THE POLITICS OF STRATEGIC BUDGETEERING Christina J. Schneider University of California, San Diego cjschneider@ucsd.edu Vera E. Troeger University of Warwick v.e.troeger@warwick.ac.uk Very preliminary draft, please do not circulate. Comments welcome. Abstract Governments want to be reelected but increasing fiscal transparency has imposed many challenges for them to pursue opportunistic fiscal policies. This paper demonstrates that governments can electioneer even when fiscal transparency is high. We argue that governments can use several strategies to increase public good provision before elections, and they choose the strategies that are most effective given the level of transparency. Whereas deficit spending is an effective strategy to artificially increase voters’ perceived welfare before elections when voters cannot observe these distortionary practices, increasing fiscal transparency makes these strategies more costly (conservative voters would punish the government). Consequently, when fiscal transparency is high governments resort to less visible strategies, such as the redistribution of budgetary resources from long-term efficient investment spending to short-term consumption spending. We test the predictions with data on the composition of government spending for 32 countries over up to 38 years and data on individual budget items for 17 OECD countries over 35 years. The preliminary findings suggest that governments indeed redistribute resources from long-term efficient investment to short-term public goods provision before elections especially if elections are contested. _______________________________ Notes: Equal authorship. For great comments and insights, we would like to thank Mark Hallerberg, Mark Kayser, Thomas Pluemper, Branislav Slantchev, XXX. The paper was presented at IPES (2014), NYU Abu Dhabi (2014), Princeton-Warwick Political Economy workshop in Venice (2014). We thank all the participants for their helpful comments and suggestions. We gratefully acknowledge financial support of the German Research Foundation. 1 INTRODUCTION Politicians prefer winning elections to losing them. For this very reason, governments in democratic countries have strong incentives to implement policies that maximize their political support in the short run even at the expense of long-term costs. One strategy to improve the likelihood to get reelected is by distorting fiscal policy. A political budget cycle occurs when incumbents increase the provision of (usually highly visible) public goods before the election, financed either through higher deficits or increased taxes in the long run.1 At the same time, voters are fiscal conservatives. They prefer governments who improve their economic welfare without imposing extensive debts or increase the tax burden in the long run (Peltzman 1992; Alesina et al. 1998; Arvate et al. 2009; Brender and Drazen 2008; Drazen and Eslava 2010). The ability of voters to punish politicians for opportunistic fiscal policies crucially depends on the availability of information about politicians’ fiscal policies. Institutions, which improve fiscal transparency, provide this information to voters and serve to impede governments from creating a political budget cycle (Alt and Lassen 2006; Shi and Svensson 2006; Klomp and de Haan 2013; Vicente et al. 2013). This has led many scholars to argue and show that political budget cycles are unlikely to occur in developed democracies, and restricted to new democracies or developing countries in general (Brender and Drazen 2005; Drazen and Eslava 2009). Have these reforms eliminated the ability of governments in developed democratic countries to pursue opportunistic fiscal policies before elections? We argue that this conclusion is too optimistic. When governments manipulate fiscal policies before elections, they have several instruments at their disposal. They can raise deficits or taxes to provide more public goods before elections, but they can also change the composition of the budget strategically to achieve the same goal. Compositional spending occurs governments shift resources from investment spending, which is efficient to generate economic welfare in the long run, to consumption spending, which improves political support in the short run. This allows governments to boost spending on electorally relevant items, without having to increase the domestic deficit. Whereas deficit spending is more easily detected in fiscally transparent systems, compositional spending is more difficult to observe and governments can rely on this strategy when deficit spending is not feasible anymore. Our theory of strategic budgeteering analyses incentives and opportunities to make use of these different strategies, and thereby produces a number of empirical implications about the conditions under which governments rely on one or the other fiscal strategy opportunistically before elections. We test our theory using two different data sets. First we look at compositional government spending where spending is either consumption or investment to distinguish between long term efficient spending and short term public good provisions. As alternatives to compositional spending we also consider deficits, tax revenues and monetary instruments in 32 countries over a period of up to 38 years. The second set of analyses uses data on individual budget items that can be either predominantly consumptive or long-term efficient investment. This data is available for 17 OECD countries and 35 years. Evidence for redistribution of resources from investment to consumption before elections if fiscal transparency is high should be detectable in both empirical investigations. Our findings provide interesting insights into the existing literature. First, whereas previous approaches have analyzed individual fiscal strategies in preelection periods, such as deficit 1 Alternatively, governments could use monetary policy to create political business cycles. See Franzese (2002) for an excellent overview of these approaches. 2 spending or compositional spending, separately (Schuhknecht 2000; Block 2002; Alt and Lassen 2006a,b; Veiga and Veiga 2007; Schneider 2010; Katsimi and Sarantides 2012), we use the insights of these analyses to develop an integrated theory of strategic budgeteering. Importantly, the theory sheds light on how governments choose between alternative fiscal instruments in the pre-election period. To the best of our knowledge, we provide the first empirical analysis that analyses these different fiscal strategies in a common theoretical framework, thereby showing how fiscal transparency affects the governments choice of different fiscal instruments. Second, recent work on political budget cycles has focused on analyzing developing countries and new democracies because it was assumed that budget cycles can only exist in these countries (Block 2002; Shi and Svensson 2006; Drazen and Eslava 2009; Saporiti and Streb 2008; Vergne 2009). Our results support the underlying notion that voters are fiscally conservatives who would punish incumbents for pursuing costly fiscal strategies before elections. At the same time, we show that budget cycles in developed democracies are likely, and exist. Incumbents in industrialized countries just use different fiscal strategies to achieve electoral gains. The result is important because it demonstrates that governments can substitute fiscal strategies when particular strategies are not available to them. Finally, most of the recent efforts to analyze compositional spending focus on local elections (Khemani 2004; Veiga and Veiga 2007; Drazen and Eslava 2009; Schneider 2010; Vicente et al. 2013). In contrast, our paper analyses compositional spending on the national level in a sample of 19 developed democracies.2 A VERY SHORT HISTORY OF STRATEGIC ELECTIONEERING It is common wisdom that governing parties have a significantly higher chance to win elections during periods of economic booms. This simple logic provides incumbents with ample incentives to stimulate the economy shortly before elections even at the expense of the long-term detrimental effect. If governments act purely opportunistic and if voters consider current conditions more than previous conditions, then the incumbent is tempted to use all available policy instruments to create a business cycle hike before elections at the cost of worsening economic conditions shortly after the elections (Wright 1974, Tufte 1978, Frey and Schneider 1978a,b, Golden and Poterba 1980, Schultz 1995, Price 1998).3 Initially, scholars applied the logic of the Philips curve (which constitutes an inverse relationship between inflation and unemployment) to provide an opportunistic explanation of political business cycles (e.g., Nordhaus 1975; Tufte 1978).4 In these models, the electorate votes retrospectively and governments expand monetary policies to lower unemployment before elections. Later approaches abolish the assumption that expectations about the inflation are adaptive and treat voter expectations as rational and anticipatory (Alesina 1987, 1988; Rogoff and Sibert 1988; Persson and Tabellini 1990). Governments cannot simply generate political business cycles because voters (who anticipate that lower unemployment before the election will lead to higher inflation after the election) adjust their behavior. Consequently, incumbents are attracted 2 3 4 The article by Katsimi and Sarantides (2012) is one exception where the authors analyze budget composition in high-income OECD countries. This idea can be traced back at least to Schumpeter (1939), Kalecki (1943), Nordhaus (1975), Hibbs (1977, 1978) and Tufte (1978). Governments can still generate business cycles (in the short term) if one assumes a NAIRU-augmented (nonaccelerating inflationary rate of unemployment) version of the ‘Philipps curve’. 3 to expansionary monetary policies only if they can signal economic competence to the electorate (Persson and Tabellini 1990). The relevance of monetary business cycles has declined because – in the course of international economic and financial integration and the emergence of independent central banks – few governments still autonomously command monetary policy instruments (Obstfeld and Rogoff 1996; Lohmann 1992, 1997; Jonsson 1995; Simmons 1996; Boix 1998, 2000; Clark et al. 1998; Garrett 1998; Franzese 1999, 2003; Oately 1999; Clark and Hallerberg 2000; Way 2000; Bernhard et al. 2002; Broz 2002; Clark 2002a; Broz and Frieden 2001). With the declining relevance of monetary political business cycles, scholars started to focus on fiscal political business cycles (also called political budget cycle). The theory of the political budget cycle is based on the premise of rational and forward-looking voter. Voters prefer candidates who are able to provide more public goods for given levels of taxation and private consumption (e.g. Rogoff and Sibert 1988; Rogoff 1990; Shi and Svensson 2002; Alt and Lassen 2006a, b). In these models, the electorate is not fully informed about the incumbent’s competence. Additionally, they do not observe the current levels of debt. Governments try to appear competent by temporarily raising economic growth or improving the welfare of large numbers of citizens before an election by providing more public goods.5 Whereas truly competent governments could pursue policies that increase public good provision without distorting the economy in the long run, less competent governments cannot do so. Strong electoral incentives, however, will make them want to appear competent by financing increased public goods provision with higher deficits. Voters observe the increased provision of public goods and attribute this to the economic competence to the government because they cannot observe the distortionary budgetary politics behind this (i.e. the fact that the government appears economically competent by raising deficits). Since voters would increase their support for incumbents whom they deem economically competent, incumbents have incentives to use deficit spending to appear competent even if it distorts the economy in the long run. Consequently, both competent and incompetent governments use increased public goods provision as a strategy to get reelected. The straightforward theoretical predictions find surprisingly little empirical support. Whereas there is evidence for an increase in targeted expenditures before elections (Tufte 1978, Alesina and Roubini 1992; Franzese 2002b), only few studies report opportunistically motivated deficit spending (Alesina et al. 1992, 1997; Shi and Svensson 2006; Persson and Tabellini 2003a). Other scholars find no or a negative relationship between the pre-election period and higher spending or deficits (Brender and Drazen 2004; Jochimsen and Nuscheler 2005; DeHaan and Sturm 1994; Drazen and Eslava 2005; Seitz 2000). The inconclusive findings raised doubts about the very existence of political budget cycles. To explain why many empirical cross-country and single-country analyses fail to find consistent evidence for deficit-induced budget cycles, recent work has been concerned with the conditions under which incumbents cannot imbalance their finances to manipulate the economy before elections. These models are based on the empirical observation that voters tend to punish governments if they increase deficits before elections expecting that “a more ‘competent’ policymaker can expand government spending or reduce taxes and still not induce the distortion that a less ‘competent’ policymaker would induce” (Drazen 5 Partisan theories to political business cycles argue that parties have different affinities for example to increase spending on different policy fields (Hibbs 1977; Alesina 1989; Cusack 1997; Boix 2000). 