Changes in the Patterns of External Financing in Mexico Since the Approval of NAFTA Alfredo Cuevas, Miguel Messmacher and Alejandro Werner Banco de México July 2002 We are grateful to Edgar Madinaveitia, Eduardo Cabal and Gerardo Gómez Ruano for research assistance, and to Lorenza Martinez, Oscar Sánchez and Enrique Dussel Peters (and his coauthors at UNAM) for sharing data with us. We thank Luis Servén, participants in seminars at the World Bank and the Banco de México, and an anonymous referee for their observations. We are responsible for any remaining errors. The views presented in this document are our own and do not necessarily reflect those of the Banco de México. Introduction In this chapter we try to identify some of the main effects of the North American Free Trade Agreement on Mexico-bound capital flows. The expression “free trade agreement” evokes an image of changes in the patterns and volumes of traffic in all sorts of merchandise among countries. Naturally, however, commerce is not the only process affected by trade agreements. Changing trade patterns should be expected to be associated with modifications in the forms, sources and levels of financing. This may come about for a number of reasons. Some corporations may desire to invest in a potential export platform; a firm may find financing opportunities abroad a more appropriate hedge to foreign exchange risk when its exporting activity increases; a foreign bank may become more willing to lend to a local firm whose earnings do not depend exclusively on domestic activity; and so on. Moreover, in the case of NAFTA there are also direct reasons to expect changes in financing patterns, given that the agreement contains specific provisions for the liberalization of the rules governing international investment within the region. Among these, the most important are national treatment and most-favored-nation privileges for any investor residing in North America. Changes in financing can be examined both from a nation-wide perspective and from the viewpoint of individual firms. Abundant macroeconomic data allows the documentation of important changes in the composition of the capital account of the balance of payments that coincided with the incorporation of Mexico into this free trade area. This is a task we undertake in the first part of this chapter, where we discuss the well-known increase in the importance of private capital flows, particularly foreign direct investment and direct external borrowing by nonbank agents, as well as the growing synchronization between the US and Mexican stock marekts. We will also argue that some of these effects are not particular to the case of Mexico, and will present the results of the statistical analysis of an international data set suggesting that free trade agreements have promoted foreign investments elsewhere too. The application of this statistical framework to Mexican data yields some interesting insights. The growth in FDI in recent years has responded both to globalization forces and to Mexico’s own regional integration in NAFTA. In particular, a conservative estimate of NAFTA’s influence would suggest that it is responsible for increasing FDI in Mexico by about 70 percent. However, the increase in FDI observed during the second half of the nineties has been disappointing relative to what one should have expected on the basis of global capital markets integration, Mexico’s overall economic performance, and that country’s entry into NAFTA. The main reason for the relatively modest performance of FDI may be the halt in the structural reform process in Mexico since around 1997. The second part of this paper uses micro-level data to explore the new financing opportunities that may have become available to firms. This work is of a more tentative nature because of the scarcity of appropriate firm-level data. All the same, we find an increasing resort to foreign financing after NAFTA went into effect, especially among export oriented firms, which were better positioned to take advantage of the new environment. Similarly, we estimated investment equations and found that, despite a general intensification of liquidity constraints due to the banking crisis, the 1 liberalization of trade and the consequent increase in exports seem to be associated with a lessening of liquidity constraints. In the rest of this introduction we discuss some of the methodological difficulties researchers face when dealing with a phenomenon such as the one we propose to analyze. The first difficulty has to do with the proper time frame over which one might want to look for the effects of NAFTA. The agreement went into effect on January 1, 1994, but that is not the only choice for dating the change in economic policy and circumstances. The formal start of the negotiation process took place after the approval of fast-track authority for President Bush’s government in May 1991 (although the governments of Mexico, Canada and the United States had expressed their intention to seek an agreement well before that time). Discussions on the main body of the agreement concluded in 1992; however, by then pressure had emerged to negotiate side agreements on labor and environmental issues, which were not concluded until 1993. The agreement went into effect in January 1994, but it provided for the gradual opening of various sectors of the three economies following a multiplicity of calendars varying by country and by tariff category (See Mayer 2001). In many cases, the attainment of full liberalization was expected to take a decade or longer. So, the date of “the” policy change is not a clearly defined point in time. We will take this into account throughout the paper, by considering the run up to the agreement as a period in which expectations of an accord may have affected investment and financing flows. In fact, we will see that it is possible to identify important changes in financing flows starting in 1991 or 1992, although it is difficult to attribute these changes to NAFTA, as we discuss next. A second difficulty is that the 1990s, and especially the period following the entry into effect of NAFTA, saw significant events and structural changes in the economies of Mexico and the world with important implications for capital flows. That decade was, in fact, a period of great instability in Mexico’s external accounts, as Figure 1 shows. These are some of the key changes that had effects on financing flows that may be difficult to separate from the impact of NAFTA: • The restructuring of Mexican Sovereign debt under the Brady deal in 1990. • The privatization program of the government since the beginning of the nineties, which included the sale of commercial banks. • The process of financial liberalization in Mexico during the early 1990s, the Mexican banking crisis of 1995 and its aftermath. • The exchange rate shock of 1994 and the adoption of a floating exchange rate regime in Mexico. • The intensification of international financial flows that is a key part of the globalization process. • The movement toward more investment-friendly policies and more open markets in a large number of countries. We will attempt to control for these factors by taking into consideration the domestic and international contexts and by making comparisons with other countries, especially 2 emerging market economies and countries that have joined free trade areas. Once these other events and trends are taken into consideration, however, it is still possible to see the influence of NAFTA on the evolving composition and increasing volume of external financing coming into Mexico. 40,000,000 30,000,000 20,000,000 Thousands of US dollars 10,000,000 0 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 -10,000,000 -20,000,000 -30,000,000 -40,000,000 Curent Account Capital Account Change in Net International Reserves Figure 1. Mexico: Main Elements of the Balance of Payments Source: Banco de México. Macroeconomic Analysis of Aggregated Financial Flows In this section we start by developing some of the arguments that might be put forward in support of the hypothesis that NAFTA has promoted the growth of foreign capital flows into Mexico. In fact, for many observers this was the main purpose of this agreement from Mexico’s perspective. It was not a matter of liberalizing trade further, this argument goes, but of creating a legal and economic environment conducive to the settlement of foreign investors. In fact, as we have mentioned already in the introduction, a key chapter of the agreement aims to facilitate foreign investment. Furthermore, trade liberalization was a process that had advanced considerably since the entry of Mexico into GATT in 1986 –even though Mexico was lagging in other structural reform areas (see Morley et al, 1999). Later in the section, we look at whether or not capital flows evolved in the expected direction during the nineties, both before 3 and after NAFTA went into effect. However, we should be careful not to establish a simple causal relationship between NAFTA and the evolution of the capital account. Other forces have contributed to shape capital flows into Mexico, and we look at them in a special subsection. The two most important among these forces are the globalization of capital markets and the Mexican banking crisis. The first of these processes helped foreign funds flow into countries such as Mexico, while the second may have sent Mexican agents in search of alternative financing sources beyond their country’s borders. Finally, we look in detail at the international experience in the area of foreign direct investment with the aid of a panel data set. The application of estimates from the regression analysis of the panel data to Mexican data allows us to measure, however tentatively, NAFTA’s contribution to the growth in FDI. Roughly, without NAFTA, the flow of foreign direct investment in Mexico would be only half as high as it is (all else equal). What was, or should have been, expected from NAFTA We will begin by discussing some of the main effects on capital flows into Mexico that could have been expected from the signing of NAFTA, especially in light of the investment-related provisions of the agreement. Some of these expectations are grounded on theoretical arguments, while others are based on the lessons from the experience of Spain and Portugal, two countries that officially joined the European Economic Community in January 1986.1 It is possible to formulate some arguments in favor of the hypothesis that NAFTA would inhibit foreign investment in Mexico. For instance, to the extent that planned or ongoing investment may have been motivated by a desire to circumvent old trade restrictions, some capital flows may be rendered unnecessary by the liberalization of trade flows agreed upon in NAFTA. As for temporary effects, it seems plausible that the expectation of better investment conditions in the near future created by the negotiation of the agreement may have led to the postponement of certain undertakings until the agreement, or some of its clauses, went into force. Also, after 1995 the preference for foreign credit was subject to opposite influences: on the one hand, the domestic banking crisis caused domestic credit sources to shrink and thus increased any residual demand for external credit; but on the other hand the move to a floating exchange rate regime increased the riskiness of foreign borrowing and may have thus reduced its attractiveness to Mexican firms. In contrast, there are good reasons to think that, on balance, NAFTA should promote the increase in capital flows, especially of FDI, into Mexico: • The free trade agreement and the general policy framework of which it is a part foster a friendly atmosphere for investment. Moreover, by giving a heightened legal status to the Mexican government’s commitment to open markets, NAFTA contributes to enhance the stability of the economic and policy environment. The locking-in of the structural reforms started with membership in the GATT in 1986 was widely considered one of the key benefits of NAFTA (Kehoe and Kehoe 1994a). 1 Levy-Yeyati, Stein and Daude (2001) offer a useful taxonomy of theoretical links between the freeing of external trade and changes in foreign investment. 4 • The policy stability argument also applies to Mexico’s partners: the US Congressional Budget Office (1993) noted that, as a result of NAFTA, Mexican producers would “face lower tariffs, fewer quotas and, and greater certainty that the United States would not suddenly put up protectionist barriers if they expanded exports.” Naturally, such stability would make Mexico a more attractive place to invest in export-oriented activities. • Being the smallest of the NAFTA partners, Mexico’s cost advantages become magnified by liberalization of trade in goods, an effect that ought to stimulate North American investment to locate in Mexico.2 • Third countries located outside North America should see Mexico as a more promising exporting platform into the United States as a result of NAFTA, and may thus want to locate some of their production facilities in Mexico. • Mexican firms taking advantage of export opportunities may find it easier --and more appropriate from the point of view of risk management-- to obtain credit abroad. • The investment chapters in the agreement should facilitate the decision to establish production facilities in Mexico by firms headquartered in the US and Canada. The last item in this list needs further elaboration. Foreign investment in Mexico had been significantly restricted under the law of 1973, which would be overhauled on the eve of the inauguration of NAFTA .3 This law was written still under the framework of the import substitution doctrine that dominated economic policy making in Mexico during the postwar period. This law, in places echoing the constitution but often going beyond it, prohibited or limited foreign investment in a number of key sectors of the economy. In some cases, such as oil, electricity, railroads and telegraphs, state owned firms were responsible for all activity. In other cases, such as air transportation, distribution of gas, forestry, and radio and TV, only Mexicans were allowed to invest. Regarding the economic sectors not reserved for the government or Mexican nationals, the 1973 law gave the government broad discretionary powers to limit foreign ownership to 49 percent of the capital of a firm. In December 1993, Congress approved a new foreign investment law. This new law took into account the investment framework laid out by NAFTA. The free trade agreement was respectful of the state monopolies established in the Mexican Constitution –emphatically, the state control of the oil and electricity industries. But it did imply the adoption of important principles that improved the relative standing of foreign investors in Mexico as well as an expansion of the areas 2 Krugman and Hanson 1993 explain this effect with the following example. Imagine a product with such economies of scale that it ought to be produced in one location only. Suppose that unit production and transport costs are $9 if production is located in Mexico and $10 if in the US, and that both countries apply tariffs of $1.5. Then, locating production in the US, where the bulk of this good is consumed, would achieve the lowest overall cost by avoiding the tariff that would otherwise fall on most units. But when both tariffs are removed Mexico’s cost advantage will make it optimal to move production there. 3 See Dussel Peters et al (2002). 5 where they could participate. The key principles incorporated in the free trade agreement were the following (Serra Puche, 1992): • The most favored nation (MFN) principle, which ensured that no investor from outside North America would be granted benefits exceeding those available to North American investors. • The national treatment principle, guaranteeing that there would be no discrimination among investors from each one of the three members of NAFTA. • The absence of trade-related performance requirements for foreign investors. • The freedom to buy foreign exchange and to transfer funds across countries (such as royalties, profits, and dividends) is fully guaranteed. There were exceptions to these principles, some times only during a transition period. For example, the automobile industry in Mexico would continue to be subject, for a period of 10 years, to net export performance requirements. Also, for a period of six years, there would be a limit on foreign ownership of firms producing auto parts and components.4 The commercial banking sector was also due to remain, for the six years following the entry into effect of NAFTA, subject to rules imposing narrow limits on foreign ownership of individual banks and on foreign participation in the banking industry as a whole (by the start of the sixth year, the limit on aggregate participation by US and Canadian investors in the banking system would reach 15 percent). Even after that period, safeguards could be invoked to impose new limits on foreign ownership of commercial banks. This safeguard permitted freezing foreign ownership if it were to exceed 25 percent of total capital in the banking system. The original liberalization schedule for this sector, however, had to be accelerated to facilitate the recapitalization of banks after the crisis of 1995. During the following years, a series of legal changes, including the approval in 1999 of the new deposit protection law, finally resulted in the full liberalization of foreign ownership in the commercial banking system. 5 The new foreign investment law of 1993, though preserving limitations on foreign ownership, was more liberal than the 1973 law by adopting the logic that, unless otherwise determined in the law, foreign investors could participate in any proportion in the ownership of Mexican corporations. As of 2002, the exceptions, besides those corresponding to state monopolies, concern largely the following areas: the retail sale of gasoline, passenger transportation by land, credit unions, development banking, and radio and TV other than by cable, which are areas reserved for Mexicans. The law also limits to 49 percent or less the foreign stake in firms operating in the areas of insurance, air transportation, explosives, fishing, and telephony. In other areas, such as private education, sea shipping, and the operation of railroads, airports and maritime ports, foreign investment is allowed to exceed 49 percent with approval by the National Commission for Foreign Investments. To allow a measure of compromise in some of these areas, the 1993 law created the figure of “neutral investment.” Neutral investment 4 Car makers had to generate 80 percent of the foreign exchange they required for their imports. The main beneficiaries of these changes were Spanish. Except for Banamex, recently acquired by Citicorp, and Banorte, still in Mexican hands, all large Mexican banks are owned by Spanish banks. 5 6 is foreign investment in non-voting shares, and it does not count in the computation of the proportion of a firm owned by foreign investors.6 4 3.5 3 Percent of GDP 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 Portugal 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 0 Spain Figure 2. FDI inflows into Spain and Portugal, in percent of GDP Source: World Bank, World Development database. Besides the specific changes in the laws governing foreign investment, the adoption of rules of origin for the determination of the goods that could benefit from the preferences established by the NAFTA also provided new incentives for the location of investments in the NAFTA region, Mexico in particular. Specific rules of origin are based on at least one of the following four principles. A good is considered made in the region if a) it is wholly produced in the region; b) its tariff classification7 is different from that of the imported inputs used in its production; c) it has a minimum regional content measured either by the proportion of costs or by the proportion of the sale price; or d) it contains inputs from outside the region with a cost not exceeding 7 percent of its value. The third criterion varied by product category, and was in some cases subject to change during an initial transition period. For example, for an automobile to benefit from tariff preferences under NAFTA during the first four years of the treaty, more than 50 percent of its net cost had to be represented by regional components; this floor would be raised 6 E. Dussel (2002) observes that information on neutral investment is difficult to obtain, as it is not reported in official statistics as foreign investment. This has given rise to some pressure to eliminate this form of investment by foreigners. 7 Using the harmonized tariff system defined by the Council of Customs Cooperation, based in Brussels. 