Essays on U.S. Agricultural Policy: Subsidies, Crop Insurance, and Environmental Auctions by Barrett Edward Kirwan Submitted to the Department of Economics in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics at the MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY September 2005 © Barrett Edward Kirwan, MMV. All rights reserved. The author hereby grants to MIT permission to reproduce and to distribute publicly paper and electronic copies of this thesis document in whole or in part. - I1/_, , I/ Signatureof Author......................................................... .1... ...... . ... Department of Economics August 15, 2005 _s Certifiedby........................................................ ..................... David H. Autor Associate Profesor of Economics A , r ofThesis Supervisor Certified by ............................................................. , .... T Michael Greenstone M Associate Professor of Economics '? -- 7 Thesis Supervisor Accepted by ............................................................................................................... Peter Temin Elisha Gray II Professor of Economics Chairperson, Department Committee on Graduate Students MASSACHUSETTSINST'TE I OF TECHNOLOGY ARCHIVES IFT T T 7, I Z' SE 3 U 20U5 LIBRARIES I Essays on U.S. Agricultural Policy: Subsidies, Crop Insurance, and Environmental Auctions by Barrett Edward Kirwan Submitted to the Department of Economics on August 15, 2005 in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics ABSTRACT This thesis investigates the unintended consequences of government policy, specifically policy meant to benefit agricultural producers. The first chapter asks how agricultural subsidies affect farmland rental rates. Chapter two examines the relative effects of ad hoc disaster payments and crop insurance, focusing on the potential to smooth income shocks, and the final chapter studies the targeting efficiency of the Conservation Reserve Program. Chapter one exploits exogenous variation in agricultural subsidies to measure the effects on farmland rental rates. The primary finding is that landlords capture one-fifth of the marginal subsidy dollar per acre. This finding stands in contrast to the standard assumption that landlords immediately capture the entire subsidy. There is some evidence that the share of the subsidy captured by landlords increases as the farmland rental market becomes more competitive. The analysis also indicates that the lower effective price of land induces tenants to rent more land such that they gain roughly $1 per dollar of subsidy. Taken together, the results suggest that agricultural subsidies benefit farmers, as well as individuals that own agricultural land. Chapter two exploits random weather variation and exogenous variation in crop insurance take-up in order to investigate the relative effect of two forms of government-provided disaster relief on farm failure rates. I find that disaster relief in the form of ad hoc disaster payments slightly reduces the average farm failure rate, while average farm failure rates increase under a crop insurance regime. The relative effect suggests that farm failure rates increase by 1.7 percentage points (about 30-percent) under the crop insurance regime. Excessively generous ad hoc disaster payments and moral hazard provide possible explanations for these findings. These findings suggest that government-provided crop insurance plays an important role in farmer risk management. Chapter three estimates the premiums received by Conservation Reserve Program participants above their reservation rents. Findings suggest that participants receive substantial premiums, and the premiums have increased over time as uncertainty about the program has decreased. Thesis Supervisor: David H. Autor Title: Associate Professor of Economics Thesis Supervisor: Michael Greenstone Title: 3M Associate Professor of Economics 3 4 Acknowledgements The research presented in this thesis has benefited greatly from the guidance and mentoring of my advisors. I am deeply grateful to David Autor. He has challenged me to think carefully with his insightful suggestions and critiques. His kindness and encouragement have been equally valuable. I also am extremely thankful to Michael Greenstone, whose clear vision and encouragement motivated me from the beginning. His rigorous intellect helped focus the research, and I hope the analyses reflect the wisdom he imparted. Jonathan Gruber provided the foundation for this research through his teaching, his encouragement and his passionate example. This research owes a great debt to his intellectual legacy. Several others deserve special mention for their contributions and suggestions. Most notably, conversations and collaboration with Michael Roberts of the U.S. Department of Agriculture-Economic Research Service provided the impetus of this research. Jim Poterba offered many helpful comments. Access to the data used in Chapter 1 was generously facilitated by James Breuggen and Jameson Burt of the U.S. Department of Agriculture-National Agricultural Statistics Service. The George Schultz fund at MIT generously funded several trips to Washington, D.C. to access the confidential data used in Chapter 1. I also wish to acknowledge financial support from the National Science Foundation during my first three years of graduate school. I am extremely grateful to my classmates at MIT from whom I learned far more than just economics. Their camaraderie and friendship will be with me always. In particular, Mara, Melissa, Manuel, and Cindy continue to be a source of inspiration. Gaining their friendship made graduate school worthwhile. I am truly thankful for the love and encouragement of my family. My parents have been a wellspring of advice, encouragement, and prayers. Brock, Jennifer, Todd, and Whitney have revealed the strength of the human spirit to me. Above all, I am profoundly grateful to my wife, Jennifer, and to my children, Ella and Samuel. Their love, devotion, and strength are at the heart of this thesis. 5 6 Contents The Incidence of U.S. Agricultural Subsidies on Farmland Rental Rates 1 Introduction ....................................................... 2 Literature Review................................................................................................ 12 3 Institutional 15 3.1 3.2 4 Background 9 ...................................................... Overview of the Farmland Rental Market .. ..................... 15 Agricultural Subsidy Policy..................................................... 16 3.2.1 The Federal Agricultural Improvement and Reform Act.......................... 18 Data ....................................................................................................................................... 19 4.1 4.2 5 6 Sample Selection.......................................................................................................20 Variable Creation............................... 21 4.2.1 Dependent Variable................................................................................... 21 4.2.2 Independent Variables............................................................................... 22 Empirical Strategy-Identification ............................ 23 5.1 Econometric Ideal ..................................................................................................... 5.2 Unobserved Heterogeneity........................................................................................25 5.3 5.4 Simultaneity Bias ...................................................................................................... Expectation Error ...................................................................................................... 26 27 Estimation and Results......................................................................................................... 29 6.1 Ordinary Least Squares........................................................ 29 6.1.1 6.1.2 7 8 9 23 A Cross-Sectional Approach ........................................................ A New Approach ....................................................... 29 30 6.2 Instrumental Variables....................................................... 6.3 The Heterogeneity of Rental Rate Incidence across Region and Farm Size............ 34 32 6.3.1 Resource Regions....................................................... 34 6.3.2 Sales Class ....................................................... 35 Interpretation........................................................................................................... Variable Factors of Production........................ Tenant's Incidence......................................... 10 Conclusion ......................................... 11 Appendix............................................................... 36 37................ 37 40 41 ........................................ 45 Adversity and the Propensity to Fail: The Impact of Disaster Payments and Multiple Peril Crop Insurance on U.S. Farm Failure Rates I 2 3 4 Introduction.............. ........................................ Background...................................................................... 63 .......67 2.1 Two Disaster-Risk Mitigation Programs ......................................... 70 2.2 The Federal Crop Insurance Reform Act of 1994. 71 Empirical Strategy ......................................... Data .......................................... 4.1 ................................... 72 75 Farm Failure Rates.................................................................................................... 75 7 4.2 D isaster Classification ........................ .... 4.2.1 Precipitation Indices .................................................................................. 4.2.2 5 Em pirical Results .................................................................................................................. 5.1 5.2 79 81 Overview................................ 81 Randomized Experiments......................................................................................... 82 5.2.1 Randomization........................................................................................... 82 Disaster Payments ...................................................................................... 84 5.2.2 5.2.3 5.3 6 Disaster Classification............................ 76 77 Crop Insurance ........................................................................................... 85 Relative Effectiveness.............................................................................................. 86 Interpretation and Conclusion .............................................................................................. 88 How Cost-Effective are Land Retirement Auctions? Estimating the Difference between Payments and Willingness to Accept in the Conservation Reserve Program 1 Introduction ......................................................................................................................... 107 2 Institutional Background..................................................................................................... 108 3 4 The CRP Bidding Mechanism ............................... 2.1 Sum m ary Statistics .............................................................................................................. A M odel of Bidding Behavior ............................................................................................ 4.1 5 6 Empirical Model ................................... Results ......................................... Conclusion .............................. 109 110 112 115 117 118 8 Chapter 1 The Incidence of U.S. Agricultural Subsidies on Farmland Rental Rates 1 Introduction The primary goal of U.S. agricultural policy over the past century has been to increase farmers' income. Since 1973, direct payments to agricultural producers have been a vital instrument for supporting that goal'. open question. Whether agricultural subsidies actually benefit farmers, however, is an Nearly half of all farmland in the United States is rented, almost all of it from non-farmers. Agricultural subsidies may not benefit farmers if non-farmer landlords are able to adjust rental rates to capture the subsidies paid to agricultural producers. In the United States, agricultural subsidies are a significant transfer payment to farmers. Among income support policies, subsidies rank among the highest in expenditures per recipient. In 1999, the average subsidy was $17,561 per recipient household. Compare this to $2,052 annually per recipient household in food stamps; an average total unemployment compensation claim of $3,118; or $4,460 per recipient in annual benefits from SSI, an income support for the needy aged, blind, and disabled. The total amount spent on farm payments in 1999, $22.7 billion, rivals the spending of one of the largest transfer programs, the earned income tax credit, which allocated $30.5 billion in credits to low-income tax filers. The size of the farm subsidy program alone emphasizes the importance of understanding whether the stated policy goals are being met. See Orden, Paarlberg, and Roe (1997) for a history of agricultural policy. 9 Recent increased scrutiny of U.S. agricultural policy highlights the importance and urgency of this issue. Media stories about Congressmen and sports and movie stars receiving agricultural subsidies have focused the domestic debate on agricultural policy 2 . The international debate has also focused on U.S. domestic agricultural policy due to record subsidy payments from 1999 through 2001. This topic is playing a key role in the current Doha round of World Trade Organization negotiations. Despite the prevalence of rental agreements, and the importance of subsidies as a policy measure, there is little empirical work examining the relationship between subsidies and farmland rental rates. Without a clear understanding of the connection between subsidies and rental rates farm policy might be severely misguided. Rented farmland is almost entirely owned by non-farmers. In 1999 alone, 94 percent of landlords were non-farmers. Policy aimed at benefiting farmers fails if non-farmer landlords extract the entire subsidy dollar. This paper estimates the extent to which the marginal subsidy dollar is reflected in rental rates. In an effort to inform both the public debate and the academic literature, I quantify the effectiveness of government subsidies as a policy instrument used to benefit farmers, and I utilize an incidence measure to inform various assumptions in the literature surrounding farmland value determination. This paper investigates the relationship between farmland rental rates and agricultural subsidies by analyzing a panel of farm-level production data. The data are from confidential United States Department of Agriculture (USDA) - National Agricultural Statistical Service (NASS) Census of Agriculture micro files from 1992 and 1997. The nature of these data provides two identifying sources of variation. 2 The first comes from the differential acreage For example, Elizabeth Becker. "Some Who Vote on Farm Subsidies Get Them as Well." The New York Times Sept. 1, 2001, and Billy Heller. "$24M Baseballer Reaps Farm Aid." The New York Post Mar. 27, 2002. 10 enrollment in the subsidy program across farms. To illustrate, consider two otherwise identical fields, one is completely enrolled in the subsidy program, while the other is not. Under this scenario any difference in rental rates will be due to differences in subsidies. The second source of variation is due to a policy change in 1996, the Federal Agricultural Improvement and Reform (FAIR) act, which exogenously changed subsidy rates. This provides a quasi-experimental design that allows me to examine a change in subsidy rates that is plausibly uncorrelated with other behavioral changes. I employ several techniques to exploit these sources of variation and identify the effect of subsidies on farmland rental rates. I use farm fixed effects and time-varying county fixed effects to control for unobserved farm heterogeneity and regional shocks, and I exploit the exogeneity imposed on subsidy payments by the 1996 legislation to overcome bias due to simultaneity. I use instrumental variables techniques to overcome possible expectation error that could bias the estimated effect of subsidies on farmland rental rates by using the legislated, pre-determined 1997 subsidy payments as an instrumental variable to address expectation error in the 1992 subsidies. The analysis finds that between 18 and 20 percent of the marginal subsidy dollar is reflected in increased rental rates. This implies that of the $5.5 billion in farm subsidies in 1997, at most $1.1 billion may have gone to non-farmers. Although the literature typically assumes that every subsidy dollar is captured by landowners, i.e., full incidence (e.g., Chambers 1995), these findings suggest that the standard assumptions may need to be re-evaluated to more accurately reflect the factor market for land. Based on these findings, economic theory suggests that subsidies may have effects beyond the farmland rental market. Because farm subsidies are factor-specific subsidies to land, 11 the marginal subsidy dollar effectively lowers the rental rate by 80 cents. The lower rental price of land induces substitution away from other variable inputs toward rental land, while the lower marginal cost might result in greater output and increased variable input use. The ultimate effect on other variable factors of production is an empirical question. The analysis finds a significant, positive response of expenditure on nearly all variable inputs. Overall, the marginal per-acre subsidy dollar increases per-acre expenditure by 35 cents. The increased output ultimately results in a gain to tenant farmers. The analysis shows that the net returns of tenant farmers increase one-for-one with the marginal subsidy dollar, supporting the notion that ultimately the farm operator benefits from the marginal subsidy dollar. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 reviews the existing literature, noting the lack of empirical work on subsidy incidence. Section 3 details the institutional facts about the farmland rental market and subsidy policy. Section 4 describes the data. Section 5 lays out the empirical strategy employed in this investigation, emphasizing the identifying assumptions. Section 6 presents the incidence on landlords and provides evidence of the robustness of the estimated incidence. Section 7 provides a plausible explanation of the results. Section 8 examines the subsidy's effect on non-land factors of production. Section 9 provides evidence that the incidence on tenants is complementary to the incidence on landlords. Finally, section 10 interprets the findings in light of existing assumptions and policy objectives and suggests directions for future research. 2 Literature Review This paper is one of the first to examine the incidence of subsidies on farmland rental rates, but it has a foundation in a much broader literature on the determinants of farmland values. Alston 12 (1986) and Robison,et al. (1985), among others, examined the asset value of land as the present discounted value of the stream of returns to land, which they represented with the cash rental rate. Melichar (1979) noted that the discount rate in such models is comprised of a discount rate and the expected growth rate of the stream of returns. More recently Weersink, et al. (1999) disaggregated the stream of returns to farmland into the return from farming and the subsidies to land. They estimated separate discount rates for each stream, finding that subsidies are discounted less heavily than the returns to production. Virtually all of the research on subsidy incidence has examined the relationship between subsidies and land values. This investigation has taken many approaches. Morehart, et al. (2001) and Weersink, et al. (1999) are characteristic of those who use a present discounted value of the stream of subsidies in their analysis. Shoemaker, et al. (1989) approach the problem by using a computable general equilibrium model in order to ascertain the extent to which subsidies are capitalized into land values. Both of these approaches suffer from assuming perfect incidence and essentially examine only the process of capitalization. represent a separate approach using pooled cross-sections Barnard, et al. (1996) in order to assess the degree of capitalization. Although this approach does not assume perfect incidence, the findings cannot be separated into an incidence estimate and discount and expected growth rate estimates. The approach taken in this paper contributes to the discussion by explicitly separating the incidence estimate from the discount rate. By focusing on farmland rental rates, rather than land value, I disentangle the incidence question from the question of expectations over future policy. This not only contributes to the current knowledge about who benefits from current subsidies and to what degree, but it also lays the groundwork to more carefully address the questions concerning the expected growth rate of government subsidies. 13 Researchers have recently begun examining the effects of subsidies on rental rates (Lence and Mishra 2003; Goodwin, et al. 2004). A prominent feature of this research is the implicit assumption that once one controls for observable characteristics, no unobservables remain that are correlated with government payments. This assumption is the 'selection on observables' assumption. To illustrate the hazard of relying on this assumption, consider the confounding effect of the inherent productivity of land due to complex interactions among soil characteristics and climate. This characteristic is an unobserved determinant of land values that is correlated with subsidies because subsidies are a function of historic yield. In the presence of this unobservable characteristic, the coefficient on government payments will capture both the effect of subsidies and the effect of unobserved productivity. Since both effects are positively related to land values, the parameter of interest will be larger than it would be if it identified the true effect of subsidies. This paper overcomes the problem by using a farm fixed effect to purge permanent, unobserved characteristics that determine rental rates.3 In contrast, this study uses disaggregated panel data to control for unobserved heterogeneity and county-specific secular trends. The timing of the data allows me to exploit exogenous variation in subsidies from the mid-1990s policy change. The policy change acts as a 'quasi-experiment' by changing the subsidy in a way that was unanticipated and uncorrelated with the farmer's behavior, thereby reinforcing the identification of the true effect of subsidies on farmland rental rates. 3 Interestingly, Hoch (1958 and 1962) and Mundlak (1961) developed the fixed effects model to account for unobserved heterogeneity in estimating agricultural production functions. 14 3 Institutional Background 3.1 Overview of the farmland rental market Renting farmland is a common practice in U.S. agriculture, where more than 45 percent of the 917-million farmland acres are rented (USDA 2001b). A typical tenant rents 65 percent of the land he farms, paying either in cash or in shares of production. Sixty percent of rented farmland is paid for with cash, 24 percent with shares of production, and 11 percent with a cash/share combination. Those who cash lease pay $60 per acre on average. The average rental rate among those who grow subsidized crops is slightly below the national average at $50 per acre. The rental market is characterized by short-term contracts in long-term relationships. Rental contracts commonly take the form of year-to-year "handshake" agreements. formal, written rental contracts exist they also generally last one year. When In spite of frequent renewal, these arrangements are typically found in long-term landlord-tenant relationships. Allen and Lueck (1992) report an average landlord-tenant relationship length of 11.5 years in Nebraska and South Dakota, and Sotomeyer, et al. (2000) report 11.3-year landlord-tenant relationships in Illinois. by March 1St. The parties enter into the rental agreements early in the year, typically A rental rate negotiated in the spring is based on the expected returns from farming during the upcoming year. Among the expected returns are government payments, which typically are made after the harvest. The mistiming between the setting of the rental rate and the realization of government payments results in forecast error. The forecast error involved in the agreed upon rental rate may serve to confound the relationship between subsidies and rental rates if not adequately addressed. Below I detail the instrumental variables (IV) strategy used to address the issue. 