WORLD TRADE WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 23 October 2002 ORGANIZATION (02-5793) Committee on Trade and Development Dedicated Session TRADE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE: THE ROLE OF ECONOMIC SIZE? Note by the Secretariat 1. The General Council, at its meeting of 1 March 2002, instructed the CTD to establish a programme of work on small economies, to be conducted in Dedicated Sessions1. The General Council also instructed the WTO Secretariat to provide relevant information and factual analysis, inter alia, on the constraints faced by small economies as well as their shortfalls in institutional and administrative capacities, including in the area of human resources and the effects of trade liberalization on small economies. A recent document (WT/COMTD/SE/W/4) prepared by the Secretariat provided an overview of the discussion on small economies in the existing literature. Members requested that the Secretariat provide a more in depth analysis on the variables that are of relevance to small economies in light of the multilateral trading system. This note, which has been prepared under the Secretariat's own responsibility, and which is without prejudice to the positions of Members or to their rights and obligations under the WTO, aims to respond to aspects of those requests. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 2. A recent document prepared by the Secretariat (document WT/COMTD/SE/W/4: "Small Economies: A Literature Review") provided an overview of the discussion on small economies in the existing literature. The overview identified a number of key variables that seem to be of particular relevance to small economies, such as transport costs, openness to trade, diversification of exports and volatility of export earnings. 3. The present note attempts to look more closely at the key variables emphasized in the above-mentioned document. Relevant data have therefore been collected for the WTO Membership and are presented and analysed in this note. The present note attempts to clarify the relationship between the different variables and to assess their relevance for the ongoing discussion in the Dedicated Session on Small Economies. 4. For expositional reasons this paper mainly uses data analysis tools relying on sample or group averages. It should therefore not be excluded that the behaviour of single economies differs significantly from what the findings in this note would predict. To control for the robustness of the presented results, these have been compared whenever possible with the results of more sophisticated econometric analyses found in recent literature. 1 Document WT/L/447. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 2 5. The main findings of the present note can be summarized as follows: Measures of economic size Different variables have been proposed as measures for "economic size". These measures include population, land area, GDP and share in global trade. Population and land area can be considered to reflect the size of an economy's endowments. GDP is a frequently used measure for market size, as it reflects domestic demand. The analysis in the present note shows that the variables population size, GDP and geographic size are closely related. It is therefore not unreasonable to assume that each of the three measures for economic size relates in a similar way to other economic variables analysed in this note. In order to avoid repeating each exercise for three variables throughout the paper, one variable has been selected as being representative. In accordance with the approach most frequently taken in the literature, population size will be used as an indicator for size throughout the rest of the paper if not indicated otherwise. No threshold for "smallness" will be defined, however. Recent literature (Davenport, 2001) has suggested using the share in global trade as an indicator of economic size in the context of WTO issues. The relationship between this variable and population size turns out to be rather weak, but with GDP it is very strong. Share in global trade (measured as share in WTO trade) has been included in the analysis here as a separate measure for economic size on account of its direct relevance to the current discussion. Competitiveness of small economies: transport costs and scale economies An economy’s size is likely to affect its possibilities to be a successful exporter of products subject to large economies of scale. This can be considered one of the restrictions small economies face when trying to diversify exports. This paper provides a list and ranking of those manufacturing industries where economies of scale play an important role for the spread of development costs and for production costs. It has been argued that small economies are characterized by large transport costs. The analysis in the present note indicates that more than size, it is geographic location that affects transport costs. Landlocked economies tend to be subject to higher transport costs than islands. Islands in turn have higher transport costs than economies that are neither landlocked nor islands. When relating Members' share in WTO trade to transport costs, a negative relationship is found. If share in WTO trade is considered to be a measure for economic size, this finding would imply that transport costs are indeed higher for smaller economies. Interpreted differently, the finding could also indicate that transport costs have a significant effect on an economy's potential to export. In order to assess the role of transport costs for export diversification the present paper presents data on transport costs across different product groups. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 3 Small economies and trade: high reliance on imports and lack of export diversification "Smallness" is likely to limit an economy’s possibilities to diversify local production. This explains why smaller WTO Members tend to rely more heavily on trade than larger Members. Besides, the available data on export diversification indicate that the exports of smaller Members tend to be more heavily concentrated in a few commodities or services. The argument that smaller economies experience higher volatility in their export earnings is not confirmed by the relevant data for the WTO Membership. These findings are in line with those in recent economic literature. Vulnerability and economic performance of small economies Because small economies tend to be very open, any given level of variation in export earnings will tend to have a large impact on their economies. The analysis in the present note confirms that volatility of GDP decreases with economic size. This indicates that smaller economies do indeed operate in a more volatile economic environment. When relating economic size to GDP per capita, the present note finds that smaller economies are not systematically poorer than larger ones. However, GDP per capita turns out to be positively related with the variable "share in WTO trade". Economic size does not seem to have a significant effect on GDP per capita growth. Recent economic literature (Easterly and Kraay, 1999) points out that two offsetting effects may be at work. Openness to trade, while leading to higher volatility in smaller economies, also stimulates economic activity and growth. Smaller economies, however, may face bigger problems in adjusting to changes in the trade policy regime than larger economies because of the lack of diversification of small countries' export structure. If a change in policy regime is to lead to a shrinkage of a small economy's main export sector, this is likely to have repercussions for private sector activity in general. At the same time, it may be more difficult for a small economy to expand exports in alternative activities. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 4 TRADE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE: THE ROLE OF ECONOMIC SIZE? I. INTRODUCTION 6. A recent document prepared by the Secretariat (document WT/COMTD/SE/W/4: "Small Economies: A Literature Review") provided an overview of the discussion on small economies in the existing literature. The overview identified a number of key variables that seem to be of particular relevance to small economies. The present note attempts to look more closely at these key variables. Relevant data have therefore been collected for the WTO Membership and are presented and analysed in this note. This note attempts to clarify the relationship between the different variables and to assess their relevance for the ongoing discussion in the Dedicated Session on Small Economies. 7. In particular, this note discusses the role of transport costs and economies of scale as determinants of small economies' competitiveness. It assesses whether economic size affects economies' reliance on trade and level of export diversification. The issue of vulnerability is discussed as the note analyses how economic size relates to the volatility of export earnings and to GDP volatility. Last but not least the note discusses the evidence on the relationship between economic size and economic performance, measured by GDP per capita and GDP per capita growth respectively. 8. For expositional reasons this paper mainly uses data analysis tools relying on sample or group averages. It should therefore be borne in mind that the behaviour of single economies differs significantly from what the findings in this note would predict. To control for the robustness of the presented results, they have been compared whenever possible with the results of more sophisticated econometric analysis presented in recent literature. II. MEASURES OF ECONOMIC SIZE 9. Several indicators have been used to measure the "smallness" of an economy, the most popular one being population size. Other indicators of economic size include: GDP, land area and share in global trade. Tables 1 and 2 in the Appendix present the relevant figures for each of the four "measures of size" for the WTO Membership. 10. Population and land area can be considered to reflect the size of an economy's endowments. GDP rather reflects market size, as it is an indicator for the size of demand in an economy. An economy's share in global trade is likely to reflect two things: the economy's size (larger economies trade more) and an economy's openness (more open economies trade more). 11. With respect to population size, the literature uses different thresholds when referring to "small economies". Some suggest to use a population of 1.5 million as a threshold (Commonwealth Secretariat – World Bank Joint Task Force, 2000), others 5 million or even more (Streeten, 1993, Collier and Dollar, 1999, Brautigam and Woolcock, 2001), and still others something in between (Armstrong et al, 1998). Table 1 of the Appendix shows that 30 of the 143 WTO Members have a population below 1.5 million.2 Five of these countries are Least-Developed Countries (LDCs). Twenty-seven WTO Members have a population between 1.5 and 5 million, four of which are LDCs. The remaining 86 Members have a population above 5 million, 20 of which are LDCs. 2 The European Communities have been excluded from our analysis, as its member countries are included separately. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 5 12. Although GDP per capita income may vary it is, in general, the case that countries with a larger population are also characterized by a larger GDP. This positive relationship between population and GDP can be measured by the correlation coefficient. This coefficient takes values between 0 and 1 if the relationship between the relevant variables is positive.3 The stronger the relationship, the closer the coefficient's value will be to 1. For WTO Members the correlation between GDP and population size is 0.59, which is relatively strong. Table 2 in the Appendix shows the GDP of all WTO Members. 