Who Benefits from Bond Market Modernization? DAVID MUSTO University of Pennsylvania, The Wharton School & Securities and Exchange Commission ∗ JILLIAN POPADAK Duke University, Fuqua School of Business ABSTRACT We analyze the role modernization plays in shaping corporate bond market transactions. To identify the effects of technological change, we use SEC eligibility cut-off rules that allow “Well-Known Seasoned Issuers” (WKSI) to accelerate issuance speeds. We find widespread adoption of incurrencebased covenants, which serve the economic purpose of substituting for investor diligence. Evidence on covenant pricing and bondholding suggests the transformative power of technology mostly benefits those intended. Learning externalities from transitioning to covenant-heavy bonds coincide with a contract uncertainty premium, which benefits sophisticated investors. Issuers bear some costs in the transition but benefit from an expanded set of bondholders and lower volatility. Competition prevents underwriters from profiting. JEL classification: G3, G32, G2 Keywords: Raising Capital, Financial Innovation, Financial Intermediation, Fixed Income, Corporate Bonds, Contracting, Covenants, Primary Offerings, Sophisticated Investors, WKSI. ∗ Musto: The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 3620 Locust Walk, Suite 3000, Philadelphia, PA 19104 (e-mail: musto@wharton.upenn.edu) and the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). Popadak: Duke University, Fuqua School of Business, 100 Fuqua Drive, Durham, NC 27708 (e-mail: jillian.popadak@duke.edu). For helpful comments, we thank Sudheer Chava, Adam Cohen, Kathleen Hanley, Campbell Harvey, Gregor Matvos, Adriano Rampini, and seminar participants at the Napa Conference on Financial Markets, the Ohio State University, and Washington University in St. Louis. Joshua Aronoff and Jacob Ledbetter provided research assistance. The Securities and Exchange Commission disclaims responsibility for any private publication or statement by any of its employees. This study expresses the authors’ views and does not necessarily reflect those of the Commission, the Commissioners or other members of the staff. The corporate bond market is the world’s largest and deepest source of capital for firms; it facilitates capital provision for a diverse set of issuers and investment opportunities for a broad array of investors. Because bond markets play such an important role in the financial landscape, enabling their efficiency is critical. While the objective of a well-functioning bond market is clear, little is known about how the transformative power of technology affects bond market transactions and participants. Recent comments by the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) Chairman suggest investors would widely benefit from adopting new technologies in the bond markets (White (2014)). Yet theory suggests the benefits may not accrue to all investors because intermediaries may leverage such innovations to their benefit at the expense of other market participants. We shed light on this debate by analyzing a regulatory reform that modernized the bond issuance process and allowed issuers to quickly bring new deals to the market. Using novel data that captures many complexities of the bond market, we analyze the benefits and costs of transformation. A rich theoretical literature provides intuition for which market frictions may interact with changes to the bond issuance process as well as how such frictions affect efficiency. We focus on the theoretical trade-offs influenced by accelerating the speed of issuance for each of the participants involved in the deal (i.e., issuers, investors, and underwriters). First, we consider the issuers’ incentives. It is well-known that higher leverage distorts incentives, pushing management from value maximization toward shareholder value maximization (e.g., Myers (1977), Smith and Warner (1979)). Introducing debt contract terms such as restrictive covenants may ameliorate bondholders’ concerns but only at the expense of issuers’ freedom to manage. Second, we consider the underwriter’s incentives. Conducting due diligence on the issuers’ situation takes time. Legal risk encourages underwriters to perform due diligence, but at the same time, demands for timely delivery and pressures from competing underwriters may compress the time allotted to diligence in order to preserve market share. Third, we consider the investors’ incentives. The bond market has a free-rider problem where each buyer benefits from other buyers’ diligence. A potential remedy is a boilerplate contract (Kahan and Klausner (1997)) which simplifies the necessary task, but rigid contract terms impose costs when the optimal contract deviates substantially from the boilerplate. The many frictions faced by bond market participants make it difficult to disentangle the costs 1 and benefits of modernization. Moreover, empirically establishing the effects of modernization on bond market participants is difficult because modernization is not randomly assigned. We overcome these challenges to identification by examining a particular type of modernization with eligibility cut-off rules that deliver a quasi-natural experiment. So instead of using a randomization rule to assign firms to treatment, we use the eligibility cut-offs to naturally assign firms to treatment as if by randomization. Thus, we have a differences-in-difference estimator. The first difference is time, pre-modernization vs. post, and the second difference is above the cut-off vs. below, which differences out the time trends that affected both treated and control firms. The modernization we exploit involves the SEC defining a special type of securities issuer, a Well-Known Seasoned Issuer, or WKSI. By definition, WKSI eligibility requires a worldwide market value of outstanding common equity of $700 million or more. Whether an issuer meets this cutoff is precisely observable, and what the issuer gets for meeting it is immediate effectiveness of its registration statements. This immediacy from the new SEC rules allows an issuer to proceed as quickly as it likes from filing its registration to completing its offering, and thus to reduce its investors’ opportunity for diligence substantially. Embracing the fact that technology has enabled high-speed information sharing, under the new SEC rules, “access equals delivery” meaning traditional marketing documents such as a Prospectus that details the complex contractual arrangements need only to be accessible online. This rule is therefore not only convenient for strong identification but also potentially consequential for efficient contracting. First, we address the effect of modernization on bond issuances. Because accelerated issuance compresses investors’ time for scrutiny, and scrutiny helps investors gauge a bond’s risk and present value, acceleration may endanger subscription. To test this logic, we examine the reforms effect on offering quantities. Because deal volume affects a firm’s ability to finance operations and undertake new investments, any impact of modernization on issuances is critical to the growth and stability of the corporate sector. Second, we examine the reform’s effect on contract design. In particular, we test whether issuers modify contracts to simplify their values across future states, and thus make them easier to scrutinize on a tighter schedule. Using a new database assembled from SEC filings, we find the reform facilitates faster issuance speeds, has no effect on the offering amount, 2 and meaningfully affects covenant use. In particular, WKSI-eligible issuers adopt 2.8 more covenants, on average, relative to ineligible issuers in the two years following the reform. The new covenants are incurrence-based covenants that are traditionally thought to protect investors from events such as major asset sales or takeovers. For example, the change-of-control covenant allows investors in bonds threatened by acquisition to sell those bonds back to the issuer at 101% of par value. Our point estimates suggest there was 42 percentage point increase in the use of change-of-control covenants among WKSI-eligible issuers. Why incurrence-based covenants? Our evidence suggests issuers strengthened the terms of their bond contracts because investors did not have time to evaluate the likelihood of such events occurring when faster transactions began to occur. Put another way, the additional covenants serve the significant economic purpose of substituting for investor diligence. Second, we examine the pricing effects of the modernization-induced change in contractual terms. The rapid onset of covenant use isolates changes in valuation with unusual precision. Because many issuers floated bonds both shortly after and before the transition, it provides us with a set of bonds from the same issuer, with similar maturity, with and without the contracting change. The market’s appraisal of the effect of the change on bond value is apparent in the yield difference. We focus our analysis on the change-of-control covenant, which is economically relevant (Billet et al. (2007)) with well-established price effects (?) and substantial heterogeneity in the quality of its underwriting (Credit Roundtable (2008)). We find the average effect of including a change-ofcontrol covenant is 23 basis points less yield, which is in the neighborhood of others’ findings and indicative of a large impact on bond value. Closer examination, however, reveals that introducing the covenant tends to increase the yield: we find a significant negative effect on value when an issuer uses the covenant for the first time, when covenant-inclusion represents a large deviation from recent contracting by other issuers, and when the issuance terms differ meaningfully from the base prospectus. These findings suggest initially issuers bear some costs from the modernization. Who invests in the bonds that are priced with the bargain covenant? Our evidence suggest mutual funds are buying these bonds. And then, over the subsequent two quarters through secondary market trades, the bargain covenant becomes priced. The initial investors realize gains from 3 trade by selling these bonds, via small volume transactions, to subsequent investors. Overall, this evolution increases the number of bondholders relative to bonds issued prior to the modernization reform. It appears mutual funds were able to find the bargain investment, because of prior due diligence on the same issuer. This suggests other investors were free-riding off of the mutual funds’ due diligence rather than underwriters forewarning their favorite clients about the bargain covenant. Finally, volatility analyses suggest the modernization is associated with less volatile pricing once investors learn about the change in contract design. These findings suggest in the longer-term issuers benefit from the modernization. Last, we address the effect of modernization on underwriters, as represented by their market share and fees. On the one hand, underwriters face increasing legal danger when a deal goes south, but at the same time, they are being encouraged by issuers and regulators to bring deals to market at lightning speed – and if they turn down the business, they know another, less rigorous firm will simply step in and execute it anyway. We find no evidence that underwriters are able to charge higher fees for the timelier issuances. Further, we find no evidence that a single underwriter was able to gain market share either by transaction count of transaction amount from introducing the covenant-heavy contract. In fact within two quarters of the SEC reform, all underwriters began to include the incurrence-based covenants. This suggests the underwriter market is highly competitive and underwriters were not able to extract rents from the modernization. Overall, our empirical findings related to the effect of modernization on the bond issuance process highlight the importance of learning externalities. Our evidence is consistent with the notion that repetition reduces the cost that investors must expend in learning the meaning of contract terms. Initial investors after the modernization reforms may not have been aware of the contract terms because the accelerated issuance speeds constrained their ability to scrutinize them. Investors’ exposure to this contract uncertainty suggests investors should be compensated in terms of risk and reward. From this viewpoint, the first issuers bear a type of compliance cost when issuing post reform, but once the terms have become familiar through use over longer periods of time, the standardization of terms suggest investors deserve less of an uncertainty premium. This implies for all to benefit from modernization the costs of contract analysis must be reduced. One 4 potential solution is to use increasingly standardized contract terms as our analysis reveals, but the externalities such a solution imposes should be carefully considered (e.g., less effective markets for corporate control). Our findings contribute several important empirical results relevant to both academic research and policymakers. Our work complements work examining the effects of modernization on investors’ ability to hedge new equity issuance, issuer’s information disclosure and placement channel (Fenn (2000); Hanley and Hoberg (2013); Gao and Ritter (2010)). By highlighting how learning externalities shape the pricing and inclusion of covenants, we contribute to the prior literature which considers variations in agency costs (Kahan and Yermack (1998), Bradley and Roberts (2004)), path dependence (Kahan and Klausner (1997); De Franco et al. (2014)), and the supply-side (Murfin (2012)) as reasons for covenant restrictiveness. By emphasizing the time-series variation in covenant pricing, we contribute to evidence on the price of covenants (Billet et al. (2007)). Our finding that context-dependent decision-marking affects sophisticated investors shows recent work focusing on unsophisticated investors generalizes (Barber and