MANAGEMENT OF CITY-OWNED PROPERTY: A LOW-INCOME HOUSING POLICY FOR NEW YORK CITY by Elizabeth Ann Strom B.A., Swarthmore College (1980) SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS OF THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF CITY PLANNING at the MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY June c 1985 Elizabeth Ann Strom The author hereby grants to M. I. T. permission to reproduce and to thesis document in whole or in part. copies of this distribute Signature of Author Department of " Certified by Urban Studies and Planning 28, 1985 AMay ----------- ~ Phi Iip L. Clay Thesi -Superviso r Accepted by__-----------------------------Chairman, Departme t 1 Committee on M Rotch JUL11 1985 LRA P illip L. Clay sters Students MITLibraries Document Services Room 14-0551 77 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02139 Ph: 617.253.2800 Email: docs@mit.edu hftp://libraries.mit.edu/docs DISCLAIMER OF QUALITY Due to the condition of the original material, there are unavoidable flaws in this reproduction. We have made every effort possible to provide you with the best copy available. If you are dissatisfied with this product and find it unusable, please contact Document Services as soon as possible. Thank you. Some pages in the original document contain pictures, graphics, or text that is illegible. MANAGEMENT OF CITY-OWNED PROPERTY: A LOW-INCOME HOUSING POLICY FOR NEW YORK CITY by ELIZABETH ANN STROM Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning on May 28, 1985 in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Degree of Master of City Planning ABSTRACT Private disinvestment from rental properties in New York City has been a problem now for at least two decades. This process results in the abandonment of buildings, many of which are also In the past twenty years, vacated by tenants. New York City has lost approximately one million housing units. There are different theories about why landlord abandonment occurs. The neoclassical theory focuses on rent regulations and zoning laws as disincentives for reinvestment. Existing are allowed to deteriorate as regulated rents fail structures to cover maintenance and improvement costs. This theory assumes that the private market would be the most effective mechanism for providing housing if only the government would leave it alone. Challenging this theory is the contention that a growing the for number of New Yorkers do not earn enough money to pay rent-to-income upkeep of their rental units. Figures on average are not If peoples' incomes ratios bear out this contention. then government sufficient to support a private housing market, This housed. people are adequately step in to insure that must private sector to continue can be done by subsidizing the providing housing to the poor, or by circumventing the private market altogether. The economic problems that have led to this affordability gap are generally beyond the control of any municipal government. Yet certainly city governments suffer the consequences. City services are taxed by the symptoms of neighborhood deterioration; valuable. the city tax base is erroded as property becomes less completely; In the most extreme cases, property loses its value foreclosure the city government becomes its actual owner through taxes. In some New York City for non-payment of real estate percentage the municipal government owns a sizeable neighborhoods property. of the residential New York City appears to be unique in the extent of its taxWhile vacant foreclosed inventory and its methods of managing it. Most occupied buildings are not. buildings are sold at auction, city's housing agency. are managed by the occupied properties Others enter one of several alternative management programs; the goal of most of these is to sell the building to the tenants as limited equity cooperative. a been problemnone of these programs has While certainly all have been effective in providing shelter to the poorest free, segment of the population living in the most delapidated housing. alternative of current the long term success Doubts about management programs center around the lack of resources devoted to city buildings enter fact that most In spite of the them. city programs with every major system deteriorated, ownership rehabilitation of only a few thousand dollars toward the devote The future of these housing programs seem imperiled by each unit. the frayed shoestring on which they must operate. require for city-owned propertry would not funding Proper in program with a change In fact, new resources. substantial the to ensure more would be needed $20 million design., only be This is money that would viability of each unit. structural since the city's failure to invest in its properties spent, well today will only lead to greater expenses tomorrow. more of attracting should explore ways officials While adequate fact in sources, and tapping private money federal An equitable tax funding should be available in the city budget. developers for abatements not be would there which in system, revenue to sufficient generate would areas, in lucrative operating pay for the renovation of city-owned residential buildings. Thesis Supervisor: Title: Associate Dr. Phillip L. Clay Professor of Urban Studies and Planning TABLE OF CONTENTS Abstract Table of Contents INTRODUCTION............................................... . . ...... 1 A. Traditional Responses to Gaps in the Supply of and the Demand for Housing: The Case of New York City......... .2 B. Housing Costs and Renter Incomes in New York City...... .4 1. The Rent Gap Today: A Snapshot................... .5 2. The Rent Gap: Trends............................. .7 C. The Southside.......................................... 10 D. What is the In Rem Housing Program?.................... 12 PART I 1. Landlord Abandonment................................... A. The Dymanics of a Declining Neighborhood............... B. Portraits of Slum Landlords............................ 17 17 21 2. A. ..1 a Tax Delinquency and Foreclosure.... .. a Overview........................... .. a B. Tax Delinquency in New York City... C. City Ownership and Tax Delinquency in the Southsi de. .. a D. Conclusions........................ 27 27 29 35 42 PART II 3. Antecedents to the In Rem Housing Program. A. Homeownership for the Poor................. B. Self-Help Housing and Sweat Equity........ C. Early New York City Cooperatives.......... D. Early City-Sponsored Cooperatives......... .45 .46 .48 .50 .53 .57 4. Creation of Current In Rem Programs....... .57 A. The Office of Property Management......... B. The Division of Property Management: Public Landlord......60 5. A. B. C. 6. A. B. C. Management Progr ams: Creation of the Division of Alternative Application of Self-Help Housing Models to Management of CityOwned Property.......................... ................ a a ... 68 The Community Management Program........ .. 69 ................ a ... 72 Tenant Interim Leasing.................. .. 74 a a a Why Self-Help?.......................... ................ .. 75 1. Critiques of Self-Help: I.......... . .a............. U 2. Critiques of Self-Help: II......... ... 83 DAMP's Effectiveness in Creating Tenant Lack of Alternatives............ ...... Sales Policy.................... .. Aaa.. a Financial Viability............. 195 South Fourth Street....... 167 Havemeyer Street.......... Cooperati ves. ......... ......... ......... ......... ......... aa aa as ... ... ... 92 93 95 .. 98 .. 102 .. 106 7. A. B. C. PART 8. A. B. C. D. E. A Proposed Alternative Management Tenant Leasing: Assisted 112 Model.......... 112 Program Design.. a ...................... 116 Sales Policy.... e...................... 117 . . . . . . . . . . Program Rational e. III Funding the In Rem Housing Program......... How Much for In Rem Housing?............... Additional Government Funding Sources...... Housing Trust Funds. Alternative Funding Sources: The Cross-Subsidy Program.................. . .n . . An Equitable Tax System.................... 119 121 124 125 132 133 CONCLUSION....................................................136 A. The Future of In Rem Housing..............................138 APPENDICES Systems, Summary of Changes in New York City Rent Regulati on 1. 142 ........ a. 1943 through the present......................... ........ a. 143 2. The Redemption Process............................ ........ 146 3. The Legal Status of DAMP cooperatives............. Costs for In Rem Calculating Projected used for 4. Assumptions ........ 148 Buildings........................................ 5. Sources for Proposed Housing Trust Fund...................149 BIBLIOGRAPHY...................................................152 GIntroduction INTRODUCTION ... for most of the last three decades housing groblems have generally been confined to low-income and minority people. Others have had housing inconveniences. 1 -- Cushing Dolbeare study This was motivated need provide to public Although there has been a adequate housing for the poor. to provide basic needs such as food and health care to commitment There publicly supported housing is available only to a few. all, is by the urgent consensus streets, but that people should not be driven to live there is no consensus on how to provide in the sufficient housing to avoid this consequence. Difficulty in defining national in luxury, distribution of housing involve construction and finance industries, some these participants. the many levels of and the each of which makes money at Consumers of housing are point in the process. supporting Finding a way to provide housing to those incomes aren't sufficient to motivate this establishment is whose therefore over The production good and investment. consumer due necessity Housing is both part to its schizophrenic nature. and all policies for housing is complex. past four decades reflect the needs owners. The constant shifts in the consumers, No group has been able to find an efficient way to create low-income housing. 1 policies disagreement about who developers, to be subsidized--the government or most the and equitable Rarely real has a public program worked outside of estate industry, profits. the endeavoring to limit costs by private eliminating This is precisely the approach of New York City's In Rem Housing Program. This program represents New York's attempt to handle the thousands of occupied housing units that have come into its ownership by virtue of the former owner's failure property taxes. It is thus a program by default, Gradually, officials city have begun to see treating (or the impossibility of stock. They together, have offer low-income not by design. the necessity programs that, unique and comprehensive means of housing. In pay of ignoring) their occupied housing developed a series of a to rem housing programs, taken preserving most of which replace traditional control, have taken root only because of the private sector's lack of interest subsidies. in private providing management with low-income public housing or tenant without deep But they offer alternatives to the for-profit housing system that could extend beyond the landlord-abandoned stock. A~. Traditional Res29ones2 to Ga2sin the SU221Y of and the Demand for Housing: than The Case of New York City More than any other city, New York is a renter's town. Less 30"/ owns of that With the of the population its housing, and 2 percentage predominance (75%) 7.3% live in cooperative apartments of multi-family apartment live in investor-owned rather . buildings, than most owner renters occupied 3 buildings .When tax burdens become too high in other cities, property owners lobby for changes in tax assessments. York the voices of small of But in New property owners are drowned out by those tenants demanding rent regulations and developers lobbying for tax abatements. take This may explain why New York has been able such bold steps in seizing landlord and tax-delinquent to buildings: the homeowner lobby has relatively little influence policy-making. The city is further unique in the fact that in most landord-abandoned property is of the multi-family tenement stock. Furthermore, New York has lost an astounding 360,000 housing 4 units since 1970, the equivalent of this loss has persisted A Table inspite of four Bostons Paradoxically . low vacancy rates: Net Vacancy Rates By Mognthly Contact ityn 12h4 RentL NRw York New York City Rental Monthly Contract Rent Vacancy RatS Total 2.04% Less than $100 $100-$124 $125-$149 .52 1.44 .26 .69 .37 $150-$174 $175-$199 $200-$249 $250-$299 $300-$399 1.50 2.18 1.45 1.77 2.99 $400-$499 $500 or more Source: Stegman, from 1984 Housing and Vacancy Survey This apparent contradiction exists because most New Yorkers pay Units enough that can't rent to make proper building maintenance worthwhile. are standing abandoned, whether they are left or demolished, are no longer considered part of the housing stock and therefore are not included in the calculation of the vacancy rate. The bulk of housing loss occured during economic distress for the entire faster than renters' incomes, these city. and total the 1970s, a time of Operating population fell. trends have begun to reverse in the 1980s, housing abandonment has slowed. costs rose Some of and the rate of For the first time since before 1970 there was a net gain of nearly 85,000 housing units, although a continued drop in the number of rental housing units. Between 5 1981 . and 1984 population rose by 1.1'4 rates The very low vacancy reflect the impact of population growth on a housing market not yet recovered from the disasterous 1970s. B. Housing Cgts and Renter Incomes in New York City The difficulty of providing housing for low-income has increased over the past few years, risen must faster than incomes. reflects a continuing trend, housing quality sheltering between it as the as operating costs is so severe that it In most New York critical City the has replaced barrier 4 to discrepancy what people can pay and what the market demands is indeed. have This affordability crisis, which nation's population. families large 1. The Rent Gap Tgdgyi Today, a month. A Snagshgt the median apartment in New York City rents for $330 Median income for all New York renters is close to 6 $13,000 a year A tenant earning the median and paying a quarter . of his or her gross income for rent could afford $270.00 a $60 below the median. month, This gap would be closed if the rent-income ratio were increased to one-third, in which case the median tenant pay $360.00 a month. could for a single person, While this might be a feasible ratio however, a family with children 7 pressed to pay one-third of a small A comparison is hard- income for shelter of median rents and median incomes is not an adequate measure of housing affordability in New York for several reasons. First, $330.00 of 1,901,000 rental units in the city. a month is the median This includes the units run by the New York City Housing Authority rents in which 218,000 apartments median rent the With a waiting list of over ten years, NYCHA apartments are not actually available on the are rent-controlled of $259 a month brings down market. (see Appendix the Similarly, 1) their city-wide median. the current city regulations apartments become decontrolled upon vacancy. be (NYCHA), all 168,000 are held to 27% of a tenant's income and subsidized by federal government. Under rent Therefore these apartments cannot be considered to available on the market at those apartments, or 17.5% of the rental rents. In total, stock, are either not available or not available at current low rents in any meaningful snapshot of the rental situation 386,000 sense. is somewhat misleading; A current tenants in place enjoy a reasonable median rent, but those seeking apartments are faced with another supply curve altogether. In as New a city encompassing such extremes of wealth and York suspect. that does, black monthly rent family, which but the actual median can afford $166.00, Clearly, housing for instance, under $13,000, Hispanics many only $229.00 the $298.00; is is Hispanic is confronted with a $275.00 minority families are far more constrained market. for median average black family can comfortably pay a The median. it is $11,000 a year and for renters $8,000. problem a A breakdown of the statistics will reveal while annual income for all renters is just for the any aggregate measure such as poverty That finding an affordable apartment is families is indicated by the 32.9% of in a all 8 households paying over 40% of their income for rent Another inadequacy affordability rents may is not that, of the median rent as in severely deteriorated reflect the actual cost of running a measure of neighborhoods, a building. Landlords serving low-income tenants are frequently delinquent in their property tax payments (see Chapter Two) or in their building Their tenants pay low rents but maintenance practices. substandard housing in return. well What it costs to run a receive building may be higher than the median rent in poor neighborhoods. 6 2. The Rent Gap: Trends These figures suggest that, even in the absence of all other deterrents, low incomes are enough to prevent occupying decent private housing. rent the poor A look at the trends affecting levels and incomes shows that the rent gap will most increase, especially for the poor. abandonment median peaked, operating shocks of 1973 and likely During the 1970s, when owner expenses rents and median incomes. property owners--fuel from rose faster than Two of the largest costs and capital--were climbing rapidly. 1979 drove the price of oil from both for The oil a reported 9 twelve cents a gallon were marginal in While faster 1970 to $1.05 a gallon in 1980. the prime rate jumped from 5% to same time, expenses in than is less of levelling off, incomes. a problem today median rents are From 1981 to 1984, real dollars) of 10 5.8% . renters actually fell 4.4% while real number of coop conversions: became coop or condominium owners,. calculated This as in operating still increasing income (in rents increased the because many upper income their incomes are part of the renter total. large renters no But there are 1967 longer factors Landlords feel are entitled to recover the profits they claim to have lost the legal and disparity is due at least in part to other than a shift in tenure preference at work. they Properites that 1970 would be losing money ten years later. inflation are 18%. At the 1970s, and the Rent Guidelines Board, rent levels in New York City, determines has granted increases changes in operating costs in recognition of 7 which their claims. above Thus crises: New be Subscribers notion one City is experiencing supply and affordability. problems opens York addressed to when the by increased new follow housing, the government public policy disincentives that (e.g., "trickle as down" filtering housing. (e.g., the this expensive, below. would best be It development by rent by would served by a removing regulations) tax abatements). tax cuts for the rich have never into process promoted embrace as housing vacated zoning restrictions and and offering incentives just interest housing production. however group is filled by the group just that But housing filtration up units all the way down the line, income related Logic would dictate that both popular theory of they reason that two bank accounts doesn't appear to Weinstein proposes several of the provide managed poor, adequate so to the low-cost reasons for its failure: open to has barriers housing market ... the competition and the easy movement of dwellings from one group of users to another, such as fixity of location, zoning, deed restriction, discrimination and simply because of the lack of a surplusli. Critics of the filtration theory have pointed to the plight of residents of the Bronx, where the construction of the 60,000-unit, middle-income of sound apartments. middle-class but Coop City project was expected to open up thousands they Apartments vacated by the primarily Coop City residents were occupied by black soon deteriorated 8 into slums and many wbite tenants, are now 12 . abandoned Whatever the dynamics that lead to deterioration and building abandonment the next chapter), new, high-rent neighborhood (they will be explained in this example suggests that the construction of units provides an insufficient guarantee of improved housing conditions for the poor. It is also unlikely that rent subsidies alone can compensate for the paucity of adequate, to enable renters theoretically families, except into opening seek up new apartments They are meant at higher opportunities for rents, low-income but the extremely low vacancy rates in-New York for all luxury housing question. above to affordable housing. (see Table A) Rental bring this line of subsidies would have to reasoning bring families the $500-a-month level to give them a significantly chance of finding subsidies to all supply an apartment. Even then the better issuance of eligible renters without any increase in housing would merely raise the base rent for slum housing without necessarily improving conditions. The inadequacy of such provisions for low-income led to the inception of other federal for instance, offering 231-unit costs of HUD's Section 8, tried to address both supply and affordability by construction developers. programs. families But Harlem financing and generous rent subsidies the projects sponsored by Section 8, apartment complex with estimated to such as a construction $80,000 a unit and requiring another $12,440 a year to 13 subsidize exorbitant rentals building , only and seemed to waste tax operating costs render 9 dollars. the Such systematic construction politically 'of new poor both course, such deep subsidies benefit the developers than the tenants. the premise deteriorated of and more Poor families can be housed just as comfortably less expense in moderately renovated units. lies impractical unpopular. Of at units for the of the In Rem Housing In this assumption which Program, saves housing units before they succumb to the last stages It achieves moderate rehabilitation at abandonment. minimal but developers, cost by relying for renovation not on for-profit on the tenants themselves. do What It's too expensive to construct new units for the poor, housing? and affordable units population is the affluent for construction new open will no especially up, While newly growing. now is must abandonment. simultaneously The reduce since New York's units constructed the loss that guarantee units of this In Rem Housing Program addresses are city housing, necessary to accomodate the demand for market-rate policy low-income these trends suggest for the future of through latter issue. C. The Southside Because interesting trends that aggregate data can obscure so many disparate I felt it was important to study factors, in one neighborhood. is experiencing I wanted to examine a private 10 disinvestment, but and housing neighborhood is not a SI' V \. [ .4: * 0 0 * I 0 L * U I F 7 0 a b# P U P SOUTHSIDE STUDY AREA & . 1*j V.. .1 '2' t * * - - See - - REIENTIAL DEVELOPMENT wasteland. I chose the Southside, comprising the 1. Although it of is lotated in other Southside has much Harlem Williamsburg-Greenpoint section neighborhoods of Northern for a number of reasons: Brooklyn, woes one of several Brooklyn and shares many of the neighborhoods in the "outer boroughs.," is only ten minutes from downtown Manhattan. in common with Manhattan neighborhoods such and the Lower East Side, where the trend toward the It as the depreciation of property values is beginning to be reversed. There are the first signs of land speculation but few yet of gentrification or upgrading. 2. 40% of the Southside's housing stock--turn-of-the century tenements--resembles that of Manhattan neighborhoods, but the many one- to-four- unit brownstones are similar to those in other Brooklyn neighborhoods. The population therefore contains both tenants and homeowners. 3. There is a high incidence of city ownership in this area and many city-owned buildings are in alternative management programs. Because of the long history of tenant management in the Southside I was able to interview tenants in longestablished cooperatives as well as those living in buildings still undergoing conversion. 4. The Southsi.de is one of the poorest neighborhoods (see Table B) in the city. The In Rem Housing Program's effectiveness in this area would therefore indicate whether the program can indeed create housing opporunities least affluent. ii for the Table B A Profile The Southside: Number of persons Number of households Persons per household 22,872 7,493 3.05 Persons of Spanish origin Population of Spanish origin 20,146 88% Labor Force participation 52% (labor force/population.aged 16-65) Unemployment 11.7% Median income $6,319 Receiving Public Assistance 30.0% Source: D. Census What Is the In Rem Housing Program? Officially, in 1980 the In Rem Housing Program (described at length Chapters Three and Four) is the means by which New handles its abundant stock of occupied, York City landlord-abandoned, tax- foreclosed housing. foreclosed stock are among the poorest in the city--their annual But since tenants living in income is $4,000 less than the median for all IRHP is, occupied rental in effect, the taxmedian renters--the a housing program for the poor. The 46,000 in rem units represent only 2.4% of the city's occupied 14 stock but they are clustered in deteriorated neighborhoods: these areas, where there is little private market activity, handling neighborhood the housing of policy. 12 city-owned On the property other becomes hand, the city-owned represent buildings the gentrified neighborhoods; the poor housing last islands of affordable in their disposition decides the future of in those areas. While many occupied, city-owned buildings are managed by the the Department of Housing Preservation housing agency, city Development, one-third of the units are managed by other sponsors. able of these are tenant and community groups which are Many the buildings, purchase has IRHP The is management and as cooperatives. after some renovation, tremendous impact in taking hold, for where neighborhoods traditional unlike to tenant production programs, it builds on community strengths and ultimately develops local institutions studying in the process of In Rem Housing Program we have the the housing. developing opportunity In to evaluate the applicability of such alternative forms of management to a large housing program. small-scale none but Many cities have experimented with tenant management and/or sweat equity projects, but of treatment for the IRHP this has proposed kind thousands of units. and propose a similar alternative program that confronts.some important issues, such as In this thesis I describe the IRHP, insuring the long-term viability of tenant-managed buildings, and determining an appropriate role for community organizations, which the current program handles poorly. I make this proposal bearing in mind that there are a few things that the IRHP is 1. It is not a solution to all 13 city-wide housing not. problems. It not is even a complete solution to It builds no new units, problems. housing low-income and is limited to those buildings that are abandoned by their owners. apartments. not a proposal for renovating vacant is It 2. vacant renovate is no low-cost way to there Unfortunately buildings. which was once envisioned as Even sweat equity, can a means of creating housing for low-income families, no longer produce inexpensive units. presents a model of for the management of While it 3. property in the absence of private investment, it does not provide a means or a rationale for taking low-income housing Thus it out of private hands when there is market interest. cannot support the efforts of low-income housing advocates in gentrifying neighborhoods. 4. This is not an alternative to publicly subsidized housing. subsidies The needed this for program are lower much on than those for rehabilitation programs that depend private developers and those for public housing, but they are necessary. thesis This addresses the question, house its poor in the absence of private interest government sufficient federal funds?" need to maintain the New York City, connect Part landlord-abandoned properties of described the Southside, low-income as and outlined some of Part I landlord abandonment and neighborhood these processes with the phenonmenon of tax II will the The introduction has presented backround data points of the In Rem Housing Program. theories whether or tenant control best addresses public agency, housing resources. on In this pAIper I will contrast the in rem housing alternatives and further question for-profit, and New York City's response to that query is its In Rem Housing Program% current municipal "How can a contain a description of 14 will examine decline, and delinquency. the components of the In Rem Housing Program, tenant and questions concerning its basic premise--that management can save landlord-abandoned housing. The strengths and shortcomings of the IRHP will also be examined, with suggestions for improvement. In Part III I will discuss the financial resources needed for a viable program, and identify some potential funding sources. Notes for Introduction 1. Cushing Dolbeare, "The Low Income Housing Crisis," in Chester Hartman, ed., America's Housing Cisis: What Is To Be (Washington D.C.: Institute for Policy Studies, 1983). Done? 2. Michael Stegman, Hggging in New York: Study of a Qity (New York: Department of Housing Preservation Development, 1985) 45. 