13. The rank-correlation is another indicator that can be used to measure the relationship between two variables.4 The rank-correlation for GDP and population size is even higher than the normal correlation coefficient: 0.80. This implies that chances are high, for instance, that the country with the tenth largest population also has the tenth largest GDP. Figure 1 reflects this relationship graphically. Figure 1: Correlation between WTO Members' position in the population ranking and their position in the GDP ranking 14. The relationship between land area and population size turns out to be less strong that the one between GDP and population. The normal correlation between countries' population and their land area is 0.55. Again, the rank correlation is higher: 0.72. See Table 2 for information of the land area of WTO Member countries. 15. Population size, land area and GDP have been identified by the literature as measures for economic size. The analysis in the previous paragraphs has shown that these three variables are closely related. It is therefore not unreasonable to believe that each of the three measures for economic size relates in a similar way to other economic variables analysed in this note. In order to avoid repeating each exercise for three variables throughout the paper, one variable has therefore been selected as being representative. In accordance with the approach most frequently taken in the literature, population size will be used as an indicator for size throughout the rest of the paper, if not The coefficient takes values between 0 and –1 if the relationship is negative. The correlation coefficient measures the closeness of the relationship between the value of one variable and the value of another variable. The rank correlation coefficient instead measures the closeness of the relationship between two sets of rankings – that is, between rankings of one variable and the rankings of the other variable. 3 4 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 6 indicated otherwise. No threshold for "smallness" will be defined, however. Instead, the entire WTO Membership will be included in the analysis. 16. In a recent contribution, Davenport (2001) suggested using "share in world trade" as an indicator for smallness. He finds that the group of countries with a share in overall merchandise trade of less than 0.02 corresponds more or less to the group of 42 "small vulnerable states" as defined by the World Bank. The question therefore arises whether "share in trade" is an appropriate measure for economic size. 17. Table 2 reflects Members' shares in total WTO trade.5 This variable turns out to be much less correlated with population size than GDP and land area. For all WTO Members the correlation is only 0.26. This implies that differences in participation in WTO trade only to a limited extent reflect differences in population size.6 The rank correlation for population size and share in WTO trade is 0.57.7 Figure 2 reflects this rank correlation. The comparison between Figure 1 and Figure 2 shows that the relationship between population size and Members' share in WTO trade is indeed weaker than that between population size and Members' GDP. In Figure 1 the data points are rather closely ranged around an (imaginary) line with an increasing slope. In Figure 2, the positive relationship between the two variables is less clear as data points cover nearly the entire plotting area. Figure 2: Correlation between WTO Members' position in the population ranking and their position in the ranking of share in WTO trade 18. WTO Members' share in total WTO trade is, however, very closely related to GDP. The correlation coefficient between the two variables is 0.85 and the rank correlation is 0.92. The latter relationship is depicted in Figure 3 below. 5 Both trade in commodities and trade in services have been taken into account. However, this correlation is higher, 0.50, when only Members in Africa, Asia, the Middle East and Latin America are taken into account (excluding also Australia, Japan and New Zealand). 7 The rank correlation is 0.54 for the restricted sample. 6 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 7 Figure 3: Correlation between WTO Members' position in the GDP ranking and their position in the ranking of share in WTO trade 19. This finding supports the arguments presented in Davenport (2001). Yet, as has been pointed out before, the variable "share in trade" is a rather indirect measure of economic size. Besides it is not closely related to population size. Share in WTO trade has been included in the analysis for this paper as a separate measure for economic size. It turns out to relate quite differently to several key economic variables (e.g. GDP per capita) than the variable population size. Whenever this is the case, it will be pointed out explicitly in this note. III. COMPETITIVENESS OF SMALL ECONOMIES: TRANSPORT COSTS AND SCALE ECONOMIES 20. It has been argued that many small states are rendered less competitive in world markets because they are situated far away from major centres of trade and commerce. Remoteness does have an impact on competiveness because it increases transport costs for imports and exports. In competitive global markets, higher transport costs would have to be offset either by lower wages or by reduced costs somewhere else in the production process in order to allow firms to compete. 8 The literature has identified several factors that affect the size of transport costs:9 21. Economies that are located further from major markets are likely to face higher shipping costs than proximate economies;10 8 See Radelet and Sachs (1998). See Radelet and Sachs (1998). These factors may apply to any type of economy, independent of its size or development stage. 10 Radelet and Sachs (1998) find that a 10 per cent increase in sea distance is associated with a 1.3 per cent increase in shipping costs. Clark et al. (2002) relate a 100 per cent increase in distance to a 20 per cent increase in transport costs. 9 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 8 Overland transport costs tend to be considerably higher than sea freight costs. Thus for a given distance from main markets, economies with a higher proportion of transit by land will tend to have higher overall transport costs;11 There are extra costs to inter-modal transport (e.g. in which freight must be shipped both by land and sea), because of extra costs of transferring between transport modes; Transport costs differ because of differences in the quality of ports administration and/or ports infrastructure; and Transport costs will depend on the composition of trade. The costs of shipping agricultural products, for instance, will differ depending on whether they are perishable or dry bulk and the extent to which they have been processed. 22. Data on transport costs are not readily available. The most frequently used measure is the so-called "CIF/FOB ratio". The FOB (free on board) price measures the cost of an imported item at the point of shipment by the exporter as it is loaded on to a carrier for transport. The CIF (costinsurance-freight) price measures the cost of the imported item at the point of entry into the importing country, inclusive of the costs of transport, including insurance, handling, and shipment costs, but not including customs charges. The higher the value of the ratio, the higher the share of transport cost in the value of traded goods. 23. Figure 4 represents the CIF/FOB ratio for WTO Members divided into three groups: landlocked Members, islands and other Members. The Figure is based on the data presented in Table 3 in the Appendix. It is clear that landlocked Members tend to face significant disadvantages when it comes to transport costs. This is due to the fact that they must pay the high costs of overland transport from the neighbouring ports. These costs are increased by the costs of crossing at least one additional border. Islands also face higher transport costs than "other Members", probably due to the large distance of most of them from the major centres of trade. The finding that landlocked economies face particular transport cost disadvantage is confirmed by the econometric literature on the subject. Limão and Venables (1999) and Radelet and Sachs (1998) both emphasise this phenomenon. 11 Limão and Venables (1999) find that an extra 1000 km by sea adds $190 to transport costs whereas a similar increase in land distance adds $1380. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 9 Figure 4: Transport costs for WTO Members Average CIF/FOB ratios for landlocked Members, islands and other Members 24. For the WTO Membership the correlation coefficient between population size and CIF/FOB ratios is –0.07. This value is very close to zero and indicates that there is hardly any relationship between economic size and transport costs. In other words, transport costs do not decrease with population size. This finding can to a large extent be explained by the distribution of islands and landlocked economies across population groups in the WTO Membership. Figure 5 shows that out of 30 WTO Members having a population of less than 1.5 million, 17 Members are islands, but only three are landlocked. The average CIF/FOB ratio for this population group is 0.127. The previous paragraph has shown that landlocked economies are characterized by the highest transport costs and relatively high numbers of landlocked Members are situated in the groups with a population between 5 and 10 millions (8 out of 26) and between 10 and 25 million (9 out of 29). These population groups are also characterized by the highest CIF/FOB ratios: 0.130 and 0.152 respectively.12 12 The average CIF-FOB ratio for the population range of 1.5-5 million is 0.108 and the one for the group with highest populations (25+) is 0.092. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 10 Figure 5: Number of islands, landlocked and other WTO Members in different population groups and average CIF-FOB ratios in percentages 25. Figure 6, however, shows that transport costs do decrease with higher shares in WTO trade. 13 If share in WTO trade is considered to be a measure of economic size, this figure would indicate that transport costs are indeed higher for smaller economies. Yet interpreted differently, the figure could also indicate that transport costs have a significant effect on the potential of an economy to export. This latter interpretation would be in line with findings in recent economic literature (e.g. Limão and Venables, 1999). This double interpretation indicates that one needs to be cautious when using share of trade as an indicator for economic size, as this variable is also a reflection of trade performance and/or openness to trade. It also serves as a reminder of the fact that figures like the one below do not say anything about causation. 13 The shape of this figure strongly depends on the thresholds being used to define the different groups, as the correlation between the two variables is only –0.26. The first threshold has been chosen according to the criterium used by the WTO to set the minimum level of WTO budgetary contributions. The other thresholds have been set in order to create groups of similar sizes. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 11 Figure 6: CIF-FOB ratios grouped according to WTO Members share in WTO trade CIF-FOB ratios 0.2 0.18 0.16 0.14 0.12 0.1 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 <0.015 0.0151- 0.05 0.051- 0.2 0.21- 1 >1 Share of WTO Trade 26. Transport costs will reduce the possibilities for landlocked countries and, to some extent, islands to compete in certain types of products. This will for instance be the case for products with a high import content, such as electronics.14 It will also be the case for products facing high transport and/or insurance costs when exported. Table 4 in the Appendix gives an overview of the CIF/FOB ratios for different product groups.15 The SITC groups of crude materials (includes cork and wood) and food and live animals (includes fruits, nuts and sugar) turn out to have the highest CIF/FOB ratios.16 27. Small economies may also face difficulties in exporting products that are subject to large economies of scale.17 Serving the home market will not allow producers to exploit economies of scale and they will produce at high unit costs. Table 1 presents a ranking of manufacturing industry groups according to the importance of scale economies in the production process. It reveals that motor vehicles, other vehicles and chemicals are particularly subject to large economies of scale. 