Odean (2008); Hastings and Shapiro (2013)). Our evidence on bondholders’ due diligence efforts complements research examining bond market clienteles’ preferences and portfolios having a real effect on prices (Becker and Ivashina (2014)). More broadly, our research provides empirical evidence for competing theories of the economic consequences of financial innovation (Lerner and Tufano (2011); Zingales (2015)). Section I reviews the theory and evidence on bond market modernization and details the main hypotheses. Section II outlines the SEC regulatory reforms. Section III details how the regulatory reform is used to construct estimators that isolate the impact of bond market modernization. Section IV presents the data. Section V describes the results. Section VI places the results in context, and Section VII concludes. I. Theoretical Framework Financial innovation, including both product and process innovation, has been one of the most influential trends prevailing in international financial markets since the 1980s. There are a number of surveys which document the emergence and growth of new financial markets and products such 5 as derivatives and securitized assets (e.g., Tufano (2003)). To a lesser extent, there exists research covering financial process innovation such as the implementation of information technology into financial transactions; the financial process innovation research, however, is primarily theoretical rather than empirical. Hence, our empirical application provides an important testing ground for competing theories. When is financial process innovation beneficial and when is it not? To answer this question, theory separates the rent-seeking components of financial innovation from those that benefit society. We categorize the economic consequences of financial innovation as follows: enhanced efficiency; exploitation of unsophisticated investors; exacerbation of managerial agency problems; and rent-capture by financial intermediaries. We borrow from the economic theories underlying these consequences to derive a set of null and alternative hypotheses that result from bond market modernization via accelerated issuance speeds. As emphasized by Lerner and Tufano (2011), we are careful to consider the complexity of externality when evaluating the financial innovation’s welfare implications. Enhanced efficiency resulting from bond market modernization is our null hypothesis. In the traditional view, efficiency gains from financial innovation are realized either through transaction costs savings or its risk-reducing properties (Allen and Gale (1994)). In our setting, if before the regulation to accelerate bond issuance speeds, bond contracts are too customized, and modernization leads to a more standardized contract with a higher usage and lower transaction costs, this would be evidence of enhanced efficiency. The efficiency gains may also occur indirectly through financial intermediaries. For example, if financial process innovation increases competition among financial intermediaries, the economic surplus from such competition could accrue to issuers and/or bondholders through firm’s ability to raise capital in larger amounts and at a lower cost than they could otherwise and/or superior underwriting as a result of intermediaries competing for market share. The timing component of our setting suggests a third type of efficiency gain – improved market timing. In capital markets that are inefficient or segmented, market timing benefits firm’s investors at the expense of entering and exiting investors in the market. In a survey of CFOs, Graham and Harvey (2001) found a market-timing factor ranked above four traditional factors in 6 the decision to issue debt. In contrast to these traditional efficiency arguments, some theorists demonstrate how with the additional assumption of belief disagreement among investors, financial innovation increases transaction costs, promotes excessive trading, and/or increases risk (e.g., Simsek (2013a); French (2008); Simsek (2013b)). Exploitation of unsophisticated investors, primarily retail investors, is a popular perception of a harmful consequence of financial innovation (Zingales (2015)) and is an alternative hypotheses to efficiency gains. Such exploitation comes in both direct and indirect forms. First, investors may be directly sold a bond they do not understand and would have never wanted had they understood it. In our setting, if after modernization, investors buy a bond with contractual covenants that they would not have wanted had they understood or had the time to understand, this would be evidence of a detrimental effect of modernization. Second, if investors are attracted to bonds that are very convenient for sophisticated investors, who buy the cheap version and disregard the expensive version, but turn out to be costly for the unsophisticated investors. In our setting, if after modernization, sophisticated investors buy bonds with “free” or mispriced contractual features but sell them to retail investors at higher prices, this would be evidence of another detrimental effect of modernization. Free-riding by investors potentially amplifies any of the harmful consequences to unsophisticated and/or time-constrained investors brought about by financial innovation. The free-rider problem is simple: a bond is placed with many investors, each of whom benefits if others make the costly effort to ensure that the bond is worth the offering price. If financial innovation leads to the development of a new contractual term, the issuer can achieve a degree of customization that may not be available with terms that recent issuers have used. In contrast, the use of a contractual term which has been commonly used in the past can offer other benefits, because the effort potential investors need to exert is more costly when the bond’s contractual features make it hard to compare. This implies that as more issuers employ the same contract term, it becomes significantly more attractive for comparative reasons. Such intuition has been formalized and documented by Kahan and Klausner (1997). In our context, free-riding may reduce and delay the efficiency gains from innovation, because at first, the additional requirement on investors to learn any new contract terms 7 may make them unwilling to subscribe to the bond offering or require issuers to yield a greater return to potential investors in the form of a contract uncertainty premium. This is an important alternative hypothesis that we test. Because financial engineering provides an extremely flexible tool to exploit contractual relationships, managerial agency problems may be exacerbated by financial innovation and reduce the aggregate efficiency gains. In our setting, the firm’s investors may be unaware that their agents, the managers, are putting in place covenants such as anti-takeover provisions which insulate managers from the market for corporate control. Billet et al. (2007) show the inclusion of a change-of-control covenant, which is the dominant anti-takeover covenant in bonds, reduces the probability of becoming a takeover target by 50%. Because of the sizeable economic consequences of such entrenchment for investors, this is a critical alternative hypotheses. Rent-capture by financial intermediaries has both theoretical reasons and empirical evidence to claim that its’ an important component of financial innovation that needs to be considered as an alternative hypothesis. Gennaioli, Shleifer, and Vishny (2015) theorize that financial intermediaries cater to investor preferences by engineering securities perceived to be safe but exposed to neglected risks. Because the risks are neglected, issuance volume is excessively high and intermediaries profit from such transactions. Similarly, Dang, Gorton, Holmstrom, and Ordonez (2014) suggest intermediaries may leverage the timely information to their benefit at the expense of other market participants. These rent-capture theories compete with more traditional reputation arguments which suggest financial firms’ value their reputations and intend to be infinite-lived, so any innovation in underwriting or transactions will be value-added. II. SEC Regulatory Reform In 2005, the SEC adopted a series of new rules that reformed the registration, communication and public offering processes under the Securities Act of 1933. These new rules, which became effective December 1, 2005, were meant to improve and modernize the securities issuance process, and they serve as our source of identification. The regulatory change offers a unique opportunity to study the implications of financial innovation, to the extent that the change had a large, sudden, 8 and direct effect on the speed at which new bonds were issued for a segment of issuers in the corporate bond market. The SEC reforms focus on modernizing the communications regulatory scheme applicable to registered securities offerings. Eckbo, Masulis, and Norli (2007) provide an overview of these reforms, which they describe as “sweeping changes” and “major innovation.” While the new rules defined four types of issuers, our focus is on the creation of a new category of issuers called “well known seasoned issuers” (WKSI). We focus on the WKSIs because they receive treatment from the perspective of a statistical experiment meant to isolate the effect of innovation on the bond issuance process. Before detailing the reforms aimed at modernization or treatment that the WKSIs are subject to, it is important to be clear about what issuers meet the SEC definition of WKSI-eligible. While the definition involves several components, the requirement of a worldwide market value of outstanding common equity of $700 million or more is the binding constraint for the vast majority of issuers. A WKSI-eligible issuer is one that: (1) meets the registrant requirements of Form S-3 or Form F3, which include being current and timely in its reporting obligations under the Securities Exchange Act of 1934; (2) as of a date within 60 days of the determination date1 , has either a worldwide market value of outstanding voting and non-voting common equity held by non-affiliates of $700 million or more; or both (i) registered and issued at least $1 billion in aggregate principal amount of non-convertible debt or preferred stock for cash, not exchange, during the past three years, and (ii) will only offer non-convertible debt or preferred stock (unless the issuer is also eligible to register a primary offering of its securities on Form S-3 or Form F-3); and (3) is not an “ineligible issuer2 ” 1 The determination date is the later of (i) the filing date of the issuers most recent shelf registration statement (S-3); (ii) the date of the most recent amendment to the issuers shelf registration for purposes of satisfying Section 10(a)(3) of the Securities Act; and (iii) the filing date of the issuers most recent 10-K or 20-F (if the issuer has not filed a shelf registration statement for the prior 16 months). 2 “Ineligible issue” includes issuers that (i) are not current in their Exchange Act reporting requirements; (ii) are blank check companies, shell companies, penny stock issuers or limited partnerships offering other than through a firm commitment underwriting; (iii) within the past three years, have filed for bankruptcy; (iv) within the past three years, have been convicted of any felony or misdemeanor under certain provisions of the Exchange Act; (v) within the past three years, were made the subject of any judicial or administrative decree or order arising out of a governmental action that prohibits certain conduct regarding (including future violations of) the U.S. federal securities laws, requires them to cease and desist from violating the anti-fraud provisions of the U.S. federal securities laws or determines that they have violated those anti-fraud provisions; or (vi) within the past three years, have had any registration statement subject to an SEC refusal order or stop order. 