12@!L and 3. Committee on Housing and Urban Development, Recommendations of the In Rem Housing Task Force," Service Society, 1981) 1. 4. Robert Schur, "Growing Lemons in the Bronx," (July/August 1980) 42. 5. Stegman, 6. IBID "Report and (Community uggsing in New York, Working PgggEM, 10. 7. Michael Stone, "Housing and The Economic Crisis: An Analysis and An Emergency Program," in Chester Hartman, ed. America's Housing gCisis. 8. 9. Stegman, Houging in New York, Mel jagazine Ziegler, 11. Jerome I. George 1976), "Biography of an Unwanted Building," New (May 24,1971), 10. Stegman, Weinstein, ed. York 30. uggsing in New York, Sternlieb, 146. 122. "Housing Subsidies: HousingL 1973-4 An Overview," (New York: AMS in Press, 84. 12. Joseph Shuldiner, quoted in Joseph Berger, "Failure of Plan for Homeless Reflects City Housing Crisis," New York Times 19 February 1985. 15 "New York City's Housing Cycle: Seymour Durst, 13. Down, "Emgire State RgggEt 9 (July 1983), 20. 14. Stegman, Huggging in New York, 16 228. Down and GPart I CHAPTER ONE: A of study of LANDLORD ABANDONMENT city-owned housing must begin with a landlord abandonment. owns nearly landlords worth 10,000 at After all, residential if the City of buildings it is discussion New York now because some point decided that keeping them was no the trouble. empty hulks of While the term abandonment evokes buildings, in fact not all by their owners end up vacant. investors have remainder of walked from many their longer images of buildings that are left This chapter explains why private New York neighborhoods. The this thesis is about what happens to the people left behind. A. Ih DyggMics of a Declining Ngighbghgood There is no simple explanation of landlord abandonment. might think--and many housing analysts continue to One maintain--that unwise government policies, such as excessive property tax burdens and stringent rent controls, might have discouraged owners from maintaining their properties and ultimately led them to walk away. Profiles of all slum landlords dating back through the 1970, failed to regulations studies of neighborhoods landlords rents any contributed have existence find evidence that to either 1 disinvestment . taxes or Other national shown no correlation between abandonment 2 rent control . More likely, tenants are paying all they can for their are charging what the market will bear. would not produce higher market rents, 17 however, and in apartments, Higher rent the slum and legal and therefore would have no impact on a landlord's ability to maintain his property. The to phenomenon of the demographic changes associated with exodus of It abandonment bears a striking correlation -- "white flight" city. largely middle-class residents out of the white, the is sad to think that white families would rather abandon their neighborhoods only talk than live with Blacks and Hispanics, need as strongholds white families in such white to but one the Northwest Bronx and the southeastern part of Brooklyn to sense the fear with which they view the entry of people of color into neighborhoods. building--and racial The a rapid exodus of an entire population makes a neighborhood--vulnerable between the slumlord and the tenant. process, possible Black they to dynamic also comes into play in the milking their described abandonment. hostile The relationship The ugly last phases of the later in more detail, are in part because of a white landlord's disrespect for his or and Hispanic tenantry. can live without heat Since they somehow "don't her count," in the winter and have drug dealers as neighbors without causing their landlord much guilt. This dynamic 3 is apparent in the previously cited studies conversations and with Southside landlords. The impossible connection between disinvestment and ethnic change to ignore but difficult to explain. Stegman is posits that the lower incomes, larger families and different attitudes of non-white the in-movers have an impact on the quality of cost of maintaining it. attitude toward its and He further suggests that a family's apartment may be more is housing important than its income for estimating the potential in "If deterioration: gets or creates a tenant who does not seem to care, landlord net earnings are partially cut. . . a his and there is some incentive to 4 allow the property to deteriorate" . More precisely., tenant can double the cost of maintaining his or her the landlord and tenant are of thus properties, for potential process decreasing personal contact and increasing the rapid turnover in a neighborhood At the first signs of will declare a neighborhpod off-limits. becomes a self-fulfilling prophecy. and abandon it. of the to sell forced the devoting transition, banks, Thus disinvestment Even landlords who want maintain their buildings can no longer get financing, sometimes area's beginning abandonment discourages public agencies from resources to that area. too, an so much on the investors' confidence in the of his he may even be afraid to investment decisions in both the private and public hinge stability, unquantifiable antagonism. Because sector When visit for instance; tenants, races, unit. The landlord may be willing to take advantage of problems arise. the different a careless to are and so to a slumlord who will milk the building The timidity of lenders can have a subtler low-income housing market. Because of the high impact risks associated with inner city investments, banks may look for shorter increasing the monthly debt service burden on This added pressure compels the landlord to for ways of increasing his or her income to maintain his or pay-back the look periods, property owner. her bank payments. Bank red-lining cannot be blamed entirely for disinvestment, however; one study found that over three-quarters of the landlords in some inner-city neighborhoods would not 5. improvements even if long-term financing were available The loss inability of withdrawal private capital neighborhood amenities. the to have converted only in the but also in the It is the removal deterioration of a recreational site that to an area's residents. decline is evident not property owners to get financing, of landmark, seems of a movie Every I@W=i@ME@f theater that into a Pentacostal church. is Withdrawal abandonment City either abandoned of public Many Brooklynites swear that services since neighborhoods also the fiscal crisis of 1975 "triage" policy, poor services abandonment. be fighters such Public as sanitation as a factor for instance, this the issue in New caused allowing In leading city the the cited to deterioration withdrawal from an arson-prone neighborhood can result of housing units. to landlords service reduction and housing very closely linked; demonstrated and Ebbets to become even more underserved. Women's City Club study of a Bronx neighborhood, can 1957, contributes This has been a controversial administrators to adopt a de facto poorest or of the borough's decline. process. ever a signals the public housing project constructed on the site of Field as a symbol York of R@!@h9BFhSS9 Brooklyn began to go downhill when the Dodgers left in see make of fire in the loss The residents of the Northside of Williamsburg connection seven years ago. In this neighborhood, dominated by wood frame houses, arson was becoming a 20 disturbingly common means of landlord abandonment. closed the only local firehouse. neighborhood protest Yet the city The residents, seeing that their was doomed without firefighting services, began a that included a year-long occupation of the firehouse and culminated in a demonstration blocking rush-hour traffic Brooklyn-Queens Expressway. neighborhood services survived. on The firehouse was reopened, More commonly, however, and the the decline of that leads to abandonment is more gradual neighborhood residents are less capable of the and therefore perceiving and halting it. B.Portraits of Slum Landlords Responding to the stereotypes of the 1950s and led to slum clearance policies, 1969 -and 1970 studies, slumlord Their showed Sternlieb and Stegman, that, minority one-third sixty years old, Newark, professional of property owners, Pittsburgh, 45% of in unconscionable of inner-city property owners in while that their were determined to debunk the myth of as a big-time operator reaping profiles 1960s of profits. several landlords made up a cities sizable the rest were a diverse group. inner city property owners and one-half earned under $10,000 all landlords were craftspeople, a the were 6 year . In over In workers or small real estate only 21% professionals in the businesspeople,- and 7 field . In New York City, where the predominance of multi-family tenements would seem to lend itself to the owners were professionals. only 31% of or small businesspeople; 15% 21 professional ownership, 34% were craftspeople were retired or unemployed, and the 8 balance was split among between miscellaneous professions Of cism. course, First, this breakdown must be viewed with some skepti- percentages refer to the population of the number of housing units. Professional represent one-third of all owners, units. In Baltimore, percentage of total for real but control instance, owners, not estate people may two-thirds of fifty landlords--a property owners--were found to all small control one- 9 quarter owners of the inner-city rental inventory can register their buildings in the name of or another individual. Stegman profitable and property, transformation explain Rolf the corporation large landlords. Sternlieb describe landlords operating rental invested. a property In the Southside buildings were sometimes "owned" by mothers, sons or associates of the Second., . of the many of whom seemed neighborhoods in barely overwhelmed which they had Goetze created a typology of property owners housing market in a similarly transitional by to Boston 10 neighborhood Type B, . His Type A, Blue-Collar landlords. returns Established Owners and Managers, and Investors, describe most of Stegman's Both types operate in stable markets, count on steady and security, and make their money by providing decent housing. But difficult the economic trends of for such owners to make a profit. introduction made clear, income the 1970's made it increasingly As the data in the escalating operating costs have outpaced gains for most renters. Between 1970 and 1976, rents in 11 New York City rose 179% faster than renters' incomes these figures, a profit Type A and B landlords who had been barely earning in 1970 were, unattractive options. or they could sell Whichever of contribute for by 1978 or to the Operatorsq faced Goetze's Type D these options the original landlords to the decline of the building and running them down without concern with two the landlords. chose, they neighborhood, unprofitable buildings by for housing quality in a process "milking." One of the more intriguing aspects of New York's real estate market is the persistence of Southside, buildings which 1980, They could walk away from their buildings, the Operator makes a living off of known as Given . title reveal marginal these Operators. In the searches and interviews with tenants in a dozen a pattern: Most of had been owned by an individual these New Law tenements, or family for decades, were at some point sold to a corporate entity that represented one of a small group of local landlords. the death of the original owner, point The rapid after but often price to cluster around increases. 1973-4 and Robert followed it seemed to come at a which he could no longer make a sales seemed oil In some cases the sale Schur legitimate 1979-80, suggests profit. times that of many original landlords who sold to Operators were "not sufficiently 12 cognizant of ["milking"'s] nuances " . Tenant reports of decreased undesirable Activists services, tenants from illegal coincided rent increases, with the and an change in other low-income neighborhoods report identical to that in the Southside. influx of ownership. a pattern There is money to be made in unfortunately for those who live in them, from them well running "milks" a by avoiding as many will foreclose started possible: be reluctant to foreclose. to an longer. on a property after one year of water, and landlord end result only and in Chapter possible even action and hot Meanwhile the Peter Salins describes the slipshod repairs. continues to collect rent. of this the services provide limited heat infrequent, of indebtedness, installment agreement that delays Maintenance Debt (although legally the city and even when the city threatens foreclosure it is sign to Payment fact foreclosures take place every three years or so--see Two) owner because the landlord knows that the property taxes can be avoided for years can as An not because the building was purchased for or postponable, holder expenses already but comes but from running them poorly. service is either minimal, very little, buildings, the profit profit from a building which has deteriorate mortgage these process: A combination of aggressive rent collection efforts, minimal maintenancetax delinquency, low purchase down payments, and delinquency in paying off purchase money mortgages can permit an owner to make a handsome profit for a limited time, even as he writes off a larger portion of the rent roll and depreciates the asset value of the property to zero by walking away from his building when its economic potential is exhausted (13). The extent Operators alternatives in of disinvestment poor neighborhoods available to city 24 and the preponderance circumscribe officials. For the of policy instance, a slumlord whose profit comes from milking will not necessarily provide adequate services if government subsidies allow his or her tenants to pay higher rents. Even a more reputable property.owner might not feel that rent subsidies assured a sufficient income merit new investment. such as those government, tenantry. currently might necessarily Interest subsidies on improvement offered encourage A program landlord-tenant Another from landlords to by the city renovate but not to deal with a deteriorated neighborhood loan money with subsidized rents. this expensive proposition still does not address some of the less tangible but, New landlords loans, to maintain rents affordable to the former low-income would have to couple subsidized And to to as Stegman's study which has become the unarticulated policy York City, manager. The foreclosure in is not to try to stop landlords from walking away their unprofitable properties. of significant tensions that contribute to neighborhood decline. alternative, management demonstrated, In the landlord's these buildings is handed over to a legal statute mechanism for doing this not-for-profit is that allow the city to seize tax properties and then either run them itself to low-income housing providers. Housing Program. 25 absence, the tax delinquent or negotiate their sale This is the basis of the In Rem Notes on Chapter One 1. Michael Stegman, uggsing Inyestment in the Inner City, (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1972) ; George Sternlieb, Ihe Tenement Landlord, (New Brunswich: Center for Urban Policy Research, 1969); and Women's City Club, With Love and Affection: A Study g Building ebagdonments (New York, 1977). 2. Peter Marcuse, Housing Obandonment: Does Rent Control Make a Difference? (Washington D.C.: Conference of Alternative State and Local Policy, 1977). Stagman, 3. Landlord, Housing Investmimnt, Stern1iab, and Women's City Club. 4. Stegman, 5. Sternlieb, The Tenenement Landlord,201. IbM oggsing Ieestment,163. 6. George Sternlieb and Robert Lake, "The Dynamics Estate Tax Delinquency," National Tax Journal 29 (1976), 7. Sternlieb, 8. Ibid. 9. Stegman, 10. Iioament of Real 265. The Tenement Lanldord. ousing lneystment,27. Understanding Neighbrgood Change: The Role of Ballinger Revitalization, (Cambridge: 81-82. Rolf Goetze, xgaeStations Press, 1979), in Urban 11. Harry DiRienzo and Joan B. Allen, It New York City In Housing EcggERg, (New York: Urban Coalition, 1985),13. 12. Robert Schur, "Growing Lemons in (July/August 1980),44. 13. Peter Salins, Effects of Public the Bronx," Rem Wgring Pagng The Ecology gf Hgsing Destruction: Economic Intervention in the Housing Market, (New York : New York University Press, 1980), 26 14. CHAPTER TWO: TAX-DELINQUENCY AND FORECLOSURE A. Overview Separate abandonment from is but not independent the phenomenon of tax of the problem delinquency. of Certainly property can be neglected and vacated while the landlord continues to pay property taxes., but a building is not truly abandoned long as the taxes are being paid. city's one policy, in private hands, to this study. and how an understanding of the process tax foreclosure of tax affects low foreclosure. that willingness to enforce its own tax laws is integral tax property today and in years It becomes clear is income Lastly it looks at the status of the Southside to determine the impact, come, marginal This chapter explains real estate property housing in New York City. in foreclosure is the instrument for halting the deterioration of properties important Since tax as the to city's to the success of any programs treating the in rem housing stock. Threatened seizure of tax-delinquent properties is, cities, the means of enforcing tax collection. like bank foreclosures, are in rem actions, the title to the property is thing," in which further claim against the owner is made. obligate Such or actions In rem for most seizures, "against vested but actions, no which the city only to inform owners by sending notices to the address on the building registration record, are preferred to 27 in personam lawsuits, which must be done individually that the owner be served personally with all in personam and require legal papers. While actions might be more effective for recovering lost tax dollars, they would be burdensome to any city with more than a token tax foreclosure case load. It play is in the abandonment process. properties deciding In hard to say just what role real estate do not factor fact, abandonment point that payments owners of marginal tax burdens landlord walks away from his correlate taxes with are Of course, desire higher taxes; the investment. likelihood find that landlords with higher tax burdens are likely to abandon. owners suggest that property when a studies Studies of tax of less this does not imply that property it only underscores the self-evident that owners of more valuable properties are less likely to walk away from their investments. Tax delinquency need not be a sign of disinvestment. payment penalties are below market interest rates,- many If late property owners will be slow in their payments since it costs them less, in effect, to "borrow" money from the city than the bank. cities have uniform or expeditious foreclosure policies, little incentive to be punctual in real is thus possible that some degree of there is estate tax payments. It tax delinquency can exist and not indicate any problems in an area's housing market. 28 Since few High rates of tax abandonment, owners however, delinquency are generally associated and indicate a housing market so weak that are willing to lose their property. A rule of business is that a firm must cover all operate; fixed costs can be put off for a period. taxes constitute landlord will a fixed cost, stop with paying it taxes thumb in variable costs in order to is likely before Since property that a defaulting marginal on such 1 operating company expenses will as fuel cut off or salaries. After all, his credit a lot faster than the foreclose on his building. likely to be the final the oil city will Therefore, nonpayment of taxes is not indicator of the abandonment process. neither is it the first indicator. But Most building systems require periodic upgrading, but can continue to operate for some time even without proper maintenance. rather than replaced. re-papered; While every few years, title For instance, boiler tubes can be capped rather vestings for such deferred a roof can be patched nonpayment of taxes maintenance can go on for a than occur dozen years before a major system gives out. B. Tax Delingugngy in New York City New York City is one of the few municipalities that regularly forecloses willingness Cleveland, on delinquent properties, to seize occupied and is nearly unique in buildings. Pittsburgh its and two other cities with tax payment problems, backed off from ambitious proposals that would have left them responsible for 2 abandoned property . In Boston, tax foreclosures are ad hoc, occurring only if there is interest in a 29 particular parcel. I found no city references to clear-cut foreclosure procedures other than New York., be any policies and in rem buildings. It and no other city has programs dealing specifically with occupied may in that the severity of New York's abandonment problem has forced this city to pursue a more aggressive strategy, but in fact New York cities, has a lower percentage of including Boston, abandoned units than other that do not foreclose on thousands of tax-delinquent buildings each year. Tax delinquency to the point of foreclosure was first noted as a problem in New York City during the Depression, at which time the Citizens Housing Council published a deliquency with other symptoms of urban blight state Administrative Code in time, was used sparingly until the mid-1960s, tax for the first borough foreclose in one year. three years of The fiscal on landlord process, in making an entire any property that owed more crisis of 1975 focused attention on all including Part of the revenue shortfall Concern tax receipts for that fiscal over than aspects of its collection of property that brought New York the brink of bankruptcy was its overestimate of potential estate it taxes was eligible for foreclosure. the city's fiscal management, taxes. although delinquent properties By law, This power At this time computerization records streamlined the foreclosure to tax A change in the to foreclose directly on delinquent properties. possible to . linking 1948 allowed the city, abandonment was noted much earlier. of study year by some $46 City real 4 million growing delinquency rates was instrumental in City Council's passage of Local Law 45, foreclosure which allowed the city to begin proceedings on any property that owed more than quarters of taxes. involved in community-based acceleration Some council members, revitalization particularly efforts, of the title vesting process as a way to four those saw the alter the involvement of city government in low-income housing. More likely, however, the this bill serious majority of those on the City Council were anxious to "send a signal about pursuing all believed voting for to Albany" that they were revenue collecting alternatives, that a shorter grace period would simply prod and landlords 5 into paying their taxes more promptly In fact, Local Law 45 had the dual effect of improving tax payments and pushing unprecedented numbers of buildings into ownership. For properties, those yearly owners foreclosures interested in keeping limited the number of they can afford to wait before paying their taxes. the verge of sooner. the results disparate proponents: could point advocating see an immediate property the number that objectives (see Table of on much the responsibility 2.1) those intervention in deteriorating buildings could increase 1978-1980, Since in the number the sudden of increase units in in city city-owned immediately following the law's of buildings going (See Table 2.2). quarters and programs. in the those concerned with fiscal to improved collections public management satisfied their Buildings being abandoned entered city ownership Thus city in rem each year has been passage, falling Table 2.1 Tax Delinguency Rates, 1Z4-1984 (OOOs) Fiscal Year %Not Collected 1975 6.9 7.5 $2,897,460 1976 1977 1978 NA NA 6.8 4.7 3,378,611 3, 318,583 3,329,998 1979 1980 1981 3.6 3.6 3.7 3,499, 080 3,798,604 3.996,383 4,200,567 1982 1983 1984 3.2 2.9 3.0 From Moody's Municigal and Government Manual (as reported by the City Comptroller) Table 2.2 Year In Rem Actions Since Passage of Local Borough 1978 1978 1978 1979 1980 1980 1980-81 1981 1982-84 1984 1985 Estimated Total (Action #)* Buildings Taken Staten Island(35) Manhattan(29) Bronx(31) Brooklyn (32) Queens(37) Staten Island(36) Manhattan (30) Bronx(32) Brooklyn(33) Queens(38) Bronx(33) 536 2167 3947 7331 1677 131 813 1121 5824(est) 826 (est) 771 (est) 25,144 From Fourth Annual In Rem interview with Howard Hecht. *In Law 45 Rem Actions numbered sequentially by borough. RegCt, and In after spite the of these successes, vestings of Local 1978-79. Law 45 was never enforced While the city authority to vest any property owing a year of wait at least three years between in rem retains the taxes, in fact they actions. The official explanation for these delays centers on the expense and difficulty of year taking title to and managing thousands of (see Chapter Four). estate market foreclosure fiscal new properties It is also likely that the improved real in many areas qbviated the need for threat to enforce property tax responsibility each advocates no longer an payments. With the concerned about tax delinquency, only low-income neighborhoods where abandonment has not abated--not housing immediate advocates from a those powerful constituency--are pushing for city involvement. Further delinquency, complicating abandonment gentrification. Just the relationship between tax and foreclosure policy is the spread of three or four years ago tenant leaders most low-income neighborhoods tenant leaders could be certain that any building with poor services and numerous code violations had accumulated tax arrears, next title vesting. in and would be taken by the city Today this is true in fewer Wherever there exists the first whisper of property owners will resume tax payments. market also in the neighborhoods. revitalization Poor services may be an indication, not of the owner's intention to abandon, but of his or her plan to empty the building of income minority tenants in order its present, to rent to presumably lowmore affluent newcomers. many The effects of upgrading tenantry are significant in neighborhoods; while it bodes well for the health of the city, general fiscal it does not mean an improvement in the living conditions of those that inhabited the area in its dark days. fact, in some areas, buildings taken by the city in earlier days are now the only remaining low cost rentals. city-owned In buildings keeps these Only the presence of neighborhoods economically integrated. City-wide prompt tax statistics may reflect-an encouraging trend toward payments, but they mask the fact that in some neighborhoods tax delinquency is still rampant. Responsible owners continue to flee, selling buildings to "milkers" (see Chapter One) or simply abandoning them. which in In these areas both the speed with the city forecloses on deteriorating properties and the way which it manages and disposes of the buildings it owns have powerful city impact on the community; in fact, is by far the largest landlord. shows that in neighborhoods, the the Southside, length in these areas The data and presented presumably of time between in foreclosure a the below other actions allows hundreds of housing units to deteriorate and become vacant. Since those that do enter city ownership are successfully and form the still shaky backbone of neighborhood efforts, occupied, it revitalization would behoove city officials to take action deteriorating process as possible. properties treated as early in the against abandonment C. City wnersh i2 and Tax Delinguency in the Southside A portrait of city ownership patterns and building conditions in the Southside inaction--on that can Table demonstrates the one neighborhood. impact the percentage of city is even higher, owner-occupied programs and city The parcels 27"4 are city-owned dwelling units controlled by (see the since the small buildings are more typically less likely to become in rem. affecting city-owned property would have a impact on this action--or Of buildings and vacant be classified as residential, 2.3); of Clearly, considerable community. number of city-owned parcels is not surprising given the depressed condition of the private market in Williamsburg over the past fifteen years. More striking is that 40.6% of all city- and privately-owned, to This comes to some eleven fifteen vacant buildings or lots on each tax successful currently presence one is vacant. lost the programs that treat the under of to city ownership, their 456 vacant properties. 