14 See Radelet and Sachs (1998). For this table ratios have been computed using a U.S. data set for imports into the U.S.. 16 Exports of many small countries tend to be determined by natural resources. A comparison of this Table with Table 6 in the Appendix shows that several small Members are actually exporters of products characterized by relatively high transport costs. 17 That is, products for which unit costs fall when they are produced on a larger scale. 15 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 12 Table 1: Ranking of manufacturing industry by economies of scale Industry groups are listed in order of the importance of economies of scale for spreading developing costs and for production costs 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Motor vehicles Other vehicles Chemicals Man-made fibres Metals Office machinery Mechanical engineering Electrical engineering Instrument engineering Paper printing and publishing 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Non metalic mineral products Metal goods Rubber and plastic products Drink and tobacco Food Other manufacturing industries Textiles Timber and furniture Footwear and clothing Leather goods Source: Pratten (1988) 28. It has been argued, however, that the home market is not the relevant market for open economies. Their relevant market would also be determined by the market size of foreign partners. 18 In theory, at least, trade may allow small economies to exploit economies of scale. Non-traded goods and services, particularly infrastructure, are not subject to this rule and should they represent an important share of inputs in traded good production, small state competitiveness in international markets might be affected (Srinavasan, 1986). IV. SMALL ECONOMIES AND TRADE: HIGH RELIANCE ON IMPORTS AND LACK OF EXPORT DIVERSIFICATION 29. It has been argued that "smallness" limits an economy’s possibilities to diversify local production. As a consequence small economies are expected to rely heavily on imports to support local consumption. At the same time, small economies' exports will be characterized by a lack of diversification. Transport costs and the problems of exploiting economies of scale may be additional factors affecting small economies' potential to diversify exports. 30. Smaller economies tend to rely more heavily on external trade and foreign investment to overcome their inherent scale and resource limitations. The high degree of openness brings real benefits that accrue from trade – consumers in small states are able to obtain a greater variety of goods at lower costs than if their choices were confined to domestically produced goods, while producers in small states can sell on world markets – provided they have effective market access – earning more than if they were confined to meeting limited domestic demand. Participation in the world market also helps to channel new ideas and information about opportunities to firms and consumers in small states. Figure 7 shows the average ratio of trade to GDP for WTO Members grouped according to population size. It reveals that Members are indeed more open to trade the smaller they are. 18 See for instance Alesina and Spolaore (1997). WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 13 Figure 7: Small economies' reliance on trade Based on data for all WTO Members presented in Table 5 Appendix 31. Small size limits an economy's opportunities to diversify. Smaller economies thus have to rely on imports in order to increase the choice of goods and services supplied to their population. At the same time their exports tend to be less diversified than those of larger countries. As discussed in the previous section, transport costs and the problems to exploit economies of scale may be additional factors restricting the scope for small economies to diversify exports. A lack in export diversification is considered to be a disadvantage because it makes smaller countries more vulnerable to changes in demand for or prices of the few commodities or services they export. 32. Table 6 in the Appendix shows the first and second commodity or service exported by WTO Members and their respective share in total exports. Table 6.A reveals that exports of Members with a population of less than 1.5 million tend to be highly concentrated in one product or service. Also, the second most important export good or service tends to represent a high share in total exports. A look at tables 6.B-6.E, however, shows that other factors also seem to affect countries' level of export diversification. Petrol producers tend to be highly dependent on exportation of petroleum and petroleum related products, independent of country size (e.g. Venezuela, rank 112 in population and Nigeria, rank 136 in population). Also, the level of development seems to play a role. Several large LDCs are characterized by a high export dependence on one good. This is the case, for instance, for Tanzania (37.7 per cent travel), Uganda (coffee, 41.8 per cent), Burkina Faso (cotton, 51.8 per cent), Mali (cotton, 75.7 per cent) and Malawi (tobacco, 58.6 per cent). 33. It has been argued that smaller economies experience higher volatility in their export earnings because of the afore-mentioned lack of diversification. It has also been argued that smaller economies are more likely to export goods particularly subject to price volatility. This would be another cause for high volatility in export earnings. 34. Figure 8 reveals that our data for WTO Members do not confirm this argument. Volatility of export earnings does not seem to decrease with economic size.19 A related finding by the Commonwealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force (2000) goes in the same direction: "The terms of trade of small countries – the price of their exports (which tend to be concentrated in a relatively narrow range of goods and services) relative to the price of their imports (which tend to 19 Economic size is measured by population size in Figure 8. If measured by share of WTO trade the results are similar, the correlation coefficient between volatility of export earnings and share of WTO trade being negative but rather small: -0.21. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 14 cover a broad range of goods and services) – are not significantly more volatile than those of other developing countries." Easterly and Kraay (1999) come to the same result in their econometric analysis. Figure 8: Population size and volatility of export earnings Based on data presented in table 5 Appendix 35. Yet, because small economies tend to be very open, a large proportion of domestic economic activity tends to be accounted for by exports and imports. Even minor variations in world markets – such as fluctuating demand and prices for exports – can then have a large impact on their economies. To take this into account Easterly and Kraay (1999) also analyze whether the volatility of the "weighted" terms of trade is affected by economic size. They define "weighted" terms of trade shocks as the growth in the local currency price of export times the share of exports in GDP less the growth in the local currency price of imports times the share of imports in GDP. This measure thus captures both the magnitude of price fluctuations (changes in export and import prices) and their importance for the domestic economy (weighted by the shares of exports and imports in GDP). They find that the standard deviation of their measure is indeed significantly higher for smaller economies with the fact of being small adding around thirty percent to the average volatility. 36. This section has shown that smaller economies indeed tend to rely more heavily on trade and tend to be characterized by a lack of export diversification. It is however not the case that this lack of export diversification leads to a significantly higher volatility of their export earnings. It is rather the case that any level of volatility has stronger repercussions on their domestic economy because trade represents such a high share of domestic activity. The next section will have a closer look at this issue. V. VULNERABILITY AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE OF SMALL ECONOMIES 37. According to the Commonwealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force (2000): "Overall, the range of per capita incomes and rates of growth are not significantly different in small and large WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 15 developing countries. However, the residents of small states experience higher volatility in their incomes."20 38. The findings for WTO Members confirm the above statement only to a limited extent. Figure 9 reflects the volatility in GDP for WTO Members in Africa, Asia, the Middle East and Latin America grouped according to population size.21 Focusing on this group of Members has the advantage of excluding particularly rich small economies (like Iceland, Liechtenstein and Luxemburg) from the analysis and to focus on the more vulnerable small economies. 22 Figure 9 is based on the data presented in Table 5 of the Appendix. According to this Figure the group of Members with the smallest population sizes has only the second largest GDP volatility. Apart from this, however, the figure shows that GDP volatility decreases with population size.23 Figure 9: Volatility of GDP for WTO Members in Africa, Asia, the Middle East and Latin America24 Based on data presented in table 5 Appendix 39. A simple Figure like the one above does not take into account that variables other than economic size will tend to affect GDP volatility. Certain regions, for instance, tend to be more volatile than others. Whether a country is an oil exporter or not is another important factor. When taking these variables into account in their econometric analysis, Easterly and Kraay (1999) find a clearly significant and negative relationship between economies' size and GDP volatility. 40. This finding can be related to those of the previous section. Small economies tend to be more open to trade and to be less diversified. Their export earnings seem not to be significantly more 20 The term "income" refers to real per capita GDP. GDP volatility has been measured by the standard deviation of per capita GDP growth rates, a standard measure in the economic literature. 22 Focusing on this group of economies also facilitates the comparison with the findings of the Commonwealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force (2000) study quoted in paragraph 37, the analysis of which is restricted to developing economies. When including the entire WTO Membership in the analysis, the relationship between GDP volatility and population size remains negative but is weaker than the one found for the restricted sample. 23 The figures for all WTO Members are similar with the averages of standard deviation being 4.8, 5.99 and 4.57 for the first three population groups. 24 Australia, Japan and New Zealand are not included. 21 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 16 volatile than those of larger countries. Yet because trade represents such an important part of economic activity, overall GDP volatility tends to be higher in smaller countries. 