4 2000b: 101).6 In other words, the argument that governments signal competence remains unconvincing in this case, since no competence is needed to run deficits. The ability to observe deficit spending thus became the central focus of a new generation of research on political budget cycles. The claim is that incompetent governments may only feign competence if the share of informed voters is relatively low and the rents of remaining in power are high (Shi and Svensson 2002). The amount of information the voter receives about the incumbent’s actions (and thus the extent to which electioneering is possible) may depend, for example, on the transparency of fiscal institutions within a country (Alt and Lassen 2006; Shi and Svensson 2006; Klomp and de Haan 2013; Vicente et al. 2013). This argumentation explains some of the mixed findings very well. Research has consistently shown that political budget cycles are restricted to weak and new democracies, that is, to those countries where voters have restricted capacity to monitor and evaluate the fiscal policy process (e.g., Schuhknecht 1994; Akhmedov and Zhuravskaya 2004; Hallerberg, de Souza and Clark 2002; Persson and Tabellini 2002b, 2003; Shi and Svensson 2000, 2002, 2006; Brender and Drazen 2005; Drazen and Eslava 2009). State-enforced media reinforces the effect of low transparency (Ferejohn 1999). In sum, all these findings point to the importance of information and fiscal transparency as an important factor restraining the incumbents’ ability to pursue opportunistic deficit spending in the preelection period.7 As Brender and Drazen (2005) famously concluded: “In new democracies it is possible to carry out such manipulation, whereas in more established democracies, voters have the ability to identify fiscal manipulation and punish such behaviour, so that politicians avoid it.” The new generation of political budget cycle research therefore increasingly focused on analysing political budget cycles in developing countries (Schuknecht 2000; Block 2002; Sapority and Streb 2008; Drazen and Eslava 2009; Vergne 2009; Vicente et al. 2013). Is the political budget cycle dead in the developed world as much of the literature suggests? In this paper we argue that it is not. To support this claim we make two interrelated arguments. First, the theoretical literature points to the importance of fiscal transparency. Whereas fiscal transparency tends to be higher in high-income maturely democratic countries than in lowincome newly democratic countries, there is still significant amount of variation in the level of fiscal transparency across high-income democracies. Thus, we would expect deficit spending to take place in countries where voters cannot observe distortionary opportunistic spending. In fact, Alt and Lassen (2006) show that low fiscal transparency increases the likelihood that OECD countries use deficit spending before elections. Second, and more importantly, we build on the literature of compositional spending to argue that even if fiscal transparency is high in developed democracies, they can still expand public goods provision before elections if they redistribute spending from long-term investment spending to short-term consumption spending.8 The redistribution of the budget enables governments to increase public goods provision without having to raise deficits. We will argue below that compositional spending is less easily detectable than deficit spending. Based on this assumption we will show that governments use deficit spending when fiscal transparency is low, but revert to compositional spending when fiscal transparency is 6 For empirical support see Alesina, Perotti and Tavares 1998; Brender 2003; Brender and Drazen 2005; Drazen and Eslava 2005; Peltzman 1992; Schneider 2007. 7 Milesi-Feretti (2004) and Rose (2006) further examine the impact of fiscal rules on the scope for political budget cycles. 8 The literature analyzes compositional spending usually independent of deficit spending, and mainly in the context of developing countries (Schuknecht 2000; Block 2002; Sapority and Streb 2008; Drazen and Eslava 2009; Vergne 2009; Vicente et al. 2013). Schneider 2010 and Katsimi and Sarantides are exceptions as they find some evidence for compositional spending in developed countries. 5 high. In fact, our argument is consistent with some more recent findings about compositional spending in developed economies (Schneider 2010; Katsimi and Sarantides 2012). The strategic use of different fiscal strategies for reelection purposes is what we call strategic budgeteering. A THEORY OF STRATEGIC BUDGETEERING We develop a theoretical argument about how opportunistic governments choose between different fiscal strategies in order to maximize their chances to get re-elected by rational and prospective voters. In a nutshell, we argue that incumbents want to spend more on public goods if elections are close even though these short-term investments are not welfare enhancing in the long term. Whereas they prefer to use deficit spending to generate public goods, higher fiscal transparency decreases their opportunities to pursue this strategy. Rather than deciding not to electioneer, increasing fiscal transparency will induce governments to substitute deficit spending with compositional spending. Consequently, deficit spending should be more prevalent in countries with low fiscal transparency, whereas compositional spending should be more prevalent in countries with high fiscal transparency. Our theory is based on a number of standard political economy assumptions. Voters care about their expected wellbeing and choose whom to vote for based on their expected income in the time after the elections. Whereas voters value increased consumption possibilities, they are fiscal conservatives. They want the government to increase public good provision because they are competent, not because they increase deficits or use other distortionary policies to achieve that goal (Peltzman 1992; Alesina et al. 1998; Arvate et al. 2009; Brender and Drazen 2008; Drazen and Eslava 2010). To assess whether the incumbent is likely to perform in the future, the voter can use past performance as an indicator. This incentivizes incumbents to signal economic competence before elections. To keep the theory parsimonious we assume a set of domestic institutions where opportunistic monetary policies are not feasible in the preelection period. This simply implies that countries either experience high central bank independence, or have pegged exchange rates, so their ability to use expansive monetary policies is limited. According to Clark and Hallerberg (2000), governments who have no monetary policies at their disposal are more likely to rely on fiscal policies to maximize voter welfare. Whereas we make this assumption to render the theoretical argument more parsimonious we will show in the empirical section that this assumption in fact holds for our sample of countries (all of which experience high central bank independence or pegged exchange rates).9 Consequently, politicians can only rely on fiscal policies when trying to appear competent to their electorate. To improve the welfare of their voters before elections, incumbents may choose between alternative fiscal strategies. They can (a) raise taxes, (b) increase deficit spending, (c) increase compositional spending, and (d) they can reduce taxes.10 Strategies (a), (b), and (c) all 9 An interesting extension to our theory strategic budgeteering would be to integrate monetary policies. Governments that possess these policies would then be able to choose between monetary policies, deficit spending, and compositional spending. Importantly, we would assume that the choice between monetary and fiscal strategies more broadly depend on the international economic pressures (Clark and Hallerberg 2000). The choice between compositional and deficit spending should be more relevant in situations where exchange rates are fixed or central bank independence is high. 10 We distinguish between long-term and short-term spending unlike Drazen and Eslava (2005) who separate targeted from non-targeted spending. We concur that this is a useful distinction but argue that both targeted and nontargeted spending are part of short-term public good provision before elections, and targeted spending is electorally more relevant in the developing context. 6 serve to pay for the increase in public goods provision, whereas strategy (d) increases voters’ perceived welfare directly. In the following, we discuss these strategies and how attractive they are to incumbents under different conditions (see also Table 1 for a summary). Importantly, we assume that incumbents prefer to use some fiscal strategy rather than abstaining from pursuing opportunistic strategies in the electoral period altogether. When choosing between different fiscal instruments incumbents have to assess the benefits and costs of each individual strategy relative to all other strategies. Let’s first consider the feasibility of raising taxes before elections in order to finance greater public goods provision (option a). Whereas this strategy gives the incumbent a guaranteed and long-term access to additional resources for public goods provision, it comes with a relatively high cost: higher taxes are immediately visible to voters in the, and reduce their welfare in the preelection period, therefore likely reduces the voters’ support for the government. Raising taxes is therefore a strategy that may actually undermine the incumbent’s goal to get reelected. Supporting this interpretation, we are not aware of any empirical results that support such a strategy. Table 1: Fiscal Strategies in the Preelection Period Advantages (a) Raise Taxes Prevents raising deficits and does not distort the economy in the long run (b) Deficit Spending Less visible to raising taxes (c) Compositional Least visible Spending (d) Reduce Taxes Disadvantages Very visible to voters who dislike higher taxes Distorts economy in the long run (greater debt) Distorts economy in the long run (less investment spending) Visible to voters who Inflexible instrument for like low taxes short-term electoral politics Governments could also decrease taxes in order to provide an immediate welfare benefit to voters (option d). Since the change in taxation is immediately visible to voters it could provide the government with the desired boost in public support. The empirical evidence for this strategy is mixed, and evidence in favour of the tax-reduction hypothesis is not very robust (Alesina et al. 1993; Persson and Tabellini 2003; Brender and Drazen 2003; Veiga and Veiga 2007; Katsimi and Sarantides 2012). For examples, the findings do not tend to be robust across different operationalizations of tax revenues and oftentimes are inconsistent across studies (e.g. Katsimi and Sarantides (2012) find a significant effect for direct taxation (a null effect for indirect taxation), whereas Erhart (2010) finds a significant effect for indirect taxation (a null effect for direct taxation). In addition, as Eslava (2011) points out, it is not clear whether the reduction in revenues owes to a decrease in taxes or some other strategy the government uses to reduce revenue collection before elections. One of the main disadvantages of using taxation as an instrument to boost public goods provision are the difficulties in achieving tax cuts on short notice. Tax cuts have to go through the whole legislative process and are therefore much less flexible to control. Most importantly, tax cuts are very difficult to reverse undetected after the elections, and may therefore be counterproductive in the medium term. Consequently, whereas some governmnents may rely on lowering taxes as a electoral strategy, we assume that governments typically choose between deficit spending and compositional 7 spending as most