9 or “asset backed issuer.” The treatment the WKSIs receive under the new rules is the flexibility to access the capital markets at will relative to other issuers and reductions in required information about the issuance prior to launching. In particular, WKSIs qualify for on-demand automatic shelf registration (ASR), which means WKSIs register securities offerings on significantly simplified registration statement that automatically and immediately becomes effective. Under the new Rule 462, an ASR and any post-effective amendment to an ASR also becomes effective immediately upon filing with the SEC. Moreover, revised Rule 415(a)(1)(x) permits primary offerings to occur immediately after effectiveness of an ASR. Under new Rules 456 and 457, the WKSI need not pay filing fees upon filing of the ASR, but rather can wait until the securities are “taken off of the shelf” and the actual offering commences. As a result, WKSIs face neither the time constraints, the financial constraints, nor the information risks associated with the SEC staffs review of a registration statement. In addition, under the new Rule 430B, the ASR and any Prospectus filed in connection with the ASR may omit a significant amount of information. Specifically, the WKSI may omit the description of the securities including the amount offered, but not including the type of securities, the distribution plan, any information that is unknown or not reasonably available (Rule 409), any potential covenants, whether the issuance is a primary or secondary offering, the identity of other issuers and the names and respective amounts of any selling securities holders. Rule 430B and Rule 512(a) allow the WKSI to include any omitted information in either a post-effective amendment to the ASR, a prospectus supplement filed under Rule 424(b) or by incorporation by reference to the WKSI’s other Exchange Act reports. Finally, Rule 413 permits WKSIs to add new classes of securities and additional issuers to its ASR through a post-effective amendment. Together, these changes eliminated the post-effective amendment requirements that obligated issuers to file amendments related to any fundamental disclosure change. As a result, the reforms streamline the issuance process for WKSIs. Once the ASR is effective, which occurs immediately, the WKSI can sell its securities whenever it wants. Depending on the WKSI’s view of the market, this could be immediately after filing, or it could be months later. At the time of the actual offering when the WKSI launches the deal, bringing 10 the securities to the market, the WKSI must simply file a post-effective amendment or a Rule 424(b) Prospectus supplement. The deadline for filing a Rule 424(b) Prospectuses is the second business day following the earlier of the pricing date and the date first used after effectiveness for public offerings or sales. In practice, the Preliminary Prospectus Supplement is typically filed the same day that the takedown launches, while the Final Prospectus is filed the morning after pricing. Typically, new issues trace the timeline outlined in Figure 1. As the figure shows potential investors, even if they may hear rumors of a prospective offering, do not get the Preliminary Prospectus Supplement, which is likely to include significantly more information such as the restrictive covenants, until just fifteen minutes or so before the deadline for expressing interest to the bookbuilder. Diligence in so little time would be significantly strained. How different is a WKSI offering from what those issuers did previously? While many commentators have stated that the reforms were a major innovation and the timeline provides a sense of the compressed timeframe investors’ face, an example helps solidify the differences. Figure 2 illustrates the issuance of a new bond by General Mills prior to the reform and Figure 3 illustrates the issuance of a new bond by General Mills after the reform. The figures describe the information contained in each SEC filing, what may change from one document to the next, as well as the length of the document, the number of times a covenant is mentioned and the textual overlap between the base Prospectus and the Final Prospectus Supplement. What is striking to note is that in the post-reform era there are only minutes to review a document that is 87 pages long that has changed more than 25% of the content in it including the covenants. Specifically, what we see is that after the WKSI reform, the issuer registered its potential new securities issuances using Form S-3/ASR, which does not require SEC review. The S-3/ASR usually includes some type of base Prospectus, but this does not include covenant terms. The S-3/ASR provides prospective buyers with basic firm information, risk factors, use of proceeds, and the plan of distribution. Then, at any point thereafter even when the risk factors or business outlook in the base Prospectus may have changed substantially, the WKSI issuer can go to market. When the issuer goes to market that would be the first time potential buyers learn about the issuance. In practice, rumors usually get out a few days before launch, or large bond investors have in-house 11 models to predict when a popular credit may go to market. On that offering date, under rule 424(b), the issuer submits a Preliminary Prospectus Supplement, which will have a description of the covenants, updated risk factors, and firm financials, but the supplement often becomes available at virtually the same time the new issuance is actually priced as indicated in Figure 1. In our example, the Preliminary Prospectus Supplement was provided the same morning that the new issuance is priced. Under Rules 164 and 433, the pricing and terms of the deal are recorded and distributed in the form of a term sheet that is used to market the securities the day of the launch and is called a Free-writing Prospectus (FWP), which is a short document that contains no information about covenants. Then, within two business days of the offering date, the Final Prospectus Supplement must be filed with all the details combined from the Free-writing Prospectus and any potential changes from the Preliminary Prospectus Supplement if there was negotiations for changes in contracts terms such as restrictive covenants between potential buyers and the issuer prior to pricing. In contrast to the post-reform era, our example WKSI-eligible issuer filed an S-3 shelf-registration form that had pre-specified details about potential takedowns (i.e., the amount and the types of issuance such as convertible debt, unsecured debt, etc . . . ). If those issuers need to increase the size or plan of distribution, they would need to file a post-effective amendment to the registration and wait for review, which typically takes about 48 hours. In our example, the issuer filed an S-3/A, and this filing also documented a small change in covenants. Not until the post-effective amendment is approved would it be a day when they could offer/price the bond. The S-3 shelf registration statement includes a base Prospectus, but in contrast to the S-3/ASR base Prospectus, the S-3 base Prospectus provide details about covenants and other terms ultimately contained in the indenture. There is, therefore, never a need to file a Supplement to the base Prospectus/registration statement at the time of issuance, because investors have had substantial time to scrutinize the terms. In our example, investors have had more than one year to familiarize themselves with the terms of a potential issuance from General Mills. Then, just like in the WKSI-era, in the pre-reform era, our issuer documented the final version of the indenture including the pricing terms after the offering is completed and accounting for any changes made as a result of negotiations with investors in a 12 Final Prospectus Supplement filed under Rule 424(b). Why did the SEC even adopt the reforms in the first place? By integrating disclosure and process under the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, the new rules were meant to reduce the procedural aspects of securities offering and enhance capital formation processes. While the SEC had circulated preliminary reform rules for commentary well before the adoption, the final rules were adopted with several changes to address a number of points raised by commenters. Hence, the exact date of the adoption and the details of the adoption are unlikely to have been anticipated by market participants. Further, it seems plausible to believe that firms that needed to raise capital in public debt markets in a timely manner would not have delayed raising debt until the rules were in place. This suggests that the adoption of the rules did have a sudden and direct effect on those that qualified, and those that qualified vs. those that did not qualify were subject to similar pre-treatment trends from a statistical viewpoint. In the next section, we detail how we use this SEC reform to isolate the effect of modernization on bond market participants. III. A. Identification Strategy Difference-in-differences Analyses We analyze the role modernization plays in shaping corporate bond market transactions. To empirically identify the effects of technological change, we use eligibility cut-off rules from the SEC’s WKSI regulatory reform that allowed bond issuers to significantly accelerate issuance speeds. Specifically, the WKSI issuers receive special filing exemptions that allow them to quickly go to market. The thresholds for eligibility provide a unique natural experiment. The firms just below the $700 million market value of common equity outstanding threshold remain subject to regulatory delays while those just above the threshold are not. As long as the firms are statistically indistinguishable along other dimensions close to the thresholds, the firms that do not qualify for WKSI status serve as an ideal counterfactual or control group to those treated firms that are subject to the financial modernization. Hence, the regulatory reform provides a quasi-natural experiment in which a difference-in-differences estimator captures the average treatment effect of the SEC reforms 13 aimed at bond market modernization. In our differences-in-difference design, we compare treated issuers (i.e., those that are eligible for WKSI) with a control issuers (i.e., those that are ineligible for WKSI) in the quarters pre-reform and post-reform. Typically, one cannot observe the counterfactual of what the contract design would have been absent treatment, but in this unique case, we are able to get a very good idea of what it would have been. To ensure our control firms are similar to our treated firms, we limit our sample to issuers near the $700 million threshold; doing so reduces the potential bias from unobservable factors that might be correlated with the threshold and with outcomes of interest such as pricing. Furthermore, because most firms visit the capital markets infrequently, firms are not required to be in the sample for all time periods around the event. We estimate the average treatment effect using the following issuer-panel regression: Yjit = α + βEligiblei + δ (Eligible × P ost)it + γXjit + g (CEjit , T otjit ) + ft + εjit (1) where Yjit represents outcome variables of interest such as pricing, quantity, and risk-sharing for issuance j by issuer i in quarter t, Eligible is an indicator for issuers that are eligible for WKSI status, P ost is an indicator for the post-reform period, and Xjit is a vector of issuer and issuance controls. We include time fixed effects, ft , to ensure that we estimate the impact of the regulatory reform after controlling for any fixed differences in contracting practices across time. An indicator for P ost is not included in the specification as it is collinear with the time fixed effects. To account for potential covariance among issuer outcomes, we cluster the standard errors at the issuer level. Finally, g (CEjit , T otjit ) is a flexible polynomial that is included in some specifications; the polynomial controls for how far the treated and control issuers are from Eligible based on the conditions of common equity market capitalization (CEjit ) and total offerings in the past three years (T otjit ). The flexible polynomial is a more conservative approach to difference-in-difference estimation, because it safeguards against comparing firms that are far from the qualifying threshold. 14 B. Within-Issuer Analyses The rapid modernization of the bond issuance process isolates changes in valuation and invest- ment with unusual precision. Because many issuers floated bonds both shortly after and before the transition, it provides us with a set of bonds from the same issuer, with similar maturity, with and without any modernization-induced contractual changes. This byproduct of the reform allows us to control for all issuer-specific variables by comparing the post-onset bond with a same-issuer, similarmaturity pre-onset bond. We use this within-issuer estimator to isolate different mechanisms via which modernization impacts the market participants. Our within-issuer sample focuses on WKSI-eligible issuers that changed contractual terms after the reform. By collecting a sample that spans a 10-year horizon, we started with a sufficiently large number of issuers that transitioned. The large sample size allows us to use a within estimator (i.e., fixed effects estimator) for our analyses. The within estimator measures the association between individual-specific deviations of dependent and independent variables from their respective average values over the observations. Because our issuer-specific pairs always involve two observations, the dataset can also be viewed as a panel dataset with two periods. In this special case of k = 2, the fixed effects estimator is statistically equivalent to a first difference estimator. To examine the pricing of contractual changes, we estimate the following two observation issuerpanel regression: Yjik = α + βCovjik + γXjik + fi + fk + εjik (2) where Yjik is the dependent variable for issuance j by issuer i at offering period k. Example outcome variables include yield less treasury, underpricing, etc . . . Covjik is an indicator for a covenant of interest. We include issuer fixed effects, offering year fixed effects, as well as a vector of issuance controls Xjik , which includes credit rating, maturity, and offering amount. To explore the heterogeneity underlying the subsequent pricing empirically, we return to the first-difference estimator and focus on salience and novelty as potential sources of variation. Our exact first-differences specification is as follows: 15 ∆Yji = β∆Salientji + γ4Xji + ∆fk + ∆εji (3) where ∆Yji is the difference in the dependent variable for issuance j by issuer i with and without the covenant. Salientji is an indicator for the covenant being the salient attribute relative to pricing or offering amount. F irstji indicates when the covenant is the first time that issuer has ever included such a covenant. Dissimilarji indicates the contract terms included at the time of issuance had changed significantly from the base prospectus (defined as below median textual similarity). Because of the differencing in this specification, we have effectively controlled for issuer fixed effects, but we continue to control for offering year fixed effects. Further, we control for differences in a vector of issuance controls Xji , which includes credit rating, maturity, offering amount, and offering yield. C. Underwriter Analyses While the difference-in-differences and within-issuer analyses allow us to estimate the effects of modernization on issuers and investors, we are also interested in the effects of modernization on underwriters. To examine the effects on underwriters, we estimate the following regression: Yit = α + βU nderwritingQualityit + γXit + fi + ft + εit (4) where Yit is the dependent variable of interest for underwriter i in in quarter t. Example outcomes include the number of new bond issuances, dollar volume of new bond issuances, market share, and underwriting fees. U nderwritingQualityit is the key variable of interest and measures aspects of the quality of the underwriting in the bond contract such as the inclusion of restrictive covenants, changes from the base Prospectus to the final Prospectus, the quality of the legal language used in the indenture as well as the time allowed for investor due diligence. We include underwriter fixed effects, quarter fixed effects, as well as a vector of other issuance controls including credit rating, maturity, offering amount, offering yield, and underwriter fees when appropriate. 