Capital Flows and Fragmented Credit Markets in Latin America Pablo Duarte∗ January 26, 2015 Abstract The Latin American financial sector is fragmented in a formal and an informal segment. International capital flows may affect the segmentation through its influence on credit supply and interest rates. I examine the effect of the buoyant capital inflows in the region between 2006 and 2010 on the relative usage of informal financing sources by firms of 18 Latin American countries. I focus on the role legal-institutional barriers play on amplifying or dampening the effect. I find that capital inflows are related to a lower usage of informal sources of finance. Lower banking concentration – a supply side institutional barrier – as well as lower costs to start firms and a more equal protection of property rights – demand side institutional barriers – amplify the effect. Keywords: informal finance, banking concentration, capital flows. JEL Codes: G21, K42, O17 ∗ Institute for Economic Policy; University of Leipzig; Grimmaische Str. 12; 04109 Leipzig; Germany; Email: pablo.duarte@uni-leipzig.de. 1 1 Introduction Informal markets are a widespread phenomenon in Latin America. At informal markets people exchange legal goods and services without fulfilling the formal conditions required in a jurisdiction. Examples are houses without building permits, food without fulfilling sanitary regulation or credit without fulfilling financial requisites as transaction taxes or interest rate caps.1 Informal markets for credit are the most important source of finance for microenterprises and a non-negligible source of finance for medium size firms in Latin America (CAF, 2011). Formal financial intermediaries need a bank license to operate, have to comply with reserve requirements at the central bank and in some countries must collect financial transactions taxes and observe interest rate caps. At informal credit markets transactions are done without a bank license, without having reserve requirements at the central bank, without paying taxes or at interest rates without restrictions. The most common informal financing sources in Latin America are family members, private lenders, pawn shops and alike (CAF, 2011, 196). Capital flows may have different effects on the relative usage of formal vs. informal financing sources. With buoyant capital inflows, as it has been the case in Latin America since 2006 and more strongly since the zero interest rate policy of the Federal Reserve after 2008, the loanable funds at formal markets increase. Such increase in formal credit supply might have different effects. On the one had it might ease access to formal credit and thus increase the relative use of formal finance. On the other hand, it might lower formal interest rates and motivate arbitrage movements to the informal credit markets. After discussing some theoretical issues I examine the effect of capital flows on the relative usage of informal finance for 18 Latin American countries. 1 Transactions of (in Latin America) illegal goods as cocaine or illegal “services” as hired killing are not considered when studying informal markets. For a deeper discussion on the definition of informality see Schneider and Enste (2000). 2 Since the 1970s Latin America has experienced four phases of buoyant capital inflows. The resulting boom-and-bust-cycles haven been intensively studied. Reinhart et al. (1994), for instance, compare the B&B cycles of the 1970s and the 1990s. Calvo et al. (1996) analyse the macroeconomic effectiveness of the different economic policy reactions of capital inflows in Latin America and South East Asia. Ocampo (2009) und Jara et al. (2009) examine the macroeconomic effects of the most recent global financial crises in Latin America. De Paula et al. (2012) examines the macroeconomic consequences of the regions’ actual ”Capital-Bonanza”. Gómez et al. (2014) examine the connection between capital debt flows and the local credit market in Colombia. They find that a negative shock international debt flows has a negative effect on the proportion of firms having access to (formal) financial intermediation. They also find that in the long-run capital flows and the growth of domestic (formal) credit are positively correlated. To my best knowledge, however, there are no studies which examine the effect of capital flows specifically taking to account the fragmentation of the credit markets in Latin America. The contributions of the paper are twofold. First, I identify three characteristics of the legal-institutional framework that motivate informal financial transactions and second, I shed a light on the effects of capital inflows on the use of informal financial sources and the role the legal-institutional barriers play in the scenario of buoyant capital inflows which the regions experiences since 2006. 