15 The incidence measures the division of subsidy benefits between the tenant and the landowner. Whenever a land-owning farmer rents out land, the incidence question asks whether the tenant or land-owning farmer benefits from the policy. To the extent that rented land is owned by a non-farmer, the incidence denotes how much of each dollar leaves agriculture. In the United States, non-farmers own 94 percent of the rented land, or 340 million acres-twice the size of Texas (USDA, NASS 2001b). This makes the issue of subsidy incidence a particularly poignant one if agricultural subsidies are meant to benefit farmers. In effect, one can view the incidence as describing the portion of each subsidy dollar not going to a farmer. 3.2 Agricultural Subsidy Policy A key component of domestic agricultural policy is the support of farmers' income. The U.S. farmers' income is supported by a two-tier system: 1) price supports and 2) income supports, i.e., subsidies. Price supports have existed since the farm program began in the 1930s. For most of the century, they were the chief mechanism for transferring money to the agricultural sector. Prices are supported by the government's promise to purchase the commodity at a predetermined price. Although the government once took direct possession of these purchases, today it generally augments the price the farmer receives from sales to a third party. Income supports became a distinct objective with the introduction of production subsidies in 1973. Since their inception, subsidies have been calculated in a consistent way. An acre of land used to grow one of seven crops-wheat, corn, sorghum, barley, oats, rice, and cottoncould qualify to be subsidized. A qualifying acre receives a subsidy equal to a national subsidy rate times an output yield assigned to that acre. Between 1985 and 2002 the assigned yield, 16 called a program yield, approximately equaled the farm-average yield between 1980 and 19854. An acre that qualifies for a subsidy is called a base acre. A farm's total crop-specific subsidy is the product of the subsidy rate, the program yield, and the total number of base acres for that crop. That is, subsidy = subsidy rate * program yield * base acres. Prior to 1996, the subsidy rate was designed in a way that made subsidy payments counter-cyclical. This was done by calculating the crop-specific deficiency rate as the difference between a legislated target price and the national average price received. As the national average price fell, the difference between it and the target price increased, causing the subsidy to increase. It is important to note that program yield and base acreage are specifically tied to a qualifying acre of land. As an acre changes ownership, these parameters are transferred with the land. As such, agricultural subsidies are factor-specific subsidies to land. However, not all land planted to a subsidized crop qualified for the subsidy because subsidies were closely associated with supply control measures through the base acreage allotment. Prior to 1996, total subsidized acres could not be greater than an average of the number of acres planted to that crop over the previous five years. If a farmer's planted acreage exceeded his base, he was disqualified from receiving subsidies for that year, although his increased planting would enter into a five-year moving average when calculating the farm's total base acres in subsequent years. This feature provided farmers with some means to affect current and future subsidies through current behavior. (See Duffy, et al. (1995) for an analysis of the effect of base acres on land values.) " Prior to 1985 the program yield was the 5-year Olympic average of the farm's annual yield. The current program yield is the average of the 1980 - 1985 program yields. 17 As an additional supply control measure, farmers were required to remove a designated proportion of their base acres from production each year and leave it fallow. This program was called the Acreage Reduction Program (ARP), but it was commonly referred to as the "set-aside" program. The Department of Agriculture annually established the set-aside proportion, which could be as high as 25 percent. In 1992, producers were required to leave 5 percent of their wheat, corn, sorghum, and barley base acres fallow; 10 percent of their cotton base acres fallow; and none of their rice or oats base acres fallow. These planting constraints and supply control measures imposed costs that kept many producers from participating in the subsidy program. Before 1996, participation rates usually ranged from 60 to 80 percent of qualified acres5 . After the 1996 policy change, which removed the costly constraints, nearly all qualified acres were enrolled in the farm program. 6 The identification strategy relies, in part, on the cross-sectional variation in acres participating in the subsidy program. 3.2.1 The Federal Agricultural Improvement and Reform Act The 1990s saw an end to the supply control measures and the completion of the process to decouple subsidies from contemporaneous production. In a dramatic move, the Federal Agricultural Improvement and Reform (FAIR) Act froze base acres at their 1995 level and removed all planting restrictions, including set-aside requirements. With the exception of certain fruits and vegetables, producers were given complete planting flexibility, while they still received subsidies based on their 1985 program yield and their 1995 acreage base. At the same time, the subsidy rate was no longer conditioned on the commodity's price, as it was before 5 Land qualified to receive subsidies for oats is the single exception, where the participation has been between 20 and 40 percent of qualified acres 6 This variation will be used in future work by the author to measure the costs of program participation. 18 1996, but it was exogenously determined by the policy. I exploit this innovation to identify the effect of subsidies on farmland rental rates. Two aspects of this reform are significant to the analysis below. First, by freezing the farm-specific program parameters (program yield and base acres), the policy divorced farmer behavior from the subsidy. As described below, this unique feature of the legislation allows me to control for simultaneity that would otherwise serve to confound the incidence estimates. Second, the 1996 legislation removed the uncertainty of subsidy payments by establishing a schedule of annual payments from 1996 to 2002. I exploit the post-1995 known subsidy payments as an IV for pre-1995 ex ante uncertain subsidy payments. Failure to address this issue would result in attenuation bias of the incidence estimate. 4 Data The primary source of data used in the analysis described below is the U.S. Census of Agriculture, a quinquennial census of those who produce at least $1,000 of agricultural goods. These data are confidential micro files accessed under an agreement with the USDA Economic Research Service and the USDA National Agricultural Statistics Service (NASS). The data are available at NASS in Washington, DC 7. The Census of Agriculture contains farm-level information such as total acres farmed, total acres rented, and total government payments received. It also contains detailed information on the number of acres harvested and the total production of each crop. The value of production is reported for 13 crop groups and for all livestock. The census also collects information on the corporate structure of the operation as well as demographic information on the primary operator. 7 Any interpretations and conclusions derived from the data represent the author's views and not necessarily those of NASS. 19 Additionally, approximately one in three farms receives the census's long form which requests further information on the production and financial structure of the operation8 Recipients are asked to report production expenses in 15 cost groups, including cash rent paid on land and buildings. Recipients are further asked to report the estimated value of the farm's land and buildings. The long form also collects information on the type and amount of equipment used, the number of workers hired, and the use of agricultural chemicals and fertilizers. 4.1 Sample Selection Two years of the Census of Agriculture, 1992 and 1997, are used to create a balanced panel of farming operations. Each year has roughly 1.6 million respondents. Although the total number of respondents remains roughly equal over the two years, this masks a great deal of turnover (see Hoppe & Korb, 2001). There are 1,040,305 farm operations observed in both years of the data 9 . The population of interest is all farms that could potentially receive subsidies in the base year. I approximate that population by focusing on the 437,979 farms that grew any one of the seven program crops in the base year. The first column of Table 1 contains the summary statistics for this population. Because I am concerned with the financial structure of farming, I limit the sample to those who returned the long-form in both years, yielding 100,936 observations in each year. Since rental rates are the outcome of primary interest, I include only those who report paying cash rent in both years' ° . I remove farms that are primarily renting structures by The Census attempts to collect financial information from all farms with sales over $500,000, and randomly 8 samples from the remaining farms. 9 This is not indicative of the failure rate of farms, but rather the incomplete response rate to the census. About 85% of farm operations respond. 10 Renting in 1997 is a potentially endogenous decision since the propensity to rent farmland in 1997 might be influenced by the 1996 policy change. This source of endogeneity could cause downward bias if farms experiencing a high incidence stopped renting, but those experiencing low incidence continued to rent. I investigate this using a two-step Heckman sample selection correction. A well-known test of sample selection bias is a simple significance 20 dropping those with imputed rental rates greater than two standard deviations above the mean" The cutoff is $470, which is conservative considering the highest response to the 1997 June Agricultural Survey, a nationwide survey that specifically asked for cropland cash rental rates, was $448. The final analysis sample consists of 58,302 farms observed over two years. Table 1 contains the summary statistics of the estimation sample and the population of farms growing subsidized crops. The median farmer in this sample has operated a farm for 23 years, compared to 22 years in the population. The average net returns per acre to a farmer in the analysis are $92.50, a bit less than the average in the full sample of those reporting net returns. Of those receiving subsidies in the sample the average total government payment is $16,614. The median is $10,000. This suggests that a few farms receive large subsidies. The sample statistics of key variables can be found in Table 1. 4.2 Variable Creation 4.2.1 Dependent Variable The Census of Agriculture does not report the per-acre rental rate, however respondents do report the total amount paid in cash rent. The total acres rented on a cash, share, or free basis also are reported. From these two variables, I create the per-acre rental rate by dividing total cash rent by total acres rented. Admittedly, the resulting rental rate will be too small for farms that cash rent part of the land and share rent another part. The resulting measurement error is not classical measurement error. Since the calculated rental rate is less than or equal to the true cash rental rate, the expected value of the measurement error must be greater than zero. As long as test of the coefficient on the inverse Mills ratio. This coefficient is statistically insignificant, and the null hypothesis of no sample selection bias cannot be rejected. See Appendix table 1 for the coefficient estimates. '' This drops less than 1% of the sample. 21 the non-classical measurement error is uncorrelated with the regressors, only the intercept will be confounded. However, if the measurement error is positively correlated with the magnitude of government payments, the estimated effect of government payments on rental rates will be biased downward'2 . I investigate this source of bias using the microfiles of the 1999 Agricultural Economics and Land Ownership Survey (AELOS), a follow-up survey to the 1997 Census of Agriculture which asked for detailed information about the type of lease arrangement, the total cash rent paid, and the value of the share of production paid as rent. estimate of the non-classical measurement Using these data I construct an error, and I estimate the relationship between the measurement error and government payments'l3. When controlling for county-level unobserved heterogeneity, I find no relationship between government payments and the measurement error, implying no bias in the primary analysis. 4.2.2 Independent Variables The subsidy variable is constructed from the reported government payments variables. Every agricultural producer is asked to report non-price support payments received from the government. Producers are asked to report both total payments received and payments received from the Conservation Reserve Program (CRP). By subtracting CRP payments from the reported total payments, I construct an approximate measure of subsidy receipts. In 1992, subsidies accounted for 68 percent of direct government payments net of Conservation Reserve Program payments. The remaining 32 percent are from disaster relief (17 percent) and other programs (USDA, NASS, 1996). In 1997, even fewer total payments are attributable to non- 12 13 Appendix 1 formally lays out the potential for bias and details the analysis that is summarized below. The estimates are reported in Appendix Table 1. 22 subsidy sources, with only 4 percent of direct government payments going to neither subsidies nor CRP payments (USDA, NASS, 2001). The remaining covariates are constructed directly from variables contained in the Census of Agriculture. All regressors are measured on a per-acre basis, using total farmland acres in the denominator. 5 Empirical Strategy - Identification Here I lay out the obstacles that must be overcome in order to identify the effect of government subsidies on farmland rental rates. I begin by specifying a simple rental rate equation that, under ideal circumstances, yields the incidence measure. In the face of a less than ideal experiment, I lay out the modifications necessary to identify the parameters of the conditional expectation function. After setting out a fixed-effect estimation equation, I detail the instrumental variables procedure necessary to overcome attenuation bias in the econometric model. The resulting IV model overcomes the obstacles separating the real-world situation from the econometric ideal. 5.1 Econometric Ideal If subsidies were randomly assigned, then the parameter identified by a regression of the rental rate on subsidy per acre would be the proportion of each extra subsidy dollar per acre reflected in higher rental rates. Denote the rent on acre i at time t by ri, and let gi, be the amount of subsidy payments associated with acre i. Then we may write (1) where i, is the residual. ri = a + gi Y +i, Random assignment identifies y* as the incidence of agricultural subsidies on farmland rental rates. 23 However, subsidies are not randomly assigned, git is most likely correlated with it, and the resulting OLS estimate of yin equation (1) will be biased. The subsidy is a function of yield and crop choice; hence, it is an endogenous variable reflecting the characteristics of the land and the producer's behavior. This endogeneity problem can be overcome by addressing three issues: unobserved heterogeneity, simultaneity, and farmer's expectation error due to the mistiming of rental contracts and subsidy payments 14 . The innovation of my analysis is to address all three problems and identify the parameter of interest in the conditional expectation function. First, I use farm fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity, such as different land characteristics and entrepreneurial skill. Second, I control for simultaneity by exploiting a unique aspect of the policy change that divorced producer behavior from subsidy payments. Finally, I am able to overcome the expectation error by using an IV strategy. The best instrumental variables for agricultural subsidies are the program parameters (program yield and base acres) underlying the subsidies. These parameters fulfill the requirements of instrumental variables because, as detailed below, within the fixed effects model they are highly correlated with the subsidy and plausibly uncorrelated with the error term. Data on the program parameters are unavailable at the farm level, but two farm level variables closely reflect the program parameters. They are the 1992 set-aside acres and the 1997 subsidy level. The 1992 acres that were set aside as part of the ARP are a linear function of the base acres, and the 1997 subsidy is a known, deterministic function of the underlying program parameters. These features allow me to use the 1992 set-aside acres and the 1997 level of government payments as instrumental variables for the 1992-1997 change in government payments. 14 Measurement error will also be a problem as only 68% of government payments in 1992 were subsidies. This is much less of a problem in 1997 when 98% of government payments were subsidies. Instrumental variables techniques will address this issue. 24 5.2 Unobserved Heterogeneity Many farm characteristics cannot be observed by the econometrician, yet they are influential to both subsidies and farmland rental rates. Among these are farm-level soil properties and farmer human capital and entrepreneurial skill. Transient shocks, such as drought or pests, also may affect rental rates and government subsidies. Typical analyses are performed at the county or regional level, under the assumption of farm homogeneity within the geographic unit of observation. However, differences in farm size, structure, and productivity within a county serve to confound the conventional analysis'5 The unique nature of the data allows me to control for permanent farm-level characteristics that cause yto be inconsistent. One source of bias comes through the unobserved characteristics, such as farm productivity, that positively influence both subsidies and rental rates. This positive correlation between government payments and the unobserved factors that influence productivity will result in an upward bias to incidence estimates and confound y as a measure of the effect of subsidies on rental rates. Including farm and time-varying county fixed effects allows me to overcome this source of bias. Rewriting equation (1) using ft as the fixed effect for farm i in year t yields: (2) r,=a +gi, + i, +f +C,+Ci, The parameter C, is the time-varying county effect which allows for shocks, such as weather or pests, that impact everyone within a localized region. Xi, is a vector of observable covariates such as yield, selection and production of crops, occurrence of irrigation, farm size, sales, and costs. "5Current work by the author examines the information lost due to aggregation. 25 Controlling for unobserved heterogeneity in this way has the advantage of avoiding the inherently nonlinear relationships between soil characteristics and productivity. Because of this nonlinear relationship, even explicitly using soil characteristics as controls cannot overcome the omitted variable bias-a problem other researchers have faced (e.g. Moss, et al. 2002). This method of conditioning on unobserved farm-level characteristics also overcomes the bias inherent in studies on more aggregate units of observation (Lence and Mishra 2003). The estimating equation used in this study is obtained from equation (2) by first differencing the data to absorb the farm effect, resulting in (3) Ar = C + Agiy + Xi92 + AEi . The first difference of the control variables is not included because the 1997 level of these variables are potential outcomes influenced by the exogenous subsidy change. Instead, the 1992 values of these variables are included in the estimating equation. In a panel with t=2, the coefficients estimated from first difference data will be identical to those obtained by including the individual fixed effects. 5.3 Simultaneity Bias Simultaneity bias arises when at least one of the explanatory variables is determined simultaneously along with the response variable. Prior to the 1996 FAIR Act, output prices played a role in determining both subsidies and rental rates. When expected prices were high, rental rates were high and expected subsidies were low. Thus, simultaneity caused a negative relationship between the subsidy and the rental rate. A unique feature of the 1996 FAIR Act allows me to exploit the policy change itself to overcome the simultaneity problem. The 1996 legislation was titled the "Freedom to Farm Act" 26 because it lifted planting restrictions and divorced the subsidy from prices and producers' behavior. Such a divorce meant that prices no longer determined the subsidy rate, and simultaneity bias ceased to be a problem for the incidence estimates. Hence, the policy provides an exogenous change in subsidy rates, and its structure eliminates the obstacle to identification caused by simultaneity bias. 5.4 Expectation Error Without the obstacle of simultaneity bias, the remaining problem to be addressed is expectation error, which causes attenuation bias. As detailed earlier (see Section 3.1), rental rates are set according to expected receipts, including expected subsidy payments. Prior to the 1996 FAIR Act, subsidy payments were conditioned on the market price and thus were unknown until after the harvest, while rental rates were agreed upon before planting in the spring. To see the effects of this mistiming on the incidence parameter, rewrite equation (2) using the expected government payments, gi*, r,=a +gy +f +C,+e,. (4) Actual government payments will equal the expected government payment and an expectation error, g =g (5) + Substituting for expected subsidy receipts in equation (4) yields (6) ' = a + g, + f + C, + , - ci . The expectation error becomes part of the error term in the estimating equation. Assuming the expected subsidy and the expectation error are uncorrelated, i.e. Cov(g, cE/)=OVt,s, implies that realized government payments, git, are correlated with the error term in equation (6). The 27 effect on the coefficient of interest is the same as classical errors in variables, namely attenuation bias. The 1996 FAIR Act reduces the complexity of the problem by eliminating expectation error in 1997. Recall that in 1996 the subsidy rates were exogenously predetermined for the next seven years. Because of this feature of the legislation, there was no expectation error in 1997. The expected government payments for 1997 and 1992, respectively, are: (7) gi97 = gi97 (8) g92 = gi92 -92 i . *gg Substituting (7) and (8) into equation (2) and first differencing results in Ar = C + Agiy + Ae i - Ei92. (9) An adequate instrument is correlated with the change in government subsidies and uncorrelated with the composite error term in equation (9). requirements, the 1992 set-aside acres, denoted as sai92, Two variables meet these and the 1997 subsidy level. Both variables are assumed to be strictly exogenous. That is, conditional on the fixed effects, sai92and gi97 are uncorrelated with both i92 and i97. Thus, they are uncorrelated with zAi. Furthermore, both variables are uncorrelated with the second error term, ig9. The 1992 set-aside acres are proportional to the base acres, and are known when rental rates are set. Thus, under rational expectations, the 1992 set-aside acreage is uncorrelated with the expectation error. The 1997 subsidy level is uncorrelated with the second error term due to the absence of expectation error in 1997 which allows one to write the orthogonality condition asE(i 92gi97)= 0. This condition holds if the subsidy shock in 1992 contained no information for the expected subsidy in 1997, a reasonable assumption. 28 Since the 1997 level of government payments is uncorrelated with the composite error, it is therefore a good instrumental variable insofar as it is correlated with the 1992-1997 change in government payments. The top panel of Table 4 contains the results of the following first stage equation of a two-stage least squares estimation strategy: (10) Ag i = C + gi97 5 + sai92 ; + u i The coefficient of determination and the F-statistics are very high for both instruments, satisfying the requirement that the instruments are correlated with the endogenous variable. 