73 block. private the the represents foreseeable future. low-income were the market to grow strong enough to investment, Southside residents. buildings impact is dwarfed by Public rehabilitation or new construction programs for attract However Southside Each vacant unit low-incoming housing for families no longer exist; property, it would exclude most current Table 2.3 Total City god Private Ownershig Residential Parcels* in the Southside 1122 City owned 308 (27%) Privately owned, vacant lot 174 (15.5%) Privately owned, vacant building 47 590 Privately owned, occupied (4X) (52.6%) *Estimated, using maps and surveys. It is difficult to determine whether a vacant lot was once the site of a residential building; a lot is considered residential if the surrounding buildings are residential. Buildings with both commercial and residential units are considered residential, but loft buildings that have recently attracted illegal residential tenants are not. Table 2.4 Total Vacant Lots and Buildings Residential Parcels 1122 Vacant lots 313 (27.9%) Vacant buildings 143 (12.7%) 36 Table 2.5 Total City-Owned Progerty City-Owned Parcels 308 Vacant lots 139 (45'4) Vacant buildings 96 (31%) Occupied buildings Central Management Alternative Management Tenant-owned cooperative 73 (24%) 35 24 14 Sources: Survey, and New York City Department of Housing Preservation and Development, Office of Property Management. Since HPD seldom Southside buildings each was a large, or evacuates occupied properties were closed after the last vesting the assumption vacant by the time the city takes them is the the two action; seriously deteriorated structure with only two remaining tenants), are (only one buildings (See Table 2.5) There is an active demolition program, so an in rem action would include many public more vacant buildings and fewer empty lots. Thus, any policy that is to have a serious impact on housing in the Southside must intervene earlier in before a building becomes vacant. the abandonment process, Given the state of the private market described in Chapter One, it is unlikely that incentives to landlords would such as property tax abatements and have a major impact on abandonment. low-interest loans The alternative is to take the buildings out of for-profit management once the signs abandonment are clear, but while the buildings are still viable. of This was one of the goals of to Law 45, and the authority seize title to properties with over four quarters of tax arrears remains abandonment. have the city's Because several title vestings, however, most potent property weapon against years are allowed to elapse between the reality is that no vesting papers been filed on buildings three or four years in arrears. Brooklyn the summer of 1979, Today, at Local first post-Local Law 45 vesting took place the next one three years later in the earliest it will in August,. no third vesting has even been scheduled, In the 1982. suggesting that take place is the spring or summer of 1987. Vesting work delays occur for several behind each vesting legwork of visiting buildings is. same and enormously While the legal time-consuming, assuming management of the thousands of Currently vesting and management are handled by the HPD personnel, chaos. is not reasons. Furthermore, so an annual vesting would create perpetual each vesting brings thousands of new units under city management, adding expense and taxing the staff. Since many occupied buildings remain in city ownership indefinitely, buildings are not leaving their portfolio to make room for the new ones. Given officials these considerations, are reluctant it is not surprising that HPD to pursue a more vigorous foreclosure policy. Delaying run, title but foreclosures may lighten HPD's burden in the in the long run it has its costs. vestings, buildings In the time short between in the abandonment cycle become :38 more dilapidated; ultimately their boilers give out, they records of are vacated. they lose units to f'ires, and Because there saved with faster foreclosures. rem action arrears and occupancy adequate But accurate of the all of 250 units, costs of with substantial For require any of an be tax go from nearly full displacement or the cost to the neighborhood of buildings. is units that could vacancy as services were withdrawn. measure it in the winter before the 1982 I did see five tenements, containing a total to families, would no the exact dates on which buildings become vacant, impossible to calculate the precise number of in are There to is these another five no 250 vacant these units ever to provide housing again investment of between $40,000 and $70,000, depending on the extent of destruction by exposure to the elements and they vandals. would Had these buildings been vested two years earlier, have maintenance work, needed only systems replacements and which could have been done for $10,000 other a unit with little disruption to the inhabitants. Tax delinquency continues to be a problem in the Southside, and tax delinquent buildings continue to be among the worst neighborhood. quarters of housing As of in the last June, 216 buildings owed at least three tax arrears, representing 36.6'. of the privately owned (see Table 2.6). Many of the 174 privately owned may also owe taxes, but these don't show up on HPD's records. 39 lots Table 2.6 Total Tax Arrearage in Occugied Buildings Privately Owned, Occupied Buildings Quarters in Arrears: 3 4-7 8+ Source: New 590 51 (8.6%) 89 (15.1%) 76 (12.9%) City Department of City York Planning. A profile buildigng units. of small a skewed distribution with an average of 32.7 units each, (three and four unit) recorded quality, of represents buildings. heat, suggests violations a the presence of deterioration. hazardous tenants a local are violations large irregularity violations measure of in 10.4 large number many code less-than-ideal building (e.g., each lack building The sample buildings or 3.5 violations per these, four violations in each building there nine several hazardous conditions a serious level of considered hazardous. of and a exposed or frayed electrical wiring) have 35.5 violations each, reveals tax-delinquent While the housing inspections and the pickiness of makes the Table 2.6 reveals that they have an average of This buildings of in of a sample of forty-nine of apartment. Of (.4 per dwelling unit)- are An examination of the large buildings alone slightly fewer violations (.45) per dwelling (3.24) unit. In but more addition, in 20% of the tax delinquent buildings have complained to tenant advocacy group about poor services in the past year. A comparison of the scope of tax delinquency today and three years ago shows that very little has changed. 40 The last Brooklyn in rem action was held in arrears since the 1982, encompassing buildings fallen 1979 action. eligible to be taken, and 93 of 193 Southside those buildings (mostly the smaller or 48.1%, were subsequently redeemed by their owners Two with the were ones), (see Appendix for an explanation of the redemption process). consistent into This is city-wide estimate that only 20% of not those 6 eligible for foreclosure will suggests that the Southside has fewer landlords putting ultimately become city-owned and off tax vesting, 165 payments without intending to lose their buildings. Last June, Southside three years after the last title buildings were four quarters in arrears eligible for foreclosure. and therefore If the same percentage of landlords were to redeem as had in 1982, a title have netted 85 buildings. owing three quarters. payment, action then last buildings. taken in vesting at that time would In June there were also 51 If these landlords had neglected their next 216 buildings would have been eligible for fall, Either 1982, with an expected figure yield buildings vested in rem city-owned the 100 buildings currently Interestingly,. of vesting list in the next in rem action. instituted a the of be again be on the Since the city has since "supplementary vestings" had been on the previous in rem list 41 to This means that nearly 93 redemptions will once policy in 23 of the in arrears were those scheduled 1982 and subsequently redeemed. that 112 in and suggests that there has been little change one-quarter properties of is in the range of the Southside from the 1979-82 period. 216 buildings in which and whose owners had defaulted on their redemption agreements can be into city ownership between official taken actions. D.Conclusions This and overview of city-wide and neighborhood tax foreclosure trends suggests several appears market that is the overall health of improving. neighborhoods, suggests First, directions. New York City's familiarity with some of with the affordability data in areas estate New York's Chapter experiencing property that have traditionally strong markets are Second, some degrees the neighborhoods means have tax of now delinquency down, the low not experienced "turned getting been around"; and housing costs income. this 1, market: that in the mid-1970's had of abandonment have values are up, beyond areas It real the following trends in New York City's housing stronger. are taken My policy delinquency Meanwhile, upgrading, so some remain affordable to the poor but continue to suffer abandonment and show high rates of tax delinquency. Tax foreclosure policy must be sensitive to these different trends. In traditionally strong areas tax delinquency has never a major concern. collecting the In these areas city officials are interested in sufficient transitional areas, been taxes to support municipal services. the city treasury should be benefitting increase in property values; In from buildings that had become city- owned at an earlier time must be maintained as low-income housing. It is in deteriorated areas that tax 42 foreclosure becomes the Part II major component of housing policy. The city must foreclose frequently -- every other year at least--and be willing to interim vestings, taking title to buildings whose signed repayment agreements and defaulted. buildings owned revitalization private can efforts. interest--and happen--the form If even the a neighborhood of begins in the Southside this has ensuring an integrated community. landlord foundation city-owned stock will remain a owners had City foreclosures save before the abandonment process is complete, buildings conduct low-income and city- grassroots to attract begun to resource, Now that the crisis is over and abandonment is slowing down, the city should be able to deal with it more effectively where it is still occurring. Notes on Chapter Two 1. If there was an outstanding mortgage, the landlord would probably continue paying debt service on it even after defaulting on taxes, since a private mortgage holder would probably act against a defaulter more expeditiously than a municipal government. In many depressed neighborhoods where tax delinquency is most common,however,there are few outstanding bank mortgages after years of red-lining Current owners have bought their buildings with cash, or have arranged purchase money mortgages with the seller, who is probably not eager to regain his property. In many cases, therefore, the threat of mortgage foreclosure on these properties is not a real one. 2. Michael Goodwin, "City-Owned Houses Come Pandora's Box.," New York Times, 7 January 1979. Complete with 3. Brian Sullivan, "The Division of Alternative Management Programs: The Last Best Hope for In Rem Housing in New York City," (Pratt Center, 1982), 3-6. 4. Harry DiRienzo and Joan B. Allen, The New York City In Rem Housing PCggram, (New York: Urban Coalition, 1985) 5. Goodwin, "City-Owned Houses." 43 6. New York City Development, The First Department of Housing Preservation Annual In Rem Housing Regort, 6. 44 and ANTECEDENTS TO THE CHAPTER THREE: IN REM HOUSING PROGRAM Urban self-help housing grew out of the housing crisis that confronted low-income, inner city tenants in the early 1970s. net result of urban renewal had been the loss of The affordable housing: by 1967, 404,000 low- and moderate-income units had been 1 destroyed, replaced by 41,580 units . The moratorium on federally assisted housing had left a void in the creation of income new, units not filled by city programs, mixed-income developments low- which concentrated such as Battery Park City on and Roosevelt Island, and on stabilization of transitional 2 neighborhoods . Low city-wide vacancy rates, the worsening condition of opportunities private tenement housing, and restricted housing for blacks and Hispanics created the conditions in which poor tenants had little choice but to take action. Tenants had been taking over their buildings from abandoning landlords since the mid-1960s, if not earlier, and by the early 1970s many had found ways to renovate and purchase their buildings as legal cooperatives. over where their landlord had failed? and Ronald Lawson, empowerment assertion based incarnation and able to take According to Robert Kolodny their confidence had been boosted by grassroots movements. Kolodny maintains that of consumer rights and the resurgence of voluntary reversal of Why were they willing action, it is unlikely that roles would have emerged" of the civil . "without the neighborhood- such Furthermore, a dramatic the urban rights movement had focused directly 45 on housing issues. The Harlem rent strike of 1962-3, which had rapidly spread to other New York City ghettoes, had been initiated 4 by CORE organizers . Civil tension and Owners visit to rights unrest, for better or worse, exacerbated distrust between black tenants and white interviewed by Stegman and Sternlieb who were their properties (see Chapter One) may have their tenants' certainty that before the city could take them in rem. Receivership and appointment Article 7a, both of of their These measures which as newly legal provide and the Emergency Repair Program, to reacting their voiced measures buildings include for of an administrator to manage a property in place the landlord, city Residents' since helped tenants take control have afraid been may have hastened the creation of dissatisfaction landlords. increased racial militance as well their rights as renters. of the the of which allows the to provide emergency services when the landlord is unwilling 5 and to place a lien on the property A.Homeownershig fgr the Poor The New concept of tenant-initiated York City was built elsewhere: homeownership Homeownership for behalf conversion on two ideas that were in good for low-income largest scale under Title 1 of 1968. cooperative the poor and families was self-help undertaken in currency housing. on the Housing and Development Act the of Known as Section 235, this program consisted of payments on of the low-income homeowner by the federal 46 government to mortgage holders in'order to reduce the interest rate to as low as 6 1. . One goal of 235 housing was to provide poor families with alternatives to segregrated, same institutional expenditure [as for public housing] could purchase (about $25,000 "The a unit) a house in suburbia and a new car for the poor 7 who could live much like anybody else" . Another goal, family based public housing: on the assumption that an owner-occupant would inclined than a tenant to keep up his or her home, improved housing within the inner city. stressed the financial benefits of more was to promote The program's proponents home ownership, deductions and equity accumulation, be such as tax as well as the psychological benefits: "Owning a home can increase responsibility and stake out a man's place in his community. The man who owns a home has something to be proud of and good reason to protect and preserve it"B. With each summer -bringing a new wave of racial cities, a program encouraging the poor to unrest to the inner invest in their neighborhoods was welcomed. Because section 235 was exclusively a program for of single-family (Interestingly, project in Bronx--are in it had little impact on New York however, East using factory-built homes, two current New York and Charlotte projects--the Gardens 235 mortgage subsidies to erect houses on vacant land.) in conversion projects. as the New York City equivalent 47 City. Nehemiah the South single-family, But the ideas Section 235 housing were considered by the sponsors cooperative purchasers represented of early Cooperative ownership was seen of homeownership, and the benefits ascribed to homeowners 9 shareholders as well were B.Self-Helg Housing and Sweat believed "participation by accrue to coop new, being EgUity The concept known as self-help housing simply to is hardly the maintenance of family in the construction and 10 their dwellings" . Its application by planners in 1960s to the creation of the late however, was application: occupation the push innovation. urban Two homesteading, trends emerged from this the The second was which substitutes labor for cash in the acquisition rehabilitation of property. habitable, housing, which generally involved west by nineteenth-century pioneers. undoubtedly urban of vacant inner city houses in much the same spirit as sweat equity, and an low-cost used in While many urban some form of sweat equity to make this homesteaders their homes section sweat equity specifically refers to organized, multi-family efforts. Urban se, in homesteading is not a low-income and often the housing program per homesteaders are more affluent than the inhabitants neighborhoods into which they move. HUD, which sold buildings on which it had foreclosed to homesteaders for as little as a dollar, throughout the conducted a study of 241 program country in 1978 and found that were more affluent, more likely to be white, the participants homesteaders better educated and less likely to be on public assistance than their neighbors. differential existed even though the program was executed only 48 The in 11 areas that had not fallen into deterioration In New thought of The considerably thrust of the New York City which program from other homesteading initiatives. projects, emphasis was on resulting in cooperative ownership. often homesteading, was as a program for homeowners, was extended to multi-unit buildings. family City the concept of York sweat possibilities as by rehabilitation While other homesteaders were their need for shelter, projects were comprised of In the multi- equity income people motivated as much by middle differed the the investment Equity Sweat low-income families, and the coops were Whereas structured so that participants would not earn a profit. in homesteaders purchase price of other cities were subsidized only in the low sweat equity homesteaders received their units, more extensive public subsidy. early 1970s "pure" sweat which relied completely on participants' volunteer labor. New York Sweat Equity projects in the Original were of equity, Later The earliest kind was varieties. three projects built labor stipends into their mortgages so that participants could devote themselves to renovation work full-time. Still later, residents CETA funds were used to pay participants. could continue to afford these assistance of subsidies at many levels. from the financing Program. city at The for $100 below a unit, and projects, Loan 49 Program with the They purchased buildings received the market rate through the Municipal Low-income was rehabilitation Municipal Loan by the replaced Participation Loan Program, which mixed Community Funds, lent at 5%., with a conventional low. There were coordinated loan to keep Development interest rates was no contractor's or developer's fee; Professional by a services city were agency usually and the projects non-profit donated by sponsors. lawyers and architects who were excited by these projects. C.EarEly New York City Cogati yes A 5200 the 1973 study identified 72 New York City projects containing units that either had attained cooperative status or were in 12 conversion process . The projects ranged from those initiated by sponsoring organizations to prevent disinvestment in transitional initiated neighborhoods ("preventative conversions") to those by tenants in landlord-abandoned buildings situated severely deteriorated neighborhoods. While many of the in projects involved sweat equity renovation of vacant buildings, as described above, others, like today's in rem buildings, were comprised of current tenants more concerned with gaining control in the absence of in a responsible landlord than in participating renovation work. Since programs and funding sources have changed since case-by-case More look relevant at early coops is not useful to 1973, a this study. is an understanding of both the motivation behind the cooperative conversions and the factors contributing to success. individual Recognition and of the benefits of homeownership their to the to society motivated some of the sponsors of the 50 preventative conversions, model Not but it was assumed that the cooperative would not work for the very poor in only stock were was prospective sponsors concerned that too rehabilitation, deteriorated dilapidated to lend itself housing. the to housing low-cost but they were further convinced that poor tenants lacked the motivation and organizational skills to pull off such a 1973 defied these assumptions. Most project. The projects studied in were precisely the kind viewed by experts as unworkable; located run they were in deteriorated buildings in neglected neighborhoods by tenants with little formal training. These participants were not even attracted to the presumed they were interested simply in improving their living without forgoing affordable rents. homeownership Their efforts, and benefits; conditions as Kolodny explains, "owed little to a petit bourgeois interest in ownership for its own sake or alternatively to a radical ideology that advocated expropriation of private property and community control. The central issue has been control at a level sufficient to remedy painful housing conditions"(13). That those seeking remedy worked struggles in other buildings, in isolation, unaware of similar further suggests that cooperative conversion was a spontaneous response to desperate conditions. These pioneering cooperatives, public programs designed for that purpose, principles official formed without the benefit of and lessons offered a that were important in the tenant-management programs. of creation of The early projects of 1970s marked the beginning of the age of moderate 51 number the rehabilitation, a necessity at a time when the billions of federal dollars needed for clearance and new construction were becoming scarce. previously in away from the big on the part willingness rehabilitation project of relied involving a financial package. on different was in Some halted have been management scant to ad work This willingness was critical isolated cases until hoc, group of experimental participants low- 1979. Early programs, each and a different to the since participants could not move in until complete. municipal Indeed, many of the projects fiscal delays. crisis, loan programs collapsed. delays prevented some tenants from realizing conversion, internal factors accounted into trouble after conversion. lack a modify renovation in mid-renovation by the 1975 While official that fell officials 1973 never achieved conversion due to such during which all goal of denoted Perennial delays were most perilous sweat equity projects, identified also the and publicity they generated, income coop conversions remained rehabilitation However, of sweat equity methods. In spite of the excitement their mentality standards so that less extensive to the development conversions expensive. housing would be eligible for public funds. were had been thought that moderate rehabilitation with tenants place was cumbersome and therefore move It of money and lack of for The two biggest problems training. The expertise in many of the cooperatives is due attention given to pre-conversion those training. dearth to of the Cooperatives that mismanaged by sponsors outside by initiated were by inexperienced but even those established tenants, "persons who landlords Ebut] did the tenants themselves were later mismanaged by leaders of struggles against 14 management" in leaders good to be not prove excellent were number of high later often were unfortunately An early coops have fallen into financial difficulty, loan with the majority owing property taxes and falling behind on 15 repayments D.Early City-Sggngred Cooeratives the early grassroots interest of spite In In city sponsorship came slowly. conversion, Consultation was Unit Administration formed within the in cooperative 1970 a Cooperative Housing Development tenants low-income (HPD's predecessor) to advise considering conversion, but the city itself did not sponsor the early cooperatives. evolved, in fact, Program. Estate This Its support for conversion efforts first by default, with the failure of the Receivership Real in which the city's Department of program, stepped in by court order to manage properties no longer was in charge of twenty receiving services from their landlords, buildings any of in 1970; by it 1972 was burdened with over 200 buildings. The DRE managers were especially ill-equipped to handle these troubled properties. clout and sophistication, Community groups, buildings gained persuaded HDA to contract with them for the management of buildings in Receivership. Receivership which had began Management Program was conceived. to go in As community-managed rem, the Community The CMP's transfer the receive initial the community follows: Loan for rehabilitation, building groups unrehabilitated uncertainties would balked at properties. of be sold the these municipal buildings for an the Municipal CMP group would the notion work tenants. of funding to was But purchasing suspect that the the leaving them responsible indefinite period. The program Between the was cut-off Loan funding and the uncertainty and red tape of the program's administration, 1979. would and when to changed to provide for repairs before sale. of the city They were familiar enough with rehabilitation process might take years, for The building to the community group, a Municipal completed plan was as however, An example of the kind of is the fate of no sales took place until delays encountered 149 South 4th Street, a in the early Southside building. The first building to enter Community Management as a Receivership building in the 1973, program 1982. As buildings are conveyed directly to the it was not sold to the tenants until exists now, tenants after rehabilitation. Community groups only rarely become owners themselves. In rem 1975 the Direct Sales Program was established to enable in tenants to purchase their buildings directly from Simple in theory, this program was impossibly complex before for sale, control the city. in practice: tenants were expected to sign a management contract 16 of their building consisting of some 32 documents Disposition procedures were never clarified and sales prices never determined. In short, the record of city sponsorship 54 of low- income coops before 1978 was dismal: Thus, in two coops in five years. spite of the growing interest through the 1970s in cooperative conversion as a response to landlord abandonment, officialdom remained aloof. rem management programs had no significant long The tenant The predecessors of the current impact after the cooperative movement had gained its own programs that did city exist, programs for vacant buildings., along with other in until momentum. homesteading were understaffed, underfunded and underestimated as viable solutions to the shortage of decent low- income housing. Notes on Chapter Three DiRienzo and 1. Harry (New York: Housing EEogram Joan Allen, The New York City- In Urban Coalition, 1985), 10. ECgggsal 1974) 2. Urban Homesteading Assistance Board, 2. (New York: Homesteadi ng Asistance Board for the 3. Robert Kolodny, "Self-Help Can Be an Effective Tool the Urban Poor," Journal of Housing, (March, 1981) 139. 4. Ronald Lawson, Owners of Last Resort (New York: 1984) 10. Housing Preservation and Development, 5. Ibid, 6. U.S. Families: Urban in Housing Department of 5. Commission on Civil Rights,Hgeownershi2 for A Regort on the Racial and Ethnic 235 ProgCaM, (1971), ImpAct Lower Income gf the Section 5. 7. William Tabb, Ihe Political Economy g York: WW Norton &Co., 1970),18. 8. Rem U.S. Commission on Civil (New Rights, 2. in gelf-del Robert Kolodny, 9. United Neighborhood Houses, 1973),9. the Inner Organization for Social and Technical 10. (Cambridge, 1969),1. Housing in the U.S.A., 55 the Black Ghetto, City, Innovation, (New York: Self-Hel2 11. U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Analysis of the Urban Homesteading PCggam(1978),34. 12. Kolodny, "Self-Help Can Be an Effective Tool ", 13. Ibid. 14. Lawson,, Owners of Last Resort, 15. Ibid, Baseline 139. 35. 36. 