2 Institutional determinants of informal financial transactions To understand the characteristics of the legal-institutional barriers which motivate people to supply and demand capital at informal rather than formal markets, it is useful to think about the characteristics of an ideal market. The essence of markets is to be found in its nature of a competitive order in which individuals voluntarily exchange as legal equals (Vanberg, 2004, 9). The fact that individuals meet as legal equals implies that the rules under which exchange takes place do not grant 3 privileges to any market participant and that free entry to the market is possible. Only under such condition of law equality, the market price system can fulfill its function as a coordination mechanism for individual plans (Böhm, 1966, 121). In an ideal financial market anyone with a sound project can access the financial market and “it will be the quality of the underlying assets or ideas that will determine whether finance is forthcoming, and the identity of the owner (...) will be irrelevant” (Rajan and Zingales, 2003, 9). Said differently, if N is the total number of entrepreneurs in a jurisdiction and θN , with 0 ≤ θ ≤ 1, the number of entrepreneurs who have access to finance, an ideal financial system would require that θ = 1. Informal finance is mainly understood as the response of creditors and borrowers to imperfect financial sectors and state interventions (Burkett, 1988). Imperfections are present when θ < 1, as the excluded individuals would have incentives to evade regulation and supply and demand capital informally. There are mainly three structural barriers which reflect a low θ in Latin America. The barriers can be classified as supply and demand side barriers. 2.1 The credit supply channel High entry barriers for credit suppliers, specially at the banking sector, might motivate informal financial transactions in two ways. First, they exclude potential creditors from the legal possibility of supplying capital. Second, entry barriers lead to bank concentration and market power of incumbent banks, what hardens access to finance for entrepreneurs. High entry barriers for banks and thus a low θ create incentives for excluded entrepreneurs and capital owners to trade informally. Beck et al. (2004) and Love and Peria (2012) study the role of banking concentration and banking competition on access to finance. Both studies suggest that market concentration increases firm-reported financing obstacles and reduces actual access to finance. Beck et al. (2004) find that higher bank concentration 4 leads to more firm-reported obstacles to finance for firms of all sizes in a cross section of 74 countries. The relation, however, holds only for low-income countries and is dampened by the level of institutional development measured as the average of six indicators.2 In the same sense, Love and Peria (2012) find that high bank competition, represented by a low Lerner index, facilitates access to finance and that higher financial development, measured by the ratio of private credit to GDP, reduces the effect of lower banking competition on financial access. 2.2 The credit demand channels Entry barriers for entrepreneurs and an unequal enforcement of property rights are the barriers at the capital demand side of credit markets. When entrepreneurs face high start-up costs at the formal sector, they often decide to produce informally. As informal producers do not appear in the public registries and usually do not register their own operations, do not use identifiable payment mechanisms such as banking accounts and do not properly separate the firm’s from the individual’s capital (Straub, 2005, p. 301), the screening costs for formal credit lenders are prohibitively high. Entry barriers to the formal economy lower the value of θ as informal producers can not provide formal banks with the necessary information. Informal firms are therefore usually excluded from the credit markets, even if they have a sound investment project. Djankov et al. (2002), for example, find that higher regulation of entry, measured as the number of procedures, the costs as percentage of GNI per capita and the time procedures take to start a business, are positively related with the size of the informal sector in a cross-section of 85 countries as measured by Schneider and Enste (2000). The second demand side characteristic which reflects a low θ is the unequal enforcement of property rights. Formal credit suppliers normally use a collateral 2 The index of institutional development summarizes variables for voice and accountability, political stability and absence of violence, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law and control of corruption from the World Governance Indicators(WGI). See Kaufmann et al. (2009) for the newest version of the