attractive and flexible policies. The main advantage of using deficit spending and compositional spending over tax policies is the flexibility and the lower visibility of distorting actions. It is important to note that although we focus on these two strategies, we will analyse in the empirical section whether our assumption holds, that is, governments do not systematically exploit taxation policies before elections to gain political support. To understand the choice between compositional spending and deficit spending we have to analyse the relative costs and benefits of using each of these fiscal instruments in the electoral period. Deficit spending refers to the strategy where the government increases the domestic deficit in order to finance an increased level of public goods provision before the election. This implies that incumbents have to somehow reduce the deficit after the elections in order to balance the budget. Deficit spending is therefore costly to voters in the long run. Compositional spending refers to a strategy where the governments shift resources from budget items that are efficient to generate economic welfare in the long run to budget items that improve political support in the short run.11 Public budgets are divided into a number of different budget items (such as defense, social security, education, etc.) and governments may choose to increase or decrease spending on either of them. We assume that governments may principally raise expenditures on two different types of public goods – long-term efficient investment and/or short-term efficient consumption. Public goods that are efficient in the long term have no immediate welfare implications for the voters. Rather, the welfare implications arise in the future (and therefore after the election). Examples of such long-term public goods are investments in public order and safety, education or health. In other words, the provision of these public goods is important for voter welfare in the long-term, but they do not increase voter welfare right before the election. Short-term public goods are efficient only in the short term. That is, they increase voter welfare in the short-term, but since they are purely consumptive they do not have a long-lasting positive effect on voter welfare. Examples of such highly visible short-term policies are labor market programs, social security spending, or other social transfer payments. Whereas voters generate utility from private consumption and short-term public goods right before the election they only gain from long-term public goods after the election. Opportunistic governments can therefore increase the voters’ welfare directly before elections by providing more short-term efficient public goods in the preelection period. Investing in short-term public goods for electoral reasons implies a reduction in resources available for investment in long-term public goods, which bears distortionary effects in the long run. To sum up to this point, both deficit spending and compositional spending are less visible to voters than strategic taxation, so they should be the preferred instrument to generate political budget cycles. In addition, both strategies are distortionary in the long run – deficit spending leads to lower spending or higher taxes after the elections and strategic budgeteering leads to long-term costs through low investments in the short term. The big advantage of deficit spending is its flexibility vis-à-vis compositional spending. Governments are restricted to remain within the budgetary limits when they change the composition of the budget from investment to consumption spending. In addition, some investment 11 In the literature, there are two types of compositional spending. One strategy is to shift resources from less visible to highly visible expenditure items (i.e. more consumption spending than investment spending). The other strategy is to shift resources from non-targeted items to targeted items. The importance of targeted spending appears to be more pronounced in developing countries that are oftentimes characterized by highly clientelistic domestic politics (Drazen and Eslava 2005). Since we are interested in political budget cycles in high-income countries, where voters care about public goods provision in general, we focus on the strategy that shifts spending towards consumption spending, thereby increasing short-term public goods provision. 8 spending cannot be revised easily in the short term, which provides additional limitations for governments before elections. These limitations limit the government’s ability to expand public good provision. In contrast, governments can raise deficits much more easily and are less restricted in the amount of deficits that they incur as they are not forced to keep a balanced budget in the short term. Consequently, deficit spending should provide the government with more leverage to provide more public goods before elections than compositional spending. The big disadvantage of deficit spending is its feasibility if fiscal policies are transparent visà-vis compositional spending. Voters derive their utility from voting for the incumbent depends on their welfare in the short and the long term. Whereas they can directly observe their welfare in the preelection (current) period, any welfare benefits in the long-term are not fully anticipated by voters and therefore discounted. At the same time, they expect lower future well-being the higher the public deficit incurred by the government in the preelection period. Consequently, and in line with the literature, voters are fiscally conservative and prefer governments not to incur high deficits. How well voters can observe debt-creation by the government depends on how transparent the fiscal system is (e.g. Alt and Lassen 2006).12 We define fiscal transparency as “public openness about the structure and functions of government, fiscal policy intentions, public sector accounts, and projections. It involves ready access to reliable, comprehensive, timely, understandable, and internationally comparable information on government activities (…) so that the electorate and financial markets can accurately assess the government’s financial position and the true costs and benefits of government activities, including their present and future economic and social implications” (Kopits and Craig 1998, 1). Fiscal transparency determines the visibility of deficit-creation by the government and indicates the need to re-balance the budget in the period after elections. We argue that the deficit spending is more visible and problematic for two reasons. First, higher deficits are more visible than lower investment spending even in high transparency countries. Rogoff (1990), for example, argued that voters can observe investment spending only after the elections whereas deficit spending is immediately visible as long as fiscal transparency is high. The problem for voters to correctly assess investment spending is that it usually involves long-term projects where any assessment about the inputs is difficult as long as they are on-going (Block 2002). Voters cannot observe the output of investment expenditures immediately when they are incurred during the election year, but rather observe the results of investment spending from previous years (i.e. those investment projects that bore fruit by the time the election comes). Consequently, voters would have to track the government’s investment expenditures in the current budget itself because those are usually not discussed by the media or even by opposition parties. The media and opposition parties mainly use deficit-creation of the incumbent government to point out her incompetence in the political competition. It is therefore more difficult for voters to assess the government’s investment spending patterns than to assess the government’s deficit spending patterns. Second, voters are more likely to interpret higher deficits as distortionary and opportunistic policy than lower 12 Note, since we assume that our incumbents are elected, we do not need to take into account the quality of democratic institutions to measure the visibility of governmental fiscal policies (e.g. Shi and Svensson 2000, 2002, 2006). However, both – fiscal transparency and democratic quality – have the same notion as they measure the extent to which governmental debt-creation is visible. Consequently, we would expect the substitution effects between deficit spending and compositional spending to hold for different levels of democratic quality. 9 investment spending. Empirical research shows that voters perceive large deficits as signal that the economy is not doing well and tend to punish the incumbent for bad economic policy outcomes (Peltzman 1992; Kraemer 1997; Brender 2003; Brender and Drazen 2005; Drazen and Eslava 2005). The same pattern has not been observed for incumbents who increase short-term transfers in the year before elections. To the contrary, Veiga and Veiga (2006) show at least for Portugal that preelectoral increases in highly visible spending tends to increase public support; whereas changes in long-term efficient spending has no effect on public support. Consequently, the main trade off for governments when choosing between deficit spending and compositional spending is the question of flexibility versus feasibility (with respect to achieving political support) under different levels of fiscal transparency. When fiscal transparency is low, governments can use both fiscal strategies to increase the welfare of their voters, but they prefer to use deficit spending because this is a more flexible instrument that allows them to provide more public goods before elections. When fiscal transparency is high, deficit spending becomes an infeasible strategy to governments who want to maximize political support. Even though compositional spending may not be as flexible of an instrument it will be more feasible and therefore more likely to be employed by opportunistic incumbents. This leads us to the following hypotheses: Hypothesis 1: The lower fiscal transparency, the greater the likelihood that governments use deficit spending to increase public goods provision in preelection periods, ceteris paribus. Hypothesis 2: The lower fiscal transparency, the smaller the likelihood that governments use compositional spending to increase public goods provision in the preelection period, ceteris paribus. Hypothesis 3: The greater fiscal transparency, the less likely governments use deficit spending to increase public good provision in the preelection period, ceteris paribus. Hypothesis 4: The greater fiscal transparency, the more likely governments use compositional spending to increase public goods provision in the preelection period, ceteris paribus. Whereas hypotheses 1-4 reflect the most straightforward predictions that can be deducted from our theory, there are other empirical implications that allow us to test the theoretical mechanism more closely. First, the existing literature suggests that governments’ incentives to use distortionary fiscal policies before elections should increase the greater the electoral uncertainty. If governments are not certain to be reelected they will be more willing to incur the long term costs of deficit spending and compositional spending. There are various sources of electoral uncertainty, but most important to the government may be the closeness of elections. The more competitive the electoral race, that is, the closer the opposition and the incumbent are in the public opinion polls, the greater the incentive for the government to get an electoral advantage using fiscal instruments. Consequently: Hypothesis 5: The closer the election, the more likely governments use deficits spending and compositional spending to increase public good provision in the preelection period, ceteris paribus. 