41. Another characteristic unrelated to trade also affects GDP volatility of small economies. According to Commonwealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force (2000) many small states are in regions susceptible to natural disasters such as hurricanes, cyclones, drought and volcanic eruptions. Because of the small size of the country, these natural disasters will easily affect the whole population and economy, leading to high fluctuations in GDP. 42. Although a volatile environment can be considered to be an unfavourable influence on the functioning of an economy, it is not the case that smaller countries are systematically poorer than larger ones. The examples of very rich, small economies like Liechtenstein and Luxembourg are well-known. Yet even when excluding this type of economy, GDP per capita does not increase with economic size. Figure 10 shows that this also holds for WTO Members in Africa, Asia, the Middle East and Latin America.25 The correlation coefficient between GDP per capita and population size for this group of members is –0.08 and thus insignificant.26 Figure 10: GDP per capita for WTO Members in Africa, Asia, the Middle East and Latin America grouped according to population size 27 Based on data presented in table 7 Appendix 43. Figure 11 shows that GDP per capita relates very differently to economic size, when share in WTO trade is taken as a measure for economic size. The figure reflects a clearly positive relationship between share in WTO trade and GDP per capita. The correlation coefficient is also positive and rather high: 0.46.28 A look at the composition of the group of "largest economies" in each figure gives some indications as to the reasons for the difference between Figure 10 and Figure11. Only five WTO Members in the relevant regions have a trade share larger than 1 per cent: China, Hong Kong, China, Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Mexico and Singapore (See Table 2 in the Appendix). Only China and the Republic of Korea also figure in the group of Members with the largest population 25 Australia, New Zealand and Japan have been excluded from the sample. The correlation coefficient for all WTO Members is –0.05. 27 Australia, New Zealand and Japan have been excluded from the sample. 28 It increases to 0.58 when the entire WTO Membership is taken into account. 26 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 17 (larger than 25 million). Malaysia figures in the second largest group, Hong Kong, China in the middle group and Singapore in the second smallest (see Table 1 Appendix). Both Hong Kong, China and Singapore are very open economies. This confirms the argument that "share in trade" is an indicator reflecting both economic size and openness to trade. Openness to trade is expected to have a positive effect on GDP per capita, which could explain the positive relationship depicted in Figure 11. This idea is confirmed by the subsequent discussion on GDP growth. However, further analysis would be needed to explain the differences between Figure 10 and 11. Figure 11: GDP per capita for WTO Members in Africa, Asia, the Middle East and Latin America grouped according to share in WTO trade 29 16000 14000 GDP per capita 12000 10000 8000 6000 4000 2000 0 <0.015 0.0151- 0.05 0.051- 0.2 0.21- 1 >1 Share of WTO Trade 44. Econometric analysis has shown that economic size has no significant effect on GDP growth (Easterly and Kraay, 1999). A look at the relevant data for the WTO Membership seems to confirm this finding. Figure 12 shows the average GDP growth rate for the periods 1980-2000 for WTO Members in Africa, Asia, the Middle East and Latin America. The correlation coefficient for the relevant group is 0.35, which reduces to 0.09 when the outliers China and India are excluded. When share of WTO trade is used as a measure of economic size the correlation coefficient is 0.46 for the relevant group. This high value is mainly due to the strong performance of the five economies with the largest trade shares mentioned in the above paragraph. The correlation reduces to 0.24 when they are excluded. 29 Australia, New Zealand and Japan have been excluded from the sample. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 18 Figure 12: Average growth rate of GDP per capita for WTO Members in Africa, Asia, the Middle East and Latin America30 45. Easterly and Kraay (1999) give an explanation for this weak relationship between economic size and growth. Their analysis shows that openness to trade has a significantly positive effect on GDP growth. They also find that volatility in GDP is bad for GDP growth. It has been shown before that small states are particularly open. This openness stimulates economic activity and growth. At the same time, however, openness to trade is one of the main reasons for the GDP volatility that characterizes small economies and GDP volatility is bad for economic growth. Easterly and Kraay (1999) show that the positive and negative effects from openness roughly offset each other in the case of small states. They therefore do not find any significant effect of smallness on economic growth. 46. Smaller economies, however, may face bigger problems in adjusting to changes in the trade policy regime than larger countries. In other words, while having an open trade regime tends to be beneficial for small economies, changing the trade regime may be more cumbersome. The reason for this is linked to the lack of diversification of the export structure of small economies. If a change in a policy regime leads to a shrinkage of a small economy's main export sector, for example, this is likely to have repercussions for private sector activity in general. This leads to externalities that represent an additional adjustment burden in economies characterized by a lack of export diversification.31 At the same time, it may be more difficult for a small economy to expand exports in alternative activities. An expansion in exports can take the form of an expansion of existing export activities or of the startup of new export activities. The less diversified an economy, the more probable it is that new activities need to be developed. It has been argued that starting new export activities is more costly and involves more risks than expanding existing ones.32 As a consequence, a change of policy regime may lead to more severe adjustment problems when countries are characterized by a lack of diversification in their export structure. VI. CONCLUSIONS 30 Australia, Japan and New Zealand have been excluded. See Rama (1999) and Bacchetta and Jansen (2002). 32 See Bacchetta and Jansen (2002). 31 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 19 47. This note presents and discusses evidence on the relationship between economic size and selected economic indicators for the WTO Membership. In particular, the note discusses the role of transport costs and economies of scale as determinants of small economies' competitiveness. It assesses whether economic size affects economies' reliance on trade and their level of export diversification. The issue of vulnerability is discussed as the note analyses how economic size relates to the volatility of export earnings and to GDP volatility. Last but not least the note discusses the evidence on the relationship between economic size and economic performance, measured by GDP per capita and GDP per capita growth respectively. 48. The analysis presented in the paper suggests that "smallness" limits an economy’s possibilities to diversify local production. As a result smaller WTO Members tend to rely more heavily on trade than larger Members. The available data on export diversification also indicate that the exports of smaller Members tend to be more heavily concentrated in a few commodities or services. 49. Transport costs turn out to depend more heavily on geographic location than on economic size. Landlocked economies tend to be subject to higher transport costs than islands. Islands in turn have higher transport costs than economies that are neither landlocked nor islands. Among the WTO membership islands tend to be among the Members with small population size. Landlocked Members instead tend to have rather large population sizes as compared to islands. 50. This note examines the vulnerability of small economies by analysing how economic size relates to volatility in export earnings and in GDP. It finds that the volatility of export earnings does not clearly decrease with economic size. This result is in line with findings in relevant recent literature. But, because small economies tend to be very open, a large proportion of domestic economic activity tends to be accounted for by exports and imports. Even minor variations in world markets, such as fluctuating demand and prices for exports, can then have a large impact on their economies. The analysis in the present note confirms that volatility of GDP decreases with economic size. This indicates that smaller economies do indeed operate in a more volatile economic environment. 51. Although a volatile environment can be considered to be bad for the functioning of an economy, it is not the case that smaller economies are systematically poorer than larger ones. The findings in this note also confirm the results in the relevant literature, that economic size does not have a significant effect on GDP per capita growth. 52. Smaller economies, however, may face bigger problems to adjust to changes in the trade policy regime than larger economies because of the lack of diversification of small countries' export structures. If a change in policy regime is to lead to a shrinkage of a small economy's main export sector, this is likely to have repercussions for private sector activity in general. At the same time, it may be more difficult for a small economy to expand exports in alternative activities. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 20 BIBLIOGRAPHY Alesina, A. and E. Spolaore (1997), "On the Number and Size of Nations." Quarterly Journal of Economics. November 1997. Armstrong, H.W., R.J. de Kervenoael, X. Li and R. Read (1998), "A Comparison of the Economic Performance of Different Micro-states, and Between Micro-states and Larger Countries", World Development, 26(4):639-56. Brautigam, D. and M. Woolcock (2001), "Small States in a Global Economy", WIDER Discussion Paper 2001/37. Commonwealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force (2000), "Small States: Meeting Challenges in the Global Economy", report of the Commonwealth Secretariat, Commonwealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force. Clark, X., D. Dollar and A. Micco (2002), "Maritime Transport Costs and Port Efficiency", World Bank Working Paper 2781, World Bank, Washington D.C. Collier, P. and D. Dollar (1999), "Aid, Risk and Special Concerns of Small States", paper presented at the Conference on Small States, Saint Lucia, 17-19 February. Davenport, M. (2001), "A Study of Alternative Special and Differential Arrangements for Small Economies", Interim Report, Commonwealth Secretariat. Easterly, W. and A. Kraay (1999), "Small States, Small Problems?", World Bank Working Paper 2139, The World Bank, Washington D.C. Limão, N. and A. Venables (1999), "Infrastructure, Geographical Disadvantage and Transport Costs", World Bank Working Paper 2257, The World Bank, Washington D.C. Pratten, Cliff (1988), "A Survey of the Economies of Scale", Chapter two in "Research on the Cost of Non-Europe: Basic Findings, Volume 2 of Studies on the Economics of Integration, Commission of the European Communities. Radelet, S. and J. Sachs (1998), "Shipping Costs, Manufactured Exports and Economic Growth" mimeo, Harvard Institute for International Development. Rama, M. (1999), "Public Sector Downsizing: An Introduction", The World Bank Economic Review, 13(1):1-22. Srinivasan T.N. (1986), "The Costs and Benefits of Being a Small, Remote, Island, Landlocked or Ministate Economy." World Bank Research Observer, 1(2), 205-218. Streeten, P. (1993), "The Special Problems of Small Countries", World Development, 21(2):197-202. UNCTAD (2001): "Handbook of Statistics", United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva. DATA APPENDIX Table1: Population Data of WTO Members ranked according to population size (in 2000) 0-1.5 Liechtenstein St. Kitts and Nevis Antigua and Barbuda Dominica Grenada St. Vincent and the Grenadines St. Lucia Belize Barbados Maldives * Iceland Brunei Malta Suriname Macao, China Luxembourg Solomon Islands * Qatar Djibouti * Bahrain Cyprus Guyana Fiji Swaziland Mauritius Guinea-Bissau * Gabon Trinidad and Tobago Gambia, The * Estonia 32,000 41,000 68,000 73,000 98,000 115,000 156,000 240,000 267,000 276,000 281,000 338,000 390,000 417,000 438,000 438,400 447,000 584,890 632,000 691,000 757,000 761,000 811,900 1,045,000 1,186,140 1,199,000 1,230,000 1,301,000 1,303,000 1,369,000 Members 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 Botswana Namibia Kuwait Slovenia Lesotho * Latvia Oman Mongolia Jamaica Mauritania * Panama United Arab Emirates Congo, Rep. Uruguay Albania Lithuania Central African Rep.