16 IV. Data To examine the role modernization plays in shaping corporate bond market transactions, we collect detailed information on firm characteristics of bond issuers, the contractual design of bond issuances, the underwriters for the issuances, the quality of the underwriting, the pricing of the bonds, the investors in the bonds, and the subsequent trading patterns of the bonds. A. Bond Issuers We start with bond-level data from Mergent’s Fixed Income Securities Database (FISD) which is a comprehensive database of publicly-offered U.S. bonds. FISD provides details on corporate debt issues and the issuers. Mergent provides its’ own unique identifier for each issuer, the nine-character Committee on Uniform Securities Identification Procedures (CUSIP) that uniquely identifies an issuer and the type of security, the name of the issuer as recorded in the prospectus, and the name of the issuer as reported to the CUSIP. Using the unique CUSIP, we cross-reference this database with Thomson Reuters’ eMAXX database for U.S. corporate bond issuances as well as FINRA’s Trade Reporting and Compliance Engine (TRACE) database. Approximately 90% of bonds are consistently recorded across the three databases; for those with conflicting data, we search on Bloomberg and SEC’s Edgar database to resolve discrepancies. Based on the available issuer details such as CUSIP, ticker, and name from the bond-level dataset, we match the issuance data with Compustat to obtain financial and accounting data for these firms. Further, we match the data with corporate governance data from FactSet. B. Bond Contracts and Underwriting While Mergent’s FISD is a relatively comprehensive database of corporate bond issuances, its’ coverage of bond contract features is incomplete. For example, less than 10% of the bonds in its database have information on the covenants recorded. Even when the sample is limited to U.S. corporate bonds with an investment grade rating issued after 2000, only 70% of the bonds in its database have information on the covenants recorded. Further, the information provided in FISD on the covenants is typically only a yes or no indicator for if the covenant was included in the final 17 contract rather than information about the quality of the covenant’s underwriting or key thresholds. To overcome these data limitations, we web scraped the 424(b), S-3, S-3/A, S-3/ASR, FWP, and POS AM filings associated with new bond issuances from the SEC Edgar website. The Securities Exchange Act of 1933 requires issuers to file registration statements with the SEC before making an issue available for purchase by the public. As is outlined in Section II, the SEC reforms aimed at modernization altered the required form, timing of the filing, and type of information recorded in the filings. As such, we analyze the text contained in these filings in multiple ways. First, we obtain a simple count of the number of words in the file as well as the number of times the word “covenant” is mentioned as proxies for complexity. Second, we analyze the quality of the underwriting by examining specific phrases included by the underwriter in the contract. Third, we compute the linguistic similarity between the information available in the base Prospectus, which available at the time of pricing, and the Final Prospectus. Appendix B details the natural language processing techniques used to compute the linguistic similarity. The intuition for the similarity measure is that a score of 1 means the contracts are identical, a score of 0.75 would indicate 75% overlap in contracts, and 0 would indicate no overlap in contracts. To determine the quality of the underwriting, we follow legal precedents, which highlight two fundamental issues in the design of a change-of-control covenant. The first is the extent to which the covenant’s effectiveness depends on a credit rating change. Almost all investment grade bonds have some ratings condition. There is variance as to whether the bond must (1) cross from investment grade to high yield; (2) be high-yield; or (3) be lowered from investment grade to high-yield or from high-yield to an even lower rated high-yield. The second fundamental design issue is what defines a change-of-control event. There are five common triggers: (1) a person acquires more than 50% of the voting stock of the issuer; (2) a sale of substantially all assets; (3) a merger where the issuer’s shareholders don’t continue to own a majority of the merged firm; (4) a continuing directors test; and (5) adoption of a plan of liquidation or dissolution. Finally, there is also a “holding company” exception that can affect the operation of these triggers. The holding company exception nullifies some of the five common triggers, because in an acquisition of the issuer by another public company, the merger transaction does not result in a surviving corporation that is 18 more than 50 percent owned by any single “person” or “group” then the trigger event legally did not occur. We focus on the change-of-control covenant’s underwriting because this covenant has important economic consequences but also because it’s underwriting has been scrutinized at the highest level of courts. Based on the court findings and best practices published by Credit Roundtable (2008), there is solid legal precedent for determining the quality of the underwriting for this particular covenant. For the covenant to have strong underwriting, it cannot be subject to the defective holding company clause, it must have all five of the triggers, it must be dual triggered, and it must not require rating verification. For the covenant to have moderate underwriting, it cannot be subject to the defective holding company clause, it must have at least four of the triggers, it must be dual triggered, but it can require rating verification. For the covenant to have moderate underwriting, it can be subject to the defective holding company clause, it must have at least three of the triggers, it must be dual triggered, but it can require rating verification. For the covenant to have weak underwriting, it either has two or fewer triggers or it is not dual triggered. C. Bondholders and Bond Trades The bondholding data for our analysis comes from Thomson Reuters’ eMAXX database. The data provides comprehensive coverage of quarterly fixed income holdings by individual insurance companies, mutual funds, pension funds, annuity funds, hedge funds, and other institution-like investors (e.g., governments and hospitals). This allows us to construct a panel dataset with the total par value held by these sophisticated investors; we also know the number of holding portfolios, buying portfolios, and selling portfolios in any time period. With details on the other holdings by these investors, we know their experience holding covenant-light vs. covenant-heavy bonds, holding bonds when a firm becomes the target of a leveraged buyout (LBO), etc We combine the bondholder information with trade information from FINRA’s TRACE database. This database provides intraday transaction level trades. We use this data to determine the liquidity, trading volume, return volatility, and price paths for our sample of bonds. 19 V. A. Results Difference-in-Differences Results A causal interpretation for our difference-in-differences estimator is predicated on the assump- tion that absent the SEC reform, the WKSI-eligible issuers would, on average, have had the same changes in bond issuance outcomes such as changes in pricing, quantity issued, and contractual terms as ineligible issuers. Hence, we begin by examining the actions of eligible and ineligible issuers prior to the reform. Firms eligible for the WKSI status are very similar to our sample of ineligible firms in the years before the SEC reform became effective. Table I reports the ex-ante characteristics of WKSI-ineligible firms in column (1) and the ex-ante characteristics of WKSIeligible firms in column (2). The p-value from a t-test of differences in means is reported in column (3). The two groups are similar in market-to-book ratio, profitability, ROE, investment intensity, and recent growth in cash, assets, and revenue. Put another way, we are unable to reject the null hypothesis that WKSI-eligible issuers are similar to ineligible issuers in all of these dimensions. This evidence supports the interpretation that the effects of the SEC reforms aimed at modernization are caused by changes in the nature of the bond issuance process, rather than other unobservable contemporaneous changes differentially affecting control and treatment issuers. As expected, the issuers are slightly different in terms of firm size. For this reason, we include additional controls for distance from the qualifying size-based threshold to ensure issuers far from the threshold and thereby the likely counterfactuals are not driving the result. To estimate issuers responses to the SEC reforms aimed at modernization, we compare changes in the WKSI-ineligible and WKSI-eligible issuers’ outcomes around the time of the reform. We use the difference-in-differences estimation strategy described in Section III. Panel A of Table II presents the effects of the SEC reform on the price and quantity of newly issued bonds. Because accelerated issuance speeds shorten investors’ time for scrutiny, and scrutiny tends to make investors more comfortable subscribing to an offering, the faster schedule may come at a cost of endangering subscription. To test this logic, we first examine the reforms effect on offering prices and quantities. Because deal volume and higher borrowing costs affect a firm’s ability to finance ongoing operations 20 and undertake new investments, these factors are critical to the growth and stability of the U.S. corporate sector of the economy. Column (1) and (2) of Panel A show no evidence of an effect on the offering amount or pricing of an issuance. Column (3) and (4) repeat the estimation but using a four-year window on each side of the reform. If the effect of the reform took time to manifest in the pricing and quantity, the longer would capture these results. Again, we find no evidence to support pricing and quantity as the margins of adjustment for issuers after the reform. Where we find evidence of adjustment after the reform is in contract design and risk-sharing specifically. Panel B of Table II presents the effects of the SEC reform on contract design. We test contract design, because a possible remedy for the threat to the price and quantity involves changing the contract design to reduce the risk borne by the investor and thereby incentivize the investor to be more comfortable with subscribing to the offering even with the faster schedule. This hypothesis is consistent with the traditional view of financial innovation which proves efficiency gains are realized either through risk-reducing properties (Allen and Gale (1994)). We find that, on average, treated issuers statistically significantly increase covenant usage as a result of the SEC regulatory reform. The estimates reported in Column (1) indicate that, after the SEC reform, WKSI-qualifying issuers increased their use of restrictive covenants by adding, on average, 2.8 additional covenants relative to the issuers that did not qualify for WKSI status. Column (2) through (5) show the specific covenants for which issuers increased their use. All of the covenants are incurrence-based, restrictive covenants such as asset sale, change-of-control, fixed charge, and negative pledge covenants. Our point estimates in Panel B and C of Table II suggest the change-of-control covenant is the most common covenant to be adopted as a result of the modernization event. We find WKSIeligible issuers, on average, increased change-of-control covenant use by 29% to 42% as a result of the reform. The 29% point estimate is based on a four-year window around the reform whereas the 42% estimate is based on the two-year window around the reform. Both point estimates are significantly different from 0 at a 1% level. Such an increase in covenant usage is very economically meaningful. In fact, prior to the reform, less than 10% of new issuances included the restrictive change-of-control covenant but after the reform around 65% of new issuances included the covenant. 