10 Second, above we argue that voters perceive the costs of deficit spending as more distortionary than the costs of reducing investment spending. Another way of analyzing the effect of long-term costs on the likelihood that distortionary fiscal policies are implement is to analyze the reaction of governments to variations in the long-term costs of deficit spending when fiscal transparency is high. There are two potential sources of costs that seem important. First, there may be variations in the long-term fiscal costs of opportunistic deficit spending. The negative effect of fiscal transparency on the likelihood that incumbents can use deficit spending is particularly pronounced if maintaining deficits is more costly. In particular, the higher the interest rates the more costly it will be for the government (and the voters) to balance the budget after the elections. Consequently, higher interest rates should provide an additional impetus to refrain from deficit spending when fiscal transparency is high. Second, there may be variations in the institutional setting with effects for opportunistic government spending. If governments have to abide to domestic or international institutions that have budget balance requirements, then the likelihood that governments use deficit spending should decline. One example of such institutions are is the Stability and Growth Pact in the European Union, which restricts EMU countries to limit their budget deficits to 3% of domestic GDP. Such requirements will limit the feasibility of deficit spending (although there clearly are differences in the credibility of threats across member states) and increase incentives to use compositional spending. This provides us with additional interesting empirical implications that shed more light on the theory of strategic budgeteering: Hypothesis 6: The higher interest rates, the less likely governments use deficits spending to increase public good provision in the preelection period, particularly when fiscal transparency is high, ceteris paribus. Hypothesis 7: EMU governments are less likely to use deficits spending to increase public good provision in the preelection period than non-EMU countries, particularly when fiscal transparency is high, ceteris paribus. Hypothesis 8: EMU governments are more likely to use compositional spending to increase public good provision in the preelection period than non-EMU countries, particularly when fiscal transparency is high, ceteris paribus. In a way of summarizing, governments in mature and developed democracies still have both motive and opportunities to use fiscal policies to increase their chances of staying in power after elections. Our theory of strategic budgeteering provides insights into how governments choose alternative strategies, in particular deficit spending and compositional spending, given their flexibility and feasibility. Whereas deficit spending is preferred due to its relative flexibility, which allows the government to boost consumption spending more than would be possible under compositional spending, its feasibility declines when fiscal transparency is great. In this situation, compositional spending substitutes for deficit spending as an instrument to increase public goods provision opportunistically. We derived several hypotheses from our theory that we will test in the next section. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS In the following we attempt to put the predictions of the theoretical model to the test. We use two different data sets to investigate our theoretical propositions. First we simply look at the composition of government spending into consumption (current spending) or investment (capital spending) to investigate whether governments indeed move resources from long-term to short11 term expenditure if fiscal transparency is high. In addition we check for electoral cycles in deficit spending and under what conditions (level of transparency) deficit spending is used to finance short term public good provision. Alternatives to strategic budgeteering (tax rates and revenues, monetary policy measures) are investigated for electoral cycles as well. In a second step we investigate data on the composition of public expenditure for 17 OECD countries over 35 years.13 The data provides information on 23 spending categories ranging from expenditure for defense, public order and safety to education, social security and welfare, agriculture, mining and manufacturing, as well as infrastructure such as roads and railways. Table 2 describes all items in more detail. We employ both total expenditure and relative expenditure per item as the dependent variable. Compositional Spending We start our empirical investigation by looking at the two interesting components of government spending: consumption (current spending) and investment (capital spending). We use OECD national accounts data, specifically general government final consumption expenditure (consumption) and general government gross fixed capital formation (investment). Our first dependent variable is the ratio of the two (consumption/investment, both measured in millions of US dollars). This allows testing for a direct shift from investment to consumption (the ratio increases) in the pre-electoral period. We also use both variables individually as left-hand-side (LHS) variables as percentage of GDP to see direct pre-electoral effects. In order to analyze both aspects of strategic budgeteering we investigate electoral cycles in deficit spending (measured as annual changes in debt per GDP (OECD and WDI if missing) as well as the effect of preelectoral deficit creation to increase public good provision (consumption)14. In addition to these main features of strategic budgeteering we test for the existence of electoral cycles in fiscal and monetary alternatives, specifically we look at inflation and real interest rates (WDI), tax revenue per GDP (WDI), statutory corporate tax rates and effective average corporate tax rates (Devereux et al. 2002) as well as average income tax rates (OECD). We are mostly interested in pre-electoral effects. To determine the pre-election period we simply generate a dummy that takes the value one for the 12 month prior to a legislative election and zero otherwise. The data comes from the Database of Political Institutions (DPI 2012) of the World Bank (Keefer 2004).15 In addition we look at the effect of pre-electoral deficit spending on the composition of the budget. The theoretical model predicts that strategic reshuffling of resources depends on the fiscal transparency of the country and (to a lesser extent) the ex ante probability of winning an election (the closeness of the electoral competition). We operationalize the first condition by using data from the Open Budget Survey that is conducted on the bi-yearly bases by the International Business Partnership. The survey consists of a battery of 125 question that range from questions about the budgetary process, e.g. at what point in the process the executive has to provide de13 The 17 countries are: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, france, Germany, Iceland (not for all models), Italy, Japan, The Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the US. The data collection was funded by the German Science Foundation (DFG). 14 We use changes in debt instead of deficit since the data is more comprehensive and covers more cases. Also we believe that changes in debt are the more accurate measure because of the complicated computation of deficits. 15 We experimented with two pre-election years with no substantive changes to the main estimation results. For a better operationalization of the pre-electoral period and a more detailed discussion see Franzese (2002, 2003) 12 tailed reports, what institutional actors are involved in the budgetary decisions, who has veto power, who needs to be consulted (e.g. whether the executive is required to seek input from the legislative when shifting resources between budget items - question 103), whether there is an audit process, who carries out the audit process, legal and regulatory restrictions on spending decisions etc. In addition, questions about involvement of the public are asked, e.g. how often does the government have to publish reports on the budget, how detailed does the reports have to be and what information has to be disseminated in what form to the public, does the government only have to publish information about the agreed budget or also about projected spending and changes, does the government have to lay out how the proposed spending is related to stated policy goals, is the government formally required to engage the public, what channels and formal mechanisms (e.g. public hearings) exist for the public to feed input into the budgetary process, does the executive provide formal feedback on how public input has affected budget decisions, are audit reports publicly available etc. These survey questions are combined into sub-indexes e.g. for the executives budget proposal, the audit process and the public engagement and an overall index, the Open Budget Index (OBI), which ranges between 0 and 100, whereas larger values indicate more open budgets and thus more fiscal transparency. We use the overall index since it correlates highly with the sub-indexes. Unfortunately, OBI scores are only available for 2006, 2008, 2010, 2012. We follow a two-fold strategy to fill in the missings. First, we use the score for the previous year to fill in scores for following years, second we follow a regression approach to inpute missing values. The OBI score is highly correlated to other political measures of governance and freedom of press, thus we use the transparency index provided by Alt and Lassen (see below), the government effectiveness estimates from the World Bank governance indicators, and the Freedom House freedom of press and political pressures and controls of media scores to generate a regression score to fill in missings of the OBI score. 16 Figure 1 shows average OBI scores for the countries in our sample, ranked from the lowest to highest scores. Figure 1: Average OBI score across countries 16 Other governance indicators such as corruption are possible candidates too, but we used the variables that gave the best and most parsimonious fit. 13 Mexico Indonesia Turkey Slovak Republic Portugal Japan Italy Russia Czech Republic Spain Belgium India Ireland Germany Iceland Switzerland Canada Korea Finland Denmark Poland Brazil Netherlands Australia Austria Slovenia United States Sweden Norway United Kingdom France New Zealand 40 50 60 70 80 fiscal transparency (open budget index) 90 The ranking seems to make intuitive sense and is very similar to the Alt and Lassen score (correlation 0.58). Basically, we argue that in more fiscally transparent countries, incumbents cannot easily use deficits to provide public goods before elections but have to reshuffle the budget from long-term efficient to short-term beneficial spending. Thus, high transparency should make strategic budgeteering more likely. As a robustness check we use the fiscal transparency index provided by Alt and Lassen (2005) which is based on a 1999 OECD questionnaire sent to all Budget Directors of OECD member countries. The main problem of the variable consists in its time invariance.17 Figure 2: fiscal transparency score by Alt and Lassen 17 Since we use country dummies in all our models, we use interaction effects with long- and short-term items as well as election periods to identify the effect of transparency. 14 Japan Germany Norway Switzerland Belgium Denmark Ireland Italy Austria Canada Finland France Iceland Sweden Netherlands Australia United Kingdom United States New Zealand 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 fiscal transparency (Alt/Lassen) 9 10 11 The second condition – closeness of elections – states that governments only resort to heavy budgeteering if the elections are highly contested. To capture this factor we use a variable provided by the DPI (2004) which measures the margin of the majority by dividing the number of seats won by the largest government party by the total number of seats (government plus opposition plus non-aligned). Thus the larger value of the variable the less contested the elections are. Of course, this operationalization cannot capture situations of unexpected landslide victories but comes very close to our theoretical definition.18 Clearly and as stated elsewhere (Franzese 2002), electoral budget cycles are expected to be flatter when governments have some discretion over setting the actual election date. Much research has been done on so called endogenous election timing (e.g. Smith 1996, 2003, 2004), that we do not need to re-iterate here. The main argument we take from the discussion in the literature is that if incumbent governments have discretion over setting the election date they can chose a period when the economy is doing well and thus have less incentive to use fiscal measures to manipulate the budget cycle. If this argument held, we should not find a significant impact of our main interesting variables because the effect of endogenous election timing would erase our hypothesized effect. However, we still are interested in testing this counterbalancing effect directly and thus use data from the Institutions and Elections Project (Regan and Clark). We combine the information on two variables, the election timing variable considers whether there is a no formal schedule (1 – full discretion), exact intervals for elections (2 – no discretion), the timing is determined by the political process within a fixed interval (3 – some discretion). Most countries in our sample fall in category three. However, we only code the countries falling in this category as “endogenous election timing” if the executive has the power to set the election date within the specified interval. 