16. Susan Baldwin, City Limits 3 (March "Red 1978). Tape Threatens Direct Sales 56 Success,," CHAPTER FOUR: CREATION OF CURRENT IN REM HOUSING PROGRAMS A. The Office of By the crisis. had Progerty Management late 1970s the City of New York was Abandonment was at faced with its peak and the fast foreclosure law made every residential property with a four-quarter tax -- tens of thousands of units, foreclosure. properties favored The debt many of them occupied--eligible for traditional had been to sell a means of disposing them at auction. because it enabled the city to return of in rem This approach was the building to the private sector quickly, absolving the city of extensive management responsibilities the lost and generating income that could compensate tax revenues. But New troublesome. York's A experience with auction sales had 1978 report documented that properties proved sold auction more often than not ended up back in city ownership. years after sale, 94% of former city-owned parcels were arrears; 54% were at least four quarters eligible for foreclosure, and Perhaps a worse indictment of the for buildings in in at Four tax arrears and therefore 25% had paid no taxes at the auction program was that 44% that had been occupied at sale no longer all. of afforded 1 adequate housing responsibilities . While some purchasers, of property ownership, 57 naive about may have gotten in the over their heads, purchasers were intention "the the of assumption slumlords who of the properties (see the in Chapter One for more details). the disastrous consequences of moratorium on them in 1978. by sold bought properly maintaining them Operator" been was that many auction. auction sales, defaulting without description of In response to the city declared a Since then no occupied buildings have Sales of vacant have properties with the added stipulation that bidders file resumed, statements revealing they had or currently have an have any been disclosure the condition of other properties in interest. The which failure of auction sales underscored the disintegration of the private market in poor neighborhoods, and left the city owner of thousands of properties without any means to dispose of them. Before 1970 buildings. owned By areas. management had administration handled by Division Services). ownership been limited to When the been seen as just another and, in like all rem Real Property stock had been aspect under the (later city- small, of to Department municipal had been become of abundant the General and horror stories of tenants freezing in city-owned buildings became distressingly common. same its But the logarithmically increasing workload proved to be beyond the capacity of the DRE, the few previously city property management, Estate a by and tax delinquency was spreading to the Department of Real of had 1978 some neighborhoods were dominated property, stable city time, community city-owned organizations in stock were insisting 58 neighborhoods that this At with landlord- abandoned property presented an opportunity for alternative response 1978, of the development of management and ownership for low-income to these pressures, City Council tenants. passed Local shifting responsibility for the management and in rem residential.properties from bureaucracy, to Development, the council member supposed to the Department EHPD's] area officials administrative policy of expertise. 2 the DRE3'" agency. shift: We "'That's they of housing They were potentially responsible for up to 30.000 substandard buildings sheltering the city's and information them; became coverage of same these Had they been sixty properties all the front page news in who problems agency that had few for trained As the fate of tax-foreclosed 1978 and this issue conveyed a sense of managers real experienced buildings would have posed and no management system. personnel housing to another. they worked for a public and most about these buildings was somehow transferred from one managers estate They had to see that troubled families. bureaucracy large and One figured hard to convey the confusion and anxiety during this period. indigent in disposition Preservation explained the rationale for the be is an Housing recently created housing couldn't do a worse job [than It of DRE, Law 3 In early impending are now incapable (100 properties per person) will of 1979, press doom: "The managing now try their 6,000 skills housing or nearly 3 ,800 units of upon 534 properties per person, 3 manager!" . The resulting crisis facilitated the creation of per the institutions necessary to carry out uncomfortable responsibility as landlord of 59 the city's last resort. new and Ta-ble 4. 1 OCCUPIED IN REM BUILDINGS FY 1979 'IIAL FY 1980 11,717 (166,184) 'Ibtal Occup. 4,092 (34,779) (UNITS) BY PIOGPAM, FY 1979 - FY 1983 FY 1983 FY 1982 FY 1981 8,800 (NA) 8,289 (NA) 9,580 (NA) 4,197 (38,950) 3,870 (37,462) 3,727 (36,229) 3,945 (38,677) 3,547 (23,745) 3,223 (22,675) 3,204 (25,292) 3,430 (26,739) NA DPM 3,681 (26,512) DAMP 411 (8267) 645 (15,205) 647 (14,787) 523 (10,937) 515 (11,938) CMP TIL 130 POMP 230 316 33 66 (5645) (7058) (1302) (1200) 219 333 48 47 (4409) (8082) (1363) (933) 165 311 47 (3535)' (7458) (1471) 158 291 41 (3402) (6636) (1469) OTHER NA NA (2500) (5683) (820) (735) SALES 0 5 (82) 50 (1632) 112 (2263) 104 (3049) 226 I Frcm New York City Department of Housing Preservation and Developmnt, "In Rem Program Annual Report" numbers 1 through 5. Department of Housing Preservation and Development Office of Property Management DIVISION OF P10PERI MAGEMEN DIVISION OF ALTENATIVE MAGEENT Responsible for all Central Management buildings. Tenant Interim Leasing Private ownership and Managenent Program Comnunity Management Program Although programs have been altered and today's 4.1, In Rem Housing Program, is essentially identical outlined improved since in Figure 4.1 1979., and Table to that which emerged at that time. Most tenants in city-owned buildings continue to be managed by HPD through its Division of Property Management were before 1979. all occupied Division of But (DPM) much 13X of these buildings, dwelling units, are in one of Alternative Management Programs they containing 31% three areas (DAMP). the Private Ownership and Management Program as of of the One of these, (POMP) hires private real estate professionals to manage and purchase in rem buildings. The other two, Interim the Community Management Program Leasing (TIL) are outgrowths of the "self-help" housing movement discussed above, sell B. (CMP) and Tenant grassroots, urban and are designed to buildings to tenant cooperatives. The Division of Progerty Management: Public Landlord Buildings administered by HPD are managed tra'ditionally, with the Division of Property Management Immediately after the city takes title, is known as Alternative selected from Property Central Management. managers, located at landlord. eventually (in the case of TIL) CMP and POMP) Central nine responsible for a list of buildings. repairs are done as needed. as all buildings enter Those that Management must apply to (in the case of of acting site offices, what enter or be Management. are each Basic services are provided; Tenants pay their rent to HPD either 60 by mailing it the several traditional centrally rental some. managed housing, Tenants buildings are operated have complain of a point. like they encounter the same difficulties, poor services, and managers complain of dismal rent collection figures. sides of banks that accept these payments. Because plus or by delivering it to the site office or one property Indeed, Centrally managed buildings are the both least desirable buildings in the in rem stock, and their rent collection is by far the poorest. a program but properties This is because Central a default united only landlord or tenant group, Since buildings there option. Its Management is not portfolio in their inability to consists inspire of anyone, to want to own them. is no data comparing the conditions of across programs, in rem much of the information regarding the comparatively deteriorated state of Central Management property is anecdotal. Certain statistics, however, do suggest factors that would lead to the their troubled state. fewest units (4.2 (16.1 per building) and have the smallest rooms per unit) of all commercial spaces in rem stock. city-wide apartments vacancy rate of vacancy rates, 2.04%, and renting for under $250 a month. apartments They have the and the lowest commercial They also have high residential a These buildings have the occupancy fewest (72.2%). 23.4%, compared to close to 1.0% for It is not surprising to find that they have the lowest assessed value of all city-owned 4 buildings . Yet Central Management buildings are expensive to run. An estimated $3300 to $3400 a year, 61 or nearly $300 a month, is spent on each dwelling unit. than the real conditions cover estate necessitate frequent emergency repairs. expenses: $184.80 industry Although this is 150% higher 5 standard , the poor building Tenants pay on average $44 a room for an average estimated at (4.2 room) apartment; $70 a room, Since city-owned rents could be Rents do not monthly, break-even has or $294.00 for an average buildings are not subject to legally increased; but or rent because been 6 apartment regulations HPD officials believe those in centrally managed buildings are among the poorest of all 7 year , 50% in rem tenants, whose median income is just over $8,000 a they are probably the least able to absorb a rent increase. of them are on public assistance--compared to 25% of those in 8 alternative management buildings, 25% of all NYCHA tenants , and 9 14.3% of renters city-wide . Therefore Central Management runs a deficit which was as high as $11.8 million in FY 1980, and is down 10 to $6 million in FY 1983 . The deficit is made up by federal CD funds and city tax If its the centrally managed portfolio weren't troubled position as unwanted stepchild of exacerbates motivated away, Central its difficulties. by have planning their levy revenues. the belief that until City if in rem enough, management policy-makers, further seemingly you ignore a problem it will recently refused- to engage in any go long-term for the approximately 32,000 occupied units currently in Management. reassurances In every policy statement that the objective of return buildings to private ownership, 62 officials continue in rem policy is to but seldom acknowledge the existence of some 30,000 Unwillingness private York traditional such officials is no is in part due to the notion that a should not be a landlord. City Management. to invest in buildings for which there or community interest municipality New units stuck in Central have functions of municipal been Since the fiscal reluctant governments, to crisis overstep believing it was benificence that depleted the city treasury ten years ago. The further assumption of policy-makers is that the private sector can run things more efficiently than a public agency; those in the real estate industry seem especially eager to point out the city's 11 management shortcomings . HPD should therefore be seeking ways to rid itself of its management responsibilities as quickly as possible. In spite of these arguments, responsibility for the city must accept its large rental stock. long-term The simple fact is that HPD owns this property, and this is unlikely to change in the foreseeable future. the city, it potential could With the shortage of affordable apartments in would of behoove housing A moderate these units. prove cost attract program, discussed opportunity "creams" it to back rent Most of the Central has been rejected by the private sector, without below, which to the strategy collections and Management stock and has few features that massive offers purchase in rem properties, subsidies. private The managers succeeds because the most attractive of these buildings and 63 examine rehabilitation effective by improving decreasing operating costs. would planners ignores POMP the it the others. The fact size, their is that there are properties which, due to their layout, uncooperativeness of the of extent their tenants are or disrepair neither the attractive private owners nor suited to tenant self-management. to Yet tenants in these buildings are entitled to adequate services, and it is in the city's interest to provide these as efficiently as possible. In the management Annual past few years the city has in capabilities. Each fact improved year the In Rem Housing its Program Report proudly documents increased productivity among workers and fewer heatless days in its buildings (in 1981 its it took an average of 2.1 days to restore heat, compared to 14 days in 12 1980) . When DPM first began managing buildings in 1978, hardly were anyone paid rent; sent insisted tenants never got to tenants who didn't exist, that tenants mail unworkable cash, legal in for checks to and a billed, the system central Today, better flexible rent payment system, record-keeping that office people who were accustomed to paying person. bills a was landlord and a more along with better service delivery, have led to an improvement in rent collections from a meager 36.9% 13 in FY 1979 to a barely respectable 72.0% in FY 1982 . Tenants in some buildings have even begun to organize through the City Tenants, pleased to and managers deal of some of the site with these tenant groups rather 14 having to respond to individual complaints These part of Union offices than 64 seem constantly improvements point to a tacit acknowledgement some HPD officials that of centrally managed buildings on are the a long-term city responsibility, underscore this commitment. and several The Mayor funds for in rem buildings opening up a new revenue source for repairs. dramatic plight of the homeless has inspired HPD to renovate vacant apartments clients have initiatives In his recent budget request, Koch included the allocation of capital (see Chapter Eight), recent living been thousand in Central Management in shelters or hotels. completed; the buildings for So far 4,000 per unit renovation apartments cost dollars represents a.savings for the city, Welfare of a whose few Human Resources Administration pays over $1000 a month for an inadequate hotel room. While program families, any is renovation of these buildings is welcomed, designed primarily to address the needs and is a program for in rem housing only of this homeless secondarily. Long-term tenants express frustration at the fact that in New York you have to be homeless to raise public concern over your living 15 conditions . tenant A who has lived with leaking pipes and peeling paint for years, perhaps struggling against a landlord's neglect and pressuring the city for repairs, must be puzzled see the apartment next door completely renovated for a The homeless program is a necessary one, step toward the acceptance of fixtures in the New York City rental In sum, city policy toward some ambivalence. advocates newcomer. but it is a very city-owned buildings as to small permanent housing picture. its management portfolio denotes Responding on the one hand to tenants and their who demand decent housing, 65 and on the other to critics who call for a withdrawal of the city from the housing management business, public officials continue to provide management services but are reluctant rental property. expensive., repair to plan for the long-term this by for the buildings will the centrally growing managed numbers of of its shortsightedness as high maintenance costs are the result plans spurred Unfortunately viability of inadequate buildings. homeless Perhaps, families, begin to be maintained as a resource for is these low-income families in years to come. Notes on Chapter Four 1. Susan Baldwin, "City's Auction Sales: City Limits 3 (September, 1978),1. 2. "Property March, 1978. Seizures Going, Going., Gone? in City are Chaotic," New York Times 3. St. George, Philip, "City-Owned Buildings: 1978," City Limits 3 (January 1978), 8. 4. Brian Sullivan, 2-16. Allen, 6. Ibid. 7. Michael Stegman, Housing In New York, 8. DiRienzo and Allen, 39. 9. Stegman, Hgusing in 12. New Owners' York The New Issue of New York, The New York City In Newsletter City Dept. of 66 Rem 236. 10. 10. New York City Department of Housing Development, Eifth Annual In Rem Housing Program ProgCty 19 Division of Alternative Management PrggCams, 5. Harry DiRienzo and Joan B. Housing Prgam, 43. 11. " Preservation ReggEt. and 1. HPD, Eifth Annual In Rem Housing Program Beg~t. 13. Ibid. 14. Dave Robinson interview. 15. Dave Robinson interview and Sue Reynolds interview. CREATION OF THE DIVISION OF ALTERNATIVE CHAPTER FIVE: APPLICATIONS OF SELF-HELP MANAGEMENT PROGRAMS: HOUSING MODELS TO MANAGEMENT OF CITY-OWNED PROPERTY The large in rem actions on auctions, in 1978, coupled with the moratorium a backlog of created city-owned became interested in any program that could load. So DAMP was established, Community Management Program, renamed Tenant was the Private another was similar to its and a staff portfolio housing Program (POMP), Program Management one and (HAMP)-was contractor--which When DAMP opened its doors on September consisted of By the end of that year, units. reinvigorated of self-help Ownership and Management 1982. a two new programs were started: POMP but with NYCHA acting as in lessen its management consisting of the Housing Authority terminated 1978, Soon after HPD an overhauled Direct Sales Program Interim Leasing, movement leaders. buildings. 1700 containing 85 buildings 1, responding to pressure from HPD Management as possible, it 1 In the midst of expanded to 413 buildings with 8200 units . to get as many buildings out of Central had this crisis city officials were willing of new forms of housing management: suspicion to their overcome "After initially viewing these initiatives with great skepticism, the New York City government has begun actively encouraging tenant takeover, because the city doesn't know what else to do, 2 being a slumlord itself" In the Southside, are currently 14 in TIL. 24 of the occupied, partly and doesn't enjoy city-owned buildings in alternative management programs--ten in CMP and An addition 14 have completed either TIL or CMP and are now legal buildings cooperatives. are., buildings, on average, one-third of all probably Southside, where and This is a higher than the city-wide figure the a degree local of tenant community organization group, This in Southside the United Typically, large city- therefore their entry into alternative management of is Approximately 760 Southside households now live in city-sponsored, ten Management have tenant associations by the time they become quite natural. from Central has been active for over twelve years. buildings owned, than management occupied units in alternative managment. indicates Housing, larger alternative most likely more than half the city-owned units are in alternative managment. of Since the tenant- or community-managed buildings. these buildings were interviewed for Tenants this study. Their comments are interwoven throughout the following sections. A. The Community Management Prgrgam Community programs Management and Tenant based on self-help Interim Leasing are the housing models. Management, community-based organizations to Community (CBOs) receive contracts manage and rehabilitate city-owned properties in their service areas. Generally buildings, a, contract will include five to twelve or 100 to 300 units, providing operating subsidies and a management fee. CBOs In two with contracts. As of Fiscal Year 1983, there were twenty-two Under the contract terms the groups hire a management and maintenance staff to collect rent and make repairs. Rehabilitation work of up to $20,000 per unit 69 is usually done by subcontractors., house although recently, in a money-saving effort, maintenance crews have also been doing renovations. inWhen rehabilitation is complete, tenants are expected to purchase their apartments Appendix for a predetermined price of $250 CMP becomes not just a housing one with secondary functions of organizational job creation. comparisons of for a attractive to (87%) . moderate apartments. provide residents. by high rent lends level of rehabilitation it spent on maintenance any program with multiple goals, far and the highest per unit costs of over portfolio and producing only 11% statistic programs $16,000 those than per of have the Community Management sides. CMP is all DAMP the rehabilitated apartment, At an Tenants and of Of of community the course, the average CMP costs are also programs, 28% of the sold units. costliness of CMP. 70 local economy. more about the underfunding private developers. to been rehabilitation 60% of the budget for management of says produce It has the largest budget and receiving this can secure employment with good benefits Money and sufficient Through CMP community groups itself to extensive criticism from all by (88%) Because the program provides most expensive DAMP program. has development and collections materials and salaries is circulated in the local Like program, life under Community Management with other housing demonstrated occupancy rates able (See Measures of its success include tenants' favorable experiences, funds unit. 3 for a detailed explanation of sales terms.) By involving CBOs, but per other cost lower of than activists complain that landlords, CMP contractors behave too much performing possession run them, traditional adequately as managers but failing to train tenants to assume responsibility themselves. take like As a result, tenants of their buildings without any notion of how and CBO staff struggle in their uncomfortable to landlord role. CBOs complain es@Fatie@ Ap@6t§ 9f th@iF as a CMP that management responsibilities contractor it affect all a group to be rated well by HPD FP must be prompt and accurate in its reporting, achieve high rent collections, and dispose of buildings 4 quickly . Success by these measures could force a group to abandon the role in which it most likely gained credibility in the neighborhood--that Some groups portion will of make activities This of depend tenant advocate and on their CMP their budget. a It conflict of contracts for a organizer. significant is unavoidable that this dependence group think twice that community before engaging in organizing may lead to confrontations with city officials. interest can ultimately damage the group in eyes of neighborhood residents. One original CMP the contractor, a Manhattan group called Housing Conservation Coordinators, decided not reason, to renew its management contract for just this stating: 'The basic philosophy of HCC has been to educate tenants with the aim of tenant self-help.... Community Management' has instead made HCC into a typical landlord's agent and has impeded efforts in developing tenant self-help management'(5). While other HCC CBOs is the only group that refused to renew its have voiced 71 similar complaints contract, about their participation in the program. 6 B. Tenant In Interim Leasing the TIL program tenants sign a gives them management control the lease, lease with the city over their building. tenants must also sign a Upon which signing letter expressing intent to purchase. As manager, the tenant association collects rents, and uses money this to cover operating operating subsidies available. will expenses. weatherization replacement. repairs The is to and tover extent between DAMP the of associations institution, organizations technical of HPD-funded and tenant and may assistance. in depend HPD Homesteading Assistance Board many are on has (UHAB), them window pre-sales leaders, TIL are not formally although enough but The unit (See Appendix 3) sales price for all TIL buildings is $250.00. community cost seldom exceed $2,000 to $3,000 per unit. Tenant no During the term of the lease, HPD money nature negotiated expenditures tied involved for contracted various with to with any local kinds the of Urban a city-wide group well-known its work with low-income cooperatives, to provide training for tenants. entering Association leaders are expected to attend classes upon the program, management skills, at are generally replace one or two faulty systems and find state for There which associated time with at which time they learn bookkeeping and and before finalizing the building's purchase, they become familiar with ownership. 72 When TIL the additional buildings are tasks clustered together and have a working relationship connection with a CBO), (usually through a mutual UHAB can arrange training classes within the neighborhood. TIL is considered successful on several counts. First, it is the most cost effective DAMP program, producing the most units for sale at the lowest per-unit cost. DAMP portfolio, It currently handles 55% of the accounting for only tenant satisfaction is high, 19% of its budget. often in spite of what appear to oppressive neighborhood and building conditions. satisfaction it Second, in a tenant-run building Measuring tenant is tricky, since essentially requires asking tenants to rate themselves as managers. collections and occupancy be rates are both over 90%, Rent offering objective proof of success. Interviews with TIL tenants all convey the pride and commitment that these people bring to their environment. housing They seem convinced that, options available to the poor, self-management. housing "They Said one respondent, considering the in limited they are better off under asked to situations of friends and relatives in the live -living [tenant-run buildings) or they are discuss the neighborhood, exploited by 7 landlords" Major problems confronting most TIL buildings fall not unrelated categories. The first is leader into burn-out. two, Since TIL leaders often have functions beyond typical tenant association members--negotiating with contractors, attending endless meetings, waiting for the plumber, and all the while incurring the wrath 73 the uninvolved who blame them for anything that goes wrong--it of is not surprising that many begin to feel That few buildings have sufficient bookkeeper on the or a professional elected money. leaders. income to hire a exhausted. manager, superintendent adds to the It follows that the second a pressure problem is TIL is the only in rem program in which the rent roll is expected to cover all other isolated and than Central component. When envisioned TIL as ready for sales, roll. In fact, better off operating expenses. It is also the only one Management that doesn't have a DAMP was designed, rehabilitation its originators a program for buildings that were with few structural may have practically defects and a healthy rent TIL buildings are not, on average, significantly DAMP either financially or physically than the other buildings. Since TIL is the in rem tenant's only "as of right" alternative to Central Management--entrance into POMP and CMP is conditioned upon selection by the contractor--to restrict to sales-ready buildings is to deny the option of self-managment and it ownership to most in rem tenants. C. Why Oelf-Hel? and CMP tenant TIL represent two means of arriving at the cooperative ownership. But is this direction for the city's in rem housing policy? raises help some of model discussion the goal appropriate The next section the arguments for and against reliance on a to preserve low-income housing. of how well self- It is followed by current DAMP programs realize their 74 of a goal, the and program that of an alternative outline be could more effective. 1.Critigues of Self-Helg: Critics on I right, the among them professionals, do not attack the efforts of to Instead, run their buildings. many tenants who are trying they question the efficacy of around a housing rehabilitation and management program centering that model. First, the success of Their argument has two parts. cooperative depends on the confluence of so one estate real factors--e.g., the many unreliable the lawyer's willingness tenants' good will, from to volunteer services, etc.--that success is never guaranteed They question to the next. project one circumstances, is replicable, success If market is still or whether such these projects These critics claim secondly that will be only token efforts. private under whether, of the most efficient provider the housing. landlords were given the same boosts that the city now gives to such as grants for rehabilitation, coops, low purchase price, and then they could produce more units adjusted rent levels, cost with far less difficulty. at lower The first argument, concerning the replicability of the selfhelp model, has some validity. management buildings, that its When one talks to tenants in self- one is struck by the effort has gone into maintaining the building. story, patched usually beginning before city 75 Each building ownership, boiler functioning through the winter, and dedication has of an oatmeal- or a contractor finally repairing a collapsed roof after the tenant association president's grandmother gave him a piece of her mind. Each tenant association scrapes special skill. success can't by The be because someone knows someone or "extras" that may predetermined. Perhaps orchestrate than good will of the building residents. coop won't least leave dealings. the luck or special last too long if their All a cooperative's more skills is the difficult to cooperation and Even an economically viable its members can't get personal a differences out along, of or at their business business relationships are conflictual, but when participants especially allow has also share their living space they contentious. may become When tenants are forced into collective action at the time the landlord abandons'the building, they share only the fact that at some point they all apartment at the same address, of similar tenant association disaster into ethnic movies, and often, happened to rent an the fact that they are and economic backgrounds. To some resembles the cast of of one degree those a formula in which an unlikely group of people are thrown a life-threatening situation, escape from which depends on their ability to work together. In than spite of a having these obstacles, few cases. DAMP programs do work in They are now being applied to already sold an additional 10,000 units. 