* Ireland Costa Rica New Zealand Singapore Moldova Croatia Norway Togo * Jordan Kyrgyz Republic Source: World Bank, World development Indicators 2002. Chinese Taipei population estimates are from EIU 2001. Note: * Indicates Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. 1.51-5 1,602,000 1,757,000 1,984,400 1,988,000 2,035,000 2,372,000 2,395,000 2,398,000 2,633,000 2,665,000 2,856,000 2,905,080 3,018,000 3,337,000 3,411,000 3,695,000 3,717,000 3,794,000 3,811,000 3,830,800 4,018,000 4,282,000 4,380,000 4,491,000 4,527,000 4,886,810 4,915,000 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 Members 5.1-10 Georgia Sierra Leone * Nicaragua Papua New Guinea Finland Denmark Slovak Republic Paraguay Israel Benin * El Salvador Honduras Hong Kong, China Burundi * Switzerland Guinea * Chad * Haiti * Austria Bulgaria Bolivia Dominican Rep. Rwanda * Sweden Senegal Tunisia 5,024,000 5,031,000 5,071,000 5,130,000 5,177,000 5,336,000 5,401,790 5,496,000 6,233,210 6,272,000 6,276,000 6,417,000 6,797,000 6,807,000 7,180,000 7,415,000 7,694,000 7,959,000 8,110,240 8,166,960 8,328,700 8,373,000 8,508,000 8,869,000 9,530,000 9,563,500 Members 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 111 112 Portugal Hungary Zambia * Belgium Czech Republic Malawi * Greece Niger * Mali * Cuba Burkina Faso * Guatemala Zimbabwe Ecuador Angola * Cameroon Chile Madagascar * Netherlands Cote d'Ivoire Mozambique* Australia Ghana Sri Lanka Uganda * Taipei, Chinese Romania Malaysia Venezuela, RB 10.1-25 10,008,000 10,022,000 10,089,000 10,252,000 10,273,300 10,311,000 10,560,000 10,832,000 10,840,000 11,188,000 11,274,000 11,385,300 12,627,000 12,646,000 13,134,000 14,876,000 15,211,300 15,523,000 15,919,000 16,013,000 17,691,000 19,182,000 19,306,000 19,359,000 22,210,000 22,400,000 22,435,000 23,270,000 24,170,000 Members 113 114 115 116 117 118 119 120 121 122 123 124 125 126 127 128 129 130 131 132 133 134 135 136 137 138 139 140 141 142 143 25.1> Peru 25,661,000 Morocco 28,705,000 Kenya 30,092,000 Canada 30,750,000 Tanzania * 33,696,000 Argentina 37,032,000 Poland 38,650,000 Spain 39,465,000 Colombia 42,299,300 South Africa 42,800,992 Korea, Rep. 47,275,000 Myanmar * 47,749,000 Congo, Dem. Rep.* Italy 57,690,000 France 58,892,000 United Kingdom 59,738,900 Thailand 60,728,000 Egypt, Arab Rep. 63,976,000 Turkey 65,293,000 Philippines 75,580,000 Germany 82,150,000 Mexico 97,966,000 Japan 126,870,000 Nigeria 126,910,000 Bangladesh * 131,050,000 Pakistan 138,080,000 Brazil 170,406,000 Indonesia 210,420,992 United States 281,550,016 India 1,015,923,008 China 1,262,460,032 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 21 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 Members WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 22 Table 2: GDP, land area and share in WTO tradea for WTO Members for year 2000 A. Members with Population < 1.5 million GDP, PPP (Millions, current international $) 1,216 1 Liechtenstein 513 2 St. Kitts and Nevis 717 3 Antigua and Barbuda 268 4 Dominica 743 5 Grenada 639 6 St. Vincent and the Grenadines 890 7 St. Lucia 1,346 8 Belize 4,137 9 Barbados 1,238 10 Maldives * 8,312 11 Iceland 1,707 12 Brunei 6,736 13 Malta 1,584 14 Suriname 7,967 15 Macao, China 21,947 16 Luxembourg 737 17 Solomon Islands * 12,628 18 Qatar 513 19 Djibouti * 10,053 20 Bahrain 15,764 21 Cyprus 3,016 22 Guyana 3,790 23 Fiji 4,694 24 Swaziland 11,882 25 Mauritius 905 26 Guinea-Bissau * 7,672 27 Gabon 11,663 28 Trinidad and Tobago 2,149 29 Gambia, The * 13,780 30 Estonia Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators 2002. a Exports and imports of merchandise and commercial services. Macau, China land surface area are from the EIU 2000. Rank Members Land area (sq km) 160 360 440 750 340 390 610 22,800 430 300 100,250 5,270 320 156,000 24 2,586 27,990 11,000 23,180 690 9,240 196,850 18,270 17,200 2,030 28,120 257,670 5,130 10,000 42,270 Share in WTO Trade N.A 0.003 0.007 0.002 0.003 0.003 0.006 0.006 0.020 0.006 0.045 0.038 0.049 0.007 0.054 N.A 0.003 0.083 0.002 0.069 0.061 0.012 0.015 0.016 0.039 0.001 0.033 0.047 0.003 0.064 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 23 Table 2: GDP, land area and share in WTO tradea for WTO Members for year 2000 B. Members with Population 1.51 – 5 million GDP, PPP Land area Share in WTO (Millions, current (sq km) Trade international $) 11,508 566730 0.039 31 Botswana 11,300 823290 0.027 32 Namibia 31,351 17820 0.192 33 Kuwait 34,526 20120 0.161 34 Slovenia 4,133 30350 0.008 35 Lesotho * Latvia 16,711 62050 0.049 36 19,748 212460 0.105 37 Oman 4,277 1566500 0.009 38 Mongolia 9,582 10830 0.055 39 Jamaica 4,468 1025220 0.006 40 Mauritania * 17,137 74430 0.115 41 Panama 48,855 83600 0.538 42 United Arab Emirates 2,196 341500 0.021 43 Congo, Rep. Uruguay 30,150 175020 0.058 44 11,959 27400 0.012 45 Albania 26,257 64800 0.077 46 Lithuania 4,355 622980 0.003 47 Central African Rep.* 113,311 68890 1.205 48 Ireland 32,963 51060 0.114 49 Costa Rica 76,884 267990 0.244 50 New Zealand 93,846 610 1.980 51 Singapore Moldova 9,032 32910 0.012 52 35,441 55920 0.134 53 Croatia 134,362 306830 0.823 54 Norway 6,526 54390 0.008 55 Togo * 19,380 88930 0.063 56 Jordan 13,324 191800 0.010 57 Kyrgyz Republic Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators 2002. a Exports and imports of merchandise and commercial services Note: United Arab Emirates and Oman data for GDP was available from WDI for the year 1998. Rank Members WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 24 Table 2: GDP, land area and share in WTO tradea for WTO Members for year 2000 C. Members with Population 5.1 – 10 million GDP, PPP (Millions, current international $) 13,386 58 Georgia 2,467 59 Sierra Leone* 11,999 60 Nicaragua 11,698 61 Papua New Guinea 129,405 62 Finland 147,417 63 Denmark 60,735 64 Slovak Republic 24,325 65 Paraguay 125,481 66 Israel 6,212 67 Benin * 28,226 68 El Salvador 15,743 69 Honduras 170,964 70 Hong Kong, China 4,021 71 Burundi * 206,561 72 Switzerland 14,696 73 Guinea * 6,704 74 Chad * 11,677 75 Haiti * 217,075 76 Austria 46,630 77 Bulgaria 20,190 78 Bolivia 50,515 79 Dominican Republic 8,024 80 Rwanda * 215,312 81 Sweden 14,386 82 Senegal 60,849 83 Tunisia Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators 2002. a Exports and imports of merchandise and commercial services Note: Hong Kong China GDP data are from the WDI for the year 1999. Rank Members Land area (sq km) 69700 71620 121400 452860 304590 42430 48080 397300 20620 110620 20720 111890 1098 25680 39550 245720 1259200 27560 82730 110550 1084380 48380 24670 411620 192530 155360 Share in WTO Trade 0.013 0.003 0.020 0.030 0.644 0.920 0.199 0.052 0.570 0.010 0.059 0.039 3.164 0.001 1.641 0.012 0.006 0.011 1.378 0.094 0.025 0.128 0.003 1.441 0.023 0.127 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 25 Table 2: GDP, land area and share in WTO tradea for WTO Members for year 2000 D. Members with Population 10.1 – 25 million GDP, PPP (Millions, current international $) 173,033 84 Portugal 124,431 85 Hungary 7,868 86 Zambia * 278,629 87 Belgiumb 143,734 88 Czech Republic 6,336 89 Malawi * 174,252 90 Greece 8,079 91 Niger * 8,640 92 Mali * 24,099 93 Cuba 11,005 94 Burkina Faso * 43,501 95 Guatemala 33,270 96 Zimbabwe 40,506 97 Ecuador 28,726 98 Angola * 25,334 99 Cameroon 143,242 100 Chile 13,041 101 Madagascar * 408,436 102 Netherlands 26,100 103 Cote d'Ivoire 15,101 104 Mozambique* 492,850 105 Australia 37,913 106 Ghana 68,330 107 Sri Lanka 26,839 108 Uganda * 313,900 109 Taipei, Chinese 144,098 110 Romania 211,019 111 Malaysia 140,036 112 Venezuela, RB Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators 2002. a Exports and imports of merchandise and commercial services. b Refers to Belgium and Luxembourg for share to WTO trade data. Rank Members Land area (sq km) 91,500 92,340 743,390 32,820 77,280 94,080 128,900 1,266,700 1,220,190 109,820 273,600 108,430 386,850 276,840 1,246,700 465,400 748,800 581,540 33,880 318,000 784,090 7,682,300 227,540 64,630 197,100 36,000 230,340 328,550 882,050 Share in WTO Trade 0.572 0.418 0.019 2.838 0.501 0.008 0.416 0.005 0.010 0.069 0.005 0.063 0.043 0.077 0.073 0.033 0.291 0.015 3.493 0.064 0.014 1.147 0.043 0.094 0.019 2.039 0.168 1.276 0.317 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 26 Table 2: GDP, land area and share in WTO tradea for WTO Members for year 2000 E. Members with Population > 25 million GDP, PPP Land area Share in WTO (Millions, current (sq km) Trade international $) 123,157 1280000 0.127 113 Peru 101,798 446300 0.157 114 Morocco 30,752 569140 0.044 115 Kenya 856,090 9220970 3.958 116 Canada 17,606 883590 0.024 117 Tanzania * Argentina 458,344 2736690 0.465 118 349,838 304420 0.697 119 Poland 768,454 499440 2.430 120 Spain 264,267 1038700 0.212 121 Colombia 402,380 1221040 0.482 122 South Africa 821,652 98730 2.373 123 Korea, Rep. 348,484 657550 0.032 124 Myanmar * 36,877 2267050 0.024 125 Congo, Dem. Rep.* Italy 1,363,003 294110 4.150 126 1,426,548 550100 5.291 127 France 1,404,385 240880 5.742 128 United Kingdom 388,792 510890 0.954 129 Thailand 232,539 995450 0.260 130 Egypt, Arab Rep. 455,336 769630 0.762 131 Turkey 300,136 298170 0.556 132 Philippines 2,062,239 356680 8.951 133 Germany Mexico 883,974 1908690 2.276 134 3,394,373 364500 6.381 135 Japan 113,663 910770 0.185 136 Nigeria 209,928 130170 0.106 137 Bangladesh * 266,159 770880 0.153 138 Pakistan 1,299,353 8456510 0.929 139 Brazil 640,345 1811570 0.776 140 Indonesia 9,612,680 9158960 15.954 141 United States 2,395,376 2973190 0.853 142 India 5,019,395 9327420 3.166 143 China Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators 2002. a Exports and imports of merchandise and commercial services Note: Myanmar and Congo, Dem. Rep GDP data was taken from the WDI for the year 1995 and 1998 accordingly. Rank Members Table 3: Transport Costs described by CIF-FOB input ratios sorted by population groups 1 2 3 4 Members LL I Liechtenstein St. Kitts and Nevis Antigua and Barbuda Dominica X 5 Grenada 6 St. Vincent and the Grenadines 7 St. Lucia 8 9 10 11 12 Belize Barbados Maldives * Iceland Brunei 13 Malta 14 15 16 17 Suriname Macao, China Luxembourg Solomon Islands * 18 19 20 21 22 Qatar Djibouti * Bahrain Cyprus Guyana 23 24 25 26 27 Fiji Swaziland Mauritius Guinea-Bissau * Gabon Average CIF/FOB by group 31 32 33 34 LL I CIF/FOB Botswana Namibia Kuwait Slovenia X 17.60% 3.17% 15.07% X X X X 10.00% X X 11.70% 10.00% 35 Lesotho * 36 Latvia X 10.00% 37 Oman X X X 10.00% 10.00% 17.67% 10.00% 38 39 40 41 42 X 11.10% 12.30% X X X 20.00% 12.00% X X X X X X 12.00% Mongolia X Jamaica Mauritania * Panama United Arab Emirates 43 Congo, Rep. 44 45 46 47 11.00% 10.20% 10.00% 48 49 50 51 52 33.84% 1.40% 10.00% 15.00% 21.10% 53 54 55 56 57 Uruguay Albania Lithuania Central X African Rep.