18 It is always problematic to use ex post outcome data to model ex ante expectations. In future iterations of the paper we will use survey data on pre-electoral preferences to operationalize the incumbents ex ante expectation of winning the election. 15 I addition, to these main interesting variables we use a number of political and economic control variables in order to avoid omitted variable bias19. We estimated fixed effects models20 (thus only use within country variation to identify effects), include a trend, and compute country-wise clustered standard errors. Table 2 presents the regression results for the ratio of government consumption/investment. Table 2: Ratio of government consumption/investment DV: consumption/investment ∆ debt Pre-election period Fiscal Transparency (OBI/Alt-Lassen) Preelection*transparency Preelection*debt Debt*transparency Peelection*debt*trans trend EMU membership Preelection*EMU Preelection*debt*EMU Endogenous election timing (1=yes) Preelection*endog elect Margin of Majority Preelection*Margin of Majority Does Party of Executive Control All Houses? Vote Share of Largest Government Party Legislative Electoral Competitiveness Government Fractionalization Index Checks and Balances Polarization Baseline OBI 0.006*** (0.002) -0.116** (0.052) -0.004*** (0.001) 0.002** (0.001) 0.002** (0.001) 0.000*** (0.000) -0.000** (0.000) 0.006*** (0.002) Baseline Alt/Lassen 0.007*** (0.002) -0.108*** (0.034) Dropped due to collinearity 0.034** (0.012) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.001** (0.000) -0.001** (0.000) 0.005*** (0.002) extended OBI 0.007*** (0.001) -0.096 (0.072) -0.003*** (0.000) 0.002** (0.001) 0.001** (0.001) 0.000*** (0.000) -0.000** (0.000) 0.007*** (0.001) -0.032* (0.018) -0.017 (0.066) 0.000 (0.001) 0.030 (0.028) -0.011 (0.022) -0.099* (0.056) -0.001 (0.089) Pol. controls OBI 0.007*** (0.001) -0.131 (0.081) -0.004*** (0.000) 0.002** (0.001) 0.001** (0.001) 0.000*** (0.000) -0.000** (0.000) 0.007*** (0.001) -0.026 (0.019) -0.035 (0.069) 0.001 (0.001) 0.026 (0.029) -0.001 (0.025) -0.346*** (0.098) 0.035 (0.105) -0.028 (0.019) 0.003** (0.001) 0.027 (0.077) 0.196*** (0.060) -0.001 (0.005) -0.017* full OBI 0.002 (0.001) -0.238* (0.127) -0.003*** (0.001) 0.003* (0.002) 0.002 (0.002) 0.000*** (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) -0.002 (0.002) -0.075*** (0.026) -0.008 (0.063) 0.000 (0.001) Dropped due to collinearity 0.007 (0.028) -0.047 (0.123) 0.139 (0.114) -0.047* (0.028) 0.001 (0.002) -0.120* (0.062) 0.125* (0.075) -0.023** (0.009) 0.015 19 For parsimony, the names of the variables can be found in regression tables, the sources are the Worldbank WDI, OECD and Database for Political Institutions (DPI, Worldbank, Keefer et al. 2004). 20 Random effects results are similar, but Hausman tests suggest the use of country fixed effects. 16 (0.009) 0.603 (0.545) (0.014) -0.005*** (0.001) -0.005* (0.003) -0.000* (0.000) -0.026*** (0.002) 0.004*** (0.001) -0.008*** (0.002) 0.018*** (0.007) -0.006 (0.004) 2.056*** (0.472) 0.409 696 30 21.276 0.645 342 30 18.452 Foreign direct investment (% of GDP) GDP per capita growth GDP per capita Gross savings (% of GDP) Trade (% of GDP) WDI Inflation CPI Age dependency ratio Tax revenue (% of GDP) Intercept 0.733*** (0.061) 0.589*** (0.069) 0.753*** (0.044) R2 (within) 0.399 0.413 0.405 N 822 652 764 Number of countries 32 19 31 F statistic 10.343 23.921 32.616 Standard errors clustered on country level in parentheses, *** p≤0.01, ** p≤0.05, * p≤0.1 In order to be able to interpret the main effects directly we have graphed the interaction effects from the baseline model. 100 .02 .004 .015 .01 0 .005 0 -.002 -.004 80 .005 40 60 fiscal transparency 0 20 Kernel Density Estimate of OBI .015 .01 Kernel Density Estimate of OBI marg effect of preelectoral deficit 0 .002 .2 .1 0 -.1 -.2 -.3 pre-election effect Figure 1b: pre-electoral effect of deficit spending on consumption/investment ratio .02 Figure 1a: pre-election effect on consumption/investment ratio 0 20 40 60 fiscal transparency 80 100 Our theory predicts that when fiscal transparency is high, resources should be redirected from investment to consumption in the pre-electoral period (hypothesis 4) and that is exactly what figure 1a shows: when transparency is high, the pre-electoral effect is positive implying that the ratio changes in favor of consumption. When fiscal transparency is low this is not the case and governments do not shift resources from investment to consumption (hypothesis 2). Moreover, figure 1b depicts the pre-electoral effect of deficit spending. When fiscal transparency is low, higher deficit spending is used to increase government consumption (hypothesis 1). This effect vanishes with above average fiscal transparency (hypothesis 3). Thus fiscal transparency pre17 vents governments from using the “easier” measure deficit spending to increase public good provision before elections and forces them the reshuffle resources within the budget. With respect to compositional spending, hypothesis 5 is only partially confirmed; the actual closeness of election has an effect throughout the electoral period but is not reinforced in the preelectoral period. As said this measure has to be taken with some caution since it is an ex-post measure. Better survey data should enable us to get a more precise operationalization of this notion. The EMU membership (hypothesis 8) hypothesis cannot not be confirmed for compositional spending, EMU members generally are less likely to use fiscal measures to manipulate the economy but we cannot detect a cycling effect since there is no additional effect in the preelectoral period. Finally, endogenous election timing does not seem to reduce incentives for governments to use compositional spending to manipulate the electoral cycle. Even though it seems that governments should have less inclination to use fiscal measures before elections when they can time the election date, they can only do so within a limited interval and prediction economic conditions is not an easy thing to do. Moreover, these timing decisions are complex and do not just depend on economic considerations but also political ones (e.g. domestic and international conflicts). The control variables generally influence the outcome in the expected way, better economic conditions reduce incentives to budgeteer, veto players reduce the ability to electioneer and fractionalization of the government increases budgeteering which confirms the coalition government and size of government hypotheses (Persson/Tabellini). To confirm this initial analysis we test the pre-electoral effects of transparency on the change in governmental debt. The previous analysis suggested that indeed governments use deficits in the pre-electoral period to finance higher consumption if fiscal transparency is low. Table 3 presents similar results for the change in debt on the left hand side. Table 3: Pre-electoral Effect on Change in Debt DV: ∆ debt Pre-election period Fiscal Transparency (OBI/Alt-Lassen) Preelection*transparency EMU membership Preelection*EMU Endogenous election timing (1=yes) Preelection*endog elect Margin of Majority Preelection*Margin of Majority GDP per capita growth trend Vote Share of Largest Government Party Government Fractionali- OBI 0.818 (0.936) -0.020* (0.012) -0.008 (0.016) OBI 2.089 (2.647) -0.014 (0.013) -0.009 (0.015) -2.252*** (0.825) 0.568 (1.105) 2.294* (1.297) 1.078 (1.016) -1.236 (4.831) -5.164 (4.141) -0.936*** (0.083) -0.034 (0.030) -0.096 (0.071) -2.501 Alt/Lassen 2.691** (1.065) Dropped due to collinearity -0.431* (0.230) Alt/Lassen 2.233 (2.729) Dropped due to collinearity -0.373* (0.194) -1.932** (0.824) -0.603 (1.124) 2.577** (1.175) -0.193 (1.090) -6.280 (4.940) -0.391 (4.256) -1.252*** (0.094) -0.074*** (0.027) -0.132* (0.071) -2.012 18 zation Index Checks and Balances (3.108) -0.301 (0.207) Intercept 1.870*** 6.896*** 0.820*** (0.655) (2.556) (0.278) R2 (within) 0.006 0.184 0.011 N 839 750 652 Number of countries 33 32 19 F statistic 1.642 10.585 3.433 Standard errors clustered on country level in parentheses, *** p≤0.01, ** p≤0.05, * p≤0.1 (3.096) -0.495** (0.211) 11.964*** (2.755) 0.290 585 18 16.098 Generally the effects for deficit spending are not as strong as the previous results. However, the main interesting theoretical effect exists and is captured in figure 221: -5 -3 -1 1 pre-election effect 3 5 Figure 2: pre-electoral effect on change in debt 0 2 4 6 fiscal transparency Alt/Lassen 8 10 The result in figure 2 represents the necessary condition for hypotheses 1 and 3 to hold: if fiscal transparency is low governments increase deficit spending before elections, which in turn is used to increase public consumption (figure 1b). If transparency is high, deficit spending is not significantly increased over non-election years. From table 3 we can also see that in general governments increase deficits in the pre-election period. EMU membership decreases the use of deficit spending in general but there is no additional reducing effect in pre-electoral periods (hypothesis 7). Interestingly, endogenous election timing increases deficit spending contrary to expectations that governments should have fewer incentives to engage in fiscal electioneering if they can set the election date. If we speculated to a certain extend as to the underlying mechanism, one could argue that since voters know that governments with discretion would prefer to schedule the election during a period of economic prosperity, they might use fiscal measure to appear more competent to the public who expects elections to take place during an economic high. 21 Note however that the effect is only significant for the less informative fiscal transparency measure provided by Alt and Lassen. 19 To support the previous empirical findings we run the same models for consumption (as % of GDP) separately. Empirical results are shown in table 4: Table 4: Pre-electoral effects of changes in debt and transparency on consumption per GDP DV: ∆ debt Pre-election period Fiscal Transparency (OBI) Preelection*transparency Preelection*debt Debt*transparency Peelection*debt*trans consumption 0.058*** (0.018) -1.297 (0.853) -0.023 (0.014) 0.020** (0.008) 0.020** (0.008) 0.001*** (0.000) -0.000* (0.000) EMU membership Preelection*EMU Preelection*debt*EMU Endogenous election timing (1=yes) Preelection*endog elect Margin of Majority Preelection*Margin of Majority GDP per capita growth (annual %) WDI trend Vote Share of Largest Government Party Government Fractionalization Index Checks and Balances Intercept R2 (within) N Number of countries F statistic 18.979*** (0.445) 0.209 839 33 10.745 consumption 0.050*** (0.010) -1.246 (0.848) -0.025*** (0.005) 0.012 (0.009) 0.012* (0.007) 0.000*** (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) 0.245 (0.210) -0.094 (0.764) 0.004 (0.010) 0.120 (0.329) 0.045 (0.261) -4.009*** (1.001) 0.431 (1.051) -0.138*** (0.023) 0.018** (0.008) 0.047*** (0.014) 2.245*** (0.630) -0.071 (0.052) 19.552*** (0.646) 0.274 750 32 13.889 The empirical findings in table 4 support our previous conclusions. Pre-electoral deficit spending is used to increase consumption if transparency is low (figure 3a) but has not effect if transparency is high (hypotheses 1 and 3). Re-shuffling of the budget of course cannot be tested with the set up in table 4. Figure 3a: pre-electoral effect of deficit spending on consumption 20 .02 0 .005 .01 Kernel Density Estimate of OBI .015 .04 .02 0 -.02 0 20 40 60 fiscal transparency 80 100 Competitiveness of elections impacts consumption as expected: the more competitive an election is the higher turns out to be public consumption (hypothesis 5). EMU membership has no effect (or only mildly negative effect) on short-term public good provision. In these models above the pure pre-electoral effect on public consumption turns out to be insignificant. We also ran the same models for established democracies only because there the electoral incentives to provide wide spread public goods to the median voter before elections seems to be more prevalent. In this case, as expected, the pre-electoral effect of government consumption turns out to be significantly positive but declining in fiscal transparency. This is consistent with the argument that while governments always have an electoral incentive to increase public good provision, fiscal transparency reduces all opportunities to electioneer but makes reshuffling of the budget more likely. Figure 4 displays this result graphically: Figure 4: Pre-electoral effect on government consumption depending on fiscal transparency 21 4 3 2 1 0 -1 0 20 40 fiscal transparency 60 80 This finding is also consistent with figures 5a-5c below which show effects for single budget items. Finally we test electoral cycles for monetary and fiscal alternative to strategic budgeteering (deficit and compositional spending). We analyze monetary measures, e.g. inflation and interest rates, other fiscal measure, e.g. tax revenue and tax rates. Table 5 shows the main results22. Table 5: Pre-electoral effects on alternative measures to deficit spending and budgeteering DV: inflation Real interest rate Tax revenue Tax revenue Pre-election period -2.620 (21.866) -0.074 (0.302) -0.044 (0.371) -1.968 (2.040) -0.030 (0.029) 0.046 (0.034) 0.132 (0.470) 0.000 (0.004) -0.003 (0.007) 32.179** (15.928) 0.000 1235.000 7.283*** (1.587) 0.003 949.000 18.254*** (0.265) 0.001 547.000 -0.040 (0.482) -0.003 (0.005) -0.000 (0.007) -0.781 (0.496) 0.014* (0.008) 18.450*** (0.291) 0.008 546.000 Fiscal Transparency (OBI) Preelection*transparency Post-election period Postelection*transparency Intercept R2 (within) N Statutory corporate tax 0.007 (0.014) -0.001*** (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) Effective average corporate tax 0.001 (0.010) -0.001*** (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) Average income tax 0.447*** (0.011) 0.072 468.000 0.323*** (0.007) 0.050 468.000 18.068*** (0.414) 0.008 821.000 0.156 (0.585) -0.017** (0.007) -0.001 (0.010) 22 Results in table 5 are reduced to the main interesting variables, models including controls can be found in the appendix. 