WGI. 5 to overcome information problems and to secure repayment. Borrowers, however, cannot use assets as collateral if the assets are not protected by a property rights system. De Soto (2000) calls this kind of assets “dead capital”. The lack of a collateral, that is a legally protected and registered asset, excludes the potential borrower from the formal financial sector. In that sense, the less equal the protection of property rights in a jurisdiction, the lower is the value of θ. Informal producers and entrepreneurs owning dead capital are likely to recur to informal financial institutions as informal lenders have monitoring comparative advantages against formal ones. The comparative advantages rely on the enforcements and monitoring mechanisms informal credit suppliers use, which are more accurate given the lack of official registries and accurate collateral (Ayyagari et al., 2010; Arnott and Stiglitz, 1991; Stiglitz, 1990). Specifically in Latin America, the enforcement and monitoring mechanisms often rely on violence and physical threat (CAF, 2011, p. 196) and are based on the access to local information, only available to informal lenders because of their social and physical proximity to the borrower.3 3 The reaction of informal credit markets to capital inflows Figure 1 shows the relationship between formal and informal credit sources for the 18 Latin American countries. In all countries is the percentage of credits from informal sources more than 50% of total finance from external sources with Mexico with almost 76% and Honduras with 51%. With a higher supply of formal and informal capital and lower interest rates due to buoyant capital inflows, entrepreneurs face new possibilities at the credit markets. Given that the conditions for formal credit (interest rates and repayment 3 “The following story, told by the president of the Paraguayan association of finance companies, describes the kind of enforcement usurers favor: One of our clients was heavily indebted with several creditors, including us and a usurer. As a way to remind him of his obligation, the usurer sent him a bullet in an envelope. The client paid the usurer first and then filed a reorganization procedure. We recovered only a small fraction of the formal loans.” (Straub and Sosa, 2001, p. 296). 6 Figure 1: Finance of Working Capital by External Sources (2010) 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% Informal Bank Source: Enterprise Surveys, The World Bank. enforcement mechanisms) are typically more advantageous than for informal credit, the additional availability of capital from formal sources may motivate a different rearrangement of the firm’s capital sources. The rearrangement, however, depends on whether formal and informal credit suppliers compete with each other for the same customers or the informal lenders enhance the formal lenders (mainly banks) in a different market. 3.1 Formal and informal credit sources as competitors Specially when credit supply side barriers predominate, informal credit suppliers tend to compete with established formal ones. That means, informal and formal credit suppliers have the same potential clients. The entry barriers for credit suppliers, as discussed in section two, keep formal credit supply constrained. As credit constrains are eased with the additional availability of loanable funds due to the international inflow of capital, firms have more possibilities of getting formal financing. They would substitute informal for formal credits, as far as the credit barriers allow to. Therefore, the relative usage of informal finance as percentage of total external finance would decrease. The credit supply and demand barriers 7 identified in section 2 may dampen or amplify the effect. On the credit supply side, high bank concentration dampens the effect of capital inflows on the usage of informal finance. Banking concentration hinders the increase of the supply of capital at the formal sector and the lowering of interest rates impulsed by the increasing international capital. If informal credit sources are mainly an alternative for entrepreneurs when formal sources are not available, the usage of informal sources will not decrease as much as if the levels of banking concentration were low. If informal credit sources are mainly a complement for formal financial markets, the difference between the formal and informal interest rates will not be as high as without entry barriers for banks, less capital will flow in the informal financial markets and the relative usage of informal finance will not decrease as much. Following the same logic, credit demand side barriers are also expected to dampen the reduction in the relative usage of informal credit sources. The higher the start-up costs for entrepreneurs, the higher is the probability that entrepreneurs act informally and the more difficult it would be for them to change from informal to formal finance. In the same sense, the more deficient the protection of property rights, which determines the portion of “dead capital”, the more difficult it is for firms to substitute informal for formal credit. 