6 Estimation and Results 6.1 Ordinary Least Squares 6.1.1 A Cross-Sectional Approach The approach taken by this paper has the advantage of controlling for unobserved characteristics of the farm, such as the operators entrepreneurial skill and the productivity of the land. Estimates that fail to account for these characteristics likely suffer an upward bias as productivity and skill are probably positively correlated with the subsidy. Subsidies are a direct function of the productivity of the land, and more skillful farm operators may better understand the complexities involved in maximizing subsidy payments. Estimation methods that fail to adequately control for these variables will attribute rental rate variation to the subsidy that should be attributed to productivity and skill. I explore the consequences of unobserved heterogeneity by ignoring the panel nature of the data and estimating the incidence in each year separately and in the pooled cross-section. Table 2 contains the results of this exercise. Panel A reports the estimates for 1992, panel B 29 reports the estimates for 1997, and panel C reports the estimates obtained by pooling the two cross-sections. Column one contains the results of a bivariate regression of the rental rate on the per-acre subsidy, while column two includes as covariates the proportion of the farm planted to 13 different crop groups, the output yield of 8 crops, sales, variable factor expenditures, farm size, and the proportion irrigated. It is noteworthy that in 1992, the incidence estimate found from the simple bivariate relationship is far below perfect incidence. In fact, the estimate in column one suggests that only 46 cents of the marginal subsidy dollar is reflected in rental rates. As controls are added, the incidence estimates change dramatically, falling nearly fifty percent in panels B and C, with a 30 percent drop in panel A. In such a setting, county fixed effects may adequately control for unobserved heterogeneity if farms within a county are sufficiently homogeneous. Columns three and four present the incidence estimates when a county fixed effect is included. The specification reported in column three includes no covariates, and it yields incidence estimates very similar to those in column 2. Column four includes covariates, and the incidence estimate declines even more to 0.23 in the 1992 cross-section, 0.39 in the 1997 cross-section, and 0.26 in the pooled cross-sections. A notable feature of Table 2 is the extensive change in the incidence estimate as more controls are added. This parameter instability causes one to wonder how much bias continues to exist because of other unobservable and excluded covariates. 6.1.2 A New Approach Table 3 contains the incidence estimates when I control for unobserved heterogeneity, as delineated in equation (3) above. Columns one and two report the coefficient from a random and 30 fixed effects regression respectively. The random effects regression will be consistent and efficient if the unobserved qualities of the farm are uncorrelated with the regressor (here per-acre government payments). However, the random effects model will be inconsistent if the farm effects are correlated with the regressors. Performing a Hausman test on the appropriateness of the random effects model effectively tests whether the unobserved farm characteristics are in fact biasing the estimate. The Hausman test statistic is reported at the bottom of columns one and two in Table 3. It soundly rejects the random effects model, suggesting that one should be concerned with unobserved heterogeneity when seeking a consistent estimate of the incidence parameter. Columns two and three of Table 3 report the results of the fixed effects model including farm and time-varying county effects. Column two contains no covariates, while column three includes the 1992 level of the covariates listed above. As noted earlier, the 1997 values of these covariates are potential outcomes affected by the changing subsidy and their inclusion in this specification would serve to confound the incidence estimate. Compared to the estimates in Table 2, the incidence estimate is lower once one accounts for unobserved farm characteristics, signifying a decrease in the upward bias. Another important feature of columns two and three is the stability of the incidence estimates. Once farm fixed effects are included, additional covariates do little to change the estimate, suggesting that farm fixed effects account well for potential sources of bias. The most notable characteristic of Table 3 is the low incidence estimate; the estimated incidence is only 0.18. In other words, 18 cents of the marginal subsidy dollar is reflected in higher rental rates. As discussed earlier, conventional wisdom and economic theory suggest that the land owner should capture all of the Ricardian rents, including the subsidy. The evidence 31 presented here suggests that the truth lies far from perfect incidence; the landlord is only able to capture 18 cents of the marginal subsidy dollar. One may be concerned that this estimate suffers from attenuation bias caused by measurement error or expectation error. The next section details the instrumental variables strategy used to account for these sources of bias and demonstrates that the conclusions reached above are essentially unchanged. 6.2 Instrumental Variables As discussed earlier, the measurement error and expectation error concerns apply to the 1992 government payments and can be addressed with instrumental variables. The ideal instruments for 1992 government payments would be the farm-specific subsidy parameters: program yield and base acres. These parameters are known in advance, are highly correlated with actual subsidy payments, and are uncorrelated with the idiosyncratic shocks to prices that ultimately determine subsidy payments. Thus, program yield and base acres are good instruments because they are correlated with the realized subsidy payment and uncorrelated with shocks that contribute to the expectation error. Unfortunately, data on program yields and base acres are unavailable. In order to closely approximate the ideal instruments and stay within the constraints on data availability one must look to linear functions of these variables, such as set-aside acres and 1997 government payments. Since set-aside acres are an exogenously determined proportion of base acres they provide a good instrument for the 1992 subsidy level. As noted earlier, base acres are known when the rental contracts are agreed upon, thus they are highly correlated with the expected 32 subsidy. The 1997 subsidy payments are a potentially good instrument because in 1997 the subsidy on an acre of qualified land equaled the 1992 program yield multiplied by the 1997 subsidy rate. The 1997 subsidy should thus be highly correlated with the ideal instrument, the 1992 program parameters. The first panel of Table 4 reports the first stage of a two-stage least squares estimation strategy. Column one reports the coefficients and the F-statistic when no covariates are included in the fixed effects specification. Both instruments are significant predictors of the change in subsidies. The F-statistic is 20,011. Stock and Staiger (1997) have suggested that strong instruments have an F-statistic greater than five. These instruments easily meet the criteria. The second panel of Table 4 reports the IV estimates. The IV estimates, 0.186 and 0.214, are slightly higher than the OLS estimates, revealing some attenuation. However, the small difference between the OLS and IV estimates suggests that expectation error is not a large concern in this investigation. By accounting for the potential sources of bias, namely unobserved heterogeneity, simultaneity bias, and expectation error, I have found that the landlord captures only 20 cents of the marginal subsidy dollar. Economic theory predicts that if land is the only specific factor of production and if markets are perfectly competitive then the landlord will capture the entire marginal subsidy dollar. These findings call into question the validity of these assumptions in the short run. 33 6.3 The Heterogeneity of Rental Rate Incidence across Region and Farm Size One might be concerned that the results presented mask variation in response across region or the size of the farm operation. Regions within the U.S. differ substantially in the crops grown and the predominant lease contract type. Noting that each crop is subsidized separately, one might worry that the incidence differs according to crop and subsidy regime. also influence the size of the incidence. Farm size might For instance, perhaps large farms are better able to negotiate for lower rental rates, and they are driving the relatively low incidence. I explore the robustness of the results by estimating the incidence separately for different regions and different farm sizes. 6.3.1 Resource Regions Table 5 reports the regional' 6 mean and median rental rates and per-acre subsidies for 1992 and 1997. This Table highlights the heterogeneity in both the levels and in the 1992-1997 changes of these variables. Five of the nine regions experienced a decline in mean and median rental rates. While the average per-acre subsidy almost uniformly declined, five of the regions experience an increase in the median per-acre subsidy. Table 6 presents the OLS and IV incidence estimates by resource region. A prominent feature across resource regions is the stability of the incidence estimate, which generally ranges from 0.17 to 0.30 with a couple of zeros. The incidence is somewhat higher in the Heartland region, where subsidized crops are a significant share of output. Regions with fewer farms and less subsidized crop production generally have lower incidence, sometimes not significantly 16 The USDA has established 9 resource regions corresponding to predominant crop mix and farming practices. 34 different than zero, but nearly always significantly different than one. In spite of regional differences highlighted in Table 5, the incidence estimates are all relatively similar; no one region seems to be driving the results. 6.3.2 Sales Class Another concern could be that the incidence differs by farm size. Large farms might be able to negotiate lower rental rates and thereby keep a larger share of the subsidy. Alternatively, small farms might be better acquainted with the landlord and hence receive a more favorable rental rate. In the analysis below I define farm size to be gross sales, and I adopt the classification system espoused by the USDA. 17 Table 7 reports the summary statistics for rental rates and per-acre subsidies by sales class. Interestingly, both rental rates and subsidies monotonically increase with sales class, presumably reflecting the higher productivity of the land farmed by larger farms. Columns one and two of Table 7 report the estimated subsidy incidence when the data are treated as pooled cross-sections and the panel nature of the data is ignored. These columns reveal a significant degree of variation in the estimated incidence across farm size when one fails to control for the unobserved characteristics of the farm. Notably, the incidence estimates are smallest for the smallest and largest farms, suggesting that the unobserved characteristics are more highly correlated with size for these two sales classes than for the others. estimate once controls are added is also noteworthy. The change in the The relative instability of these estimates supports the position that the unobserved farm characteristics may play a role in biasing the incidence estimate. 17For example, see http://www.ers.usda.gov/Briefing/FarmStructure/Gallery/farmsbyconstantdollars.htm 35 Columns three through six report the OLS and IV estimates once unobserved heterogeneity is accounted for. The incidence estimates do not significantly differ across farm sizes, ultimately settling around 0.2. These results give further confidence in the twenty percent incidence reported above. 7 Interpretation Economic theory predicts, and economists have long held, that under competitive markets, incidence is perfect and landlords are able to extract the entire marginal subsidy dollar. Intuitively, a subsidized parcel of farmland should result in competition among renters to secure the subsidy. Such competition will result in an increased rental rate as potential tenants bid against each other until ultimately the price of that parcel of land fully reflects the return from the subsidy. The evidence presented here suggests that this does not always happen. In the short-run, competition only serves to increase the rental rate by 20 cents. A possible explanation of this fact is imperfect rental markets. In a market with many landlords and few renters, the landlords may implicitly share the subsidy dollar in an attempt to attract tenants. In order to examine this hypothesis I create five measures of rental market concentration. The first measure is the proportion of farmers in a county who rent some land, and the second is the proportion of farmland in a county that is rented. The next measure is an approximation of the tenant-landlord ratio within a county. This measure is an approximation because each farmer reports the number of landlords from whom they rent land, but there is no way to tell whether a single landlord rents to multiple tenants. This approximate tenant-landlord ratio will be lower than the actual ratio. Finally, I calculate two Herfindahl indexes to measure rental market concentration. One Herfindahl defines market share over total county rental expenditure, the 36 other defines market share over the total number of rented acres. I interact these measures with the change in government payments in order to determine whether the marginal effect of subsidies changes as rental markets become less concentrated. The results from this exercise are found in Table 9. If rental market imperfections do not play a role, I should see no relationship between the incidence and rental market concentration. These results suggest that I can safely reject the null hypothesis that the subsidy incidence is not related to rental market concentration. Nearly every measure of concentration returns a sign and magnitude that is consistent with the alternative hypothesis that subsidy incidence decreases with rental market concentration. For instance, the first row of Table 9 indicates that if all farms in a county rented land the incidence would increase to about 25 percent. These findings suggest that rental market imperfection is a plausible explanation for the incidence finding reported above. 8 Variable Factors of Production Agricultural subsidies are defacto specific subsidies to land. As such, they serve to reduce the rental price of land. A 20 percent subsidy incidence on landlords, as found above, implies that the marginal per-acre subsidy dollar lowers the rental rate by 80 cents. By lowering the rental rate of land, the subsidy changes the relative prices of the factors of production. The altered relative prices will have an indeterminate impact on the use of non- land inputs. Because the relative price of non-land inputs has increased, producers will substitute away from them toward the relatively cheaper land. At the same time, since total costs are lower, the farmer may expand output and demand more non-land variable inputs. The net result on the non-land factors of production is theoretically ambiguous. 37 The subsidy will directly affect the demand for land. Facing a lower rental rate, farmers will rent more acres. The first row of Table 10 supports this implication. Since the number of rented acres will have a mechanical, negative relationship with the subsidy per acre, the rented acres are regressed on the total subsidy. One should thus interpret the coefficient as the change in rented acres due to the marginal subsidy dollar rather than the marginal subsidy dollar per acre. The results of this estimation suggest that increasing the subsidy by one dollar per acre (a total increase of $1,040 for the median farm) leads to between one and three more acres rented. This result supports the theoretical prediction about the direct effect of subsidies. I measure the indirect effect of subsidies on non-land variable factors of production by applying the empirical strategy developed above to expenditures on 13 variable factors of production. The data on variable input expenditures are reported by those returning the census long form. Using the same sample of cash renters as above, I treat the expenditure on each input as the dependent variable and estimate the effect of subsidies using equation (9). The appropriate specification in this setting differs slightly from that used above in order to adequately account for the trend in expenditures. The time-varying county effect not only captures local shocks, but also accounts for the county-specific trend in expenditure. If the expenditure trend is proportional to the farm size then the per-acre transformation is sufficient for the county effect to capture the change. However, if the trend is proportional to total expenditures and not to farm size then a log-log specification would be preferred. reason that factor expenditure proportional to the acres farmed. growth for livestock It stands to and feed, for instance, will not be Therefore, a more appropriate specification is the log-log model. 38 Table 10 reports the OLS coefficient on government payments for each of the 13 factor expenditure regressions and for a total expenditure regression. All of the regressions include a complete set of covariates as specified earlier. For comparison purposes, column one reports the results from the per-acre specification. The largest response comes from expenditures that are least likely to grow in proportion to farm size, such as livestock and feed. Column two of Table 10 reports the elasticity estimates from a log-log specification. Columns three and four report the incidence which is calculated by evaluating each elasticity at the mean and median of the dependent and independent variables. Using OLS, I estimate that the marginal subsidy dollar result in a 35 cent increase of total variable factor expenditures. Expenditures might also suffer from expectation error in much the same way as rental rates. To account for this, I instrument for the change in government payments using the 1992 set-aside acres and the 1997 government payments. Table 11 reports the IV estimates. The estimate is essentially unchanged from the OLS. The indirect effect of the subsidy increases expenditure on variable factors by about 35 cents, revealing a positive production response to the factor-specific subsidy. This response is consistent with the cost of farming an additional acre of land. As noted above, increasing the subsidy payment by one dollar per acre for the median farm would increase the total subsidy payment by $1,040 and result in about one more acre rented. The average cost of farming an acre of land, according to the summary statistics in Table 1, is about $385. The expenditure results imply that an extra $1,040 subsidy results in $365 more dollars spent on other variable factors of production, an amount consistent with the cost of farming one additional acre. This result is noteworthy since under WTO rules subsidies are allowed if they are nondistortionary. The evidence presented here suggests that these subsidies might not meet that criterion. 39 9 Tenant's Incidence The above analysis found landlords capturing 20 cents of the marginal subsidy dollar, and tenants increasing expenditures on variable inputs by 35 cents. Yet the question of how the subsidy ultimately affects the tenant remains. If variable inputs are perfectly elastically supplied, and the farmer is a risk-neutral profit maximizer, then one would expect the farmer's net returns to increase by at least 80 cents. incidence on the tenant. The production response should not dissipate the subsidy Using the same empirical strategy as the one detailed in section 5, I measure the tenant's incidence by regressing net returns on government payments. Here the instrumental variable strategy is slightly different. There is no expectation error associated with the dependent variable in this specification; net returns are calculated as the total revenue (including government payments) less total variable costs. However, measurement error in the 1992 subsidy measure remains. Fortunately, for the same economic reasons as above, the 1997 subsidy level is an appropriate instrument for the change. Namely, the cross-sectional variation in 1997 subsidy payments accurately reflects the variation in program yield and base acres, and these parameters are independent of the component of 1992 subsidies that suffers from measurement error. Table 12 reports the ultimate effect of the marginal subsidy dollar on the farmer's net returns. As with the other estimates, the IV in columns three and four results are slightly larger the OLS results in columns one and two, but the result is consistent. Tenants ultimately benefit one for one from the marginal subsidy dollar. The production response outlined above seems to be sufficient to make up for the 20 cents extracted by the landlord. 40 10 Conclusion This paper has investigated the direct effect of agricultural subsidies on farmland rental rates, the indirect effect on other factors of production, and the ultimate effect on the farm operator. In the investigation, I have overcome three significant obstacles: unobserved heterogeneity, simultaneity, and expectation errors. Using a nationally representative dataset of individual farms, I have controlled for unobserved heterogeneity with fixed effects. I exploited the 1996 FAIR Act to account for any concern about simultaneity bias, and I used IV techniques to overcome measurement and expectation error, thereby identifying the effect of subsidies on rental rates. The analyses are based on individual-level data from 1992 and 1997, years that bracket the 1996 policy change. The evidence on the incidence of agricultural subsidies demonstrates that some, but not all, of the subsidy is passed to landlords. The point estimates suggest that, on average, about 20 cents of the marginal subsidy dollar per acre are passed to landowners in the form of higher rents. Considering that 94 percent of landlords are not farmers, this incidence implies that if all subsidy recipients were tenant farmers, then non-farmer landlords would have received about $1.1 billion of the $5.5 billion in agricultural subsidies paid to farmers in 1997, signifying a "leakage" of 20 percent. Of course, not all subsidy recipients are tenants, and the distribution of subsidy payments between tenants and owners will result in a lower leakage. Overall, a vast majority of the aid to farmers stays in the farm sector. Evidence was presented indicating that tenants ultimately benefit one-for-one from the marginal subsidy dollar. Farm policy appears to accomplish its stated purpose to increase farmers' income. The evidence presented in this paper also demonstrates the production effects caused by agricultural subsidies. Because incidence is incomplete and the subsidy is factor-specific, the 41 marginal subsidy dollar effectively reduces the farmland rental rate by 80 cents. In response, farmers rent more land and purchase more variable inputs in order to produce a crop on the extra acreage. Overall, the marginal subsidy dollar increases variable factor expenditures by 35 cents. As a result of the production response, farmers ultimately benefit one-for-one from the marginal subsidy dollar. These results provide a first step in accurately characterizing the farmland rental market. The body of literature that has investigated the effect of government payments on land values has typically assumed full incidence because land has a zero elasticity of supply while all other factor inputs are supplied with infinite elasticity. However, this paper's results show that in the short-run such an assumption is untenable. Future work should investigate the role played by market imperfections or sticky prices in the farmland rental market. Imperfect rental markets provide a plausible explanation; the evidence presented suggests that the incidence may increase to twenty-five percent if all farmers within a county were tenants. A large presence of long-term tenant-landlord relationships might cause rental rates to adjust slowly. Incidence may be higher in the long run as rents adjust when new tenant-landlord relationships are formed, but the time frame of this analysis could be too short to capture this occurrence. 42 References Allen, D.W. and D. Lueck. 1992. "The 'Back Forty' on a Handshake: Specific Assets, Reputation, and the Structure of Farmland Contracts." The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 8(2), 366-376. Alston, J.M. 1986. "An Analysis of Growth of U.S. Farmland Prices, 1963-82." American Journal ofAgricultural Economics 68(1), 1-9. Barnard, C.H., G. Whittaker, D. Westenbarger, and M. Ahearn. 1997. "Evidence of Capitalization of Direct Government Payments into U.S. Cropland Values." American Journal of AgriculturalEconomics79(5), 1642-1650. Chambers, R.G. 1995. "The Incidence of Agricultural Policies." Journal of Public Economics 57, 317-35. Duffy, P.A., C.R. Taylor, D.L. Cain, and G.J. Young. 1994. "The Economic Value of Farm Program Base." Land Economics 70(3), 318-29. Goodwin, B.K. and F. Ortalo-Magne. 1992. "The Capitalization of Wheat Subsidies into Agricultural Land Values." Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 40, 37-54. Goodwin, B.K., A. Mishra, and F. Ortalo-Magne, 2004. "Landowners' of Agricultural Subsidies." Working Paper http://research.bus.wisc.edu/fom/documents/lr-latest.pdf Riches: The Distribution downloaded from Hoch, I. 1958. "Simultaneous Equations Bias in the Context of the Cobb-Douglass Production Function." Econometrica 30, 566-578. Hoch, I. 1962. "Estimation of Production Function Parameters Combining Time Series and Cross-Section Data." Econometrica 30, 34-53. Hoppe, R.A. and P. Korb. 2001. "Farm Operations Facing Development: Results from the Census Longitudinal File." Presented at the Symposium: "Urbanization and Agriculture: Measuring Urban Influence and Its Impact on Farmland Values and Costs of Production. " AAEA 2001 Annual Meeting. Lence, S.H. and A.K. Mishra. 2003. "The Impact of Different Farm Programs on Cash Rents." American Journal ofAgricultural Economics 85, 753-61. Melichar, E. 1979. "Capital Gains versus Current Income in the Farming Sector." American Journal ofAgricultural Economics 61(Dec.), 1086-1106. Morehart, M., J. Ryan, and R. Green. 2001. "Farm Income and Finance: The Importance of Government Payments." Presented at the Agricultural Outlook Forum, 2001. 43 Moss, C.B., G. Livanis, V. Breneman, and R.F. Nehring. 2002. "Productivity versus Urban Sprawl: Spatial Variations in Land Values." In Agricultural Productivity: Measurement and Sources of Growth, V.E. Ball and G.W. Norton, eds. Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 1 1 7-33. Mundlak, Y. 1961. "Empirical Production Function Free of Management Bias." Journal of Farm Economics 43, 44-56. Robison, L.J., D.A. Lins, and R. VenKataraman. 1985. "Cash Rents and Land Values in U.S. Agriculture." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67(4), 794-805. Sotomayer, N.L., P.N. Ellinger, and P.J. Barry. 2000. "Choice among Leasing Contracts in Farm Real Estate." Agricultural Finance Review 60, 71-84. Staiger, D. and J.H. Stock. 1997. "Instrumental Variables Regression with Weak Instruments." Econometrica 65(3), 557-86. Orden, D., R. Paarlberg, and T. Roe. 1999. Policy Reform in American Agriculture. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press. U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service. 1996. Agricultural Statistics 1996 Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service. 2001a. Agricultural Statistics 2001 Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service. 2001b. "1997 Census of Agriculture: Agricultural Economics and Land Ownership Survey (1999)." Vol. 3, Special Studies, Part IV. Weersink, A., S. Clark, C.G. Turvey, and R. Sarker. 1999. "The Effect of Agricultural Policy on Farmland Values." Land Economics 75(3), 425-439. 44 11 Appendix 1 The census of agriculture reports the total cash rent paid and the total number of acres rented on a cash, share, or free basis. I use the ratio of these variables to construct the rental rates variable, which is the dependent variable in the primary analysis. Because the number of acres rented for cash are not reported separately constructed from the number rented for a share of production, cash rental rate may be smaller than the true cash rental rate. the The induced measurement error is not classical measurement error because it has a positive expected value. Formally, the true cash rental rate, r,*, equals the calculated cash rental rate, ri,, plus measurement error, pit: ri, = ri+ , Since the calculated cash rental rate is less than or equal to the true cash rental rate, r, 2>r,, the measurement error must be greater than or equal to zero, E(u, ) 2 0, with equality only when all farms cash rent only, i.e., when there is no measurement error. The potential inconsistency due to the non-classical measurement error can be seen using the estimating equation: , f, + C,+J, . rJ=r, + ,Ui, =:a + gr + ,Xi+ To see the source of inconsistency, write the linear projection of the measurement error, pit, onto government payments, git, observed farm characteristics, Xi,, and a county fixed effect, z,: Uit= o0+ l g ,, + 2X, +r, +vit. 0 Substituting into the estimating equation and rearranging yields: ri, = (a - )+ ( - )gi, + ( - 45 2 )Xi, + f, + (C, - , )+ 1c , + Vo,. This equation illustrates the possible inconsistency. When the measurement error is ignored the plim of the coefficient on government payments is: plim = 7- I. If government payments are positively correlated with the non-classical measurement error, i.e. lI>0, the estimate will be biased downward. I investigate this source of bias using the 1999 Agricultural Economics and Land Ownership Survey, which sampled over 26,000 farms nationwide and asked detailed questions about the farm operation, including the number of acres rented for cash and the total rent paid on those acres, and the number of acres rented for a share of production and the value of the share of production paid on those acres. Using the data from this survey I construct the 'true' cash rental rate by dividing the total cash rent paid by the acres rented for cash. I reproduce the rental rate variable used in the main analysis by dividing the total cash rent paid by the acres rented for cash summed with the acres rented for a share of production. The difference between the true cash rental rate and the rental rate variable used in the main analysis is an estimate of the non-classical measurement error. By regressing the calculated non-classical measurement error on the per-acre government payments, observable farm characteristics, and a county fixed effect I estimate the magnitude and direction of the potential bias. Appendix table 1 contains the results of that analysis. The population of interest consists of farms that either cash and share rent or cash rent only. These criteria resulted in a sample size of 11,924. It should be noted that on average there are about 5 farms per county in this analysis, resulting in less power for the county fixed effects. Columns 1 and 2 report the results when there are no fixed effects and when there are state-level fixed effects, respectively. In each of these specifications the coefficient on government payments in statistically significant, equaling 0.06 without fixed effects and 0.03 with state-level fixed 46 effects. These results imply that if one assumes that the measurement error is independent of unobserved county fixed effects, such as local institutional factors, the primary results in the paper should be increased by 0.06, resulting in an incidence estimate of 0.24. Column 3 of appendix table 1 reports the most general specification controlling for local unobserved heterogeneity with county fixed effects. The result is a statistically insignificant coefficient of .00329 on the government payment variable. Based on this estimate one cannot reject the null hypothesis that government payments and the non-classical measurement error are uncorrelated, hence the primary estimates reported in the paper are consistent. 47 Table 1 Summary Statistics: U.S. Census of Agriculture Micro Files Program Crop Producers Sampled Renters N=437,979 N=58,302 Mean Variable Size (Acres) Sales ($/Acre) Expenditures ($/Acre) Irrigated Acres Proportion in Pasture Proportion Irrigated Proportion in Cropland Subsidies ($) (including zeros) Subsidies ($) (exluding zeros) Subsidies ($/ Acre) (including zeros) Subsidies ($/ Acre) (exluding zeros) Rental Rate ($/ Acre) Median Year (1) (2) 1992 1997 1992 1997 1992 1997 1992 1997 1992 1997 1992 1997 1992 1997 1992 1997 1992 1997 1992 1997 1992 1997 1992 1997 712.988 737.155 282.923 329.000 632.886 227.470 494.116 47.803 54.290 0.182 0.195 0.058 0.060 0.802 0.769 5,621.83 5,148.58 9,497.64 7,987.03 8.116 14.338 13.712 22.242 n/a n/a Mean (3) 325.000 163.288 182.471 127.567 137.000 0.000 0.000 0.063 0.057 0.000 0.000 0.900 0.880 1,124.00 1,345.00 4,800.00 4,128.00 3.391 4.418 10.188 9.767 n/a n/a Median (4) 1,638.330 1,743.750 1,040.000 1,116.000 465.250 483.460 369.717 385.997 299.546 303.898 233.362 230.172 138.924 161.452 0.135 0.133 0.100 0.000 0.000 0.015 0.008 0.000 0.106 0.000 0.821 0.824 17,234.20 14,287.55 22,643.12 17,918.44 12.947 11.085 17.011 13.902 0.912 0.921 10,393.93 9,919.00 15,447.56 13,900.00 9.514 9.000 13.541 11.687 47.605 34.468 50.123 36.543 Notes: The sample consists of all farms that returned the Census of Agriculture's long form in both 1992 & 1997, payed cash rent in both years, and reported growing program crops in 1992. There are 58,302 farms in each year of the sample. All monetary values have been adjusted to 1997 dollars. 48 Table 2 - Annual Cross Sections Effect of Subsidies on Farmland Rental Rates Dep Var: Farm Average Rental Rate ($/acre) Farm Level Analysis No Controls 0.463 ** (0.013) 0.309 (0.015) 0.033 (0.009) -0.029 (0.010) -0.452 (0.095) Costs Farm Size (Acres) Proportion Irrigated Proportion Pasture ** 0.261 County Fixed Effects and Covariates (4) (3) (2) A. 1992 Cross Section (1) Government Payments Sales Covariat es County Fixed Effects ** (0.012) 0.199 (0.013) 0.021 (0.001) -0.019 (0.001) -0.200 (0.064) ** ** ** ** ** 22.282 ** 29.985 ** (1.073) -33.222 (1.168) (1.377) -14.006 (1.463) ** 0.320 ** ** B. 1997 Cross Section Government Payments Sales 0.946 ** (0.022) 0.019 (0.004) -0.013 (0.003) -0.295 (0.052) Farm Size (Acres) Proportion Irrigated Proportion Pasture 0.645 (0.000) ** ** ** ** ** ** (0.017) 0.011 (0.001) -0.008 (0.001) -0.086 (0.064) ** ** 23.441 ** 27.648 ** (1.072) -33.341 (1.343) (1.422) -16.732 (1.553) ** C. Pooled Cross Sections 0.371 ** 0.303 ** (0.010) (0.012) 0.022 ** (0.004) Costs -0.017 ** Farm Size (Acres) (0.004) -0.372 (0.050) Proportion Irrigated Proportion Pasture 0.424 (0.017) (0.022) Costs Government Payments Sales 0.493 ** 23.284 ** (0.762) -33.097 (0.907) ** 0.230 (0.010) 0.014 (0.000) -0.011 (0.000) -0.141 (0.045) 29.251 (0.978) -14.888 (1.052) ** ** ** ** ** ** ** long formin both 1992& 1997, Notes: The sampleconsistsof all farmsthat returnedtheCensusof Agriculture's payedcashrent in both years,and reportedgrowingprogramcropsin 1992. Thereare 58,302farmsin eachyearof standarderrors areshowninparentheses. The dependentvariableiscash the sample. Heteroskedasticity-robust rentalrate. Whenincluded,thecovariatesare the 1992values;the 1997valuesare not includedbecausetheyare potentialoutcomes. The controlsarethe 1992valuesof per-acresales,per-acrevariablecostsexcludingrent, farm size ( 1,000sof acres),proportionof farmlandthat is irrigated,proportionof farmlandin pastureor range,proportion of total fannacres plantedto corn, wheat,oats, barley,sorghum,cotton,rice,soybeans,other grains& beans,hayand seeds,vegetables,fruits& nuts, and other crops. Allmonetaryvalueshavebeenadjustedto 1997dollars. ** indicatessignificanceat 99thpercentile. 49 Table 3 - Individual Farm Effects Estimates Dependent Variable: 1992 - 1997 Change in the Cash Rental Rate Random Effects Farm Fixed Effects (1) Government Payments Sales 0.408 (2) ** (0.009) 0.183 (0.061) Costs Farm Size (Acres) Proportion Irrigated Proportion Pasture Hausman Test p -value County x Time Effects (3) ** 0.183 Time Effect (4) ** 0.172 (0.018) -0.008 (0.018) -0.007 (0.005) 0.007 (0.006) 0.006 (0.006) (0.007) 0.099 0.109 (0.055) -5.269 (1.958) -4.678 (0.051) 1.038 (1.321) -1.790 (1.845) ** ** ** (1.564) 1033.100 (0.000) Notes: The sample consists of all farms that returned the Census of Agriculture's long form in both 1992 & 1997, payed cash rent in both years, and reported growing program crops in 1992. There are 58,302 farms in each year of the sample. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. The dependent variable is the change in the cash rental rate, except in the random effects model where the dependent variable is the cash rental rate. When included, the covariates are the 1992 values; the 1997 values are not included because they are potential outcomes. The controls are the 1992 values of per-acre sales, per-acre variable costs excluding rent, farm size (1,000s of acres), proportion of farmland that is irrigated, proportion of farmland in pasture or range, proportion of total farm acres planted to corn, wheat, oats, barley, sorghum, cotton, rice, soybeans, other grains & beans, hay and seeds, vegetables, fruits & nuts, and other crops. All dollars have been inflated to 1997 dollars. ** indicates significance at 99th percentile. 50 Table 4 - Farm Effects IV Estimates 1992 Set-aside and 1997 Subsidy as Instruments No Covariates Covariates (1) 1997 Government Payments 1992 Set-Aside Acres Sales 0.830 (0.005) -327.517 (2.771) Costs Farm Size Proportion Irrigated Proportion Pasture First Stage F-stat R2 Government Payments Sales 20,011 0.31 0.186 (0.020) Costs Farm Size Proportion Irrigated Proportion Pasture Overidentification Test p -value 20.77 0.00 (2) A. First Stage ** 0.902 (0.004) ** -323.647 (2.636) 0.0005 (0.0002) -0.0007 (0.0003) 0.1527 (0.0183) -3.112 (0.3941) 3.644 (0.4185) 2,057 ** ** ** ** ** ** ** 0.51 B. IV Estimates ** 0.214 (0.019) -0.0075 (0.0011) 0.0065 (0.0013) 0.098 (0.0808) -4.953 (1.7449) -4.778 (1.8513) 21.25 0.38 ** ** ** ** ** Notes: The sample consists of all farms that returned the Census of Agriculture's long form in both 1992 & 1997, payed cash rent in both years, and reported growing program crops in 1992. There are 58,302 farms in each year of the sample. Standard errors are shown in parentheses. The dependent variable is the change in the cash rental rate. All specifications include a farm fixed effect and a time-varying county fixed effect. The instruments are the proportion of the farm enrolled in set-aside in 1992 and the per-acre subsidies in 1997. When included, the covariates are the 1992 values of the variable; the 1997 values are not included because they are potential outcomes. The controls are the 1992 values of per-acre sales, per-acre variablecosts excluding rent, farm size (1,000s of acres), proportion of farmland that is irrigated, proportion of farmland in pasture or range, proportion of total farm acres planted to corn, wheat, oats, barley, sorghum, cotton, rice, soybeans, other grains & beans, hay and seeds, vegetables, fruits & nuts, and other crops. All dollars have been inflated to 1997 dollars. In panel A, the F-statistic is for the test of whether the coefficients on the instruments are jointly equal to zero. In panel B, the F-statistic is for the test of overidentifying restrictions. **indicates significance at the 99th percentile. 51 Table 5 - Region Summary Statistics Rental Rate Subsidy per Acre Mean Median Mean Median Region Heartland N=18,920 Northern Crescent 1992 1997 (1) 55.28 60.28 (2) 48.84 53.92 (3) 13.62 13.79 (4) 12.51 12.77 1992 1997 49.75 50.06 39.43 38.87 9.11 8.83 5.04 6.87 Northern Great Plains N=6, 198 1992 1997 25.85 25.08 16.83 18.07 9.01 6.53 7.66 5.54 Prarie Gateway 1992 1997 19.50 19.68 10.79 10.81 10.84 7.94 7.87 5.98 1992 1997 28.48 25.40 19.45 17.05 6.85 5.49 0.00 2.11 1992 1997 53.24 51.55 38.99 37.50 8.69 8.40 2.00 5.19 Fruitful Rim N=3,358 1992 1997 70.75 73.45 53.45 55.56 22.15 14.01 7.77 7.18 Basin and Range 1992 1997 42.80 42.62 24.00 20.71 6.90 5.43 1.59 2.00 1992 1997 35.88 34.75 28.48 26.43 27.29 16.74 20.46 13.68 N=10,280 N=7,049 Eastern Uplands N=1,921 Southern Seaboard N=6,250 N=1,263 Mississippi Portal N=3,063 Notes: Data are from the confidential microfiles of the Census of Agriculture. Regions are as defined by the USDA's Economic Research Service as Farm Resource Regions. 52 Table 6 - Regional Incidence Estimates OLS Region Heartland No Covariates (1) 0.274 ** (0.051) Northern Crescent 0.137 (0.056) Northern Great Plains 0.063 (0.074) Prarie Gateway 0.222 (0.044) Eastern Uplands 0.033 (0.066) Southern Seaboard 0.194 Fruitful Rim Basin and ** ** (0.134) Mississippi Portal 0.137 (0.028) Covariates (2) (3) (4) 0.288 ** 0.148 0.270 ** (0.030) ** 0.150 0.294 ** (0.030) ** 0.173 ** (0.056) (0.053) (0.053) 0.065 (0.073) 0.063 (0.068) 0.146 (0.068) ** 0.171 (0.047) ** 0.190 (0.042) 0.041 (0.072) 0.003 (0.113) ** 0.216 ** (0.055) 0.255 ** 0.315 ** (0.064) (0.064) ** 0.235 ** (0.055) (0.082) 0.006 (0.116) 0.082 (0.142) ** 0.107 (0.028) ** ** 0.121 (0.049) 0.040 Range Covariates No Covariates (0.050) (0.051) 0.221 (0.055) IV ** 0.240 0.164 (0.043) 0.074 (0.114) ** 0.259 ** (0.064) 0.087 (0.155) ** 0.166 ** (0.039) Notes:. The sample consists of all farms that returned the Census of Agriculture's long form in both 1992 & 1997, payed cash rent in both years, and reported growing program crops in 1992. There are 58,302 farms in each year of the sample. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. The dependent variable is cash rental rate. When included, the covariates are the 1992 values; the 1997 values are not included because they are potential outcomes. The controls are the 1992 values of per-acre sales, per-acre variable costs excluding rent, farm size (1,000s of acres), proportion of farmland that is irrigated, proportion of farmland in pasture or range, proportion of total farm acres planted to corn, wheat, oats, barley, sorghum, cotton, rice, soybeans, other grains & beans, hay and seeds, vegetables, fruits & nuts, and other crops. All monetary values have been adjusted to 1997 dollars. ** indicates significance at 99th percentile. 53 Table 7 - Summary Statistics by Sales Class Rental Rate Subsidy per Acre Mean Median Mean Median 1992 Sales (1) (2) (3) (4) 0.00 0.00 < $10,000 N= 2,597 1992 1997 24.56 16.41 27.65 17.05 3.01 4.94 $10,000 - $100,000 35.45 N= 31,587 1992 1997 32.97 23.71 20.63 8.87 7.53 4.15 4.37 $100,000 - $250,000 N= 5 7,091 1992 1997 41.86 44.48 30.09 32.01 12.17 10.57 8.59 8.54 $250,000 - $500,000 1992 1997 49.03 50.01 37.61 10.83 38.76 13.38 12.16 1992 1997 60.43 64.35 47.74 50.46 15.06 12.45 11.29 10.69 N= 49,222 $500,000 + N= 26,562 10.51 Notes: Data are from confidentialU.S. Census of Agriculture microfiles. Sale class taxonomy as used by the USDA Economic Research Service. Statistics weighted by sample weights developed by the USDA National Agricultural Statistical Service. Observations per sales class represent weighted totals. 54 Table 8 - Sales Class Incidence Estimates OLS No Fixed Effects 1992 Sales < $10,000 $10,000-$100,000 No Covariates Covariates (1) (2) 0.411 ** 0.195 (0.110) (0.098) 0.615 ** $250,000-$500,000 0.671 (0.018) ** 0.541 ** 0.425 (0.026) ** 0.221 0.463 (0.021) ** 0.429 ** ** 0.294 ** ** 0.190 (0.024) ** 0.171 ** 0.184 (0.031) 0.227 ** (0.055) 0.173 (0.024) ** 0.180 ** ** 0.208 (0.032) No Covariates (3) -0.207 (1.707) ** Covariates (4) -4.644 (11.708) 0.100 0.192 (0.083) (0.079) 0.152 (0.041) ** 0.177 ** 0.222 (0.046) ** 0.211 (0.038) ** 0.211 ** (0.031) (0.032) (0.023) (0.022) (0.027) IV Fixed Effects Covariates (4) -1.027 (1.826) (0.055) (0.022) (0.020) $500,000+ 0.334 No Covariates (3) -0.360 (0.852) (0.021) (0.021) $100,000- $250,000 OLS Fixed Effects ** 0.244 ** (0.045) Notes: Dependentvariableis therental rate. Columnsthreethroughsixare estimatedin firstdifferences;therethe dependentvariableis the change in farmlandrentalrates. Controls,whenincluded,are the 1992values;the 1997valuesare not includedbecausetheyarepotentialoutcomes. The controlsarethe 1992valuesof per-acresales;per-acrevariablecosts, excludingrent; farmsize ( ,000sof acres);proportionof farmlandthat is irrigated;proportionof farmlandinpasture or range;proportionof total farmacresplantedto corn, wheat,oats, barley,sorghum,cotton,rice, soybeans,othergrains & beans,hay and seeds,vegetables,fruits& nuts, and other crops;and 1992yieldof corn, wheat,oats, barley,sorghum, cotton,rice, and soybeans.All dollarshavebeen inflatedto 1997dollars. ** indicatessignificanceat 99thpercentile. Salesclasstaxonomydefined by theUSDAEconomicResearchService. 55 Table 9 - The Effect of Rental Market Concentration on the Subsidy Incidence Coefficient on Government Payments & the Interaction Term Reported OLS Main Effect Interaction Term IV Interaction (1) (2) Herfindahl Market Share = Rental Expenditures -0.090 (0097 (0.097) 0.213 (0.044) -0.042 -0.042 (0.065) 0.147 (0.034) 0.400 (0.40) (0.140) -0.242 (0.122) 0.368 0.368 (0.114) -0.077 (0.112) Herfindahl Market Share = Acres Rented 0.220 (0.026) Proportion of Farmers who are Tenants Tenant-Landlord Ratio Proportion of Farm Land that is Rented ** ** ** -0.162 (0.038) ** ** ** Main Effect Interaction (3) (4) 0.009 (0.020) (0.020) 0.048 (0.021) 0.019 0.019 (0.019) 0.135 (0.016) 0.246 (0.026) (0.026) 0.338 (0.052) 0.275 0.275 (0.027) 0.148 (0.075) 0.170 (0.021) ** ** ** -0.050 (0.025) ** ** ** * * Notes: The sample consists of all farms that returned the Census of Agriculture's long form in both 1992 & 1997, payed cash rent in both years, and reported growing program crops in 1992. There are 58,302 farms in each year of the sample. Heteroskedasticityrobust standard errors are shown in parentheses. The dependent variable is change in the cash rental rate. The interaction terms are county level measures of rental market concentration. The Herfindahl indexes treat market share as a farm's proportion of total rental expenditure in the county, and a farms proportion of the total acres rented in the county. The instruments are the per-acre subsidies in 1997 and the per-acre subsidies in 1997 interacted with the measure of rental market concentration . All monetary values have been adjusted to 1997 dollars. ** indicates significance at 99th percentile. 56 Table 10 Effect of Subsidies on Variable Factor Expenditures - OLS Regressions Coefficient on Government Payments Reported . Log-log Specification Incidence Incidence at the at the Mean Median OLS (3) (4) Acres 0.003 ** (0.000) 0.011 ** (0.000) 0.001 0.001 Livestock 0.218 (0.099) 0.571 (0.131) 0.035 (0.005) 0.075 (0.007) 0.078 (0.006) 0.043 (0.005) 0.010 (0.004) 0.027 (0.003) 0.020 (0.002) 0.024 (0.002) 0.044 (0.003) 0.014 (0.001) 0.026 0.000 0.077 0.009 ** 0.022 0.023 ** 0.051 0.053 ** 0.079 0.068 ** 0.016 0.018 0.020 ** 0.008 0.006 ** 0.072 0.042 ** 0.031 0.033 ** 0.022 0.008 ** 0.066 0.066 ** 0.006 0.005 0.016 ** 0.033 0.027 0.339 0.349 Dependent Variable Feed Seed Fertilizer Chemicals Fuel Electricity Labor Repair Machine Rental Interest Property Taxes (2) (1) ** ** ** ** ** ** 0.014 ** (0.004) 0.074 ** (0.022) 0.061 ** (0.009) 0.016 (0.012) 0.092 ** (0.015) 0.004 (0.004) 0.098 ** (0.002) 0.030 (0.004) 0.021 (0.002) 0.041 (0.005) 0.042 (0.003) 0.015 (0.002) Other Expenditures (0.040) (0.001) Total Variable Factors 1.289 ** (0.251) 0.016 (0.001) ** Notes: The sample consists of all farms that returned the Census of Agriculture's long form in both 1992& 1997, payed cash rent in both years, and reported growing program crops in 1992. There are 58,302 farms in each year of the sample. Standard errors are shown in parentheses. All specificationsinclude covariates from 1992; the 1997 values are not included because they are potential outcomes. The controls are the 1992 values of per-acre sales, per-acre variablecosts excluding the dependent variable; farm size (l,000s of acres), proportion of farmlandthat is irrigated, proportion of farmland in pasture or range, proportion of total farm acres planted to corn, wheat, oats, barley, sorghum, cotton, rice, soybeans, other grains & beans, hay and seeds, vegetables, fruits & nuts, and other crops. Due to computationalconstratints, the robust regressions do not include the time-varyingcounty effect. The log-log specificationreports the elasticityestimates, which are evaluated at the mean and median of the subsidyand the dependent variableto obtain the incidence estimates. All monetary values have been adjusted to 1997 dollars. ** indicates significanceat 99th percentile. 57 Table 11 - Effect of Subsidies on Variable Factor Expenditures IV Results - 1992 Log Set-aside and 1997 Log Subsidies Instruments Coefficient on Log Government Payments Reported Log-log Specification No Covariates Dependent Variable Acres Livestock Feed Seed Fertilizer Chemicals Fuel Electricity Labor (1) Incidence at Incidence at the Mean th,e Median (2) (3) 0.002 0.002 0.025 0.025 ** 0.095 0.095 ** 0.030 0.030 ** 0.069 0.069 ** 0.083 0.083 ** 0.021 0.021 ** 0.009 0.009 0.039 ** 0.095 0.095 0.037 0.037 ** 0.025 0.025 ** 0.070 0.070 ** 0.008 0.008 0.015 (0.001) 0.009 (0.005) 0.033 (0.004) 0.027 (0.002) 0.032 (0.002) 0.046 (0.004) 0.019 (0.001) 0.023 (0.003) (0.004) Repair 0.026 ** Other Expenditures (0.002) 0.047 (0.006) 0.044 (0.004) 0.021 (0.003) 0.021 (0.002) ** 0.044 0.044 Total Variable Factors 0.019 ** (0.001) 0.399 0.399 Machine Rental Interest Property Taxes Covariates Incidence at Incidence at the Mean the Median (5) (6) 0.002 0.002 0.020 0.000 ** 0.088 0.010 ** 0.029 0.029 ** 0.063 0.064 ** 0.085 0.074 ** 0.018 0.021 ** 0.008 0.005 ** 0.081 0.047 ** 0.032 0.034 ** 0.024 0.009 ** 0.061 0.062 ** 0.007 0.006 ** 0.038 0.031 0.017 ** (0.001) 0.351 0.362 (4) 0.020 (0.001) 0.008 (0.005) 0.030 (0.004) 0.025 (0.002) 0.029 (0.002) 0.047 (0.004) 0.016 (0.001) 0.019 (0.003) 0.033 (0.004) 0.022 (0.002) 0.045 (0.006) 0.039 (0.004) 0.017 (0.003) 0.018 (0.002) Notes: The sample consists of all farms that returned the Census of Agriculture's long form in both 1992 & 1997, payed cash rent in both years, and reported growing program crops in 1992. There are 58,302 farms in each year of the sample. Standard errors are shown in parentheses. Farm and time-varying county effects are included in all specifications. The instruments are the log of acres in the farm enrolled in set-aside in 1992 and the log of subsidies in 1997. When included, the covariates are from 1992; the 1997 values are not included because they are potential outcomes. The controls are the 1992 values of peracre sales, per-acre variable costs excluding the dependent variable; farm size (1,000s of acres), proportion of farmland that is irrigated, proportion of farmland in pasture or range, proportion of total farm acres planted to corn, wheat, oats, barley, sorghum, cotton, rice, soybeans, other grains & beans, hay and seeds, vegetables, fruits & nuts, and other crops. All monetary values have been adjusted to 1997 dollars. ** indicates significance at 99th percentile. 