22 Number of countries F statistic 37.000 0.111 35.000 0.806 36.000 0.182 36.000 0.840 18.000 11.583 18.000 7.763 29.000 2.185 Generally, we cannot find electoral cycles in any of the measures presented in table 5. As argued above we didn’t expect to find electoral effects in these variables but we wanted to confirm our suspicion empirically, otherwise findings for budgeteering could be blurred by the use of other fiscal and monetary measures. Especially in our sample of countries, governments don’t have monetary policy autonomy since they face independent central banks, are member of a currency union or have fixed exchange rate regimes. Tax measures on the other hand are not flexible enough to be exploited for electoral purposes, changing tax laws and regulations is a difficult legislative undertaking and usually faces considerable veto-power. Interestingly though, fiscal transparency seems to reduce taxes overall which seems to make sense given that observability should increase public pressure on tax authorities. Re-shuffling Resources across Single Budget Items In a second step we attempt to tackle the issue of strategic budgeteering by looking at redistribution of resources between 23 single budget items. In order to test the hypothesis on strategic reshuffling from long-term efficient to short-term beneficial public spending in pre-election periods, we have to decide which items rather constitute long-term efficient and which short-term strategic public goods. The last column of table 1 shows our allocation which relies heavily on the categorization provided by Drazen and Eslava (2005) and we also consider work on German partisan spending preferences (Bawn 1999, Koenig / Troeger 2005). We only allocated the most obvious items and exclude the residual category from the empirical analysis. Drazen and Eslava (2005) mostly distinguish spending items with respect to targeted and non-targeted spending. We argue that both targeted (e.g. sectoral, regional) spending and non-targeted spending, especially social security transfers can be used in the short term to manipulate electoral behavior. We therefore find it more plausible to distinguish long-term efficient investment from short-term inefficient public good provision either to the median voter or targeted groups. Admittedly the assignment of items to a long-term and a short-term category is still pretty ad hoc and needs more theoretical derivation. Yet, for a first empirical investigation this allocation seems to provide us with relatively robust and consistent results23. The assignment of items to long-term efficient and short-term beneficial public spending allows testing the first prediction on strategic budgeteering that incumbents tend to reshuffle resources from efficient investment to inefficient public good provision before elections in order to increase their chances staying in office. Table 6: Composition of Government Spending 23 Also as a robustness check we randomly allocated items to long-term and short-term spending and re-run the analysis 1000 times. None of these random allocation produced significant results. See appendix for the simulation analysis. 23 Expenditure Item 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 Description General Public Services Defense Public Order & Safety Education Health Social Security & Welfare Housing & Community Amenities Recreational, Cultural & Religious Affairs Fuel & Energy Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing & Hunting Mining, Manufacturing & Construction Transportation & Communication Other Economic Affairs & Services Other Expenditures of which: Interest Payments Adjustment to Total Expenditure Economic Affairs & Social Services (9-13) (only if 9-13 not available) Environmental Protection Electricity, Steam, Water Roads Inland & Coastal Waterways Other Transport & Communication Other Economic Services Longterm/ shortterm Longterm Longterm Longterm Longterm Shortterm / non-targeted Shortterm Shortterm/ Targeted Shortterm/ Targeted Shortterm/ Targeted Shortterm/ Targeted Shortterm Longterm Shortterm Shortterm We conduct the second empirical analysis in two steps. First we run models for alternative strategies to reshuffling the budget such as relaxing monetary policy, debt creation, and tax reduction. In a second step we estimate the extent of strategic budgeteering depending on the two conditions (transparency (Alt-Lassen) and closeness of elections) as well as controlling for alternative strategies. We also test for partisan effects but do not exhaustively cover this question and leave it for future research. In a first stage we re-examine whether governments in OECD countries use strategic measures before elections in order to increase their odds of being re-elected. We look at debt creation (debt per GDP, OECD), monetary policy and monetary outcomes (interest rate and inflation – both WDI), and taxation (consumption tax revenue – OECD, average effective tax rates on capital and labor – own calculations, see Troeger 2008). We regress these instruments on the pre-election period, transparency and their interaction. We control for the unemployment rate and GDP per capita (both WDI), left and right cabinet portfolios (both DPI), the electoral system (1 – majoritarian, 0 – proportional, DPI) and Checks and Balances to the executive 24 (DPI). Since the theoretical model predicts an impact of interest rates on the ability of policy makers to create higher deficits we include the main lending rate (OECD) to the right-hand-side of the debt ratio equation. We also add a dummy for EMU members that adopted the Maastricht criteria in order to test for the effect of stricter constraints to deficit spending and debt creation for those governments. 24 We use different measures for veto players/ points, and institutional constraints to the executive with essentially the same statistical results. 24 We employ the fixed effects vector decomposition method suggested by Plümper and Troeger (2007) since the transparency measure is time invariant and the electoral system is slow moving at best, but certainly cross-sectionally dominant. This allows us to keep the beneficial characteristics of the fixed effects estimator for all time varying right-hand-side variables but still efficiently estimate coefficients for transparency and electoral system. We also employ a PraisWinston transformation to eliminate existing serial correlation.25 Table 6 depicts the estimation results. The most interesting (for our purpose) conclusion is that we cannot find any business cycle or at least pre-electoral activity for taxation or monetary policy which corresponds to our theoretical discussion. Only for debt creation we can observe that governments on average increase the debt prior to elections in order to provide public goods that serve their electoral chances. Yet, in more fiscally transparent countries, incumbents are less likely to use debt creation for electoral purposes – the electoral business cycle becomes flatter. This finding supports the first hypothesis of our theoretical model: incumbents in fiscally transparent systems are less likely to use deficit spending prior to elections in order to increase their probability of being re-elected. In addition we find that higher interest rates indeed reduce deficit spending in general since debt services become more expensive. Also, as expected EMU members have lower debt ratios on average. Table 6: Electoral Business Cycles for Taxation, Monetary Policy and Debt Creation 25 We are painfully aware of all the endogeneity and simultaneity issues of this approach. It would certainly be better to estimate a simultaneous equation model. Yet, our most important results do not change. 25 Model 1a Debt Pre-election Model 1b Inflation Model 1c Interest rate -0.112 (0.470) 0.038 (0.121) -0.206*** (0.073) -0.211*** (0.066) -0.000*** (0.000) -0.006 (0.007) -0.009 (0.007) -0.089* (0.059) 0.478** (0.190) Model 1d Consumption tax 28.059 (34.833) -4.210 (6.872) 18.858*** (2.529) 0.204 (2.626) 0.026*** (0.002) -0.511 (0.400) -0.231 (0.488) -11.256** (5.612) 347.782*** (25.752) Model 1e Labor tax 4.901** 0.207 -0.578 (2.394) (0.430) (0.531) Pre*Transp. -0.695** 0.004 0.112 (0.363) (0.108) (0.103) Transparency -0.197* -0.365*** 0.546*** (0.121) (0.090) (0.032) Unemployment 3.757*** -0.768*** 0.647*** (0.192) (0.061) (0.052) GDP per cap. 0.001*** -0.001*** 0.000*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Left cabinet 0.038** -0.012*** 0.012* (0.015) (0.004) (0.006) Right cabinet 0.014 -0.012*** 0.003 (0.018) (0.004) (0.007) Checks & Bal. -1.176*** -0.042 -0.036 (0.327) (0.051) (0.112) Majoritarian -19.502*** 0.766*** -12.162*** (0.964) (0.122) (0.249) Interest Rate -0.302** (0.128) EMU -2.207** (0.945) Intercept 12.810*** 26.998*** 18.968*** -324.723*** 28.365*** (0.449) (0.294) (0.269) (18.732) (0.289) Fevd fevd fevd fevd fevd R² adj. 0.878 0.644 0.561 0.897 0.909 N 439 477 426 480 492 F 14595.300 707.237 42.018 184.135 1429.866 Prob. > F 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Robust White Standard Errors in Parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Model 1f Capital tax -0.419 (0.959) 0.104 (0.209) 0.108 (0.106) -0.085 (0.115) 0.000 (0.000) 0.008 (0.014) 0.010 (0.010) -0.126 (0.164) 8.913*** (0.409) 22.831*** (0.395) fevd 0.786 485 395.294 0.000 If governments cannot create debt, do they strategically reshuffle the budget from long-term efficient investment to short-term beneficial public goods in order to improve their electoral prospects? This section tries to empirically answer the question. Since our dependent variable is a composite of different budget items, efficiency issues due to substitution effects arise. We have yet to find a suitable way to address these issues in a satisfactory manner. However, this model exactly estimates possible substitution effects between long-term efficient investments and shortterm public goods because it only includes these budget items into the model. We use dummy variables for these two categories and interact these with the most important theoretical variables. We are aware that this approach does not account for any other substitution effects between single spending items but we are confident that the empirical results give us some insights into the mechanisms of strategic budgeteering. To further address substitution issues we use both relative expenditure per item as well as total expenditure per item (with overall spending on the RHS of the model capturing the budget constraint) and compare the results.26 The data structure 26 We also use yearly changes in spending per item with mostly the same findings, yet significance levels drop. 26 is three-dimensional: spending item per country per year (15*17*35). Spending data are consistently available for about 13 spending categories which leaves us with about 7735 observations from which we can use 5000-6000 observations for 16-17 countries due to missing data for some of the institutional variables especially before 1980. We use other budgeteering measures (debt, monetary policy and taxation) and the same political and institutional variables as in the first stage models as control variables. We include country dummies into all models so that the level effect of transparency is soaked up by the