7 to 56 percent starting in the fifth year of the treaty, and to 62.5 in the ninth year of the treaty. Rules or origin like this one are meant to prevent trade benefits from leaking to goods produced largely outside the region. For this reason, their effects should include an increase in investment in those industries where existing (or prospective) levels of integration were (would have been) below the threshold levels determined by the rules. The lesson from the experiences of other countries entering free trade arrangements is also suggestive of the potential for increased capital inflows. For example, Kehoe and Kehoe (1994b) explain that for Spain one of the key benefits from joining the European Community was a large increase in foreign investment: “For the six years before Spain joined the EC in 1986, that country averaged $1.5 billion per year in foreign investment; in the six years after it joined, Spain averaged $12.8 billion.” It has also been noted that in the early 1980s FDI was equivalent to under 10 percent of gross fixed capital formation excluding construction, and that this proportion rose to over 20 percent in the 1986-1992 period, even though GFCF grew at a real rate of 8 percent during this period (Bajo-Rubio and López-Pueyo, 1997). Portugal also experienced a large increase in capital inflows after joining the EC. During 1986-1991, cumulative net foreign direct investment into Portugal was almost eight times as large as it had been during 19801985. Over two thirds of this capital originated in other EC countries.8 10.0 9.0 8.0 7.0 Percent of total 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 0.0 Figure 3. Combined Share of Spain and Portugal in World FDI Inflows Source: World Bank, World Development database; and UNCTAD, WIR database. 8 World Bank Development Indicators, various years. 8 As Figure 2 shows, there was a veritable boom in FDI into Spain and Portugal starting around 1985; however, the boom was not permanent: by the mid-nineties, the FDI to GDP ratio had returned roughly to the level it had before the accession of these countries to the European Community. Figure 3 indicates that the post 1985 boom in FDI into Spain and Portugal was not just a reflection of international trends, and it suggests that a good proportion of this boom involved a sort of FDI diversion effect, since the percentage of world FDI inflows going to Spain and Portugal rose for a period of six or seven years following their entry into the EC, and then fell back again. Moreover, the monotone decline in these countries’ share in world FDI inflows during the nineties shown in Figure 3 indicates that the recovery of the FDI-GDP ratios in the second half of the 1990s in Portugal and Spain shown in Figure 2 was not an event specific to those to countries, but rather a manifestation or part of the globalization process. Combined, these figures suggest that a stock adjustment process took place after these countries joined the EC, with world investors, as it were, rebalancing their portfolios in favor of Spain and Portugal in a process that lasted several years. The lesson from Spain and Portugal, therefore, was that Mexico should expect a boom in foreign investment following its entry into NAFTA, at least for a period of several years. One possible caveat to the drawing of such a parallel is the difference between the levels of development of Mexico and its NAFTA partners, which was considerably more pronounced than the corresponding difference between Spain and Portugal, on the one hand, and the core countries of the European Community on the other. The larger imbalance in the case of Mexico and NAFTA, especially in the sense that it involved large differences in overall levels of education and in the quality of institutions, could represent a larger obstacle to foreign investment. Moreover, NAFTA, a free-trade area, was from the start more limited in scope than the European Community, which involved a closer integration already in 1986 as a customs union and has continued to evolve toward an even deeper integration since then, including through the unification of labor markets, the coordination of macroeconomic policies, and the adoption of a common currency. The European Community (now the EU) also had a series of compensatory policies in favor of its poorest members, and these policies were complementary to private investment. Perhaps partly as a result of this fact, outward flows of FDI originating in European countries have tended to be directed towards other European nations, a bias not observed to the same extent in other regions.9 These differences relative to the Spanish and Portuguese experiences suggest that Mexico should not have expected to obtain as strong an effect from its own integration process as Portugal and Spain had obtained from theirs (see Berzosa, 2000, and Oyarzún, 2000). Changes in Capital Flows Observed Around the Time of Implementation of NAFTA Although the great instability shown by the external accounts through the 1990s makes data excessively noisy, it is possible to appreciate at least three major changes in capital flows into Mexico: an increase in the volume of net inflows, an increasing weight of private agents as recipients of foreign capital, and the strengthening of foreign direct investment. This constellation of developments is consistent with the expectations of change in capital movements as a result of NAFTA that were discussed previously. 9 This is not to say that FDI inflows in Europe have been predominantly European. According to Segre (1998), prior to 1985 the US was the most dynamic source of investment for most countries in the European Community, and that after 1985 Japan became an increasingly important source. 9 However, there are other possible explanations for some of the changes, as we will discuss later. (For detailed capital flow accounts see Appendix 1.) As Figure 1 illustrates, capital inflows increased following the signing of NAFTA. The capital account reached its maximum of the last twenty years during 1991-1993, when the current account deficit also was at its widest (except for 1994). As we will see shortly, it is likely that a part of this increase in capital inflows responded to the positioning of foreign investors in Mexico in anticipation of the launching of NAFTA, although other reasons for this increase in inflows can be found in the liberalization of domestic financial markets and in the privatization program of the government. That program reached its maximum during 1991-92 with the sale of the phone company, the commercial banks nationalized in 1982, various large steel works and other enterprises. Foreign investors participated actively in most of these operations (the main exception was the sale of banks and of the national phone company, where legal restrictions strongly favored Mexican buyers). Despite the large drop in the capital account of the balance of payments after its high of 1993, and with the possible exception of 1996, during the years following the signing of NAFTA the capital account surplus has hovered significantly above the level observed before negotiations of a free trade agreement started in 1991. 35,000 30,000 25,000 Millions of US dollars 20,000 15,000 10,000 5,000 0 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 -5,000 -10,000 -15,000 Capital Account Consolidated Public Sector Private Sector Foreign Direct Investment Figure 4. Mexico: Main Components of the External Capital Account Source: Banco de México 10 Also the composition of the capital account balance showed important changes since 1991. As Figure 4 shows, the capital account came to be increasingly a reflection of net private inflows, which remained positive even at the height of the crisis in 1995. The behavior of private inflows during the 1990s thus stands in contrast with that observed during the 1990s, when they were negative most of the time. The reverse change seems apparent in public sector flows. These showed limited variation between 1982 and 1990, but then oscillated strongly in the 1990s, with high inflows in 1995 reflecting the international rescue package, and outflows in the second half of the decade when the government pursued fiscal consolidation and repaid the funds received during the 1995 rescue operation. 15,000 Millions of US dollars 10,000 5,000 0 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 -5,000 -10,000 Commercial Banks Loans to Nonbank Agents Foreign Direct Investment Investment in the Stock Exchange Figure 5. Mexico: Main components of Private Capital Flows Source: Banco de México We can divide the study of the effects of the free trade agreement on private flows in two stages, the first of which was a boom in portfolio investment that preceded the entry into effect of NAFTA (Figures 4 and 5). It is possible that one of the reasons for this boom was that some foreign investors sought to buy into Mexican firms positioned to take advantage of the strengthened relationship with the US that could already be anticipated. These flows subsided after 1994. The trajectory of portfolio related flows, however, is likely to have been influenced also by contemporaneous changes that 11 affected Mexico and other countries. We can mention here the privatization program of the government and the renegotiation of Mexico’s sovereign debt under the Brady plan, concluded in 1990 (See World Bank 2002, Appendix 2). Following this renegotiation, the Mexican government started to issue securities in external markets. The correlation between the placement of this type of securities and foreign investment in the Mexican stock market suggests that the latter may have been responding in part to the same effects as the former (Figure 6). 12,000 10,000 8,000 Millions of US dollars 6,000 4,000 2,000 0 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 -2,000 -4,000 Investment in the Stock Exchange Public Securities Issued Abroad Figure 6. Mexico: Some Foreign Capital Flows Received by Public and Private Agents Source: Banco de México An additional piece of evidence, albeit indirect, against the hypothesis that the expectation of NAFTA was a key factor behind the boom in foreign portfolio investment comes from the behavior of the Mexican stock exchange itself. Figure 7 shows the sector-specific stock indexes that comprise the general stock index. Figure 7 presents these indexes deflated by consumer prices and scaled so they all equal 1 in May 1991, when the US Congress granted President Bush fast-track authority for the negotiation of NAFTA. If the anticipation of this agreement had been an important force, we would have expected the manufacturing10 industry index to exhibit aboveaverage growth. However, this was the least dynamic of all sectors, worse even than services and retail and wholesale trade, two essentially nontraded sectors that followed closely the overall performance of the market. (We will look again at the stock market later, to gauge the change in the comovement between US and Mexican stock prices). 10 This is an approximate translation of the original name of this group, the “industria de transformacion.” 12 The second stage in the process of growth of the private external capital account has been dominated by the increase in foreign direct investment. As noted earlier, NAFTA addresses issues of foreign investment explicitly (see Serra Puche 1992 and Borja Tamayo 2001). The regional investment regime established by NAFTA is based on the principle that each one of the NAFTA countries should give “national treatment” to firms from the other NAFTA countries. This principle is supplemented by the adoption of the “most favored nation” clause. This way, NAFTA residents are entitled to the best treatment available in each one of the NAFTA countries. The agreement also reduced or eliminated existing limits on foreign ownership of Mexican firms, and prohibited the imposition of certain performance requirements on foreign investors (such as export quotas). All of these factors tended to promote intraregional investment. However, at least in the case of Mexico, the agreement also seems to have improved the investment environment for firms headquartered outside the NAFTA region. One of the most contentious issues during the negotiation of the agreement was the definition of rules of origin, which determine under which conditions a producer, possibly owned by a resident of a third country, can take advantage of the benefits established in NAFTA. These rules were chiefly meant to prevent Mexico from becoming a cheap platform for exports into the United States originating in third countries. In the end, these rules act as an encouragement for firms coming from outside North America to establish substantial operations in the NAFTA region if they wish to take advantage of the free trade agreement. 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 General Index Wholesale & Retail Mining Comm. & Transport Manufactures Services Oct-1994 Jul-1994 Abr-1994 Ene-1994 Oct-1993 Jul-1993 Abr-1993 Ene-1993 Oct-1992 Jul-1992 Abr-1992 Ene-1992 Oct-1991 Jul-1991 Abr-1991 Ene-1991 Oct-1990 Jul-1990 Abr-1990 Ene-1990 0.0 Construction Other Figure 7. Mexico: CPI-Deflated Sector-Specific Stock Price Indexes (May 1991 = 1) Source: Infosel 13 The empirical evidence tends to confirm the expectation of increased foreign direct investment flows following NAFTA. Figure 5 indicates that FDI, which was slowly improving through the second half of the eighties, shows two distinct jumps. The first one, still modest, took place in 1991, and was again probably associated with the prospect of an agreement. FDI then plateaus and even trends slightly downward until the effective implementation of the agreement. Then, the second jump occurs in 1994, and FDI remains high even during the critical 1995-96 period. Table 1. Mexico: FDI originating inside and outside North America before and after NAFTA went into effect 1989-1993 1994-Sep 2001 From North America In millions of US dollars Annual Average In percent of total 13,860 2,772 60.7 64,764 8,096 71.2 From Other Regions In millions of US dollars Annual Average In percent of total 8,967 1,793 39.3 26,228 3,279 28.8 Sources: period 1989-1993, Borja Tamayo 2001, Table 3; period 1994-2001, Dirección nacional de Inversiones Extranjeras. The significant increase in the volume of FDI in Mexico after NAFTA went into effect and the growing dominance of North American investment in Mexico are reflected in Table 1, an updated version of a table appearing in Borja Tamayo (2001). However, as it is shown by the change in the annual average inflows reported in that table, other regions of the world did increase their investment in Mexico following the entry into effect of NAFTA. This stands in contrast with the results reported for Canada by Borja Tamayo (2001). That author notes that NAFTA meant a swelling of North American FDI in Canada, but had virtually no effect on FDI originating outside the region. A more detailed analysis of FDI in Mexico by country of origin is presented in Table 2. In that table we can see that two thirds of FDI in Mexico has come from the United States during the time NAFTA been in effect. The share of American capital in FDI has been significantly above average during 2000-2001. In 2001 especially American FDI was boosted by the acquisition of Banamex by Citigroup. Conversely, except for the period 2000-September 2001, the European Union increased its share in total foreign direct investment in Mexico since NAFTA went into effect. However, it is not possible to discern a clearly increasing trend in European investments as we would expect to see in the run up to the signing of the free trade agreement between Mexico and the European Union in 2000. Investments of Japanese origin occupy a very distant third place and show considerable volatility. 14 Table 2. Mexico: Inward Foreign Direct Investment by Place of Origin Jan.-Sep. Cumulative 2001 '94-sep '01 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 In millions of US dollars Total 10,632 8,227 7,689 11,927 7,784 12,165 13,665 18,903 90,992 North America United States Canada European Union Japan Switzerland India Cayman Islands South Corea Netherlands Antilles Other 5,564 5,394 170 1,827 156 200 51 29 104 70 226 5,694 5,178 516 1,128 139 80 286 49 86 63 164 7,517 7,281 236 3,140 350 29 29 330 191 9 332 5,287 5,106 181 1,991 99 19 0 106 50 6 226 7,320 6,747 573 3,151 1,231 106 0 90 44 3 220 11,170 10,623 547 1,605 416 101 27 97 20 17 212 16,518 15,989 529 1,945 62 63 -1 60 18 22 216 64,764 61,271 3,493 16,721 3,084 652 1,611 854 528 659 2,119 Growth rates Total -22.6 -6.5 55.1 -34.7 56.3 12.3 n.a. North America United States Canada European Union Japan Switzerland India Cayman Islands South Corea Netherlands Antilles Other -2.3 8.9 -77.1 -5.5 -75.3 270.4 -95.8 -68.8 593.3 -85.1 -56.8 2.3 -4.0 203.5 -38.3 -10.9 -60.0 460.8 69.0 -17.3 -10.0 -27.4 32.0 40.6 -54.3 178.4 151.8 -63.8 -89.9 573.5 122.1 -85.7 102.4 -29.7 -29.9 -23.3 -36.6 -71.7 -34.5 -100.0 -67.9 -73.8 -33.3 -31.9 38.5 32.1 216.6 58.3 1,143.4 457.9 n.a. -15.1 -12.0 -50.0 -2.7 52.6 57.4 -4.5 -49.1 -66.2 -4.7 n.a. 7.8 -54.5 466.7 -3.6 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 North America 53.6 67.6 74.1 63.0 67.9 United States 46.6 65.6 67.3 61.0 65.6 Canada 7.0 2.1 6.7 2.0 2.3 European Union 18.2 22.2 14.7 26.3 25.6 Japan 5.9 1.9 1.8 2.9 1.3 Switzerland 0.5 2.4 1.0 0.2 0.2 India 11.5 0.6 3.7 0.2 0.0 Cayman Islands 0.9 0.4 0.6 2.8 1.4 South Corea 0.1 1.3 1.1 1.6 0.6 Netherlands Antilles 4.4 0.9 0.8 0.1 0.1 Other 4.9 2.7 2.1 2.8 2.9 Source: Dirección Nacional de Inversiones Extranjeras and author´s calculations 60.2 55.5 4.7 25.9 10.1 0.9 0.0 0.7 0.4 0.0 1.8 81.7 77.7 4.0 11.7 3.0 0.7 0.2 0.7 0.1 0.1 1.6 87.4 84.6 2.8 10.3 0.3 0.3 0.0 0.3 0.1 0.1 1.1 71.2 67.3 3.8 18.4 3.4 0.7 1.8 0.9 0.6 0.7 2.3 Shares in total Total 5,694 4,953 741 1,934 631 54 1,219 93 15 469 523 100.0 Other Factors that Contributed to the Observed Changes in Capital Flows Were the trends described in the previous section in any way typical of the times, or did they distinguish Mexico from other countries? In this section we will discuss other wellknown forces that, besides NAFTA, lie behind the behavior of capital flows into Mexico during the 1990s. We focus our attention on globalization and on the Mexican banking crisis. 15 Global trends Essentially, no developing country received significant amounts of foreign portfolio investment before 1989. But starting in 1989, and especially since 1991, portfolio investment into many developing economies grew dramatically. As Figure 8 illustrates, in this trend Mexico (shown by the heavy line) had a leading role during the years of negotiation of the free trade agreement. In 1993 alone, Mexico received US$14 billion in this type of investment. In that chart, the flows into a group of emerging economies from different regions show that portfolio flows became important during the 1990s. But these inflows exhibit the most explosive growth in the case of Mexico before 1994. By the second half of the past decade, however, Mexico seemed to have ceased being a prime destination of portfolio investment. 16,000 14,000 12,000 Millions of US dollars 10,000 8,000 6,000 4,000 2,000 0 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 -2,000 Argentina Brazil Chile Hungary Korea, Rep. Malaysia Mexico Peru Poland Thailand Figure 8. Portfolio Equity Flows into Selected Countries Source: World Bank FDI flows into developing countries have a longer history than portfolio flows; but in this case too the overall trend during the 1990s was one of growth, as Figure 9 illustrates. Once more, however, Mexico –represented in that chart by the heavy line— seems to have been running ahead of many other emerging market countries. This is particularly clear starting in 1994, when Mexico-bound FDI jumps up. This discrete change in the behavior of FDI in Mexico contrasts with the gradual increase seen in the flows going elsewhere. Nevertheless, as in the case of portfolio flows, other countries 16 have eventually overtaken Mexico as recipients of FDI. In particular, the main Mercosur partners, Brazil and Argentina, became important destinations for foreign investment in the last years of the 1990s. Part of the apparent switch in the places of Mexico and Brazil or Argentina as recipients of FDI reflects the timing of privatization activity. By 1994, Mexico was essentially finished with its main privatizations (those of the phone company and the banking system), whereas privatization activity remained important in Brazil and Argentina well after that. Not only timing was important; it was also a matter of volume, as the Mexican privatization program, important as it was, was considerably smaller than the Brazilian and even the Argentine ones. In particular, the Argentine government sold its remaining stake in the national oil company to Repsol of Spain in 1999 in an operation worth over US$15 billion. Besides selling some electric utilities, Brazil auctioned off numerous licenses for the operation of long distance carriers and mobile telecommunications companies in 1998, which explains a large proportion of the high level of FDI experienced by that country in 1998-1999. 