3.2 Informal lenders enhance formal lenders (banks) When credit demand barriers predominate, formal and informal credit suppliers do not have the same potential clients. Informal credit suppliers work as informal “branches” of banks transmitting the new international capital to the entrepreneurs without access to the formal financial sector. Additional availability of loanable funds due to international capital inflows would increase the relative usage of informal sources of finance, as individuals cannot easily change to formal credit sources. 8 Following the same logic as above, the credit supply barriers dampen the increase of the relative usage of informal credit sources. The interest rate differential, which motivates arbitrage movements and increases the loanable funds for informal sources, would be smaller the higher the bank concentration. Less credit is available at the informal financial credit markets and the increase in its relative usage is less than in cases with low bank concentration. The credit demand barriers would amplify the increase in the relative usage of financial credit sources. The higher the star-up costs for entrepreneurs and the higher the unequal protection of property rights, the more important are informal credit sources for financing working capital. The percentage of total external finance from informal sources would increase with additional capital availability principally because credit financing would increase, and informal sources are the most likely alternative in the case in which formal and informal lenders are complementary. Summing up, one might expect that the effect of capital inflows on the relative usage of informal credit source depends on the relationship between formal and informal lenders. If they are competitors, the usage of informal credit sources is expected to decline with capital inflows. If informal lenders enhance formal lenders, the relative usage of informal finance is expected to increase. The credit supply and demand side barriers identified in section 2 may dampen or amplify the effects. Bank concentration – the credit demand side barrier – dampens both, the reduction of the usage of informal sources in the competition case and the increase in the non-competition case. The supply side barriers dampen the decrease of usage of informal sources in the competition case and amplify the increase in informal credit in the non-competition case. 9 4 Empirical Evidence 4.1 Data and model I test for the effects of capital inflows on the usage of informal capital sources by entrepreneurs for 18 Latin American countries (see Table 1). I use micro and macroeconomic data. All the microeconomic data is at a firm-level and is provided by the Enterprise Surveys published by the World Bank. The Enterprise Surveys report the answers of over 12,000 formally registered firms in the 18 Latin American countries of the sample about, among others, their financing sources for working capital as percentage of total finance. I use data of year 2010 for all countries excepting Brazil, for which data is available for 2009. I therefore use data of year 2009 for Brazil. The baseline regression is: inf ormalf inance = β0 + β1 Kinf lowsj + β2 (1 − θ1 ) + β3 Kinf lows × (1 − θ1 )+ totalf inance i,j β4 (1 − θ2 ) + β5 Kinf lows × (1 − θ2 ) + β6 θ3 + β7 Kinf lows × θ3 + β8 Xj + β9 Zi,j . For the endogenous variable inf ormalf inance totalf inance i,j (wk inf ormal) I constructed three categories given the available information: formal, informal and own. The sum of the three categories equals 100. Informal financial sources include family and friends, supplier credit / customer advance, informal sources, other sources and remittances. The endogenous variable is expressed as percentage of total finance. The three θi variables capture the three institutional barriers which motivate informal financial transactions identified in section 2. The variable (1-θ1 ) is captured by a bank concentration index (concent), which captures the assets of the five largest banks as a share of the total commercial banking assets and by a Lerner index (lerner). Both measures are provided by the Global Development Financial Database published by the World Bank. Three indexes provided by the Doing Business database of the World Bank capture (1-θ2 ). These are the costs, steps and days required in each country to start a business. θ3 is captured by the property 10 rights protection index provided by the Index of Economic Freedom (p rights). All values are at a national level for the year 