58 Table 12 Effect of Subsidies on Net Returns Dependent Variable: Net Returns ($/Acre) OLS IV (1) Government Payments Farm Size 0.959 (0.086) 0.976 Pasture No (3) ** (0.089) 0.656 (0.576) 27.500 Irrigated Acreage Controls (2) ** 1.076 ** (0.128) (4) 1.080 ** (0.124) 0.660 (0.576) 27.647 ** ** (11.494) (11.494) -22.202 ** (11.240) -22.462 ** (11.242) Yes No Yes Notes. Net returns here are total sales plus subsidies minus total variable costs. The instruments are the 1992 proportion of the farm enrolled in set-aside and the 1997 peracre subsidy. The sample consists of all farms that returned the Census of Agriculture's long form in both 1992 & 1997 and reported growing program crops and paying cash rent in both years. There are 58,302 farms in the sample. Acreage controls are the 1992 total farm acres planted to corn, wheat, oats, barley, sorghum, cotton, rice, soybeans, other grains & beans, hay and seeds, vegetables, and fruits & nuts. A farm fixed effect, year effect, and time-varying county fixed effect are included. Standard errors are shown in parentheses. ** indicates significance at 99th percentile. 59 Appendix Table 1 - Sample Selection Correction Dependent Variable: 1992 - 1997 Change in the Cash Rental Rate (1) Government Payments 0.181 Inverse Mills Ratio Include Crop-Mix Covariates In Second (2) ** 0.295 (0.017) (0.075) 5.174 64.587 (5.864) (38.525) N Y ** Stage? Notes: The sample consists of all farms that returned the Census of Agriculture's long form, reported growing program crops, and cash rented in 1992. There are 151,534 farms in the sample. The coefficients reported are from the second step in a Heckman two-step sample selection correction model. The dependent variable is the change in the cash rental rate. When included, the covariates are the 1992 values; the 1997 values are not included because they are potential outcomes. The controls are the 1992 values of per-acre sales, per-acre variable costs excluding rent, farm size (1,000s of acres), proportion of farmland that is irrigated, proportion of farmland in pasture or range, proportion of total farm acres planted to corn, wheat, oats, barley, sorghum, cotton, rice, soybeans, other grains & beans, hay and seeds, vegetables, fruits & nuts, and other crops. Model 1 identifies off of the exclusion restriction; model 2 identifies off of the non-linearity of the inverse Mills ratio. All dollars have been inflated to 1997 dollars. ** indicates significance at 99th percentile. 60 AppendixTable 2 - Non-Classical Measurement Error Dependent Variable: Calculated Measurement Error from 1999 AELOS (1) (2) ** 0.033 (3) Government 0.066 ** 0.003 Payments (0.008) (0.006) (0.006) Fixed Effects N None 11,924 State 11,924 County 11,924 Notes. The data are from the 1999 Agricultural Economics and Land Ownership Survey. The sample consists of all farms that reported cash renting or both cash and share renting. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. The dependent variable is constructed as the difference between the cash rental rate, and the total cash rent paid divided by the sum of the acres cash rented and the acres share rented. The covariates are the amount of sales per acre, the total cost per acres excluding rent, the value of assets per acre, the value of debt per acre, and the value of new machinery per acre. All dollars have been deflated to 1997 dollars. ** indicates significance at 99th percentile. 61 62 Chapter 2 Adversity and the Propensity to Fail: The Impact of Disaster Payments and Multiple Peril Crop Insurance on U.S. Farm Failure Rates 1 Introduction "Crop insuranceand a systemof storagereserveswouldhelp to protect the incomeof individualfarmers againstthe hazardsof cropfailure; it wouldhelp to protect consumersagainstshortages offood supply and againstextremesofprices; andfinally, it would assist in providing a morenearly evenflow offarm supplies,thus stabilizingfarm buyingpower and contributingto the securityof businessand employment." - Franklin D. Roosevelt, February 18, 1937 A key purpose of government-provided insurance is to help recipients smooth income or consumption during adversity. Thus, the marginal contribution of government-provided insurance may be small when there are many other means of risk management. Farmers in particular have a myriad of risk management devices such as self-insurance through savings, crop diversification, and many financial instruments and contract types, to name a few. Although much research has examined adverse selection and moral hazard in crop insurance markets, few have addressed the income smoothing and business security benefits of this program. As policy makers seek the optimal size, scope, and program design, they require information on both the costs and the benefits of crop insurance, as well as the effectiveness of various crop insurance designs. Recent legislation focused on crop insurance demonstrates the salience of this information. Weather events have always played a significant role in the decline in the number of farms in the U.S. Spurred by the 1862 Homestead Act, the number of farms in the U.S. grew 63 rapidly from 2 million in 1862 to 6.5 million in 1917. From 1917-1921 farmers in the newly settled Midwest and Great Plains experienced their first major drought, which slowed the growth in the number of farms. As demonstrated in figure 2, the number of farms in the U.S. peaked in 1935 and declined precipitously until the last decade when numbers have leveled off at about 2 million farms.'8 As vividly captured in Steinbeck's Grapes of Wrath, the decade long drought that caused the Dust Bowl in the 1930s contributed greatly to the initial decline in farms in the late 1930s. More recently, major weather events such as the 1988 drought in the Midwest and the 1993 flooding in the Midwest have captured media attention and galvanized support for the family farmer. The popular perspective on the declining number of farms overlooks the economic efficiency brought about through farm failure. Economists since Hayek and Schumpeter have recognized the economic benefits of reallocating productive resources from inefficient firms to efficient firms. The near century-long decline in farm numbers is due in no small part to rapid technological advancement and shifting factor prices (Barkley 1990; Huffman and Evenson 2001). Thus, from an efficiency standpoint the declining number of farms is not particularly disconcerting, but the relative increase in the decline due to temporary shocks, such as weather shocks, may be a source of concern. Credit market imperfections may prevent viable firms from smoothing temporary shocks, resulting in inefficient failures due to adverse shocks. An important element of perfect credit markets is the existence of state-contingent contracts, e.g. insurance. For instance, in the presence of liquidity constraints efficient firms benefit from the ability to insure against temporary adverse shocks (Kiyotaki and Moore 1999; Krishnamurthy 2003). The absence of insurance contracts, for instance due to asymmetric 18 Since 1974, the definition of a farm has been based on $1,000 worth of agricultural production, a nominal amount whose real value has eroded thereby liberalizing the definition of a farm and contributing to the apparent leveling off of farm numbers. 64 information, may be a market imperfection leading to inefficient farm turnover. In this case, government-provided insurance increases efficiency by overcoming the market failure and allowing viable farms to smooth temporary shocks. Insurance market failures due to adverse selection provide the key motive for government intervention. The government addresses these insurance market failures in a number of different ways. Typically, the government mandates that all individuals or all firms participate in an insurance market and pay premiums through specific taxes (e.g. Social Security for individuals and unemployment insurance for firms) or through premiums to private insurers (e.g. workers compensation). However, in the case of multiple peril crop insurance (MPCI), the government tries to entice farmers by generously subsidizing the insurance premiums paid by individuals to private insurers that are subsequently reinsured by the government. participation Due to low (about 25-percent of eligible acres in the 80s and early 90s) adverse selection continued to be a significant problem (Just et al., 1999; see Goodwin and Smith, 1995, for a comprehensive review of early studies). Moral hazard comprises another cost that influences the design of government-provided insurance programs. In the crop insurance literature investigators have focused on two moral hazard-induced types of behavior: input use and cropland choice. Several researchers examined input use, such as fertilizers and chemicals, and found that input use is negatively correlated with crop insurance (Quiggen et al., 1993; Babcock and Hennessy, 1996; Goodwin and Smith, 2003). Others have investigated the influence of crop insurance on the type and amount of land in production (Claasen et al., 2005; Wu, 1999; Goodwin et al., 2004). This body of work has generally found that crop insurance is associated with more environmentally sensitive land being brought into production. 65 In contrast to the voluminous work examining the costs associated with crop insurance, little has been done to investigate the benefits. This paper fills that gap. By exploiting random variation in weather and a major policy change in 1994, I exploit two natural experiments that identify the causal effect of crop insurance on farm failure rates. My empirical design also allows me to address crop insurance program design issues by comparing the effectiveness of crop insurance versus ad hoc, ex post disaster payments. Making this comparison also gives insight into the crop insurance induced crowd-out of other risk management behaviors. In the analysis I focus on two regimes, one primarily consisting of ex post disaster payments in 1994 and the other a purely crop insurance regime in 1995. I find that during the disaster payments regime farms experiencing a disaster are slightly less likely to fail than farms that are not hit by disaster, while under the crop insurance regime I find that disaster-stricken farms are about 1.3 percentage points more likely to fail. The lower failure rate under the disaster payment regime does not necessarily indicate that it is more efficient. In light of the 'efficient failure' argument above, the lower failure rate more likely speaks to the inefficient allocation of funds under the politically driven disaster payments regime. Garrett et al. (2003) provide evidence that key political figures allocate relatively more disaster payments to their constituents. Hence the lower failure rate may indicate that inefficient farms are being artificially propped up. Although the absolute effects of crop insurance are immeasurable without a base period free from government provided assistance, I compare the two regimes to find that farms are about 2 percentage points (30-percent) more likely to fail under mandatory crop insurance than under a program primarily consisting of ex post disaster payments. Moral hazard associated with 66 ex ante crop insurance provides a plausible explanation of the increased failure rate. Future research with more appropriate data will test this hypothesis. Although somewhat surprising, the relative effect supports the idea that government provided crop-loss assistance does not completely crowd out other means of risk management. If farmers were able to fully insure through some other means, variation in crop insurance regimes would not alter failure rates. The 30-percent relative effect suggests that government intervention can potentially play a significant role in this market. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 lays out the policy and program background. Section 3 introduces the empirical strategy. The data are discussed in section 4. Section 5 presents the empirical results. The interpretation and conclusion are put forward in section 6. 2 Background Passed as part of New Deal legislation, the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938 introduced the Federal Crop Insurance Program as a form of social insurance meant to smooth the consumption of the 32 million people living on farms in the United States. Spurred on by the decade-long drought that produced the Dust Bowl, policy makers established a national crop insurance product for wheat that insured against losses due to, "drought, flood, hail, wind, winterkill, lightning, tornado, insect infestation, plant disease, and ... other unavoidable causes..." (52 Stat. 74). Private firms had previously tried and failed to provide multiple peril crop insurance (MPCI). Owing to the geographic concentration of their policyholders, private insurance firms succumbed to geographically correlated weather events, such as drought and flooding. Private 67 insurance companies succeeded only in providing insurance for hail and fire, events that are typically spatially uncorrelated. Due to poor farm-level yield data, as well as problems with the program design, the Federal Crop Insurance Corporation (FCIC), a U.S. Department of Agriculture agency established to manage the Federal Crop Insurance Program, failed to take in more in premiums than it paid out in indemnities for the first 8 years of operation. In spite of this, while the FCIC made adjustments to the program, MPCI was extended to cotton in 1942 and flax in 1945. In 1947 crop insurance premiums finally exceeded indemnity payments. However, in that same year Congress severely reduced the program size, essentially making it an experimental program. From 1947 until 1981 the Federal Crop Insurance Program remained a relatively small experimental program; by 1980 only about half of the counties in the U.S. and just 26 crops were eligible for insurance coverage. While crop insurance was in an experimental phase, Congress pursued another method to address the crop insurance market failure. The Agriculture and Consumer Protection Act of 1973 and the Rice Production Act of 1975 established a disaster payments program, which, for some crops, overlapped with the protection provided by federal crop insurance. Essentially, disaster payments amounted to free universal coverage for a select group of crops. 19 Low-yield payments were made to farmers who participated in income- and price-support programs when yields fell below two-thirds of normal. This program was popular with farmers because it provided catastrophic coverage with no premium. However, detractors claimed that the program resulted in heavily distorted behavior. In particular, they argued that the moral hazard behavior of farmers planting on high-risk, environmentally sensitive land imposed a great cost to society. As a result, the program ended in 1981, having paid out $3.4 billion in total. 19barley, oats, corn, rice, sorghum, upland cotton, and wheat 68 The modem era of federal crop insurance began with passage of the Federal Crop Insurance Act of 1980. The Act authorized crop insurance expansion to every county in the United States with significant agriculture and to every crop with sufficient actuarial data to establish premiums. In 1981, 252 additional counties received crop insurance, resulting in 1,340 additional county programs (a county program is a particular crop-county combination). Crop insurance extended to 1,050 additional counties in 1982, adding 8,278 county programs. Crop insurance policies were consistently structured from 1980 - 1994. Producers selected from three guaranteed yield levels (50-, 65-, or 75-percent of their insurable yield) and from three guaranteed price levels. Price election levels were determined from FCIC forecasts of expected prices. The top price election level was set at 90-100 percent of the expected market price. If the producer's yield fell below the elected coverage level, the producer received an indemnity payment equal to the product of the elected price coverage and the yield shortfall. This yield shortfall was determined by the amount that actual yields fell short of the farm's insured yield. Determination of the farm's insured yield initially was based on area average yields. This method increased the adverse selection problem as the risk pool became increasingly filled with farms that had loss-risks above the area average (Skees and Reed 1986). Consequently, after 1985 a farm's insured yield was based on the preceding ten years of the farm's actual production data. Among government-provided insurance, crop insurance is unique in that it has not typically overcome adverse selection by mandating participation. Instead the Federal Crop Insurance Program has sought to entice producers to join by subsidizing premiums. From 1980 1994 the subsidy reduced premiums by 30-percent for the 50- and 65-percent coverage levels, and by about 17-percent for the 75-percent level. 69 2.1 Two Disaster-Risk Mitigation Programs The 1980 Act sought to create an insurance program that would replace disaster relief measures. However, Congress quickly established a precedent2 0 of providing ad hoc, ex post disaster relief, thereby sustaining the pattern established in the 1970s of having two parallel mechanisms for dealing with crop-loss risk: crop insurance and disaster payments. In spite of premium subsidies, enrollment in the Federal Crop Insurance Program was low and grew little through the 1980s. Table 1 contains measures of program size from 1981 - 2001. From 1981 - 1988 participation remained around 20-percent, increasing to 40-percent in 1989 only as a consequence of mandatory insurance for those receiving disaster payments in 1988. The implicit guarantee of ex post disaster payments is a key reason for the historically low participation rates. The U.S. General Accounting Office (1989) reported that, "other federal disaster assistance programs provide farmers with direct cash payments at no cost to the farmers, resulting in the perception [among farmers] that crop insurance is unnecessary." As many others have pointed out (e.g., Just et al. 1999; Glauber 2004), those who did participate were adversely selected and more likely to collect indemnity payments. Table 1 contains the annual loss ratio (indemnities paid out divided by premiums collected), which averaged 1.47 in 1981 - 1994 and dropped below 1 only in 1994. The consistent payout of more indemnities that premiums collected from 1981 - 1994 supports the idea that those who chose to purchase crop insurance 20 In 1986, a severe drought in the Southeast prompted Congress to pass supplemental disaster legislation. Then, in 1988 an extreme drought hit the Midwest, prompting congress to pass the Disaster Assistance Act of 1988 allocating $3.5 billion to producers who suffered crop loss. Congress subsequently passed 16 ad hoc, ex post facto disaster bills between 1989 - 2005. 70 expected a positive return, while those who did not chose to rely on the costless disaster payments. 2.2 The Federal Crop Insurance Reform Act of 1994 The Federal Crop Insurance Reform Act of 1994 (FCIRA) constituted the most radical change in the Federal Crop Insurance Program since coverage was expanded to all counties in 1980. The 1994 Act established a mandatory minimum level of crop insurance coverage in order for producers to qualify for any other government-sponsored program, including subsidy and credit programs. For the first time, adverse selection in the crop insurance industry was addressed through mandatory participation. All insurable crops had to have at least catastrophic coverage, which insured production losses falling below 50% of expected yield, indemnified at 60% of the expected price of the insured crop. The Act facilitated compliance by authorizing a 100% subsidy on the catastrophic insurance premiums, requiring producers to simply pay a $50 administrative fee per crop insured. 2 ' The Act also greatly expanded the options and subsidies for coverage beyond the catastrophic level, termed "buy-up" coverage. The maximum buy-up coverage level increased from 75- to 85-percent, and several tiers were added to the three coverage levels allowed earlier. The average subsidy also increased significantly. For example, the subsidy for the 65-percent yield coverage increased from 30-percent to 41.7-percent of the premium. The subsidy also varied by the coverage level under FCIRA, with the highest buy-up coverage level (85-percent) receiving a 13-percent subsidy. As with the Federal Crop Insurance Act of 1980, the stated goal of FCIRA was to eliminate ad hoc, ex post disaster payments. 21 In the subsequent three years this goal was The administrative fee was capped at $200 per producer per county with an absolute cap of $600 per producer. 71 generally accomplished with only $14 million in disaster payments made in 1995, $2 million in 1996, and none in 1997 (see table 1). However, when market conditions collapsed in 1998, Congress quickly reverted to providing disaster payments ($1.9 billion) in spite of 70-percent participation in the crop insurance program. The FCIRA was responsible for a large increase in both the number of acres insured and the level of coverage. Figure 1 illustrates the total number of acres insured from 1981 - 2003. As figure 1 illustrates, the number of insured acres increased dramatically due to the 1994 Act. The total number of acres insured increased from 99.6 million in 1994 to 220.5 million in 1995. Of these 220.5 million acres, over half, 115 million acres, were covered by the newly mandated catastrophic coverage. Coverage levels also increased as farmers took advantage of increased subsidies. Mandatory participation lasted only one year. Through the Federal Agriculture Improvement and Reform (FAIR) Act of 1996, Congress modified the crop insurance rules to allow farmers to opt out of catastrophic coverage. Table 1 and figure 1 both show a steady decline of insured acres after 1995 as farmers opted out until 1998 when 40 million fewer acres were insured. 3 Empirical Strategy The objective of this paper is to investigate the role of government provided crop insurance in risk management by comparing the efficacy of disaster payments and crop insurance in reducing the failure rates of farms that receive government. I accomplish this by exploiting variation in weather and the exogenous change in the take-up of crop insurance induced by the Federal Crop Insurance Act of 1994. 72 Agricultural subsidy recipients were the target of the 1994 crop insurance mandate, and thus are the focus of my investigation. They also are both politically important and economically important. Farms that receive agricultural subsidies produce a substantial majority of the value of all agricultural output. Subsidized farms produce the major export crops, providing 39% of the world's corn, 19% of the world's cotton, and 28% of the world's wheat exports. These farms also are the objects of much policymaker attention. Over the past 20 years Congress has passed five major agricultural bills primarily aimed at this group of farmers, directing over $305 billion to their support. The 1994 crop insurance expansion, which expanded coverage by 120%, provides a source of exogenous variation in crop insurance coverage. By exploiting this exogenous variation I overcome the endogeneity problem. Farmers who choose to purchase insurance coverage are likely to be different than their uninsured counterparts in many ways. Some differences will be unobservable to the econometrician, thereby resulting in an inconsistent estimate of the relationship between crop insurance and farm failure rates. Mandating that all farms participate in the crop insurance program overcomes this source of bias. The 1994-1995 time period also provides a stark regime shift between politically-driven disaster payments and privately-administered crop insurance. In the decade prior to 1995 Congress had doled out over $10.3 billion in disaster payments. In 1993, one of the worst flooding years this century, farmers received nearly $2.5 billion in disaster payments. The disaster payments regime was particularly relevant in 1994. It was a relatively normal weather year in which indemnity payments were the lowest in the decade, yet over half a billion dollars in disaster payments were made. The regime shifted drastically in 1995 when farmers were required to have crop insurance, and disaster payments sharply decreased to $14 million. 