Simultaneous Search in the Labor and Marriage Markets with Endogenous Schooling Decisions∗ Luca Flabbi UNC-Chapel Hill CPC, IZA Christopher Flinn New York University CCA October 26, 2015 Very Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract Labor and marriage market decisions are joint decisions. If individuals are engaged in a stable relationship, labor market decisions are taken at the household level. If individuals are not yet engaged in a stable relationship, marriage market decisions and opportunities are strongly influenced by the individual current and expected labor market position. The literature recognizes the joint nature of these decision processes but usually focuses only on one side of the decisions tree. Our analysis, instead, develops and estimates a model designed to determine the joint equilibrium distribution of labor market outcomes and marriage market statuses, together with an endogenous schooling decision. The model is estimated by the Method of Simulated Moments using labor market information from the Current Population Survey and marriage market information from the American Community Survey. Using the estimates of the model, we perform several comparative statics exercises. On top of being of interest in themselves, they provide an empirical assessment of the importance of taking into account the joint nature of the decision process in the two markets. We also plan to use the parameter estimates to perform a series of policy experiments comparing a labor income tax system based on individual taxation with a system based on joint taxation. JEL Codes: D13,J12,J64 ∗ Sergio Ocampo and Mauricio Salazar Saenz provided excellent research assistantship. Partial funding from the Inter-American Development Bank (IDB) ESW grant RG-K1415 is gratefully acknowledged. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the IDB. 1 1 Introduction Labor and marriage market decisions are strongly interrelated. If individuals are engaged in a stable relationship, labor market decisions are among the most important choices affecting overall household welfare, and therefore are not taken in isolation but at the household level. If individuals are not yet engaged in a stable relationship, marriage market decisions and opportunities are strongly influenced by the individual’s current and expected labor market position. The literature often recognizes the joint nature of these decision processes, but usually focuses only on one side of the decisions tree. With respect to the impact of the marriage market on labor market decisions, there now exist a number of estimated models of household search1 that are able to examine the impact of one spouse’s labor market status on the other spouse’s current and future labor market choices. However, these contributions ignore the process leading to the formation of the household and frequently lack intrahousehold behavior, since they typically impose the existence of a household utility function.2 With respect to the impact of the labor market on marriage market decisions, there exists a huge literature in economics, demography and population studies focusing on how an individual’s current labor market state and future labor market performance may impact outcomes in the marriage market. However, most of these contributions ignore dynamic considerations and all of them consider labor market characteristics as a fixed individual-level characteristic. In other words, these contributions ignore the fact that the individual’s current labor market state may endogenously change as a result of marriage market decisions.3 Our analysis utilizes an innovative methodological framework designed to determine the joint equilibrium distribution of labor market outcomes and marriage market statuses. 1 See Dey and Flinn (2008); Gemici (2011); and Flabbi and Mabli (2012). Guler, Guvenen and Violante (2012) do not estimate the household search model but provide an exhaustive theoretical discussion. 2 The notable exception is Gemici (2011) which includes some intrahousehold behavior and endogenous marriage choices. However, intrahousehold behavior is mainly limited to the impact on the geographical location decisions of the household and the marriage decisions are derived without imposing equilibrium conditions on the marriage market. 3 Recent examples include DelBoca and Flinn (2014) which looks at married people but recognize that marital sorting is influenced by labor market variables. However, these labor market variables are state variables that cannot change as a result of the marriage. This is also the case in Chade and Ventura (2005) which allows for endogenous household formation and dissolution (but not for wage dispersion.) There also exists a rich literature on marriage sorting processes which exploits equilibrium conditions in the marriage market (Pollack (1990); Dagsvik (2000); Choo and Siow (2006); and Choo (2015).) This setting studies sorting over individual level characteristics which in principle may include labor market outcomes but they are instead limited to demographic characteristics. Finally, the search and matching literature with two-sided heterogeneity has been applied to study sorting in the marriage market (see for example Shimer and Smith (2000)). Wong (2003) is an application estimating the model with the inclusion of labor market variables (wages). However, wages are just one component of a single index describing individual heterogeneity and they are permanent components, not allowed to change as a result of marriage market dynamic. 