2010 and 2009 for Brazil. The variable kinf lows sum captures the sum of net capital inflows from 2006 to 2010 as percent of GDP for each country. The net capital inflows are defined as the current account deficit reported by the balance of payments statistics of each country in each year. The sum is done from 2006 to 2010 because on average, in the year 2006 began the most recent phase of capital inflows in the region. The data is from the International Financial Statistics (IFS) published by the IMF. The baseline regression also includes an interaction term of θi with kinf lows sum which intends to capture the effect of capital inflows on the relative usage of informal finance due to the interaction with each θi index. The vector Xj includes two control variables at a national level. These are: logarithm of GDP per capita in 2010 (lgdpp c), which controls for the overall development level of each country; inf lation, which controls for the financial stability of each country. The vector Zi,j includes control variables at a firm level. These are: size, which takes the value of 1 if the firm has less than 20 employees, 2 if it has between 20 and 99 employees and 3 if it has more than 100 employees; inf ormal ini which takes the value of 1 if the firm was officially registered in the year it began operations. The variable is intended to capture the “legal maturity” of the firm. Firms which were registered at the beginning of their operations are less likely to use informal financing sources; inf ormal, provided by the Enterprise Survey, takes the value of 1 if the firm assures to compete against informal firms in the market and 0 otherwise. inf ormal intends to control for the portion of the firms which are not part of the survey and are likely to use informal finance. Table 1 shows the descriptive statistics of the variables. On average, the firms financed 26.44 % of their working capital from informal sources. In Colombia the average percentage of total finance coming from informal sources is the highest with almost 41% compared with 7.5% for Panama. The country which received the 11 12 wk inf ormal 30.05 21.22 25.34 26.06 40.85 13.58 29.57 31.81 31.27 28.36 14.84 29.23 11.52 7.50 21.69 28.97 23.57 27.28 26.44 country Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Costa Rica Dom. Rep. Ecuador El Salvador Guatemala Honduras Mexico Nicaragua Panama Paraguay Peru Uruguay Venezuela Total 5.26 -10.53 -42.62 0.25 -8.99 12.80 25.63 32.25 -8.35 21.50 16.06 36.31 5.09 62.63 32.89 -11.06 2.62 11.78 -35.21 kinf lows sum 73.13 52.97 79.43 65.99 . 67.59 75.60 86.45 72.88 83.60 79.82 69.38 71.21 100.00 72.50 70.94 88.38 73.79 85.20 0.24 0.30 0.27 0.23 0.31 0.37 0.15 0.16 0.17 0.35 . 0.19 . . 0.31 0.03 0.38 -0.18 0.31 concent lerner 24.72 16.90 100.80 6.90 6.80 14.70 10.50 19.20 32.60 45.00 49.10 47.20 12.30 111.90 10.30 55.10 13.60 42.10 30.20 costs 26 50 119 22 14 60 19 56 17 37 14 9 39 9 35 27 65 141 days 10.24 44.33 14 15 14 8 9 12 8 13 8 12 13 6 8 6 7 6 11 17 steps Table 1: Descriptive Statistics 43.93 20 10 50 85 50 50 30 20 50 35 30 50 25 40 30 40 75 0 p rights 8.48 8.74 7.07 8.57 9.06 9.06 8.59 8.47 8.09 7.99 7.73 7.32 9.00 7.13 8.75 7.45 8.25 8.83 8.70 lgdp pc 25.40 38.77 31.26 14.88 21.44 20.33 41.26 26.67 20.78 13.85 25.80 31.53 19.88 45.65 20.59 27.83 12.55 33.27 76.66 inf lation 1.91 1.99 1.91 1.83 2.03 1.91 1.86 1.99 1.92 1.98 1.94 1.68 2.00 1.71 1.85 1.85 1.99 1.85 1.65 size 0.90 0.92 0.87 0.95 0.94 0.84 0.77 0.83 0.87 0.77 0.89 0.87 0.90 0.79 0.99 0.98 0.92 0.95 0.97 inf ormal ini 0.67 0.71 0.80 0.66 0.53 0.76 0.73 0.73 0.64 0.67 0.73 0.59 0.65 0.66 0.59 0.75 0.73 0.73 0.36 inf ormal 13 wk inf ormal kinf lows sum concent lerner costs steps days p rights lgdp pc inf lation size inf ormal ini inf ormal 1 -0.07 -0.05 0.09 -0.07 -0.02 -0.04 0.01 0.09 -0.06 -0.02 0.00 0.04 wk inf ormal 1 0.35 -0.15 0.14 -0.35 -0.28 0.13 -0.16 -0.09 -0.03 -0.10 0.03 kinf lows sum 1 0.04 0.47 -0.41 -0.09 -0.07 -0.47 0.05 -0.02 -0.06 -0.01 1 -0.33 -0.19 -0.26 -0.19 0.13 -0.23 0.04 -0.03 -0.03 concent lerner 1 0.13 -0.07 -0.43 -0.81 0.37 -0.04 -0.06 0.04 1 0.71 -0.39 -0.19 0.44 -0.06 0.02 -0.01 costs steps 1 -0.08 -0.06 0.16 -0.07 0.06 -0.04 days 1 0.54 -0.47 0.04 0.02 -0.03 1 -0.14 0.05 0.04 -0.04 1 -0.06 -0.02 -0.05 p rights lgdp pc inf lation Table 2: Correlation Table 1 0.11 -0.11 size 1 -0.09 inf ormal ini 1.00 inf ormal highest capital inflows (net) between 2006 and 2010 was Nicaragua with 62.7% of GDP and the country with the highest capital outflows was Bolivia with 42.62 % of GDP. The concentration and lerner indexes show that the banking sector of the region is highly concentrated. This is the result of a consolidation and concentration process which took place in the last decade (Chortareas et al., 2012; de la Torre et al., 2012; Rojas-Lopez, 2006). On average, the surveyed firms have between 20 and 99 employees. Table 2 shows the correlation coefficients of the variables. 