73 In 1996 disaster payments fell to $2 million, and in 1997 no disaster payments were made for the first time in over a decade 2 2 . This dramatic regime shift sets the stage to directly compare the efficacy of the two primary methods used to address losses caused by extreme weather events. In spite of the dramatic regime shift, uniform application of the federal policy change makes it challenging to identifying the relative effect of crop insurance with treatment-control comparisons. I overcome this obstacle in a novel way by using weather shocks to form the treatment and control groups. Although specific weather events are generally unpredictable, long-run weather patterns are not geographically random. For example, the odds of having snow and freezing temperatures in January in Ithaca, NY are pretty high. I address this issue by using conditional climate indices to come a close as possible to random assignment. These climate indices use the county-month specific weather distribution to calculate the conditional cumulative probability of an observed weather event. In other words, conditional on observing Tompkins County, NY in January, the climate index allows one to determine the likelihood of observing 48 inches of snow or more. Because the climate indices standardize the measure of an extreme event, all counties have an equal likelihood of being assigned to the treatment group, i.e. the treatment group is randomly selected. Using this empirical approach, I estimate the effects of disaster relief. Under the assumption of random assignment, I estimate the effect of disaster assistance under each regime by simply comparing the average farm failure rate in the control group with that of the treatment group. I augment the simple differences with regression analysis in the event that the 'randomization' results in non-equivalent treatment and control groups. This will reduce sampling error and provide a check on the random assignment assertion. To further check the 22 This dramatic shift was primarily caused by moving disaster payments from off-budget to on-budget, thereby requiring proponents of disaster payments to find cuts elsewhere in the budget to compensate for the disaster expenditures. 74 random assignment assertion I design a difference-in-differences estimator to provide an alternate estimate of the effects of disaster relief under the crop insurance regime. Finally, these two exogenous events, weather and mandatory crop insurance, allow me to create a simple difference-in-differences estimator to calculate the relative effectiveness of crop insurance versus disaster payments at smoothing exogenous shocks by reducing farm failure rates. The identifying assumption of this estimation strategy is that there are no shocks in disaster stricken counties that are associated with the regime change but not caused by the regime change. If extreme weather events are truly randomly assigned over time, then the identifying assumption is a fairly weak one.23 4 Data 4.1 Farm Failure Rates I use USDA administrative data obtained under the Freedom of Information Act in order to construct annual, county-level farm failure rates. The data consist of every payment made by the Farm Services Agency (FSA) from 1990 until 2001. Agriculture's (USDA) administrative arm, which programs, as well as disaster relief programs. The FSA is the U.S. Department of administers price and income support Although the data are not explicitly an enumeration of every farm in the United States it does contain information on the population of interest, every farm that received agricultural subsidies. If a farm is observed at two points in A means of addressing concerns about this assumption is to compare the outcomes of subsidized crop farms to farms in the same county that were unaffected by the crop insurance reforms. Two groups that qualify as withintreatment-controls are farms that primarily raise livestock and farms that grow non-insured crops, i.e. crops for which insurance is unavailable through the Federal Crop Insurance Program, typically fruits and vegetables. Livestock farms did not experience the crop insurance regime shift; they continued to qualify for the Livestock E mergency Assistance, a disaster payment-type program. Non-insured crops had a slight change to their disaster payments mechanism, but it was essentially the same. (See Lee et al. (1996) for discussion of the differences.) Performing this difference-in-differences-in-differences estimation requires data on livestock or non-insured crop farm failure rates, which are unavailable. 23 75 time, I extrapolate the farm's existence during the intervening period. If a farm drops out of the dataset and is never observed again, I label that farm as having failed in the last year observed. A key feature of these data is that in 1996 virtually all farms that qualified for subsidies received subsidy payments 2 4 . Hence, farms that may have chosen to opt-out of the subsidy program in 1994 or 1995 (when the participation rate was about 85%) are not counted as failures. Figure 3 illustrates the annual farm failure rate for this population. 4.2 Disaster Classification The exact definition of an agricultural disaster is nebulous at best. Ex post measures such as crop yield loss presumably demonstrate the effects of weather shocks, but these measures are also determined by farmer behavior, making them endogenous to the question at hand. A much more satisfying classification is to quantify weather shocks as they occur. However, the heterogeneity in climate makes it impossible to use temperature and precipitation directly. Ten inches of rain in July in Florida will have a much different effect than ten inches in Montana. Therefore, in classifying drought and excess precipitation I employ the Palmer Drought Severity Index (PDSI) and the Standardized Precipitation Index (SPI). These indices are widely used by climatologists. For example, the U.S. Drought Monitor and state drought monitors use these indices to monitor drought conditions, the National Weather Services Climate Prediction Center uses the PDSI as their primary measure of drought, and disaster legislation often uses the PDSI to trigger disaster declarations. The indices also allow one to easily and directly compare weather shocks across different climates, e.g. Florida and Montana. The indices also provide a standardized measure of 24 This feature is important. Farms may temporarily drop out of the dataset without having actually failed, but a failed farm cannot temporarily show up in the data. This asymmetry potentially induces one-sided measurement error in the dependent variable. Since virtually all farms are observed in 1996 the measurement error caused by some farms temporarily opting out is dramatically reduced. 76 weather extremes. By these measures a farm in drought-prone West Texas is no more likely to experience a 'disaster' than a corn farm in Iowa. 4.2.1 Precipitation Indices The Standard Precipitation Index provides a standardized measure of precipitation relative to the county-month specific time-series distribution of precipitation. The SPI is essentially a z- statistic constructed by transforming the location-specific time-series precipitation distribution into a standard normal distribution. One can then confidently speak about the likelihood of an event at least as extreme as the one observed and make geographic comparisons of precipitation- related weather events. The units of the precipitation distribution can be varied. If one were interested in long run precipitation anomalies one could look at the distribution of one- or five- year total precipitation. Because agriculture is very sensitive to short run weather shocks, I chose to examine the two-month total precipitation distribution for this analysis. The first panel of table 2 contains the event scale commonly associated with the SPI. The Palmer Drought Severity Index incorporates temperature, precipitation, soil characteristics, and location to develop a supply and demand model for water. A drought is classified by the extent of excess demand for water, while excess wetness classification depends on the excess supply of water. The PDSI is a widely used measure of drought that considers the rainfall history, making it less sensitive to transitory events than the SPI. However, since agriculture responds to short-term transitory weather shocks, I also incorporate an index used to create the PDSI, the moisture anomaly index, generally know as the "Z" index. The Z index is the difference between the actual precipitation that fell in a specific month and the amount of precipitation needed to maintain normal soil moisture, adjusted for the climatic characteristics of 77 the location. Essentially the Z index can be used to show how wet or dry it was during a single month without regard to recent precipitation trends. The commonly used classification system for the Z-Index and the PDSI are shown in the panel B and C respectively of table 2. Using Unix programs available from the National Agricultural Decision Support System and the National Drought Monitor, I calculate the PDSI, its components, and the SPI for each county in the United States. The publicly available datasets typically report the PDSI and the SPI at the climate division, a level of geography than encompasses multiple counties. Climate division data are best used "to assess large-scale climatic features or anomalies with respect to a long period or century-scale perspective" (Guttman 1995). Although agriculture certainly suffers from such large-scale events, even smaller scale, relatively local weather events can have adverse effects. In order to exploit the smaller scale variation in weather, I calculate the PDSI and the SPI on the county level by using county-level weather data derived from the Parameterelevation Regressions on Independent Slopes Model (PRISM) and county-level soil characteristics from the State Soil Survey Database (STATSGO) 2 5 . The PRISM modeling system generates estimates of precipitation and temperature at 4x4 kilometer grid cells for the entire United States. These estimates are based upon data collected by the National Oceanic & Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) Cooperative Weather Stations at over 3,000 locations nationwide from 1970 - 2001. In order to focus on the weather occurring on cropland these data are used in conjunction with data on the land use within each 4x4 km grid to calculate the average temperature and total precipitation for cropland. The PDSI also requires a measure of the available water capacity (AWC) of the soil in the location where the temperature and precipitation are collected. 25 The AWC is the amount of 1 am grateful to Olivier Deschenes and Michael Greenstone for generously providing the PRISM data used in this analysis. 78 water that a soil can store that is available for use by plants (USDA-NRCS 1998). I calculate the average AWC for all cropland in each county using STATSGO data. STATSGO is a dataset collected by the US Department of Agriculture - National Soil Conservation Service containing soil characteristics, up to 6 layers deep, across the entire United States. In order to determine the characteristics of soil associated with cropland, I combine STATSGO with the National Resource Inventory (NRI), which collects data every five years on the land use of 844,000 points across the entire United States. I employ the land use data from 1992, the most recent year prior to the policy reform. The final input into the PDSI calculation is the latitude corresponding to each data point. To obtain these data I use geographical information system (GIS) software to calculate the latitude of each county centroid. 4.2.2 Disaster Classification Establishing objective disaster criteria is vital to the analysis that follows. myriad of factors contribute to disaster, of which weather is just one. Unfortunately, a Consequently, the climatology literature contains a set of possible criteria, but not a clearly defined standard. I draw upon that literature and rely upon the three indices outlined above in order to develop a 'disaster/non-disaster' classification. The PDSI, the Z-Index, and the SPI capture the short- to medium-term moisture events that are most applicable to agriculture. The National Climate Center uses these three indices as the core of its 'Short-Term Blend Weather Monitor' used to monitor weather events that could have significant effects on agriculture. 2 6 As noted earlier, table 2 contains the classification system of each index. 26 http://www.cpc.ncep.noaa.gov/products/predictions/experimental/edb/droughtblend-access-page.html 79 I ultimately use all three indices in order to establish the disaster classification. I calculate a county specific index for each month of the year. Because of my focus on extreme events I calculate the most extreme positive value of a county's index across all twelve months within a year, and I calculate the most extreme negative value of a county's index across all twelve months. Disasters occurring during the growing season have a significantly greater impact on agriculture than disasters during the non-growing season. Therefore I limit my focus to extreme index values occurring between May and October. Once I calculate the relevant extremes, I classify a county as having experienced a disaster if the PDSI and the Z-Index both exceed the 'severe' threshold on their respective scales, and the SPI value has a less than 5- percent likelihood. These criteria result in 795, 355, and 476 counties classified as disaster counties in 1993, 1994, and 1995 respectively. The cross-sectional distributions of the moisture indices are shown in table 3. For the question at hand the interesting part of the distribution is not the center, as is usually reported, but the tails, i.e. the extreme events. In order to take a closer look at the tails, the upper panel of table 3 presents the 5th, h 15 t , average of each county's h 8 5t , and 95 th percentiles. annual monthly-maximum county's annual monthly-minimum The lower panel of table 3 shows the index value and the average of each index value for 1993, 1994, and 1995. Each of the indices characteristics can be seen in table 3. The Z-Index is most responsive to monthly precipitation and registers the greatest number of extreme values. The PDSI is a medium-term measure that adjusts slowly, as demonstrated by the continual downward trend in the monthly maximum PDSI, even though both the Z-Index and the SPI increase in 1995. The SPI has responsiveness between the Z-Index and PDSI, being very responsive to significant weather events. 80 The three panels of figures 4, 5, and 6 each show the geographic distribution of the three weather indices in 1993, 1994, and 1995 respectively. from table 3: Climatologically, These figures underscore the information 1993 was an extremely wet year, whereas 1994 was a relatively normal year. 1993 and 1995 were fairly similar, wet years. In the analysis that follows I will demonstrate the comparison between 1993 and 1995 as well as 1994 and 1995. 5 Empirical Results 5.1 Overview In this section I exploit two natural experiments in order to examine the 'survival smoothing '2 7 effects of disaster payments and crop insurance, the two most heavily used means of crop-loss insurance. I create randomized experiments by taking advantage of exogenous extreme weather events. In both natural experiments examined below I rely on random weather events to classify counties into disaster (treatment) and non-disaster (control) groups. Random assignment allows me to avoid the endogeneity concerns associated with directly analyzing the impact of disaster or indemnity payments on farm failure rates. Farmer behavior associated with adverse selection and moral hazard affect the loss-likelihood and thereby determine the size of the disaster or indemnity payment. This same behavior also is plausibly correlated with the propensity to fail, thereby resulting in a spurious, non-causal relationship between payments and failure rates. By relying on the random component of croploss payments I avoid these concerns. 27 1 adapt this term from the consumption smoothing effects that are examined in the social insurance literature. Since I am focused on failure rates, I deem a constant failure rate across states of nature 'complete survival smoothing.' 81 In addition to calculating the survival smoothing effects of disaster payments and crop insurance, one would like to examine the absolute effects of these two programs on farm failure rates. For example, policy makers would benefit from knowing the decrease in farm failure rates when a farmer moves from an uninsured state to being covered by catastrophic crop insurance. Unfortunately for this investigation, there has not been a time when farmers have not been potentially covered by disaster payments, crop insurance, or both.2 8 Nevertheless, because of the virtual elimination of disaster payments and the increased insurance coverage in 1995 I can compare the relative effectiveness of these two programs. This is a fundamentally relevant policy question as Congress has operated these two programs in parallel intermittently for the past 35 years with frequent debate about the relative benefits. In the analysis that follows I first examine each of these programs separately, and then I examine their relative effectiveness and test the survival smoothing hypothesis. 5.2 Randomized Experiments 5.2.1 Randomization Random weather shocks play an intricate role in agricultural yield reduction. The type, severity, and timing of weather events interact in complicated, non-linear ways to influence output (Roberts and Schlenker, 2005). For example, a wet spell can have dramatically different effects on wheat yield if it occurs in early May instead of later June. Consequently, it is very difficult to develop a single metric to quantify a disaster. In order to ensure that the classification used in this paper corresponds to actual yield losses, I present the average per-acre disaster payment and the average proportion of crop liabilities indemnified for each treatment and control group. 28 In future work I will exploit yet to be obtained data and the dramatic expansion in crop insurance availability due to the 1980 Federal Crop Insurance Act to answer this question. 82 Panel A of table 5 reports the average per-acre disaster payments in 1993 and 1994 for the disaster and non-disaster counties. The standard errors are in parenthesis, and the group size is in brackets. The disaster/non-disaster difference is also presented, along with its standard error. The average per-acre disaster payment for disaster counties in 1994 was $5.11. In 1993 the amount was nearly double that at $10.34, due to the worst flooding in the Midwestern United States this century. For the non-disaster counties the average per-acre disaster payment was $2.90 and $8.54 for 1994 and 1993 respectively. In both cases the disaster counties receive significantly greater disaster payments, validating the classification scheme. The presence of substantial disaster payments in non-disaster counties underscores the importance of using exogenous weather events in this investigation. Although some of the imperfect correlation between disaster payments and weather is surely due the complicated relationship between yield and weather, moral hazard effects and fraud provide an additional, more insidious explanation for the magnitude disaster payments to non-disaster counties. A somewhat less nefarious explanation is also viable. Disaster payments require Congressional action, and the political economy may result in large "disaster" payments directed to the constituents of key politicians. Garrett et al. (2003) demonstrate that between 1992 and 1999 about $7 billion of disaster aid was the result of political influence rather than due to disaster losses. This political economy may interact with moral hazard to magnify the effects. Others also have noted that counties that do not objectively appear to experience a disaster receive considerable disaster payments (Lee et al. 1996). Panel B of table 5 demonstrate that disaster counties received greater indemnities as a proportion of total liabilities than did non-disaster counties. In 1995 11.2-percent of crop insurance liabilities were indemnified in disaster counties, compared with 8.2 percent in non- 83 disaster counties. This again shows high, but imperfect, correlation between actual weather events and compensated losses. In a randomized experiment, the treatment groups should be statistically similar. Table 4 the disaster and non-disaster county characteristics as measured in the 1992 Census of Agriculture. With a few rare exceptions, the treatment and control groups look statistically identical, further supporting the quasi-random experimental design. 5.2.2 Disaster Payments Using the quasi-random experiment described above I evaluate the effect of ad hoc disaster payments on farm failure rates by simply comparing the average farm failure rate of the randomly assigned disaster counties to the average farm failure rate of the non-disaster counties. I make this comparison in two ways. First, table 5 panel C shows the averages failure rate of each group and the failure rate difference between the two groups. displayed in parentheses, and the group size is in brackets. The standard errors are The average failure rate in non- disaster counties is 6.5-percent in 1994 and 5.4-percent in 1993. The average failure rate in disaster counties is 5.9-percent and 5.0-percent in 1994 and 1993 respectively. Both the 1994 failure rate difference between groups and the 1993 difference show that under the disaster payments regime farms were slightly less likely to fail when hit by a disaster. The difference is small, but statistically significant, suggesting that disaster payments help sustain farms that otherwise would fail, regardless of whether they faced a disaster. In terms of survival smoothing, these findings suggest that disaster payments are not simply a substitute for other means of self-insurance. Clearly, government intervention aids in smoothing temporary shocks. 84 An alternative method for analyzing this experiment is with an ordinary least squares regression. This approach provides a check on the contention that treatment is quasi-random. Under true randomization other observed county characteristics should not influence the estimate, but the sampling variability should decrease when conditioning on covariates. Panel A in table 6 lays out the regression results using the county-crop mix as controls. The regression results are consistent with the simple differences outlined above, although the estimate changes somewhat with the inclusion of controls, suggesting some caution should be used when interpreting this in a strictly experimental sense. Although disaster payments provided the vast majority of assistance in 1993 and 1994, it should be noted that the disaster payments regime included some farms that also held crop insurance. Disaster payments were more than twice the net indemnities (indemnities minus premiums) paid by crop insurance in 1993, and net indemnities were zero in 1994. Hence, the conclusion that disaster payments provide for survival smoothing is a statement about the entire regime, in which ex post disaster payments play a dominant role. 5.2.3 Crop Insurance I also examine the influence of crop insurance on farm failure rates through a quasi-randomized natural experiment. As with the experiment investigating the disaster payments regime, I categorize counties into disaster and non-disaster groups using exogenous, random weather events. The lower half of panel C in table 5 contains the results of this experiment. The results from this experiment are generally consistent with an increased failure rate when faced by a disaster under the crop insurance regime. Farms with crop insurance have a 1.3 percentage point 85 increased failure rate when hit by a disaster. This raises the average failure rate to 8.3-percent from a 7-percent failure rate when not hit by a disaster. These findings suggest that crop insurance fails to provide complete survival smoothing. High deductibles provide a plausible explanation. Deductibles ranged from 35-percent to 50percent of production. The most widely held coverage level, the mandated catastrophic coverage, had a 50-percent of production deductible. Such a large deductible possibly provided an insufficient buffer for some farmers, resulting in permanent effects of large, temporary shocks (Basker, 2003). As with the disaster payments regime, I use ordinary least squares regressions to augment the experimental approach by including covariates in the analysis. The third row of panel A in table 6 contains the regression estimates. Once covariates are included in the analysis the coefficient decreases to 0.7, becoming statistically insignificant in spite of the slightly smaller standard error. This estimate signifies nearly no change in failure rates due to disaster under the crop insurance regime, although the original, simple-difference estimate is still within the confidence interval. 