11,000 Not even in more units New York could a program that is providing housing for 21,000 families be considered a token effort. in spite Comments of made experts' by Why the model works so frequently skepticism is difficult tenants reflect the spirit noted 76 to in document. the 1973 of survey with few housing options are willing to work hard to keep tenants their neighbors' had they to which interest, should seem surprised extrordinary their and self- necessity one Observed others. to that "Too often people are disposed to deny as soft-headed interviewer, that the poor reports sentimental and These tenants were proud of is motivated by them arson, inspiration seemed to draw but seemed accomplished, behavior, and to due displacement those around them. from the plight of what of fears or exorbitant rents, abandonment continually Those I interviewed referred their buildings going. to that simply suggests which early cooperatives the people--protecting vital their are other like acting and can interests as best they 8 banding together when the going gets rough" The second criticism--that with similar incentives the private could provide housing more efficiently--can sector more concretely, managers Ownership repetory mechanism for there is an HPD program that gives private The Private an opportunity to operate in rem housing. and for management of Program, Management 1979 in addressed be or POMP, after Mayor Koch suggested tapping private in rem property. real estate the entered be there that in expertise DAMP a the Initially there was little private program but today it attracts more private firms than it can accommodate, and award for enthusiasm criticism innovative much community skepticism about the and has The winner of a been muted. use of CD Funds, well-administered 1984 HUD POMP appears to be a well-designed, program and is therefore a good model 77 by which to test the effectiveness of Under POMP, private in rem management. HPD contracts with real and purchase in rem buildings. for Proposals; estate firms to Firms are solicited by manage Requests last year there were eighty applicants from which 9 HPD Applicants are carefully screened. six firms were chosen . looks for firms that are already involved in management of similar buildings in the area, six more for whom the additional to eight buildings, than or 200 to 300 units) will not one-third of their portfolio. made payments on city repair agreements, harrassing tenants, buildings chosen. like workload (usually represent Managers who have who have been accused of who have neglected code violations, or whose do not appear well-maintained upon inspection HPD the wants above all are to avoid any intimation that abandoned auction program, not is reselling not POMP, buildings to at the end of At the beginning of owners that had once milked them. POMP sign a one-year agreement, contractors which the terms of purchase are negotiated. the expected with and expenses, plan is determined; Community repairs help of the A shortfall. deficit and income and determines the the manager documents the anticipated contract, POMP staff, "rent restructuring" increase) (or rent in the meantime, HPD subsidizes any operating pays a management fee as it does to contractors in the Management Program. that come to HPD also agrees to an average of $3500 to make $4000 subcontractors are chosen and supervised by the manager. end of the year, the real estate firm is 78 systems unit; per At the expected to purchase the entire portfolio it has been managing. used twenty-two contractors, their portfolio. levels are Since 1979 the program has and only two have failed to purchase Restrictions extend beyond purchase: determined by Rent Stabilization new rent guidelines; and buildings cannot be resold for five years without HPD approval. While as this program does not handle the same volume of CMP or TIL, less it succeeds in selling buildings faster and effort than the others. At the end of Fiscal Year POMP buildings containing 4,000 units had been sold. the program generally TIL). units are closely monitored by DAMP staff, well-managed, with 87X rent collection with 83, 75 Buildings in and they are (second only to However, a 1982 study found a sample of POMP buildings were not as well-managed as might be expected considering the expertise 10 the professionals bring to them . There has been one court case, Laureano v. Koch, in which tenants in one POMP building challenged the arbitrary way in which HPD implemented plan, and himself. POMP But this legal purchasing attack was aimed at HPD it did not question the effectiveness of the POMP manager There buildings have been no complaints about the maintenance of from tenant or community groups, could be expected to be vocal The restructuring charged that they were denied the option of the building themselves. policy; its rent success both of if criticism were deserved. of POMP so far proves that carefully screened managers, given adequate rents and new building systems, buildings well. Does this mean that the POMP model 79 which can run should be expanded while tenant self-help is de-emphasized? we consider not what POMP does well must but how To answer this long and how extensively its measures can be applied. POMP will not work in most in rem buildings, not meet the contractors' requirements. real of estate manager, Peter Burgess, a Brooklyn has a POMP contract of seven buildings, which are in the Southside; potential because most do buildings, most of he chose these from a two long list of which he deemed inappropriate. To attract contractors, Burgess says, buildings must contain at least 30 units plus commercial commercial other POMP succeeds only in those distinguishing qualities would and preferrably be located on street so that storefronts can attract good rents. words, of "cream" space, them the in rem stock. require as buildings potentially The typical that In have profitable--the city-owned more substantial subsidies to a attract building a private owner. Burgess Mr. because vacant prefers buildings with a number of apartments can be renovated using HPD then rented for much more than current tenants are rents paid Extension, actually owned. been a thirty-unit money paying. by new tenants allow the manager to make money Southside building that run by a tenant association before becoming In September rent roll was $5197. and High even An example is 145 Grand though old tenants continue to pay less. Street vacancies, had city- 1983, before it entered POMP, the building's In January 1985, program, monthly rents totalled $8114. 80 after nine months in Mr. the Burgess takes pride in the fact the rent of a single tenant increasing tenants., $170 was this 150% improvement that without accomplished in place. old But while nearly all of whom are on public assistance, pay between and $220 for three- and four- whom Mr. room apartments, Burgess admits are "a different kind of new tenants, 11 tenant" , are paying $375 for one bedroom and $425-450 for two bedrooms. Two of also survey successful said was tenancy in managers successfully change in rent levels, hinges on the gradual rent the the apartments to to and or no buildings people paying Whether these apartments will remain available higher rents. to housing little the long term success of turnover of 1982 Burgess improving frequently with tenants in place, of to and are a important a reluctance indicated 12 . So although Mr. public assistance POMP conditions a change in that buildings, on families other the three other contractors interviewed to the poor depends on the continued availability of rent subsidies, and on the new owner's willingness to keep rents at a level acceptable to the subsidy programs. POMP buildings produce management, them. can, with an income, Thus, only the good will POMP's success. Mr. management of in challenge. After rem Burgess, HPD-funded but no one will politics. for example, good rich from years of managing upper But he is guarantee has undertaken the buildings because he is 81 get and of private managers will excited by income cooperatives another neighborhood he claims to be tired of cooperative repairs meetings and a businessman and as such the in intramust If the intuition that led look for ways to increase his profits. him to choose 145 Grand St. Extension is correct and the Southside then in five years, when becomes a more attractive neighborhood, rent and resale restrictions end, sell the buildings at he will have the opportunity to a good profit to a landlord who may not have If his his commitment to ensuring old tenants an affordable rent. intuition is incorrect and the neighborhood deteriorates, he will be faced with the same situation that caused the original owner to abandon in the first place. reluctant In spite of his enthusiasm he probably be management if operating costs begin to exceed to provide the present will high-quality income. While the short-term success of POMP has been convincing, for reasons the units it has produced probably won't constitute these a long-term low-income housing resource. Because the program is new, there have been no follow-up studies done of buildings after they are sold; since none of year period of HPD-monitored period of no way of knowing how they will five- those buildings are past the restricted sales, there is fare without government oversight. Two conditions are necessary for these buildings to provide a more temporary resource: than and profits, a landlord willing to forgo large, quick a neighborhood where the housing market is stable. these conditions more prevalent than the existence of groups of tenants willing to work hard to preserve their housing? Policy Are must be based on the assumption that people act out of interest. always their self- The provision of adequate housing for the poor may not be in the interest of the private realtors on 82 which -POMP relies. It is, on the other hand, always in the interest of a building's inhabitants to help themselves. 2. Critiguges f Self-Hel2 II Other criticisms of self-help housing for low-income focus and on both the political on its concerns and ability implications of this to produce housing. tenants housing movement The first of these is that encouraging tenants to purchase their apartments undertake management discourages them from radical political involvement, both by changing their position in the housing market and by distracting them with managerial tasks. self-help merely program The second that without adequate support and convenient way for government to funding, absolve is itself a a of responsibility to house the poor, is addressed in Chapter Six. The first criticism addresses the concern that the latent purpose of programs encouraging the poor to own their dwellings is to trap them into having a financial stake in status quo and in this way mute their opposition to those in the argument goes, to his or society power. First, ownership changes an inhabitant's relationship her living space, and thus to society. No longer propertyless, the homeowner has something to protect, a reason not to throw a brick through someone's window. has a from a homeowner new set of responsibilities that may keep him or her community ownership, forces Second, while tenant organization activities. Critics argue that promoting contact between immediate leaders rather cooperative neighbors, to arrange the complex affairs than use their energies to away further of their broader all too often, when workers erupted in political struggles: strikes, organizers collected dues cards; pay ". . formed organizers marshalls, and stood off rent when tenants refused to building when people were burning and looting, organizers used committees; 13 ':moment of madness' to draft constitutions" that as homeowners, confront each other; order turn owners cooperative they issues the toward their energy Not only do . but they are often forced to turn it on leaders must exercise authority over others in elected to fulfill management obligations, to the extent of being called upon to evict their neighbors. In this view, tenant self-managers are accepting the rules of "housing as a profitable commodity" system. the current been They have property of their own to cultivate as they wish handed are busying themselves with that the fact addressing activity rather than their adequate considered not a right but a privilege, and that that the system is still unjust, housing is still that they must earn the right to keep it by sacrificing their time money. programs Some radical housing that analysts believe divert pressure from society's powerful, development of and a movement mass advocating and self-help hindering the government's responsibility to provide housing for all. The day when our government acknowledges its shelter all people through have its citizens may be long in coming, to live somewhere. The in a combination of public rental 84 rem obligation to and meanwhile poor housing program, housing and tenant-managed cooperatives, realized offers today. several housing alternatives that The question for those who both advocate help housing and share the goal is whether can of a public commitment to the self-help aspects of the IRHP run be selfhousing counter to the efforts to reaffirm public responsibility for the poor. Those tenure who status But change in 235 implied that homeownership opportunities would turn disenfranchised values. a are basing their fears on the rhetoric of the program, which the fear the deradicalizing effects of it poor into upholders of American capitalist is far more probable that many disadvantaged households place a value on a permanent homestead and the holding of property that has little to do with more mainstream, market-oriented standards of the goodness of investment(14). Low-income minority cooperative participants characteristics, society's attractive been of equally They rental housing. 235 similar were option of home ownership, offensiveness in have of stakeholders. substandard others purchasers housing, as ethnic and disinterested not their community, becoming toward as much as "pushed" out Participants repeatedly cited of their previous living situations, as reason to pursue family or cooperative ownership, and those either without expressing any to are people in low tax brackets, structured so that 85 of the of interest The deductions mean little and many subsidized little capital the single- in altering their social status or improving their finances. financial benefits of ownership such as tax as economic in "pulled" well gain can be cooperatives realized. In sum, are "low-income really renters indicating interest expressing a desire for improved housing quality, 15 dwellings" Interviews evidence of with people sensibilities. Those in better owner-occupancy neighborhoods and not simply a fee interest in DAMP participants provide "selling out" questioned or little abandoning mentioned and their further their tenant affordability, good services, and the power to maintain those benefits as the factors 16 made their present situation preferable to renting . Even that residents of coops that were unsuccessful by objective standards such as fiscal health and management performance still preferred 17 cooperative ownership for these reasons . Tenants in several Southside buildings mentioned the dismal conditions housing in the neighborhood as sufficient motivation 18 takeover ; a tenant in a TIL building in a in private for tenant gentrified neighborhood felt that self-management was the only way she could 19 avoid being forced to move ; a tenant in a city-owned building which has between been city preferred mishandled by HPD and a local programs still stated CBO and unequivocally shunted that her current predicament to the exploitation of she private 20 ownership . In Harlem,. residents of TIL buildings "could not answer TIL the question, 'What would you have done if there were no 21 program?'" The statement of a member of a recently purchased DAMP coop illustrates the continuing sense of among tenants turned owners: "We started several Desperation Tenants Association. struggle years ago as the Today, things have changed, and 22 we are the Desperation Cooperative". 86 The claim prevents not that the responsibility of running tenants from engaging in other community borne out periodically emphasize by feel the the evidence. overwhelmed by lessons of many participating in a coop: 23 situations Surely these you must fight to gain " something "Working "In . Furthermore, the impact of has been profound. All interviewed felt gained from involvement. they had other participation on especially women, skills the 24 positive" individuals, building., they sentiments would encourage participation in community struggles. is leaders responsibilities, together you can accomplish more than working alone worst building activities Although their a personally leaders their Aside from their pride in their ability to manage a they have gained confidence in and the value of president spoke something useful, of their opinions. the even "satisfaction of if the their organizational One tenant being issue being 25 association able to discussed offer is not directly related to your building" By yirtue officially leaders or of the fact that many informally associated with buildings a local are either CBO, tenant may get involved in other community issues. The CBO in the Southside is run by a Board on which every tenant-run building in the result neighborhood is entitled to have a representative. of this initial association., several tenant leaders become active Board members and community spokespeople on issues. In the Southside and in Harlem as well, study by Leavitt and Saegart, many of 87 As a have diverse according the the the men in tenant leadership roles had activities, for the previously but first been involved in community most of the women were drawn out of 26 time by tenant issues . Some women or their participate public in job assistance Another challenge its to the participants Critics the oil. communal Several who were previously claim that the self-help nature on housing of cooperative would argue that cooperative housing is just except everyone has to chip in to pay While New York City coops are not living Owens' utopias, the services get their Equivalency Diplomas, or is like single-family housing, for in are now employed. depoliticizes ownership. training. homes involved their tenant associations were thus exposed to community and inspired to study English, church along the lines of an Israeli experiments kibbutz or they can be an alternative--even a in Robert challenge--to "dream house" ideal popularized and promoted in this country 27 government policy and private market advertising . Such an by alternative becomes more important as the nuclear family for which the traditional Making cooperative indifference have of detached home was designed becomes less ownership work in the and skepticism and appreciating of official its unique benefits opened the eyes of some DAMP participants to the possibility "redesigning the American dream." As tenants in a building band together, their landlord, or in his absence, nature of their relationship and fac'e common. services are 88 to run their to each other informally either to exchanged; challenge building, is transformed. older the Skills residents, for example, provide childcare for the younger ones, read or translate important letters. are in basements and courtyards. out while months of tenant this in another the superintendent set and their organization in another building, one of between and children played in white a few the few (primarily apartment doors the up basement After Jewish) and Hispanic tenants, unlocked in An @y@ on the troublesome boiler. study that was equally split elderly left making one room into a brightly he and his friends could hang out kept h@ commodity, In one building the tenants cleaned colored meeting/party room; so Together the scarcest urban the garbage-filled basement, weights them Families without telephones connected to the outside world by those with them. residents create recreation space, in who help hallways. were Older residents commented happily that it was "like the old days." Certainly people don't need to own their building in order to cooperate with successful they because before ownership gives people a sense of brings the build developed that some tenant-run their neighbors; this collective activity. landlord contact on walked beyond As renters, close relationships away. owners, The would are that But cooperative control over their environment casual friendship and into they can't decide who moves in next door or how often the halls get cleaned, basement buildings or decide that be a great place to have a Christmas the party. As with the they can. pride of the tenants 89 interviewed coupled objective rates indicators and good suggests that buildings. rent of management success collection) tenant Whether for these efforts will found in self-management this can (e.g., and low other save studies., abandonned the HPD programs provide sufficient be addressed vacancy support in the next chapter. Notes on Chapter Five 1. Sullivan, Division of Alternative Management fggrams. 2. Schur, 3. Sullivan. 4. Ibid, 5. Ibid, 4-13. 6. 7A Leasing There are actually three tenant leasing programs: (in which a court-appointed administrator runs the building) and Tenant Ownership Program, for buildings of one or two by far the largest. units. TIL is 7. Cosme interview. 8. Kolodny, Self-Helg 9. Alter "Growing Lemons", 43. 4-30. in the Inner City 177. interview. 10. Sullivan, 8-20. 11. Burgess interview. 12. Sullivan., 8-13. Pgor Richard Cloward, Frances Fox Piven and 13. Books, .1977).,xiii. (New York: Vintage Movements Peoles 14. Victor Bach, "A Chance to Own," Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Urban Studies and Planning, (1977),256. 15. Stegman, Housing Ineystment., 195. 16. Sullivan. 90 M.I.T. 17. Lawson. 18. Melendez 19. Cabrera interview. 20. Cosme interview. interview. 21. Jacqueline Leavitt and Susan Saegert, Buildings: A Feminist Approach to Housing," (Summer 1984) 35. 22. Speech given by tenant association reception marking the sale of the February 6, 1985. " Women and Abandoned Social Policy 15, member at City Hall 10.,000th DAMP unit, 23. Cabrera interview. 24. Cosme interview. 25. Melendez interview. 26. Leavitt and Saegert, 37. 27. Dolores Hayden, Norton & Co. 1984). Redesigning the American Dream 91 (New York: WW CHAPTER SIX: DAMP'S EFFECTIVENESS IN CREATING TENANT COOPERATIVES Given the. conclusion that the self-help model represents good blueprint for preservation of personal development and low-income housing, encouraging community involvement as providing alternatives to the depressed rental market, section DAMP I will currently look at whether structured, a the specific encourage the long-term well as in the next programs, stability of as the coops. Whether section will created in this viable. If, as some critics charge, the city is merely practicing all mean its own brand of the benefits described in a thing depends on whether program are financially lemon socialism, optionless tenants, the the and preceding cooperatives organizationally dumping hopeless. properties on then self-help is no more than fancy rhetoric for allowing the poor to fend for themselves. Interviews organization approach and staff to with tenant, point self-help city officials to three areas of which, if not lack buildings; the policy--both purchase areas and alternatives second the is the for general pressure put on tenant of pysical the cooperatives, tenants seriously in is the city-owned about groups by HPD sales staff strong and the third is the which often HPD's The first confusion defects and increasingly without 92 in addressed, the policy of treating buildings in differently than the others; underfunding serious of community weakness jeopardize the long-term success of the program. perceived and are to market chronic sold assurances with of rental A. subsidies. Lack of Alternatives Not everyone wants to live in a cooperative. cooperatives maintenance payments are usually adequate to the services of a building manager,, to ensure In upper income adequate upkeep. cover and are certainly high enough Because upper income cooperative dwellers can renters, while enjoying ownership benefits of equity accumulation occupy their and tax deductions, New York City. still the In spite of these advantages there are that business. how you live and with expenses. Monthly individual apartments, ownership whom brings is someone with carrying charges don't cover and it additional repairs building-wide emergencies personally prefer to rent, sometimes rents one would certainly choose the former. This agree to an alternative management program, While improvements in HPD's management standards has been performance is still Central Management. noted, too uneven and the future too uncertain tenant group to feel is the result of is cooperative ownership, or opt for at They must which any inside if faced with.the the situation of most tenants in city-owned buildings. either else's joining a cooperative or risking substandard housing uncertain who assessments. While one may choice of many in objecting to the meetings and rules and to Furthermore require special were coop apartments have become very popular choose to rent, sense apartments almost as though they that chosing to remain a rental will for not be regretted shortly. of a permanent promulgate The city's ambivalence about the existence rental stock., manifested in its clear policies about rent levels or commit rehabilitation standards, has the effect of failure to itself to driving tenants to the alternatives. Why should this be a problem? After all, one of of this thesis is that the self-help model should as many tenant desirability is groups as that model's tenants are As long as there are no options there These non-enthusiasts range from those who pay their rent but resent any further involvement, don't tenant evict the be those in DAMP buildings who would rather be in a different housing situation. who be available to However, predicated on the assumption participating voluntarily. will possible. the points pay rent, don't keep up their apartments, leaders to use expensive, them. In to problem tenants time-consuming legal some cases tenant associations, future under Central Management, and force means wary of agree to alternative to their management evem though they lack solid support from the majority of tenants. (TIL requires that 75% of all the program, understanding When tenants sign an agreement to but experience shows that people will the implications and later refuse they are unable to run their building, sign to leaders enter without cooperate.) feel they have failed. Tenant groups should choose alternative management the concept of control and eventual 94 because ownership appeals to them, not it's their only way of assuring adequate services because secure future. opting for Furthermore, self-management cooperative individual buildings who don't wish to participate building nearby. Perhaps HPD and a local work out some kind of exchange, DAMP opportunity to in a coop by can't interest in the idea could be referred to local Since is important ultimate control that DAMP tenant could elsewhere. her DAMP or his buildings. associations retain over tenant selection it would not be possible to assure such a tenant a DAMP apartment, to another CBO apartment neighbors it a Management building who wants the in a Central live in whereby a household in a building could be offered a suitable Similarly, a tenant useful in should have the option of being relocated to city-owned entering tenants a and DAMP buildings but such a system could be looking for prospective coop participants. B. Sales Policy Another shortcoming of current HPD tenant-management programs is their vague and arbitrary sales policy. has been Sales, Some tenant groups complain of being purchase their buildings before they are ready., are confusion about tenant what or "outtake," the most contentious DAMP issue since the division created. purchase or unclear about the cause of stems from the lack of delay. pressured managment, Much consensus among city consensus about DAMP's purpose. goals were articulated: traceable to to others waiting to should be accomplished during the interim community was further of this officials period of lack of During its first year., three DAMP one, to provide decent housing to tenants 95 of in rem buildings; two, to train organizations to manage and thereby test their ability to eventually own in rem buildings; three, and "to ultimately convey title of upgraded through 1 a period of the properties, responsible and stabilized management, to private groups" Early statements also emphasized