35,000 30,000 25,000 Millions of US dollars 20,000 15,000 10,000 5,000 0 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 -5,000 Argentina Brazil Chile Hungary Korea, Rep. Malaysia Mexico Peru Poland Thailand Figure 9. FDI inflows into Selected Countries Source: World Bank 17 Table 3. Inward Flows of FDI by Receiving Region Average 1990-91 Average 1992-93 Average 1994-95 Average 1996-97 Average 1998-99 2000 Average 1996-2000 World 180.8 188.0 270.3 428.0 884.0 1,271.0 779 Developed countries Developing Countries 141.9 37.5 121.7 61.8 168.0 93.3 245.6 166.0 656.5 205.0 1,005.2 240.0 562 196 South, East and Southeast Asia China Hong Kong South Korea Other 20.3 3.9 1.1 1.0 14.2 36.8 19.3 1.9 0.7 15.0 59.3 35.6 2.1 1.2 20.5 93.5 42.0 11.0 2.5 38.0 91.0 42.0 20.0 8.0 21.0 137.0 41.0 64.0 10.0 22.0 101 42 25 6 28 Latin America Argentina Brazil Mexico Other 12.1 2.1 1.0 3.6 5.3 18.6 5.2 1.7 4.4 7.3 25.9 2.6 4.0 7.5 11.9 58.5 8.1 14.9 11.4 24.2 96.5 15.7 30.0 11.8 39.1 86.0 11.2 33.5 13.2 28.1 79 12 25 12 31 Other Developing Areas 5.1 6.4 8.1 14.0 17.5 17.0 16 Central and Eastern Europe 1.4 4.6 9.0 16.4 22.5 25.8 21 World 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 Developed Countries Developing Countries 78.5 20.8 64.7 32.8 62.1 34.5 57.4 38.8 74.3 23.2 79.1 18.9 72.1 25.2 11.2 2.2 0.6 0.5 7.9 19.6 10.3 1.0 0.3 8.0 21.9 13.2 0.8 0.4 7.6 21.8 9.8 2.6 0.6 8.9 10.3 4.8 2.3 0.9 2.4 10.8 3.2 5.0 0.8 1.7 13.0 5.4 3.2 0.8 3.6 Latin America Argentina Brazil Mexico Other 6.7 1.2 0.6 2.0 2.9 9.9 2.8 0.9 2.3 3.9 9.6 0.9 1.5 2.8 4.4 13.7 1.9 3.5 2.7 5.6 10.9 1.8 3.4 1.3 4.4 6.8 0.9 2.6 1.0 2.2 10.2 1.5 3.2 1.5 4.0 Other Developing Areas 2.8 3.4 3.0 3.3 2.0 1.3 2.1 Central and Eastern Europe 0.8 2.5 3.3 3.8 2.5 2.0 2.7 Shares in FDI Received by Developing Regions Developing Countries 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 In Billions of US Dollars Shares in Total FDI South, East and Southeast Asia China Hong Kong South Korea Other South, East and Southeast Asia China Hong Kong South Korea Other 54.1 10.5 3.0 2.6 38.0 59.6 31.3 3.0 1.1 24.2 63.6 38.2 2.2 1.2 21.9 56.3 25.3 6.6 1.5 22.9 44.4 20.5 9.8 3.9 10.2 57.1 17.1 26.7 4.2 9.2 51.5 21.3 12.8 3.2 14.3 Latin America Argentina Brazil Mexico Other 32.3 5.7 2.8 9.7 14.1 30.1 8.5 2.7 7.1 11.8 27.8 2.7 4.2 8.0 12.8 35.2 4.9 8.9 6.9 14.5 47.1 7.7 14.6 5.7 19.1 35.8 4.7 14.0 5.5 11.7 40.3 6.0 12.5 6.1 15.7 Other Developing Areas 13.6 10.3 8.7 8.4 8.5 7.1 8.1 Source: UNCTAD World Investment Reports 1995, 2000 and 2001 and authors' calculations. 18 The growth of FDI in developing countries, however, has lagged behind the growth of FDI in advanced economies in recent times. Table 3 shows that, after rising dramatically in the early nineties, the share of FDI going to developing economies has fallen back to levels not seen since the second half of the nineties. This shrinkage masks important changes in the destination of FDI inside the developing world. Thus, Hong Kong and Brazil have become key recipients of FDI, while most other developing regions have seen their participation in FDI flows fall in the last years of the past decade. In particular, Mexico’s share in global FDI seemed to rise first in the run-up to NAFTA (which coincided with the height of privatization program, as we have observed), then to reach its maximum during the initial years of NAFTA, when it reached a level of 2.8 percent, only to fall back to under 1.5 percent after 1997. (Despite its visibility, India’s share of FDI remains small enough that it does not enter Table 3.) 70.0 60.0 50.0 Percent 40.0 30.0 20.0 10.0 0.0 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 -10.0 Canada Europe Mexico Asia and Pacific Latin America w/o Mexico Figure 10. US Investment Abroad by Receiving Region Source: US Department of Commerce Even Mexico’s share of American investment abroad is small, as inspection of Figure 10 shows (as usual, Mexico is represented by the heavy line). This share jumped up in 2001 due to the Banamex transaction, but it is not clear that the share will stay at its 2001 high. In that sense, what seems more remarkable is the stability of the Mexican share of US investment abroad since the late 1980s. Throughout the nineties, the US stepped up and stabilized the proportion of its investment going to Europe and Canada, left the share going to Asia more or less unchanged, and dramatically reduced the share of its external investment that went to Latin America. In that regard, it appears that NAFTA prevented the repetition of this trend in the case of investment in Mexico. 19 Table 4. Mergers and Acquisitions (Sales) and Greenfield FDI Inflows 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Average 1995-2000 227 305 532 766 1,144 527 165 16 189 35 235 65 445 81 681 74 1,057 70 462 57 South, East and Southeast Asia China Hong Kong South Korea Other 6 0 2 0 4 10 2 3 1 4 19 2 7 1 9 16 1 1 4 10 28 2 4 10 12 21 2 5 6 8 17 2 4 4 8 Latin America Argentina Brazil Mexico Other 9 2 2 1 4 21 4 7 1 9 41 5 12 8 16 64 10 29 3 21 42 19 9 1 12 45 5 23 4 13 37 8 14 3 13 Other Developing Areas 1 4 5 1 3 3 3 Central and Eastern Europe 6 4 6 6 11 17 8 World 59.2 60.1 63.8 76.7 71.3 90.0 70 Developed countries Developing Countries 81.0 16.0 85.9 23.9 86.5 34.5 92.1 43.0 82.1 33.2 105.2 29.0 89 30 South, East and Southeast Asia China Hong Kong South Korea Other 9.7 1.1 81.1 12.8 16.6 11.1 4.8 29.7 28.2 11.5 18.8 4.2 66.6 27.9 20.9 18.4 1.8 6.3 79.5 46.1 29.6 6.0 16.7 91.5 59.0 15.4 5.5 7.5 64.5 34.6 17 4 35 51 31 Latin America Argentina Brazil Mexico Other 32.5 47.9 36.2 10.3 39.6 44.6 51.6 59.4 15.9 47.0 57.9 50.4 64.5 57.4 56.2 77.0 142.4 103.1 25.9 59.4 38.1 80.5 29.8 7.2 29.0 52.6 47.1 68.7 30.0 46.2 50 70 60 24 46 Other Developing Areas 13.0 40.4 28.7 5.2 20.0 19.6 21 Central and Eastern Europe 49.9 27.3 28.2 26.4 48.7 65.6 41 Estimated Greenfield FDI (FDI Inflows minus M&A Sales, in billions of US dollars) 128 151 173 161 309 127 175 1995 World Mergers and Acquisitions (billions of US dollars) 187 Developed countries Developing Countries M&A as a Percent of FDI Inflows World Developed countries Developing Countries 39 84 31 110 37 122 38 107 149 148 -52 170 40 124 South, East and Southeast Asia China Hong Kong South Korea Other 59 37 0 1 20 78 38 8 1 31 80 42 4 2 32 70 43 14 1 12 68 38 21 1 8 116 39 59 4 14 79 39 18 2 20 Latin America Argentina Brazil Mexico Other 18 2 3 6 7 25 3 4 8 10 30 5 7 6 13 19 -3 -1 9 14 68 5 22 11 30 41 6 10 9 15 34 3 8 8 15 7 7 12 18 13 14 12 16 12 9 11 Other Developing Areas Central and Eastern Europe 6 10 14 Source: UNCTAD World Investment Reports 2000 and 2001 and authors' calculations. 20 One of the reasons that Mexico’s participation in the flow of FDI appears to be relatively lower than one might expect is the combination of two factors: the increasing importance of mergers and acquisitions (M&A) in the global flows of FDI, and the relative bias towards greenfield FDI in Mexico.11 Table 4 presents information from UNCTAD on M&A sales by region and country. The table also presents estimates of Greenfield FDI obtained by subtracting M&A from net inflows of FDI. This estimation is only approximate, because, due to methodological problems, reported M&A sales activity is not strictly a subset of FDI inflows. Table 4 shows that M&A activity has been growing faster than overall FDI, as noted by the increasing proportion of FDI accounted for by M&A. In contrast, the bottom panel shows that Greenfield FDA has been relatively stagnant, displaying an inverted U shape interrupted by the year 1999, which looks like an outlier. M&A activity has been highly important in developed countries through the entire period covered in table 4. Among developing countries, M&A operations seem to have been most important in Latin America, and especially in Brazil and Argentina. This is in large part a reflection of privatization activity in those countries, as we explained above. For our purposes, the most remarkable piece of information from Table 4 is the very limited role of M&A activity in Mexico for most of this period. In every one of the years covered in the table, M&A is a smaller proportion of total FDI inflows in Mexico than in Latin America as a whole -- and much lower than in Brazil in particular. In four of the six years covered, and on the entire period, the proportion of M&A in Mexico is lower than it was for the average developing country. When discussing Table 3, we had remarked that Mexico’s share in global FDI inflows had been falling during the second half of the nineties. Now Table 4 makes clear that this was due to the fact that Mexico was not participating of the growth in M&A activity. In fact, using the information in the bottom panel of Table 4 we can see that Mexico’s share in total greenfield FDI shows no discernible trend, oscillating around a mean of 4.6 percent and in fact, climbing as high as 7.3 percent of world greenfield FDI in 2000. Finally, Table 5 shows FDI as a ratio of gross capital formation. From our previous discussion, it is clear that we do not mean to imply that all (and not even most) FDI are reflected in new physical investments. Table 5 is just mean to compare FDI with a reasonable metric, in this case capital formation. Now, what this table indicates is that the importance of FDI relative to investment increased during the second half of the1990s throughout the world.12 While this tendency was truly global, it seemed more pronounced in the advanced economies and in Hong Kong. Mexico did participate in it, as is especially apparent for the years 1996-97, but it was by no means an exceptional case. Once again this is a reflection of Mexico’s declining share in global FDI inflows. All the same, it should be noted that the high level shown by the ratio of FDI to capital formation in Mexico during 1985-1995 could reflect in part the large privatizations that took place during the Salinas administration. 11 As their names indicate, greenfield and M&A forms of foreign investment are different in their immediate economic effects, with the first one implying the actual formation of capital and the second involving the transfer to foreign investors of ownership over existing corporations. See Calderón, Loayza and Servén (2002). 12 In Table 5, we have grouped together Central European countries with the developed economies, which tends to exaggerate the apparent rise in this ratio for that group of countries. But this is not relevant to the comparison among Mexico, the world, and developing nations. 21 Table 5. Inward Flows of FDI as Percentages of Gross Fixed Capital Formation, by Receiving Region Average 1985-1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 Average 1996-1999 World 4.0 5.9 7.5 10.9 16.3 10.2 Developed countries Developing Countries 3.8 4.7 4.8 9.1 6.2 10.9 10.6 11.7 17.1 13.8 9.7 11.4 South, East and Southeast Asia China Hong Kong South Korea Other 6.0 6.4 18.9 0.9 7.2 9.1 14.3 21.7 1.2 7.4 9.8 14.6 19.8 1.8 8.4 10.5 12.9 29.9 5.5 6.5 11.2 11.3 60.2 9.3 5.8 10.2 13.3 32.9 4.5 7.1 Latin America Argentina Brazil Mexico Other 5.7 7.5 2.1 10.5 6.4 12.3 13.2 7.0 15.5 18.0 15.9 15.4 11.7 17.7 19.8 17.6 11.0 18.4 13.2 22.0 27.3 47.7 31.3 11.7 28.5 18.3 21.8 17.1 14.5 22.0 1.9 4.4 6.6 6.0 4.6 5.4 Other Developing Areas Source: UNCTAD World Investment Reports 2000 and 2001 and authors' calculations. Events affecting the domestic banking system The nature of external borrowing changed during the 1990s, as we saw earlier with the aid of Figure 3. Private nonbank agents had been net repayers of external debt during the 1980s, but starting in 1990 they became net takers of foreign loans. This behavior became entrenched as the decade progressed, to the extent that direct foreign borrowing by nonbank agents became the second largest source of external capital starting in 1998. These developments stand in contrast with the shrinking role of banks in the intermediation of foreign capital associated with the onset of the banking crisis in 1995. To understand them, it is useful briefly to recall some of the main events in the banking system in the 1990s. The first half of the 1990s produced a strengthening of the role of the domestic banks in the market for private credit. Since the beginning of the 1990s a process of liberalization took place in the banking industry, including the privatization of commercial banks and the elimination of mandatory reserve requirements and directed credit.13 At the same time, the net debt of the public sector to the banking system shrank dramatically from the equivalent of 20.9 percent of GDP in 1989 to about 5.5 percent of GDP in 1994, in large part as a consequence of the government’s privatization revenues, fiscal adjustment, and debt management strategy. As noted earlier, this strategy included the issue of securities abroad following the Brady renegotiation, and some of the funds thus borrowed were used to reduce public indebtedness to domestic banks. In addition, as Figure 3 shows, commercial banks borrowed substantial amounts abroad over the 19891994 period. All of these convergent processes, along with the liberalization of financial markets in Mexico, produced a major enhancement in the intermediation of 13 Morley et al (1999) have developed a financial liberalization index running from zero to 1. On this scale, Mexico went from 0.609 in 1988 to 0.99 by 1990. 22 resources of foreign origin by commercial banks in the first half of the 1990s. The counterpart of these forces was the increase in domestic bank credit to the private nonbank sector. Thus, between 1989 and 1995, the private sector went from being a creditor of the banking system (with a net position of 4 percent of GDP) to being a net debtor of the banks (with a net position of –4.5 percent of GDP).14 This change in the balance sheets of the banks made them increasingly vulnerable to the type of shocks that rocked the economy in 1994. By then, the banks’ balance sheets seemed to be well hedged in terms of the currencies in which assets and liabilities were denominated. However, some “foreign-currency denominated assets” were in reality loans to domestic firms with no significant source of foreign-currency income and complex securities such as the exotic derivatives discussed by Garber and Lall (1996), which carried foreign exchange risks.15 The currency and financial crisis that broke out at the end of 1994 led a large number of debtors to stop servicing their loans to the banking system. The proportion of nonperforming to current loans went from 9.8 percent at end-1994 to 28.5 by end-1995. Starting in 1995, the government pursued a strategy to prevent a systemic crisis that included the extension of full deposit guarantees; a debtor support program featuring restructurings involving the redenomination of loans in indexed units; enhanced supervision, accompanied by bank interventions and liquidations; the acceleration of the liberalization of the rules governing foreign ownership of banks; the exchange of bonds issued by the deposit insurance agency (FOBAPROA) for nonperforming bank loans subject to the condition that bank owners should contribute to recapitalize their banks;the temporary capitalization of banks through the purchase by FOBAPROA of subordinated, convertible bonds issued by banks with low capital/asset ratios; and a dollar liquidity facility for those banks with high levels of foreign currency liabilities (which was not a major problem, since preexisting regulations had succeeded in limiting the extent of foreign currency risk taken on by banks). As a result of this strategy, the banks ended up with very large quantities of FOBAPROA bonds in their portfolios and became dependent on these assets.16 Bank credit to the private sector never recovered from that crisis. Commercial banks’ assets fell from 39 percent of GDP in 1995 to only 25 percent in 1999, a proportion lower than the Latin American average, as Gonzalez Anaya and Marrufo (2001) have observed. Credit to the private sector was a decreasing slice of this dwindling pie: Serrano (2001) estimates that commercial bank credit to the private sector shrank from 25 percent of GDP in 1996 to 6.6 percent in 2000, and that by mid 2001, virtually one half of the bank loans in good standing were owed by the public sector, including the government and the deposit insurance agency. As a consequence of the collapse in bank credit to the private sector, private agents have had to look for new sources of finance, including direct external borrowing and suppliers loans. Thus, the collapse of domestic bank credit has doubtless led to an increase in demand for external credit by Mexican residents which contributes to explain the behavior of external capital flows (especially direct external borrowing) that we have described above. However, it would be virtually impossible to quantify the exact influence of these demand factors on the evolution of the external capital account. 14 For an account of this period, see Hernández and Villagómez 2001. By the close of 1994, the depreciation of the currency caused this part of the banks’ loan portfolio to balloon to over 40 percent of the total. 16 See Banco de Mexico 1996. 15 23 A statistical look at the importance of regional trade agreements, with an application to Mexico In the first two parts of this section this section we use regression techniques to look at the influence of membership in a free-trade area on foreign direct investment, and then use our estimates to try to gauge the relative contribution of regional integration, globalization, and other factors to the evolution of FDI in Mexico. The most straightforward results we obtain are that joining a free trade area will generally help promote FDI, and that this has indeed been the case in Mexico. Looking at the Mexican case more closely, however, three tentative conclusions can be drawn. Firstly, NAFTA and the rest of the trade agreements signed by Mexico seem to have led to an increase of between 40 and 70 percent in FDI relative to what it would have been on a counterfactual scenario without trade agreements. Secondly, globalization seems to have made a larger contribution to the growth of FDI in Mexico than NAFTA. And third, in the latter half of the nineties Mexico received less FDI than our models would have led us to expect. This disappointing performance of foreign investment may well be related to the slow progress in some structural reform areas experienced since approximately 1997. In the last part of the section we take a look at stock market data from the US and Mexico in search of evidence of increasing co-movement between stock prices since NAFTA went into effect. The conclusion from that section is that movements in Mexico’s stock price data seem to be increasingly explained by the evolution of American stock prices, a result consistent with the deeper integration of financial markets in the region. Panel Regressions of FDI Our approach in estimating regressions is similar to that of Levy-Yeyati, Stein and Daude (2001), who fitted a gravity model to bilateral FDI flows data. In their basic model, the stock of direct investments by residents of country A in country B depends on gravitational factors represented by the gross domestic products of the two countries and geographic distance, and on dummies for common membership in a free trade area and common language, which attempt to measure reductions in economic distance. In addition, they include two variables measuring “extended market effects.” The first one, expected to make investment in B more attractive, is the sum of the gross domestic products of all countries that have free trade agreements with B. The second extended market variable is the sum of all the gross domestic products of countries that have free trade agreements with A. This last variable, therefore, represents the menu of options open to investors residing in country A, and its growth is expected to divert investment away from country B. This model yields results supporting the idea that regional integration and membership in a free trade area promote bilateral FDI. We estimate a model to explain the behavior of total (net) inflows of FDI into each country, rather than bilateral stocks, and so we must construct our extended market variables differently. Also, we include some indicators of macroeconomic stability and a direct measure of the globalization process. The data set we use is a panel of 45 countries with observations over the period 1980-1999 (the list of countries constitutes Appendix 2). The free trade areas we considered for the construction of these variables are largely the same blocks studied by Frankel and Wei (1998). These are ASEAN, EFTA, what today is the EU, NAFTA, the Group of Three, the Andean Group in its 24 recent revival, Mercosur, and COMESA. In this regard, we considered joining the EU from EFTA a jump in the FTAMEM variable, and did only considered COMESA’s upcoming upgrading as a free trade area for the construction of EXFTAMEM. Our dependent variable is total net inflows of FDI into a country measured in constant (1995) dollars. We run the regressions in logarithms to aid interpretation, but we will have the occasion to revert to levels to illustrate the implications of our results for Mexico. The list of right-hand side variables includes two dummy indicators of participation in free trade agreements. FTAMEM is a dummy taking on a value of 1 if the country was officially a member of a free trade area in a given year. EXFTAMEM, representing the expectation of joining a free-trade area, takes on a value of 1 during the two years preceding the country’s entry into a free trade area.17 In addition, we constructed extended market variables to capture the positive and negative effects of integration on FDI mentioned above. FTAGDP is the sum of the gross domestic products of all countries with which a given (“index”) country has free trade agreements and the GDP of the index country itself (PARTNERGDP excludes this last quantity). For the investment diversion effect we constructed an overall measure of integration, INTEGRATION. This is a weighted sum of the gross domestic products of all countries in the sample which belong to a free trade arrangement. The weights are the proportion of total sample GDP covered by its trade agreements. Thus, Chile’s GDP is already included in this measure; but if it reaches and agreement with the US, its coefficient in the sum will rise. Eventually, if all countries in the sample signed free trade agreements with one another, INTEGRATION would equal the value of aggregate sample GDP. At a particular country, if it has a constant level of FTAGDP, an increase in INTEGRATION would signal stronger competition from other countries. This should, ceteris paribus, make the focus country less attractive for global investors. 