5.3 Relative Effectiveness One would like to use the 1994-1995 policy change that more than doubled the rate of insurance coverage to examine the absolute effect of crop insurance coverage. As noted earlier, this is unfortunately not possible because ad hoc, ex post disaster payments were the norm prior to the 1994 Act. Instead, it is informative to compare the effectiveness of the disaster payments regime to that of the crop insurance regime. Knowing their relative effectiveness at decreasing farm 86 failures in the face of disaster is the first step to understanding the incentive effects of each regime and to designing an optimal government-provided crop-loss insurance scheme. I evaluate the relative effectiveness of the two regimes by comparing the outcomes of the previous two quasi-random experiments. Panel C in table 5 contains the results of the experiments in 1993, 1994, and 1995. I report the relative effects of the two regimes in the last two rows of panel C by taking the difference between each of the disaster payment regime results and the 1995 crop insurance regime results. These difference-in-differences estimates demonstrate the relative effectiveness of these two programs. The results of these comparisons are remarkably similar. Relative to the 1993 regime, farms suffering a disaster in 1995 are 1.7 percentage points more likely to fail. That likelihood is 1.9 percentage points when 1994 is the base period. Both of these results are statistically significant. I extend my analysis of the relative effects controlling for observable county characteristics in a regression framework. As with the quasi-random experiments, any failure of the randomization resulting in treatment group heterogeneity could be problematic. Through regression analysis I also address the concern that the composition of the treatment group is allowed to differ between the two periods by controlling for other observables that affect failure rates. The regression equation has the following form: Fi, =a + , X, + 82r, + 3disasteri,+ 4 (r,x disasteri,). In this equation i indexes counties and t indexes years (1 if after the policy change, 0 if before). F;, is the farm failure rate, X is a vector of observable county characteristics, effect, and disaster is a dummy variable for disaster counties in either regime. 87 is a fixed time The form of the regression resembles the typical difference-in-differences regression. However, the interpretation of the coefficients is slightly different because the treatment group is not the same in both periods. The time fixed effect controls for time-series changes in the failure rate. The disaster variable captures the effect of a disaster in the first period while the second order interaction term captures the relative effect between the two regimes. The set of covariates includes the proportion of cropland planted to 12 different crops. Panel B of table 6 reports the coefficients of the interaction term for the various criteria. Controlling for covariates, I cannot reject the hypothesis that there is no change in farm failure rates when moving from the 1993 disaster payments regime to the 1995 crop insurance regime. However, relative to the 1994 disaster payment regime, a farmer is 1.2 percentage points more likely to fail with crop insurance in 1995 after controlling for crop mix. This estimate is similar to the point estimate of 1.9 percentage points from the simple difference-in-differences 6 estimate. Interpretation and Conclusion The analysis above found a decreased failure rate for the disaster payments regime, and less than complete smoothing for the crop insurance regime. I estimate that, relative to the disaster payments regime, farm failure rates increase by between 1.7 - 1.9 percentage points under the crop insurance regime. From an average failure rate of 7.2-percent this change represents a 30- percent increase in the likelihood of failure when faced with a natural disaster under the crop insurance regime. This is a surprising finding for several reasons. First, the ultimate structure of ex post disaster payments and mandatory catastrophic crop insurance is very similar. Ex post disaster payments provided coverage of loss greater than 65-percent of yield at 60-percent of the 88 expected price. The catastrophic coverage was less generous, covering only 50-percent of crop lass at 60-percent of the expected price. This reduced generosity might play a factor in the findings, but one would expect the overall coverage increase due to substantially increased premium subsidies to have had an off-setting effect. An alternative explanation could be in the moral hazard incentives that are likely more substantial with an ex ante insurance plan. Ex ante insurance provides incentives for the farmer to shirk early on in the growing season, when reduced tillage, chemical treatment, or fertilizer will have the greatest impact. Coverage uncertainty under the ex post disaster payments regime reduces the incentives for moral hazard behavior. Even if disaster payments were implicitly anticipated, the Congressional action necessary to activate coverage is likely somewhat capricious. Under this sort of coverage, the moral hazard incentives might only set in late in the season when it became certain that Congress would act. Delaying moral hazard may be a factor contributing to the greater effectiveness of the disaster payments regime. More data are required in order to investigate this explanation. Obtaining data on fertilizer and chemical input will help in evaluating these claims. 2 9 Alternative explanations are also viable. Fraud might play a role if it is better addressed under the crop insurance regime than under ex post disaster payments. The Federal Crop Insurance Program is operated primarily through private insurers that are reinsured by the U.S. Department of Agriculture. The private insurers might be better at policing and weeding out fraudulent claims. If this is the case and if fraudulent claims are made by farms that are more likely to fail, then fraud could be a factor in the finding. In other words, the greater likelihood of farm survival under the disaster payments regime is not necessarily a good thing. Perhaps the greatest cost of an ad hoc, ex post disaster payments 29 The author is currently pursuing use of confidential survey data in order to address this issue. 89 program is in terms of the disutility of farmers forced to bear the ex ante risk of failure due to random weather events. Public policy will greatly benefit from research more closely examining the potential costs associated with these program structures, in addition to the moral hazard and adverse selection costs studied by others and the survival smoothing benefits outlined in this paper. Although the absolute effects of crop insurance and disaster payments remain unknown, finding a positive relative effect allows me to conclude that disaster payments do provide survival smoothing and do not perfectly crowd out other means of risk mitigation. This finding suggests that there is a significant role for government-provision of crop-loss insurance. 90 References Babcock, B.A., and D.A. Hennessy. 1996. "Input Demand under Yield and Revenue Insurance." American Journal ofAgricultural Economics 78(2), 416-427. Barkley, E. P. 1990. "The Determinants of the Migration of Labor out of Agriculture in the United States, 1940 - 1985." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72(3), 427-435. Basker, E. 2002. "Do Temporary Shocks have Permanent Effects? Agricultural Sector." Unpublished PhD Dissertation, MIT. Evidence from the Claasen, R., R.N. Lubowski, and M.J. Roberts. 2005. "Extent, Location, and Characteristics of Land Cropped Due to Insurance Subsidies." Selected paper prepared for the American Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting. Garrett, T.A., T.L. Marsh, and M.I. Marshall. 2003. "Political Allocation of Agricultural Disaster Payments in the 1990s." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 2003005A. Glauber, J.W. 2004. "Crop Insurance Reconsidered." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86(5), 1179-1195. Goodwin, B.K., and V.H. Smith. 1995. The Economics of Crop Insurance and Disaster Aid. Washington, DC: The AEI Press. Goodwin, B.K., and V.H. Smith. 2003. "An Ex Post Evaluation of the Conservation Reserve, Federal Crop Insurance and Other Government Programs: Program Participation and Soil Erosion." Journal ofAgricultural and Resource Economics 28(, 201-216. Goodwin, B.K., M.L. Vandeveer, and J. Deal. 2004. "An Empirical Analysis of Acreage Effects of Participation in the Federal Crop Insurance Program." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86(4), 1058-1077. Huffman, W. E. and R. E. Evenson. 2001. "Structural and Productivity Change in US Agriculture, 1950 - 1982." Agricultural Economics 24(2), 127-147. Just, R.E., L. Calvin, and J. Quiggin. 1999. "Adverse Selection in Crop Insurance: Actuarial and Asymmetric Information Incentives." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 81(4), 834-849. Kiyotaki, N. and J. Moore. 1999. "Indexation and Insurance: A Stochastic Model of Credit Cycles." Working Paper, London School of Economics. Krishnamurthy, A. 2003. "Collateral Constrains and the Amplification Mechanism." Journal of Economic Theory 111()277-292. 91 Lee, H., J. Harwood, A. Somwaru. 1997. " Implications of Disaster Assistance Reform for NonInsured Crops." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79(2), 419-429. Quiggen, J., G. Karagiannis, and J. Stanton. 1993. "Crop Insurance and Crop Production: Empirical Study of Moral Hazard and Adverse Selection." Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics 37(, 95-113. Skees, J.R., and M.R. Reed. 1986. "Rate-Making for Farm-Level Crop Insurance: Implications for Adverse Selection." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 68(3), 653-659. U.S. General Accounting Office. 1989. "Disaster Assistance: Crop Insurance Can Provide Assistance More Effectively than Other Programs." GAO/RCED-89-211. Wu, J. 1999. "Crop Insurance, Acreage Decisions, and Nonpoint-Source Pollution." American Journal of AgriculturalEconomics81(2), 305-320. 92 Table 1. Crop Insurance and Disaster Payment Details Crop Total Year 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 Acres Policies (thousands) -- (mil) 45.0 416.8 42.7 386.0 27.9 310.0 42.7 389.8 414.6 48.6 48.7 406.9 433.9 49.1 461.0 55.6 949.7 101.7 893.7 1991 706.2 1992 1993 1994 663.1 678.8 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 800.4 2,039.2 1,623.3 1,320.1 1,242.4 1,287.9 1,323.2 1,297.9 1,259.4 101.3 82.3 83.1 83.7 99.6 220.6 205.0 181.9 181.7 196.3 206.5 211.8 215.5 Participation Premium Indemnity Rate ($ mil) ($ mil) 16 15 12 16 18 20 22 25 40 40 33 31 32 38 41/85 44/76 43/67 46/69 53/73 59/76 63/78 66/80 Total Loss Ratio 376.8 396.1 285.8 433.9 439.8 379.7 365.1 436.4 819.4 835.5 736.4 758.7 755.6 407.3 529.1 583.7 638.4 683.1 615.7 369.8 1,067.6 1,215.3 1,033.6 958.5 922.5 1,653.4 1.08 1.34 2.04 1.47 1.55 1.62 948.9 600.9 1,543.0 1,838.4 1,773.8 1,874.2 2,304.4 2,540.1 1,566.5 1,491.0 990.1 1,659.3 2,416.1 0.63 1.02 0.81 0.56 0.89 1.05 1.02 1.00 1.39 2,961.9 2,915.9 2,591.0 2,959.4 4,054.0 Disaster Payments ($ mil) 306 115 1 0 0 556 1.01 10 2.45 1.48 1.24 1.30 1.22 3,386 2.19 1,500 6 960 872 2,461 577 14 2 0 1,913 1,452 2,348 0 2,145 Notes: Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture - Risk Management Agency. Participation rate calculated as acres insured as percent of eligible acres. For 1995 - 2002, the first number is the participation in "buy-up" and the second number is total parti 93 Table 2. Climate Indices Index Value Classification A. Standardized Precipitation Index 2.0+ Extremely Wet 1.5 to 1.99 Very Wet 1.0 to 1.49 Moderately Wet -0.99 to 0.99 Near Normal -1.0 to -1.49 -1.5 to -1.99 Moderately Dry Severely Dry -2.0 and less Extremely Dry B. Moisture Anomaly (Z) Index 3.50+ Extremely Wet 2.5 to 3.49 1 to 2.49 Very Wet Moderately Wet -1.24 to 1 Near Normal -1.25 to -1.99 -2.0 to -2.75 -2.75 and less Moderate Drought Severe Drought Extreme Drought C. Palmer Drought Severity Index 4.0+ Extremely Wet 3.0 to 3.99 Very Wet 2.0 to 2.99 Moderately Wet 1.0 to 1.99 Slightly Wet 0.5 to 0.99 Incipient Wet Spell Near Normal 0.49 to -0.49 -0.5 -1.0 -2.0 -3.0 to to to to -0.99 -1.99 -2.99 -3.99 -4.0 and less Incipient Dry Spell Mild Drought Moderate Drought Severe Drought Extreme Drought 94 - Table 3. Climate Indices' Distributions 5% -1.21 -2.67 -2.29 SPI PDSI Z-lndex June 1995 15% 85% -0.59 1.6 -1.41 2.93 -1.43 2.42 95% 2.03 3.68 4.1 1993 1994 1995 SPI -1.29 (0.61) -1.38 (0.49) -1.47 (0.58) PDSI -0.29 -0.50 -0.71 Z-Index (1.85) -1.81 (0.96) (1.86) -2.05 (0.63) (1.82) -2.03 (0.77) 1.54 (0.69) 2.56 1.38 (0.65) 2.04 1.48 (0.52) 1.87 (1.88) 3.43 (2.02) (1.83) 3.04 (1.77) (1.67) 3.28 (1.59) Minimum Monthly Maximum Monthly SPI PDSI Z-Index Notes: The climate indices are: the Standardized Precipitation Index (SPI), the Palmer Drought Severity Index (PDSI), and the Palmer Moisture Anomaly (Z) Index (Z-Index). The climate indices are calculated for each month of the year. The upper panel contains the indicated percentiles of each index in June, 1995. The cells in the lower panel contain the cross-sectional average of the minimum and maximum value across all 12 months. The standard deviations are in parentheses. See table 3 for the magnitude classification of each index. 95 Table 4. Characteristics of Disaster and Non-Disaster Counties Disaster Criteria--Palmer Moisture Anomaly (Z) Index & Palmer Drought Severity Index & Standardized Precipitation Index Characteristic Farm Size (acres) Land Value ($/acre) Sales ($) Proportion of Cropland Barley Corn Cotton Soybeans Oats Sorghum Wheat Rice Beans Sunflowers Other Proportion of Farms Cattle Beef Cows Milking Cows Hogs and Pigs Sheep and Lambs Layers Broilers Proportion of Farmland Rented Farmland Irrigated Farmland Farmer Characteristics Experience Age Full Owner Part Owner Tenant Primary Occupation Farming Family Farm Partnership Family Corporation Corporation Disaster Payments (1993) NonDisaster Disaster Disaster Payments (1994) NonDisaster Disaster Crop Insurance (1995) NonDisaster Disaster 521.361 732.923 1,093.90 1,160.12 77,850.50 87,233.88 885.787 1,056.58 97,798.61 666.612 1,170.80 83,785.73 0.031 0.261 0.082 0.205 0.030 0.023 0.181 636.722 956.25 90,673.57 741.739 1,227.76 84,168.31 0.022 0.329 0.006 0.252 0.028 0.043 0.224 0.003 0.003 0.007 0.017 0.037 0.233 0.074 0.174 0.040 0.024 0.213 0.012 0.008 0.002 0.048 0.022 0.257 0.095 0.154 0.044 0.014 0.182 0.001 0.007 0.010 0.089 0.033 0.280 0.053 0.201 0.036 0.030 0.207 0.012 0.007 0.004 0.031 0.033 0.228 0.037 0.186 0.035 0.042 0.286 0.006 0.008 0.553 0.416 0.076 0.152 0.051 0.039 0.006 0.559 0.438 0.069 0.073 0.044 0.051 0.015 0.553 0.419 0.084 0.101 0.031 0.048 0.016 0.557 0.433 0.069 0.094 0.048 0.047 0.012 0.593 0.454 0.085 0.053 0.050 0.010 0.550 0.427 0.068 0.094 0.045 0.047 0.013 0.449 0.047 0.363 0.074 0.336 0.046 0.395 0.069 0.398 0.085 0.386 0.062 20.6 52.4 0.514 0.356 0.131 0.612 0.856 0.095 0.039 0.004 19.4 19.8 19.8 53.9 0.587 0.306 0.107 0.522 0.854 0.097 0.037 0.005 53.5 0.576 0.327 0.098 0.539 0.874 0.086 0.029 0.004 53.4 0.558 0.324 0.119 0.556 0.852 0.098 0.038 0.004 20.3 53.4 0.530 19.7 53.4 0.566 0.319 0.115 0.546 0.855 0.098 0.036 0.004 0.011 0.033 0.101 0.351 0.119 0.591 0.855 0.092 0.041 0.004 0.011 0.006 0.004 0.039 . . Notes: Data for all groups are from the 1992 Census of Agriculture, except data for crops data which are from the U.S. Department of Agriculture-National Agricultural Statistics Service Crop County Files for each of the years listed. See text for criteria used to assign counties to disaster and non-disaster groups. 96 . Table 5. Quasi-Random Experiments: The Effects of Disaster Payments and Crop Insurance on Farm Failure Rates Disaster Criteria--Palmer Moisture Anomaly (Z) Index, Palmer Drought Severity Index & Standardized Precipitation Index NonDisaster/Non-Disaster difference Disaster Disaster Regime A. Per-Acre Disaster Payments 8.567 10.336 Disaster Payments (1993) (0.429) (0.449) Disaster Payments (1994) {795} {2007} 5.113 (0.485) 2.904 (0.199) {355} {2440} B. Proportion of Liabilities Indemnified 0.112 0.082 Crop Insurance (1995) (0.003) (0.007) {465} 1.770 (0.621) 2.209 (0.524) 0.030 (0.007) {2239} C. Causal Effect of Disaster Payments and Crop Insurance on Farm Failure Rates -0.004 0.050 0.054 Disaster Payments (1993) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) Disaster Payments (1994) Crop Insurance (1995) {795} {2007} 0.059 (0.002) 0.065 (0.001) {355} {2440} 0.083 0.070 0.013 (0.005) {476} (0.002) {2314} (0.005) -0.006 (0.002) 1993 - 1995 Relative Effect 0.017 (0.005) 1994 - 1995 Relative Effect 0.019 (0.006) Notes: Standard errors are given in parentheses. The disaster classification corresponds to the 'severe' classification of each climate index: Z-Index > 2.5 or < 2, PDSI > 3 or < -3, and SPI > 1.5 or < -1.5. Panel A contains the average dollars per acre in disaster payments for each group in the disaster payments regime. Panel B contains the ratio of indemnitied to liabilities for each group in the crop insurance regime. The cells in panel C contain the average farm failure rate for each the group during each regime. 97 Table 6. Treatment-Dummy Results Across Regimes Regime Failure Rate A. Quasi-Random Cross-sectional Experiments Disaster Payments (1993) -0.004 0.003 (0.002) (0.002) Disaster Payments (1994) -0.006 (0.002) -0.006 (0.002) Crop Insurance (1995) 0.013 (0.005) N 0.007 Covariates (0.005) Y B. Relative Program Effects 1993 - 1995 Relative Effect 0.017 (0.005) 0.003 (0.005) 1994 - 1995 Relative Effect 0.019 (0.006) 0.012 (0.005) Notes: White's heteroskedastic-robust standard errors are in parentheses. The dependent variable is the county-level farm failure rate. In panel A the coefficient is that on the 'disaster county' indicator in the cross-sectional analysis for each regime. Panel B contains the coefficient on the interaction term when comparing the two years. The covariates are the proportion of cropland planted to 12 different crop groups. 98 250.0 200.0 5 150.0 C 100.0 50.0 0.0 I 1 I I I 9 f 9 T I · I I I9 · I r 9 I 93 I 995 11) 1 I t\ T I I' 999 1 r I n; Figure I . Total Acres Covered by Crop Insurance 8000 7000 '= 6000 _. 5000 4000 3000- , 2000 1000 O FT I II II IF II IrII 111 1 I rITI r 1o 11 1111 I Figure 2. Number of Farms, 1910 - 2004 99 rII 11III IIII 1 -IIT T l0I Il U.UY - 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0O I 1990 I 1991 1992 1993 1994 I I 1995 1996 Figure 3. Farm Failure Hazard Rate 100 I 1997 1998 1999 2000 Figure 4. 1993 Geographic A. Standardized Distribution Precipitation Monthly-Minimum - c:::::J. of Climate Indices Index Monthly-Maximum ............ &euer.ly Or" B. Moisture Anomaly (Z) Index Monthly-Minimum ( ... ) .lnZlM>-a c=J _ UWa.1.-lly Dr'au;tlt Ib'1NI (=:::J _ a.--. -.-- Monthly-Maximum DrOUQht .... Y.&n... II!!!!!!!I .......... (_J -.lIJlD.a DrouQtIt ~ _____ Oruuvhl "- _"'ICllll)' _&"-I", C. Palmer Drought Severity Index Monthly-Minimum Monthly-Maximum ( __ I0 I J __ PDRI~ c::::::J a..--. o...ought _~."'I","'t _1 as- _NodI.r ....... u- 102 Figure 5. 1994 Geographic A. Standardized Distribution Precipitation Monthly-Minimum of Climate Indices Index Monthly-Maximum _~"""I ~~IYDry B. Moisture Anomaly (Z) Index (--) .1ri"DSlec Monthly-Minimum Monthly-Maximum Monthly-Minimum C. Palmer Drought Severity Index Monthly-Maximum _t.~I~==1 ( ... _fJler-I~"" 103 ) _.t'D8IK c::::J IUtr_ _"'I~II~ _ber-Iv c:==J Drougt1t , . ~. _~.wl" ..., Draught 104 Figure 6. 1995 Geographic A. Standardized Distribution of Climate Indices Precipitation Monthly-Minimum =--- ..., B. Moisture Index Monthly-Maximum Anomaly (2) Index Monthly-Minimum Monthly-Maximum (_) Monthly-Minimum (_).1 .... 1-= _.llrm.c _s--- ....~ _ .... ic.II" ...... C. Palmer Drought Severity Index Monthly-Maximum _~=I~~I (_l_PD8I-= _~"';:Ie---~I _bw-I" _bar-lif"" 105 ..., 106 Chapter 3 How Cost-Effective Are Land Retirement Auctions? Estimating the Difference between Payments and Willingness to Accept in the Conservation Reserve Program Co-Authored with Ruben N. Lubowski and Michael J. Roberts 1 Introduction The Conservation Reserve Program (CRP), established by the Food Security Act of 1985, offers annual rental payments to farm operators who voluntarily retire environmentally sensitive cropland under ten- to fifteen-year contracts. and its environmental benefits. The CRP is notable for the size of both its budget The CRP currently pays about $1.7 billion per year to retire about 34 million acres (equal to about 8% of U.S. cropland, or the size of Iowa). For comparison, Congressional appropriations for toxic waste cleanups under the Superfund program, one of the nation's highest profile environmental initiatives, totaled $1.3 billion in 2003. To date, the CRP has disbursed over $26 billion in direct payments. Researchers have estimated that the environmental benefits exceed the program's costs (Feather, Hellerstein, Hanson 1999; Ribaudo et al. 1990). This paper measures the cost-effectiveness of the CRP's bidding mechanism. Currently, landowners submit bids that are ranked according to a score comprised of both an environmental benefits index (EBI), which includes erodibility and other environmental factors, as well as the landowner's proposed rental rate, subject to soil-specific maximums.30 Bids with the highest In the literature from the Farm Service Agency (FSA), the total contract "score" is called the EBI and the environmental components are termed the EEBI (environmental EBI). Here, we use EBI to refer to just the 30 107 scores are accepted into the program after each sign-up period. Landowners with especially high EBI scores and especially low opportunity costs for their land can potentially submit rent bids above their reservation rents and still have their lands accepted into the program, resulting in windfall gains to these landowners. Our objective is to estimate the size of these premiums based on observed bidding behavior using data on all individual CRP contract bids from regular sign-ups since 1997. We estimate the relationship between farmers' proposed rents net of costs and their bid score, which is endogenous; farmers can increase the environmental component of their score via their proposed conservation practice and the cost component of their score via their bid rent. To deal with this issue, we use exogenous components of the EBI by farmers' proposed rent or practices - those that cannot be influenced as instruments for the total score. In earlier research on CRP bidding behavior, Vukina, Levy, and Marra (2003) examined CRP bid data to determine farmers' valuation of environmental benefits; Shoemaker (1989) examined rental premiums obtained by farmers in the first two years of the CRP, before the current EBI-based mechanism was established; and Cason and Gangadharan (2004) used experimental auctions akin to CRP auctions to examine bidding behavior. These studies all suggest that landowners adjust their bid rents upwards with increasing likelihood of acceptance into the program. 2 Institutional Background environmental components and "score" to refer to the overall total. In this way, we seek a more intuitive usage of the term "environmental benefits index." 108 2.1 The CRP Bidding Mechanism Initially focused on reducing soil erosion, CRP's environmental objectives were broadened with the introduction of the EBI in 1990. In an effort to reduce costs, soil-specific maximum rental rates also replaced earlier rate caps set at state and sub-state levels. Starting with sign-up 15 in 1997, the EBI was revised to include wildlife habitat and air quality benefits in addition to water quality and soil erosion. Since then, CRP offers have been scored as follows. Landowners offer a parcel of land with a set of proposed conservation practices for enrollment in CRP. The offer receives an environmental score equal to the sum of six factors, NI through N6 (collapsed to five factors beginning with sign-up 26 in 2003). The six factors contain points delineated as follows: NI for grass covers, tree planting, location, and wetland restoration practices that create wildlife benefits; N2 for water quality benefits from reduced erosion, runoff, and leaching; N3 for on-farm benefits from reduced erosion; N4 for benefits that will likely endure beyond the contract period; N5 for air quality benefits from reduced wind erosion; and N6 for state or national conservation priority areas. 