4.2 Results As explained in section 3.1, the accumulated capital inflows can have a direct effect on banking concentration. Table 3 shows the results for the baseline regression using the different variable for θi . In all specifications, in countries with higher capital inflows as percent of GDP informal financial sources were less used. This negative and significant effect implies in a scenario with additional capital available at lower interest rates, firms decide to finance a lower portion of their working capital from informal sources. The θ variables have a different effect on the endogenous variable. Using the Lerner Index for banking concentration (first three columns of table 3), a higher banking concentration induces a higher financing from informal sources in specifications 1 and 2, as argued in section 2. In both specifications Lerner is positive and statistically significant. The interaction term is negative in the three cases and statistically significant. This implies that the θ1 values amplify the negative effect of capital inflows. Adding the size of the coefficients of lerner, kinf lowssum and the interaction term, the overall effect is positive. Despite the capital inflows, a high banking competition still motivates firms to finance working capital from informal sources. This implications do not hold when using Days as the variable capturing θ2 . Using concentration (columns 4, 5 and 6) the results are similar, but not 14 Table 3: Baseline Regression (OLS) (1) wk informal -0.143 (-1.56) (2) wk informal -1.006*** (-7.60) (3) wk informal -0.102 (-1.22) (4) wk informal -0.294*** (-2.65) (5) wk informal -1.003*** (-7.95) (6) wk informal -0.144** (-2.05) informal 3.229*** (4.62) 2.786*** (3.96) 3.082*** (4.35) 3.011*** (4.44) 2.824*** (4.18) 3.045*** (4.50) size -1.653*** (-3.98) -1.624*** (-3.88) -1.676*** (-3.99) -1.374*** (-3.46) -1.476*** (-3.72) -1.457*** (-3.68) -0.981 (-0.88) -1.065 (-0.95) -1.299 (-1.16) -0.485 (-0.47) -0.173 (-0.17) -0.611 (-0.60) inflation -0.484*** (-10.57) -0.330*** (-7.35) -0.428*** (-8.94) -0.387*** (-7.41) -0.338*** (-7.65) -0.224*** (-5.11) lgdp pc 18.63*** (13.45) 11.14*** (12.00) 10.54*** (11.85) 11.74*** (8.77) 9.284*** (10.95) 2.447*** (2.63) lerner 18.97*** (5.20) 9.822*** (2.77) -6.045 (-1.60) lerner X Kinflows sum -0.699** (-2.54) -0.559* (-1.93) -0.380 (-1.37) costs 0.404*** (11.09) 0.118*** (4.24) 0.00713*** (10.03) 0.00121* (1.90) Kinflows sum informal ini costs X Kinflows sum p rights -0.244*** (-9.03) -0.243*** (-7.94) -0.168*** (-6.54) -0.199*** (-5.89) -0.321*** (-7.74) 0.0769* (1.81) p rights X Kinflows sum 0.000155 (0.09) 0.00955*** (5.99) 0.00285** (2.22) 0.00367 (1.13) 0.0124*** (4.51) 0.00363 (1.41) steps -0.690*** (-4.66) 0.107 (0.79) steps X Kinflows sum 0.0603*** (7.70) 0.0482*** (7.00) days -0.0666*** (-6.54) -0.0621*** (-6.28) days X Kinflows sum -0.00209*** (-3.27) -0.00594*** (-6.66) concent con f X Kinflows sum cons N R2 adj. R2 AIC -119.6*** (-10.47) 9420 0.040 0.039 91667.4 -41.45*** (-6.51) 9420 0.029 0.028 91770.4 t statistics in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 15 -38.18*** (-6.14) 9420 0.028 0.027 91779.5 0.0444 (1.08) 0.203*** (4.23) -0.0643 (-1.40) 0.00437* (1.94) 0.0128*** (6.05) 0.0183*** (7.06) -59.52*** (-4.60) 10782 0.029 0.028 105471.7 -44.87*** (-4.55) 10782 0.030 0.029 105459.3 17.67* (1.81) 10782 0.032 0.031 105438.8 identical. The accumulated capital inflows have a negative and statistically significant coefficient. Contrary to the lerner index, the interaction terms are positive and statistically significant. The size of the coefficients are, however, much smaller compared to the effect of the lerner index. The difference reflects that the information captured in each variable is different. The correlation coefficient between lerner and concent is 0.04 (table 2). The lerner index captures the possibility banks have on setting a price above the marginal costs while the concentration index focuses on the assets owned by the five biggest banks. The concentration measure, however, does not necessarily imply a higher market power of the incumbents. For that reason, the Lerner index might be a more accurate measure (Love and Peria, 2012). The variables capturing θ2 , that is the costs to start a firm, show a similar behavior. Higher costs in terms of GDP imply a higher use of informal finance. The interaction term is also positive and the coefficient is insignificantly small. Steps and days show contradictory effects. In this case the variable also captures different information. Table 1 shows, for example, that in Brazil 119 days are needed for 14 steps to start a firm. In Bolivia, one step more is needed, but the firm can be started in less than the half of the days needed in