18 Therefore, we expect the coefficients of the free-trade dummies and of FTAGDP to be positive, and that of INTEGRATION to be negative.19 As noted earlier in this paper, the bulk of FDI flows among rich countries, and we wanted to measure this effect. The variable we used, RELGNIPH, is a measure of how well off a citizen of a country is, regardless of how big that country’s economy may be. This variable is the ratio of a country’s PPP-adjusted per capita gross national income to that of the United States. So, if GDP captures the size of an economy, RELGNIPH measures the prosperity of its citizens relative to that of their American contemporaries. Our earlier discussion leads us to expect that this variable will have a positive coefficient. Size itself, measured by both GDP and exports (which also captures the outward orientation of an economy), should have a positive impact on FDI inflows. 17 We tried several variations on the form of this variable, such as using 1-and 3-year lengths for the anticipation period (instead of 2), and using leads of partner GDP instead of dummy variables. These changes don’t affect the overall fit of the regressions nor the estimated coefficients of the other variables in any major way. The various representations of the expectation of an upcoming FTA are significant in most cases. Appendix 3 shows regression 2 from Table 6 along with similar regressions where the expectations variable is measured in the several ways we have explained in this footnote. 18 In principle, this variable should be able to handle some cases that might give trouble to the investment diversion variable in the model of Levy-Yeyati et al (2001). That model has trouble capturing the adverse competitive effects that might arise among third-party countries. For example, when Brazil joined Argentina in Mercosur in 1991, they became more attractive to third party-investors who might also have been considering investing in other countries in the region (say, Chile). Our variable would show no change in Chile’s FTAGDP, while reporting an increase in INTEGGDP. 19 All variables with a monetary dimension, such as FTAGDP and others that will be mentioned below, are measured in constant dollars and then expressed in natural logs. 25 The rest of the explanatory variables in our regressions are controls. Many of these variables are meant to capture important elements of the investment environment such as macroeconomic stability and good economic policy management. This is the case of the external current account balance (CURRENT) and the budget surplus (BUDGETBAL), both measured in percent of GDP, and of consumer price inflation and real growth of output (GDPGRWTH). As controls for the state of the world in any given year we use the rate of real growth in global output, WORLDGRTH, and the level of the one-year treasury bill rate in the US. This variable can also be viewed as a measure of the opportunity cost of investing. The key scale variable is the aggregate level of inward foreign direct investment flows in the world, FDIWORLD. This variable serves as control for the increasingly important globalization forces. The regressions were estimated using a fixed-effects model. Fixed effects techniques are standard for this type of setting, and seem better advised than the random effects model because they do not rely on the assumption of the lack of correlation between the identity of the country (i.e., the “random” effects) and the explanatory variables (Greene, 1990). The first set of regressions is reported in Table 6, where each one of the numbered columns represents a variant of our estimated model. Our preferred specification is that of the second column, where we have avoided the redundancy between FTAMEM and FTAGDP observed in the first column. The sign of FTAMEM in that first column is in fact contrary to expectations; but it is not significant. The third and fourth columns show variants of columns one and two where we have replaced FTAGDP with PARTNERGDP. The bottom panel of the table indicates that all regressions have reasonably good fit for a panel data set. The coefficients of the variables measuring different aspects of the free-trade dimension, which are the main focus of our attention, strongly support the notion that entering a regional trade block should lead to higher FDI inflows. All regressions confirm that the expectation of joining a free trade area has a positive impact on foreign investment. In no regression is the coefficient of this variable lower than one third, indicating that announcing an imminent entry into a larger regional market raises investment by that proportion, and it is significant in all. The fact that the free trade area dummy has a statistically insignificant coefficient is a reflection of the inclusion of a more direct measure of integration in the form of FTAGDP. The elasticity of foreign investment with respect to this extended market variable is approximately between one tenth and one seventh, which is not necessarily low when we consider the fact that joining a free trade area produces a discrete hike in the value of FTAGDP. If a country joins a free trade area five times as large as the country itself, it can expect FDI inflows to rise by one half or more. The only surprise is the absence of an investment diversion effect. INTEGRATION has positive but insignificant coefficients. This may be due to the fact that this variable has no inter-country variability, and thus cannot capture all of the competitive effects that are suffered by individual countries. 26 Table 6. Fixed-Effects Regressions of the Ln of FDI Against Membership in a Free Trade Area and Other Variables (t-stats under each coefficient) Variable \ Model FTAMEM 1 2 -0.254 -1.160 EXFTAMEM RELGNIPH 0.332 1.667 3 4 0.038 0.175 0.406 2.153 0.360 1.799 0.348 1.845 -1.959 -1.752 -1.940 -1.966 -1.634 -1.477 -1.612 -1.646 0.034 2.961 0.033 2.881 0.032 2.808 0.032 2.827 INFLATION 0.000 -1.168 0.000 -1.337 0.000 -1.546 -0.001 -1.540 BUDGETBAL -0.033 -2.252 -0.031 -2.159 -0.033 -2.237 -0.330 -2.286 CURRACCT -0.040 -3.679 -0.400 -3.691 -0.041 -3.767 -0.041 -3.766 WRLDGRWTH -0.084 -2.038 -0.081 -1.967 -0.083 -2.002 -0.083 -2.019 US1YTBILL 0.004 0.207 0.006 0.287 0.004 0.188 0.004 0.179 EXPORTS 0.723 3.298 0.690 3.174 0.719 3.268 0.724 3.329 FDIWORLD 0.774 6.668 0.770 6.629 0.794 6.821 0.795 6.844 GDP 0.243 1.006 0.280 1.170 0.353 1.490 0.353 1.490 FTAGDP 0.159 2.200 0.102 1.920 0.003 0.218 0.005 0.456 GDPGRWTH PARTNERGDP INTEGRATION 0.170 1.202 0.173 1.230 0.182 1.288 0.182 1.285 -16.209 -8.548 -15.780 -8.483 -15.947 -8.389 -15.989 -8.484 0.474 0.662 0.579 0.473 0.679 0.591 0.471 0.651 0.572 0.470 0.650 0.571 F test regressors DF 46.84 14, 728 50.32 13, 729 46.200 14, 728 49.810 13, 729 F test country effects DF 14.39 44, 728 15.03 44, 729 14.03 44, 728 14.33 13, 729 0.013 0.304 0.01 0.215 0.005 0.121 0.006 0.130 787 787 787 787 CONSTANT R-sq: within between overall GDPGRWTH Endogeneity F-equivalent t-stat Number of observations 27 The negative sign of the coefficient of RELGNIPH seems to contradict our expectation that richer countries are the preferred destination of FDI. Although the coefficient is not significantly different from zero at the 5 percent significance level, it is right at the threshold for rejecting a one-sided test on its being positive. This suggests that in a broad sense, being rich is really a summary of other characteristics that make a country attractive to investors, such as having a relatively stable economic environment or an educated labor force, and that once we control for them, the simple fact of being rich ceases to be a factor that attracts investment. Globalization forces have the right sign and are significant; in fact, FDIWRLD is one of the key determinants of net FDI inflows into any given country in any given year, and the elasticity of the latter with respect to the former is almost 0.8 in all regressions.20 Similarly, the elasticity of FDI inflows with respect to exports is about 0.7 in all models. While this is consistent with our expectations, it is possible to wonder if there might not be some simultaneity problem affecting exports, which could arise if FDI targets traded sectors and leads to stronger export performance. However, there is likely a long gestation period between new investment and exports, which reduces the risk of simultaneity. Furthermore, a considerable part of FDI is represented by the purchase of existing production facilities through mergers and acquisitions. As Calderón, Loayza and Servén (2002) have noted, this type of operation represents the majority of FDI in developed countries and a substantial proportion of it in developing ones, and it is only with a lag that such operations tend to lead to new investments in additional physical capital. This extra lag further reduces the risk of simultaneity. A more serious simultaneity possibility is the one affecting GDPGRWTH. To rule out this possibility, we performed a regression-based version of the Hausman test for endogeneity of regressors. The test consists of regressing the suspect variable, GDPGRTH, on all other right hand side variables in the regression and at least one more exogenous variable not included in the regression. We chose the ratio of gross fixed capital formation to GDP as this instrument. The errors from this auxiliary regression are then added as a right hand side variable to the original regression, and if they are significantly different from zero, the maintained exogeneity of GDPGRWTH must be rejected (see Wooldridge 2002). The results of these tests are reported in the bottom panel of Table 6. We cannot reject the hypothesis of exogeneity in any one of the regressions. For the most part, the coefficients of the control variables reflecting the economic environment have the expected signs in Table 6. Low inflation and high economic growth, both signs of a stable economy, facilitate foreign investment . The main puzzle in this case is the “wrong” sign in front of the budget balance in all versions of the FDI regression –the coefficients are not significant, though. With its negative coefficient, the current account balance seems to represent financing need rather than an unstable environment in all columns. Another two puzzles are those related to the unexpected signs in front of the US T-bill rate and the rate of economic growth of the world, especially the latter, which is statistically significant. 20 A reason this elasticity is different from 1 may be that some of countries not covered by the panel have been growing in importance as recipients of FDI. This is possible because our measure of total FDI inflows is not the sum of the inflows into the sampled countries, which are obtained from a World Bank database, but a worldwide total reported by UNCTAD’s World Investment Report. 28 Table 7. Fixed-Effects Regressions of the Ln of FDI Against Membership in a Free Trade Area and Other Variables (t-stats under each coefficient) Variable \ Model FTAMEM 5 6 -0.178 -0.715 7 8 -0.011 -0.043 EXFTAMEM 0.312 1.540 0.371 2.004 0.335 1.652 0.339 1.825 RELGNIPH -4.944 -3.469 -4.844 -3.417 -5.005 -3.495 -5.000 -3.507 0.037 2.784 0.036 2.733 0.035 2.649 0.035 2.657 INFLATION 0.000 -0.328 0.000 -0.414 0.000 -0.577 0.000 -0.580 BUDGETBAL -0.028 -1.784 -0.027 -1.742 -0.030 -1.873 -0.030 -1.890 CURRACCT -0.035 -2.702 -0.035 -2.683 -0.036 -2.705 -0.036 -2.707 WRLDGRWTH -0.114 -1.811 -0.112 -1.787 -0.110 -1.753 -0.110 -1.754 US1YTBILL 0.044 1.116 0.044 1.127 0.043 1.091 0.043 1.092 EXPORTS 0.636 2.362 0.615 2.299 0.625 2.315 0.624 2.326 FDIWORLD 0.643 4.611 0.638 4.581 0.645 4.607 0.645 4.622 -0.006 -0.018 0.030 0.100 0.107 0.367 0.108 0.371 0.147 1.854 0.109 1.842 0.015 0.878 0.014 1.111 GDPGRWTH GDP FTAGDP PARTNGDP INTEGGDP 0.265 1.596 0.261 1.574 0.273 1.641 0.273 1.642 GOVTSTAB 0.140 2.897 0.141 2.928 0.146 2.997 0.146 3.006 LAWORDER 0.281 4.281 0.288 4.433 0.294 4.487 0.294 4.511 BUREAU 0.072 0.906 0.067 0.851 0.092 1.162 0.092 1.178 -12.812 -5.762 -12.538 -5.727 -12.561 -5.559 -12.551 -5.626 0.497 0.328 0.361 0.496 0.343 0.372 0.494 0.303 0.348 0.494 0.326 0.361 F test regressors DF 33.810 17, 583 35.92 16, 584 33.090 17, 575 35.660 16, 584 F test country effects DF 12.29 44, 583 12.76 44,584 12.59 44, 575 11.99 44, 575 -.006 -0.106 -.010 -0.158 -0.011 -0.185 -0.011 -0.187 645 645 645 645 CONSTANT R-sq: within between overall GDPGRWTH Endogeneity F-equivalent t-stat Number of observations 29 Finally, Table 7 reports additional regressions where we have added a few institutional quality variables. These are indexed of government stability, law and order, and the bureaucracy’s quality put together by the World Bank. These variables have positive signs as one should expect, and only the quality of the bureaucracy fails to be significant. These regressions and those of Table 6 are not strictly nested, because the institutional information starts only in 1984, and thus we proceeded to estimate our regressions without some 200 observations. For the most part, the coefficients on the variables appearing in both tables are quite similar. The main exception is RELGNIPH, which becomes strongly significant in Table 7. Both exports and world FDI flows see their coefficients fall in this table. We also ran regression-based tests of the exogeneity of GDPGRTH. In the last two models, where we use partner’s GDP rather than the aggregate GDP of the free trade area, the test statistics come out high, capable of rejecting exogeneity at the 10 percent significance level. Application of Results from FDI Regressions to the Mexican case In this section we will combine Mexican data with the estimates of the relation between foreign direct investment and the explanatory variables indicated in Table 6 in order to try to determine the contribution of different factors to the growth of FDI inflows in Mexico. The main conclusion emerging from this analysis is that Mexico’s participation in NAFTA and other free-trade arrangements during the second half of the nineties may have meant about a 70 percent rise of the foreign direct investment it would have received had it remained outside those arrangements. A second conclusion is that factors outside the model have caused an exceedingly slow growth of FDI inflows in Mexico. Given the strong globalization forces at work in the world and Mexico’s active participation in free-trade blocks, especially NAFTA, we would have expected much higher levels of FDI than those we have observed in recent years. A likely explanation of this disappointing performance is the stop in the process of economic reforms in Mexico since the mid nineties, which increasing has placed this country at a disadvantage relative to other countries that have continued reforming. Figure 11 shows the predicted values of FDI in Mexico on the basis of Mexican data and the coefficients of regression 2 in Table 6. The variables included in that regression have been combined to produce a series of fitted values, which we call Yhat. Yhat is the in-sample prediction of our dependent variable, the logarithm of FDI inflows. The fit of the model is quite good, as evidenced by a high correlation of 0.86 between Ln(FDI) and Yhat. Since the Mexican data are only a subset of the data used to estimate regression 2, we cannot decompose the variance of Ln(FDI) into the variances of Yhat and of the estimated errors to compute a sort of R2 for the Mexican data. The reason is that the estimated error term and Y hat are not orthogonal for any given subset of the observations, although they are mutually orthogonal by construction for the whole set of observations. Indeed, they are negatively correlated for the Mexican observations, a meaningful fact we will discuss shortly. 30 12.0 10.0 Natural Log of FDI Inflows 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 0.0 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 -2.0 Ln( FDI ) Error Y hat Figure 11. Actual and predicted values of the logs of FDI in Mexico Between 1991 and 1999, foreign investment inflows in Mexico approximately doubled. Using the coefficients estimated in regression 2 in combination with the data for Mexico, one can try to distinguish the different forces behind this overall increase in FDI. Table 8 shows, in levels (constant dollars), an illustrative calculation of those forces. The calculations in Table 8 are illustrative since the regressions we estimated, linear in logs, are therefore multiplicative in levels, and thus the order in which we present each independent effect influences the apparent magnitude of its contributions to the change in FDI. Clearly, such order does not affect the magnitude of the overall change in FDI. The main forces we single out in Table 8 are FTA effects and globalization effects, and other effects dominated by the growth in size of the country, measured by its GDP and exports. The fact that the last two lines of table 8 are equal does not imply that our model is a perfect fit for the Mexican data. The model predicion error is being treated, for purposes of Table 8, as another variable. This “variable” is in fact responsible for a steep “decline” in FDI as shown between the second and third lines of the table. This is simply a numerical representation of the fact, evident in Figure 10, that the model overpredicts FDI toward the end of the sample –that is, the error term turns large and negative. For our purposes, the most interesting piece of information is the jump in FDI due to the integration of Mexico into NAFTA. This jump from US$7,864 million to US$10,782 million implies that the contribution from joining NAFTA is an increase of nearly 40 percent of FDI relative to what it would have been if Mexico had remained outside any regional arrangements. 