2 Informed by the importance of human capital investments in both the marriage and labor market, we also introduce an endogenous schooling choice which takes place before entering both markets. Exploiting a number of simplifying assumptions, we are able to estimate the model using cross-sectional wage distributions, unemployment durations, and transitions across marriage market statuses taken from readily available and nationally representative data sources. As a result, we can empirically assess the importance of taking into account the joint nature of the decision process in the two markets and the cost of ignoring it when using models for policy evaluation purposes. We assume individuals begin adult life by making a schooling decision. After schooling is completed, individuals enter the marriage and labor market, jointly searching (in continuous time) in both. Each market is characterized by frictions and by match-specific shocks. Household interaction is assumed to be non-cooperative with each spouse making job choices solely along the extensive margin, i.e., they decide to accept or reject an offer if receiving one themselves and they decide to stay or quit their current job when their spouse’s employment state changes. We solve the potential equilibrium multiplicity that may arise in such a dual searcher setting by assuming that the spouse who is receiving the offer is the first-mover, while the other spouse acts as a follower. A few recent contributions introduce elements of interactions between the marriage and labor markets. Jacquemet and Robin (2013) model endogenous household formation, allowing for wage dispersion and a labor supply decision. However, only the labor supply decision is endogenous and allowed to change with marriage market outcomes, while wages are treated as a permanent individual-specific component. Greenwood, Guner, Kocharkov and Santos (2015) develop a similar setting, adding, like us, an endogenous education decision. However, the interaction with the labor market is even more limited than in Jacquemet and Robin (2013), since only women are allowed to endogenously adjust labor supply. Finally, Chiappori, Dias and Meghir (2015) allow for the same three choices we consider in our model: schooling, marriage, and jobs. However, the interactions between the labor and marriage market choices is more limited than in our case, since the marriage decision is irrevocable and taken before entering the labor market. On the other hand, labor market dynamics are allowed to possess a life-cycle pattern. These patterns are essentially ruled out within our stationary setting. After developing the model, we estimate it by the Method of Simulated Moments (MSM) using labor market information from the Current Population Survey (CPS) and marriage market information from the American Community Survey (ACS), under the assumption that a monthly CPS sample is a point sample from the steady state distribution. With no on-the-job search in the labor market and no on-the-marriage search in the marriage market, identifying the transition rate parameters associated with the labor and marriage markets is reasonably straightforward, as are the wage offer distributions under parametric (log normal) assumptions. The identification of the distribution of marriage match values is more problematic, but it is solved by exploiting the rich combination of “types”of couples arising in equilibrium. Types are described by combinations of school3 ing levels, labor market states, and wage levels when an individual is employed. Finally, the distribution of schooling costs is the one on which we observe the least amount of information and as a result we assume the distribution to be known up to one parameter. Using the estimates of the model, we perform several comparative statics exercises. In addition to being of direct interest in themselves, these exercises provide an empirical assessment of the importance of taking into account the joint nature of the decision process in the two markets. First, we explore the impact of changes in the labor market structure on the joint equilibrium distribution of both markets. We analyze two changes: reducing labor market frictions and eliminating gender differences in the wage offer distributions. Second, we plan to estimate lifetime returns to schooling, showing the importance of both markets in determining the final equilibrium outcomes. Some exercises will show how ignoring one of the two markets, or ignoring the interaction between them, may impact the estimated returns. Finally, we plan to assess the impact of changes in the marriage market structure, such as recent demographic changes, on the joint equilibrium distribution of both markets and on overall welfare. As a final contribution, we plan to use the parameter estimates to perform a series of policy experiments comparing a labor income tax system based on individual taxation with a system based on joint taxation. Specifically, we will set a tax revenue objective, impose alternative taxation schemes, and obtain the tax schedule necessary to satisfy the tax revenue target under the two regimes. We will then obtain the joint equilibrium distribution of schooling levels, labor market outcomes, and marriage market statuses under the two regimes and compare their associate lifetime welfare levels. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the model and section 3 the data. Section 4 describes identification and econometric issues. Section 5 contains the preliminary estimation results and section 6 the preliminary experiments results. No policy section is included at the moment. Section 7 concludes. 2 Model 2.1 Environment Individuals begin adult life by making a schooling decision, which involves a comparison of the values of entering the labor and marriage markets with schooling type s ∈ {L, H}, denoting a low and high schooling level. The benefit of acquiring schooling is the access to a schooling-specific labor market which is completely segregated from the labor market of the other schooling level. The access to a schooling-specific labor market also has an impact on marriage market opportunities. The cost of acquiring the high schooling level is heterogeneous in the population and it is gender-specific. We denote gender with g ∈ {f, m} and the cost of schooling with q ∼ Q(q|g). After schooling is completed4 , individuals enter the marriage market and the labor 4 The timing implies that we ignore any time cost involved in the acquisition of schooling and any marriage 4 market. Each market is characterized by frictions and by match-specific shocks. In the labor market, we denote the Poisson rate of arrival of job offers with λ (g, s) . A job offer is fully characterized by a wage w ∼ F (w|g, s) . If a job is accepted and a match realized, it is terminated by an exogenous shock η (g, s) . A job-match may also be endogenously terminated as a result of changes in the marital status or a as a result of changes in the labor market status of the other spouse. There is no on-the-job search in the current version of the model. Marriage markets are also characterized by frictions and offers arrive following a Poisson process. Any member of one gender, no matter the education group, may meet and marry a member of the other gender, no matter