21 While the reform cannot explain all of the increase in restrictive covenant usage, it does explain a meaningful portion of it. Figure 4 illustrates visually the evidence supporting the point estimates reported in Table II related to risk-sharing for the WKSI-eligible issuers after the SEC regulatory reform. Plot (1), the upper left plot, illustrates an increase in total number of covenants included in a bond indenture for the treated issuers. Plot (2) illustrates the percentage point increase in use of asset sale clauses. Plot (3) illustrates the percentage point increase in change-of-control covenants. Plot (4) illustrates the percentage point increase in fixed charge covenants. In each plot, the navy side represents the 8 quarters before the reform, the reform is demarcated by a black vertical line, the maroon side represents the 8 quarters after the reform, and ninety-percent confidence intervals are shaded. What the plots reveal is that the number of covenants increased by 2 covenants, an additional 25% of bonds had asset sale covenants, an additional 30% had change-of-control covenants, and an addition 12% had fixed charge covenants. Overall, the plots in Figure 4 provide suggestive evidence of the mechanism driving the effect of the SEC reform on covenants. Because bonds are issued quickly under the reform, issuers and their investment bank advisors may want to offset the effect of the shorter schedule on the difficulty of selling the bonds by adding contractual terms that make the bond’s future payoffs simpler. Arguably, the change-of-control covenant makes the future payoffs simpler because a bond that pays 101 in specific future states is simpler than a bond with unspecified value in those states. Similarly, asset sale covenants protect bondholders from potential sharp changes in price attributable to major asset sales. As a final check of the difference-in-differences results, we examine the identifying assumption that the treatment and control group would have evolved along parallel paths had it not been for the SEC reform. One way to assess the validity of such an assumption is to examine the data to determine if the issuers with varying status post reform displayed similar trends prior to the reform. Figure 5 illustrates that the issuers did indeed display parallel trends prior to the reform, but post reform the trends diverged. Because there does not appear to be a violation of the parallel trends assumption and our results are robust to the inclusion of a flexible polynomial that 22 enables comparison of the most similar issuers, it is plausible the identifying assumptions for our difference-in-differences research design are satisfied. B. Within-Issuer Results Covenant inclusion should be priced by the market. Prior research suggests that covenants that restrict managements’ actions by protecting bondholders’ interests should benefit management in terms of lowering borrowing costs. For this reason, we study a set of issuers that floated bonds both shortly after and before the reform. Doing so provides us with a set of bonds from the same issuer, with similar maturity, with and without the contractual change. Because we want to benchmark any price changes to prior pricing studies, we focus on the change-of-control covenant, which first became popular in the 1980s and consequently has been studied. Table III summarizes the characteristics of our bond issuers and their issuances that had similar maturities but one bond had the contractual change and one did not. We observe that bonds with the restrictive covenant have similar offering amounts and yields, ratings at issuance, and gross spread. As expected, the time to evaluate the contract is significantly shorter for the issuances with the restrictive covenants at only 1.4 hours on average or 0.6 hours at the median. The average issuance with a change of control covenant has 3.3 of the 5 triggers, but 48% of issuances include the holding company exception that can prohibit the effective operation of the triggers. The majority of issuances require at least two agencies to publicly verify the cause of the downgrade is attributable to the change-of-control event. Our text-based analysis of the bond contracts show that the bonds with the covenants have slightly longer contracts and unsurprisingly, the word covenant occurs more frequently. Table IV shows the results from examining the initial pricing for the issuer-specific bond pairs, in which issuers floated bonds both before and after the change, and thus had concurrently-outstanding bonds both with and without the covenant. Column (1) of Panel A reveals that on average, all else equal, including the covenant reduces the issuers’ yield by 23 basis points. This finding is statistically significant and robust to the inclusion of issuance controls, issuer fixed effects, and year fixed effects. While this suggests issuers are being compensated from the new contractual 23 arrangement, the constraints on investors time to evaluate the offering terms at issuance suggest this average may belie substantial heterogeneity. To explore the heterogeneity in bond pricing, we explore price-heterogeneity that stems from context-dependent decision-making (McFadden (2001)). We examine three measures that capture different features of context-dependent decision-making: (1) boilerplates (i.e., the information-based case), (2) saliency (i.e., the behavioral-based case), and (3) dissimilarity (i.e., time-based case). We want to account for the potential costs borne by issuers and investors when an issuance breaks the boilerplate contract to adopt the change-of-control covenant, its’ use of a change-of-control covenant is particularly salient relative to recent issuances, or the contractual details of its issuance differ substantially from the base prospectus provided to investors in the initial S-3 filing. The logic for the boilerplate test of context-dependent decision-making is as follows. Because any one investor gains little from evaluating the precise terms of an offering, the disincentive for investor due diligence promotes free-riding and the reuse of previous deals’ terms. Underwriters, therefore, are unlikely to benefit either in terms of profit or market-share from customizing bond contracts for the exact risks of an issuer. This practice of boilerplate contracting or sticky covenants (Kahan and Klausner (1997), De Franco et al. (2014)) is largely borne out in the summary statistics, where we find 80% of the content from the most recent bond issuance is retained in the next bond issuance. This is even more remarkable when one considers the fact that issuers often change underwriters from one issuance to the next. We specifically examine the within-issuer pairs and see if when an issuers’ issuance first includes the change-of-control covenant, if the pricing is correct. Further, if the pricing seems out-of-line with the risk-return profile it generates, we examine whether issuers or investors are amassing the benefits of the mispricing. The logic for the saliency test of context-dependent decision-making is as follows. A buyer exhibits a context effect if his choice between two alternatives systematically depends on the presence of other options. In a recent study, Hastings and Shapiro (2013) provide large-scale evidence of context-dependent decision-making among retail consumers in gasoline markets while Barber and Odean (2008) find evidence of context-dependent decision-making among retail traders in equity markets. In contrast to the boilerplate example, context-dependent choice arises in this case when 24 a buyer’s attention is drawn to salient attributes of goods, such as quality or price (Bordalo, Gennaioli, Shleifer (2012); Bordalo, Gennaioli, Shleifer (2013)). An attribute is defined as salient for a good when it stands out among the good’s attributes relative to that attribute’s average level in the choice context. The main prediction is that buyers attach disproportionately high weight to salient attributes, and their choices are tilted toward goods with higher quality/price ratios; they are bargain-hunting based on the most salient attribute. We specifically examine the within-issuer pairs and see if when an issuers’ issuance includes a covenant that is salient relative to offering yield and quantity, if the initial secondary market pricing is correct. Further, if the pricing seems out-ofline with the risk-return profile it generates, we examine whether issuers or investors are amassing the benefits of the mispricing. The bargaining-hunting motive supported by theory suggests the primary alternative hypothesis is that investors benefit. Columns (2) – (4) of Table IV present tests for price heterogeneity in the initial pricing for the issuer-specific bond pairs. The specification is the same as in Eq.(3) and includes indicator variables for if the issuance is the first by that issuer with the covenant or if the covenant is the salient attribute when the covenant is included. We find that significant heterogeneity underlies the initial pricing of the covenant. Our evidence suggests initial investors benefit from the modernization in terms of a free or bargain covenant and issuers suffer because they are not fully compensated in terms of yield reduction. In particular, the observed heterogeneity suggests even sophisticated institutional bond investors do not take into account fully all the information available to them in the bond contract, but overemphasize the information their minds focus on. Columns (2) – (4) provide statistically significant evidence to suggest when the covenant is the most salient attribute relevant to offering amount and pricing, issuers receive less of a reduction in yield. Similarly, when an issuer first includes such a covenant and breaks the boilerplate, the issuer receives less of a reduction in yield. Finally, when the final contract terms are dissimilar to the base contract terms the covenants are priced at bargain levels. How long does it take for bond traders to arbitrage away the price inconsistency? Figure 6 examines the persistence of the pricing heterogeneity over time. The y-axis plots the reduction in yield accrued to the issuer and the x-axis plots the quarters since issuance. The left-hand side 25 plot illustrates the pricing differential when covenants are the salient attribute; it reveals that those issuances trade with a sizeable 20 basis point yield differential for at least a year following the offering slowly mitigating three years later. The right-hand side plot illustrates the pricing differential when an issuer first includes such a covenant; it reveals that those issuances do not trade with a sizeable differential, which indicates they more quickly arbitrage back to a yield indistinguishable from other issuances. This suggests that while the modernization reform initially brought benefits to investors, those benefits quickly dissipated. C. Bondholder and Underwriter Results Who were the investors that initially benefited from the bond market modernization? In par- ticular, was there one group of bond investors performing their due diligence while others free-ride? Were underwriters forewarning their favorite institutional clients in hopes of gaining future business or market share? Or were the benefits to investors spread evenly across different groups of investors? We explore the answers to these questions both graphically and statistically. Table V provides descriptive statistics of the bondholding data for our study. The data comes from Thomson Reuters’ eMAXX database and provides comprehensive coverage of quarterly fixed income holdings by individual insurance companies, mutual funds, pension funds, annuity funds, hedge funds, and other institution-like investors (e.g., governments and hospitals). This allows us to construct a panel dataset with the total par value held by these sophisticated investors; we also know the number of holding portfolios, buying portfolios, and selling portfolios in any time period. With details on the other holdings by these investors, we know their experience holding covenantlight vs. covenant-heavy bonds, holding bonds when a firm becomes the target of a leveraged buyout (LBO), etc . . . . Using the bondholder data, Figure 7 examines which investors initially invested in the covenant-heavy bond contracts with the favorable covenant pricing. The figure suggests institutional investors, and mutual funds in particular, buy the bonds that are priced as though they have a free covenant. Table VI provides statistical evidence about the bondholders and bond trades that eventually lead to the covenant pricing. Turnover in ownership shows the initial mutual fund investors realize 26 gains from trade by selling these bonds. Overall, this evolution increases the number of bondholders relative to the covenant-light bonds. Volatility analyses suggest the covenant usage and dispersion in ownership are associated with less volatile pricing once learning occurs and this price stability benefits the bond issuers. Panel B, C, and D of Table VI focus specifically on the issuances with “bargain” covenants. There do appear to be some differences across these attributes. What we consistently see is that mutual funds are the ones who initial bought the bargain covenants and sold the bonds as the covenant became priced in the market. Table VII delves into why a difference exists in trading and bondholding behavior between the bargain and priced covenants. Specifically, we examine the role of bondholder characteristics in terms of ability to perform due diligence and prior issuer-specific and LBO experience as potential explanations. Tests of differences across the two types of pricing reveals that despite the shorter time for diligence, many of the mutual fund investors had prior issuer experience which helped facilitate evaluation of the contractual terms. Surprisingly, prior LBO experience does not seem to affect subsequent bondholding suggesting that the specific form of the covenant is not what mattered but rather that the covenant serves to simplify due diligence by protecting downside risk in highly idiosyncratic events. Were underwriters faced with increasing pressure to deliver bonds at fast speeds reducing the quality of their underwriter? We explore this question both visually and statistically. Figure 8 examines which underwriters use covenant-heavy bond contracts after the modernization reform. The graph shows that all underwriters quickly adopted the new covenant-heavy contracts. Additional statistical analyses of the underwriters’ market share pre and post the reform show suggest the underwriting market for corporate bonds is quite competitive as no firm was able to achieve a statistically significant gain in market share by three quarters after the reform. Table VIII explores the extent to which underwriters benefited from the SEC reforms that modernized the bond issuance process. The specification is as in Eq.