country effects. We still can identify the pre-electoral effect of fiscal transparency which is sufficient for the test of our hypothesis. We again employ a Prais-Winston transformation to control for existent serial correlation. This specification is also useful since we are interested in short-term adjustment effects in spending. The results presented in Table 7 test the argument that governments reshuffle resources from long-term investment to short-term public goods before elections and whether this is conditional on fiscal transparency. The model fit is reasonably good for total expenditure but poor for relative expenditure which is to be expected due to the high share of pre-determined spending. Still all models in table 3 support our prediction that governments indeed engage in strategic budgeteering before elections. Long-term efficient investment is reduced in the pre-electoral period and more money is spent on short-term public goods, especially social security, manufacturing and other sectoral subsidies. In addition, fiscal transparency dampens the electoral cycle and incumbents in more transparent countries are less likely to reshuffle the budget before elections but invest in long-term efficient projects such as infrastructure and education. These findings are robust throughout all models in table 7. Yet, the effect is not as strong as for deficit spending suggesting that even though fiscal transparency constrains electioneering ceteris paribus it has a smaller impact on strategic budgeteering. The more transparent a country the higher the probability that voters can see thru all kind of measures whose sole purpose is to manipulate the electoral business cycle. Table 7: Strategic Budgeteering and Transparency 27 Model 2a Relative exp. per item Total gov. exp. Preelection longterm spending Pre*long*Transp. Preelection shortterm spending Pre*short*Transp. Model 2b Total exp. per item -0.04*** 0.088*** (0.006) -3369.75*** (0.010) 0.004** (0.002) 0.043** (0.017) -0.003 (0.003) Model 2c Relative exp. per item Model 2d Total exp. per item Model 2e Relative exp. per item Model 2f Total exp. per item -0.02*** 0.091*** (0.008) -3808.30*** -0.022** 0.091*** (0.008) -2394.334* (933.888) 290.745** (123.602) 5654.359** (0.006) 0.002* (0.001) 0.057*** (1061.337) 343.850** (139.392) 6567.498** (0.009) 0.002* (0.001) 0.048* (1263.005) 267.070** (134.216) 5304.239* (2454.492) -608.965* (321.497) (0.016) -0.005* (0.003) (2856.804) -734.906** (373.468) (0.024) -0.004* (0.003) -0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.001 (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.061*** (0.016) yes 0.009 5801 2.949 (3552.546) -665.477* (382.674) -24.356 (18.933) 22.458 (50.112) 15.916 (22.294) 75.641** (31.492) 17.573 (61.696) 74.523* (44.688) -0.071 (0.828) -5429.18** (2666.167) yes 0.278 5801 57.754 Pre*long*debt Pre*short*debt Debt per GDP 0.000 14.940 (0.000) (21.620) Inflation 0.000 75.165** (0.000) (31.427) Labor tax 0.001 18.970 (0.000) (61.560) Capital tax -0.000 74.479* (0.000) (44.694) Consumption tax rev. 0.000 -0.091 (0.000) (0.826) Intercept 0.072*** -1378.037* 0.061*** -5440.959** (0.004) (739.683) (0.016) (2666.214) Country dummies yes yes yes yes R² adj. 0.004 0.283 0.009 0.278 N 6268 6268 5801 5801 F 4.106 79.183 3.073 62.387 Robust White Standard Errors in Parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 In addition we check whether incumbents who are unable to use deficit spending for electoral purposed compensate by reshuffling more money across budgetary items. Yet, the results remain inconclusive since the estimates turn out statistically insignificant. If anything it seems that governments who use deficit spending before elections also have a higher propensity to engage in strategic budgeteering which would support the results found with respect to transparency. The main findings from tables 6 and 7 are graphically depicted in figure 5: Firgure 5a: pre-election effect on deficit Figure 5b: pre-election effect on long-term items Figure 5c: pre-election effect on short-term items 28 0 2 4 6 Fiscal Transparency 8 10 0 .08 0 .02 .04 .06 pre-election effect on relative shortterm spending Mean of Transparency -.02 -.06 -.04 -.02 0 pre-election effect on relative longterm spending .02 10 8 6 4 2 0 pre-election effect on debt -2 -4 -6 Mean of Transparency 2 4 6 Fiscal Transparency 8 10 Mean of Transparency 0 2 4 6 Fiscal Transparency 8 10 The most striking effect is that when fiscal transparency increases, pre-electoral deficit spending turns from positive to insignificant, however there is still reshuffling going on from long-term items (negative effect) to short-term items (positive effect). Most of the control variables do not exert a significant effect on overall spending, just inflation and capital taxation lead to higher expenditure on all spending items. The models in table 8 test for the second condition – the closeness of election as well as some partisan budgeteering. We interact pre-electoral long- and short-term spending with the margin of the majority and expect that the smaller the margin the higher the propensity for redirecting resources from long-term investment to short-term electoral gifts. And we find exactly this: the more contested the elections the more money is reshuffled. The larger the margin the smaller the need for the incumbent to engage in strategic budgeteering and thus the positive sign for long-term spending and negative coefficient estimates for short-term expenditure. The signs are consistent throughout all models but the coefficients only turn out to be significant for the effect on long-term spending. The findings for pre-electoral reshuffling and transparency remain stable throughout all models. Finally, we test some partisan hypotheses. Based on predictions by Bawn (1999) and Koenig and Troeger (2005) we chose the most obvious partisan items for right-wing and left-wing parties – military (defense) spending and social security & welfare spending. We also examine whether governments increase social security spending before elections in case the economy does badly – the unemployment rate is high. The results are shown in the bottom right corner of table 4 (Model 3e and 3f, grey shaded area). The findings are strong and as expected. Left-wing incumbents spend more on social welfare before elections and right-wing incumbents increase expenditure on defense issues before elections in order to cater to their specific constituency. Independent of partisanship governments increase pre-electoral welfare spending in case the unemployment rate is high. Table 8: Strategic Budgeteering and Closeness of Elections, Partisan Budgeteering 29 Model 3a Relative exp. Model 3c Relative exp. -0.031** Model 3b Total exp. per item 0.090*** (0.007) -6532.98** Model 3e Relative exp. -0.020* Model 3d Total exp. per item 0.093*** (0.009) -6033.321** -0.019* Model 3f Total exp. per item 0.102*** (0.010) -6738.809** (0.015) 0.003* (0.002) 0.006 (2850.240) 280.040** (125.950) 5810.986* (0.013) 0.002* (0.001) 0.010 (2952.013) 346.340** (140.816) 3907.761* (0.014) 0.001 (0.001) 0.015 (2674.757) 372.816*** (129.299) 4695.976 (0.023) 0.039* (4086.931) 10098.556* (0.023) 0.043 (2221.841) 11205.359* (0.025) 0.027* (3048.595) 3630.990* (0.026) -0.004* (0.003) -0.017 (0.061) (7194.097) -636.766* (330.225) -7487.568 (10161.018) (0.036) -0.005* (0.003) -0.028 (0.063) 0.000 (0.000) 0.001 (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) (7522.284) -729.984* (374.857) -8321.073 (10429.683) 84.923** (35.008) 8.118 (72.049) 85.560* (52.075) -0.388 (1.008) (0.018) -0.003* (0.001) -0.004 (0.031) 0.000 (0.001) 0.000 (0.001) -0.000 (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.001) 0.000 (0.000) -0.002* (0.001) 0.034 (0.031) 0.014 (0.017) -0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.037*** (0.002) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.000*** (0.000) 0.030 (0.040) yes 0.172 4916 28.652 (2412.679) -502.394* (313.175) -1.08e+04 (9827.533) 214.210* (109.373) -30.326 (102.137) 87.858* (54.160) 2.523* (1.785) 188.375 (187.133) -0.302* (0.182) -83.586 (152.240) 23124.490** (10130.891) 1383.456 (2413.600) -3.783 (11.113) -1.047 (9.808) 3554.101*** (516.566) 199.355** (91.215) 12.898* (9.051) -2.60e+04** (10842.177) yes 0.325 4916 35.008 Total gov. exp. Preelection longterm spending Pre*long*Transp. Pre*long*Margin maj. Preelection shortterm spending Pre*short*Transp. Pre*short*Margin Inflation Labor tax Capital tax Consump. tax rev. Checks & Balances GDP per capita Unemployment Majoritarian Margin of Majority Left cabinet portf. Right cabinet portf. Pre*unemp*SoSec Pre*Left*SoSec Pre*Right*Def. Intercept 0.073*** -1623.061* 0.062*** -5915.837* (0.005) (861.843) (0.016) (3041.554) Country dummies yes yes yes yes R² adj. 0.004 0.277 0.010 0.273 N 5742 5742 5391 5391 F 4.003 68.301 3.008 55.134 Robust White Standard Errors in Parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 30 CONCLUSION The literature on political business cycles in fiscal policies has come a long way. Most importantly, scholars have highlighted different fiscal strategies which are used by incumbents to increase the voters’ well-being before elections. Additionally, they have investigated into the constraints governments face particularly when employing deficit spending in the pre-election period. They thereby elucidate the conditions under which deficit spending as a strategy to win re-election is effective. Based on the insights of these models which analyze different strategies in isolation, this paper developed an integrated formal model of fiscal strategies in the pre-election period. Most importantly, we analyzed how opportunistic incumbents choose between different fiscal strategies, such as deficit spending and strategic budgeteering, to increase their electoral prospect in the period before the election takes place. One of our main departures from the literature was that we assumed that governments may either spend on long-term efficient investment or short-term efficient public good provision. They increase public good provision in the pre-election period by either raising deficits or by redirecting resources from long-term efficient investments to shortterm efficient public goods. We find that governments principally have an incentive to increase short-term public good provisions if they fear fierce electoral competition and small chances of getting re-elected. To finance these opportunistic policies, governments increase the deficit in the pre-election period. Deficit spending becomes less attractive if fiscal transparency is high (and consequently, fiscally conservative voters would be able to observe the distortive policies of the government) and interest rates rise. The incumbent then faces a trade off between short-term public good provision and long-term efficient investment. Because they cannot use deficit spending under fiscal transparency, governments tend to change the composition of the budget if elections are close. Strategic budgeteering goes at the expense of long-term efficient investments. In other words, long-term efficient fiscal policies are less likely the higher fiscal transparency and the smaller the probability that the incumbent gets re-elected. In a way of summarizing, the model presented here elucidates under which governments either rely on deficit spending or the redistribution of budget resources – what we call strategic budgeteering – in order to increase the voters’ welfare in the period before elections. The model offers a parsimonious account of opportunistic governmental strategies. It thereby provides the basis for several important extensions. First of all, governments do not only face a trade off when choosing alternative fiscal policies. Under certain conditions – e.g. if exchange rates are flexible or central bank independence low – monetary policy instruments become effective leaving fiscal strategies ineffective. An important extension of our model would thus include the possibility to use monetary policies to generate political business cycles. Additionally, we have neither considered partisan preferences nor different forms of strategic budgeteering in our baseline model. However, we expect that different political parties would serve different voters, and thus increase spending on different budget items or have different preferences of raising the deficit. This is directly linked to different forms of re-distributing the budget. While our baseline model simply assumes that governments choose between long-term efficient investment and short-term efficient public goods, redistribution could take several forms. In an extension to the baseline model, it would be thus important to distinguish between, for example, (a) functional, (b) sectoral, and (c) regional budgeteering. 