31 Landowners can influence the number of environmental points they receive mainly via factors N1 and N4, depending on the type of grass or tree covers and wetland restoration practices (if applicable) they choose to offer for their enrolling land. Points from the environmental factors are added to a cost factor to obtain the total score. The cost factor penalizes higher proposed rents and offers that propose sharing the conservation practice costs with the government. Specifically, Costfactor = w(1-rl(HIGH)) + 10(l-s) + Min(15, rm-r), 31 (1) Starting with sign-up 26 in 2003, the points for conservation priority areas were eliminated as a separate factor and incorporated in the wildlife and water quality factors. The cost factor (described below) became N6. 109 where r is the proposed rent, r is the parcel's soil-based maximum rent (r must be less than or equal to rm), HIGH is the highest allowed soil-specific rent for all contracts received, and s denotes the farmer's decision to share costs (s=1 if share, s=0 if not). If farmers elect to share costs, the government typically pays half the cost of establishing the proposed conservation practice; if they forgo cost sharing, they receive an extra 10 points on their bid score. The last term confers additional points for offering rent r below the maximum allowable rent r. This component was introduced starting with signup 16 and adds one point for each dollar offered below the maximum rent up to a limit of 15 points. The value of w is set at the government's discretion. It was 175 for sign-up 15 and 125 for subsequent sign-ups. In this paper, we use EBI to refer to the sum of the environmental EBI factors, N1 through N6 (N1 through N5 in sign-up 26), and SCORE as the sum of EBI plus the cost factor N7 (renamed N6 in sign-up 26). The endogenous component of EBI refers to the sum of factors N1 and N4, and the exogenous component of EBI refers to the sum of the other environmental factors.3 2 3 Summary Statistics Our data are from the Farm Service Agency's (FSA) CRP bid files. We focus on five CRP general sign-ups (15, 16, 18, 20, and 26) conducted between 1997 and 2003.3 3 Sign-up 15 is the largest in terms of both the number of bids submitted (251,959) and the number accepted (160,624). Sign-up 20 had the least number of bids submitted (56,093) and sign-up 26 had the 32 Subfactor N5d for carbon sequestration, introduced in sign-up 26, depends on the choice of cover practice and is treated as an endogenous part of the EBI in our analysis of this sign-up. Other N5 components are considered to be exogenous. 33 Data from the latest general sign-up, 29 held in 2004, were not available at the time of this study. "General" sign- ups account for the bulk of CRP enrollment and are subject to the competitive bidding process discussed above. FSA conducts smaller "continuous" sign-ups on a rolling basis that offer fixed rental payments for enrolling specific high priority environmental practices. 110 least number accepted (38,621). In table 1 we report some summary statistics from these data, cross-tabulated by quartiles of the exogenous component of the EBI and quartiles of the soilbased maximum payment (rm). For each subgroup, the table reports the average offered rent, the average discount below the maximum rent, the proportion offering a discount below the maximum, the average endogenous EBI, and the proportion of offers accepted in the program. Several patterns emerge from this presentation of the data. Most notably, farmers appear to offer higher rental rates if they have a high exogenous EBI score conditional on their maximum payment quartile. This pattern is somewhat visible in the mean rent offered, which generally increases across exogenous EBI quartiles within a maximum payment quartile. The behavior is most clearly visible in the mean discount offered. Since a farmer can increase his total SCORE by offering to accept a rental rate below the soil-specific maximum, we uniformly observe farmers with lower exogenous EBI scores offering a larger discount even after conditioning on the maximum payment quartile. For instance, in sign-up 16 among farmers in the lowest quartile of maximum payments, farmers in the lowest exogenous EBI quartile offer a discount more than twice as large as those in the highest exogenous EBI quartile (1.2 versus 0.5). This pattern holds across all maximum payment quartiles in sign-up 16 and across virtually all sign-ups. Discounts were lowest in sign-up 15 and greatest in sign-up 16. This may reflect initial uncertainty about the new program structure in sign-up 15 and the influence of additional points, introduced in sign-up 16, for bids below the maximum allowable rent. A large share of bids have zero discounts, especially in the lower payment categories. The proportion offering non-zero discounts tends to increase as the maximum rent increases and tends to decrease for higher exogenous EBI scores. For example, in sign-up 26, the proportion 111 of non-zero discounts declines within the first maximum rent quartile from 30 to 19% and declines from 85 to 62% in the highest maximum rent quartile. Another way for farmers to increase their total EBI is by adopting more valuable conservation practices, such as plantings of native grasses. The set of columns in table 1 labeled Conservation Practice Points demonstrate the tendency to adopt a more valuable conservation practice at lower exogenous EBI scores. Conservation practice points tend to increase with the maximum payment quartiles, but the pattern is not universal. In general, the summary statistics would seem to indicate the landowners increase the endogenous components of their bid as their exogenously-determined EBI decreases. This pattern is consistent with the hypothesis that landowners with higher exogenous EBI scores are able to command greater windfall gains from the program. 4 A Model of Bidding Behavior Although reservation rents are not directly observed, they are implicit in farmers' proposed rents and conservation practices. Under the program's incentive structure, the exogenous components of the EBI encourage farmers to propose higher rents and less costly covers and wildlife practices, all else remaining the same. In this section, we spell out these incentives using a simple model. Define F as the distribution function of farmers' subjective beliefs about E*, the critical bid score. All scores above E* are accepted into the program and all scores below E* are rejected, but farmers do not know E* when they submit their bids. The Secretary of Agriculture 112 makes this decision after all bids have been submitted.34 Farmers choose their proposed rent, r, conservation practice with annualized establishment cost, c, and whether or not they propose to share costs with the government, s.3 5 Higher proposed rents negatively influence the SCORE. The EBI is a function of exogenous factors and of the conservation practices chosen with associated costs c. Assume farmers choose r, c, and s in order to maximize the expected net benefit from their proposed contract given their reservation rent and the maximum rental payment rm. Once a bid is accepted, the farmer's yearly net benefit is the rent minus their reservation rent (the opportunity cost of their land) and the annualized value of establishing the proposed conservation practice, (r - r - ac), for the duration of the contract. We call this net benefit the farmer's premium, PREM. The parameter a equals 1 if s=O and a equals /2 if s=1. Thus, the farmer's objective is: max V(r, c, s) = PREM x F + r (2) subject to: (rm - r) 2 0, where F =Prob[E* < SCORE], and SCORE = g(c) + z - Or+ 1Os. The function g(c) gives the endogenous component of the EBI as a function of cost, c; z is the exogenous EBI component, and the parameter 0 scales the marginal reduction in SCORE from a $1 increase in the proposed rental rate. If r< rm (the maximum rent constraint does not bind), the first order conditions are: 34 The weight w in N7 is also uncertain in the eyes of landowners. We do not explicitly examine this source of uncertainty, though it should affect marginal incentives to bid in a similar way as uncertainty about E*. Although this weight can be changed at the government's discretion, this value has been the same in sign-ups 16, 18, 20 and 26 so we'expect variation in beliefs about this weight to be small. While the weight is not explicitly reported, it could be approximated from publicly available statistics on each sign-up. 35 Practices may also involve annual maintenance costs, which are not subject to the cost-sharing option. Instead, the government typically pays a fixed maintenance allowance of $5 per acre. As long as the difference between the actual maintenance costs and this allowance is small, this will not significantly influence the farmer's decisions. 113 - 0(r - r - ac)F'+F= O (3) g (r - (4) ac ? - ac)F'-aF = These conditions imply that the marginal expected benefit from an increase in the probability of acceptance equals the expected marginal cost from the decreased premium. If we define G = FIF', an increasing function of SCORE, these conditions can be written as: - (r-r--ac)+G=O -(r 8c Thus, PREM = G/ = aG/ ag / c' - - ac) - aG = 0 (5) (6) where G is the distribution function divided by the density function of farmers' beliefs regarding the critical EBI score. This implies farmers will balance their offered bids and costs until 0-= /a, such that the marginal costs of raising the SCORE by lowering the bid equal the marginal costs of doing so by increasing costs. The discrete cost share decision (s) cannot be analyzed from these marginal conditions, but does influence the marginal tradeoffs via a. Both conditions imply PREM is an increasing function of SCORE, unless the constraint (r' - r) > 0 binds, in which case PREM < G/0 =aG/ g . This is consistent with the intuition / ac given in the introduction. Farmers with higher SCORES, all else the same, will have higher rental premiums, unless these are constrained by the maximum allowable rent. 114 4.1 Empirical Model Because we do not observe PREM, we rewrite the first order condition (5) in terms of rent net of costs: r - ac -G +r. (7) Reservation rents are not observable and are embodied by the intercept and residual in our regressions. The intercept reflects the average reservation rent and the residual embodies the difference between this average reservation rent and that of the current observation. Since affects farmers' choice of SCORE, SCORE is endogenous. Dealing with the endogeneity of SCORE is our main econometric challenge. By using the exogenous component of the EBI as an instrument for SCORE, we solve the problem that SCORE is a choice variable. However, a different form of endogeneity arises if r is correlated with the exogenous EBI, not because one variable affects the other, but because heterogeneous land attributes affect both land values and the exogenous components of the EBI. In order reduce unobserved heterogeneity of land, we include the soil-specific rental rate, measures of on-farm wind and soil erosion, and fixed effects for state. Another issue concerns the functional form of G. In general, G has a positive slope. For most parametric distributions, G will be a non-linear function of SCORE. Of course, we have no information about the shape of landowners' prior beliefs about E*. Rather than explicitly modeling this unknown distribution of beliefs, we estimate (7) using a simple linear model: (ri - aci ) = + AISCOREi + controlsi + ui, 115 (8) In this formulation, - = l0 + ,l SCOREi, where SCORE, is the predicted SCORE from the first stage. The estimated parameter shape or whether landowners ] G gives the average slope of - regardless of the function's have heterogeneous beliefs about E*.36 Simplicity is also necessary because we must estimate a censored regression model (with instrumental variables) to account for the constraint, (rm - r) > 0. The reservation rent () is embodied by a combination of the controls and the residual, ui. Costs (aci) are observed only for offers that propose costsharing with the government (where s=1 and a=1/2). We annualize these establishment costs by multiplying them by 0.10. For offers not sharing costs, we approximate costs from offers in the same county proposing the same practices that do share costs. In order to estimate the effect of SCORE on the rent premium, we must account for the constraint that bids cannot exceed the soil-specific maximum payment. But for this constraint, farmers with very high EBI scores may offer a very high rental rate. In this sense, the farmer's true offered rent is censored by the soil-specific maximum rent. Farmers can circumvent the constraint to some degree by offering less expensive conservation practices, thereby netting a higher rental payment. A strictly constrained bid is one that offers to accept the maximum rental rate and to provide the least expensive conservation practice. Our inability to observe the least expensive conservation practice necessitates an estimation strategy that provides upper and lower bounds to the effect of SCORE. We estimate these bounds using (1) a linear instrumental variables (IV) model and (2) an IV-tobit model that treats all bids that offer to accept the 36 Besides the functional form of G and the maximum rental rate, the slope of the PREM and SCORE relationship is influenced by the EBI cost function, whether or not a farmers chooses to share costs with the Federal government, whether or not a farmer's offered rent is more than $15 below the maximum rental rate, and unobserved heterogeneity in beliefs about E*. For these reasons it is important to interpret estimates from our linear model as estimates for the average slope, which may not accurately reflect the slope associated with any particular offer. 116 maximum payment as constrained. The linear IV underestimates the effect of SCORE by assuming that all bids are unconstrained and optimal, and the IV-tobit overstates the effect by labeling too many bids as constrained and suboptimal, even though they may not be constrained by the cost of the conservation practice. We estimate reservation rents as predicted values from the estimated models with the values for SCORE re-set to the lowest observed value. This prediction is based on the theory, which tells us reservation rents equal the observed values minus G(SCORE). Since we only approximate G(SCORE) with a linear relationship, it is inappropriate to extrapolate beyond the region of our data by setting SCORE to zero. By setting SCORE to the minimum observed value in each sign-up, we approximate the minimum observed value of G(SCORE), which is likely close to zero. Essentially, this assumes those with the lowest bids believe they have a small chance of being accepted into the program and have negligible premiums. 5 Results Table 2 summarizes results from our IV and IV-tobit regressions. For each sign-up, the table reports the estimated coefficient and standard error on SCORE for each of the two regressions. This coefficient gives the estimated increase in a landowner's premium for each additional SCORE point, holding all other factors the same. For example, the first row of column 2 reports the IV estimated coefficient on SCORE as 0.015. This estimate implies farmers received a premium of 1.5 cents per acre for each additional point they received in sign-up 15. If all farmers were to bid their reservation rents, their bids would effectively be exogenous, and this coefficient would be zero. In nearly every sign-up, the coefficient on the IV-tobit regression is larger than the IV counterpart. In line with the reasoning given above, the IV estimate 117 constitutes a lower bound on the marginal premium and the IV-tobit constitutes an upper bound. The single exception is sign-up 15 where the difference between the estimates is negligible. The coefficient on SCORE increases markedly between sign-ups 16, 18, and 20, during which the configuration of the EBI remained unchanged. This pattern is consistent with a progressive decline in bidders' uncertainty regarding the critical score needed to gain acceptance into the program, enabling landowners to extract larger premiums. The estimated coefficients for sign-up 26 are below those for sign-ups 18 and 20. This may reflect greater uncertainty over the critical score in sign-up 26 due to the changes to the EBI introduced with this sign-up. For each regression, the table also reports the R2, and an F-test from the first-stage regression, which indicate our instruments are strong predictors of SCORE.3 7 Table 3 reports average rents paid by the CRP and the average estimated premium for all contracts accepted in the U.S. and for all those accepted in each of the eleven states enrolling more than one million acres in total over the five sign-ups examined. The estimates show how much premiums have increased over time between sign-ups 15 and 20 before decreasing somewhat in sign-up 26. In sign-up 20, we estimate an average premium per-acre of $15.1 to $21.2 with an average rent paid of $52.8, implying that about $37 to $52 million of the $129 million in annual rent payments associated with this sign-up constitute windfall gains to participating landowners. 6 Conclusion In this paper we have estimated the premiums received by CRP participants above their reservation rents. Estimated premiums have generally increased over time and constitute 10 to 37 Parameter estimates for the controls and first-stage regressions are not reported for brevity but are available upon request. 118 40 percent of the program's rental pay-outs under sign-ups 20 and 26, the two most recent signups for which we have data. However, it is not clear whether the same lands with the same conservation practices could be retired for less money. These premiums may be necessary to induce landowners to reveal their reservation rents and enroll their land in CRP under alternative systems. Our estimates may begin to clarify the tradeoffs being made in the current bidding scheme and inspire consideration of alternative payment mechanisms. For example, a cost-effective alternative to the current program is one that institutes a Pigouvian tax or subsidy. Barring large administrative costs, the CRP could reduce economic costs by either offering rental rates on a schedule that pays a constant price per EBI point, or taxing plantings of those who do not retire cropland at a rate equal to a constant price per EBI point lost from non-retirement. 3 8 In both cases, this scheme would reduce societal costs, though not necessarily government outlays. Economic efficiency would be achieved so long as the price per EBI point was set equal to marginal environmental benefits in equilibrium. However, these options may be politically infeasible because they would entail potentially large transfers of wealth from taxpayers to farmers under the subsidy option and vice-versa under the tax. The current system attempts to balance economic efficiency with limiting wealth transfer to farmers. By establishing maximum rental payments, the current scheme seeks to limit transfers to farmers, but it also inhibits farmers with reservation rents above maximum rents from submitting bids, even if their land would have high EBI scores. Furthermore, under the current scheme, those submitting bids with high exogenous EBI scores have little incentive to adopt more valuable conservation practices, even at low private costs, since their bids are likely to be accepted regardless. 3, FSA currently offers a fixed price for specific conservation practices under the continuous CRP sign-ups. 119 Might it be possible to implement a bidding scheme that achieves a more efficient balance between wealth transfer and environmental gain? Our findings suggest that potential cost savings could be substantial. Future research might fruitfully explore the implications of alternative bidding schemes and program structures. 120 References Cason, T. N. "Auction Design for Voluntary Conservation Programs." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86 (2004): 1211-1217. Feather, P., D. Hellerstein, and L. Hansen. 1999. "Economic Valuation of Environmental Benefits and the Targeting of the Conservation Programs: The Case of the CRP." Agricultural Economics Report No. 778. U.S. Department of Agriculture Economic Research Service. Washington, D.C Ribaudo, M. O., D. Colacicco, L. L. Langner, S. Piper, G. D. Schaible. 1990. "Natural Resources and User Benefit from the Conservation Reserve Program." Agricultural Economics Report No. 627. U.S. Department of Agriculture Economic Research Service. Washington, D.C. Shoemaker, R. 1989. "Agricultural Land Values and Rents under the Conservation Reserve Program." American Journal ofAgricultural Economics 65 (1989): 131-137. Vukina, T., A. Levy, and M. Marra. 2003. "Do Farmers Value the Environment? the Conservation Reserve Program Auctions." Manuscript. http://www.ag-econ.ncsu.edu/faculty/vukina/vukina.htm 121 Evidence from -"D00I 1- -9 ,-'t' s OI -t -t. r- CO1 t ON" 0OD -' 'C N " -_ c0 £0 O = - t N O 0 0 C4 a(n U U U C) -0 O 00 I'D - o C 'I oo 000000 00O - - Cl 0000 00: 00 0 00 0C 00 C &i Ci r) w kr ,I "t W) k r- NN'; .0 - r 'C 00-rli ct "- k C r.r 10 0 1C CII CI . 9 :a C 0 C C) C I in o o6 r4C,, 00 "Cl 6666 r. 6 0 0 6 0 6 rN r o66 oo6 en 00 r)0 -INd - t Cl " o )o C O l rq C C C C)0C> I'\dC~ °ON c " " lC ro C>C)C>C II z c-I 'IT)"00 0 ,,I rx~ ,I 5 n rcn C 00 C oo - 00 - I'l 00 00 00 t oo - - O00 S .S e\000000 ON0000l0 &C l r00 000000C elN'INkj lirN 0N,00 0000 C).. C.) C)Q -l 4 " M o O0 ,: f)kf tO -_= C) rn h) C m O 0 h-I n Cl4 C, O W) ) tn W) -D (= (= ( c cnr n ON 00 CN clqlrq"" 00 c W) V) "C "C110 r ,C in - T O en , ^'t mm td- 00 n ^ Id 0 0 C R o ON O 't O "C 'D00'. to n- ' eC 00oC 00 m '0D 6 6 )6 OC moo o ClC II II r~( m mm; m;; . Q m mv v l .mm0 X< - C * oN - V 11 e Ux O V O' ' N V 00 00X IM. I . 1 V) o - w0o V V -IN lbb v v am " .r.cn p v, "C 0\c O o 0- N ON V0 C 0 )mIXO 0 II II mm m O°° k 1 o) k)- k, 0 ,t V V V- X Xl \000V I II V 6 VV - C) C N r- sD0 N 00 II ~ n enr M en C~ C~ .0 C' C.) - O CN C O~C>ON - tn O C1 C I- rh W) " ; Io0T o nC O.O Co> (71 c C) _ ~c M c ON \ :n W - -'IN -< - o0\0\ -4 fNON N ONONONO, Cl0Cl000 C v0 f&~ 00 00000N, ,t o r-- O - e~ o -o _n [., O ("1 ("', ,m-, N C -N NoO ,4d m O - - 6 6 66 rc cr ·1 ., o t - O- -4 -: Cf C)l- 0D C 0 00 I i dN _ · _1 x W ,,IN'INr acl -o I- I 'I O " ) (U v - 'C d- -m 0,C, . o .- N- rCCl C 0000 C 0 O o= =o O 0 cl tO ·C£ l DVNN.0. r 00 -00 00t > 6 00 .o o O cor _N'.0'. C - -- 0 r M rlo 6666 C - cl nC i0 00 00 en N 'I 00 t 00 l t ^r C> t o \C DCc 'IT It I It It oo6 56 0 N C- -- rl- 11 6oo 6'0 C) 0 ONOtr0t " - 00 'I 600 006 C5 6666 0 00 o oo0 -e) ONOa-,00 ' -- N"00 'IN ,t NNNr O 'I0 C ' A 0= oo C) - o r 00 6 ONON00 6N 6 6 I 00 alc o oo 1D oo C, DA c-'IN NN O00Oal C C m O O c *-"o - 0 0D n o0 o 00 od -4 : WN u 'Ci 1~0'IC Ci o Cj. · , 0 ,o4- - o "T._-i ,,:I-t I ac C M tg aE e 'IC ON, O 00 en 00 00 On 00k0 'I _ ON O' 00 N 00 o4 t -Vr) -; \n 9 ICN 1 - l cn 11o 'IC C 0 0000 W) aE o - '.0 I '.0'.0dd -e~oOOO ON l0 oo~ k C r- ~t oe nrn "Ir C ' en r) oo r- O~ llD sr t o0 OC O 0,N - U I.c co a) t 0000 O~ " t V) Ci 0o It e t t CO lo oCr 'C C CE r I oon00 6 666N ~t N--00 6a N rm'.00 Clh(nNO ~ o66 6 6 6 6o Co6 O 00 ON 6 6 06 6 ro 0000 0000 _Un O O O O o0O o6 " C, o, r- n Cl C. C U O OOO -o 0 O n. )tN00 CNNON . . t. . . -0 ". tnNrON m -Ci -o 0 o -o O 0 dddd~'I'N0I 0 VXbI V V Cl ,o x *" O 0 Xv w w~ OO - v c oo00~ . pC )a \ 3 ~' ~C) o ~ ~ __ ' cn O c > 'o t~~~~ st <c, oo oo °o m-3crI o M3 C (a. a,a,, 0 v,~o - . _A3-v o c~~~~~k )V1 C)a r- I o ~~~~= I -lt:~~~~ nI:T kf) > O rCD tw u u 0 -\t:'A c Iq E c)~~ C3 (OI. 3; t Ov (00 =r U 0 O~~~D~ vlO ~oo~o 00 o 0~ o~~~~~~~~~~~~~t U z 0 >l f oo 033 cl (1) (21 C~~~O C13 CA \o 000 o 0 1 k. C7, c~~~~~~~ a ~ O~ ~~ r, rc, 0 c o o o;- r=~~~~~~~~~~~~~~V 00 egg~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~D~~~"a ~~~~~~~~~~~~ S 0 d~ c,d O~~~~~ c~~" ' - a u, dv, O " 0~~~~~~ ~~~ C C-1 C-_ .n '"'~ _ Fw ", " IZI I 3 ; -i5 ! nM a "8ol~~. o:N~~~~~~~~'z o\ C) - Oa,'-tr) " O o o ~ t > 4d m. -, m 41.0 C's 4-4 0 E C4 L E ~ 0 M _n W z - F 4 P- C13C u 7" b $, - `O .D, I. W u o~ °o = 00 -vp . m c, ~ o to z oo~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ En m ~~ ~~~~~;° t-~~~ . . a, W aa ^" C)) cn ]- . " 0 , )Q rn cn ~~~ ° o owyOO ' m 300~~3 o c~,'U ~e c CZ= 0 a, u3C.~::; C's ~ a I ~ --"- - . c ~~ vl9~~ I o 00 a-z~0u L. I rj ¢ kn 0a)t) m t4 C) o i) .) C' kncn 00 Cl C e er Incrln~,v Cl _ 0) V W) m 4 V) t p~ "t Cl Cl' = " ~~ Cl ~~l ~ l ~~l C l~l~~lC lrI 0 )0 SuQ p4< E 0) _ -e c O o0 0 OC= OOD Oo= o I- iI, -rCl . _ d_ -0) - - 0N00 9 0) lI t- I " <mw1 I) tn n " r- ,% .- I I c, cnM kn ~ c lf A\00~ 0 ~~0~~~V C ; c.,r - 0) O I- QC> S; O _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ I-.c pCcd ,CD- _ W r.o 0 Cl -n . av n - rI In n;^ .. C 0 -n 0 o* _ - - - - - 'ud LQ U ° 3 I00( C5 V] Hz e 00O kD m00 N *0) oo o C0 Fa -E , 0 * FI 00 kn Cn W) 0 C1 m 00 r-: r O I~ I 00 ClC> 00 00 NCl Cl ¢- I I rI 0 1orod 0 6 IO 00 1-00t-g: I0 o 6' II AC ' D 5PC5 E5 ¢. c 0 ~~~~~~~~~ 00 .S 00 to f~~~~~~~t~ I0 - Cl n , v C,3'n- In I , ) C) aH 4-. 4-. C l - Ct ¼ ._ -^ 0n C_ 0.0N0 oC~dC~0 a) Ct a I- . Ev ra r. C -0) 0 _F t 1 0 cn 'n _ ud 0o u 00 ^.D 0 000 0r 0 00'ClN m 0 ~~4u O* k. 00 C- w C* c~~v z0)z ccio~c6~S