31 Table 8. Mexico: Illustrative Decomposition of the Rise in FDI Between 1991 and 1999 (millions of 1995 US dollars) Concept FDI in 1989 Plus: Increase in country size and other factors identified in the regression Plus: Decrease due to steep negative change in error term Plus: Increase due to globalization process Plus: Increase due to Mexico’s entry into NAFTA and other arrangements FDI in 1999 Amount 5,306 9,457 2,509 7,864 10,782 10,782 The decomposition presented in Table 8 underestimates the true contribution of regional integration in NAFTA to the rise in FDI. The reason is that the growth in exports, which we include in “size effects,” is due in part to the free trade agreement. A back-of-theenvelope calculation, however, suggests that a more reasonable estimate of NAFTA’s true contribution to FDI growth may be a hike of over 70 percent rather than one of 40 percent. The details of this computation are described in Appendix 4, and we offer it as a counterpoint to the basic characterization of this effect presented in Table 8. Our higher estimate seems remarkably similar to that obtained by A. Waldkirch (2001), who uses bilateral FDI data to conclude that FDI from North America would have been some 42 percent lower in the absence of NAFTA (i.e., that NAFTA lead to a 72 percent increase in FDI from Canada and the US). However, the resemblance between these results is less complete than it appears at first blush. Waldkirch argues that NAFTA has not brought about a significant increase in FDI from other countries. For our part, we noted earlier with the aid of Table 1 and Figure 8 that FDI originating in the NAFTA region had reacted more positively to Mexico’s membership in NAFTA than FDI originating elsewhere had, but that even this third-party FDI seemed to have risen after NAFTA went into effect, although it was not possible to determine the contribution to such increase from the trade agreement itself. Thus, the estimates of the effect of NAFTA on total FDI derived in this section must be considered an average of relatively higher effects for investments originating in the NAFTA region and lower effects for investments coming from elsewhere, although the data do not permit a separation of these two effects, since it does not correspond to bilateral FDI flows. The point to keep from this discussion is that, if we had been asked in 1991 to forecast FDI growth with only knowledge about future global forces and regional integration factors, we would have said that FDI would grow by a factor of eight, with an initial less-than-doubling on account of Mexico’s future growth (excluding here growth effects due to accession to NAFTA), a second more-than-doubling on account of Mexico’s participation in global currents of investment, and finally an additional increase of some two thirds due to joining NAFTA. However, with this forecast we would have far overshot our target. Our regression-based model, however, cannot account for the relatively disappointing growth of FDI inflows during the past decade. The model can only offer an adverse evolution of the error term, whose effect can be seen in the second row of Table 7. Figure 11, depicting the in-sample prediction error, shows that the moment of accession to NAFTA was one of actual overshooting of FDI, even beyond the predictions of the 32 model. But after 1996, the model increasingly overpredicts foreign direct investment in Mexico. In the latter part of the nineties Mexico became relatively less attractive to foreign investors despite objective factors working in favor of increased investment there, such as the growing intensity of global capital flows, Mexico’s closer integration with its NAFTA partners and its recent GDP and export growth. This phenomenon of overprediction towards the end of the sample is not typical of the model as a whole. For the entire sample, the correlation between a simple time trend and the in-sample prediction error of the model is small 2.5 percent. For the Mexican data, this correlation is large and negative: –65.6 percent. The lackluster performance of FDI during the last few years of the 1990s is probably the result of several processes. We have previously documented an overall decline in the proportion of FDI going to developing countries during the second half of the nineties (Table 3). Mexico’s relatively low levels of FDI may just be a manifestation of this general trend.21 A second candidate explanation is the limited size and early end of the Mexican privatization program. As noted by Calderón et al (2002) and explained earlier with the aid of Table 4, a growing proportion of FDI takes the form of mergers and acquisitions of existing firms. Measured with that yardstick, Mexico has been an outlier in recent years. However, this just tells us which form of FDI Mexico has failed to receive. It does not explain why Mexico has been so different from other countries. Following our earlier discussion of Portugal and Spain, it is also conceivable that NAFTA was only responsible for a stock adjustment that took place during a few years starting in 1994, and that such adjustment is over and FDI is now settling toward more “normal” levels (see Figures 2 and 3). In addition to the arguments presented above, however, we must point to a policy issue. The weakening of the growth of FDI flows into Mexico seems to have coincided with the decline of that country’s competitiveness as measured by the World Economic Forum (2000) and similar organizations. Between 1999 and 2000, in fact, Mexico worsened its position in the global competitiveness ranking, jumping from the 31st to the 42nd place. A partial list of the countries that overtook Mexico is quite informative: Hungary, Poland, the Czech Republic, Turkey and Slovakia were all working to upgrade their institutions with a view to joining the European Union, while Greece and Italy were trying to strengthen their macroeconomic policies to meet the Maastricht criteria for monetary integration. These countries were working on structural reforms and on deepening their regional bonds. The case of Mexico offers a clear contrast: the pace of structural reform slowed down drastically after the approval of a new system of social security for private sector workers in 1997, and NAFTA is and will remain for the foreseeable future a trading block. 21 This suggests two avenues for further work: testing the stability of the coefficient of GNI in the regressions of Table 5 around 1995, and making detailed country estimates such as the ones presented in this section for several other countries. 33 12.0 10.0 Natural Log of FDI Inflows 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 0.0 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 -2.0 Ln( FDI ) Error Y hat Figure 12. Actual and predicted values of the log of FDI in Mexico based on a regression including some institutional quality variables. The data from the regressions of Table 7 might be used to conduct a similar analysis, but this time trying to take into account some institutional factors. Granted, the government stability, law and order, and bureaucracy quality indexes are only limited indicators of structural reform. Yet, it is interesting to attempt to incorporate these factors. Figure 12 shows the actual and predicted values of FDI inflows for Mexico during 1984-1999 on the basis of regression 6 (Table 7), and the corresponding prediction errors. Remarkably, we find the same pattern of underprediction at the start of NAFTA and overprediction toward the end of the nineties. For this case too we carried out the same calculations as before. Our main results are remarkably similar despite the difference between the sample sizes: a direct estimation of the impact of NAFTA on FDI, excluding any export size effects, indicates that FDI is 40 percent than it would be without NAFTA, and a more reasonable estimate including possible effects through export growth rises the contribution of NAFTA to FDI growth during the nineties to the figure of 72 percent. The underprediction towards the end of the sample is, however, more moderate than before: now the correlation between a time trend and the prediction error is –35.7 percent (for the entire sample it is 1.7 percent). In other words, bringing some measurement of institutional development into the analysis helps explain part of the disappointing performance of FDI in Mexico. This suggests that, at least in part, relatively low FDI can be explained by the slowing down of the structural reform process in Mexico. 34 The Growing Integration of Stock Markets in Mexico and the US. In this last section of the analysis of aggregate trends we report on some simple measures of co-movement between American and Mexican stocks. It was to be expected that entry into NAFTA would promote a closer coordination of the movement between those markets for two reasons. One is that foreign investors more often look at Mexican stocks as potential investment targets, and the other is that firms listed in the Mexican exchange with increasing frequency take advantage of the American Depositary Receipts (ADR) to obtain funds abroad. Both mechanisms should heighten the transmission of stock price shocks across both countries (and especially from the US to Mexico). As we will see, this is supported by the data, although a first rough cut would seem to imply otherwise. 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 2001/06 2000/12 2000/06 1999/12 1999/06 1998/12 1998/06 1997/12 1997/06 1996/12 1996/06 1995/12 1995/06 1994/12 1994/06 1993/12 1993/06 1992/12 1992/06 1991/12 1991/06 1990/12 1990/06 -0.2 1989/12 0 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8 -1 Figure 13. Moving retrospective 12-month correlations between the DJ and IPC indexes (deflated by the American and Mexican CPIs), 1989-2001. We start by looking at twelve-month moving correlations between the end-of-month readings of the Dow Jones and the IPC (the main Mexican index, “the indice de precios y cotizaciones”). The indexes have been deflated by the consumer price indexes of each country, and the correlations are backward looking. The trajectory of these correlations, depicted in Figure 13, seems to contradict the expectation expressed above. Between 1989 and 1994, they were consistently positive, but starting in 1995 they exhibit a rather erratic behavior, becoming at times negative. The behavior of these correlations reflects a basic instability in the Mexican market in the nineties that is most likely associated with its vulnerability to sudden confidence shifts, including through contagion. This fact becomes clear when we look at the indexes themselves. Figure 14 shows the DJ and IPC, deflated by the US and Mexico CPIs, and expressed on a common base. As we see, 35 most of the time both indices exhibit an upward trend. This is especially certain of the first several years represented in the chart. The simple positive correlation indicates that both indexes were showing positive growth, but cannot, by its arithmetic nature, indicate the fact that the growth of the IPC was so much the faster. This tremendous growth was due to the liberalization of financial markets, and its efficient cause was the rise, virtually from zero, of foreign flows of portfolio investment in Mexico, which boomed dramatically diring the 1990-1993 period, as we saw earlier with the aid of Figure 6. In other words, this initial stage reflects a large stock adjustment in the portfolios of foreign investors, instead of a more normal or settled situation. 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 DJ 2001/07 2001/01 2000/07 2000/01 1999/07 1999/01 1998/07 1998/01 1997/07 1997/01 1996/07 1996/01 1995/07 1995/01 1994/07 1994/01 1993/07 1993/01 1992/07 1992/01 1991/07 1991/01 1990/07 1990/01 1989/07 1989/01 0 IPC Figure 14. CPI-deflated DJ and IPC stock indexes (end-of-month closings), 1989-2001. The Mexican index, which during upswings tends to grow faster than the American index, was subject to large and some times relatively long reversals that had no comparable counterpart in the US data. These reversals can be individually identified with the drop in the correlations of Figure 13, and respond to well specified events. The 1995 precipitous drop in the Mexican exchange was due to the generalized economic crisis of that year, which clearly was an idiosyncratic shock. The negative correlation of 1996 reflects the combination of a (by now) clearly dynamic American market and a sluggish level of prices in the Mexican stock exchange that year. However, in 1996, and despite a fall of five percent in the real value of the IPC, the Mexican stock exchange started its recovery, with an increase in capitalization, valued in dollar terms, of over 20 percent, in part due to the return of some of the portfolio investment flows that had vanished in 1995. This partial recovery of portfolio inflows was already noted when discussing Figure 8. The 1998 drop in the IPC was a result of contagion from Asia and especially Russia. During that year, as we also saw in Figure 8, gross inflows of portfolio investment returned to their depressed levels of 1995, and the net result of both 36 portfolio inflows and outflows was negative.22 In other words, the peaks in instability arising from Mexico’s condition as an emerging market in a more volatile period in the international economy that contrasts with the resilience of the American market in the face of shocks originating outside the US. However, starting in 1999, the IPC seems to track the DJ a lot better than before, even though this index no longer exhibits a monotonic behavior. This enhanced association between the two stock markets likely reflects the growing coincidence between the US and Mexican cycles resulting from NAFTA.23 In fact, the behavior of the IPC around the fall of 2001 reflects the change in mood in the US in the face of uncertainty arising from terrorism and the quick (albeit partial) recovery of expectations seen in October 2001 in the US as a consequence of the vigorous policy response implemented by the FED and the Treasury of the US. At the same time, it is hard to find convincing signs of contagion from Turkey or Argentina. Figure 13, then, suggests that Mexico may be becoming more closely associated with its main NAFTA partner, despite being an emerging market, which is shown in the volatility of the IPC, which seems to remain higher than that of the DJ. One way to look for confirmation of the hypothesis of growing integration between the two countries’ equity markets is to perform a sequence of naïve regressions and examine their explanatory power. We regress the change in the IPC against the change in the DJ (and a constant) over three different sample periods, all of which end in December 2001. The first sample period starts in February 1989, the second one in January 1994, and the third one in January 1998. The idea is to exclude first the preNAFTA period, and then also the currency and banking crisis of 1995 and its aftermath, up till the Asian crisis, but leaving already in the last period the Russian and Brazilian crises. The data we used in the first set of regressions were the stock indexes from the two countries deflated by the CPI; in the second set, we used the dollar-valued indexes. The raw data were seasonally adjusted using a multiplicative X11 algorithm, and then differenced. We tried to include lags of both the dependent and independent variables in the equations, but these always came out insignificant, so we report only the simplest form of the regressions (the lack of explanatory power of the lagged variables in these regressions offers additional support for these procedures themselves). The main result of the exercise is the increase in the value of the adjusted R2 observed as we reduce the sample size. A secondary result is the increasing value of the coefficient of the DJ variable in the regression as the sample period reflects more directly a post-NAFTA, post-crisis era. This result is not too strong, however, since in all regressions the hypothesis of a common elasticity of the IPC with respect to the DJ (e.g., a unit elasticity) cannot be rejected. The estimated values of the regression constants contain are never statistically different from zero, and their absolute magnitude does decline markedly in the shortest samples, as does the estimated probability that they are nonzero. So, the model does not seem to have changed all that drastically; but its predictive usefulness has increased. As time passes, the ability of movements in the American stock exchange to explain movements in the price of Mexican stocks has grown, confirming the closer linkage of the Mexican to the US economy since NAFTA went into effect. 22 23 See Banco de Mexico (1996, 1997 and 1999). See Cuevas, Messmacher and Werner (2002). 37 Table 9. Regressions of Changes in the IPC against Changes in the DJ.* Sample Period Constant t statistic DJ Coeff. t statistic Adj. R squared N. of Obs. CPI-Deflated Indexes Feb 1989 - Dec 2001 Jan 1994 - Dec 2001 Jan 1998 - Dec 2001 0.454 -0.899 -0.150 0.737 -1.192 -0.016 1.018 1.127 1.212 6.416 6.361 6.064 0.207 0.294 0.378 155 96 60 Indexes in Current Dollars Feb 1989 - Dec 2001 Jan 1994 - Dec 2001 Jan 1998 - Dec 2001 0.707 -0.891 0.397 0.960 -0.919 0.376 1.139 1.253 1.333 6.066 5.563 6.045 0.189 0.240 0.376 155 96 60 * Seasonally adjusted data. Microeconomic Analysis of Financial Flows After having discussed foreign capital flows from a macroeconomic perspective, in this section we will explore the effects of NAFTA on financing opportunities from the point of view of individual firms. As before, our expectation is that the free trade agreement will open new doors to the private sector, especially to exporters, and that firms will try to obtain foreign financing to match their increasing openness. This expectation, as we will see, is mostly confirmed by the analysis. The first part of this section uses data on listed firms to answer some questions about the composition of financing. The upshot of that analysis is the finding that foreign financing has become more important for the relatively large firms in our sample. The second part of this section fits investment equations both to the listed-firms data set already mentioned and to a data set more broadly representative, since it comes from the Annual Industrial Survey. The results of the estimation in the second data set are stronger, showing that liquidity constraints remained a significant determinant of investment after NAFTA went into effect, but also suggesting that NAFTA provided firms with additional incentives to invest and contributed to reduce the severity of liquidity constraints. Firm financing To test our expectations we will use data collected by the Mexican stock exchange. These data have been used before to test hypotheses concerning the effect of the 1995 banking crisis on firm financing in Mexico (Martínez Trigueros, 2001). The data set is an unbalanced panel of 367 firms sampled between 1989 and 2000. Of these firms, only 64 are present for the whole sample period. The firms in the sample are not fully representative of the private sector: they are relatively large and modern, since they have been listed in the Mexican Stock exchange (or placed debt in domestic capital markets). These firms employ, in any given year, between three and six percent of the formal private labor force in Mexico (on average for 1994-2000, 4.4 percent of the workers contributing to the private-sector social insurance scheme). Since listed firms tend to be relatively sophisticated, their 38 participation in economic activity is larger than their participation in the labor market. On average, these firms’ net sales (excluding taxes and transportation costs) were equivalent to six percent of GDP, and their total assets, to 36 percent of GDP. Within the data set itself, the distribution of firms by the size their total assets is very skewed, with a few large firms pulling up the average size in the sample, as can be inferred from Table 10. In that table, we present selected percentiles of the distribution of relative size of the firms, defined as the ratio of a firm’s own assets to the average level of assets among firms sampled during a given year. Table 10. Distribution of Relative Size in the Stock Exchange Sample Selected Percentiles, by Year Year P5 P 25 P 50 P 75 P 95 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2.8 2.9 3.2 3.2 2.2 2.1 1.8 1.9 1.5 1.6 1.3 1.2 11.6 9.9 9.7 8.9 8.0 6.5 5.5 6.3 5.0 6.0 6.9 6.6 26.1 31.8 29.3 28.7 24.3 23.3 23.9 27.8 23.8 27.4 28.3 27.9 111.4 96.6 92.1 83.4 88.7 85.4 87.5 97.4 79.1 116.0 89.1 96.9 470.4 378.7 400.3 405.7 433.9 470.0 477.5 466.7 431.5 404.5 417.5 347.8 The data set consists of the main items in the balance sheets and profit-and-loss statements of these firms, such as total assets, bank debt, payables and receivables, and pre-tax profits. In addition, the data set contains important miscellaneous items such as proceeds from the disposition of physical and financial assets, whether a firm issued ADRs (American Depositary Receipts), the breakdown of net sales between exports and domestic transactions, and the breakdown of debt by the residence of the creditor (external and domestic).24 Using these data it is relatively easy to produce a series of indicators of leveraging (the ratio of debt to assets), profitability (pretax profits to assets), and openness (the ratio of exports to sales). It is also a simple matter to produce indicators of the composition of debt by type and residency of creditors. The average levels of these and other indicators in our sample are presented in Table 11. The impact of the free trade agreement seems evident from Table 11, as the average percentage of sales accounted for by exports went from single to double digits starting in 1995. During the sample period, the average degree of indebtedness reached its peak in 1995, doubtless influenced in part by the revaluation effect of the depreciation of the peso. Debt ratios, however, have not fallen back to their pre-1995 levels. Consonant with the behavior of debt, the burden of servicing it jumped in 1995, as a result of the 24 Strictly speaking, the data indicate the currency in which liabilities are denominated. We are equating dollar denominated liabilities with liabilities to foreigners. 