Brazil (50). The costs in Brazil in terms of per capita income are much lower than in Bolivia. In this case, the start-up costs as percent of per capita income is the most objective and comparable variable. Finally, the Property rights index (θ3 ) is in all minus one specification negative and statistically significant. This implies that a better and more equal protection of property rights induce firms to finance a lower portion of their working capital from informal sources. The interaction term is always positive, but very small and its influence insignificant. The dependent variable of the regression kinf lowssum can only take the values between 0 and 100. That means that it is censored at an upper and a lower limit and that the coefficients of the baseline regression might be biased. Table 4 shows 16 Table 4: Tobit Regression (1) wk inf ormal model kinf lows sum -0.179** (-2.37) inf ormal (d) 3.297*** (4.80) size -0.309 (-0.74) inf ormal ini (d) -0.796 (-0.71) inf lation -0.604*** (-12.74) lgdp pc 23.80*** (16.48) lerner 23.95*** (6.33) lerner × kinf lows sum -1.582*** (-5.24) costs 0.551*** (14.22) costs × kinf lows sum 0.00719*** (9.14) p rights -0.340*** (-11.97) p rights × kinf lows sum -0.00425** (-2.57) 9420 Observations R2 Adjusted R2 AIC 57420.9 Marginal effects; t statistics in parentheses (d) for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 17 the results for a Tobit-regression using only the Lerner index and the start-up costs as percent of per capita national income. The accumulated capital inflows have a negative and statistically significant effect. Such effect is amplified by the interaction of the capital inflows with the banking concentration index. That implies, that in countries with a higher baking concentration, incoming international capital will have an even higher effect on the reduction of informal finance. The overall effect is however positive, as the coefficient of the lerner index is much bigger than the sum of the coefficients of the capital inflows and the interaction term. Higher start-up costs lead to more usage of informal finance and the interaction term with capital inflows is insignificantly small. A better protection of property rights is related to a lower usage of informal sources to finance working capital and its interaction with kinf lowssum is also insignificantly small. 5 Conclusions I examine the effect of capital inflows on firms’ usage of informal financing sources in 18 Latin American countries. Latin American entrepreneurs without access to formal financial markets demand and supply capital informally, that is without fulfilling the legal regulation of each jurisdiction. In a perfect financial system, any entrepreneur with a sound investment project could access finance irrespective of her identity. I identify three barriers which interfere with the perfect functioning of financial markets in Latin America and makes it more difficult for entrepreneurs with sound projects to access finance. Banking concentration, a supply side barrier, leads to lower credit supply and financing obstacles for entrepreneurs. Entry barriers for firms and an unequal protection of property rights are credit supply side barriers. The barriers lead to an imperfect overcoming of information problems which hardens credit transactions at the formal financial sector and motivate informal financial transactions. 18 With international capital inflows, more capital is available, first at the formal financial sector. The additional capital lowers interest rates at the formal markets. This might have two effects which depend on the relationship between the formal and the informal financial markets. If both are complements, the usage of informal finance might increase as the difference between the higher informal interest rates and the formal interest rates increase, motivating arbitrage movements between the two markets. If the markets are substitutes, the lower interest rates and easier credit constrains would motivate individuals to turn to the formal financial markets. Using data from the Enterprise Surveys published by the World Bank, and national macroeconomic data, I find that capital inflows induce a reduction of firms’ usage of informal sources to finance working capital. I additional find that banking concentration, the credit demand barrier which induces the usage of informal finance, increases the financing from informal sources and that it dampens the reduction of informal finance by the capital inflows. I also find that the costs to start a firm, the first credit supply side barrier, increase the usage of informal finance and that the interaction term with capital inflows is insignificantly small. A more equal protection of property rights, the second credit supply side barrier, reduces the financing from informal sources and it neither