the education group. However, the probability of meeting between and within schooling groups are allowed to be different and to be governed by a CRS matching function Γ [S (g, s) , S (g 0 , s0 )] where S (g, s) denotes the measure of single of gender g and schooling level s in the economy and the superscript 0 denotes the other spouse variables. As a result, the Poisson arrival rate of a marriage opportunity to an individual of gender g and schooling s with an individual of the opposite gender5 and schooling s0 is: Γ [S (g, s) , S (g 0 , s0 )] λM g, s, s0 = (1) S (g, s) A marriage offer is characterized by the gender, education level and labor market status of each of the two spouses and by a match-specific utility of marriage denoted by θ ∼ G (θ). One individual of each gender is necessary to create a married couple. Only single individuals are allowed to meet in the marriage market. Marriages can be terminated only by an exogenous process with rate ηM . Each single individual of gender g and educational level s has a utility function given by: u(l, c|g, s) = α (g) ln(l) + (1 − α (g)) ln(c) (2) where: c = wh (g, s) + y T = l + h (g, s) Consumption c is equal to the sum of labor income wh (g, s) and nonlabor income y. Time T is allocated between leisure l and work but there is not intensive margin decision on labor supply: h (g, s) is the gender and school-specific amount of hours required by each job contract and individuals cannot choose it. An unemployed agent sets l = T , where T is the upper bound on time available for leisure and work at any moment in time. market or labor market activities happening during the schooling completion process. The schooling decision is fixed after entering the labor and marriage markets. 5 Driven by data availability, we impose that marriage only happens between individuals of opposite sex. 5 Each married individual of gender g and educational level s married with an individual of gender g 0 and educational level s0 has utility function given by: u(l, c, θ|g, s, s0 ) = α (g) ln(l) + (1 − α (g)) ln(c) + θ (3) where: c = wh (g, s) + w0 h g 0 , s0 + y + y 0 T = l + h (g, s) Consumption c is a public good and it is equal to the sum of both spouses labor and nonlabor incomes. θ is another public good and by the utility of staying together. Time T is allocated between the private good, leisure l and work, under the constraint mention above that h (g, s) is not a choice variable but a job requirement. For the case in which a spouse s is unemployed, then w = 0, and the same is true for spouse s0 . Household interaction is assumed to be non-cooperative. Each spouse decides to accept or reject a job offer and whether to keep or quit their current job. The spouse who is receiving the offer is the first-mover, while the other spouse acts as a follower. This timing convention solves the equilibrium multiplicity that may arise in the dual-searcher setting we are analyzing. It may be justified by assuming that the spouse receiving the offer may restrain from informing the other agent about the job offer unless it is optimal to do so.6 We assume that agents live forever and they they face a common instantaneous discount rate, ρ. 2.2 Value Functions The value function for an agent of gender g and schooling s, employed at wage w and married to an agent with schooling s0 employed at wage w0 and enjoying a marriage flow value of θ is: ρ + η (g, s) + η g 0 , s0 + ηM V w, w0 , θ|g, s, s0 = u(l, c, θ|g, s, s0 ) (4) 0 0 0 0 +η (g, s) V 0, wR w , 0|g , s , s , θ|g, s, s +η g 0 , s0 max V w, 0, θ|g, s, s0 , V 0, 0, θ|g, s, s0 +ηM max {V (w|g, s) , V (0|g, s)} The value function is conditioned on the gender of the agent, their schooling, and the schooling of the spouse, and it is function of wage of the agent (a wage of zero denotes unemployment), the wage of the spouse, and marriage match-value. Given the state, three shocks may hit the agent: an exogenous termination of her job at a rate η (g, s); an 6 When two single employed agent meet and decide to marry, it is not clear who should be considered and who should be considered the follower conditioning on the criteria just described. In this case, we randomize assuring a 50% chance to each gender. 6 exogenous termination of her spouse’s job at a rate η (g 0 , s0 ); and exogenous termination of the marriage at a rate ηM . Notice that each spouse reacts optimally to a shock to the other spouse’s labor market status, following the household interaction process described above. We denote the optimal reaction (quitting or not quitting the current job) with the function wR . For example wR (w0 , 0, θ|g 0 , s0 , s) in equation (4) assumes either value w0 if the spouse keeps the current job after the agent has been exogenously terminated or value 0 if the spouse quits the current job as a result of the agent’s change in labor market status. The agent also reacts optimally to exogenous divorce, deciding whether to stay in the current job or to quit in order to look for a better job offer. Notice we have introduced the notation for value functions of single agents: they are just a function of the agent’s labor market state. The value function for an agent of gender g and schooling s, unemployed and married to an agent with schooling s0 , working at job w0 and enjoying a marriage flow value of θ is: ρ + λ (g, s) + η g 0 , s0 + ηM V 0, w0 , θ|g, s, s0 = u(T, c, θ|g, s, s0 ) (5) Z +λ (g, s) max V w, wR w0 , w, θ|g 0 , s0 , s , θ|g, s, s0 , V 0, w0 , θ|g, s, s0 dF (w|g, s) +η g 0 , s0 V 0, 0, θ|g, s, s0 +ηM V (0|g, s) Given the state, three shocks may hit the agent: a job offer at a rate λ (g, s), an exogenous termination of her spouse’s job at a rate η (g 0 , s0 ), and an exogenous termination of the marriage at a rate ηM . When the spouse’s job is terminated, no endogenous reaction follows since agents are not allowed to divorce as a result of a change in labor market status. When the agent receives a job offer, she will decide to accept or reject the job by maximizing over the alternative value functions, anticipating the spouse’s optimal reaction. As before, we denote the spouse’s optimal reaction with wR . If the marriage is terminated, no additional actions are available. The value function for an agent of gender g and schooling s, employed at wage w and married to an agent with schooling s0 , searching for a job, and enjoying a marriage flow value of θ is: ρ + η (g, s) + λ g 0 , s0 + ηM V w, 0, θ|g, s, s0 = u(l, c, θ|g, s, s0 ) (6) 0 +η (g, s) V 0, 0, θ|g, s, s Z +λ g 0 , s0 V wR w, w0 , θ|g, s, s0 , w0 , θ|g, s, s0 dF w0 |g 0 , s0 A0 (w|g,s,s0 ) +ηM max {V (w|g, s) , V (0|g, s)} where: A0 w|g, s, s0 = w0 : V w0 , wR w, w0 , θ|g, s, s0 , θ|g, s, s0 > V 0, w, θ|g 0 , s0 , s 7 Given the state, three shocks may hit the agent: exogenous job termination at a rate η (g, s), a job offer to her spouse at a rate λ (g 0 , s0 ), and exogenous termination of the marriage at a rate ηM . When the job is terminated, no endogenous reaction follows since agents are not allowed to divorce as a result of a change in labor market status. When the spouse receives a job offer, she will decide whether to accept the job. If he accepts, the agent in question will react optimally, as denoted by the reaction function wR . But not all the job offers are acceptable to the spouse and in general the acceptance region depends on the agent’s labor market state and type. We denote by A0 (w) the support of the job offers distribution which is acceptable to the spouse given the agent’s job (w, h) . If the marriage is terminated, the agent decides whether to continue employment at their current job or to quit into unemployment so as to look for a better job. The value function for an unemployed agent of gender g and schooling s, married to an unemployed agent with schooling s0 , and enjoying a marriage flow value of θ is: ρ + λ (g, s) + λ g 0 , s0 + ηM V 0, 0, θ|g, s, s0 = u(T, c, θ|g, s, s0 ) (7) Z +λ (g, s) max V w, 0, θ|g, s, s0 , V 0, 0, θ|g, s, s0 dF (w|g, s) Z 0 0 +λ g , s V 0, w0 , θ|g, s, s0 dF w0 |g 0 , s0 A0 (0|g,s,s0 ) +ηM V (0|g, s) Given the state, three shocks may hit the agent: an exogenous job offer at a rate λ (g, s), a job offer to the spouse at a rate λ (g 0 , s0 ), and exogenous termination of the marriage at a rate ηM . When the agent receives the offer, she is the first mover and decides whether to accept the offer. When the spouse receives the offer, the spouse decides whether to accept the offer. In both cases, the other spouse has no ability to respond. If the marriage is terminated, the agent is back to the single unemployed state. The value function for an unemployed single agent of gender g and schooling s is: [ρ + λ (g, s) + λM (g, s, L) + λM (g, s, H)] V (0|g, s) = u(T, c|g, s) Z +λ (g, s) max {V (w|g, s) , V (0|g, s)} dF (w|g, s) X + λM g, s, s0 × s0 ∈{L,H} U (g 0 , s0 ) max {V (0, 0, θ|g, s, s0 ) , V (0|g, s)} dG (θ) + 0 0 B(0,0|g R R ,s ,s) 0 0 max {V (0, wR (w0 , 0, θ|g 0 , s0 , s) , θ|g, s, s0 ) , V (0|g, s)} E (g , s ) 0 0 0 0 0 C(g ,s ) B(w ,0|g ,s ,s) 0 0 0 0 0 0 dG (θ) dF (w |g , s , w ∈ C (g , s )) R 8 (8) where: B w, w0 |g, s, s0 ≡ θ : V wR w, w0 , θ|g, s, s0 , wR w0 , w, θ|g 0 , s0 , s , θ|g, s, s0 > V (w|g, s) C (g, s) ≡ {w : V (w|g, s) > V (0|g, s)} Given the state, two shocks may hit the agent: a job offer at a rate λ (g, s) and a marriage offer at a rate λM (g, s, L) if coming from a low schooling-level individual or at a rate λM (g, s, H) if coming from a high schooling-level individual. Given the schooling level, the potential spouse can be unemployed or employed: we denote the endogenous measures of these two sets in equilibrium with U (g 0 , s0 ) and E (g 0 , s0 ) . The set of employed singles is drawn only from the accepted wage distribution of this type, which has support C (g 0 , s0 ). The set B (w, w0 |g, s, s0 ) takes into account the fact that marriage is consensual and the current agent can decide about marrying a potential spouse only if the potential spouse also agrees to marry. The value function for a single agent of gender g and schooling s, employed at wage w is: [ρ + η (g, s) + λM (g, s, L) + λM (g, s, H)] V (w|g, s) = u(l, c|g, s) (9) +η (g, s) V (0|g, s) X + λM g, s, s0 × s0 ∈{L,H} U (g 0 , s0 ) max {V (wR (w, 0, θ|g, s, s0 ) , 0, θ|g, s, s0 ) , V (w|g, s)} dG (θ) + 0 0 B(0,w|g R R ,s ,s) 0 0 E (g , s ) max {V (wR (w, w0 , θ|g, s, s0 ) , wR (w0 , w, θ|g 0 , s0 , s) , θ|g, s, s0 ) , V (w|g, s)} C(g 0 ,s0 ) B(w0 ,w|g 0 ,s0 ,s) 0 0 0 0 0 0 dG (θ) dF (w |g , s , w ∈ C (g , s )) R Given the state, two shocks may hit the agent: an exogenous job termination at a rate η (g, s) and a marriage offer at a rate λM (g, s, L) if coming from a low schooling-level individual or at a rate λM (g, s, H) if coming from a high schooling-level individual. As before, meeting in the marriage market may be with singles of any schooling level who can be employed or unemployed. And as before, each agent reacts optimally with respect to her labor market decision when considering marriage. However, now there is the possibility that two single employed agents meet in the marriage market, generating an ambiguity about which one of the two is the leader in the game. In the notation, above we are assuming that the agent for whom we are writing the value function is the leader. In simulation and estimation, we randomize which one of the two agents is the leader when meetings of two employed singles occur. 9 2.3 2.3.1 Equilibrium Definition The optimal decision rules have a reservation value property. In the labor market the reservation value is defined over the wage w; in the marriage market over the marriage match value θ; and the schooling reservation value is defined with respect to the schooling cost q. First, we look at labor market decisions. When single, decision rules are identical to a standard single agent search model and the reservation wage above which offers are accepted is defined as: w∗ (g, s) : V (w∗ |g, s) = V (0|g, s) (10) When married, labor market decision rules also depend on the labor market status of the spouse, due to the nonlinearity of the utility function.7 As a result, the reservation wage of an individual with schooling s, married to a spouse with schooling s0 and labor market status characterized by w08 , in a marriage generating a match value θ is given by: w∗ w0 , θ|g, s, s0 : (11) ∗ 0 ∗ 0 0 0 0 V w , wR w , w , θ|g , s , s , θ|g, s = V 0, w , θ|g, s, s Next, we consider marriage market decisions. Again, given the assumptions on the utility function, the two markets are interdependent and the marriage market decision depends on the labor market status of both the agent and the potential spouse. The reservation match value for the marriage to occur (from this agent’s perspective) is: (12) θ∗ w, w0 |g, s, s0 : ∗ 0 ∗ 0 0 0 ∗ 0 V wR w, w , θ |g, s, s , wR w , w, θ |g , s , s , θ |g, s = V (w|g, s) Finally, we look at schooling decisions. Schooling decisions have a different timing than labor market and marriage market decisions because they are taken before entering the two markets. Once a schooling decision is made, it cannot be changed and the individual enters simultanously the marriage and labor market as a single unemployed agent of schooling level s. As a result, the reservation cost of acquiring the high level of schooling H is given by: q ∗ (g) : (13) ∗ V (0|g, H) − q = V (0|g, L) where individuals with cost less than or equal to q ∗ (g) acquire schooling level H. We can now propose the following: 7 See Dey and Flinn (2008). A systematic treatment of the issue is also provided by Guler, Guvenen and Violante (2012), while Flabbi and Mabli (2012) exploit the result in estimation. 