the subordination of sales goals to the larger aims of neighborhood stabilization: The success of the In Rem Housing Program will be marked not by short term revenue gain at the expense of future deterioration of the existing stock. Rather, the Program will have achieved its goal if neighborhoods where there are presently large numbers of City-owned properties have been strengthened and if buildings once sold remain on the tax rolls and do not return to City ownership several years after sale(2). By and 1981 program participants noted a new emphasis less concern Forgetting while the training Report would stated, be on initial an appropriate DAMP goals of new managers, "The whether stabilization providing the Fourth Annual true test of on the success of they could achieve volume period. decent In sales housing Rem DAMP Housing programs rehabilitation and sales" Ideally, for a coop to be successful things must occur before the tenants While some enter organizations period to developed; must reach and achieve city ownership secure finances, these ends. its members must in the long run, several purchase with their sophisticated most require A tenant an tenant incubation association must learn how to manage a building; a consensus on organization by-laws and 96 building. learn be they enough about the decisions legal principles of about their future. cooperative ownership Meanwhile, to make the renovation work A continual agreed to tenant leaders is that HPD's pressure to purchase begins or not by HPD must be completed. these processes have been complaint A completed. of whether 1982 study confirmed these impressions, finding that a building's position in the in sales "pipeline" was correlated only with the program, its length of and not with buiding conditions or time management 4 ability The development of a cohesive sales policy has been further hindered by the Koch administration's fear that tenant cooperators in gentrifying neighborhoods will resell profit. Concern situated Here, plus centered around their apartments at great the Chelsea-Clinton on Manhattan's West Side between 14th and 59th the real estate boom that has affected all Streets. Manhattan, the development of a the new Jacob Javits Convention and proposed commercial development for Times Square, what had been New York's toughest neighborhood, as of area, Hell's Kitchen, $100,000 coops. into an area of $1,000 City's hands. strengthening, Management this would have turned previously By some 1982, dozen as the real buildings were known a month rentals Ten years ago the old housing stock of had been considered undesirable, so much of Center this area it had ended up in the estate market completing was Community and Tenant Interim Lease and preparing for sales. time HPD informed the tenants have to purchase their in these buildings apartments at a "fair 97 and that market At they rate"., which would certainly be beyond the means of An unprecendented management tenants, city-wide most of mobilization them. of alternative all of whom felt their future threatened if the Clinton-Chelsea tenants were displaced, succeeded in restoring the $250 per unit sales price. exchange for earned efforts to C. this was gained resale restrictions that require a portion profits by work Appendix 3) However, sale of shares to revert to out the details of this the of in any city. The plan (see cumbersome have held up sales on a number of buildings. Financial Viability The whether last and most critical test it provides the financial long term viablity of of the DAMP program resources needed to ensure is the its cooperatives. DAMP sales are too recent for there to have been any longitudinal studies at this point, but pre-sale financial data and follow-up studies on cooperatives developed under other programs suggest that many DAMP coops be head for trouble. stability of implications management In this section I will projects of under insufficient TIL and funding could examine the financial CMP for and discuss future the alternative efforts. In 1982, Pratt Institute surveyed twelve Community Management and eleven Tenant Interim Lease buildings other things, their financial viability. buildings to determine, They found that to bring up to acceptable standards in the Community Program, in which up to $ 2 0 , 0 00 98 among Management per dwelling unit may be spent for rehabilitation, low-interest a loans combination of was sufficient. required a $9,418 per apartment amount going buildings range: located investment, in the Southside were at systems repairs and $2222 for after each sales building with the bulk of this The two survey the high end South 2nd Street required $12,070 for repairs); On average, toward building-wide systems repairs. 227 ($9848 program funds and of per dwelling cosmetic the unit apartment and 263 South 2nd Street needed $11,938, with $7642 for 5 systems and $3756 for apartments In $1500 TIL buildings, per dwelling unit where the maximum investment in 1982 (since raised to $2,000 to situation was very different. study investment needed came to $9211 $5355 needed for per apartment systems repairs. between the needs of the program. the the eleven buildings in the required repair work beyond the scope of the program. average of Ten of $3,000) was per dwelling This left unit, The with a gap of some $8,000 the building and the provisions The study concluded that Any projections for successful long-term disposition of TIL buildings to their tenants must be based on the rather tenuous assumption that this mismatch will be overcome....The failure of the TIL program to succeed by this critical measure undermines completely whatever success it achieves by the other...criteria(6). On carrying the whole the Pratt analysts were satisfied that costs were within the rent-paying range of tenant population. the the monthly in rem CMP buildings required post-purchase rents in $35-50 per room range. The two Southside buildings 99 in the sample were at the high end of was $40 a room, a room, were this range: 227 South 2nd Street or $208 a month, and 263 South 2nd Street was $55 or $273 a month for a two-bedroom apartment. affordable to families earning These rents $8,303 or $10,928 respectively, assuming a family could pay a rent equivalent to 30% of its income. building to TIL rents fell into the same range; the located in the Southside that was studied was require rents of nearly $50 a room, apartment, affordable 7 family earning $10,098 Pratt's (assuming questionable comfortably assumptions. projected or $252 for a two-bedroom a 30". rent/income ratio) concludsion that the rents needed to buildings are affordable to most TIL to support a these in rem tenants is premised on two First, it assumes that a family can pay 30% of its gross income for rent. figure used by the federal government, but This in fact it is the is high for B a family with children , especially since monthly rentals do not include electricity and cooking gas, which could add $25 to $45 to a family's monthly budget. the assumption systems operating If they monthly repairs, that Second, the renovations in TIL buildings will expenses borrow projected rents are based on needed to somehow be made. repair If they are for these buildings are likely to be to make repairs, they will debt service to their expenses. If have faulty to not higher. add their they don't make the their operating expenses will reflect the fact that they will be making constant emergency repairs. 100 I have therefore reviewed the monthly financial statements of several TIL buildings assumptions. in the Southside in different The two presented here are fairly typical--one is in good condition, the other in fair condition. program under August, 1982 Both entered the TIL after of period of unofficial tenant management, and both are expected to be sold to the tenants within the coming year. various the rent assumes I 25% to 30% of its gross income for rent. have given three sets of mechanical they will projections. the building envelope is weathertight; has working a projections borrows HPD In first will makes no repairs and remain constant; considered repairs, In the inspection,, too sale: income lost to rent arrears. the possibility of HPD hard to extimate and second, the third set of tenant -association replace two collection to In neither case have undertaking without first, a non-system because thorough the building because that is the kind of work tenants are most capable of accomplishing Unfortunately that fifteen projected rents are high endugh except for appliance replacement; are today. and each apartment both cases I have assumed that the rent compensate for costs stove and refrigerator. another money from a low-interest revolving fund to systems. I The systems are in good enough working order so function without major breakdown for in each needed repairs before years; rates For that the building is sold to the tenants as it is The second assumes that HPD makes all all support levels assuming that a family can pay somewhere range of building I have calculated the income needed to themselves. it is hard to evaluate the potential 1C)1 fiancial succes of a building from these income and expense statements. would appear, high monthly for instance, It that a tenant association that expenses could anticipate more financial had problems than one that didn't spend so much, when in fact the former may be more diligent in making repairs. information from monthly information from tenant expenses would included the I have therefore combined expense and income statements interviews to get a sense of be incurred over the course of additional projected a expenses the with what kinds of year. I associated have with ownership. 195 South Fourth Street This apartments is (see Table 6.1) a 35-unit building with no commercial have either 3.5 or 4.5 rooms. units. All some rent It has had collection problems, mostly due to one or two delinquent families. The tenant month) New association pays 7% of to one of its members, windows and a recapped roof are the only designed oversized, and to heat inefficient. 102 two major $300 a functions. improvements All other systems- are faulty, the boiler has been a constant source of originally (around who performs management undertaken over the past few years. and the rent roll anxiety and expense; buildings, it is ancient, Table 6.1 195 South Fourth Street Monthly Income and Expenses (based on reports for November and December, 1984 and January, 1985) Income Rents Billed Rent Collected $5300 4660 (87.9") EX~e sesm Fixed Costs: Super's Salary Manager's Fee Liability Insurance Debt Servic-e $150 300 90* 135** 675 Subtotal Variable Costs: Oil Electrical Repairs Supplies Service 2400*** 115**** 600 200 Subtotal TOTAL 3990 *Not actually paid this quarter **On no-interest loan taken from local repairs. ***Adjusted to reflect winter months. ****Covers electricity for common areas boiler) 103 fund to (halls, make boiler basement and In made, Projection 195 South Plumbing repairs., 1 (see Table 6.2), Fourth Street in which no is very repairs expensive to are operate. boiler maintenance and fuel make up the bulk of the monthly expenses. To make ends meet the tenants would have to pay $68.00 a room or $240 for the 3.5 room apartments and $306 for the 4.5 room apartments. 25% and 30% of incomes of Since all its income for rent, these apartments would require $8655 to $11,520 and $11,016 tenants between in Assuming a family pays somewhere between the in this building probably have $6500 median rem tenants in subsidies to pay this Projection the Southside most of incomes somewhere and $8000 median them would require 2 assumes that HPD has repaired require an approximately building. At 195 South Fourth $7000 per unit In all for rent systems before Street investment. would need a smaller reserve expenses are lower. respectively. rent. the building for the city, selling the to $14,688, this case, minimal fund., rent that would As a result and operating increases would be required. Projection repair debt 3 assume that the tenants have borrowed $90,000 to their plumbing system and replace their service obligation of $622 a month, boiler. they must raise rents to $52 a room: $182 4.5 room apartment. Some tenants would require rent A With a their for a 3.5 room apartment and $234 for a susbsidies. large reserve fund would be needed to cover emergency repairs to those systems not covered by the loan money. 104 Table 6.2 195 South Fourth Street Projected Monthly Expenses and-Required Rents After Sale Ec::2d.L 1 Pr PriA2 Fixed Costs: Fire&Liability Corporate Taxes Prop. Taxes Salaries Debt Service $ 416.60 75.00 625.00 450.00 135.00 416.60 75.00 625.00 450.00 135.00 416.60 75.00 625.00 450.00 757.00 Variable Costs: Plumbing Electrical 1500.00 350.00 350.00 150.00 350.00 350.00 350.00 75.00 100.00 Painting Appliances Extermin. Boiler Elect. Serv. Fuel Misc.Supplies Misc.Repairs Reserve 80.00 400.00 75.00 200.00 115.00 2400.00 150.00 200.00 700.00 80.00 200.00 75.00 100. 00 115.00 1700.00 150.00 100.00 300.00 80.00 400.00 75.00 100.00 115.00 1900.00 150.00 150.00 700.00 TOTAL 6520.00 5096.60 4470.00 68.00 42.50 52.00 Plaotering Required Rent per room 240.00 3.5 Rm Apt Required Income 8655-11,520 150.00 5365-7200 306.00 4.5 Rm Apt Required Income 11,016-14,688 190.00 6885-9120 182.00 6552-8736 234.-8424-11,232 *Projection 1--Building sold as is. **Projection 2--HPD does all needed repairs ***Projection 3--Tenants borrow $90,000 at 3%, Appendix (See calculated.) 4 for an 105 explanation of 15-year pay-back. how figures were 167 Havemeyer Street building has twenty apartments, This rooms, four and stores. the tenants rents in own their pay no management fee. building; or stores, the rents at Havemeyer Street has always been collection their keep to each with 4.5 The rents paid by the compared to other commercial modeset allow (see Table 6.3) 5.5 while neighborhood, low. rent The They excellent. They have made a number of improvements in only their plumbing and electrical systems pose problems. Projection Under 1, tenants would have to the 4.5 room apartment would rent for $245 $10.,692 to Many $14,256). commercial rents difficulties repairs. physical need rent its costs by increasing (see Table 6.4). these if would of Under the other two projections, analyses give us only a partial of $8820 (requiring incomes tenants 167 Havemeyer Street could cover These viability the of subsidies to pay these amounts. however, (requiring imcomes of a 5.5 room apartment for $297 to $11,760); Thus a rents to $54 a room. rents by 20. and their own commercial the raise they cooperatives. had 167 Havemeyer, condition, could sense of the potential Clearly to buy their both manage without buildings thanks to its commercial any rents and good with only access interest loan and no HPD-funded repairs. have would to a low- 195 South Fourth Street would require at least some combination of city-sponsored repairs 106 Table 6.3 167 Havemeyer Street Monthly Income and Expenses (based on reports from November and December, 1984 and January, 1985) Income $4409 1150 Rents billed Commercial Residential 3259 Rents collected 4075 Fixed Costs Super's Salary Liability Insurance 74.00 84.00 Variable Costs Fuel (gas) Electrical Repairs Supplies Service (92.5%) 1340. 00* 60.00 1533.00 579.00 4210.00 TOTAL *Adjusted to reflect winter months. 107 Table 6.4 167 Havemeyer Street Projected Monthly Expenses and Required Rents After Sale Ecgd..L Fixed Costs: Fire&Liability Corporate Tax es Prop. Taxes Salaries Debt Service Io 1 .3 ..- 500. 30 60. O0 833. 00 74.00 691.00 74.00 -- O-- 500.30 60.00 833. 00 74. 00 -- 0-- Variable Costs: Plumbing Electrical Plastering Painting Appliances Extermin. Boiler Elect. Serv. Fuel Misc. Supplies Misc.Repairs Reserve 1500.00 200.00 200.00 50.00 229.00 75.00 50.00 60.00 1340.00 150.00 200.00 500.00 200. 00 100.00 50.00 50. 00 116.00 75.00 50.00 60.00 1340.00 150 . OO0 100.00 300.00 200. 00 100.00 50.00 50.00 116. 00 75.00 50.00 60. 00 1340.00 150. 00 100.00 300.00 TOTAL 60210.30 4058.30 4749. 30 54.00 35.00 35.00 20%X 10% 20X $500.30 60. 00 833.00 Required Rent per room Commercial rent increase 245.00 4.5 Rm Apt Required Income 8820-11,760 5.5 Rm Apt Required Income 297.00 10,692-14,256 157.50 5670-7560 157.50 5670-7560 192.50 6930-9240 1?2. 50 6930-9240 *Projection 1--Building sold as is. **Projection 2--HPD does all needed repairs ***Projection 3--Tenants borrow $100,000 at 3X, 1 5-year pay-back. Appendix (See calculated.) 4 for an explanation 108 of how f i gures were and access to loan money to survive in the long run. neither of these buildings has the resources to survive emergency. not Since low-interest emergencies. repairs out a course, a major tenant cooperatives in slum neighborhoods likely to get conventional the Of loans bank loans, provided by are it is important HPD be that available for One problem with relying on these funds for systems before sales is that once a tenant association has loan it will be hard-pressed to find funds to deal taken with an emergency. Whether and how cooperatives will financial pressures be able to cope with future is of concern to their participants. previously cited follow-up of the projects studied in that debt for that all of the 46 cooperatives had very serious tax and 9 service arrears . Since DAMP cooperatives are not eligible tax abatements and are frequently borrowing to HPD will not do, Division through the same Avenue, a the confronted TIL difficulties as their program and been will predecessors. 104 purchased raising in had 1982, gone is now the systems not repaired by HPD. in order to borrow money. also considering the possibility of and repairs they cooperative in the Southside that with the breakdown of units, make there is the possibility that The tenants must raise their rents the showed but 26. experience are 1973 The capital increasing the when people by They price into of the 10 cooperative Low-income . cooperatives may discouraging other turn housing to this method poor families from 109 advocates of fear raising joining. that many money, thus Several other Management good the Community substantial received considerably more A few years after sale these buildings are still physical pressures. and and Program, rehabilitation. in had been produced through cooperatives Southside condition and therefore free of financial Some of them, however, are experiencing organizational management problems, perhaps traceable to CMP's failure to train tenant associations adequately. It housing is the spectre of financial failure that cause low-income advocates the most concern about the future of management of in rem properties in New York City. self-help They are worried that without proper funding these programs are doomed from while desperate tenants run the start, them work. in circles trying to tenants set adrift in Images of make or leaky lifeboats, "cooperative ownership as 'judas-goat' . . . leading the proverbial 11 claim critics are evoked. The harshest to slaughter" lambs that the program is merely an acceptable way for the government ignore its responsibility to provide housing income tenants respond to the promise of for the poor. control to Low- and security, but without sufficient funds it turns out to be illusory. The lesson of the stories related management can work, and when above is that tenant it does it can produce benefits such community involvement as well as improved housing. But the success of tenant-managed buildings depends on a delicate as increased balance of financial cooperation. support, In several technical crucial the confluence of these factors. 110 assistance, and resident ways, HPD programs fail to ensure By encouraging tenant control in landlord-abanondoned opportunity to affordable homes buildings., create a using the network minimal City of of permanent, subsidies., buildings that would otherwise drain municipal paying sources of pride. doing whatever is New York has the comfortable, thereby turning resources into tax HPD's efforts should be directed toward necessary to make these projects work, especially since their failure only results in greater management burdens for the city. Notes on Chapter Six 1. New York City Development, First 2. Ibid, Department of Housing Preservation Annual In Rem Housing Fggam Begort and 30. Department of Housing Preservation nnual In Rem Housing Prggram Beggt and 6. 48. 3. New York City Development, Fourth 4. Sullivan., Division of Alternative Management 5. Ibid. 6. Ibid, 10-52. 7. Ibid, 10-45. 6. Michael Hartman, ed. 9. Stone, "Housing and the Economic America's Housing grisis. PCgrams. Crisis," in Chester Lawson, Owners of Last Resort 118. 10. ii. 2-21. Barbara Schliff Sullivan, interview. Division of Alternative 111 Management Prggrams CHAPTER SEVEN: ASSISTED TENANT LEASING: A PROPOSED ALTERNATIVE MANAGEMENT MODEL Both Community programs designed to create tenant strengths, ability but to both viable Interim cooperatives., have flaws that call develop development. a Management and Tenant housing into while Leasing., have two important question fostering their community CMP provides jobs, renovates apartments, facilitates relationship between tenant groups and knowledgeable organizations, and offers CBO the opportunity to community extend their influence in their communities. It does not, however, adequately prepare running their building, tenants for the task of and it compromises CBOs by making them middlemen between HPD and tenants. TIL, on the other hand, management, but leaves financial support. programs, whereby receive gives tenants the opportunity for them Moreover, the with insufficient technical buildings arguing less. and there is an inequity in these two in Community Management up to $20,000 of renovation funds per unit, buildings receive much self- can whereas TIL While tenants in CMP buildings are about the color of their new bathroom tiles, TIL tenants are making do with inadequate plumbing. A. ProCam Dsign I am proposing Assisted Tenant Leasing as an alternative replace both Community Management and TIL. The structure of to ATL would be very much sign a lease with HPD, accepting management responsibility for its building like that of TIL. and agreeing to eventual 112 A tenant association purchase at $250 an would apartment. HPD would contract with CBOs to perform services in support of There is already a buildings in their catchment area. for this sort of arrangement: Currently, precedent HPD contracts with CBOs its Community Consultant program. through ATL Recognizing that its programs are only as good as their ability to reach those who need that CBOs already have communication networks in their and them, HPD areas, services city Community Consultant Contracts, funded by federal bureaucracy. dollars, and programs city as a liaison between community residents and act generally pays groups to promote are usually sufficient to cover the cost of CD one or two expand the staff people. As of the ATL program, part HPD would Community Consultant program so that groups in areas with current city-owned stock could devote one or two extensive exclusively working with tenant-run buildings, to parallel program to achieve the same purpose. buildings typewriter and coops. For instance, up a The contract would by there might be money for ATL a and funds to reimburse the its photocopying machines and telephones. Tenant- buildings might also be able to use the CBO's facilities meetings. for Since new tenant associations are often unfamiliar with organizational with or set for CBO for use of CBO people or other office equipment that would be available tenant" association officials to use, their staff for staff and for overhead costs incurred funds provide run either procedures, meetings, CBO staff could be available to attend help them determine agendas and set up by-laws. staff can also be indispensable in acquainting tenant leaders government programs that can benefit 113 their building, and arr-anging technical could bulk purchasing and credit. splitting to hire the professional the fee. of with the various staff performing day-to-day benefit that extends beyond its immediate also provides Frequently of a trained repairs, ordering function, maintenance staff will be hired by This is since employment for a dozen or so community CMP coops provide materials, and at times undertaking major rehabilitation. a staff leadership. the benefits of CMP is its provision maintenance require And CBO staff would be available to training whenever there is turnover of One buildings architects or lawyers CBO services of engineers, arrange If it residents. TIL tenant associations to work in their buildings after regular work hours; this provides skilled local additional income for the staff and workers for tenant-run buildings. site maintenance staff is one of access However, to an on- CMP's largest expenses. One of the goals of ATL would be to enable CBOs to maintain a repair HPD's staff that was more or less contract maintenance with ATL or a CBO could include some staff--perhaps supervisor's salary. already self-sufficient. Tenant overhead costs To provision and a begin, for a maintenance associations, whether participants in cooperative owners, could hire the CBO's maintenance company for repairs, paying them for their services as they could would pay a private contractor. even bid on large renovation jobs; The if maintenance effective company it would most likely start getting requests from private landlords as well. 114 The would be for the maintenance company to become goal profit subsidiary of the CBO; a it ever actually made a if forprofit the money could be used to fund other CBO activities. Ideally, buildings their rent roll while in city ownership. TIL buildings are already self-supporting. operating tenant would be able to support themselves from In Community subsidy to cover all Management, receives the buildings in its have it. before adding the additional Rent subsidies, building is currently purchased, a idea It is important for tenants the experience of operating their building on roll an contract; association therefore buys its buildings without any of what it actually costs to run to a CBO burden of its taxes and insurance. available to tenants only should be extended into rent after the the pre-sales period as well. HPD should (electrical, envelope agree to sell heating, secure. buildings with all plumbing) Tenants working could be repairs sUch as replacing appliances, Tenant to and the responsible painting, for and systems building internal plasteri.ng. associations could decide for themselves whether they want borrow money to attend to these matters, individual cooperators. investment by $15,000 per For some buildings, HPD might be sufficient, unit--HPD should be permitted for these system repairs. per well major unit amounts -of cost estimates.) While money being allocated 115 or leave them up a $2 , 00 0 for others it flexible about per unit might the to be amount (See Chapter Eight for average ATL might result to different in unequal buildings, the inequality would coincidence interest of be based on documented need having landed in one program form of represents currently course, a gradual phase-in of smaller commitment a available every under another. of funds, soundness of would Community the Low- and tax Such abatements could take property tax to Community building as in rehabilitation dearth or than loans should remain available for emergencies, abatements should be offered as well. the rather payments. rehabilitation Management. receive a Mangement. than Ideally,, complete However, it is preferable to attend to This the is of moderate given the structural many buildings than to completely renovate some while others have major system deficiencies. B. Sales Policy ATL's goal would be to enable tenants to complete the program in two to three years. allow for delays management skills. timetable development. remain flexible, to in repair work and the development of tenant Periodic meetings should be held with tenant association officials, a This time period must CBO staff and HPD personnel to discuss the for repairs, HPD and CBO coordinators could arrange appropriate rent increases, and management training to address tenant association weaknesses. Resale restrictions should be designed to ensure the continued availability of these units to low-income families. The law for under which these coops are formed 116 (see Appendix 3 details), which combined forbids the income exceeds six sale of units times the rent, to families whose is sufficient to do this, but enforcement mechanisms must be created. The terms of resale restrictions are difficult, because they must balance with the public's interest in maintaining the coop investment. owner's After all, affordable right to earn a return while on housing his or her "you've limited the profits on these 1 buildings, . . you've done nothing to limit the risks" . The . current HPD policy in "hot" neighborhoods--demanding a percent profits for Sellers will be tempted to charge more for their shares in order earn their expected rate of return after paying off the city. to Given the situated itself--seems low turnover like this "tax" it. Far worst in DAMP coops in profit-making areas, from the and possible the C. solution. few buildings HPD is unlikely to earn to pay the salary of the person hired to enough collect more effective would be a system in which tenants eligible for a predetermined modest rate of return on of were investment. Program Rationale CMP tenant such and TIL represent two models of groups and neighborhood institutions. interaction The former creates a dependent relationship that it stifles the development the cooperative and diverts the CBO from its advocacy latter their CBO sold, between role. is so ill-defined that TIL buildings may be struggling own in areas where the expertise of staff could be helpful. there buildings are other coop leaders Once coops in either few places they can turn to for and purchased coops must purchase fuel 117 program support. and of The on and are TIL materials, contract They for repair services., and perform clerical functions. must develop mechanisms for training new leaders. building to establish its own For each credit or buy its own typewriter and xerox, machine is counterproductive. There are many ways that time and money can be saved by inter-building cooperation. Why not use the CBOs as a basis for this cooperation? First and foremost, maintaining low-cost, mix best after of standard housing. develop its organization., sale. Thirdly, of and continues that it needs to support by working through established it contributes to their organizational even provides a means of means Second, it provides the autonomy and support to each tenant group that organizations and Assisted Tenant Leasing is a generating additional even community development, revenues and creating jobs. Notes on Chapter Seven 1. Bernard Cohen, "City-Owned Buildings: Limits 5 (February 1980), 8. 