(4). The dependent variable looks at various dimensions on which underwriters could profit, including new issuance count and dollar volume, as well as market share and fees. We find no evidence that underwriters benefit from the modernization. The underwriters that protect themselves from legal liability by writing 27 stronger contracts with more restrictive covenants appear to lose a small amount of business and see no changes in their fees. When focuses on the bond issuances with restrictive covenant packages, underwriters that provide investors with greater time for scrutiny appear to receive smaller fees and less market share. While strong underwriting in terms of legal language leads to some additional business, it does not appear to be enough to offset the reduction in business from simply including the restrictive covenant. Overall, these results suggest that underwriters do not benefit from bond market modernization. VI. Discussion Our results converge to support the traditional economic efficiency hypothesis that financial innovation generates gains through transaction costs savings (e.g., improved market-timing for firms issuing public debt) and risk-reducing properties (e.g., improved underwriting of bond contracts). Because the U.S. corporate bond market operates within a structure” of rules, technology, market practices, and other constraints, it is important to recognize that any incremental innovation produces a complex interaction among regulation and other factors like competition. And that these incremental changes can produce significant, sometimes unintended economic consequences that may not become evident for a period of years or even decades. The complex interactions resulting from the U.S. corporate bond market structure create the unique and surprising findings from our analyses. First, we find widespread adoption of incurrence covenants such as change-of-control covenants. While at first glance, this could appear to be the traditional risk-reduction property, we show these covenants serve a new purpose of simplifying due diligence in addition to the traditional shifting of risk purpose. Second, we delve into the theories that distinguish the rent-seeking components of financial innovation from those that benefit society. We find the costs and benefits of corporate bond market modernization are not evenly distributed across market participants. Learning externalities from transitioning to covenant-heavy bonds coincide with a contract uncertainty premium, which benefits sophisticated investors at the expense of subsequent investors. Issuers bear some costs, because they are not fully compensated for the managerial control relinquished to bondholders through the covenants. Issuers, however, benefit 28 from an expanded set of bondholders and lower bond return volatility from the more standardized contract. We find no evidence to support rent-seeking activities by financial intermediaries. One interpretation of this finding is competition prevents underwriters from profiting; a second interpretation is reputational concerns prohibit rent-seeking by underwriters. As with any natural empirical experiment, there could be concerns that the results may not extrapolate to other contexts. Accelerating the speed of bond issuances is a very specific type of financial innovation. It is plausible that other types of financial innovation proposed by the SEC that focus on transparency, trading speed, and changes in the number and nature of trading venues would impact market participants differently. What does extrapolate across all types of financial innovation is the finding that modernization, security design, the standardization of contract terms, and pricing are intertwined. This dynamic reality means that a one-size fits all approach to market modernization without consideration of the externalities and what should be standardized may not be appropriate. To understand the economics consequences of financial innovation for issuers and bondholders, we examine a sample of firms that exhibit variation in issuance practices by undergoing a transition from issuing covenant-light bonds to covenant-heavy bonds. While this approach has the benefit of removing confounding factors idiosyncratic to an individual issuer, one could be concerns that the results do not generalize because this is selected sample of issuers. To test the veracity of this generalizability claim, we investigate a second mutually exclusive sample from the first. We construct a matched sample based on a propensity score estimator. While this sample cannot be considered as randomly assigning contract design to issuers, because it takes a significantly different approach to testing the underlying hypotheses, when the results from the two samples coincide that suggests the original results do generalize. Specifically, this second propensity-score matched approach enhances the previous results for several reasons. Unlike the previous sample, where we limited our sample size by requiring the match to be homogenous by issuer, maturity, liquidity, and covenant transition status, the propensity score sample is drawn from the universe of all investment grade bond issuers. Thus, this constructed sample allows us to generalize our results and also because it’s a mutually exclusive 29 sample it provides a robustness check for the previous method. Further, previous studies have confirmed that propensity score matching methods allow for more accurate inferences in an observational study. Finally, since the pool of potential matches is large, the data is well suited for using this method. Appendix C shows that the fundamental results from the within-issuer sample do not change when using the larger more representative sample of issuers. Table CI shows the characteristics of the issuers and issuances for the matched sample. Table CII shows the results from examining the initial pricing for the propensity-score matched bond pairs. Column (1) of Panel A reveals that on average, all else equal, including the covenant reduces the issuers’ yield by 27 basis points. This finding is statistically significant and robust to the inclusion of issuance controls, issuer fixed effects, and year fixed effects. It is also qualitatively similar to the 23 basis points found using the issuer-specific sample. Column (1) of Panel B provides suggestive evidence that covenant inclusion is associated with greater underpricing, which is again similar to the findings in the issuer-specific sample. Table CIII shows that the subsequent trading behavior also coincides fairly closely with the previous findings. Comparing the inferences from the two samples suggests that the results from the smaller transition sample generalize to the universe of investment-grade bonds. Further, because the two approaches had different identifying assumptions, this suggests our inferences are not fragile to a single identifying assumption. VII. Conclusion In this paper, we study the role modernization plays in shaping U.S. corporate bond market transactions. In 2005, the SEC adopted a series of rules that allowed large issuers to significantly accelerate issuance speeds. Under the new rules, potential investors have 36 minutes, at the median, to evaluate Prospectus terms, the issuers credit story, and pricing expectations. For the large majority of new issue transactions, there is no conference call with the management of the issuer. At the same time, the new issue market has grown substantially and multiple issuers often come to market at the same time, which exacerbates the constraints on investors time to review each transaction. To identify the effects of this modernization event, we exploit eligibility cut-off thresholds 30 that are part of the SEC rules. We find modernization meaningfully affects risk-sharing with widespread adoption of covenants, which we argue simplifies the due diligence required to value the bond. We find a set of incurrencebased covenants gained popularity after the regulatory change. Because incurrence-based covenants provide value to bondholders in idiosyncratic, highly speculative situations such as future business combinations, spin-offs, or asset sales, we contend the inclusion of such covenants serves as a laborreducing device when time for contract scrutiny is compressed. Put another way, the additional covenants serve the significant economic purpose of substituting for investor diligence. In contrast to the critics that suggest financial innovation largely benefits the financial intermediaries who capture rents from exploiting new rules to their advantage, our evidence from bond placement and secondary market trades suggests the modernization of the bond issuance process mostly benefits those intended issuers and investors. We find underwriters operate in a competitive landscape and no underwriter captured market share or additional fees as a result of the modernization. Learning externalities from transitioning to covenant-heavy bonds coincide with a contract uncertainty premium, which benefits sophisticated investors. In particular, mutual funds are rewarded for the superior information they gather in their due diligence process. We find issuers bear some costs in terms of initial underpricing but benefit from an expanded set of bondholders and reduced volatility once the new contract terms are learned. Overall, our evidence highlights the importance of standardization in conjunction with modernization as regulators assess ways to improve current bond market practices. Our evidence is consistent with the notion that repetition reduces the cost that investors must expend in learning the meaning of contract terms. Hence, standardization of corporate bond issuances provides issuers and investors a channel for improvement. Primary among these improvements is the prospect of a more stable, less volatile issuance environment with improved transparency and lower new issue concessions. Of course, in any setting, the features included in the standardized contract need to be carefully assessed. In particular, our findings that change-of-control covenants are included in over 60% of new issuances and the potential externality that places on the market for corporate control should be carefully considered. 31 REFERENCES Allen, F. and D. Gale, 1994, Financial Innovation and Risk Sharing, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Asquith, P. and T. Wizman, 1990, Event Risk, Covenants and Bondholder Risk in Leveraged Buyouts, Journal of Financial Economics 27, 195–214. Barber, B. and T. Odean, 2008, All That Glitters: The Effect of Attention and News on the Buying Behavior of Individual and Institutional Investors, Review of Financial Studies 21, 785–817. Bebchuk, L., A. Cohen, and A. Ferrell, 2009, What Matters in Corporate Governance?, The Review of Financial Studies 22, 783–827. Becker, B., and V. Ivashina, 2014, Reaching for Yield in the Bond Market, The Journal of Finance forthcoming. Benveniste, L.M., A. Ljungqvist, W.J. Wilhelm, and X. Yu, 2003, Evidence of Information Spillovers in the Production of Investment Banking Services, Journal of Finance 58, 577–608. Billet, M., T. King, and D. Mauer, 2007, Growth Opportunities and the Choice of Leverage, Debt Maturity, and Covenants, The Journal of Finance LXII, 697–730. Bolton, P., and A. Faure-Grimaud, 2010, Satisficing Contracts, The Review of Economic Studies 77, 937–971. Bordalo, P., N. Gennaioli, and A. Shleifer, 2012, Salience Theory of Choice Under Risk, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1243–1285. Bordalo, P., N. Gennaioli, and A. Shleifer, 2013, Salience and Consumer Choice, Journal of Political Economy 121, 803–843. Bradley, M., and M. R. Roberts, 2004, The Structure and Pricing of Bond Covenants, Working Paper. Bratton, W., 2006, Bond Covenants and Creditor Protection: Economics and Law, Theory and Practice, Substance and Process, European Business Organization Law Review 39. Cheng, A. and King, T., 2009, Corporate Governance and Financial Contracting: Bondholder Takeover Defenses in Poison Puts, Corporate Ownership and Control, 7, 9–20. Cook, D. and Easterwood, J., 1994, Poison Put Bonds: An Analysis of their Economic Role, The Journal of Finance XLIX, 1905–1920. Crabbe, L., 1991, Event Risk: An Analysis of Losses to Bondholders and “Super Poison Put” Bond Covenants, The Journal of Finance XLVI, 689–706 The Credit Roundtable, 2008, Improving Covenant Protections in the Investment Grade Bond Market, available at http://www.iimemberships.com/dl/creditroundtable/. Dang, T., G. Gorton, B. Holmstrom, and G. Ordonez, 2014, Banks as Secret Keepers, NBER Working Paper No. 20255. 32 De Franco, G., F. Vasvari, D. Vyas, and R. Wittenberg-Moerman, 2014, Sticky Covenants, Working Paper. Dichev, I. and D. Skinner, 2002, Large-Sample Evidence on the Debt Covenant Hypothesis, Journal of Accounting Research 40, 1091–1123. Eckbo, E., R. Masulis, and O. Norli, 2007, Security Offerings, Handbook of Corporate Finance: Empirical Corporate Finance, E. Eckbo, editor, North-Holland/Elsevier, Chapter 13. Fenn, G., Speed of Issuance and the Adequacy of Disclosure inthe 144A High-yield Debt Market, Journal of Financial Economics 56, 383–405. Fields, J., D. Kidwell, and L. Klein, RJR/Nabisco and Event Risk Protection, Financial Services Review, 143–156. French, 2008, The Cost of Active Investing, AFA Presidential Address. Gao, X., and J. Ritter, The Marketing of Seasoned Equity Offerings, Journal of Financial Economics 97, 33–52. Gennaioli, N., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, 2015, Neglected Risks: The Psychology of Financial Crises, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, forthcoming. Graham, J., and C. Harvey, 2001, The Theory and Practice of Corporate Finance: Evidence from the Field, Journal of FInancial Economics 60, 187–243. Gulati, M., and R. Scott, 2013, The 3 1/2 Minute Transaction: Boilerplate and the Limits of Contract Design, University of Chicago Press. Hanley, K. and G. Hoberg, 2012, Litigation Risk, Strategic Disclosure and the Underpricing of the Initial Public Offering, Journal of Financial Economics 103, 235–254. Hastings, J. and J. Shapiro, 2013, Fungibility and Consumer Choice- Evidence from Commodity Price Shocks, Quarterly Journal of Economics 128, 1449–1498. Kahan, M., and M. Klausner, 1993, Anti-Takeover Provisions in Bonds: Bondholder Protection or Management Entrenchment, UCLA Law Review 40, 931–954. Kahan, M., and M. Klausner, 1997, Standardization and Innovation in Corporate Contracting, Virginia Law Review 83, 713–771. Kahan, M., and D. Yermack, 1998, Investment Opportunities and the Design of Debt Securities, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 14, 136–151. Kamenica, E., 2008, Contextual Inference in Markets: On the Informational Content of Product Lines, American Economic Review 98, 2127–49. Lerner, J., and P. Tufano, 2011, The Consequences of Financial Innovation: A Counterfactual Research Agenda, NBER Working Paper No. 16780. McFadden, D., 2001, Economic Choices, American Economic Review 91, 351–378. 