* Ireland Costa Rica New Zealand Singapore Moldova X Croatia Norway Togo * Jordan Kyrgyz Republic 3.70% X 13.90% 13.00% 14.40% 10.00% 22.90% 4.80% 8.90% 5.00% 10.70% 9.29% 6.00% 3.67% 16.40% 12.40% LL I Georgia Sierra Leone * Nicaragua Papua New Guinea 62 Finland 63 Denmark 64 Slovak Republic 65 Paraguay 66 Israel 67 Benin * 68 El Salvador 69 Honduras 70 Hong Kong, China 71 Burundi * 72 Switzerland 73 Guinea * 74 Chad * 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 Haiti * Austria Bulgaria Bolivia Dominican Rep. Rwanda * Sweden Senegal Tunisia CIF/FOB 4.50% 3.86% 88 Czech Republic 89 Malawi * X 5.00% 90 Greece X 13.89% 8.00% 20.50% 11.00% 20.01% X 13.61% 12.35% 15.00% 84 85 86 87 91 92 93 94 95 Niger * Mali * Cuba Burkina Faso * Guatemala 96 Zimbabwe X X 15.00% 1.00% X 35.00% X X X X X 15.00% 4.70% 8.48% 15.00% 43.60% 2.30% 14.40% 7.20% X 11.10% 17.78% 8.28% 12.80% LL I Portugal Hungary Zambia * Belgium 58 59 60 61 97 98 99 100 Ecuador Angola * Cameroon Chile 101 102 103 104 105 Madagascar * Netherlands Cote d'Ivoire Mozambique* Australia 106 107 108 109 110 Ghana Sri Lanka Uganda * Taipei, Chinese Romania 111 Malaysia 112 Venezuela, RB 10.68% Data are for the year 2000, from 2002 World Development Indicators Statistics. * indicates Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. LL stands for Land-Locked as defined by CIA World Fact Book country report. I stands for Island as defined by CIA World Fact Book country report. 13.15% CIF/FOB 25.1> LL I CIF/FOB X X 10.30% 0.09% 2.63% 3.10% 113 114 115 116 Peru Morocco Kenya Canada 20.00% 9.89% 16.30% 2.50% X X 3.93% 66.67% 117 118 Tanzania * Argentina 17.60% 9.10% 13.00% 119 Poland 17.28% 17.30% 42.90% Spain Colombia South Africa Korea, Rep. Myanmar * 6.00% 9.01% 8.06% 5.60% 10.00% X X X 28.20% 12.90% 120 121 122 123 124 X 15.00% 125 Congo, Dem. Rep. * 13.36% 10.00% 9.48% 126 127 128 129 Italy France United Kingdom Thailand 6.90% 3.71% 4.39% 10.80% 20.50% 5.60% 24.40% 12.03% 8.92% 130 131 132 133 134 Egypt, Arab Rep. Turkey Philippines Germany Mexico 11.10% 5.70% 7.00% 2.53% 4.70% 6.77% 11.10% 11.00% 135 136 137 138 139 Japan Nigeria Bangladesh * Pakistan Brazil 9.00% 10.70% 10.58% 9.50% 8.93% 140 141 142 143 Indonesia United States India China 12.00% 4.27% 11.70% 9.00% 9.13% X X X X 7.51% 10.50% 11.00% 14.55% WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 27 28 Trinidad and Tobago 29 Gambia, The * 30 Estonia CIF/FOB WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 28 Notes for Table 3: Note 1: Data have been taken from the IFS Yearbook, 1995, published by the IMF. These figures are not a perfectly accurate measure of actual CIF/FOB ratios, since they are in many cases estimated by IMF staff based on incomplete information. For most countries, they show little variance over time, indicating that IMF staff retain a constant CIF/FOB conversion factor once it is established for a country, and revise it only infrequently. Indeed for many countries the ratios have not been updated after 1990 and the IMF has by now stopped publishing IMF ratios. This is why we use data for 1990 in our calculations, as has been done in Radelet and Rodrik (1998) and Limão and Venables (1999). CIF/FOB ratios can also be calculated using data from the US Bureau of Census, but those data would only reflect exports by WTO Members to the US. It has been pointed out in the main text that the exports of small economies tend to be heavily concentrated in a few commodities, whereas the same countries import a broad range of goods. Given that transport costs differ according to the product trade, CIF/FOB ratios for exports differ significantly from the CIF/FOB ratio for imports in the case of small countries. It is the latter that gives a more appropriate measure for the transport costs due to geographic characteristics as it is not biased by a particular product mix. More direct shipping cost data – e.g. from transport companies- is generally proprietary information and therefore hard to assemble for a large number of countries on a systematic basis. Limão and Venables (1999) were able to use such a dataset and found that results from their analysis using CIF/FOB ratios were quite consistent with those obtained when from the shipping cost data. Note 2: The Commonwealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force (2000) recently published the following CIF/FOB ratios for a number of countries: Kiribati 26%, Comoros 24%, São Tomé 23%, Tonga 22%, Vanuatu 20%, Gabon 20%, The Gambia 20%, Solomon Islands 20%, Equatorial Guinea 19%, Trinidad & Tobago 18%, and Seychelles 18%. Some of these numbers differ significantly from the data in Table….The Secretariat order the publication holding the data on which these figures are based, but is currently still awaiting response. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 29 Table 4: CIF-FOB Ratios by Product Group CIF/FOB Ratios Average 1999-2001 0 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 Food and live animals Live Animals Meat and Meat Preparations Dairy Products and Birds' Eggs Fish, Crustaceans, Molluscs etc and preparations thereof Cereals and cereal preparations Vegetables and fruit Sugars, sugar preparations and honey Coffee, tea, cocoa, spices, and manufactures thereof Feeding stuff for animals (not including unmilled cereals) Miscellaneous edible products and preparations 7.62% 2.34% 4.54% 4.86% 5.28% 7.50% 14.45% 6.87% 5.18% 6.76% 5.35% 1 Beverages and tobacco 11 Beverages 12 Tobacco and tobacco manufactures 3.00% 2.91% 3.77% 2 Crude materials, inedible, except fuels 21 Hides, skins and furskins, raw 22 Oil seeds and oleaginous fruits 23 Crude rubber (including synthetic and reclaimed) 24 Cork and Wood 25 Pulp and waste paper 26 Textile fibers (other than wool tops and othe combo wool) and their wastes ( not manufactured into yarn or fabric) 27 Crude fertilizers, other than those of division 56, and crude minerals (excluding coal, petroleum and precious stones) 28 Metalliferous ores and metal scrap 29 Crude animal and vegetable materials 7.89% 1.97% 8.38% 9.33% 5.62% 4.55% 8.79% 3 Mineral fuels, lubricants and related materials 32 Coal, coke and briquettes 33 Petroleum, petroleum products and related materials 34 Gas, natural and manufactured 35 Electric current 23.44% 7.84% 10.29% 4.96% 15.29% 5.43% 1.72% 0.00% 4 Animal and vegetable oils, fats and waxes 41 Animal oils and fats 42 Fixed vegetables fats and oils, crude, refined or fractionated 43 Animal or vegetable fats and oils, processed; waxes of animal or vegetable origin; inedible mixtures or preparations of animal or vegetable fats and oils, n.e.s 6.46% 5.00% 6.61% 5.91% 5 Chemicals and related products, n.e.s. 51 Organic chemicals 52 Inorganic chemicals 53 Dyeing, tanning and colouring materials 54 Medical and pharmaceutical products 55 Essential oils and resinoids and perfume materials; toilet, polishing and cleaning preparations 56 Fertilizers (other than those in group 272) 57 Plastics in primary forms 58 Plastics in non-primary forms 2.88% 2.31% 5.92% 3.27% 0.86% 3.40% 6.84% 4.22% 4.55% WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 30 59 Chemical materials and products, n.e.s. CIF/FOB Ratios Average 1999-2001 3.79% 6 Manufactured goods classified chiefly by material 61 Leather, leather manufactures, n.e.s and dressed furskins 62 Rubber manufactures, n.e.s. 63 Cork and wood manufactures (excluding furniture) 64 Paper, paperboard and articles of paper pulp, of paper or of paperboard 65 Textile yarn, fabrics, made-up articles, n.e.s., and related products 66 Non-metallic mineral manufactures, n.e.s. 67 Iron and steel 68 Non-ferrous metals 69 Manufactures of metals, n.e.s. 5.10% 3.97% 5.62% 6.42% 4.69% 5.13% 5.57% 8.09% 1.70% 5.24% 7 Machinery and transport equipment 71 Power generating machinery and equipment 72 Machinery specialized for particular industries 73 Metal working machinery 74 General industrial machinery and equipment, n.e.s. and machine parts, n.e.s 75 Office machines and automatic data processing machines 76 Telecommunications and sound recording and reproducing apparatus and equipment 77 Electrical machinery, apparatus and appliances, n.e.s. and electrical parts thereof (including non-electrical counterparts n.e.s. of electrical household type equipment 78 Road Vehicles (including air-cushion vehicles) 79 Other transport equipment 1.90% 1.55% 2.82% 3.02% 3.04% 2.02% 1.78% 8 Miscellaneous manufactured articles 81 Prefabricated buildings; sanitary plumbing, heating and lighting fixtures and fittings, n.e.s. 82 Furniture and parts thereof; bedding, mattresses, mattress supports, cushions and similar stuffed furnishings 83 Travel goods, handbags and similar containers 84 Articles of apparel and clothing accessories 85 Footwear 87 Professional, scientific and controlling instruments and apparatus, n.e.s. 88 Photographic apparatus, equipment and supplies and optical goods, n.e.s; watches and clocks 89 Miscellaneous manufactured articles, n.e.s. 4.67% 8.22% 9 Commodities and transactions not classified elsewhere in SITC 93 Special Transactions and commodities not classified according to kind 95 Coin including gold 96 Coin (other than gold coin) not being legal tender 97 Gold, non-monetary (excluding gold, ores and concentrates) 98 Estimate Of Low Valued Import Transactions 0.99% 1.45% 0.48% 1.71% 0.08% 0.00% Source: US Bureau of Census. 1-Digit and 2-Digit SITC classification, Rev.3. 1.82% 1.74% 0.78% 8.37% 8.01% 4.18% 5.15% 1.56% 2.27% 5.05% WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 31 Table 5: Openness to Trade and Volatility of Export Earnings A. Members with Population < 1.5 million Rank Members % Share of Trade in GDP Volatility of Export Earnings N.A N.A 1 Liechtenstein 60.97 10.527 2 St. Kitts and Nevis 80.68 15.261 3 Antigua and Barbuda 61.01 17.010 4 Dominica 62.42 11.505 5 Grenada 60.40 13.440 6 St. Vincent and the Grenadines 64.24 11.053 7 St. Lucia Belize 55.15 7.322 8 55.20 8.276 9 Barbados 98.89 8.870 10 Maldives * 39.38 9.858 11 Iceland N.A 15.307 12 Brunei N.A 13.297 13 Malta 21.93 20.832 14 Suriname 60.04 10.493 15 Macao, China 106.51 N.A 16 Luxembourg N.A 15.216 17 Solomon Islands * N.A 21.894 18 Qatar N.A 12.720 19 Djibouti * N.A 14.435 20 Bahrain N.A 11.710 21 Cyprus 102.90 11.570 22 Guyana 56.96 11.676 23 Fiji 84.83 19.935 24 Swaziland Mauritius 65.83 15.520 25 30.25 44.878 26 Guinea-Bissau * 46.12 20.920 27 Gabon 57.09 14.139 28 Trinidad and Tobago 54.53 17.724 29 Gambia, The * 94.13 20.442 30 Estonia Source: World Development Indicators 2002 and WTO Secretariat. * refers to Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. The share of trade in GDP is computed as the sum of imports and exports of goods and services divided by two. The average of the years 1997-1999 is taken unless noted otherwise and constant 1995 US$ have been used. Volatility of export earnings was computed as standard deviation of the growth rates of export earnings (goods and services, current prices). Data for the years 1981-2001 were used. There was no available data for Luxembourg alone for volatility of export earnings. Data for volatility of export earnings was grouped with Belgium. See Belgium category (Belgium + Luxembourg). The formula of volatility of export earnings for Guinea-Bissau was calculated with data starting at 1983. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 32 Table 5: Openness to Trade and Volatility of Export Earnings B: Members with Population 1.51 - 5 million Rank Members % Share of Trade in GDP Volatility of Export Earnings 39.92 22.708 31 Botswana 54.42 7.523 32 Namibia N.A 77.700 33 Kuwait 61.46 8.755 34 Slovenia 63.32 21.807 35 Lesotho * 60.22 11.858 36 Latvia N.A 22.439 37 Oman N.A 16.995 38 Mongolia 53.76 9.418 39 Jamaica Mauritania * 42.72 13.082 40 40.43 10.269 41 Panama N.A 17.746 42 United Arab Emirates 71.09 15.896 43 Congo, Rep. 21.19 10.391 44 Uruguay 24.35 38.401 45 Albania 74.58 12.840 46 Lithuania N.A 8.333 47 Central African Rep.