118 A Hard Sell," City 'Part III CHAPTER EIGHT: FUNDING THE . to Proposals improve IN REM HOUSING PROGRAM the management programs and Central need to budget come out of federal (see Table 8.1). of began in 1978, between the City of because CD not the operation of Management's is constant total in funds were supposed to be for the low-income housing. operating costs, be cut. The conflict tax revenues to pay for applying CD funds to Central (see Table 8.2). little conflict with HUD about use of worry that they will funds rem housing was a Since the 1980, These days funds, the but city's CD allocation has fallen from $260 million to $213 million. At present it seems unlikely that this amount will but even more unlikely that it will the At the Management buildings only for repairs there buildings. New York and HUD when resolved when HPD agreed to use city Central revolve around the Community Development Use of CD funds to support conflict renovation, was Management, all alternative the the entire DAMP budget and half the Division of Property Management IRHP both find more money to invest in city-owned present, source IRHP, city's improved housing be increased. programs depend on CD money, be cut further, Since most of plans for an share of IRHP must be based on the assumption that the the CD budget devoted to in rem housing cannot be increased. 119 TABLE 8.1 Division of Alternative Management Programs Fiscal Year 1964 Budget (in millions) Community Management Program Tenant Interim Leasing Private Ownership & Management Homesteading After Sales Support (BA Loans) $19.705 5.3 3.495 .842 .3 Technical Assistance and Professional Services Personnel and OTPS .75 3.0 Total 33.392 Source: conversation DAMP Budget Director. TABLE 8.2 with Eileen White, Division of Proggerty Management Fiscal Year 1984 Funding Sources (in millions) Community Development Funds Tax Levy Funds Rent Collections $44.8 41.8 28.8 Source: Harry DiRienzo and Joan Allen, The New York City In Rem Housing Program A. How Much for This Program section Rem Housing? calculates consistent section: all In the with I the goal accomplishment of in rem buildings. managers., a budget for the have articulated in Housing previous the systems renovations as needed for Based on conversations with estimated Rem In the following repair real estate costs for a thirty-unit building: Replacement of plumbing $50,000 Replacement of electrical wiring 50,000 Replacement of boiler 30,000 Recap roof 10,o00 Replacement of apt. doors 7,500 Purchase new stove and refrigerator 21,000 Replacement of windows 50,000 Total 218,500 ($7,283 per While this estimate omits any structural which in state be weatherization budget. the $50,000 included can be devoted to other repairs. should be thought of as an average, more and others less. in does this The $7283 per unit cost since some buildings Of the two buildings reviewed the previous chapter, for example, whereas it If window replacement continues to budget major repairs, needed, which is currently provided out of the supported with state funds then require or cosmetic repairs., some buildings admittedly are sorely include money for windows, unit) will in 167 Havemeyer Street needed few 195 South 4th Street needed everything but a new roof. 121 At the end of FY 1983 there were 11,958 DAMP which 10,469 were in TIL and CMP. additional sold, title vestings buildings, of The number of units gained in have been about equal to so this figure is about the same one year later. 10,469 units Tenant Leasing program were to be treated as prescribed unit expenditure, by yearly cost would be $38.235 million $76.47 million. to the technical working with the Assisted Tenant Leasing provide fifty buildings. 8.1; is $16 $2 million assistance line to fund community groups buildings; with $40,000 each to hire this staff would and pay Each group would then have an average workload of In the increased only slightly. 8.3 the program's (see Table 8.3). is added overhead costs. Assisted each would receive the proposed $7283 per for a total program outlay of groups number If these the If repairs are accomplished over a two-year period, ten the projected The total budget other are projected DAMP budget in Table million higher than the present budget while additional programs funds have been allocated shown in Table in the projected budget, money has also been saved by equalizing the rehabilitation levels in all buildings. Projecting trickier, since a new budget for Central Management buildings is HPD's figures don't make clear how much of their budget goes for operating expenses, much for personnel. how must for repairs, and how For the sake of this calculation 122 I will TABLE 8..3 Progosed (in DAMP Budget millions) Assisted Tenant Leasing Private Ownership & Management Homesteadi ng After Sales Support Technical Assistance and Professional Services Personnel and OTPS Total $38.236 4.0 1. 0 .5 2.75 3.0 49.486 33.392 16.094 CD funds Other sources TABLE 8.4 Progosed Budget for the Division of Pro2eCty Maagement (in millions) Repairs $77.685 44.8 32.89 Operating Total Total (See 41.8 28.8 13.0 CD Funds Other sources Rent Collections Other sources Amount Required from Other Sources: Amount Already Allocated Other 41.8 Sources: Table 4.2) Balance: ignore from 61.98 HPD's 20.18 personnel costs, 123 and assume that the part of the budget funded while the 8.4). A through tax levies is the operating part funded by CD money represents repairs $41.8 million annual operating budget for 32,000 units represents as $1306 per unit cost. from Central dwelling Management unit, leaving a balance of repair Rents or $900 per spread units. out over three years., apartment, Projecting this would $77.68 million a year, or $2428 a unit each year. of leaving $32.885 million for other this is sources. cost The CD-funded, Combined with the operating shortfall, not covered by rents or CD money would be total a cost $44.8 million funding the total $45.89 city contribution for in rem housing under would be $61.98 million, each in total. funds were to be budgeted at $7283 an schedule Table collected $406 required to cover then $233 million would be required for all repair (see approximately buildngs cover $28.8 million, apartment's operating costs, or $13 million If allocation, program million. this plan or $20.18 million more than is currently budgeted. B. Additional Both of Governor Cuomo and Mayor Koch, federal fiscal Government Funding Sourges motivated by the dearth funds for low-income housing and encouraged by the conditions both state-wide and city-wide, have proposed new funding program. sources, Governor all of Cuomo which could be used for has suggested directing the the in rem revenues expected from the repayment of the Battery Park City bonds to lowincome housing. Since this income stream does not 124 begin until 1991, however, it must be considered a possibility for the 1 future Both the Governor and Mayor Koch would revenue coming from the World Trade Center, real estate concern, its tax payments if the complex or payments made-in lieu of current owner. float $1 like to see some in the form of is sold to either a private tax'es by the Port Authority, The Mayor proposes using these billion in bonds that can be used to revenues support to low- and modera'te-income housing development. As city discussed capital buildings. previously, the Mayor is interested in funds to renovate apartments in In his million a year. permanent Management current budget message he has asked for million over five years for the renovation of $15 Central using Since the capital city property, $75 9000 apartments, budget is used only or for Koch's willingness to use it for in rem buildings suggests a grudging acknowledgement of the city's term commitment were budgeted in addition to, to.maintain this housing. and not If this $15 in place of longmillion existing city commitments it would cover most the $20 million shortfall shown in Table 4.4. It's possible, however, that the Mayor's proposal refers to the aforementioned program to renovate vacant apartments for homeless Human Resource Administration clients. $20 million would still C. be needed to upgrade occupied Alternative Funding Sggurces: In In that case, apartments. Hosing Irust Funds many cities confronted by the cut-back of federal housing funds efforts have been made to raise revenue for housing from the 125 private market. The notion that those profitting from real estate development in booming downtown markets should be contributing the creation of already housing units throughout the city underlies plans implemented in discussion in New York. of San The Francisco is Boston and involve levying some form justification for taxing low-income housing is new workers to making contributions creation commensurate size of their commercial supply instituting and to housing projects, demand in balance. That the the The such a charge is the extension of powers. city. costs and legal the property taxes benefits city residents paid by middle-income residents of construct "linkage" plan a Alternatively, basis for downtown is another neighborhoods improvements developer one housing unit for every 1125 square feet space he builds. $6C,000 Francisco the Frequently., the downtown area fund the infrastructure 2 to facilitate downtown development San By with of outside of the the municipality's justification for requiring developer contributions. In complex. developers are helping to keep development are not felt equally by all needed estate the argument that commercial development increases for housing by attracting zoning trust various forms of real demand housing under to be contributed to a housing activity to aid the development of There and These plans all surcharge on development fund. to of must office he may contribute from $4000 to ($3.50 to $5.30 per square foot) to a city fund used to aid housing suppliers. The San Francisco plan is designed to address 126 problems units of housing supply, and does little to ensure that constructed with this money are affordable to low-income people. $5.00 a Since the square foot, discount foot. In Boston, tax the plan actual could twelve moderate- or development exempting the first is payable over rate, This commercial 100.,C000 years, is taxed at square assuming million feet. 10% a payment comes to only $2.50 a generate $37 to $52 the square over ten proposals for 3 years Planners instituting in New York City have levies. similar Action Institute, both low-income housing, include revenues entertained The Pratt Center and the Metr opolitan long-time advocates of publicly have proposed a housing trust fund that would f rom a numbe r of sources, existing taxes and some of whi ch would need Appendix 5 for different into 1 ist aspects development, of SOL rces.) of The comm ercial some of which new and or condomin iums. collects $3 For are to be enacted. sources luxury instance, million a year in small (See all tap residential as wel 1 as the pc pularity of converting rental cooperatives currently funded the units state registration fees from real estate syndications, most of which are in New York City. By increasing and restructur ing this collected for the housing trust fund. condominium conversions $75,000 appealing would because $21 raise $8 million could fee. An converted units selling for million. These filing suggestions they increase taxes that are already in rather than levying new ones. 127 be Sponsors of cooperative and pay a similarly token increase of this filing charge on all over fee, are place The existing taxes also affect real estate transactions that are extremely lucrative for those involved but don't directly produce new housing units. The Pratt-Metropolitan contribution provision. proposal includes a developer Like the San Francisco and Boston plans it posits a connection between commercial development and housing demand, and housing trust fund for every 1000 square feet of rentable proposes space they construct. that developers contribute $6,000 other units in production their development as low rent apartments $420 for a two-bedroom apartment), foot trends, programs. builders have the option of setting aside 10". of those renting within the HUD Fair Market Rent square office excepting projects that are part low- and moderate-income housing Residential the Unlike the other plans this one includes a levy on residential development, of to an to the housing trust fund. (defined Maximum, or contributing the $6 as currently per rentable Based on current market estimated $50 million could be raised each year from developer contributions. These in combined sources could raise $200 million for New York City. funds currently leveraged 25,000 money with new were proposed in If this were added to the $200 million of used to support low-cost market-rate funds, housing it could efforts., produce and rehabilitated units each year. If some used for moderate rehabilitation of in rem the housing previous chapter, further. 128 it could be 20,000 of units stretched CD and to this as even Other proposals to raise money focus on taxing the large profits currently being made in the luxury housing market. Marcuse, who benefits of "highways, breaks. advocates a luxury housing tax, utilities, Today those with higher public with proposes month, lower amenities: services--and tax income people, who A tax higher incomes helps to settle the on the housing of score. Marcuse taxes on the income from units renting for over $1000 a progressive property tax, units worth over $100,000, adding 2". to the tax and a speculation tax from the sale of units for over $100,000. 5 could raise $250 million a year Whether contributions or and York in the near future. rate of on capital up of gains developer miscellaneous taxes is an appropriate is not way proposals, such dedicating revenues from existing taxes to the trust fund, ability money from generate regard however, income for the city, or a luxury housing tax, Administration. Any proposals such as a are not supported divert that 129 do developer by The only official city initiative in was the creation of a mayoral do city's since they simply one budget line to another. additional contribution Koch neither do they increase the to provide services, to likely to be implemented in New The less controversial not invite much opposition; a Altogether these taxes not a housing trust fund made fund low-income housing, it as the income and better housing obtain more benefits from these public actions, 4 need such benefits more, benefit less" . those believes that good housing result from providing public infrastructure, Peter commission to study the the this use zoning authority to extract concessions--low-income housing or of Study Commission achieve some housing used to It did recommend the creation of that zoning should not broader social goals. sort money, concluded of housing trust to support development, which of Commitments This Development public amenities--from developers. low- and be moderate-income but suggested it be funded with CD and UDA6 course is already the funding source for the housing programs. city's levy on The Commission's reluctance to endorse any additional developers is indicative of officials' squeamishness regarding any policy that analysts makes demands on the business community. fear that their debilitated by any additional it has been robust apparently burden. tax customary to extend tax economy Manhattan the area. The last such City Planning incentives to developers, housing to abatements trust fund Why is New reluctant York, mid- dismayed in But planners to lose these and believe that a disincentive such as contribution would greatly discourage estate. with its strong Manhattan to charge developers with some for supporting low-income housing? Mayor, be developers abatement is scheduled to end Commission are investment in New York City real market, will In fact, until recently July of this year after pressure from City Council. a York as-of-right--even to those building in the lucrative almost on New real responsibility Certainly the attitude of whose position is reputedly pro-development, has 130 estate the influenced city policy. crisis, But which beyond that looms the memory of was evoked by every city official the fiscal I questioned. All New Yorkers dread the possibility of returning to those dark of job loss and service withdrawal, crisis" and their New influence on York as the "lessons of policy establishment. that the fiscal municipal but the "lessons of the fiscal city policy are as controversial Vietnam" are within the U.S. in foreign The Koch administration has taken the view crisis was the result of an overextension responsibilities and a climate unconducive investment; it therefore shuns programs that and to make the city an attractive place to works days to of private involve city dollars, do business. Proponents of developer contributions and/or taxes are critical of Administration market policy, contending that is so strong that additional the Manhattan real taxes can be levied estate without discouraging investment. This debate over development policy ultimately boils down to a presumably empirical question: for office and residential pass along from them, Pratt-Metropolitan of a $6 now would with the residential burdens to those who buy not be discouraged trust project. from fund proposal anticipate still $6 They found that pre-tax be getting contribution. development, a internal a or of Rents would the 131 contribution increase The the impact and developer, return healthy 30-32% internal rent investing. analyzed commercial rate demand If developers can per rentable square foot charge on a residential commercial can tax housing is the elasticity of space in Manhattan? any additional then they will What of rate of 1.5-2.5%. lowers the a who 32-33%, return For the pre-tax internal rate of return from the appear to have much affect 18.6% to 16.38%, and forces rents to 6 increase somewhere between 2.5% and 4.2% . In neither case does tax Since it would be levied on all be disadvantaged. the precise shape of While these calculations beg the questions of the demand curve, of a rent increase of under 5%. D. The Cross-Subsidy Program fund. has The section the to begun its produce and low-income Hassidic version of and potential location because a housing about to be enacted trust in one contributes the income generated from improve low- and moderate-income idea was actually devised as a Hispanic residents of area and the more affluent The large tracts of vacant developers, compromise Hassidic sale cross-subsidy program, the increased between devastated Jewish community who saw the oppportunity to create of city-owned The land in the Triangle attracted Low-income their future in the Triangle threatened by the housing. the Southside's housing for their growing community. protested from limited rent sale of vacant city-owned property in the area to a fund used nearby. saw would be minimal, program, of the Southside, "Triangle" rate own cross-subsidy cross-subsidy the they do suggest that would be unlikely to give up a Manhattan HPD profitability. developments, no one project would increases as a result of a new tax tenants on a project's lots for marketresidents development, this purpose. and The which allows existing residents to benefit market 132 value of property in their area, succeeded in ending the stalemate between the two groups. Approximately $2 million will be raised through the sale the Triangle's city-owned property, to and and this revenue will bring down the costs of the Section 235 units to supplement available an existing to tenant-managed revolving buildings, being loan of be used planned, fund that is including those in the in 7 rem programs East Side, vacant . A similar plan is being proposed for which has a parallel city-owned land, and juxtaposition of developers the Lower poor residents, interested in new opportunities. While activity good the to way allows neighborhood, it doesn't represent property already of Management buildings. the sale of of in a market and is the Revenues from sale go toward supporting operating Contributing a particular any absolute addition to available for in rem housing. Central benefits protect the interests of tenants city-owned Central the accrue to those it may negatively affect, to resources cross-subsidy of costs the proceeds from certain parcels to particular projects only means that Management's operating funds will have to come from taxes and sources for another source. E. An Eguitable Tax System While developer cross-subsidies housing funds, are contributions, worth luxury housing discussing as potential New York City should be able to raise the money it needs for tax been in rem housing from the tax base it has. abatements on built millions this dollars. added incentive The without condominiums estimated a tax abatement; sprouting $582 have midtown and Lower expansions of CBS and Irving Trust, built past, lucrative projects that would most surely without of In the cost was the Manhattan city office for instance, could have been so could the high-rise up along the East Side. million have given up by In FY the luxury 1982 city an in tax these programs is ending (tax 8 abatements abatements housing Now that the last of . are now available only for low- and moderate-income and for developments outside Manhattan), collect more taxes, Sternlieb has making additional the city levies unnecessary. suggested earmarking tax revenue from could George new, non- 9 abated developments for low-income housing On a smaller scale, New York City loses money underassessing property values in upgrading neighbhorhoods. Marcuse studied the Upper average West Side of Manhattan--and found that, while assessed values rose only decreased In that sum, each mechanical abatements, it is likely that 10 in these improving areas with of an additional $20 million its in rem buildings systems. While there untapped sources for this money, 134 net at are a number minimum, of also revenues a year HPD could have, in fact tax the 26.3%. Since one-third of the buildings sold on the Upper West Side tax Peter two such neighborhoods--Park Slope in Brooklyn and sales price rose 177%, received by ensure adequate previously it could easily be found in the city budget if existing taxes were equitably levied. Notes on Chapter Eight 1. Edward I. Koch, January, 1985, 8. "State of the City: Housing Initiatives," 2. Advisory Group on the Linkage between Downtown and Neighborhood Housing, "Report to the Mayor on the between Downtown Development and Neighborhood October, 1983. 3. Ibid. 4. Peter Marcuse, (December 1983),16. 5. 6. "A Luxury Housing Tax," ity Limits 8 Ibid. Pratt City's Center and Center for Metropolitan Action, HousingQCisis: (New York, 7. Development Linkage Housing," Private Devel ogment and New Public York Need., 1983) Appendix. Cathy Herman interview. 8. Richard McGahey, "Whatever Happened to Enterprise Zones?" New York Affairs 7 (1983), 57. "Failure of Plan for Homeless Reflects 9. Joseph Berger, Housing Crisis," New York Times 19 February 1985. City 10. Peter Limits 9 City Marcuse, "Measuring (May 1984), 26-27. 135 Gentrification's Impact," Conclusion CONCLUSION This thesis describes a model promotes neighborhood stabilization, development of subsidies, basis of for housing the poor contributes to the personal its participants, and requires only minimal red tape and agency involvement. This New York City's In Rem Housing Program, represents a clear that alternative to private, public model, the in unique. It for-profit ownership. It recognizes the importance of community. And its comes from the spontaneous actions of creative, inspiration desperate people who., without official sanction or preconceived ideology, began to seize control of property that no longer met the investor's need to make a profit but continued to meet their need to keep a over their heads. squatters pooled their who Whether these pioneers fifteen years ago were moved into empty HUD-owned houses or tenants their resources to manage their apartment buildings landlord had walked away, conviction with roof that their actions once reflected their the private sector was not going to provide them satisfactory housing and their impatience with meager government attempts to augment or replace private efforts. ad hoc responses have been formalized urban homesteading programs, York's In into These government-sponsored by far the largest of which is New Rem Housing Program. What makes the In Rem Housing Program so interesting ad hoc evolution, so different than that of which who are politicians. carefully The IRHP designed by is its most housing programs planners that was created in and 1978 debated merely by tied together a management, years. number of trends--landlord is a program that must therefore comparing it not advantage of pre-planning, nothing. the responsibility when city had the which it dubious refused to is assume owners had for in of from would have we do compare it to or more It's per unit costs serious and offers mis management. living in a tax-foreclosed participate--it maintains a guaranteed doing low-income not available to everyone--one must distinction the away government review, corruption of by management walked situation But even if had e is hardly appealing right now, it demands minimal opportunity Although evaluated alternativ housing programs it looks good. are quite low, little to the housing completely chaotic. traditional but thousands of properties, neighborhoods, be to other housing programs that have If been city and tenant sweat equity--that had been developing for It their abandonment, source of enjoy b uilding the to low-cost rental and cooperative units. The In Rem Housing Program, the Assisted, Tenant because it constructed units, for which standards. homeless in its does its present form and in Leasing proposal, not provide bathroom is housing frankly, sinks, low-income may open to comparable Some not families older even could criticism to that in rem meet FHA end up waiting for planners to develop more attractive housing at a time when the federal role in more affluent residents. lack But both in government has all housing subsidization. 