dampens nor amplifies the effect of the capital inflows. In a scenario of “capital bonanza”, the access to finance improves. Entrepreneurs seem to decide to use less informal sources to finance their working capital. Financial markets are still imperfect. If the goal of policy makers is to improve financial development in Latin American countries they would not only have the openness to international financial markets as an option. By reducing baking concentration, reducing start-up costs and improving the equal protection of property rights, and this way following the ideal of a privilege free order of legal equals, reforms could allow entrepreneurs to access formal finance and benefit from the financing possibilities of phases of buoyant capital inflows. 19 References Arnott, R. and Stiglitz, J. E. (1991). Moral hazard and nonmarket institutions: Dysfunctional crowding out of peer monitoring? The American Economic Review, 81 (1), pp. 179–190. Ayyagari, M., Demirgüç-Kunt, A. and Maksimovic, V. (2010). Formal versus informal finance: Evidence from China. Review of Financial Studies, 23 (8), 3048–3097. Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A. and Maksimovic, V. (2004). Bank competition and access to finance: International evidence. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 36 (3), pp. 627–648. Burkett, P. (1988). Informal finance in developing countries: Lessons for the development of formal financial intermediates. Journal of Economic Development, 13 (2), 81 – 110. Böhm, F. (1966). Privatrechtsgesellschaft und Marktwirtschaft. ORDO, 17, 75 – 151. CAF (2011). Servicios financieros para el desarrollo: promoviendo el acceso en América Latina. Reporte de Economı́a y Desarrollo, Corporación Andina de Fomento. Calvo, G. A., Leiderman, L. and Reinhart, C. M. (1996). Inflows of capital to developing countries in the 1990s. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10 (2), pp. 123–139. Chortareas, G. E., Garza-Garcı́a, J. G. and Girardone, C. (2012). Competition, efficiency and interest rate margins in latin american banking. International Review of Financial Analysis, (0), –. 20 de la Torre, A., Ize, A. and Schmukler, S. L. (2012). Financial Development in Latin America and the Caribbean. The Road Ahead. World Bank Latin American and Caribbean Studies, The World Bank. De Paula, L. F., Ferrari-Filho, F. and Gomes, A. M. (2012). Capital Flows, International Imbalances and Economic Policies in Latin America. UFRGS Working Papers 12, Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Sul. De Soto, H. (2000). The Mystery of Capital. Why the Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. Transworld Publishers. Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A. (2002). The regulation of entry. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (1), 1–37. Gómez, E., Murcia, A. and Zamudio, N. (2014). Foreign Debt Flows and the Credit Market: A Principal Agent Approach. ENSAYOS SOBRE POLÍTICA ECONÓMICA. Jara, A., Moreno, R. and Tovar, C. E. (2009). The global crisis and latin america: financial impact and policy responses. BIS Quarterly Review. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. and Mastruzzi, M. (2009). Governance matters VIII : aggregate and individual governance indicators 1996-2008. Policy Research Working Paper Series 4978, The World Bank. Love, I. and Peria, M. S. M. (2012). How bank competition affects firms’access to finance. Policy Research Working Paper Series 6163, The World Bank. Ocampo, J. A. (2009). Latin america and the global financial crisis. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 33 (4), 703–724. Rajan, R. G. and Zingales, L. (2003). The great reversals: the politics of financial development in the twentieth century. Journal of Financial Economics, 69 (1), 5–50. 21 Reinhart, C., Calvo, G. and Leiderman, L. (1994). Capital Inflows to Latin America: The 1970s and 1990s. MPRA Paper 8196, University Library of Munich, Germany. Rojas-Lopez, L. (2006). El acceso a los servicios bancarios en américa latina: Identificación de obstáculos y recomendaciones. Center for Global Development. Schneider, F. and Enste, D. H. (2000). Shadow economies: Size, causes, and consequences. Journal of Economic Literature, 38 (1), 77–114. Stiglitz, J. E. (1990). Peer monitoring and credit markets. World Bank Economic Review, 4 (3), 351–66. Straub, S. (2005). Informal sector: The credit market channel. Journal of Development Economics, 78 (2), 299–321. — and Sosa, H. (2001). Ensuring willingness to repay in Paraguay. In M. Pagano (ed.), Defusing default, Incentives and Institutions., Inter-American Development Bank, 8, Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 271 – 318. Vanberg, V. J. (2004). The Freiburg School: Walter Eucken and Ordoliberalism. Freiburg discussion papers on constitutional economics 04/11. 22