39 drop in sales due to the recession and the jump in interest rates and in the cost of the dollar associated with the exchange rate crisis. Table 11. Means of Key Variables and their Ratios in the Sample of Firms Listed in the Mexican Stock Exchange Year 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Total Total Assets Count Thou.Pesos 109 223 259 260 253 237 224 220 209 186 169 149 Pretax Profit Over Assets Percent Exports Over Sales Percent Debt to Assets Percent Interest Over Sales Percent Foreign Debt Over Debt Percent Bank Debt Over Debt Percent Suppliers Over Debt Percent ADR Issue Percent 2,317,417 1,801,015 1,682,519 1,704,289 1,885,097 2,234,010 2,659,633 2,539,101 2,688,463 3,016,180 3,137,924 3,795,149 1.6 1.5 1.6 1.3 1.1 -0.2 0.4 1.8 1.8 1.1 1.5 1.9 12.4 10.0 8.4 8.3 8.0 9.4 16.6 15.8 15.9 16.7 14.6 17.5 34.1 36.9 39.9 41.3 42.7 44.1 49.2 48.5 46.5 45.7 48.5 56.5 8.7 9.8 9.0 8.9 9.9 9.9 24.2 18.8 12.0 13.2 16.7 8.9 26.6 27.3 29.7 30.4 32.8 37.7 45.0 44.1 44.8 46.1 43.0 44.0 40.8 39.4 40.2 40.7 39.7 41.1 45.5 43.9 42.1 43.4 42.0 33.6 16.8 19.7 18.2 17.1 17.1 17.1 16.5 18.3 20.3 22.7 22.7 18.5 1.8 0.9 1.2 1.5 4.0 5.9 9.8 13.2 14.4 19.9 17.2 23.5 2,366,912 1.2 12.3 44.3 12.5 37.4 41.2 18.6 8.7 As for the composition of the liabilities of firms, the most remarkable development has been the increase in the proportion of foreign debt starting in 1995. Again, even if a revaluation effect was in action in 1995, it cannot be claimed as an explanation for the continued high proportion of foreign debt after 1995, let alone in 2000, when the real exchange rate appreciated. It is highly likely, thus, that the increase in the outward orientation of sales and financing may be related, as we will see below. Bank debt has been least dynamic, while payables have become a more important source of financing. If we consider the deleterious effects on credit of the Mexican banking crisis, it is quite possible that the relative stability in the average levels of bank debt masks an increasing patronage of foreign banks. Unfortunately, the data set does not permit the strict verification of this conjecture, although below we will attempt to find additional evidence of this relationship. Lastly, table 11 also shows the increasing resort to the issue of ADRs by Mexican firms. The changes in some of these dimensions of financing have not always been evenly distributed across firms. Tables 12-16 present the distribution of key ratios during the sample period; for example, Table 16 shows that the increase in the average proportion of liabilities represented by suppliers’ credit is explained by the increase in payables among less than one half of the firms in the sample. These tables also show that, while virtually all firms increased their degree of indebtedness during the nineties, a group of firms seems to have avoided external financing throughout that decade. Similarly, a large proportion of firms continued to shy away from exporting even after NAFTA went into force, and the overall increase in exports came from a subset of firms. It seems logical to suppose that firms concentrating in the production of nontraded services would account for the lack of exporting activity among almost one half of all firms in the sample. In any case, the group of firms borrowing exclusively in pesos seems smaller than the group concentrating in domestic sales, and seems to be shrinking faster too. This might reflect an increased resort to foreign credit even among firms without an export orientation in the face of the paralysis of banking credit that has been observed since 1995, as we discussed in previous sections of this chapter. 40 Table 12. Distribution of Exports-Sales Ratios by Selected Percentiles Year P5 P 25 P 50 P 75 P 95 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 6.4 3.0 1.4 1.2 0.6 1.0 3.5 5.2 5.8 5.2 5.6 6.3 18.9 13.5 10.8 10.2 9.0 10.4 28.4 23.0 22.2 25.3 24.0 25.9 53.3 50.7 42.8 44.6 40.5 53.1 65.1 63.1 64.9 73.4 63.8 72.0 Table 13. Distribution of Debt-Assets Ratios by Selected Percentiles Year P5 P 25 P 50 P 75 P 95 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 13.4 12.6 12.9 11.7 13.4 15.0 12.8 11.3 10.1 9.8 10.2 16.5 24.1 25.6 27.9 29.4 29.9 29.3 33.1 31.2 28.3 25.5 27.1 36.4 32.2 36.1 39.8 42.8 43.4 43.8 48.9 45.7 43.7 42.1 42.5 50.4 40.3 47.8 49.7 52.3 54.3 55.5 61.4 60.5 56.5 56.7 57.8 64.8 63.6 65.4 69.9 68.7 71.3 77.0 94.9 95.8 104.0 84.1 87.4 83.8 Table 14. Distribution of Foreign Debt Ratios by Selected Percentiles Year P5 P 25 P 50 P 75 P 95 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 6.0 3.5 5.4 3.8 3.7 5.9 12.5 11.4 11.1 13.0 12.4 11.1 21.0 21.3 24.7 24.6 30.0 32.1 45.6 44.5 44.5 45.5 42.7 42.5 43.0 47.6 49.5 52.8 57.1 68.2 77.9 75.3 76.3 79.5 73.4 72.2 71.4 72.2 80.7 80.8 83.8 87.0 90.9 92.1 92.5 93.2 93.2 92.4 41 Table 15. Distribution of Bank Debt Ratios by Selected Percentiles Year P5 P 25 P 50 P 75 P 95 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 0.4 0.2 1.1 1.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 24.2 21.2 20.7 24.6 19.5 19.0 22.3 22.3 16.2 19.5 18.4 14.7 43.3 41.1 41.7 42.0 40.9 41.1 50.2 44.5 44.6 44.5 40.5 32.0 61.3 58.7 58.4 57.4 59.0 63.1 67.8 66.7 68.1 69.6 66.2 50.3 72.2 73.8 75.5 78.0 79.3 81.8 85.1 86.6 82.3 86.1 84.9 76.6 Table 16. Distribution of Supplier Credit to Debt Ratios by Selected Percentiles Year P5 P 25 P 50 P 75 P 95 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 1.3 2.2 2.0 1.6 1.9 1.2 1.0 0.6 0.8 0.9 0.9 0.5 7.4 7.9 7.3 6.1 6.0 6.2 5.0 5.1 5.8 7.1 7.6 6.4 13.9 15.6 13.4 12.1 11.8 11.2 10.5 12.0 13.6 15.0 15.8 12.2 22.3 26.9 25.1 21.9 20.1 20.8 21.3 25.0 27.2 32.8 28.4 23.9 44.2 50.0 46.8 49.4 58.6 49.5 48.2 61.0 65.7 71.0 71.3 60.0 Looking at Tables 12 and 14, it is tempting to look for a connection between increased exports and higher proportions of foreign debt, and possibly of suppliers’ credit if we consider that some fraction of foreign debt is actually owed to nonresident suppliers. Table 16 constitutes a first pass at these issues. This table includes pairwise correlations among export-sales ratios (labeled exportrt), indebtedness levels (indebt), bank debt ratios (bnkdbtrt), foreign debt ratios (frdbtrt), relative firm size (relsize), profitability (profitab), and whether the NAFTA was in effect. As we expected, export orientation is highly correlated with foreign debt ratios, and it seems to be positively linked, although more weakly, to the size of the firm and its degree of leveraging. Another conjecture that seems supported by Table 17 is that the reason that bank debt has not fallen despite the Mexican banking crisis is that foreign banks may be picking up part of the slack, a development surely facilitated by the increased presence of Mexican firms abroad, both as exporters and as issuers of securities such as ADRs (as we saw in Table 11, the proportion of firms in our sample that issued ADRs rose from less than two percent in 1989 to 23.5 percent in 2000; we will return to this matter shortly). The conclusions we are drawing from the correlations table may seem too strong, but they are not. As Tables 42 12-16 show, not all firms in the sample display the same behavior, and thus the strong correlations between export behavior and foreign borrowing, and between the latter and bank borrowing must reflect the processes and connections we are describing. Table 17. Correlations Between Pairs of Selected Variables exportrt indebt bnkdbtrt frdbtrt relsize profitab nafta exportrt indebt bnkdbtrt frdbtrt relsize profitab nafta 1 0.12 0.29 0.54 0.14 -0.06 0.16 1.00 0.27 0.15 -0.03 -0.21 0.16 1.00 0.49 0.05 -0.17 0.04 1.00 0.27 -0.06 0.22 1.00 0.09 0.00 1.00 -0.04 1.00 The most interesting results for us are those presented in the last row of Table 17. The figures in that row are the arithmetic summary of the developments reflected in all of the year-by-year information we have presented so far in this section. Remarkably, the strongest correlation is that between NAFTA and foreign debt ratios, even more than that between export ratios and NAFTA. This is consistent with our discussion of Tables 11 and 13, where we noted that the group of those firms limiting themselves to domestic credit sources was shrinking faster than the group of firms producing only for the domestic market. It thus seems that even producers of nontraded goods are taking advantage of more integrated capital markets to borrow abroad, be it from their suppliers or from financial intermediaries. To seek confirmation for the tentative conclusions advanced so far, we ran regressions of our indicators of the composition of liabilities against a suitable set of explanatory variables (including sector dummies). The main focus of our regressions are the effects of export ratios (exportrt), because NAFTA’s indirect effects happen through exports, and the effects of other more direct measures of NAFTA. The latter include a dummy variable taking on the value of 1 during the period of effect of NAFTA; sector-specific measures of the preferential component in US tariffs on Mexican imports (ustariffadv), defined as the difference between the average tariffs imposed by the US on imports from Mexico and from Mercosur;25 and a measure of average Mexican tariffs 25 This simple average is taken over the import-weighted means of the tariffs imposed on the goods that fall in each one of the chapters of the Harmonized Tariff Schedule (HTS). The average over the many chapter-specific mean tariffs corresponding to each sector is a simple average to moderate the possible bias in our measure of the tariff advantage, because imports of any good should respond to tariff levels, which would tend to make import-weighted average tariffs lower than average tariffs. (Incidentally, the matching of the HTS chapters and the sectorial classification used by the Mexican Stock Exchange was done on the basis of the authors’ judgment.) However, we could not avoid using import-weighted mean tariffs at the HTS chapter level, because the tariff information had to be estimated from public data on dutiable imports and collected duties classified by HTS chapter (available at the United States International Trade Commission’s website). Also, it might have been desirable to estimate an alternative measure of the advantage obtained by Mexican exporters by calculating the difference between NAFTA/Mexico and Most-Favored-Nation tariffs, but the latter are not available in formats that may be easily used in statistical analysis. Moreover, measuring tariff advantage as the difference between tariffs on certain Mexican goods and tariffs on like goods coming from another country is more meaningful, since tariffs are on a downward trend in general. The USITC website allows the choice of almost any comparator country or region, and we chose Mercosur because this region consists of countries similar to Mexico in many respects, but which do not have a close commercial relationship with North America. 43 (mextariff26) and its interaction with a measure of the importance of intermediate inputs as a proportion of total product value (intinput). We control for some of the characteristics of the firms in our sample, such as the firm’s size, measured by its assets, relative to that of the average firm in the sample in the year of the observation (relsize); its profitability, measured by its ratio of pre-tax profit to assets (profitab) ; and whether or not it issues ADRs. The regressions also include as independent variables some environmental factors impinging on financial choices, including American and Mexican real interest rates (rxrintus and rintsect; the latter is a common interest rate deflated by relevant sector-specific price indexes) and the nominal depreciation of the Mexican peso. 27 The third set of regressors consists of a group of sector dummies for extractive activity (nonoil mining), manufacturing, construction, commerce, communications and transportation, and services. The omitted sector is “other activities,” which includes some holding firms as well as some firms that could not be assigned to a specific sector, a group that turns out to be relatively export oriented. The bottom panel of the table contains versions of the main regressions where we control for fixed-effects at the level of the firm; for that reason, the sector dummies have dropped out. Each pair of columns contains the coefficient and t-statistic corresponding to every explanatory variable in each one of the three regressions we report: for the ratio of foreign debt to total debt (frdbtrt); for the ratio of bank debt to total debt (bnkdbtrt); and for the ratio of supplier’s credit received to total debt (supprat). The foreign debt ratio regressions shown on the first pair of columns of Table 18 are the one with the best fit. The export ratio is, naturally, a key determinant of foreign debt ratios. Interestingly, the stand-alone NAFTA dummy is positive while the interaction between exports and that dummy is significant and negative. This indicates that since NAFTA, foreign financing has become more popular even beyond the circle of the most outwardly oriented firms. The trade agreement has therefore led to a rising resort to foreign debt, especially –but perhaps not only—among exporters. The issuing of ADRs is also significantly associated with higher foreign debt ratios, suggesting that various forms of foreign financing may be pursued by the same firms. Relative size is also significantly associated to higher ratios of foreign indebtedness. Finally, although they are not significant, the interest rate and peso depreciation coefficients have the correct sign most of the time (on a one sided-test, the US interest rate coefficient would just be rejected at the 10 percent level of significance. As far as sectors are concerned, the most remarkable coefficient is that on communications and transportation, a sector that boomed in the 1990s following the privatization of the phone company and the subsequent opening of the sector to foreign investment in mobile communications. Similarly, and understandably, commerce is the least dependent of all sectors on foreign financing. In the fixed-effect regression some of the direct effects of NAFTA come out more clearly, as the net effect of Mexican tariffs is negative, since intinput is less than 1 by construction (all the same, it is puzzling to see larger effects from tariff reductions in sectors where intermediate inputs are lower).The main puzzle in both regressions is the negative coefficient on the profitability variable. 26 The average is taken over import-weighted mean tariffs on inputs imported by firms in different industrial classes. The information on Mexican tariffs, produced by the Secretariat of the Economy, was generously shared with us by Enrique Dussel Peters, Luis Miguel Galindo and Eduardo Loría, of UNAM’s Economics Department. They are using these data in a broad project on microeconomic aspects of FDI in Mexico (see Dussel Peters et al, 2002). 27 Real interest rates are computed as the difference between interest rates observed today and the inflation observed from this day forward. In other words, inflation expectations are “rational” and are estimated by actual inflation. 44 Table 18. Regressions of the Structure of Firm Liabilities (t statistics to the right of the coefficients) A) Foreign Debt Ratio Coefficient t statistic B) Bank Debt Ratio Coefficient t statistic C) Suppliers' Debt Ratio Coefficient t statistic OLS regressions exportrt exportrt*nafta ustaradv mxtariff mxtariff*intinput relsize adr profitab rintsect rxrintus pesodep nafta extractive manufactures construction commerce commun. & transprt. services constant 0.854 -0.198 -0.437 -0.127 0.047 0.028 10.491 -0.322 0.058 -0.946 -0.001 10.517 -11.311 -1.929 -5.324 -15.174 9.075 0.007 26.711 No. Obs F statistic F stat d.f. Adjusted R2 15.249 -3.205 -0.691 -0.272 0.143 9.551 5.241 -1.938 0.932 -1.640 -0.044 4.479 -3.359 -1.111 -2.243 -6.987 2.600 0.003 5.250 0.482 -0.207 -0.291 0.556 -1.054 0.008 0.252 -1.300 0.062 -0.300 0.036 1.380 -7.525 -2.791 -4.840 -9.081 -5.205 -3.237 42.160 2,321 85.30 18, 230 0.395 8.648 -3.362 -0.463 1.192 -3.189 2.823 0.126 -7.853 0.994 -0.523 1.623 0.590 -2.244 -1.614 -2.048 -4.198 -1.497 -1.259 8.320 -0.042 -0.001 0.151 -1.009 0.807 -0.009 -3.809 0.876 -0.018 0.496 -0.021 -0.128 -0.673 2.916 -1.906 22.325 -4.147 -6.297 18.939 2,321 18.81 18, 230 0.121 -1.178 -0.031 0.372 -3.364 3.797 -4.584 -2.970 8.228 -0.461 1.343 -1.439 -0.085 -0.312 2.620 -1.253 16.041 -1.854 -3.809 5.809 2,321 51.00 18, 230 0.280 Fixed effects regressions exportrt exportrt*nafta ustaradv mxtariff mxtariff*intinput relsize adr profitab rintsect rxrintus pesodep nafta constant No. Obs F statistic F stat d.f. No. groups (firms) R2 within between overall F stat. firm effects F stat d.f. 0.128 0.065 0.424 -0.835 0.715 0.025 2.379 -0.312 0.074 -1.261 0.036 8.886 33.547 2.369 1.433 1.035 -2.437 2.473 3.505 1.334 -2.670 1.856 -3.587 2.642 5.559 9.824 2,321 33.93 12, 1939 370 0.174 0.292 0.266 13.43 369, 1939 0.174 -0.037 -0.613 -0.310 0.107 0.013 -2.022 -0.461 0.003 -0.113 0.043 -0.794 41.606 2.934 -0.741 -1.367 -0.826 0.336 1.649 -1.036 -3.605 0.066 -0.293 2.904 -0.454 11.127 2,321 4.96 12, 1939 370 0.030 0.154 0.090 10.21 369, 1939 -0.076 0.036 0.044 -0.570 0.171 -0.003 -2.514 0.242 -0.044 0.527 -0.004 -2.614 24.245 -2.412 1.371 0.182 -2.845 1.010 -0.774 -2.409 3.542 -1.888 2.561 -0.448 -2.794 12.131 2,321 3.64 12, 1939 370 0.022 0.074 0.074 17.15 369, 1939 The second pair of columns of Table 18 shows the regressions for bank debt, which have the worst fit of the table, as we could have expected from the rather low variability 45 of bank debt ratios shown in Tables 10 and 14. The main result from these columns worth mentioning is the fact that the coefficient of exports in this regression is unstable, in the sense that its interaction with the NAFTA dummy is negative and significant, in indicating that an outward orientation is important to obtain bank debt, but it generates less additional debt during the NAFTA years than it did before. Unlike in the foreign debt regression, this is not accompanied by a high and significant coefficient for the stand-alone NAFTA dummy. In fact, in the fixed effect regression this dummy is even negative (though insignificant). The other measure of NAFTA to come out significant in the OLS regression is the interaction of mxtariffs and intinput; the negative coefficient suggests that firms benefiting from the reduction in Mexican tariffs because of their high use of traded inputs increased their indebtedness to banks. This result, however, is not robust to the introduction of firm-level fixed effects. Commerce is the activity with the least dependence on banks. The last pair of columns, reporting the results from the suppliers’ credit regression, indicate that relatively small size and inward orientation have a positive impact on this type of borrowing (in the fixed effects regressions, in fact, the export ratio has a significant and negative coefficient). Profitability is an important determinant of access to suppliers’ credit.28 By the nature of its activity, commerce is by far the most dependent on suppliers’ credit. The net effect of Mexican tariffs is again negative, indicating that trade liberalization increased this type of credit. It is possible to hypothesize that, as price competition from imports became stronger thanks to the reduction in tariffs, suppliers made the terms of their financing more favorable to their customers. However, we can’t verify this conjecture with the data we have. The combination of these last two regressions suggests that, faced with the Mexican banking crisis, outwardly oriented firms have gone at least in part to foreign banks, while domestically oriented firms seem to have relied more on domestic supplier financing. This result is broadly consistent with the empirical literature on trade credit, which has established that firms tend more often to resort to supplier financing when they are unable to secure financing from banks (Petersen and Rajan, 1996). Table 19. Foreign Debt Ratios (in Percent) and Openness ADR 0 1 Total 29.1 39.7 63.8 65.7 29.8 43.4 34.7 65.5 37.4 Nafta 0 1 Total 28 In an alternative specification (not reported), the interaction of profitability and the NAFTA dummy had a negative sign. Looking at this data set from the perspective of the firms granting trade credit, Martínez Trigueros (2001) finds the reciprocal of these results: firms with access to foreign and bank credit offer trade credit to their customers, and after NAFTA, profitability became an important determinant of trade credit offered, as the banking system crisis that coincided with the NAFTA period intensified the liquidity restrictions affecting suppliers of trade credit themselves. 