137 A program but that abandoned ensures structurally costs adequate, is one that can address the housing problems faced by poor today. with the tenants, by safe and sanitary living quarters at Since control further their funding become available in and buildings should years to come. the resides be able to benefit more substantial Meanwhile, there's no that a combination of city-funded systems repairs tenant-funded cosmetic repairs, cannot ultimately they are the ones who will improving reason to think of the property low extend and responsible maintenance the life of these buildings for ten or fifteen years A. The Future of In Rem Housing City-wide trends suggest that the rate of decreasing. Thus, city-owned than it housing units, had approach while there will in been tax foreclosure is continue to be a net gain of the rate of a few years ago. increase will The city rem management without the sense of be can crisis slower therefore it has had. This thesis underscores the importance of tenant control a way devoted to ensure adequate housing for the much attention to the role of management in the future of The discussion of POMP of this program, poor. I have as not private managers or public in rem policy. in Chapter Four but questioned whether 1738 it indicated the success could preserve low- income housing the long run. in recommend that POMP be continued, managers and For these can be identified. private management should continue to be the exception, the for in rem properties. rule would qualified and even expanded, if properties appropriate I reasons But and not Too many questions about the long-term availability of low-cost units under private management remain unanswered. of refusal" Tenants should continue to have "first right to manage and purchase their buildings. Since in rem it is programs do involve government grants to participants, right receiving the residents of a building should have that those option of before to improve their own housing grants only a profit-oriented private manager is called in. Perhaps the most difficult task for in rem policy-makers to plan become for its Central easier in maintenance if more these money is buildings. devoted to Because HPD responsibilities,. including the vesting and all the in rem buildings, agency of One alternative plan has so be to shift processing of units. Central Mangement stabilization period, to NYCHA. was unsuccessfully attempted several years ago. failure been attributed to poor communications between and and has 1 NYCHA , handling to to the inability of NYCHA, pre-screened accomodate itself many it might be advantagous to relieve the might initial will preventative initial responsibility for managing these 32,000 buildings, after an a This task Management buildings. is which it tenants in newly-constructed 2 tothe in rem situation .It 139 used Such It's HPD to apartments, is possible that the improvement attempt shame at in HPD's intake procedures has made another inter-agency cooperation worth pursuing. that New York's in rem tenants should benefits of housing management NYCHA's cooperate. fifty years of because Another two not experience agencies It a receive in are is the low-income unwilling to alternative would be for HPD to create its own housing authority, which at least would leave the agency free to vest properties more frequently Landlord abandonment, larger market control. forces Yet it like plant closings, over which is the local a municipality has its tax foreclosure laws, the legal landlord. however, the City of New an It thus has the opportunity to create an housing market. a other cities model for prototype of municipal in Its two involvement In to investment in industry. weapon to seize housing from to the private little Cities have been able do very little to curb or replace private York has government which must contend with the results of private disinvestment. By virtue of is a symptom of abandoning alternative Rem Housing Program respects. First, can be it is a in a declining housing market. While the precise structure of the in rem housing programs not be appropriate to other cities, play a role in disinvestment relies on preserving tenant control tenant cooperatives housing for are low-income the notion that the city housing in one from which might in the others can families, 140 the of learn. to achieve much of now touted as a face its can private Second, success. it As means of providing lessons of the DAMP cooperatives--that tenant self-management can work but public support and programs--are well only in conjunction with other government with housing worth studying. Notes on Conclusion 1. "Exit, the New York City Housing Authority," Susan Baldwin, City Limits 6 (March, 1981), 16-19. 2. Sullivan, Brian PrograMs. The Division 3. Harry DiRienzo and Joan B. Housing Engrm of Allen, 141 Alternative Management Te New York City In Rem 'Appendices 157 APPENDIX ONE Summary of Changes in New York City Rent Regulation Systems, 1943-present. Year System Type of 1943 Rent Control Rents frozen except for 15% increase on vacancy. All rental units in buildings with 3 or more units. 1950 Rent Control Same as abovewith 15% across the board increase in 1953. All units as above in buildings built pre1947. 1962 Rent Control City takes over system from state; luxury decontrol in 1964. As above; decontrol in buildings units. 1969 Rent Stabilization 1970 Maximum Base Rent 7.5% annual increases depending on costs. All rent controlled units. 1971 Vacancy Decontrol All apartments decontrolled upon vacancy. All 1974 Emergency Tenant Protection Act Rent stabilization applied to all apartments which have reached market rents. All previously and regulated subsequently decontrol led units. Regulation Rent increases according to formula tied to CPI. Buildings Affected vacancy for units of 3-6 All units in buildings built 1947-1969 with 6 or more units. units Source: David Bartlett and Ronald Lawson, "Rent Control: A Second Look at the Evidence," Journal of Urban Affairs 4 (Fall, 1982). 1974-1984: Structure of both systems remained unchanged. Each year allowable increases for rent stabilized apartments are adjusted., and vacancy allowances are adjusted. In some years there have been no vacancy allowances. In 1984 administration of the rent stabilization system moved from the Rent Stabilization Association to the New York State. Rent Control is still administered by New York City. 142 APPENDIX TWO The Redemption Process The process by which the City of delinquent along to tax and there are ma ny points a slow one, the way at which a landlord can bring it to a terms of c lose. redemption are c omplicated and controversial, ease with role in On properties is New York takes ti tle since the which one can get back one's property plays determining how one will the one hand, handle property tax a policy of easy redemption a would enco urage to postpone properties at the redemption is difficult, property owners who defaulted on payments due last minute. eager further, there home In and On the redeem deli nquent other to their their keep For every story of the rap aci ous retrieve his building in order is the story of the elderly couple to the fact that there are at least their pay ments. break building, and elsewhere, designed down into those who own and live in a they small those who own one or more large buildings and live the city has followed a bifurcated redemption to of two kin ds property owners who find themselves in tax arrears, and tha t roughly it mi lk losing because hospital bills forced them to miss a few recognition of when hand, to some kind of emergency but want to buildings cannot get them back. landlord payments large payments. landlords tax The facilitate redemptions by the former policy group and discourage them by the latter. Taxes are due the first day of 143 each quarter; there is a fifteen day grace period before penalties are levied. interest 16.5% charge on overdue bills is 7% for debts under $2750 and for process other debts. of for sign agreement an property. with the additional redemption terms are Brooklyn In Rem Action 33 of action as a example. compiled a In the winter of list of all quarters of property taxes. vesting. stop until the Once a building has penalties to been full redeem or his The terms are outlined below. the action, effect foreclosure its owner must either pay in Because Finance These terms are in vesting title has begun. selected from The annual substantially 1982, we will their building vesting, called buildings owing four These buildings were 1 - 30 to come forward. from being included "filing," Owner occupants of April use this 1981-82, the Department of or more "selected" for Owners of these buildings were notified of and given until unchanged the pending In order in the next phase to of they had to do the following: 5 family buildings: -- Pay in full; -- Pay 10% of arrears down and sign agreement to pay off along with future taxes, over twelve years. -- If total 16.5%. All arrears are under $2750 interest is 7%; balance, if over, other owners: -- Pay in full; -- Pay 15% down and pay off balance over eight same as for small buildings. In both cases, years. Interest agreements could be made after the April 144 30 filing date but before vesting with 25.5% interest. Once the city vests title it landlord to get his property back. vesting is still The four month is the "Mandatory Release Period." building is released to it former owner Corporation Counsel) also enter all the owed, filing fee, whichever owner occupants of after If of a the of the Such Services, and a deposit of is less. a A landlord can into an installment agreement with the approval taxes approved, period (with approval if payment is made in full. an agreement requires a $100 for During this time Board of Estimate and the Department of General or possible the $900 agreement is one to five unit buildings receive same terms as they had before vesting; down and the balance within one year. others must pay Once the Mandatory Release Period is over, during which time a landlord can regain his property with there is still a two year Discretionary of Estimate approval. 145 50% Period Board APPENDIX THREE The Legal Status of DAMP CoogeCatives Before purchasing their buildings, tenant groups must incorporate as Housing Development Fund Corporations as described in Article XI of HDFCs of New York State's Private Financing Law. Only are permitted to purchase buildings directly from the City New York without undergoing some kind of open bidding process. HDFCs are defined required to provide housing as those whose annual times the annual rental, issue shares, cooperative), DAMP which therefore the amount is utilities. six Because HDFCs (a not-for-profit corporation it persons, is not an appropriate form cannot for a they must pay corporate income taxes. cooperatives accumulate low-income gross income does not exceed including all are for-profit corporations for are also limited equity cooperatives of equity, restricted. or profit, The resale that an individual restrictions are in can as follows: First three investment assessments. Any cooperative. years: seller recoups (presumably $250) plus any additional profit goes initial special to the After three yeaCs: seller recoups initial investment, plus special assessments, plus any capital improvements that had been approved by the cooperative. Any additional profit is split between the seller and the cooperative, with the seller retaining 30'.. The cooperative board can vote to further restrict the percentage kept by the seller, but cannot vote to liberalize the seller's share. 146 Cooperatives produced through the TIL program cannot vote to sell the entire building for ten years; Management Program cannot sell Residents required those from the Community the building for fifteen years. of DAMP coops in the Chelsea-Clinton area will to pay an additional 40. of their profit to the No mechanism for enforcing this has been devised, however. 147 be city. APPENDIX FOUR Assumgtions Used for Calculating Prgjected Costs for In Rem Buildings Fixed Costs - Based on similarly situated buildings Variable Costs Plumbing - Assumes each unit will have one to two leaks each year, each costing $500 to repair. Electrical - Based on electrical repair costs for these buildings over the past few years. It's hard to estimate the cost to a building of faulty wiring, since the risk of fire is more important than the actual cost of repairs. Plastering - Includes repairs, usually after water damage. Therefore plastering costs decrease when plumbing and electricity are repaired. Appliances - Refers to stoves and refrigerators. If all new appliances are purchased., each will cost $350.00 and will need replacing every ten years. If used appliances are purchased., they will cost $125.00 to $150.00 each, and will have to be replaced every two years. Painting - Each apartment is repainted every three years, as per New York State law. Boiler maintenance - based on past experience. Electrical Service - for building common areas; based on past experience. Fuel - based on past experience. 148 PfTai4t"V AL. 4%4MJL XVW*AM WoCltos PWCf 04. V0 a w to M 0000 U) 0 Title r1 Ct Description Real Property Tr ansfer Tax - A levy charged everyties a deed changes hands. In FY'83 40,944 deeds Ifor schedule changed hands resulting in collections of see attached 97,88,469. The entire sue stays in NYC, with 069.6 million going into the City's General Fund State Stamp Tax 4for schedule see attachedl Similar to Real Property Transfer Tax but earmarked for the State. Small nominal amount remains in NYC for adainistration. FY'53 40,944 NYC deeds generated 6,326,743 in State revenues. - Capital Bains Ta x 0 0t 0 () - A charge on the sale of property over *1 million. 10% charged on the gain difforence between the old and the new selling price. Approximately 5000 transactions of this type occurred in FY'83, generating $14,703,145. This revenue currently goes to the State General Fund and was recently abolished from going to the City's. *43.5M collected statewide. A tax levied for recording a mortgage onto Mortgage Tax the title. 37,697 NYC recordings occurred in ifor schedule FY'83, producing 079,769,961 in revenues see attachedl collected, 058W going to the State's General Fund. The balance is earmarkeds 1% to the Cityg for obligations over 0.5"m 1/4 of 12 goes to MTAI and for mortgages of $25K and above, 1/4 of 1% for the SONYMA Mortgage Insurance Program for rehabs. Statewide mortgage tax collections last FY amounted to *159.7W. Building Dept. fees - A fee charged for building inspections. Various fees charged based on size, type, and kind, eq. 635 for elevator inspection etc. FY'83 net fees $13,950,000. Comments Most of these funds are presently earmarked. However, due to the enormity of the housing need and its relationship to real estate transaction that a setaside and/or surcharge totalling 10% be instituted to contribute to a HTF. Projected Contribution 10 Million Same as above - Create a State Stamp Tax Surcharge of $15 plus 1/10 of It for amounts over 635K Surcharge would be targeted to HTF. 1.5 Million Its estimated that approx. 100 million will be generated this year. As above, we propose that a surcharge and/or setaside equivalent to 15% be instituted and that that amount be contributed to a HTF 15 Million This year we expect that SONYMA will receive approx. 048.5 million. Of this they will retain about 9% leaving $43.65 million. Of this, 65% or 028.7 million - NYC's pro-rated share should be invested in the Housing Trust Fund 28.7 Million Using this pot of 0 at present is not feasible since an increase should go into increased inspections Title Comments Description UDAS repayments Repayments of federal Urban Development Action Brants in FY'93 yielding *146,956 in principal plus $479,9046 in interest, total *625,902. Current repayments supply a revolving loan fund that is administered by the Economic Capital Corporation and is used as retension, expansion, machinery or equipment monies for industrial and com- mercial companies. I 1q& bt This year's total of $8.5 million seems exceedingly low. We estimate significant increases over the next few years. All repayments should be targeted to the Housing Trust Fund. - Repayments attributable to NYC's Participation Loan Program. .*2.7M for FY'93. Article BA Loan Program repayments - Repayments attributable to NYC's housing systems repair loan progriam. PLP repayments 0hftft - Sale of Non-Residential City Owned Property - Proceeds from the sales and mortgages of In-Rem commercial properties. 026M for FY'93. Sale of Residential City Owned Property Proceeds from the sales and mortgages of In-Reo residential properties. *6,531,292 in sales and *689,665 in mortgages for FY'93. Coop and Condominium filing fees - Fees charged for incorporation of a Coop or Condominium, payable to the Attorney Seneral's Office. *3,646,307 collected for FY'93, includes 6300K in amendment fees. Schen 1/10 df 1% of thefer4n-pric.....jxmum fee cannot exceed $10K. Fees go to State.' - Corporation filing fee - A fee imposed for the filing of corporations in NY State. *7.Ett collected statewide FY'63. Payable to Dept. of State. 10 Million In FY'53 a total $33.2 million was received. We estimate that this level will continue for the next few years. The total, minus administrative expenses, should be targeted to the housing trust fund. 30 Million These fees should be completely restructured. Base fee schedule should prevail for all units selling below $75K, the fee would be increased by 50% for units offered between *75 - 100K, and by 100% for units offered above $100K. The cap of $10,000 per building should be removed. 8 Million Fee structure should be revamped and increased with excess income estimate at *2 million going to housing trust fund. 2 Million Title Registration for Limited Partnership Byndications Comments Description Real estate related limited partnerships are a lucrative area that have not been tapped to benefit NYC. We propose an intensive investigation of how this can be done. However, we propose that the fee structure be revamped to yield a total of $9 - 10 million with the excess over $4 million going to the HTF. A fee charged for the registration of real estate syndications. Statewide' FY'83 collections amounted to $3,650,174, - almost exclusively from NYC. Fees go to State. 1/10 of 12 of dollar offering. Minimum fee $250. Maxism cannot exceed $10,000. Interest Earned on Real Estate Escrow Accounts - Interest earned on state aided or assisted real estate endeavor. H u-I Hj Hotel Occupancy Surcharge - A sliding scale surcharge averaging $.50 per room per night occupancy tax imposed on every hotel room in the City - -. Tax Increment Finance District - A surcharge levied to those benefited by a particular service or local improvement in an area. Financing usually applied to redevelopment by a bond issue that will be serviced from the anticipated additional tax revenues following the redevelopment. Big Mac Pay Back - Defined from attached.-- This is being investigated by a Veatch Foundation Study. We estimate that $10 million per year can be generated. 10 Million There are over 06,000 hotel rooms in the City averaging over 70% occupancy over the 365 days of the year. In most instances *.50 per night would amount to less than a 3/4 of 12 surcharge to the cost of overnight lodging. It we estimate that about *10 - 15 million per year can be generated by the increased real estate values attributed to public aetions. These would be harnessed under our proposal by establishing a T.I.F.D. The income of which would yield about $12.5 million per year to the H.T.F. 12.5 Million Million Interest earned on reserve accounts, paybacks, and unspent * from the proposal. Big Mac Housing Investment Fund would yield approx. *20 million per year. Inclusionary Zoning Payment Commercial Development Exactions 21 Million 20 Million $0 Million - T ot al $229.7 Million BIBLIOGRAPHY Achtenburg, Emily Paradise and Peter Marcuse. "Towards the Decommidification of Housing: A Progressive Analysis and a Progressive Program." in Hartman, Chester. America's Housing Crisis: What Is To Be Done? Washington, D.C.: Institute for Policy Studies, 1984. Advisory Group on the Linkage between Downtown Development and Neighborhood Housing. "Report to the Mayor on the Linkage Between Downtown Development and Neighborhood Housing." Boston: October, 1983. Atlas, John and Peter Dreier. "Mobilize or Compromise? The Tenants' Movement and American Politics."in Hartman, op cit. Bach, Victor. Department of "A Chance to Own." Ph.D. Disseration, Urban Studies and Planning., 1977. Baldwin, Susan. "City's Auction Sales: City Limits3 (September, 1978): 1-3. Going, M.I.T. Going, Gone?" ----- "City-Owned Buildings in Private Management Program Approach Sale Date." City Limits6 (February, 1981):18-19. ----- "City Reneges on $250 Sales Policy." 1979): 4-5, 14. ----- "City, Representative Green Ask Feds to Fund $100 Million CD Plan for City-Held Units." City Limits 4 (March, 1979):16-17. ----- " Ex i t., (March, the New York City Housing 1981):16-19. City "New Believers Buy Bite of Big 1979): 2,21. Limits4 (December, ----- "New City Auction Policy Takes Aim at Limits5 (March, 1980):12,23. ----- "Red 1978). Tape Threatens "Owners Funds for Direct Apple." Ronald Bartelt, David and W. Abandonment: Look Second A Urban A++airs4 (Fall, 1982). Berger, Joseph. Housing Crisis." Lawson. at the Limits6 Ci ty Slumlords." Sales Success." Play 'POMP' and Circumstance, City Limits5 In Rem Units." (October, City Authority." ----- ----- imits4 City Limits 3 Get $1.5 Million (June/July, 1979): (March CD "Rent Control and Evidence." Journal Homeless Reflects "Failure of Plan for New York Times., 19 February 1985. 152 City City of City to "Report Development Department. Community Cambridge Pilot Housing Limited Equity Cooperative on the Council June, 1983. Program." "Report and Development. Urban and Housing on Com mittee Community Task Force." Rem Housing In of the Recommendations Service Society, New York, 1981. "Big Gaps are Reported in Data on City Housing." Bernard. Cohen, City Limits4 (January, 1979): 1-3, 15. ----- "City-Owned Buildings: (February, 1980):8-9. Sell." Hard A City Limits5 Poor: the for Hgmes Saving Society. Service Community New York: income Tenants Can Own their own Agartments. Development Commitments Study Commission. July, 1984. New York: Dolbeare, "Report to the Mayor." The New York City In Allen. Urban Coalition, January 1985. Joan B. and Harry DiRienzo, Housing Eggam. New York: "The Low-Income Housing Crisis." Cushing. Low1983. Rem in Hartman, ed. gg cit. "New York City's Housing Cycle: Seymour. Durst, Eggire State Reggrt 9 (July 1983): 17-21. Down and Down." "Homeownership for the Poor?" Bernard and JoAnn Newman. Frieden, Transaction7 (October 1970): 49-53. "Comment on Lemon Socialism. " Rolf. Goetze, a New Society(September/October 1980). Working Eapgs for The Role of NeighgCood Change: Understanding Rolf. Goetze, Cambridge: Ballinger Revitalizlation. Urban in gectations Publishing Company, 1979. Michael. Goodwin, Pandora's Box." Complete Houses Come "City-Owned New York Times 7 January 1979. B. Rachel Gorlin, Limits8 (December "New 1984): York's Unequal Development." with City of Disposition or Conflict in "Collaboration Eva. Hanhardt, Service Society, Community New York:Property." City-Owned 1984. Chester, Hartman, Disgjgagegnt: How Law Project, 1982. fKeating Dennis to Fight It. Redesigning Dolores. Hayden, W.W. Norton & Company, 1984. 153 the LeGates. and Richard Housing Berkeley: Nat ional American Dream. New York: Herbers, John. Duty to Poor." Hinds, Michael Housing." New ----- "New April "Housing-Aid Debate Focuses on Question of New York Times 4 May 1985. deCourcy. "Deterioration York Times 17 February 1985. Housing 1985. Lags in Outer Boroughs." Koch, Edward I. "The State of the City: New York, January 1985. Kolodny, Robert. the Urban Poor." Housing Times in Housing ----- Self Helg in the Inner City: A Study g Lower Coogerative Housing Conversion in New York. New United Neighborhood Houses of New York, 1983. Lawson, Ronald. Track Records of Income Yor k: Urban Land 1978. Pr ogerty Ta Delinguency and Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Owners of New Last York Resort: City 's An Ear ly 14 Initiatives." "Self-Help Can Be an Effective Tool Journal of Housing (March 1981). Lawlor, John. Real Policy. Cambridge: City's Threatens New York U.S. Assessment Low Income of New York City Department New York: Coogergative Conversions. Housing Preservation and Development, 1984. and Susan Seagert. Jacqueline Leavitt, to Approach Feminist A Buildings: 32-39. 15 (Summer 1984): Marcuse, Peter. Difference? State and Local ----- "A Housing Abandonment: Washington Policy, Luxury Housing Tax?" D.C.: the Housing of Abandoned and "Women Pol'igy Social Housing." Does Rent Control Make a -Alternative Conference on 1981. City Limits 8 ----- "Measuring Gentrification's 1984): 26-27. Impact." (December City 1983): Limits9 15-17. (May Margolis, Richard J. "Self-Help Housing in Urban Areas." International Self-Help Housing Association, January 1968. Richard. "Whatever Happened to Enterprise Zones?" McGahey, York Affairs 7 (1983). New of Department City York September 1979. Williamsburg. City Planning. and Preservation Department of Housing City New York The In Rem Housing Program Annual Report. Numbers one 1979, 1980, 1981, 1982, 1983. five, 154 New SouthsideL Development. through Organization for Social and Technical Innovation, Inc. Self-Helg Hosing in the U.S.A.: A Preliminary Regggrt. Cambridge, June 1969. Piven, Frances Fox and Richard A. Cloward. Movements. New York: Vintage Books, 1977. Poor Peogle's Pratt Institute Center for Community and Environmental Development and the Center for Metropolitan Action. New Yor k Private Develogment and Public City's Housing Crisis: Need. December 1983. FEg'gety Qwners, "Property 1978. News "When 26. Salins, Effects York: (March/April 1985). Seizures in City are Chaotic." Reynolds, Susan. Foreclosures." ----- 1 the New York Times "Neighborhoods Pay the City Limits9 (January 1984): City Forecloses." City Limits 9 Price 5-7. of (December Peter. The Ecology of Housing gestruction: of Public Intervention in the Housing New York University Press, 1980. Sadowsky, Edward. January 1979. "Letter Saint George, Philip. 1978." City Limits 3 Schuman, Tony. Help Housing." Schuman, Tony. 4 (May 1979): to the Editor." "The Agony and the Equity: Unpublished manuscript. "The 13. Failure Stegman, Michael A. Housing Inyestment Cambridge: M.I.T. Press, 1972. Stegman, Michael A. New York City Development, 1985. in Times The New 24- 7 Issue City Wgrking Limits Pagers A Viable Means of Journal of Hosi ng the Inner Housing in New York: Study of a CityL Department of Housing Preservation City. 1984 Sternlieb, George and Robert Lake. "The Dynamics of Real Estate Tax Delinquency." National Tax Journal 29 (1976): 263-71. 155 of of Self- of Private Ownership." Scott, Franklin B. "Housing Cooperatives: Home Ownership for Low-Income Families." (July 1981). Tax Economic Mar:C:et. New A Critique Schur, Robert. "Growing Lemons in the Bronx." for a New Society (July/August 1980). Slower 1984): New York "City-Owned Buildings: (January 1978): 8-10. 19 March and Sternlieb, George. The Tenement Landlord. New Brunswick: Center for Urban Policy Research, Rutgers University, 1969. Stone, Michael. . "Housing and the Economic Crisis: An Analysis and An Emergency Program." in Hartman, ed. og cit. Sullivan, Brian. The Division of lternative Management Progams: The Last Best Hoge for In Rem Housing in New York City. New York: Pratt Institute Center for Community and Environmental Development, July 1982. Tabb, William K. The Political Economy of York: W.W. Norton & Co., 1970. United States HousingL 12Z Bureau of the Census. the Black Ghetto. Census of PogUlation and 1980. United States Commission on Civil Rights. Lower Income Families: A ReggEt on Imgact gf the Section 235 Program. 1971. Home Ownership the Racial and New and fgr Ethnic United States Department of Housing and Urban Development. Baseline Analysis of the Urban Homesteading PEggram. October 1978. Urban Homesteading Assistance Board. A Proggsal Homesteading ssistance Board. New York, 1974. for the Urban Homesteading Assistance Board. "Sweat Equity of Multifamily Housing in New York City." Housing and Urban Development, February 1977. Weinstein, Jerome I. Sternlieb, George, ed. 1976. "Housing Houing Homesteading of Department Subsidies: An Overview." 1273-4. New York: AMS Press, Women's City Club of New York. With Love and Affection: of Building Abandonment. New York, 1977. Ziegler, Mel. "Biography Magaine. 24 May 1971. Urban of an Unwanted Building." A Study New York Interviews Alter, Kevin. Director of the Private Ownership and Management Program, of the Division of Alternative Management Programs, New York City, 28 February 1985. Bass, Richard. York City, Planner for the Office of 15 February 1985. Property Management; New Burgess, 1985. Brooklyn Peter. Cayita. Cabrera, February 1985. Amy. Cohen, February Tenant real estate manager; Office Howard. Hecht, (Telephone). of Property Catholic Charities; Cathy. 7 City, 26 City, York New York City Housing Authority; New 1985. 5 March City, New York Association Treasurer; Tenant Association Secretary; Ireida. Cosme, February 1985. Herman, New York Brooklyn, New York, 27 Management, 19 1985. April 10 April Brooklyn, New York, 1985. Housing and Development Community for Coordinator Eric. Kober, Policy, Department of City Planning; New York City, 11 April 1985. Brigido. Martinez, 2 March 1985. Melendez, March Delia. 1985. Tenant Association President; Tenant Association President; Inquilinos Manager, General Pedro. Mendes, 1985. 2 May Boston, Massachusetts, Douglas. Moritz, March 1985. National Consumer Coop Bank; Attorney, Patricia. Murray, 1985 (Telephone). Susan. Reynolds, York City Ribot, Marc. Brooklyn, New York, Boricuas Brooklyn, Williamsburg Legal en New York, Services, Union of City Tenants; 1 Accion; 12 20 April Association of Neighborhood Housing Developers; 12 February 1985. Tenant Association Member; RobinsonDavid. Brooklyn, New York, New New York City, 6 February 1985. New York City, 10 February 1985. Director of Housing Resources, Southside United Barbara. Scliff, Housing; Brooklyn, New York, winter and spring, 1985. Wallick, Joan. 1985. Office of the Deputy Mayor; New York City, 29 February Division of Alternative Management Programs, White, Eileen. (Telephone). 1985 157 1 May