cost of equipment was borrowed. Only half of total borrowings were still owing. in December, 19O, ibsn the i9O farm records were taken. Probably less than this amount was still owing after harvesting was completed. The study of farm loans was complicated in 19O by the fact thst, due to the delayed harvest, all farmers had not made their 19S0 payment. when the farm record was taken. Some of these delinquent borrowers made payments later when their crops were har'cested. Others were unable to pay. The Farmers Rome Aàdnistration was permitted to make disaster loan. in the area ifter the fall, of 19O. A discussion of the sources of farm investment on a ew irriga.. tion Project deserves aoxe attention than can be given at this time, Van WInkle (13) has dealt with th. subject rather thoroughly in an earlier study on the southern half of the North Unit, Deschutee Project. The Bureau of Recl*mation is preparing (or has prepared) report comparing this study with 'o similar studies, one in Washington and one in Idiho. The report of the Farmers Roe. Adiini. tration (9) referred to previously is also useful in comparing capital needs on 'various new irrigation project. in th. Pacific Northwest. Lnvsatiga ,ifl probably are aai]abls. is a5pSct of farm orgini roductii aftr another year' a farm records 67 This tudy is an analysis of the first two years or farm develproject. The pment by the operators or 63 farms on investigation is to continua for another three yea is mad, to compa: n attempt se of land and the farm progress made by operators with waiying mounts of capital, on farm units of differsztt izes and on differing lasses of land, by using only farm investment, rop acreag and gross income data, In order to economize on research time and money, complete of production figurew were not obtained. Although it has certain limitations this method appears to be satisfactory. the efficiency of fixed capital can be corn- pared by this e may not be consistent with the amount and efficiency of operating capital on the farms being compared. Two areas of quite different topography are examined. A de oription of the sample area and sample farms in terms of oil, land capability classes, and irrigability classes is given. Irrigability class 1 and 2 lands, which differ only in slope and smoothness, are apared. Operators on class 1 lands were found to have spent 20 percent more per acre on leveling cot than operators situated on class 2 lands. Operators paid practically th. same purchase price on the two land classes. T*tal investaent and gross crop income were found to be higher on the clan 1 lands. Apart from the tact that potato.e were grown oniy on class 1 lands, no appreciable difference in the type of farming was noticeable between the two land o ii' l9SO. and on Agency Plains, which is practically level, was con to be more desirable th*n the more rolling land in Md Springs, in that the purchasers bought it up first and paid a higher pric. for it. Land in ud Springs was bought in slightly smaller unite (due to the topography; lees of it is Lrrigabl.) by operators with less capital than those on the Plains. Farm development in Vud Spring. began a few months later than on the Plains and probably for this reason land use was slightly different. By the time Mud Springs was being developed, ladino clover seed production was shown to have a cnparative advantage over alfalfa hay and red clover seed production. Relatively more ).adino and less of the other two crops was grown in Iud Springs in l9O. Livestock was of limited importance on th. project up to l9l, due mainly to limit. on the availability of capital. Few conclusions can be reached at present with regard to farm organization. Present indications may only be properly evaluated after several more years of farm records are available. Gross farm income depends upon farm size and farm An adequate farm size in terms of irrigable acreage end capital investment cannot be estimated at this time. It appears that some farm operators could have made more efficisnt use of their capt they had had a larger acreage. The average of the 63 farms ims sorevhat larger in most respects than the average of the 31 operated farme, wner- The majority of farms were less than the average else, investment and income. Nineteen farms had over ha]! of Avóree of 63 f*rss Number of farms with less than average Size - 1114 irrigable acres 38 tnvestent ... 127,OO 142 Gross crop incczie - l9,bOO 37 the total income and instaent on the 63 sample farms, A large starting net worth is useful but not .eential to frm progress. Th. operator's own l&bor end initietl.v. in farm management and developmant ar. important reecnlrees Wise use of limited capital ray make him a btter loan risk than profligate use of abundant cap- ital. The new settler generally must acquir. th, use of more resources than ha owns. Rsnting eith.r part or all of th. farm unit is a recognised way of overcoming capital limitations. It is desirable for the tenant to attain sore security of tenure since he generally makes considerable Investment, the earnings from which may be realised only over a period of years. It is diffioult to arrange a fair rental agreement on land of unknown potential. lease should be flexible to permit changes whn income and cost relationships bscoa. better known. Certain of these aep.cte of l*nd use and farm organisation which have been treated lightly her, will receive much more atton. tion in remaining years of the study, Much of the effort expended on the study to this date has been devoted to developing setegorias and procedures. It is hoped that they will bear fruit over the 70 BIBLIOGRAPHY ,Oscar trtor to 19b9. 1407p. Annual report of the secretary of the 9I9. Washington, Govt. printing office, Jots, Alexand.r, Rspay.nt experience on federal reclamation projects. Journal of farm economic. 2?s1S3.167. 19h, G. Stamm, The economic problems of irrigatior development in need of ree*roh by agricultural economists. Proceedings of the western farm economics Lee, J. Karl, end C} associstion, twenty-third annual meeting l903l0l-107. Osborn, Howard A. Preliminary report on farm development on a new irrigation project Jefferson County, Oregon. Corvallis, Oregon, Department of agricultural economics, Oregon agricultural experiment station, l$0, 18 p. (mimeographed) Peterson, Arthur I, Statistical description and ana]yeis of Proceedings of data by economic lend use class areas the western farm economics association, nineteenth annue meeting. 191i6zb7-60. er*, I. L., William I. Hill and M. F. Sandos. Land cape- bt1Ltie and conservation farming Desehutee area, central Oregon. Corvallis, Agricultural experiment station, Oregon state college. veinber 19&7. 63p. (Special bulletin in aoopsratian with .il conservation service). Preeident a water r.ources policy coiesion. Water resources law. Washington, Govt. printing office, l9O. 777p. U.S. Department of agriculture. Irrigation agrianiture the west. Washington, Govt. printing office, l918. (Miscellaneous publication no. 670) U.S. Department of agriculture, farmers home administration. Credit needs in the Columbia river drainage area l9A) through l9. l919, Washington Farmers home administration, 18p, (mimeographed5 10. U.S. Department of interior, bureau of reclamation. Dsschutee federal reclamation project. Washington, Govt. printing office, 191i8. Bp. 11. Department of interior, uroau of reclamation, Dchut project. Contract between the United States and the Jefferson water coneervncy district for the construction of the Wiciup reasrv'oir and the north unit of the Deechutes project. Washington, Govt. printing office, 1938. 13p. amendment and supplement l9L5. 8p. U.S. Department of interior, bureau of reclamation. Federal reclamation laws annotated. Washington, Govt printIng office, 1913. 766p. Winkle, Alfred Fugene. Capital used in the development of newlr irrigated farms on the north unit, Desohutea project, OregQn. Corvallis, M.S. thesis eubctitted to Oregon state college, 19S0. 62p. (mimeographed)