31 The empirical analysis supports most of our predictions, governments engage in strategic budgeteering and they do so the more contested the elections are. However, fiscal transparency seems to reduce all activities that aim at manipulating the electotral business cycle. Moreover, we found some support for partisan budgeteering. The empirical models however need to better take substitution effects as well as simultaneity and endogeneity issues into account. Include: shoud be generalizable. As developing countries become more democratic and open, there should be more evidence of compositional spending over deficit spending. Using OECD countries is a hard test for the argument. (INCOMPLETE) BIBLIOGRAPHY Adolph, C, 2001: Parties, Unions, and Central Banks: an Interactive Model of Unemployment in OECD Countries. Unpublished Working Paper. Akhmedov, Akhmed and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya, 2004: Opportunistic Political Cycles: Test in a Young Democracy Setting, in: Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(4): 1301-1338. Alesina, Alberto (1987): Macroeconomic Policy in a Two-Party System as a Repeated Game, in: Quarterly Journal of Economics 102:651-678. Alesina, Alberto (1988): Macroeconomics and Politics, in: O. Blanchard/S. Fischer (Hrsg.): NBER Macroeconomics and Annual. Cambridge. MA: MIT Press. Alesina, Alberto, 1989: Politics and Business Cycles in Industrial Economies, in: Economic Policy 5, 55-98. Alesina, Alberto, Gerald D. Cohen and Nouriel Roubini, 1992: Macroeconomic Policy and Elections in OECD Democracies, in: Economics and Politics 4: 1-30. Alesina, Alaberto, Nouriel Roubini, and Gerald D. Cohen, 1997: Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy. Cambridge: MIT Press. Alesina, Alberto and Nouriel Roubini, 1992: Political Cycles in OECD Economies, in: Review of Economic Studies 59: 663-88. Alesina, Alberto, Roberto Perotti and José Tavares, 1998: The Political Economy of Fiscal Adjustments. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1998(1): 197-266. Alt, James, 1985: Political Parties, World Demand, and Unemployment: Domestic and International Sources of Economic Activity, in: American Political Science Review 79(4): 10161040. Alt, James E. and David Dreyer Lassen, 2006a: Transparency, Political Polarization, and Political Budget Cycles in OECD Countries, in: American Journal of Political Science 50(3): 530-550. Alt, James E. and David Dreyer Lassen, 2006b: Fiscal Transparency, Political Parties, and Debt in OECD Countries, in: European Economic Review 50: 1403-1439. Andrikopoulos, Andreas, Ioannis Loizides, and Kyprianos Prodromidis, 2004: Fiscal Policy and Political Business Cycles in the EU, in: European Journal of Political Economy 20: 125152. Bawn, Kathleen, 1999: Money and Majorities in the Federal Republic of Germany: Evidence for a Veto Players Model of Government Spending, in: American Journal of Political Science, 707-736. Bernard, William and David Leblang, 1999: Democratic Institutions and Exchange-Rate Commitments, in: International Organization 53: 71-97. 32 Bernard, William and David Leblang, 2002: Democratic Processes and Political Risk: Evidence from Foreign Exchange Markets, in: American Journal of Political Science 46(2): 316333. Bernhard, William T., Lawrence J. Broz and William R. Clark, 2002: The Political Economy of Monetary Institutions. Cambridge: MIT Press. Boix, Charles, 2000: Partisan Governments, the International Economy, and Macroeconomic Policies in Advanced Nations, 1960-93, in: World Politics 53: 38-73. Bräuninger, Thomas, 2005: Do Preferences Make a Difference? Parties and the Composition of Budgets in Nineteen OECD Countries, in: Public Choice 125: 409-429. Brender, Adi, 2003: The Effect of Fiscal Performance on Local Government Election Results in Israel: 1989-1998, in: Journal of Public Economics 87: 2187-2205. Brender, Adi and Allan Drazen, 2005: Political Budget Cycles in New versus Established Democracies, in: Journal of Monetary Economics 52: 1271-1295. Buti, Mario and Paul van der Noord, 2003: Discretionary Fiscal Policy and Elections: The Experience of the Early Years of EMU. OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 351. Clark, William R., 2002a: Capitalism Not Globalism: Capital Mobility, and Political Control of the Economy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Clark, William R., 2002b: Partisan and Electoral Motivations and the Choice of Monetary Institutions under Fully Mobile Capital, in: International Organization 56: 725-749. Clark, William R., Usha N. Reichert, Sandra L. Lomas and Kevin L. Parker, 1998: International and Domestic Constraints on Political Business Cycles in OECD Economies, in: International Organization 52(1): 87-120. Clark, William R. and Mark Hallerberg, 2000: Mobile Capital, Domestic Institutions, and Electorally-Induced Monetary and Fiscal Policy, in: American Political Science Review 94: 323-346. Cusack, Thomas R., 1997: Partisan Politics and Public Finance: Changes in Public Spending in Industrialized Democracies, 1955-1989, in: Public Choice 91: 375-395. De Haan, Jacob and Jan-Egbert Sturm, 1994: Political and Institutional Determinants of Fiscal Policy in the European Community, in: Public Choice 80: 157-172. Drazen, Allan, 2000a: Political Economy in Macroeconomics. New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Drazen, Allan, 2000b: The Political Business Cycle after 25 Years, in: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 15: 75-117. Drazen, Allan and Marcela Eslava, 2005: Electoral Manipulation via Expenditure Composition: Theory and Evidence, in: NBER Working Paper No. W11085. Drazen, Allan and Marcela Eslava, 2005: Pork Barrel Cycles, in: NBER Working Paper No. W12190. Easterly, W, 1999: When is Fiscal Adjustment an Illusion?, in: Economic Policy 14: 57-76. Ferejohn, John, 1999: Acountability and Authority: Towards a Model of Political Accountability, in A. Przeworski, B. Manin, and SC Stokes (eds.): Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. New York: Cambridge University Press. Franzese, Robert J., 1999: Partially Independent Central Banks, Political Responsive Governments, and Inflation, in: American Journal of Political Science 43: 681-706. Franzese, Robert J., 2002a: Electoral and Partisan Cycles in Economic Policies and Outcomes, in: Annual Review of Political Science 5: 369-421. 33 Franzese, Robert J., 2002b: Macroeconomic Policies of Developed Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Franzese, Robert J., 2002c: The Positive Political Economy of Public Debt: An Empirical Examination of the OECD Postwar Experience. Social Science Research Network Working Paper Series. Franzese, Robert J., 2003: Multiple Hands on the Wheel: Empirically Modeling Partial Delegation and Shared Policy control in the Open and Institutionalized Economy, in: Political Analysis 11(4): 445-474. Frey, BS and F Schneider, 1978a: An Empirical Study of Politico-economic Interaction in the United States, in: Review of Economic Statistics 60: 174-183. Frey, BS and F Schneider, 1978b: A Politico-Economic Model of the United Kingdom, in: Economic Journal 88: 243-253. Golden, DG and JM Poterba, 1980: The Price of Popularity: the Political Business Cycle Reexamined, in: American Journal of Political Science 24 (4): 696-714. Goodhart, LM, 2000: Political Institutions, Elections, and Policy Choices. PhD thesis, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA: Hallerberg, Mark, Lucio Vinhas de Souza and William Clark, 2002: Political Business Cycles in EU Accession Countries, in: European Union Politics 3(2): 231-250. Hibbs, Douglas A., 1977. Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy, in: American Political Science Review 23: 1467-1488. Hibbs, Douglas A., 1987. The American Political Economy: Macroeconomics and Electoral Politics in the United States. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. International Monetary Fund, 2003: Germany. Report on Observance of Standards and Codes— Fiscal Transparency. IMF Country Report No. 03/286. Jochimsen, Beate and Robert Nuscheler, 2005: The Political Economy of German Länder Deficits. Unpublished working paper. Kalecki M, 1943: Political Aspects of Full Employment, in: Political Quarterly 7: 322-331. Koening, Thomas and Vera E. Troeger 2005:Budgetary Politics and Veto Players, in Swiss Political Science Review 11(4): 47-75. Leblang, David and William Bernard, 2000a: Political Parties and Monetary Commitments, in William Bernard, J. Lawrence Broz and William R. Clark (eds.): The Political Economy of Monetary Institutions. Cambridge: MIT Press. Leblang, David and William Bernard, 2000b: The Politics of Speculative Attacks in Industrial Democracies, in: International Organization 54: 291-324. Lohmann, Susanne, 1998: Rationalizing the Political Business Cycle: a Workhorse Model. Economic Politics 10: 1-17. Midtbo, Tor, 1998: The Open Politiconomy: A Dynamic Analysis of Social Democratic Popularity and Economic Policies in Scandinavia, in: British Journal of Political Science 28(1): 93-112. Milesi-Feretti, GM, 2004: Good, Bad or Ugly? On the Effects of Fiscal Rules with Creative Accounting, in: Journal of Public Economics 88: 377-394. Mink, Mark and Jakob de Haan, 2005: Has the Stability and Growth Pact Impeded Political Budget Cycles in the European Union? CESIFO Working Paper No. 1532. Nordhaus, William D., 1975: The Political Business Cycle, in: Review of Economic Studies 42: 169-190. 34 Oatley, Thomas H., 1999: Monetary Politics. Exchange-Rate Cooperation in the European Union. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Peltzman, Sam, 1992: Voters as Fiscal Conservatives, in: Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 327-261. Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini, 1990: Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics. London: Harwood. Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini, 2002: Political Economics. Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge: MIT Press. Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini, 2003a: The Economic Effects of Constitutions. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini, 2003b: Do Electoral Cycles Differ Across Political Systems? IGIER Working Paper No. 232. Phillips, Alban W. 1958. The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money: wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957. Economica 25 (100):283-299. Price, Simon, 1998: Comment on “The Politics of the Political Business Cycle.”, in: British Journal of Political Science 28: 201-210. Rogoff, Kenneth, 1990: Equilibrium Political Budget Cycles, in: American Economic Review 80: 21-36. Rogoff, Kenneth and Anne Sibert, 1988: Election and Macroeconomic Cycles, in: Review of Economic Studies 55: 1-16. Romer, David. 2001. Advanced Macroeconomics (2nd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. Rose, Shanna, 2006: Do Fiscal Rules Dampen the Political Business Cycle?, in: Public Choice 128: 407–431. Schneider, Christina J., 2007: Politischer Opportunismus und Haushaltsdefizite in den westdeutschen Bundesländern, in: Politische Vierteljahresschrift 48(2): 221-242. Schneider, Christina, J., 2008: Fighting with One Hand Tied Behind the Back, or: Can Incumbents Use Fiscal Policies for Electoral Gain? Manuscript. Department of Politics and International Relations, University of Oxford. Schultz, Kenneth A., 1995: The Politics of the Political Business Cycle, in: British Journal of Political Science 25(1): 79-99. Schumpeter, J, 1939: Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process. New York: McGraw-Hill. Shi, Min and Jakob Svensson, 2000: Political Business Cycles in Developed and Developing Countries. World Bank Working Paper. Shi, Min and Jakob Svensson, 2002: Conditional Political Budget Cycles. Manuscript, IIES, Stockholm. Shi, Min and Jakob Svensson, 2006: Political Business Cycles: Do they Differ Across Countries and Why?, in: Journal of Public Economics 90(8-9): 1367-1389. Tufte, Edward R., 1978: Political Control of the Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Von Hagen, Jürgen, 2003: Fiscal Discipline and Growth in Euroland. Experiences with the Stability and Growth Pact. ZEI Working Paper No. B062003. Wright, Gavin, 1974: The Political Economy of New Deal Spending: an Econometric Analysis, in: Review of Economic Statistics 56: 30-38. 35 APPENDIX Table A1: Observations for Baseline model: country No. of years Australia 22 Austria 38 Belgium 38 Brazil 5 Canada 38 Czech Republic 17 Denmark 31 Finland 38 France 38 Germany 38 Iceland 31 India 15 Indonesia 17 Ireland 37 Italy 38 Japan 37 Korea 7 Mexico 10 Netherlands 38 New Zealand 18 Norway 38 Poland 1 Portugal 38 Russia 7 Slovak Republic 8 Slovenia 5 Spain 35 Sweden 38 Switzerland 20 Turkey 5 United Kingdom 38 United States 38 36