* 85.46 14.805 48 Ireland 47.62 10.948 49 Costa Rica 31.79 8.604 50 New Zealand N.A 13.603 51 Singapore 86.57 13.327 52 Moldova 48.00 6.044 53 Croatia 37.93 10.588 54 Norway 40.31 16.049 55 Togo * Jordan 57.09 8.740 56 29.24 10.452 57 Kyrgyz Republic Source: World Development Indicators 2002 and WTO Secretariat. * refers to Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. The share of trade in GDP is computed as the sum of imports and exports of goods and services divided by two. The average of the years 1997-1999 is taken unless noted otherwise and constant 1995 US$ have been used. Volatility of export earnings was computed as standard deviation of the growth rates of export earnings (goods and services, current prices). Data for the years 1981-2001 were used. For Slovenia and Croatia data for volatility of export earnings are from 1993-2001. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 33 Table 5: Openness to Trade and Volatility of Export Earnings C: Members with Population 5.1-10 million Rank Members % Share of Trade in GDP Volatility of Export Earnings 45.903 9.685 58 Georgia 20.319 18.976 59 *Sierra Leone 60.555 17.275 60 Nicaragua 49.865 14.442 61 Papua New Guinea 36.786 12.099 62 Finland 36.025 11.104 63 Denmark 69.650 15.370 64 Slovak Republic 31.470 22.294 65 Paraguay Israel 41.431 8.570 66 24.948 33.258 67 Benin * 34.347 15.681 68 El Salvador 44.595 9.211 69 Honduras 153.416 11.017 70 Hong Kong, China 22.092 31.854 71 Burundi * 37.617 9.680 72 Switzerland 21.805 10.788 73 Guinea * 22.650 28.666 74 Chad * 24.070 49.068 75 Haiti * 44.395 10.565 76 Austria 55.181 16.113 77 Bulgaria 25.717 12.566 78 Bolivia 34.039 32.666 79 Dominican Republic 17.670 24.428 80 Rwanda * 43.785 11.005 81 Sweden Senegal 35.790 11.799 82 44.184 11.150 83 Tunisia Source: World Development Indicators 2002 and WTO Secretariat. * refers to Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. The share of trade in GDP is computed as the sum of imports and exports of goods and services divided by two. The average of the years 1997-1999 is taken unless noted otherwise and constant 1995 US$ have been used. Volatility of export earnings was computed as standard deviation of the growth rates of export earnings (goods and services, current prices). Data for the years 1981-2001 were used. For the Slovak Republic, data for volatility of export earnings was from 1994-2001. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 34 Table 5: Openness to Trade and Volatility of Export Earnings D: Members with Population 10.1 - 25 million Rank Members % Share of Trade in GDP Volatility of Export Earnings 37.658 11.771 84 Portugal 54.194 16.642 85 Hungary 40.912 15.032 86 Zambia * 71.606 10.965 87 Belgium 70.586 17.326 88 Czech Republic 42.559 15.961 89 Malawi * 25.605 10.750 90 Greece 20.457 17.914 91 Niger * Mali * 32.870 13.577 92 N.A 16.452 93 Cuba 22.954 18.635 94 Burkina Faso * 24.696 10.053 95 Guatemala 43.662 9.375 96 Zimbabwe 27.926 10.527 97 Ecuador N.A 24.308 98 Angola * 28.838 12.188 99 Cameroon 32.017 13.323 100 Chile 29.589 12.183 101 Madagascar * 59.505 9.710 102 Netherlands 40.067 12.311 103 Cote d'Ivoire 27.879 16.452 104 Mozambique* 21.561 9.469 105 Australia 46.060 18.839 106 Ghana 43.032 10.351 107 Sri Lanka Uganda * 19.528 28.270 108 N.A 11.587 109 Taipei, Chinese 39.389 16.829 110 Romania 92.031 12.568 111 Malaysia 27.767 21.025 112 Venezuela, RB Source: World Development Indicators 2002 and WTO Secretariat. * refers to Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. The share of trade in GDP is computed as the sum of imports and exports of goods and services divided by two. The average of the years 1997-1999 is taken unless noted otherwise and constant 1995 US$ have been used. Volatility of export earnings was computed as standard deviation of the growth rates of export earnings (goods and services, current prices). Data for the years 1981-2001 were used. Belgium's share of WTO Trade is the share of Belgium + Luxembourg. Czech Republic data for volatility of export earnings are from 1994-2001. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 35 Table 5: Openness to Trade and Volatility of Export Earnings E: Members with Population > 25 million Rank Members % Share of Trade in GDP Volatility of Export Earnings 16.499 11.649 113 Peru 31.890 10.061 114 Morocco 31.402 10.450 115 Kenya 42.317 6.123 116 Canada 19.707 16.217 117 Tanzania * 11.908 13.435 118 Argentina 31.604 15.151 119 Poland 28.190 8.785 120 Spain Colombia 18.443 14.819 121 24.027 9.211 122 South Africa 36.802 12.291 123 Korea, Rep. N.A 28.867 124 Myanmar * 27.536 23.187 125 Congo, Dem. Rep.* 27.058 10.123 126 Italy 24.878 9.549 127 France 32.782 8.314 128 United Kingdom 42.703 13.178 129 Thailand 22.821 11.095 130 Egypt, Arab Rep. 28.644 17.317 131 Turkey 42.407 12.492 132 Philippines 28.516 10.678 133 Germany 39.730 11.135 134 Mexico 9.125 8.894 135 Japan 46.378 31.193 136 Nigeria 14.992 11.857 137 Bangladesh * 16.831 9.472 138 Pakistan 9.487 11.260 139 Brazil 27.892 13.216 140 Indonesia 13.653 7.452 141 United States 13.430 6.752 142 India 16.458 10.709 143 China Source: World Development Indicators 2002 and WTO Secretariat. * refers to Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. The share of trade in GDP is computed as the sum of imports and exports of goods and services divided by two. The average of the years 1997-1999 is taken unless noted otherwise and constant 1995 US$ have been used. Volatility of export earnings was computed as standard deviation of the growth rates of export earnings (goods and services, current prices). Data for the years 1981-2001 were used. For China, years prior to 1983 were not taken into account for the computation of volatility of export earnings. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 36 Table 6: Concentration of export commodities and services for WTO Members (as a percentage of exports of goods and services, averages 1998 and 1999) A. Members with Population <1.5 million Rank Members Second commodity or service n.a.** n.a.** n.a.** 32.4 (travel) 45.7 (travel) 45.3 (travel) n.a.** n.a.** n.a.** 23.5 (other services) 20.6 (other services) 17.9 (other services) 10.9 (fruits, nuts, fresh, dried) 17.1 (sugar and honey) 21.6 (other services) 8.4 (fish fresh, chilled, frozen) 15.5 (transport) n.a.** 21.54 (travel) 11.43 (transport) 17.1 (outer garments knit non-elastic) n.a.** 24.9 (fish, fresh, chilled frozen) 15.0 (gas, n.a.** n.a.** n.a.** 15,6 (other services) 17.2 (gold, non-monetary nes) 14.9 (transport) n.a.** 13.3 (sugar and honey) n.a.** n.a.** 9.8 (crude petroleum) 29 Gambia, The * 72.9 (travel) 31.8 (travel) 55.2 (travel) 72.1 (travel) 25.3 (fish fresh, chilled and frozen) n.a.** 34.9 (transistors, valves, etc.) 48.1 (base metal, ores, conc nes) 51.7 (travel) n.a.** 26.6 (other wood rough, squared) 59.8 (crude petroleum) n.a.** n.a.** 47.5 (travel) 19.4 (sugar and honey) 27.2 (travel) n.a.** 20.0 (travel) n.a.** n.a.** 25.4 (petroleum products unrefined) 37.4 (travel) 30 Estonia 17.4 (transport) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 Liechtenstein St. Kitts and Nevis Antigua and Barbuda Dominica Grenada** St. Vincent and the Grenadines** St. Lucia Belize Barbados Maldives * Iceland Brunei Malta Suriname** Macao, China** Luxembourg Solomon Islands * Qatar Djibouti * Bahrain Cyprus Guyana** Fiji Swaziland Mauritius Guinea-Bissau * Gabon Trinidad and Tobago First commodity or services 32.2 (vegetable etc fresh, simply preserved) 13.4 (travel) Source: UNCTAD 2001 and WTO Secretariat. * Least-developed countries as defined by the UN. ** no data available on concentration of commodity exports in commodity trade from UNCTAD (2001). WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 37 Table 6: Concentration of export commodities and services for WTO Members (as a percentage of exports of goods and services, averages 1998 and 1999) B. Members with Population 1.5 - 5 million Rank Members First commodity or services Second commodity or service n.a.** n.a.** 31 Botswana n.a.** n.a.** 32 Namibia 40.7 (crude petroleum) 24.5 (petroleum products, refined) 33 Kuwait 9.4 (travel) 8.3 (passenger motor vehicles, exc. bus) 34 Slovenia n.a.** n.a.** 35 Lesotho * 24.0 (transport) 13.2 (wood, shaped, rail sleepers) 36 Latvia 67.3 (crude petroleum) 5.0 (passenger motor vehicle, exc. bus) 37 Oman 41.8 (base metals, ores, conc nes) 13.0 (wool (exc. tops), animal hair) 38 Mongolia 36.4 (travel) 23.9 (base metals, ores, conc nes) 39 Jamaica Mauritania * 37.9 (iron ore and concentrates) 24.7 (fish, fresh, chilled and frozen) 40 20.1 (fruit, nuts, fresh, dried) 13.5 (shellfish, fresh, frozen) 41 Panama 44.4 (crude petroleum) 7.4 (gas, natural and manufactured) 42 United Arab Emirates 60.0 (crude petroleum) 7.3 (other services) 43 Congo, Rep. 17.7 (travel) 10.9 (meet fresh, chilled and frozen) 44 Uruguay 28.4 (travel) 10.8 (leather, etc., manufactures) 45 Albania 11.0 (travel) 9.4 (petroleum products, refined) 46 Lithuania n.a.** n.a.** 47 Central African Rep.* 12.9 (other services) 11.1 (automatic data processing equip.) 48 Ireland 21.5 (office, adp machy parts, access) 12.9 (travel) 49 Costa Rica 12.3 (travel) 9.7 (meat, fresh, chilled frozen) 50 New Zealand 15.9 (transistors, valves, etc) 15.0 (automatic data processing equip.) 51 Singapore 24.5 (alcoholic beverages) 9.8 (transport) 52 Moldova 31.3 (travel) 8.9 (ships, boats etc.) 53 Croatia 25.8 (crude petroleum) 14.7 (transport) 54 Norway 29.6 (fertilizers, crude) 28.3 (cotton) 55 Togo * Jordan 23.1 (travel) 17.4 (other services) 56 21.2 (special transactions) 10.5 (tobacco, unmanufactured, refuse) 57 Kyrgyz Republic Source: UNCTAD 2001 and WTO Secretariat. * Least-developed countries as defined by the UN. ** no data available on concentration of commodity exports in commodity trade from UNCTAD (2001). WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 38 Table 6: Concentration of export commodities and services for WTO Members. (as a percentage of exports of goods and services, averages 1998 and 1999) C. Members with Population 5.1-10 million Rank Members First commodity or services Second commodity or service 25.2 (travel) 20.4 (transport) 58 Georgia n.a.** n.a.** 59 *Sierra Leone 20.6 (coffee and substitutes) 14.0 (travel) 60 Nicaragua 30.6 (prec. metal ores, waste nes) 16.7 (other fixed vegetable oils) 61 Papua New Guinea 17.2 (paper and paperboard) 13.6 (telecom equip, parts, access) 62 Finland 11.7 (transport) 7.8 (other services) 63 Denmark 11.7(passenger motor vehicles, etc bus) 6.9 (other services) 64 Slovak Republic 36.2 (seeds for soft fixed oils) 11.5 (other services) 65 Paraguay Israel 20.4 (pearl, prec, semi-prec stones) 13.5 (other services) 66 n.a.** n.a.** 67 Benin * 19.1 (coffee and substitutes) 6.9 (travel) 68 El Salvador 32.9 (coffee and substitutes) 10.8 (fruits, nuts, fresh, dried) 69 Honduras 12.0 (outer garments knit non-elastic) 9.2 (women's outwear non-knit) 70 Hong Kong, China 77.5 (coffee and substitutes) 6.67 (tea and mate) 71 Burundi * 11.5 (other services) 10.5 (medicalm, pharmaceutical prd) 72 Switzerland n.a.** n.a.** 73 Guinea * n.a.** n.a.** 74 Chad * 23.3 (travel) 16.2 (women's outwear non-knit) 75 Haiti * 15.4 (other services) 11.9 (travel) 76 Austria 16.2 (travel) 8.3 (transport) 77 Bulgaria 12.9 (aircraft etc.) 10.4 (base metal ores, conc nes) 78 Bolivia 30.3 (travel) 79 Dominican Republic 53.1 (special transactions) n.a.** n.a.** 80 Rwanda * 10.9 (telecom equip, parts, access) 9.4 (other services) 81 Sweden Senegal 14.6 (inorg chem elmnt, oxides, etc.) 12.8 (travel) 82 20.5 (travel) 12.7 (men's outweat non-knit) 83 Tunisia Source: UNCTAD 2001 and WTO Secretariat. * Least-developed countries as defined by the UN. ** no data available on concentration of commodity exports in commodity trade from UNCTAD (2001). WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 39 Table 6: Concentration of export commodities and services for WTO Members (as a percentage of exports of goods and services, averages 1998 and 1999) D. Members with Population 10.1-25 million Rank Members Second commodity or service 15.7 (travel) 7.8 (passenger motor vehicles exc. bus) 12.8 (travel) 8.7 (intern combust piston engines) n.a.