8 Recall that w0 > 0 defines employement and w0 = 0 defines unemployment. 10 Definition 1 Given g ∈ {f, m}, s ∈ {L, H}, s0 ∈ {L, H} and: α (g) λM (g, s, s0 ) λ (g, s) ρ ηM η (g, s) , , Q(q|g) , h(g, s) G(θ) F (w|g, s) an equilibrium is a set of values V ., ., θ|g, s, s0 , V (.|g, s) that solves equations (4)-(9) under the optimal decisions rules characterized by equations (10)-(13). 2.3.2 Computational Method A closed form solution for the value function characterized in Definition 1 is not available and therefore we use simulation methods to solve for an equilibrium at given parameter values. The model is solved by evaluating the value functions in a discretized grid of wages and marriage match-specific values, given the set of parameter values and the model’s steady state equilibrium conditions. The model’s steady state equilibrium conditions are particularly challenging in our context since the equilibrium distribution of singles is endogenous and it is necessary to compute the value functions. Notice that we have to keep track not only of the proportion of singles but also of their equilibrium distribution over labor market states (including over accepted wages while employed) and schooling levels since the labor market state and schooling level of single agents has an impact on marriage market decisions. The procedure works as follow. Given a set of parameters and a guess of the relevant steady state equilibrium distribution, a first set of value functions is found by solving the fixed point problem. The fixed point problem is over a quite a high-dimensional vector of values since we have to jointly iterate over value functions in the marriage market and the labor market for each value of the discretized wage and value of marriage grids, and for each gender and education level. The fixed point over the value functions for given steady state equilibrium distribution constitutes the “inner loop” of our simulation procedure. Given the value functions, we can obtain an updated value of the steady state equilibrium distribution that can be compared with the starting distribution and, in case of lack of convergence, can be used to find a new set of value functions. The computation of the steady state equilibrium distribution for given value function constitutes the “outer loop” of our simulation procedure. The process is iterated until convergence is reached using usual tolerance criteria. Given this general structure, additional details of the simulation procedure need to be solved. First, we have to decide whether to jointly simulate both sides of the marriage 11 market or whether to directly utilize the steady state distributions. In order to reduce the computational burden, we chose the second alternative. As a result, when a marriage offer is received by a given individual of gender g, a potential spouse is drawn from the steady state distribution of single agents of gender g 0 . Second, our leader-follower approach cannot solve the issue of two single employed agents meeting in the marriage market. In this particular case, we choose the randomization implemented by some previous papers in this literature: when the agent is single-employed and another single-employed agent is drawn as a potential spouse, the leader of the marriage game is chosen randomly assigning a 0.5 probablity to each agent to be the leader. Third, the simulation is done agent by agent, storing each agent’s state. The state of an agent is determined by her schooling level, wage and marriage status. If the agent is married, the spouse’s schooling level and wage and the couple’s match-specific marriage utility are also stored. Mirroring the data we will use in estimation, we store each agent’s state every three months. Finally, the steady state used in the “outer loop” is computed using the final 30% of the total number of periods simulated. A total of 5,000 agents of each type (gender-schooling) are simulated for 540 months. 2.3.3 Discussion A graphical representation of the equilibrium outcomes both in the marriage and in the labor market is reported in Figures 1 through 3. We first focus on labor market decisions. When an agent is single and unemployed, or in a couple with both spouses unemployed, the employment decision is characterized by the usual reservation wage policy rule. When an unemployed agent is married to an employed agent, the employment decision is more complex since it depends on the wage and schooling level of the spouse. In this situation, when the unemployed spouse receives an offer, three outcomes are possible: the agent can reject the job offer, the agent can accept his job offer and the spouse quit her current job, or the agent can accept his job offer and the spouse keep her current job. Figure 1 shows the solution to this game: the wife is employed at one of the wages reported on the x-axis and the husband is receiving a job at one of the wages reported on the y-axis. Each panel represents one of the possible schooling combinations. The darkest area at the bottom of each panel shows the region in which the offer is rejected; the most lightly-shaded region is where both agents keep their jobs; the remaining middle gray area to the left of each panel shows the region where the agent accepts the offer and the spouse quits her job. As expected, this area corresponds to a combination of relatively low spouse’s wages and relatively high wage offers. Similarly, the darkest area corresponds to combinations of low wage offers and high spouse wages. Only when the husband receives a relatively high wage offer and the wife is already employed at a job paying a relatively high wage, will they both be employed in