33 Murfin, J., 2012, The Supply-side Determinants of Loan Contract Strictness, The Journal of Finance LXVII, 1565–1601. Myers, S., 1977, Determinants of Corporate Borrowing, Journal of Financial Economics 5, 147–145. Noe, T., M. Rebello, and J. Wang, The Evolution of Security Design, Journal of Finance 61, 2103–2135. Simsek, A., 2013, Speculation and Risk Sharing with New Financial Assets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 128, 1365–1396. Simsek, A., 2013, Financial Innovation and Portfolio Risks, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 103, 398–401. Smith, C., Warner, J., 1979, On Financial Contracting: an Analysis of Bond Covenants, Journal of Financial Economics 7, 117–161. Tufano, P., 2003, Financial Innovation. In Handbook of the Economics of Finance (Volume 1a: Corporate Finance), eds. Constantinides G, Harris M, and Stulz R. New York: Elsevier, 307–36 White, M., 2014, Intermediation in the Modern Securities Markets: Putting Technology and Competition to Work for Investors, Speech before Economic Club of New York, June 20, 2014. Zingales, L., 2015, Does Finance Benefit Society? AFA Presidential Address. 34 Figures and Tables Time 9:00 AM Step Underwriters announce a new issue and alert investors via Bloomberg and phone. Sales force begins discussions regarding investors’ interest and pricing expectations. Investors attempt to evaluate the issuer’s credit quality and potential terms. Investors submit an order without finalized pricing or terms. 9:15 AM Preliminary prospectus is provided to investors. Offering goes subject and books are closed (i.e. orders of interest stop being accepted). 10:00 AM Price guidance is announced. 11:00 AM Deal is launched with final pricing terms which can differ meaningfully from guidance. 3:00 PM Underwriters set and release allocations to investors. 3:30 PM Deal is priced near market close. Figure 1. Example bond offering timeline post reform. 35 Pre-SEC Reform, WKSI-eligible Issuer (General Mills) 2.625% Notes due October 24, 2006, CUSIP 370334AX2 Date December 21, 2001 February 8, 2002 Time Similarity Page Covenant Info in File Count Word Count Measure Company information (financials), intended use of proceeds, description of debt The issuer registers $8 billion of securities the company may offer Shelf Registration debt securities that are to be including restrictive covenants 25 22 NA and Prospectus offered on a delayed or continuous (e.g., asset sale), plan of basis. distribution, and information about what terms of the indenture can be changed. SEC Filing File Description Description S-3 S-3/A 36 September 17, 2003 (Offering Date) September 19, 2003 12:09 PM 424B5 September 24, 2003 9:44 AM 8-K The issuer amends the registration statement, which will become effective when the SEC, acting pursuant to Section 8(a), Amendment No. 1 determines. The information in the to S-3 Shelf Preliminary Prospectus Registration and Supplement and the accompanying Preliminary Preliminary Prospectus is not Prospectus complete and may be changed. The issuer cannot sell securities until the registration statement has been declared effective by the SEC. Prospectus Supplement dated September 17, 2003, but filed September 19, 2003. This document is a Prospectus Supplement and supplements the Prospectus attached Prospectus, which is part Supplement (Final of a registration statement that the Prospectus) issuer filed with the SEC. This Prospectus Supplement contains the terms of this offering of notes. Current report Agreements related to issuance Company information (risk factors, recent developments, financials), description of the notes including restrictive 65 covenants (e.g., asset sale), underwriters, use of proceeds, and firm capitalization. 25 NA Description of the notes including pricing information, restrictive 36 covenants, underwriters, use of proceeds, and firm capitalization. 25 0.906 Underwriting agreement dated September 17, 2003. NA NA 3 Figure 2. Example of bond issuance filings before the SEC reform: This figure describes the SEC filings and information contained in the filings for a WKSI-eligible issuer prior to the reform. To quantify the due diligence required to understand the terms of the contract, a page count, covenant word count, and a text-based similarity measure are included. A similarity measure of 1 indicates the Final Prospectus is identical to the terms available at the time of issuance, whereas a similarity measure of 0 indicates no overlap in content. Post-SEC Reform, WKSI-eligible Issuer (General Mills) 1.500% Bond due April 27, 2027, CUSIP 370334BX1 Date Time SEC Filing File Description February 20, 2015 4:48 PM S-3ASR Page Count Covenant Similarity Word Count Measure Description Info in File Automatic Shelf Registration General registration of unidentified amount of debt securities. Statement becomes effective automatically without SEC review. Each time the issuer sells debt securities, the issuer will provide a Prospectus Supplement that will contain specific information about the terms of that offering, and the issuer may add, update or change information from what is contained in this Prospectus. Company information, risk factors, use of proceeds, plan of distribution, information about what terms of the indenture can be changed, and a notice that the Prospectus Supplement relating to any debt securities 37 that the issuer offers using this Prospectus will describe the amount, price, and other specific terms including any restrictive covenants, if applicable. 18 NA Description of bond terms, including restrictive covenants (e.g., change-of-control 87 covenant), underwriters, use of proceeds, and firm capitalization. 22 NA Bond terms NA NA 22 0.737 NA NA 6:12 AM 424B5 Preliminary Prospectus Supplement April 20, 2015 4:57 PM FWP Free-writing Prospectus Distributed for marketing on offering date April 22, 2015 3:48 PM 424B5 Final Prospectus Supplement Substantively identical to preliminary prospectus April 24, 2015 4:57 PM 8-K Current report 37 April 20, 2015 (Offering Date) The information in this Preliminary Prospectus Supplement is not complete and may be changed. 6 Finalized bond terms including pricing and any negotiated 89 changes such as covenants. Underwriting agreement dated Agreements related to offering 4 April 20, 2015 Figure 3. Example of bond issuance filings after the SEC reform: This figure describes the SEC filings and information contained in the filings for a WKSI-eligible issuer after the reform. To quantify the due diligence required to understand the terms of the contract, a page count, covenant word count, and a text-based similarity measure are included. A similarity measure of 1 indicates the Final Prospectus is identical to the terms available at the time of issuance, whereas a similarity measure of 0 indicates no overlap in content. (2) Asset Sale Covenant -20 0 0 % with Covenant 20 40 # of Covenants Added 1 2 3 4 60 5 6 80 (1) Total Covenants -8 -4 0 4 Quarters Relative to SEC Reform -8 8 -4 0 4 Quarters Relative to SEC Reform 8 (3) Change-of-control Covenant 15 % with Covenant 5 10 % with Covenant 25 50 0 0 -5 -25 38 75 20 100 (4) Fixed Charge Covenant -8 -4 0 4 Quarters Relative to SEC Reform 8 -8 -4 0 4 Quarters Relative to SEC Reform 8 Figure 4. The effect of SEC modernization reform: The four plots illustrate the change in risk-sharing associated with the SECmodernization reform for treated issuers (i.e., WKSI-eligible issuers). Plot (1), the upper left plot, illustrates an increase in total number of covenants included in a bond indenture for the treated issuers. Plot (2) illustrates the percentage point increase in use of asset sale clauses. Plot (3) illustrates the percentage point increase in change-of-control covenants. Plot (4) illustrates the percentage point increase in fixed charge covenants. In each plot, the navy side represents the 8 quarters before the reform, the reform is demarcated by a black vertical line, the maroon side represents the 8 quarters after the reform, and ninety-percent confidence intervals are shaded. (2) Offering Amount 2 0 100 4 Offering Yield 6 8 Offering Amount 200 300 400 10 500 12 600 (1) Offering Yield -20 -16 -12 -8 -4 0 4 Quarters Relative to SEC Reform Eligible for WKSI 8 12 -20 16 -16 -12 -8 -4 0 4 Quarters Relative to SEC Reform Eligible for WKSI Ineligible for WKSI 8 12 16 Ineligible for WKSI (4) Change-of-control Covenant % with Covenant 40 60 20 Total Covenants 7 8 0 6 5 39 9 80 10 100 (3) Total Covenants -20 -16 -12 -8 -4 0 4 Quarters Relative to SEC Reform Eligible for WKSI 8 12 -20 16 -16 -12 -8 -4 0 4 Quarters Relative to SEC Reform Eligible for WKSI Ineligible for WKSI 8 12 16 Ineligible for WKSI Figure 5. Parallel paths prior to the SEC modernization reform: In each plot, the treated issuers (i.e., the WKSI-eligible issuers) are depicted with a maroon line and control issuers (i.e., the WKSI-ineligible issuers) with a navy, dashed line. Plot (1), the upper left plot, depicts offering yield. Plot (2) depicts offering amount. Plot (3) depicts total covenants. Plot (4) depicts change-of-control covenants. The plots show the issuers follow parallel paths pre-reform but sharply diverge post-reform in the two plots related to risk-sharing. The observed “parallel trends” pre-reform suggest difference-in-differences estimates are unbiased estimates of the effect of the SEC reform, because absent the reform the paths are likely to have been the same for the treatment and control issuers. -20 Yield Reduction from Covenant -10 10 0 20 (1) Boilerplate Test of Pricing 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Quarter Post Issuance First Issuance with Covenant 8 9 10 11 Other Issuance with Covenant -20 Yield Reduction from Covenant -10 0 10 20 (2) Saliency Test of Pricing 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Quarter Post Issuance Covenant is Salient 8 9 10 11 Covenant is not Salient Figure 6. Heterogeneity in covenant pricing: The plot examines the initial pricing heterogeneity and its persistence over time in two settings. Plot (1) illustrates the pricing differential when an issuer first includes such a covenant whereas Plot (2) illustrates the pricing differential when covenants are the salient attribute. The two plots differentiate between behavioral and learning explanations for the covenant pricing. In each plot, the y-axis represents the reduction in yield accrued to the issuer and the x-axis represents the quarters since issuance. The observations are drawn from the within-issuer sample. 40 0 20 % New Issuances with Covenant 40 60 80 100 Underwriter Effects -4 -2 0 2 4 6 Quarters Relative to SEC Reform Bank of America J.P. Morgan 8 10 Morgan Stanley Wells Fargo Figure 7. Underwriter effects: This graph shows the difference in new issuances with covenants among four major investment banks. After the SEC reform, J.P. Morgan and Bank of America were the fastest adopters of the covenant with inclusion of the covenant in a large percentage of new issuances starting in the first quarter. Morgan Stanley and Wells Fargo soon followed, with each of the four banks exhibiting an initial spike in usage within a year after the reform took effect. 41 0 % New Holdings with Covenant 40 60 80 20 100 Bondholder Effects -4 -2 0 2 4 6 Quarters Relative to SEC Reform Insurance Pension Funds 8 10 Mutual Funds Figure 8. Bondholder effects: This graph shows the difference in new holdings with covenants among three types of bond holders. After the SEC reform, a greater percentage of new holdings of insurance funds and mutual funds contained the change of control covenant, compared to pension funds. However, 10 quarters after the reform, pension funds’ new holdings are converging to similar levels as those of mutual funds. 42 Table I Ex Ante Bond Issuer Characteristics This table reports summary statistics for bond issuers in the five years before the enactment of the SEC reform that modernized the bond issuance process. The sample is limited to the bond issuers within $700 million of common equity eligibility cut-off threshold. The mean and standard deviation (in parentheses) for each variable are reported separately for two samples of issuers. Column (1) reports estimates for modernization ineligible issuers and Column (2) reports estimates for modernization-eligible issuers. Column (3) reports the p-value from a t-test for the difference between the ineligible and eligible issuers. Appendix A provides the definition of each of the covariates. Ex ante Issuer Characteristics Market-to-book Profitability ROE Investment / Assets Cash Growth Asset Growth Sales Growth Leverage Firm Size Observations Ineligible (1) 1.229 (0.583) 0.135 (0.058) 0.438 (0.303) 0.221 (0.231) 1.211 (3.534) 0.219 (0.344) 0.213 (0.677) 0.375 (0.112) 7.993 (0.485) 366 43 Eligible (2) 1.214 (0.586) 0.136 (0.072) 0.445 (1.642) 0.205 (0.220) 1.585 (4.465) 0.198 (0.373) 0.308 (3.253) 0.455 (0.137) 7.216 (0.863) 203 p -value of difference (3) (0.774) (0.758) (0.955) (0.397) (0.305) (0.499) (0.680) (0.000) (0.000) Table II Effect of Modernization on Bond Issuance This table shows difference-in-differences estimates of the average change in bond issuance practices attributable to the SEC reform that modernized the bond issuance process. The sample is limited to the bond issuers within $700 million of common equity eligibility cut-off threshold. Test-statistics calculated using robust standard errors, clustered at the issuer level, are in parentheses. The exact specification is as in Eq.