46 Besides issuing debt, firms get financing by placing equity, and we had observed that this activity is increasingly taking place both in the Mexican and US markets. Earlier we had noted the fact that issuing an ADR is a sign of outward orientation. Table 19 offers a simple confirmation of this observation. There, we see that firms issuing ADRs also tend to have high foreign debt ratios. However, the increase in the propensity to borrow abroad seems to have been larger outside the group of firms issuing this type of security. Under NAFTA, however, the proportion of firms issuing ADRs has increased (see also Table 11). This relation is further explored in Table 20, where we report the results of logit regressions for the issue of ADRs. Table 20. Logit Regressions of ADR Issuance exportrt exportrt*nafta exportrt*ustariffadv ustaradv mxtariff mxtariff*intinput relsize profitab rxrintus pesodep nafta extractive manufactures construction commerce commun. & transprt. services constant No. Obs LR Chi Square Chi Square d.f. Pseudo R2 1 Coefficient z statistic 2 Coefficient z statistic 0.016 4.347 0.047 -0.034 3.589 -2.473 0.125 -0.459 -0.088 0.005 0.000 0.147 -0.004 1.492 -6.923 -1.473 9.945 -0.007 1.392 -1.193 -2.464 0.454 0.986 -0.352 2.168 -0.563 -0.077 -2.297 1.689 2.966 -0.845 5.476 -0.956 -0.126 0.092 -0.350 -0.080 0.005 0.004 0.034 -0.006 1.617 -2.652 0.465 1.052 -0.333 2.138 -0.599 -1.980 1.071 -4.134 -1.370 9.884 0.185 0.290 -1.708 2.993 -2.468 1.687 3.096 -0.788 5.344 -1.010 -2.145 2,321 441.12 14 0.316 2,321 452.52 16 0.324 3 Coefficient z statistic 0.016 3.511 -0.001 0.109 -0.340 -0.080 0.005 0.003 0.041 -0.006 1.066 -2.559 0.402 0.955 -0.389 2.099 -0.656 -1.504 -0.253 1.076 -4.063 -1.341 9.908 0.155 0.348 -1.729 2.337 -2.365 1.457 2.792 -0.928 5.233 -1.107 -1.720 2,321 447.31 16 0.321 Table 20 reports the results from a set of logit regressions for the issue of ADRs. The main difference among them is the way we model NAFTA. The fit of all three models is reasonably good, and most coefficients of interest have the expected signs and appear significant. Thus, export orientation is major predictors of ADR issue; but it becomes less important during the NAFTA era (the sign of the interaction of export ratios with ustariffadv is negative too, but not significant). The NAFTA dummy comes out significant and positive. This is a configuration much like the one we saw in the foreign 47 debt equation: foreign sources of finance have become available even to firms beyond the circle of the most clearly export oriented. The signs on Mexican tariff variables may at first blush be taken to represent simple time trends. However, mxtariff remains highly significant even though we include the NAFTA dummy, and its interaction with intinputs has also a negative sign (although it is not significant). This then suggests that trade liberalization is associated with a higher rate of ADR issue. Table 20 also indicates that larger firms are more likely to issue ADRs. Looking at the sector-specific coefficients, communications and transportation is again remarkable for its use of foreign financing despite being largely oriented to the domestic market. Investment equations As a final exercise we look at some investment equations. The first set consists of regressions from our panel of firms listed in the stock exchange; the second reports regressions made using data from the Annual Industrial Survey collected by the Mexican Statistics Institute. We take as a starting point the well-known model of Fazzari, Hubbard and Petersen (1988). This model has been used often to analyze Mexican investment data, as in Gelos and Werner (1998), Martínez-Trigueros (2001), Sanchez (2001), and Castillo (2002), all of whom find significant liquidity restrictions, especially in the second part of the nineties. 14.0 12.0 10.0 Percent 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 0.0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 Figure 15. Mexican tariffs on imported inputs (simple mean for all industrial classes). Source: Authors’ calculations using data from the Secretariat of the Economy. 48 Table 21 reports the results of the estimation of several investment equations for the Mexican stock exchange datat set. The ratio of investment in plant and equipment to the stock of productive assets at the start of the year is our dependent variable, and we regressed it against a measure of cash flows, given by the profitability ratio (profitab), and against the prospects for a firm, given by the change in net sales normalized by the firm’s productive assets (chgsales/k). In addition, we include the ratio of exports to sales and two trade-related measures of NAFTA . The first one is the sector-specific tariff advantage defined earlier (UStariffadv), which measures the difference between the average tariffs imposed by the US on imports from Mexico and from Mercosur. We don’t use this variable in isolation, but interacted with the export ratio and with profitab. The second measure of NAFTA is the annual average tariff on inputs imported by Mexican firms for the period 1990-2000 that we introduced before (Mxtariff). In Figure 15 we can see the evolution of average Mexican tariffs during the sample period. We use this variable by itself, but also interacted with the ratio of intermediate inputs to sales, since the benefit from liberalization of imports should be proportional to the importance of intermediate inputs (which are our best approximation to the tradable component of costs). In general, a positive and significant coefficient on profitab is interpreted as an indication of liquidity restrictions; we have interacted profitab with a NAFTA dummy as a Chow test of the stability of the coefficient on this variable, and also with the US tariff advantage variable. Table 21 shows two sets of regressions: the top panel has OLS models including sector dummies, and the bottom panel has fixed-effects regressions where the fixed effect is taken to exist at the level of the firm, thus eliminating the sector dummies. In each panel, the main difference among the various models is the way we model NAFTA. The first model includes only trade-related measures of NAFTA; the next two models include a NAFTA dummy interacted with profitab and also by itself; and the final two models substitute Ustariffadv for the NAFTA dummy in the interactions with profitab. One of the main results from the investment equations of Table 21 is that liquidity restrictions seemed to be relatively unimportant in the first part of the sample but became important in the NAFTA period, as evidenced by the instability of the parameter for profitability, which becomes significant and positive in the more recent part of the sample. This change is totally clear in models 2 and 3, where the interaction of NAFTA and profitab is positive and significant; but the positive sign of the coefficient of the interaction of profitab and UStariffadv in models 4 and 5 can also be interpreted this way, since the tariff advantage tended to grow after NAFTA went into force, and this temporal dimension of the variability of UStariffadv may well be the effect being captured in this coefficient. The initial situation, in which liquidity restrictions were not a problem, is likely a reflection of the nature of our sample, consisting of firms large and sophisticated enough to be listed in the stock exchange. The appearance of liquidity restrictions in the NAFTA period doubtless reflects the temporal coincidence of the banking crisis and the entry into effect of the trade agreement. It is in fact a measure of the severity of the banking crisis and its aftereffects that this set of firms shows evidence of liquidity constraints in the post-1994 period. The other standard component of the typical investment equation, the change in net sales, is an important determinant of investment through the sample period, and shows a stable and significant coefficient across all model specifications. 49 Table 21. Investment Equations for the Sample of Listed Firms 1 Coefficient t statiistic 2 Coefficient t statiistic 3 Coefficient t statiistic 4 Coefficient t statiistic 5 Coefficient t statiistic OLS regressions change sales / k profitab profitab*nafta profitab*UStariffadv rintsect exportrt exportrt*UStariffadv mxtariff mxtariff*intinput nafta manufactures construction commerce commun. & transprt. services constant 0.0082 0.0531 3.607 2.423 0.0082 -0.1475 0.2393 3.639 -2.917 4.397 0.0080 -0.0660 0.1455 3.564 -1.272 2.594 0.0339 0.0119 -0.0034 -0.4534 -0.0141 4.606 2.818 -1.439 -10.695 -0.305 0.0355 0.0111 -0.0033 -0.3797 -0.0474 4.839 2.638 -1.400 -8.363 -1.019 -0.4674 -0.5803 -0.3206 0.3676 -0.1764 4.1945 -2.252 -1.982 -1.199 0.800 -0.539 12.181 -0.4513 -0.4842 -0.2757 0.3368 -0.2423 3.8037 -2.184 -1.657 -1.035 0.736 -0.743 10.740 0.0573 0.0085 -0.0033 -0.1084 -0.0210 1.7474 -0.4914 -0.6097 -0.3779 0.2682 -0.3348 0.2162 7.079 2.033 -1.415 -1.718 -0.453 6.128 -2.398 -2.099 -1.428 0.591 -1.035 0.317 No. Obs F statistic F stat d.f. Adjusted R2 2,061 30.14 12, 2048 0.145 2,061 29.56 13, 2047 0.153 0.0082 0.0387 3.616 1.377 0.0079 0.0467 3.543 1.680 0.0176 0.0342 0.0120 -0.0036 -0.4508 -0.0166 0.821 4.639 2.845 -1.500 -10.603 -0.358 -0.4643 -0.6080 -0.2984 0.3629 -0.1693 4.1833 -2.237 -2.063 -1.110 0.790 -0.517 12.138 0.0117 0.0590 0.0088 -0.0035 -0.1178 -0.0009 1.9434 -0.5029 -0.6964 -0.3998 0.2747 -0.3033 0.0267 0.553 7.302 2.086 -1.478 -1.867 -0.019 7.068 -2.451 -2.389 -1.503 0.605 -0.936 0.039 2,061 30.62 14, 2046 0.168 2,061 27.87 13, 2047 0.145 2,061 30.07 14, 2046 0.165 Fixed effects regressions change sales / k profitab profitab*nafta profitab*UStariffadv rintsect exportrt exportrt*UStariffadv mxtariff mxtariff*intinput nafta constant No. Obs No. groups (firms) F statistic F stat d.f. R2 within between overall F stat. firm effects F stat d.f. 0.0083 0.0301 3.543 1.210 0.0084 -0.1042 0.1466 3.573 -1.625 2.273 0.0089 -0.0257 0.0605 3.803 -0.390 0.908 0.0260 0.0265 -0.0006 -0.3708 -0.0534 3.621 3.472 -0.210 -6.781 -0.804 0.0279 0.0259 -0.0008 -0.3149 -0.0864 3.862 3.401 -0.278 -5.259 -1.273 3.2057 8.846 2.9678 7.877 0.0485 0.0218 -0.0012 -0.0786 -0.0629 1.5320 -0.1996 5.778 2.862 -0.432 -1.012 -0.930 4.736 -0.260 2061 366 32.24 7, 1688 0.118 0.194 0.135 1.80 365, 1688 2061 366 28.93 8, 1687 0.121 0.204 0.142 1.76 365, 1687 2061 366 28.53 9, 1686 0.132 0.222 0.159 1.73 365, 1686 0.0084 -0.0159 3.563 -0.475 0.0089 -0.0092 3.816 -0.276 0.0488 0.0273 0.0268 -0.0010 -0.3624 -0.0569 2.047 3.785 3.509 -0.366 -6.616 -0.858 3.1593 8.709 0.0413 0.0494 0.0222 -0.0015 -0.0864 -0.0521 1.5782 -0.2405 1.741 5.895 2.904 -0.542 -1.122 -0.791 5.065 -0.316 2061 366 28.79 8, 1687 0.120 0.186 0.133 1.82 365, 1687 2061 366 28.81 9, 1686 0.133 0.210 0.156 1.76 365, 1686 Export orientation contributes positively to investment, as evidenced by the sign and strong t statistics of the coefficient on exportrt in all models. Naturally, one of the main effects of NAFTA has been to increase the export rate of Mexican firms, and this is clearly true of the firms in this sample (see Table 11), and thus the trade agreement can be credited, indirectly, with some of the impulse to investment. The interaction of the export term with Ustariffadv, however, is insignificant and has the wrong sign in all models, indicating that this variable does not have other independent effects beyond its influence on exports. However, NAFTA’s other more direct impacts can be appreciated by looking at the reduction of costs faced by Mexican firms as a result of the reduction in Mexican tariffs. The mxtariff variable is consistently negative and significant, suggesting that the liberalization of imports was an incentive to invest. Moreover, this result is robust to the inclusion of the NAFTA dummy (compare models 3 and 5 to models 2 and 4), indicating that mxtariff is not just acting as a time trend. The interaction of Mexican tariffs with with the tradable component of costs (intinputs) has the expected negative sign, but is not significant. Regarding the different sectors, the only remarkable finding is the rise in investment in communications and transportation 50 after NAFTA, which reflects activity in telephony. More surprisingly, and consistent with our discussion of Figure 5 earlier in this document, manufacturing had a below par performance. In sum, the stability of most coefficients across models, and the increase in the importance of our measure of cash flow point to a hardening of liquidity constraints. This effect, due to the banking crisis, counteracted the positive effects expected from NAFTA and which acted, directly, through the positive investment effects of the reduction of tariffs on imported inputs used by Mexican firms, and indirectly through the power of exports to explain investment and the rise in exports due to the free trade agreement. Our second set of investment equations uses a different data set. Table 22 below reports the results from a series of regressions of the ratio of investment during a given year to productive capital at the start of the year for a panel put together using investment and cash-flow information from INEGI’s Annual Industrial Survey and the mean tariffs on imported inputs inputs by industrial class produced by the Secretariat of the Economy for the period 1990-1999.29 The dataset covers 111 industrial classes and is organized following INEGI’s 1994 classification, into which we have assimilated the data for groups of establishments organized according to the 1984 classification. The post-1994 surveys include 204 classes, but the number of classes in our sample dropped to 120 upon matching of the 1994 and 1984 classifications, and further to 111 upon matching with the Mexican tariff database, which is organized according to the 1994 classification. Although the data from our two sources correspond to the same industrial classes, they do not correspond to the same respondents.30 The 111 classes in our sample comprised well over 4000 establishments (either firms or geographically independent production facilities owned by a firm) employing nearly one million people in 1998-1999. This sample comprises large and medium firms, with an average payroll of 268 employees in 1998-1999 (by contrast, the average payroll in the stock exchange sample had over 2000 employees). Thus, this is a much broader sample than the one we have explored so far. The simple average across classes of the ratio of exports to sales grew from 13.6 percent in 1994 to between 20.6 and 21.6 percent throughout the 1995-1999 period. This growth reflects the change in export behavior of most classes, even those with a moderate outward orientation. This is made clear by observing that the percentage of classes selling less than 5 percent of their production abroad dropped from 41.9 percent of all classes in 1994 to 22.8 percent in the period 1995-1999, and that the proportion of all classes selling over 20 percent of their output abroad grew from 23.3 percent to 39.1 percent between those two periods. We estimated investment equations for this data set along the lines of the Fazzari, Hubbard and Petersen (1988) framework: the investment ratio is regressed against a measure of cash flows (computed as paid out profits plus depreciation allowances), a measure of the prospects for the firms in each class in the form of the change in their sales over capital, and a real interest rate as a general measure of conditions in credit 29 The industrial survey data are produced by the Mexican Statistical Institute (INEGI), and the cash-flow and investment variables were kindly shared with us by Oscar Sánchez, who used them in a study of the effects of the banking crisis on liquidity constraints among firms (Sánchez, 2001). 30 The investment, cash-flow and sales data corresponds to samples of establishments surveyed by INEGI, whereas the tariff data correspond to national averages for the same classes. 51 markets (in this case the US real interest rate we have used in other parts of this section31). The main differences among the various models we fitted were in the way NAFTA is specified in each one of them. In all of them we have included the average tariff paid on imports purchased by the firms in the class. Largely as a result of NAFTA, the average tariff on class imports (among all classes in our sample) fell from 12.4 percent in 1990 to 8.9 percent in 1994 and further to 5.91 percent in 1999 (see Figure 15). Thus, this is a direct measure of NAFTA in our regressions, where it is called “Mex tariff.” We expect its influence on investment to be negative. In some models, we have interacted the “Mex tariff” variable with the cash-flow variable to produce a new regressor. A positive coefficient on this interaction term indicates a lessening of the severity of the liquidity restriction when tariffs fall (the combined coefficient in front of the cash-flow variable shrinks if tariffs decline). This would indicate that trade liberalization has been associated with some degree of relaxation in the liquidity constraints facing firms, given that tariffs have been falling in almost every single year and class in the sample, especially since the entry into effect of NAFTA, since the largest drop in tariffs is clearly linked to the entry into effect of NAFTA, as the dip in 1994 in the average tariff curve shown in Figure 17 indicates. Lastly, we have included in some specifications both a NAFTA dummy and its interaction with the cash-flow term as a possible test of the stability of the coefficients. Table 22 reports the results of the estimation of the investment equations. The top half of the table shows simple OLS regressions, and the bottom half the corresponding models estimated using fixed effects; t-statistics are reported to the right of the corresponding coefficient. In all models the standard cash flows and sales variables have the expected signs and are strongly significant. Altogether, the simple interpretation of the coefficients on the cash flow variable is that the equivalent of between 13 and 21 cents out of every peso in cash flows is directed to investment. Similarly, the real interest rate variable has the expected negative sign in most cases, although it is not significant in some of the specifications. The first measure of NAFTA effects, the Mex tariffs variable, has the expected negative sign in all but one model, and it comes out significant in most cases. This supports the hypothesis that trade liberalization, and therefore NAFTA, has contributed to increase investment. The more difficult issue is whether liquidity restrictions have become more or less severe since the entry into effect of NAFTA. Here our preferred specifications are those in columns 3 and 4, both of which are robust to the choice between fixed effects and OLS. The interaction between cash flows and tariffs has the expected positive sign and is statistically significant in both regressions, suggesting that trade liberalization within the North American region has helped Mexican firms become less dependent on their own cash for the financing of investment. This is true regardless of whether we include a NAFTA dummy in the regression. The coefficient on this dummy turns out significant and positive, and it takes away some of the explanatory power of the Mex tariff regressor, but without rendering it insignificant (although it does make the coefficient on interest rates insignificant). 31 We have chosen the US real interest rate for various reasons. For one, it was virtually impossible to construct class-specific interest rates as we did with the listed firms data because of the difficulty of matching the list of industrial classes to the lists of elements in the baskets that compose the major price indexes. In addition, the US rate has the advantage of being fully exogenous to the estimated equations. 