equilibrium. Next, we look at marriage market decisions. When two unemployed agents meet, the 12 marriage decision depends only on the match draw θ and, for a given schooling level combination, there will exist a unique reservation θ∗ above which the agents decide to marry. The marriage decision when two employed agents meet is more complicated because each θ draw is defining an acceptance region over the space of the couples’ accepted wages. Figure 2 represents such region for a given θ value. The equilibrium is characterized by four regions: the darkest area (with wages below the reservation values and therefore never active) indicates non-marriage; the lightest area indicates marriage with both agents keeping their current job; the second darkest (next to the vertical axis) indicates marriage and quitting of the current job by the man; and the second lightest (next to the horizontal axis) indicates marriage and quitting by the woman. Note that, similarly to what happened in Figure 1, quitting is induced when one wage is relatively low when compared to the other. As a result, we observe married couples with both agents employed only when they both have relatively high wages. Figure 3 displays the joint distributions of wages for a married couple where both spouses are employed, conditioning on the four schooling levels combinations. The joint distributions show the assortative mating in wage levels implied by the equilibrium behavior we have shown in Figure 1 and 2. Figure 3 also shows how both markets, combined with the spouses’ schooling levels, have a genuinely joint impact on the four equilibrium distributions. 3 Data We use the Current Population Survey (CPS) to extract moments referring to: proportion across labor market states, unemployment durations, means and standard deviations of accepted wages, and correlations between spouses accepted wages. We use the American Community Survey (ACS) to extract moments referring to proportions of the population in the various marriage market states and transitions between marriage market states over time. All the moments are computed by gender and schooling level. We impose the following restrictions on the sample: • Age: 25-49; • Education: – High level of schooling: College completion or more; – Low level of schooling: Associate degree, some college, HS completed or less; • Race: White; • Year: 2007. 13 The states in the two markets are defined as follows. Married individuals are individuals who declare that they are currently married. We classify all the individuals who are not married as single, including those cohabiting. Employed individuals are individuals currently working. All the other individuals are considered searching in the labor market, even if they declare to be out of the labor force. 4 Econometric Issues The identification of the model requires a set of additional functional form assumptions. As shown by Flinn and Heckman (1982), we need to assume recoverable wage offer distributions if we want to identify them from accepted wages information. We assume the wage offers distributions to be lognormal with gender- and schooling-specific parameters µ (g, s) and σ (g, s). The marriage match-specific value θ is unobservable but the equilibrium shows it has an impact on the “type” of marriage that is realized,9 where type is defined by the labor market state and schooling level of the spouses. We assume a normal distribution with parameters µθ and σθ . The cost of acquiring the high schooling level with respect to the low schooling level has only an impact on the schooling level acquired before entering the marriage and labor market. This simple threshold-crossing impact forces us to assume a one-parameter distribution. We assume a negative exponential but with gender-specific parameters τ (g). Finally, we need to impose a functional form for the contact rate functions. Since we can observe gender and schooling specific transitions, we can identify marriage market meeting rates that are gender-specific and schooling-specific in both spouses’ schooling. As a result we can identify a two-parameter matching function which we will assume has the following frequently used Cobb-Douglas specification: 0 0 Γ S (g, s) , S g 0 , s0 = β s, s0 S (g, s)ν(s,s ) S (g, s)(1−ν(s,s )) (14) The estimation procedure involves three main steps. First, we fix the following parameters: Θ1 = {ρ, T, h (g, s)}g∈{f,m},s∈{L,H} (15) The discount rate is fixed to 5% a year, the time endowment to 80, and the job hours requirements to the mean of each specific gender-schooling group. Second, we use the Method of Simulated Moments (MSM) to estimate the following set of parameters: 0) λ (g, s) λ (g, s, s M η (g, s) ηM Θ2 = , , α (g) (16) µ (g, s) µθ σ (g, s) σθ g∈{f,m},s∈{L,H},s0 ∈{L,H} 9 See in particular Figure 2. 14 where the first column refers to labor market parameters, the second to marriage market parameters, and the third to the utility function parameter. Third, we recover the following set of parameters: Θ3 = τ (g) , β s, s0 , ν s, s0 g∈{f,m},s∈{L,H},s0 ∈{L,H} by solving identities (1) and by inverting the identity equating the observed proportion in the high schooling-level group with the equilibrium proportion implied by the model. 5 Preliminary Estimation Results Preliminary point estimates from the estimation procedure are presented in Table 2. The first row reports the estimate of the preference parameter α: the weight on leisure in the log-linear utility function we assume (see equations 2 and 3.) We estimate a value quite similar to previous existing work but, contrary to previous literature, we find it to be slightly higher for men than women. The second group of parameters describes the labor market structure for each gender and schooling level. The mobility parameters are estimated to be similar to previous empirical work using a comparable setting. The location and scale parameters of the lognormal wage offers distribution imply a gender differential in average wage offers of about 6% in the low schooling group and of about 4% in the high schooling group. The returns to acquiring a high level of schooling in terms of mean wages offers is about 39% for women and about 37% for men. Both results are derived by computing the average wage offers conditional on gender and schooling at our estimated parameters. Means and variances of wage offers for the four groups are reported in the top two rows of Table 3. The third group