** n.a.** n.a.** n.a.** 10.2 (travel) 6.7 (other services) 58.6 (tobacco unmanufactured, 8.6 (tea and mate) refuse) 30.9 (travel) 23.8 (other services) 90 Greece 51.3 (uranium, thorium ores, conc) 11.2 (vegtb etc fresh, simply prsrvd) 91 Niger * 75.7 (cotton) 4.8 (gold, non-monetary nes) 92 Mali * n.a.** n.a.** 93 Cuba Burkina Faso * 51.8 (cotton) 9.1 (travel) 94 18.7 (coffee and substitutes) 9.8 (travel) 95 Guatemala 22.9 (tobacco unmanufactured, 11.8 (travel) 96 Zimbabwe refuse) 21.3 (crude petroleum) 20.8 (fruit, nuts, fresh, dried) 97 Ecuador n.a.** n.a.** 98 Angola * 27.1 (crude petroleum) 9.8 (other wood rough squared) 99 Cameroon 22.0 (copper) 9.2 (base metal ores, conc nes) 100 Chile 14.7 (other services) 11.5 (travel) 101 Madagascar * 9.6 (other services) 8.5 (transport) 102 Netherlands 33.3 (cocoa) 10.9 (petroleum products, refined) 103 Cote d'Ivoire n.a.** n.a.** 104 Mozambique* 10.6 (travel) 8.5 (coal, lignite and peat) 105 Australia 32.3 (cocoa) 11.8 (travel) 106 Ghana 14.9 (women's outwear non-knit) 11.5 (tea and mate) 107 Sri Lanka 41.8 (coffee and substitutes) 21.4 (travel) 108 Uganda * n.a.** n.a.** 109 Taipei, Chinese 7.9 (women's outwear non-knit) 6.4 (men's outweat non-knit) 110 Romania 17.2 (transistors, valves etc) 9.3 (office, adp machy parts acces) 111 Malaysia Venezuela, RB 60.8 (crude petroleum) 10.4 (petroleum products, refined) 112 Source: UNCTAD 2001 and WTO Secretariat. * Least-developed countries as defined by the UN. ** no data available on concentration of commodity exports in commodity trade from UNCTAD (2001). 84 85 86 87 88 89 Portugal Hungary Zambia * Belgium Czech Republic Malawi * First commodity or services WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 40 Table 6: Concentration of export commodities and services for WTO Members (as a percentage of exports of goods and services, averages 1998 and 1999) E. Members with Population 25.1+ million Rank Members First commodity or services Second commodity or service 14.6 (gold, non-monetary nes) 11.6 (travel) 113 Peru 18.4 (travel) 8.3 (women's outwear non-knit) 114 Morocco 20.9 (tea and mate) 13.3 (transport) 115 Kenya 12.2 (passenger motor vehicles exc. bus) 6.5 (other services) 116 Canada 37.7 (travel) 8.4 (fruits, nuts, fresh, dried) 117 Tanzania * 10.2 (travel) 8.4 (fixed vegetable oils) 118 Argentina 9.1 (travel) 7.8 (other services) 119 Poland 19.0 (travel) 10.1 (passenger motor vehicles exc. bus) 120 Spain 20.9 (crude petroleum) 13.3 (coffee and substitutes) 121 Colombia 7.9 (travel) 7.6 (pearl, prec, semi-prec stones) 122 South Africa 12.6 (transistors, valves etc.) 6.6 (transport) 123 Korea, Rep. 18.0 (other services) 11.7 (other wood rough, squared) 124 Myanmar * n.a.** 125 Congo, Dem. Rep.* n.a.** Italy 9.7 (travel) 7.6 (other services) 126 8.4 (other services) 7.9 (travel) 127 France 17.5 (other services) 6.1 (travel) 128 United Kingdom 9.6 (travel) 8.5 (office, adp machy parts) 129 Thailand 23.9 (travel) 20.7 (other services) 130 Egypt, Arab Rep. 20.6 (other services) 12.3 (travel) 131 Turkey 23.3 (special transactions) 22.0 (transistors, valves, etc) 132 Philippines 9.8 (passenger motor vehicles exc. bus) 6.9 (other services) 133 Germany 8.4 (passenger motor vehicles exc. bus) 5.5 (travel) 134 Mexico 11.3 (passenger motor vehicles exc. bus) 7.9 (other services) 135 Japan 90.6 (crude petroleum) 6.6 (other services) 136 Nigeria 22.5 (men's outwear non-knit) 18.1 (under garments non-knit) 137 Bangladesh * 12.1 (cotton fabrics, woven) 11.7 (textiles articles nes) 138 Pakistan 7.1 (other services) 5.3 (iron ore and concentrates) 139 Brazil 8.2 (special transactions) 7.8 (travel) 140 Indonesia 12.0 (other services) 9.4 (travel) 141 United States India 16.0 (other services) 12.3 (pearl, prec, semi-prec stones) 142 6.2 (travel) 4.4 (other services) 143 China Source: UNCTAD 2001 and WTO Secretariat. * Least-developed countries as defined by the UN. ** no data available on concentration of commodity exports in commodity trade from UNCTAD (2001). WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 41 Table 7: Volatility of GDP, Average Growth Rate of GDP and GDP per capita A. Members with Population <1.5 million Rank Members Volatility of GDP Average % growth rate of GDP Per Capita GDP per capita Liechtenstein N.A N.A St. Kitts and Nevis 4.12 5.18 Antigua and Barbuda 3.64 4.42 Dominica N.A N.A Grenada 3.14 3.96 St. Vincent and the 3.36 3.69 Grenadines 8.25 3.60 7 St. Lucia 4.64 2.74 8 Belize 4.09 1.23 9 Barbados 3.63 5.99 10 Maldives * Iceland 3.03 1.79 11 5.41 -3.04 12 Brunei 1.60 4.11 13 Malta 8.14 0.12 14 Suriname 4.64 2.30 15 Macao, China 2.91 4.04 16 Luxembourg 6.86 0.27 17 Solomon Islands * N.A N.A 18 Qatar 3.02 -4.61 19 Djibouti * 5.99 -0.10 20 Bahrain 2.58 4.16 21 Cyprus 5.52 0.88 22 Guyana 5.57 0.12 23 Fiji 5.74 2.00 24 Swaziland 4.06 3.86 25 Mauritius 9.43 0.36 26 Guinea-Bissau * Gabon 6.15 -0.60 27 4.34 0.80 28 Trinidad and Tobago 2.69 0.10 29 Gambia, The * 7.00 0.73 30 Estonia Source: World Development Indicators 2002 and WTO Secretariat. * refers to Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. Volatility of GDP is computed as the standard deviation of per capita growth rates 1980-2000. Average growth rate of GDP was computed for 1980-2000. GDP per capita refers to the year 2000 and is expressed in PPP current international $. GDP data for Qatar and Djibouti are for years 1998 from WDI 2002. GDP data for Liechtenstein are from the TPR of Switzerland and Liechtenstein 2000. 1 2 3 4 5 6 $ 38,000 $ 12,510 $ 10,541 $ 3,671 $ 7,580 $ 5,555 $ 5,703 $ 5,606 $ 15,494 $ 4,485 $ 29,581 $ 5,049 $ 17,273 $ 3,799 $ 18,190 $ 50,061 $ 1,648 $ 21,590 $ 812 $ 14,548 $ 20,824 $ 3,963 $ 4,668 $ 4,492 $ 10,017 $ 755 $ 6,237 $ 8,964 $ 1,649 $ 10,066 WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 42 Table 7: Volatility of GDP, Average Growth Rate of GDP and GDP per capita B. Members with Population 1.51 – 5 million Rank Members Volatility of Average % growth rate of GDP GDP per capita GDP Per Capita 3.00 4.58 $ 7,184 31 Botswana 2.86 -0.09 $ 6,431 32 Namibia 13.72 -2.26 $ 15,799 33 Kuwait 4.92 2.01 $ 17,367 34 Slovenia 4.17 1.79 $ 2,031 35 Lesotho * 9.48 0.33 $ 7,045 36 Latvia 5.24 3.20 $ 8,246 37 Oman 4.89 0.64 $ 1,783 38 Mongolia Jamaica 3.60 0.34 $ 3,639 39 2.40 0.16 $ 1,677 40 Mauritania * 4.96 0.98 $ 6,000 41 Panama 8.79 -3.15 $ 16,817 42 United Arab Emirates 7.69 0.48 $ 728 43 Congo, Rep. 5.17 1.14 $ 9,035 44 Uruguay 8.63 0.33 $ 3,506 45 Albania 9.82 -0.83 $ 7,106 46 Lithuania 4.70 -1.22 $ 1,172 47 Central African Rep.* 3.38 4.71 $ 29,866 48 Ireland 3.97 1.09 $ 8,650 49 Costa Rica 2.08 1.19 $ 20,070 50 New Zealand 3.31 5.02 $ 23,356 51 Singapore 10.62 -3.52 $ 2,109 52 Moldova 10.34 -0.03 $ 8,091 53 Croatia 1.80 2.52 $ 29,918 54 Norway 6.70 -0.95 $ 1,442 55 Togo * 6.40 0.29 $ 3,966 56 Jordan 9.45 -2.08 $ 2,711 57 Kyrgyz Republic Source: World Development Indicators 2002 and WTO Secretariat. * refers to Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. Volatility of GDP is computed as the standard deviation of per capita growth rates 1980-2000. Average growth rate of GDP was computed for 1980-2000. GDP per capita refers to the year 2000 and is expressed in PPP (current international $). GDP data for Oman is from WDI 2002 for 1998. GDP date for United Arab Emirates are from the WDI 2002 for 1998. WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 43 Table 7: Volatility of GDP, Average Growth Rate of GDP and GDP per capita C. Members with Population 5.1 – 10 million Rank Members Volatility of Average % growth rate of GDP GDP per capita GDP Per Capita 16.72 -5.07 $ 2,664 58 Georgia 6.84 -2.85 $ 490 59 *Sierra Leone 4.16 -1.58 $ 2,366 60 Nicaragua 5.68 0.20 $ 2,280 61 Papua New Guinea 3.18 2.40 $ 24,996 62 Finland 1.74 1.63 $ 27,627 63 Denmark 5.52 0.83 $ 11,243 64 Slovak Republic 3.80 0.10 $ 4,426 65 Paraguay 1.82 2.08 $ 20,131 66 Israel 3.43 0.88 $ 990 67 Benin * El Salvador 4.83 -0.11 $ 4,497 68 2.60 -0.25 $ 2,453 69 Honduras 4.37 4.22 $ 25,153 70 Hong Kong, China 4.98 -1.02 $ 591 71 Burundi * 1.91 1.02 $ 28,769 72 Switzerland 1.46 1.31 $ 1,982 73 Guinea * 8.10 0.92 $ 871 74 Chad * 4.33 -2.01 $ 1,467 75 Haiti * 1.14 1.95 $ 26,765 76 Austria 5.55 0.77 $ 5,710 77 Bulgaria 2.91 -0.40 $ 2,424 78 Bolivia 3.64 2.35 $ 6,033 79 Dominican Republic 12.25 -0.28 $ 943 80 Rwanda * 1.97 1.63 $ 24,277 81 Sweden 4.09 0.25 $ 1,510 82 Senegal 2.81 2.22 $ 6,363 83 Tunisia Source: World Development Indicators 2002 and WTO Secretariat. * refers to Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. Volatility of GDP is computed as the standard deviation of per capita growth rates 1980-2000. Average growth rate of GDP was computed for 1980-2000. GDP per capita refers to the year 2000 and is expressed in PPP (current international $). WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 44 Table 7: Volatility of GDP, Average Growth Rate of GDP and GDP per capita D. Members with Population 10.1 - 25 million Rank Members Volatility of Average % growth rate of GDP GDP per capita GDP Per Capita 2.39 2.85 $ 17,290 84 Portugal 3.86 1.28 $ 12,416 85 Hungary 3.76 -1.82 $ 780 86 Zambia * 1.53 2.00 $ 27,178 87 Belgium 4.66 0.18 $ 13,991 88 Czech Republic 5.82 0.26 $ 615 89 Malawi * 2.21 0.98 $ 16,501 90 Greece 5.47 -2.34 $ 746 91 Niger * Mali * 4.49 -0.50 $ 797 92 N.A 3.89 $ 2,154 93 Cuba 3.63 1.58 $ 976 94 Burkina Faso * 2.38 -0.03 $ 3,821 95 Guatemala 5.34 0.69 $ 2,635 96 Zimbabwe 3.71 -0.23 $ 3,203 97 Ecuador 7.25 -1.31 $ 2,187 98 Angola * 5.93 -0.40 $ 1,703 99 Cameroon 4.99 3.81 $ 9,417 100 Chile 3.25 -1.61 $ 840 101 Madagascar * 1.48 1.83 $ 25,657 102 Netherlands 4.19 -2.25 $ 1,630 103 Côte d'Ivoire 7.71 1.18 $ 854 104 Mozambique* 2.09 2.04 $ 25,693 105 Australia 3.59 0.21 $ 1,964 106 Ghana 1.36 3.32 $ 3,530 107 Sri Lanka Uganda * 3.19 2.23 $ 1,208 108 N.A N.A N.A 109 Taipei, Chinese 5.25 -0.71 $ 6,423 110 Romania 4.18 3.89 $ 9,068 111 Malaysia 4.71 -1.15 $ 5,794 112 Venezuela, RB Source: World Development Indicators 2002 and WTO Secretariat. * refers to Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. Volatility of GDP is computed as the standard deviation of per capita growth rates 1980-2000. Average growth rate of GDP was computed for 1980-2000. GDP per capita refers to the year 2000 and is expressed in PPP (current international $). WT/COMTD/SE/W/5 Page 45 Table 7: Volatility of GDP, Average Growth Rate of GDP and GDP per capita E. Members with Population > 25 million Rank Members Volatility of Average % growth rate of GDP GDP per capita GDP Per Capita 6.60 -0.149 $ 4,799 113 Peru 5.32 1.187 $ 3,546 114 Morocco 1.97 -0.056 $ 1,022 115 Kenya 2.38 1.556 $ 27,840 116 Canada 1.86 0.449 $ 523 117 Tanzania * 5.97 0.381 $ 12,377 118 Argentina 4.08 3.589 $ 9,051 119 Poland 1.84 2.416 $ 19,472 120 Spain 2.18 1.084 $ 6,248 121 Colombia 3.46 -0.339 $ 9,401 122 South Africa 4.31 5.814 $ 17,380 123 Korea, Rep. 5.00 2.183 $ 7,298 124 Myanmar * 5.18 -4.578 $ 724 125 Congo, Dem. Rep.* 1.20 1.885 $ 23,626 126 Italy 1.14 1.646 $ 24,223 127 France 2.01 1.948 $ 23,509 128 United Kingdom 4.84 4.737 $ 6,402 129 Thailand 2.06 2.852 $ 3,635 130 Egypt, Arab Rep. 4.19 2.199 $ 6,974 131 Turkey 3.76 0.162 $ 3,971 132 Philippines 1.25 1.647 $ 25,103 133 Germany 3.97 1.106 $ 9,023 134 Mexico 1.78 2.327 $ 26,755 135 Japan 5.18 -0.833 $ 896 136 Nigeria Bangladesh * 1.78 2.400 $ 1,602 137 2.05 2.689 $ 1,928 138 Pakistan 3.79 0.773 $ 7,625 139 Brazil 4.80 3.721 $ 3,043 140 Indonesia 2.00 1.986 $ 34,142 141 United States 1.96 3.658 $ 2,358 142 India 3.12 8.154 $ 3,976 143 China Source: World Development Indicators 2002 and WTO Secretariat. * refers to Least Developed Countries as defined by the UN. Volatility of GDP is computed as the standard deviation of per capita growth rates 1980-2000. Average growth rate of GDP was computed for 1980-2000. GDP per capita refers to the year 2000 and is expressed in PPP (current international $). GDP data for Myanmar is from WDI for 1995. GDP data for Congo Dem. Rep. is from WDI for1998. __________