(1): Yjit = α + βEligiblei + δ (Eligible × P ost)it + γXjit + g (CEjit , T otjit ) + ft + εjit , where Yjit is an outcome variable representing price, quantity, or the inclusion of the listed covenant for issuance j by issuer i in quarter t, Eligible is an indicator for issuers that are eligible for WKSI status, P ost is an indicator for the post-reform period, and Xjit is a vector of issuer and issuance controls including issuance amount, offering yield, and maturity as well as issuer market-to-book, profitability, ROE, investment, cash growth, asset growth, sales growth, leverage, and firm size, ft are year fixed effects and g (CEjit , T otjit ) is a flexible polynomial that controls for how far the treated and control issuers are from eligibility based on the conditions of common equity market capitalization (CEjit ) and total offerings in the past three years (T otjit ). ***, ** and * indicate p-values of 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Panel A. The Effect of Modernization on Price and Quantity 2-year Window Around Event Offering Offering Dependent Variable = Yield Amount Difference-in-Differences 2.37 5.96 (1.94) (41.21) Yes Yes Flexible Polynomial for Cut-offs Yes Yes Issuer & Issuance Controls Yes Yes Year Fixed Effects Adjusted R2 Observations 4% 306 4-year Window Around Event Offering Offering Yield Amount 0.74 -22.82 (0.78) (22.78) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 39% 306 19% 697 37% 697 Panel B. The Effect of Modernization on Risk-sharing (2-year Window Around Event) Dependent Variable = Covenant Difference-in-Differences Flexible Polynomial for Cut-offs Issuer & Issuance Controls Year Fixed Effects Adjusted R2 Observations Total Covenants Asset Sale Clause Change of Control 2.80*** (1.04) Yes Yes Yes 8% 306 0.20** (0.08) Yes Yes Yes 4% 306 0.42*** (0.10) Yes Yes Yes 23% 306 Fixed Charge Negative Pledge 0.07** (0.03) Yes Yes Yes 11% 306 0.19* (0.11) Yes Yes Yes 16% 306 Panel C. The Effect of Modernization on Risk-sharing (4-year Window Around Event) Total Asset Sale Change of Fixed Charge Negative Pledge Dependent Variable = Covenant Covenants Clause Control Difference-in-Differences 1.63** 0.04 0.29*** 0.09*** 0.18** (0.68) (0.05) (0.07) (0.03) (0.07) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Flexible Polynomial for Cut-offs Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Issuer & Issuance Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fixed Effects 2 9% 1% 25% 8% 20% Adjusted R Observations 697 697 697 697 697 44 Table III Descriptive Statistics for Within-Issuer Sample This table provides descriptive statistics for a sample of bond issuers eligible for the SEC modernization reform that issued similar maturity bonds both before and after the reform. The mean and standard deviation (in parentheses) are reported separately for eligible issuers in Column (1) and (2) and issuances in Column (3) and (4). Column (1) and (3) report estimates for bonds that include the restrictive covenant (i.e., after the reform) and Column (2) and (4) report estimates for bonds that exclude the restrictive covenant (i.e., before the reform). Appendix A provides the definition of each of the covariates. 45 Descriptive Statistics for Within-Issuer Sample Including Excluding Covenant Covenant Issuer Characteristics (1) (2) Market-to-book 1.241 1.535 (0.554) (1.417) Profitability 0.031 (0.004) (0.019) (0.084) ROE 0.131 0.090 (0.266) (0.300) Investment / Assets 0.022 0.011 (0.035) (0.130) Cash Growth 1.216 1.126 (1.219) (0.965) Asset Growth 0.901 0.862 (0.379) (0.339) Sales Growth 0.879 0.750 (0.390) (0.549) Leverage 0.325 0.238 (0.113) (0.179) Firm Size 9.688 6.577 (0.845) (2.703) E-index 1.603 2.304 (1.144) (1.171) Observations 590 590 Unique Issuers 118 118 Issuance Characteristics Offering Amount ($mm) Maturity (Years) Offering Yield Rating at Issuance Gross Spread Number of Book-running Managers Time to Evaluate Contract (Column (3) in hours, Column (4) in days) Length of Contract (Pages) Similarity to S-3 Filing Covenant Quality Trigger Count Holding Company Clause Number of Ratings Needed to Downgrade Agency Must Verify Downgrade Cause Covenant Word Count Change in Covenant Word Count Including Covenant (3) 566,545 (393,102) 6.85 (4.87) 5.15 (1.80) 7.84 (1.54) 5.21 (1.76) 3.24 (1.74) 1.39 (2.63) 59 (23) 0.748 (0.151) 2.60 (1.19) 3.32 (1.46) 0.484 (0.500) 2.37 (0.55) 0.656 (0.48) 19.68 (15.97) 8.39 (15.64) Excluding Covenant (4) 514,385 (428,653) 10.36 (5.35) 5.38 (1.37) 7.25 (1.84) 5.70 (1.50) 2.30 (1.34) 413.49 (438.58) 50 (27) 0.834 (0.169) 16.32 (13.60) 4.66 (13.63) Table IV Initial Covenant Pricing for Within-Issuer Sample The table shows the initial price effects from covenant inclusion for the within-issuer sample, which compares concurrently trading bonds issued by the same issuer with maturities within two years where one issuance has the restrictive covenant and the other does not. Test-statistics calculated using robust standard errors, clustered at the issuer level, are in parentheses. The specification for Column (1) is as in Eq.(2): Yjik = α + βCovjik + γXjik + fi + fk + εjik , where Yjik is the dependent variable for issuance j by issuer i at offering period k and Covjik is an indicator for the change-of-control. Column (1) shows the average price effect while Column (2) - (4) examine heterogeneity in the price effect. The specification for Columns (2) - (4) include indicators for covenant saliency, if the covenant is the first by that issuer, and if the contract terms included at the time of issuance had changed significantly from the base prospectus (defined as below median textual similarity). In all specifications, we include issuer fixed effects, year fixed effects, as well as a vector of issuance controls Xjik , including credit rating, maturity, total covenants, and offering amount. ***, ** and * indicate p-values of 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Avg. Pricing (1) 0.227 (1.78)* Dependent variable = Treasury Less Yield at Offering Covenant Inclusion Covenant is Salient Attribute First Issuance with Covenant Large Change from Base Prospectus Issuance & Issuance Controls Year Fixed Effects Adjusted R 2 Observations Yes Yes 62% 399 46 Heterogeneity in Pricing (2) (3) (4) 0.311 0.459 0.420 (2.18)** (2.93)*** (1.07) -0.323 (2.34)** -0.516 (3.46)*** -0.320 (1.78)* Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 63% 64% 65% 399 399 399 Table V Descriptive Statistics for Bondholders This table reports summary statistics for bondholders at the time of issuance. The mean and standard deviation (in parentheses) for each variable are reported separately for two samples of issuers. Column (1) reports estimates for issuances that included the restrictive covenants and Column (2) reports estimates for issuances that excluded the restrictive covenant. Appendix A provides the definition of each of the covariates. Including Covenant Excluding Covenant Bondholders at Issuance (1) (2) Number of Bondholders 116.8 99.5 (86.8) (88.2) Total Par Held 230,880 248,805 (192,680) (211,768) Coverage Ratio 43.6% 39.5% (18.6%) (19.6%) Percent Held by Annunity Funds 4.9% 3.7% (7.7%) (7.3%) Percent Held by Insurance 67.9% 72.1% (26.0%) (25.9%) Percent Held by Mutual Funds 26.1% 20.9% (22.6%) (21.9%) Percent Held by Pension Funds 0.8% 2.7% (4.3%) (7.4%) Percent Held by Others (e.g., Hospital, Government, etc…) 0.3% 0.6% (0.8%) (2.4%) Percent Investing With LBO Experience 48.6% 23.1% (22.4%) (24.8%) Percent of Investors Portfolio in Investment-Grade Bonds 80.5% 80.1% (10.5%) (9.9%) Percent of Investors with Prior Experience with Issuer 41.4% 45.9% (20.1%) (20.1%) Number of Other Issuances Held 1284.6 1155.3 574.2 (667.9) 778 1,554 Observations 284 376 Unique Issuers 47 Table VI Subsequent Bondholdings for Within-Issuer Sample The table shows the subsequent average price effects and bondholdings from covenant inclusion for the within-issuer sample, which contains concurrently trading bonds that had maturies within the same two year window. Test-statistics calculated using robust standard errors, clustered at the issuer level, are in parentheses. For Panel A, the specification is as in Eq.(2): Yjik = α + βCovjik + γXjik + fi + fk + εjik , where Yjik is the dependent variable for issuance j by issuer i at offering period k and Covjik is an indicator for the change-of-control. Each column represents a different time period post issuance. For Panel B, C and D, the specification is as in Eq.(3): ∆Yji = β∆Salientji + γ4Xji + ∆fk + ∆εji , where ∆Yji is the difference in the dependent variable for issuance j by issuer i with and without the covenant. Salientji is an indicator for the covenant being the salient attribute relative to pricing or offering amount. F irstji indicates when the covenant is the first time that issuer has ever included such a covenant. Dissimilarji indicates the contract terms included at the time of issuance had changed significantly from the base prospectus (defined as below median textual similarity). In both specifications, Xji is a vector of controls which includes credit rating, maturity, offering amount, offering yield, underpricing, and trading volume. ***, ** and * indicate p-values of 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Panel A. Dependent Variable = TREASURY LESS YIELD INVESTORS HOLDING RETURN VOLATILITY Panel B. Dependent Variable = TREASURY LESS YIELD MUTUAL FUND HOLDINGS Panel C. Dependent Variable = TREASURY LESS YIELD MUTUAL FUND HOLDINGS Panel D. Dependent Variable = TREASURY LESS YIELD MUTUAL FUND HOLDINGS Issuance & Issuer Controls Liquidity/Trading Controls Year Fixed Effects Observations Independent Variable = COVENANT INCLUSION (Qtr1) (Qtr2) (Year1) (Year2) 0.018 0.679 0.477 0.427 (0.02) (4.94)*** (1.94)* (1.34) 24.2 29.7 28.3 50.4 (2.33)** (2.89)*** (3.00)*** (5.31)*** 0.14 0.05 -0.03 -0.08 (1.03) (0.97) (1.71)* (2.11)** Independent Variable = COVENANT IS SALIENT (Qtr1) (Qtr2) (Year1) (Year2) -0.170 -0.112 -0.070 -0.009 (2.56)** (3.36)*** (1.79)* (0.22) 11.6% 10.6% 8.6% 8.8% (2.39)** (1.82)* (1.45) (1.82)* Independent Variable = FIRST WITH COVENANT (Qtr1) (Qtr2) (Year1) (Year2) 0.044 0.132 0.057 0.062 (0.75) (2.01)** (1.29) (1.49) 0.7% -4.8% -5.1% -6.0% (0.14) (0.90) (1.20) (1.46) Independent Variable = DISSIMILAR TO BASE PROSPECTUS (Qtr1) (Qtr2) (Year1) (Year2) -0.133 -0.104 -0.045 -0.037 (2.23)** (2.15)** (1.54) (1.18) 14.7% 12.5% 6.8% 3.4% (2.45)** (2.07)** (1.01) (0.47) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 302 298 290 258 48 Table VII Sophisticated, Duped, or Lucky Investors? This table explores the relationship between investors’ experience evaluating an issuance and the pricing of the issuances contractual terms. Column (1) examines bonds with bargain covenants and Column (2) bonds with priced covenants following the modernization to bond issuance process. Column (3) tests if there is a statistical significant difference in the time available to review the bond, LBO experience and prior issuer experience for these two pricing outcomes. In both specifications, a vector of issuance controls are used which include credit rating, maturity, offering amount, offering yield, underpricing, and trading volume. ***, ** and * indicate p-values of 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Independent Variable = Dependent Variable = Time for Due Diligence LBO Experience Prior Issuer Experience Controls and Fixed Effects Observations 49 Bargain Covenant Priced Covenant Test of Difference (1) (2) (3) -1.788 (2.05)** 0.268 (1.75)* 0.421 (2.26)** Yes 302 0.882 (1.15) 0.041 (0.35) -0.415 (2.46)** Yes 302 (2.41)** (0.48) (3.21)*** Yes 302 Table VIII The Benefits Gained by Underwriters from Modernization This table explores the extent to which underwriters benefited from the SEC reforms that modernized the bond issuance process. Test-statistics calculated using robust standard errors, clustered at the underwriter level, are in parentheses. The specification is as in Eq.(4): Yit = α+βU nderwritingQualityit +γXit +fi +ft + εit where Yit is the dependent variable of interest for underwriter i in in quarter t and U nderwritingQualityit is the independent variable of interest that measures aspects of the underwriting quality such as the inclusion of restrictive covenants, changes from the base Prospectus to the final Prospectus, the quality of the legal language used in the indenture as well as the time allowed for investor due diligence. We include underwriter fixed effects, quarter fixed effects, as well as a vector of issuance controls including credit rating, maturity, offering amount, offering yield, and spread when appropriate. Panel A focuses on all bond issuances while Panel B focuses on the bond issuances that have the restrictive covenant package. The sample is limited to underwriters with at least 3% market share in a given quarter in the sample. ***, ** and * indicate p-values of 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. Panel A. All Bond Issuances New Issuance (N) -0.08* (0.05) -0.03* (0.02) Yes Yes 55% 753 New Issuance Volume ($) -0.13*** (0.05) -0.04** (0.02) Yes Yes 53% 753 Market Share (N) -0.08* (0.05) -0.02* (0.02) Yes Yes 21% 735 Market Share Volume ($) -0.15*** (0.04) -0.05** (0.03) Yes Yes 21% 735 Underwriter Fees 0.016 (0.02) 0.012 (0.01) Yes Yes 68% 753 Panel B. Bond Issuances with Restrictive Covenant Packages New Issuance New Issuance Dependent Variable = (N) Volume ($) Quality of Underwriting 0.17*** 0.17*** (0.05) (0.05) -0.07 -0.11* Time for Diligence (0.05) (0.06) Yes Yes Issuance Controls Quarter & Underwriter Fixed Effects Yes Yes 2 57% 51% Adjusted R Observations 335 335 Market Share (N) 0.65*** (0.15) -0.07*** (0.03) Yes Yes 45% 332 Market Share Volume ($) 0.68*** (0.15) -0.08*** (0.03) Yes Yes 42% 332 Underwriter Fees 0.70*** (0.05) -0.07** (0.03) Yes Yes 49% 335 Dependent Variable = Adding Restrictive Covenants Change from Base Prospectus Issuance Controls Quarter & Underwriter Fixed Effects Adjusted R2 Observations 50