of parameters describes the marriage market structure for each gender and schooling level. The arrival rate of marriage offers λM follows the expected ranking, with offers more likely to arrive from individuals with the same schooling level. However, they are estimated to be extremely low, predicting that the average duration for receiving a marriage offer is about 26 years. We are currently working to improve the performance of the estimated model along this dimension. The location and scale parameters of the marriage match value distribution predict an expected value of about 0.307 (see Table 3.) Given that θ is additively separable in the flow utility where leisure and consumption enter in logs and since the estimated variance is fairly low, we can infer that the marriage match value plays a significant but not major role in the marriage decision for the average couple. Tables 4 to 6 present some measures of model fit. Table 4 reports a major labor market outcome: accepted wages. The fit is reasonable on the first moments for all groups but it is not on the standard deviations of the high schooling group, both in the male and female samples. We are currently working to improve the performance of the estimated model along this dimension. Table 5 reports the joint steady state proportions over labor market state, marriage market status, schooling level and gender. The average fit is good but 15 there is one particular feature we systematically over-estimate: the proportion of couples with one spouse working and the other spouse unemployed. This is another dimension we are currently working on to improve the fit. We suspect it may require some changes in our behavioral model. Finally, Table 6 presents fits over transitions between marriage and labor market states. We fit some moments quite well while others less so, even if we always manage to produce estimates of the right order of magnitude (a weak argument, we realize). 6 Preliminary Experimental Results In this preliminary version, we present just two comparative statics exercises. The first, reported in Table 7, looks at the impact of decreasing labor market frictions in the market for the high level of schooling. Since the value of participation in such a market is increasing (less frictions mean better labor market opportunities) we expect the proportion of individuals acquiring a college degree to increase. This is exactly what we observe in the two bottom rows of Table 7. When the arrival rate of offers double, the proportion of women acquiring the high level of schooling increases by about 18%, and the proportion of men increases by about 20%. We also observe a small increase in the proportion of married people. It results from the fact that more individuals have a high level of schooling (a desirable characteristics in the marriage market, too) and that those who do also have better labor market opportunities (because of the lower level of frictions). Even if limited in magnitude, this type of effect shows how even a minor change in the labor market structure gets transferred to marriage market outcomes. The second comparative statics exercise is reported in Table 8. The experiment consists in setting the female labor market structure (arrival and termination rates; wage offers at each schooling level) equal to the estimated male labor market structure. The motivation rests on the gender differential literature and it indicates how gender asymmetries in labor market structure impact gender differences in marriage rates and schooling rates. A first result concerns schooling decisions: women acquire less education than at baseline. This is due to the fact that low schooling labor market parameters for men are relatively better than those for women. A second result relates to labor market outcomes: the gender gap on them essentially disappears. Still, this is informative because it indicates that gender asymmetries in the marriage market do not negatively impact women’s labor market performance. Finally, the third result is directly informative about the joint decision process in the two markets. Despite a large change in women’s labor market parameters, the marriage rate barely changes, moving from 52.45% to 52.43%. 16 7 Conclusion The paper presents a tractable framework to analyze simultaneous search in the labor and marriage markets in the presence of endogenous schooling decisions. After developing the model, we propose an identification and estimation strategy of its structural parameters. We implement it using data from the Current Population Survey (CPS) to describe the labor market dynamic and from the American Community Survey (ACS) to describe the marriage market dynamic. Preliminary results generate reasonable point estimates and a good fit along numerous dimensions. However, we still consider them preliminary because they are not able to reproduce two data features we judge crucially important: variance of accepted wages for the high schooling groups and the proportion of married couples where one spouse works and the other is unemployed. We also provide a set of preliminary comparative statics exercises showing the magnitude of the interactions between the two markets. We plan to implement a larger set of comparative statics exercises in order to provide an empirical assessment of the importance of taking into account the joint nature of the decision process in the two markets. Finally, we plan to use the parameter estimates to perform a series of policy experiments comparing a labor income tax system based on individual taxation with a system based on joint taxation. 17 References Chade, H. and Ventura, G. (2005), ‘Income taxation and marital decisions’, Review of Economic Dynamics 8, 565–599. Chiappori, P.-A., Dias, M. C. and Meghir, C. (2015), The Marriage Market, Labor Supply and Education Choice, Working Paper 21004, National Bureau of Economic Research. Choo, E. (2015), ‘Dynamic marriage matching: an empirical framework.’, Econometrica 83(4), 1373–1423. Choo, E. and Siow, A. (2006), ‘Who marries whom and why’, Journal of Political Economy 114(1). Dagsvik, J. (2000), ‘Aggregation in matching markets.’, International Economic Review 41(27- 57). DelBoca, D. and Flinn, C. (2014), ‘Household behavior and the marriage market’, Journal of Economic Theory 150, 515–550. Dey, M. and Flinn, C. (2008), ‘Household Search and Health Insurance Coverage’, Journal of Econometrics 145, 43–63. Flabbi, L. and Mabli, J. (2012), ‘Household Search or Individual Search: Does it Matter? Evidence from Lifetime Inequality Estimates’, IZA Discussion Paper 6908. Gemici, A. (2011), ‘Family migration and labor market outcomes’, mimeo . Greenwood, J., Guner, N., Kocharkov, G. and Santos, C. (2015), ‘Technology and the changing family: A unified model of marriage, divorce, educational attainment, and married female labor-force participation’, AEJ: Macroeconomics p. Forthcoming. Guler, B., Guvenen, F. and Violante, G. (2012), ‘Joint-Search Theory: New Opportunities and New Frictions’, Journal of Monetary Economics 59(4), 352–369. Jacquemet, N. and Robin, J.-M. (2013), Assortative matching and search with labor supply and home production, CeMMAP working papers CWP07/13, Centre for Microdata Methods and Practice, Institute for Fiscal Studies. Pollack, R. (1990), ‘Two-sex demographic models’, Journal of Political Economy 98, 399– 420. Shimer, R. and Smith, L. (2000), ‘Assortative matching and search’, Econometrica 68(2), 343–369. Wong, L. Y. (2003), ‘Structural estimation of marriage models’, Journal of Labor Economics 21(3), pp. 699–727. 18 Table 1: Descriptive Statistics CPS Sample Gender: Education: Low Female High Tot Low Male High Tot 32.8 31.2 26.7 4.4 63.9 16.2 19.9 7.1 12.8 36.1 48.9 51.1 33.8 17.2 100.0 37.5 32.4 25.6 6.8 69.9 13.6 16.5 4.2 12.3 30.1 51.1 48.9 29.8 19.1 100.0 3.3 60.6 63.9 0.8 35.3 36.1 4.1 95.9 100.0 3.7 66.2 69.9 0.7 29.4 30.1 4.4 95.6 100.0 13.4 5.8 23.2 11.2 16.2 7.4 26.3 13.5 4.2 5.5 4.3 5.2 3.9 4.9 3.2 4.2 31,565 17,828 36,056 15,521 Marriage Market: Single Married with Low with High Total Labor Market: Unemployed Employed Total Wages: Mean SD U Durations: Mean SD N. Observations 19 49,393 51,577 Table 2: MSM Estimated Parameters Gender (g): Schooling (s): α (g) Female Low High Male Low High 0.167 0.174 λ (g, s) η (g, s) µ (g, s) σ (g, s) 0.320 0.022 2.445 0.423 0.370 0.015 2.980 0.309 0.352 0.020 2.483 0.468 0.446 0.019 3.009 0.337 λM (g, s, L0 ) λM (g, s, H 0 ) ηM µθ σθ 0.0031 0.0020 0.0021 0.0028 0.0031 0.0020 0.009 0.307 0.465 0.0020 0.0039 20 Table 3: Exogenous Heterogeneity implied by MSM Estimates Gender (g): Schooling (s): Female Low High Male Low High Wage Offers: E (w|g, s) V (w|g, s) 12.61 31.14 13.36 43.66 20.64 42.61 Marriage Match Values: E (θ) V (θ) Cost of Schooling: E (q|s) 233.9 21 21.45 55.18 0.307 0.217 299.4 Table 4: Model Fit: Accepted Wages Gender (g): Schooling (s): Female Low High Male Low High 15.18 16.50 23.55 25.69 16.52 18.45 24.26 27.25 5.26 5.19 6.22 6.18 6.63 6.75 6.81 7.02 13.40 14.12 23.16 23.87 16.18 19.12 26.34 30.12 5.83 6.01 11.16 11.25 7.41 7.91 13.51 13.82 Estimated: Mean Single Married SD Single Married Sample: Mean Single Married SD Single Married 22 Table 5: Model Fit: Steady State Proportions (%) Gender (g): Schooling (s): Low Female High Total Low Male High Total Estimated: Single: U E 30.1 3.0 27.1 16.9 0.9 16.0 46.9 3.9 43.1 34.3 2.8 31.5 13.8 0.7 13.1 48.1 3.5 44.7 Married: UU UE EU EE 29.3 0.4 5.6 2.9 20.6 23.7 0.2 1.8 5.2 16.6 53.1 0.5 7.3 8.0 37.2 31.0 0.3 5.9 3.2 21.5 20.9 0.2 1.9 3.9 14.8 51.9 0.5 7.9 7.2 36.3 Total 59.4 40.6 100.0 65.3 34.7 100.0 Single: U E 32.8 2.2 30.6 16.2 0.4 15.7 48.9 2.6 46.3 37.5 2.7 34.8 13.6 0.5 13.1 51.1 3.1 48.0 Married: UU UE EU EE 31.2 0.2 1.0 0.9 29.1 19.9 0.0 0.4 0.3 19.3 51.1 0.2 1.4 1.1 48.4 32.4 0.2 0.9 1.0 30.4 16.5 0.0 0.2 0.3 15.9 48.9 0.2 1.1 1.3 46.4 Total 63.9 36.1 100.0 69.9 30.1 100.0 Sample: 23 Table 6: Model Fit: Transitions (%) Single SL SH MLL Married MLH MHL Total MHH Estimated: Males: SL SH ML MH 91.1 0.0 6.8 0.0 0.0 85.9 0.0 4.5 5.5 0.0 55.2 0.1 3.3 0.0 37.9 0.0 0.0 6.9 0.0 46.6 0.0 7.2 0.0 48.8 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Females: SL SH ML MH 90.3 0.0 5.7 0.0 0.0 87.3 0.0 4.3 6.3 0.0 60.7 0.1 3.4 0.0 33.6 0.1 0.0 6.6 0.1 51.8 0.0 6.1 0.1 43.7 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Males: SL SH ML MH 95.3 0.0 3.8 0.0 0.0 92.3 0.0 2.1 3.3 0.0 73.7 0.0 1.3 0.0 22.5 0.0 0.0 1.6 0.0 24.4 0.0 6.1 0.0 73.4 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Females: SL SH ML MH 95.0 0.0 4.3 0.0 0.0 91.9 0.0 2.5 4.2 0.0 81.2 0.0 0.8 0.0 14.5 0.0 0.0 2.9 0.0 35.3 0.0 5.3 0.0 62.2 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Sample: 24 Table 7: Experiments: Reducing Labor Market Frictions for Schooling Level H Baseline Increase in λ (g, H) 10% 50% 100% Labor and Marriage Mkts. Proportions: Single U E 47.55 3.66 43.89 47.45 3.50 43.95 47.34 3.61 43.73 47.26 3.51 43.75 Married UU UE EU EE 52.45 0.49 7.62 7.62 36.72 52.55 0.53 7.53 7.53 36.96 52.66 0.50 7.76 7.76 36.63 52.74 0.45 7.89 7.89 36.50 37.27 31.31 40.99 34.75 43.91 37.55 Proportion H Schooling: Female Male 36.10 30.10 25 Table 8: Eliminating Gender Differences in Labor Market Structure Baseline Female Male Experiment Female Male Schooling: Proportion H 36.10 30.10 32.26 30.03 24.25 27.25 16.52 18.45 25.42 27.47 16.39 18.10 24.26 27.46 16.41 18.89 Labor and Marriage Markets: Wages: Single E (w|g, H, E) Married E (w|g, H, E) Single E (w|g, L, E) Married E (w|g, L, E) 23.55 25.69 15.18 16.50 Proportions: Single U E 47.55 3.66 43.89 47.57 3.55 44.02 Married UU UE EU EE 52.45 0.49 7.62 7.62 36.72 52.43 0.44 8.36 8.36 35.28 Note: The experiment consists in setting the female labor market structure (arrival and termination rates and wage offers) equal to the estimated male labor market structure. 26 Figure 1: Job Offer to Married UE couples - Husband leads Emp. Decision MUE−LL − T 1 Emp. Decision MUE−LH − T 1 100 2 80 80 60 60 Wage Wage 100 40 3 20 0 40 3 20 1 0 2 20 40 60 Wife Wage 80 0 100 1 0 20 Emp. Decision MUE−HL − T 1 2 80 80 60 60 40 3 20 0 20 40 60 Wife Wage 80 100 2 40 3 20 1 0 80 Emp. Decision MUE−HH − T 1 100 Wage Wage 100 40 60 Wife Wage 0 100 27 1 0 20 40 60 Wife Wage 80 100 Figure 2: Marriage Offer between two Employed - Husband leads M Lead LS−HS − T 3 100 80 80 Woman Wage Woman Wage M Lead LS−LS − T 3 100 60 40 20 0 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 Man Wage 80 0 100 0 20 100 80 80 60 40 20 0 80 100 80 100 M Lead HS−HS − T 3 100 Woman Wage Woman Wage M Lead HS−LS − T 3 40 60 Man Wage 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 Man Wage 80 0 100 28 0 20 40 60 Man Wage Figure 3: Joint Accepted Wages distribution - Married couple MEE LH MEE LL 6000 1000 4000 500 2000 0 0 0 0 0 50 wW 100 100 0 50 50 wW wM 50 100 MEE HL 1000 2000 500 0 0 0 0 wW 0 100 0 50 50 100 wM MEE HH 4000 50 100 wW wM 29 50 100 100 wM