52 Table 22. Investment Equations for the Annual Industrial Survey Data 1 Coefficientt-statistic 2 Coefficientt-statistic 3 Coefficientt-statistic 4 Coefficient t-statistic OLS regressions cash flow / K cashflow*tariff cashflow*nafta sales chng. / K US real interest Mex tariff nafta dummy constant 0.1436 8.400 0.2161 10.950 0.0950 0.0208 -0.0859 -0.0310 4.846 6.167 -0.975 -0.516 8.5790 10.248 -0.0314 0.0196 0.0535 0.0543 7.6702 2.7808 -1.187 5.928 0.604 0.904 6.937 2.375 No. Observations F statistic F test, d.f. Adj. R2 1,104 60.830 5, 1098 0.213 0.1257 0.0082 5.116 3.370 0.1246 0.0087 5.239 3.728 0.0217 -0.1598 -0.3515 6.419 -1.828 -3.778 11.8529 11.482 0.0191 0.0487 -0.2025 6.8534 5.5019 5.832 0.553 -2.207 8.591 4.425 1,104 60.890 6, 1097 0.246 1104 57.790 5, 1098 0.205 1,104 63.660 6, 1097 0.254 Fixed effects regressions cash flow / K cashflow*tariff cashflow*nafta sales chng. / K US real interest Mex tariff nafta dummy constant 0.1763 8.495 0.2254 9.824 0.1070 0.0160 -0.0148 -0.3185 5.261 5.068 -0.184 -3.073 9.7324 8.163 0.0236 0.0154 0.0639 -0.1110 5.4127 4.3644 0.089 4.890 0.787 -0.997 4.790 2.683 No. Observations F stat for class dummies F test, d.f. F statistic regressors F test, d.f. R2 within between overall 1,104 3.180 110,988 57.930 5,988 0.227 0.188 0.203 1,104 2.940 110, 987 53.180 6, 987 0.244 0.252 0.239 0.1882 0.0045 6.139 1.578 0.1963 0.0048 6.558 1.746 0.0166 -0.0671 -0.7150 5.183 -0.831 -5.603 13.8637 10.433 0.0153 0.0662 -0.2661 6.0954 5.3798 4.870 0.817 -1.908 7.142 3.059 1104 3.010 110, 988 51.600 5, 988 0.207 0.156 0.175 1,104 2.830 110,987 53.670 6,987 0.246 0.274 0.247 The specifications in columns 1 and 2 of Table 22 are distinguished by the use of an interaction between the NAFTA dummy and the cash flow regressor. This specification is not robust to the inclusion of a NAFTA dummy, and that is one of the reasons we find it suspect: the coefficient on the interaction term changes sign and becomes insignificant between models 1 and 2 in the OLS regression, and the coefficient on Mex tariff becomes insignificant upon inclusion of the NAFTA dummy in the fixed-effect regressions and changes sign (while remaining insignificant) in the OLS regressions. The use of a NAFTA dummy, by reducing horizontal heterogeneity, seems to increase the difference between the OLS and fixed effects regressions. In this sense, the fixed effects models should be considered more reliable, and in fact the F-statistic for the joint significance of fixed effects is higher for the models in columns 1 and 2 than in their counterpart models in columns 3 and 4. These fixed effects models do show that the reduction of tariffs raises investment, but they now show an intensification of the liquidity restrictions after NAFTA went into effect (the interaction of cash flow and NAFTA has a positive coefficient). Since the NAFTA dummy is just a time dummy, 53 this coefficient may be capturing other effects, such as those of the banking system crisis and its aftermath. In short, our investment equations for data on industrial classes indicate that NAFTA had a favorable effect on investment by reducing the severity of liquidity constraints. The results from the regression using data from listed firms are broadly consistent with these findings insofar as investment is positively affected by export behavior and by the reduction in Mexican tariffs. A remarkable result of those regressions is that even relatively large and sophisticated firms as those listed in the stock exchange experienced, on average, an intensification of liquidity constraints in the aftermath of the banking crisis. Final Remarks In this paper we have looked for evidence of changes in financing patterns that might be related to the negotiation and entry into effect of the North American free trade agreement. This is a task made difficult by the concurrent influence of other events during the nineties such as the intensification of international capital flows, and the liberalization of financial markets and the banking crisis in Mexico. All in all, however, at the end of this exercise it is possible to propose some tentative conclusions. The arrival of NAFTA coincided with a transformation of the capital account of the balance of payments in Mexico. The most salient features of this transformation are the decline in importance of capital flows related to the operations of the public sector (with the exception of the 1995 rescue), and the declining role of Mexican banks in the intermediation of external funds. First, a boom in portfolio flows into the stock exchange was observed during the period of negotiation of the free trade agreement. It is difficult to gauge, however, the extent to which these inflows were motivated by investors’ desire to take positions in anticipation of the agreement, given the coincidence of a strong privatization program at the time and the normalization of the Mexican government’s borrower status. (Additionally, some indirect evidence against the role of an anticipation of NAFTA comes from the evolution of sector-specific stock indexes.) And second, foreign direct investment series show at list two clear jumps, one when negotiations of NAFTA get underway and another when the agreement goes into effect. In fact, during the NAFTA years FDI has been by far the most important component of the capital account of Mexico’s balance of payments. Free-trade agreements, as well as the anticipation created in the run up to their adoption, have a positive influence on foreign direct investment. This presumption is supported by the analysis of a multi-country panel data set. In the case of Mexico, NAFTA seems not only to have helped increase FDI by some two thirds of what it would have been in a counterfactual scenario without NAFTA, but it may even have prevented a sharper drop in the share of global FDI going to Mexico. Such a drop might have been a natural result of the winding down of Mexico’s privatization program, which coincided with a boom in international mergers and acquisitions operations. Moreover, the combination of the rules of origin under NAFTA and the promise of access to a large regional market seems to have increased Mexico’s appeal to foreign investors coming from outside North America. However, in spite of all these positive factors, foreign direct investment seems to have been relatively low in recent years, perhaps as a result of the apparent 54 halt in the structural reform process in Mexico. In contrast, reforms have continued apace in other countries, especially in Europe. The fact that Mexico is lagging behind other countries in the structural reform effort is preventing that country from taking full advantage of the opportunities afforded by NAFTA for the promotion of investment in Mexico. At the level of individual firms listed in the Mexican exchange, it is easy to identify a strengthening of exports and of foreign financing, although a significant number of the firms in our sample remain clearly oriented toward domestic product and financial markets. On balance, however, the data suggest that the group of firms using only domestic credit is shrinking faster than the group of firms selling only to domestic customers. In this regard, the effect of NAFTA as a promoter of foreign financing seems to be stronger among firms that are relatively outward oriented to begin with, and the search for foreign resources can assume many forms, including bank debt, suppliers’ credit and the issue of ADRs. In fact, the data suggests that domestic bank credit, which fell after the Mexican banking crisis of 1995, has been replaced in part by domestic suppliers credit among domestically oriented firms, and by foreign bank financing among outward oriented firms. But the liquidity crunch due to the banking crisis has counteracted some of the positive effects on investment and financing we might have expected from NAFTA. These findings are highly tentative, though, especially because they are based on the analysis of a sample of large and modern firms. The examination of broader data sets is needed to confirm those results. As a first step in this direction, we estimated investment equations for a data set of firms grouped by industrial classes from the Annual Industrial Survey. Those equations indicate that reductions in tariffs on imported inputs –largely associated with NAFTA—are linked to a lessening of liquidity restrictions on investment by private firms during the nineties. This result confirms that the benefits from trade liberalization may have included better access to credit, other things equal. 55 References Banco de Mexico (1996, 1997, 1998) The Mexican Economy, Mexico D.F. Bajo-Rubio, O. and C. López-Pueyo (1997) “An Industry Análisis of Foreign Direct Investment in Spanish Manufacturing, 1986-1992”, Documento de Trabajo 9804, Universidad de Navarra Berzosa, C. (2000) “México y España ante dos procesos de integración” Comercio Exterior, agosto, pp. 718-723 Borja Tamayo, A. (2001) “El TLCAN y la inversión extranjera directa: el nuevo escenario” in A. Borja Tamayo, ed., Para evaluar el TLCAN, México: Miguel Angel Porrúa, 2001, 269-309 Calderón, C. N. Loayza and L. Servén (2002) “Greenfield FDI vs. Mergers and Acquisitions: Does the Distinction Matter?” mimeo, World Bank Castillo, R. (2002), “Restricciones de Liquidez, el Canal de Crédito y la Inversión en México” mimeo Congressional Budget Office (1993) Estimating the Effects of NAFTA: An Assessment of the Economic Models and Other Empirical Studies, Washington DC, 96 p. Cuevas, A., M. Messmacher and A. Werner (2002), “Macroeconomic Synchronization Between Mexico and its Nafta Partners,” mimeo, Banco de Mexico Dussel Peters, E., L.M. Galindo Paliza, and E. Loria Díaz (2002) “Visión Microeconómica de los impactos de la Integración Regional en la Inversión Inter e Intraregionales,” mimeo, Facultad de Economía, UNAM Fazzari, S., G. hubbard and B. Petersen (1988), “Financing Constraints and Corporate Investment,” in Brookings papers on Economic Activity, 1988:1, pp. 141-205 Fernández de Cordoba, G. And T. Kehoe (1999) “Capital Flows and Exchange Rate Fluctuations Following Spain’s Entry into the European Community” Frankel, J. A. and S. Wei (1998) “Regionalization of World Trade and Currencies: Economics and Politics” in J.A. Frankel, ed., The Regionalization of the World Economy, Chicago: University of Chicago, 1998, pp.189-219 Garber, P. and S. Lall (1996) “Derivative Products in Exchange Rate Crises,” presented at the Conference on managing Capital Flows organized by the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Gelos, G. and A. Werner (1998), “La Inversión Fija en el Sector Manufacturero Mexicano 1985-1994,” Documento de Investigación 9805, DGIE, Banco de México. 56 González-Anaya, J. A. And G. Marrufo (2001) “Financial Market Performance in Mexico,” paper prepared for the Mexican Credit Conference organized by the Center for Research on Economic Development and Policy Reform, Stanford university, October, 2001 Green, W. (1990) Econometric Analysis New York: MacMillan Hernández, F. and A. Villagomez (2001) “El sector financiero mexicano en el tratado de libre comercio: una evaluación preliminar” in A. Borja Tamayo, ed., Para evaluar el TLCAN, México: Miguel Angel Porrúa, 143-180 Kehoe, P. and T. Kehoe (1994a) “Capturing NAFTA’s Impact with Applied General Equilibrium Models” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review v.18, n.1 (Spring) Kehoe, P. and T. Kehoe (1994b) “A Primer on Static Applied General Equilibrium Models” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review v.18, n.1 (Spring) Krugman, P. and G. Hanson (1993) “Mexico-US Free Trade and the Location of Production” in P. Garber, ed., The Mexico-US Free trade Agreement, Cambridge, Ma: The MIT Press, 1993, 163-186 Levy Yeyati, E. E. Stein and C. Daude (2001) “Regional Integration and the location of FDI” mimeo Mayer, F.W. (2001) “Juego de dos niveles: las negociaciones del TLCAN” in A. Borja Tamayo, ed., Para evaluar el TLCAN, México: Miguel Angel Porrúa, 2001, 47-100 Morley, S., R. Machado and S. Pettinato (1999) “Indexes of Structural Reform in Latin America,” mimeo available at ECLAC’s internet website. Oyarzún de la Iglesia, J. (2000) “México en el TLCAN, España en la Unión Europea: balance de la integración,” in Comercio Exterior, agosto, pp. 688-710 Petersen, M. And R. Rajan (1996) “Trade Credit: Theories and Evidence” NBER Working paper 5602, 41p. Sanchez, O. (2001), “The Transmission of Monetary Policy and the Behavior of manufacturing Firms in Mexico,” paper prepared for the Mexican Credit Conference organized by the Center for Research on Economic Development and Policy Reform, Stanford University, October, 2001. Serra Puche, J.J. (1992) Conclusión de la Negociación del Tratado de Libre Comercio entre México Canadá y Estados Unidos, México DF: SECOFI,, 80p. Serrano, C. (2001), “The Role of commercial banks in the Provision of Credit to Small and Medium Enterprises in Mexico,” paper prepared for the Mexican Credit Conference organized by the Center for Research on Economic Development and Policy Reform, Stanford university, October, 2001. 57 Trigueros Martínez, L. (2001), Did Public Firms Take the Role of Banks After the 1995 Mexican Crisis?” paper prepared for the Mexican Credit Conference organized by the Center for Research on Economic Development and Policy Reform, Stanford University, October, 2001. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (2000, 2001) Global Investment Report, available in electronic version on the internet. Waldkirch, A. (2001)”The New Regionalism and Foreign Direct Investment: The Case of Mexico,” mimeo, Oregon State University Wooldridge, J. (2002) Econometric Analysis of Cross-Section and Panel Data, Cambridge Ma.: The MIT Press, 752 p. World Bank (2002) Global Development Finance, Washington DC: The World Bank World Economic Forum (2000) Global Competitiveness Report 2000, Oxford University Press 58 Appendix 1. Mexico: Capital Account of the Balance of Payments 1980-2000 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 9,996 8,966 1,458 1,438 6,071 0 646 0 5,425 1,029 -2,269 317 2,223 1,900 0 -1,141 339 2,728 354 -158 2,532 0 -519 0 3,051 -2,388 1,415 -3,156 -2,309 2,192 0 -530 1,306 3,843 1,076 1,229 1,538 0 -435 0 1,973 -2,537 -416 -1,605 -1,760 1,541 0 -298 -316 1,247 1,065 293 -111 0 -596 0 485 -1,564 -939 -1,283 -1,231 1,984 0 -93 2,716 2,360 1,580 714 66 0 -519 0 585 355 -732 0 -1,481 2,401 0 167 -1,189 3,529 768 428 2,333 0 -934 0 3,267 -4,718 47 -3,885 -2,531 2,635 0 -983 -1,163 -1,045 -1,059 -94 108 -693 1,389 0 -587 -118 1,380 -74 -2,928 2,880 0 -1,376 3,176 791 -299 1,677 -586 -56 -149 0 -381 2,385 980 -177 -1,157 3,176 493 -930 8,297 -865 4,810 -365 -5,310 -7,354 277 0 1,767 9,162 4,384 761 397 2,633 1,994 -1,007 In percentage of the external current account Capital Account 109.0 163.8 169.7 -5.8 Consolidated Public Sector 34.7 112.6 152.2 -46.6 Development Banks 5.9 46.2 24.7 -6.0 Central Bank -1.3 0.0 24.4 2.7 Nonfinancial Public Sector 30.1 66.4 103.1 -43.2 Guarantees 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Titled Debt Issued Abroad 0.6 6.1 11.0 8.9 Money Market 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Bank Loans Net of Deposits 29.5 60.3 92.1 -52.1 Private Sector 74.3 51.2 17.5 40.8 Commercial Banks 30.3 34.8 -38.5 -24.2 Net Variation in Bank Accounts Held Abroad by Nonbanks -7.8 -23.1 5.4 53.9 Loans to Nonbank Agents 35.9 23.7 37.7 39.4 Foreign Direct Investment 20.0 18.9 32.3 -37.4 Investment in the Stock Exchange 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 -4.2 -3.1 -19.4 9.0 Other -31.2 -91.9 -25.7 -29.4 -36.8 0.0 10.4 0.0 -47.2 60.6 9.9 38.4 42.1 -36.8 0.0 7.1 39.6 -156.0 -133.2 -36.6 13.9 0.0 74.5 0.0 -60.7 195.6 117.5 160.5 154.0 -248.1 0.0 11.6 197.7 171.9 115.0 52.0 4.8 0.0 -37.8 0.0 42.6 25.9 -53.3 0.0 -107.8 174.8 0.0 12.2 28.0 -83.3 -18.1 -10.1 -55.0 0.0 22.0 0.0 -77.1 111.3 -1.1 91.7 59.7 -62.2 0.0 23.2 -49.0 -44.0 -44.6 -4.0 4.5 -29.2 58.5 0.0 -24.7 -5.0 58.1 -3.1 -123.3 121.2 0.0 -57.9 54.6 13.6 -5.1 28.8 -10.1 -1.0 -2.6 0.0 -6.5 41.0 16.8 -3.0 -19.9 54.6 8.5 -16.0 111.4 -11.6 64.6 -4.9 -71.3 -98.7 3.7 0.0 23.7 123.0 58.8 10.2 5.3 35.3 26.8 -13.5 In millions of US dollars Capital Account 11,377 26,597 Consolidated Public Sector 3,622 18,282 Development Banks 618 7,495 Central Bank -132 0 Nonfinancial Public Sector 3,136 10,787 Guarantees 0 0 Titled Debt Issued Abroad 58 997 Money Market 0 0 Bank Loans Net of Deposits 3,078 9,790 Private Sector 7,755 8,315 Commercial Banks 3,160 5,647 Net Variation in Bank Accounts Held Abroad by Nonbanks -809 -3,754 Loans to Nonbank Agents 3,750 3,851 Foreign Direct Investment 2,090 3,076 Investment in the Stock Exchange 0 0 -436 -506 Other Composition Capital Account 100.0 Consolidated Public Sector 31.8 Development Banks 5.4 Central Bank -1.2 Nonfinancial Public Sector 27.6 Guarantees 0.0 Titled Debt Issued Abroad 0.5 Money Market 0.0 Bank Loans Net of Deposits 27.1 Private Sector 68.2 Commercial Banks 27.8 Net Variation in Bank Accounts Held Abroad by Nonbanks -7.1 Loans to Nonbank Agents 33.0 Foreign Direct Investment 18.4 Investment in the Stock Exchange 0.0 -3.8 Other Memorandum External Current Account in millions of US dollars External Current Account in percent of GDP Source: Banco de México and World bank. -10,434 -4.7 100.0 68.7 28.2 0.0 40.6 0.0 3.7 0.0 36.8 31.3 21.2 -14.1 14.5 11.6 0.0 -1.9 100.0 89.7 14.6 14.4 60.7 0.0 6.5 0.0 54.3 10.3 -22.7 3.2 22.2 19.0 0.0 -11.4 100.0 804.0 104.4 -46.7 746.2 0.0 -152.9 0.0 899.2 -704.0 417.1 -930.2 -680.7 646.0 0.0 -156.3 100.0 294.3 82.4 94.1 117.8 0.0 -33.3 0.0 151.1 -194.3 -31.8 -122.9 -134.8 118.0 0.0 -22.8 100.0 -394.1 -336.5 -92.6 35.0 0.0 188.3 0.0 -153.3 494.1 296.9 405.6 389.1 -626.9 0.0 29.4 100.0 86.9 58.2 26.3 2.4 0.0 -19.1 0.0 21.5 13.1 -26.9 0.0 -54.5 88.4 0.0 6.1 100.0 -296.9 -64.6 -36.0 -196.2 0.0 78.6 0.0 -274.8 396.9 -3.9 326.8 212.9 -221.6 0.0 82.6 100.0 89.9 91.1 8.1 -9.3 59.6 -119.4 0.0 50.5 10.1 -118.7 6.4 251.8 -247.6 0.0 118.3 100.0 24.9 -9.4 52.8 -18.5 -1.8 -4.7 0.0 -12.0 75.1 30.9 -5.6 -36.4 100.0 15.5 -29.3 100.0 -10.4 58.0 -4.4 -64.0 -88.6 3.3 0.0 21.3 110.4 52.8 9.2 4.8 31.7 24.0 -12.1 -16,241 -5.3 -5,890 -3.0 5,860 3.9 4,183 2.4 800 0.4 -1,374 -1.1 4,239 3.0 -2,376 -1.3 -5,821 -2.6 -7,451 -2.8 59 Mexico: Capital Account of the Balance of Payments 1980-2000 (cont.) 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 32,482 7,937 194 -1,175 8,918 -564 4,872 7,013 -2,402 24,545 3,328 -1,280 2,832 4,389 10,717 4,560 Capital Account Consolidated Public Sector Development Banks Central Bank Nonfinancial Public Sector Guarantees Titled Debt Issued Abroad Money Market Bank Loans Net of Deposits Private Sector Commercial Banks Net Variation in Bank Accounts Held Abroad by Nonbanks Loans to Nonbank Agents Foreign Direct Investment Investment in the Stock Exchange Other In millions of US dollars 24,507 26,419 4,336 6,874 1,651 1,175 -220 -460 2,906 6,159 -604 1,165 1,675 1,552 3,406 8,147 -1,571 -4,705 20,171 19,545 5,752 295 921 2,186 2,381 2,129 4,761 4,393 6,332 4,783 24 5,760 14,584 -142 1,329 -1,203 -268 -615 3,980 -1,942 -1,690 14,726 1,471 -3,714 1,193 10,973 4,084 720 15,406 13,326 959 13,333 -966 -662 2,994 -13,791 10,493 2,080 -4,982 -3,164 3,149 9,526 519 -2,969 4,069 -2,040 -1,246 -3,524 2,730 544 8,909 948 -7,672 6,109 -1,720 -6,055 1,968 9,185 2,801 -70 15,763 -11,420 -1,021 -3,487 -6,912 -708 -1,659 490 -5,036 27,183 -1,978 4,860 2,702 12,830 3,215 5,554 17,492 -2 240 -1,072 830 -769 198 130 1,270 17,494 -143 155 5,902 11,602 -666 643 13,537 -5,530 -765 -3,685 -1,080 -836 4,725 -942 -4,027 19,067 -1,546 -3,037 5,484 12,165 3,769 2,232 18,207 -8,651 920 -4,286 -5,285 1,290 -3,022 -25 -3,528 26,858 -2,087 3,565 8,420 13,951 447 2,563 Capital Account Consolidated Public Sector Development Banks Central Bank Nonfinancial Public Sector Guarantees Titled Debt Issued Abroad Money Market Bank Loans Net of Deposits Private Sector Commercial Banks Net Variation in Bank Accounts Held Abroad by Nonbanks Loans to Nonbank Agents Foreign Direct Investment Investment in the Stock Exchange Other In percentage of the external current account 167.3 108.1 138.8 49.2 29.6 28.1 33.9 -0.5 11.3 4.8 0.8 4.5 -1.5 -1.9 -5.0 -4.1 19.8 25.2 38.1 -0.9 -4.1 4.8 -2.4 -2.1 11.4 6.4 20.8 13.4 23.3 33.3 30.0 -6.5 -10.7 -19.3 -10.3 -5.7 137.7 80.0 104.9 49.6 39.3 1.2 14.2 5.0 6.3 8.9 -5.5 -12.5 16.3 8.7 12.1 4.0 32.5 18.0 18.8 37.0 43.2 19.6 45.8 13.8 0.2 23.6 19.5 2.4 977.1 845.2 60.8 845.6 -61.3 -42.0 189.9 -874.7 665.5 131.9 -316.0 -200.6 199.7 604.2 32.9 -188.3 174.6 -87.5 -53.5 -151.2 117.1 23.3 382.3 40.7 -329.2 262.2 -73.8 -259.8 84.5 394.2 120.2 -3.0 211.6 -153.3 -13.7 -46.8 -92.8 -9.5 -22.3 6.6 -67.6 364.9 -26.6 65.2 36.3 172.2 43.2 74.6 108.8 0.0 1.5 -6.7 5.2 -4.8 1.2 0.8 7.9 108.8 -0.9 1.0 36.7 72.2 -4.1 4.0 96.7 -39.5 -5.5 -26.3 -7.7 -6.0 33.8 -6.7 -28.8 136.2 -11.0 -21.7 39.2 86.9 26.9 15.9 102.1 -48.5 5.2 -24.0 -29.6 7.2 -17.0 -0.1 -19.8 150.6 -11.7 20.0 47.2 78.3 2.5 14.4 Capital Account Consolidated Public Sector Development Banks Central Bank Nonfinancial Public Sector Guarantees Titled Debt Issued Abroad Money Market Bank Loans Net of Deposits Private Sector Commercial Banks Net Variation in Bank Accounts Held Abroad by Nonbanks Loans to Nonbank Agents Foreign Direct Investment Investment in the Stock Exchange Other Composition 100.0 17.7 6.7 -0.9 11.9 -2.5 6.8 13.9 -6.4 82.3 23.5 3.8 9.7 19.4 25.8 0.1 Memorandum External Current Account in millions of US dollars External Current Account in percent of GDP Source: Banco de México and World bank. -14,647 -4.7 100.0 26.0 4.4 -1.7 23.3 4.4 5.9 30.8 -17.8 74.0 1.1 8.3 8.1 16.6 18.1 21.8 100.0 24.4 0.6 -3.6 27.5 -1.7 15.0 21.6 -7.4 75.6 10.2 -3.9 8.7 13.5 33.0 14.0 100.0 -1.0 9.1 -8.2 -1.8 -4.2 27.3 -13.3 -11.6 101.0 10.1 -25.5 8.2 75.2 28.0 4.9 100.0 86.5 6.2 86.5 -6.3 -4.3 19.4 -89.5 68.1 13.5 -32.3 -20.5 20.4 61.8 3.4 -19.3 100.0 -50.1 -30.6 -86.6 67.1 13.4 218.9 23.3 -188.5 150.1 -42.3 -148.8 48.4 225.7 68.8 -1.7 100.0 -72.4 -6.5 -22.1 -43.9 -4.5 -10.5 3.1 -31.9 172.4 -12.6 30.8 17.1 81.4 20.4 35.2 100.0 0.0 1.4 -6.1 4.7 -4.4 1.1 0.7 7.3 100.0 -0.8 0.9 33.7 66.3 -3.8 3.7 100.0 -40.8 -5.7 -27.2 -8.0 -6.2 34.9 -7.0 -29.8 140.8 -11.4 -22.4 40.5 89.9 27.8 16.5 100.0 -47.5 5.1 -23.5 -29.0 7.1 -16.6 -0.1 -19.4 147.5 -11.5 19.6 46.2 76.6 2.5 14.1 -24,438 -6.7 -23,399 -5.8 -29,662 -7.0 -1,577 -0.6 -2,330 -0.7 -7,448 -1.9 -16,072 -3.8 -13,995 -2.9 -17,828 60 Appendix 2. List of countries in the international panel data set. Argentina Australia Austria Belgium Bolivia Brazil Canada Colombia Chile China Denmark Ecuador Egypt Finland France Germany Hungary Iceland India Ireland Israel Italy Japan Korea (South) Malaysia Mexico Netherlands New Zealand Norway Paraguay Peru Poland Portugal Singapore South Africa Spain Sweden Switzerland Thailand Turkey Uganda United Kingdom United States Uruguay Venezuela 61 Appendix 4. Estimates of the FDI regressions using different forms of the FTA expectations variable. Note: the model in boldface is the one that appears in column 2 of Table 6 in the text. Expectation represented with dummy variable 2yr 1yr coefficient t statistic coefficient t statistic Expectation FTA RELGNIPH GDPGROWTH INFLATION BUDGETBAL CURRENT ACCT WORLD GROWTH US 1Y TBILL EXPORTS FDI WORLD GDP FTAGDP INTEGRATION CONSTANT 0.438 -1.793 0.032 0.000 -0.032 -0.041 -0.081 0.004 0.708 0.776 0.264 0.090 0.173 -15.637 R2 within between overall 1.726 -1.511 2.811 -1.425 -2.200 -3.718 -1.975 0.184 3.259 6.686 1.100 1.716 1.223 -8.393 0.406 -1.752 0.033 0.000 -0.031 -0.400 -0.081 0.006 0.690 0.770 0.280 0.102 0.173 -15.780 2.153 -1.477 2.881 -1.337 -2.159 -3.691 -1.967 0.287 3.174 6.629 1.170 1.920 1.230 -8.483 R2 within between overall 0.000 -1.809 0.032 0.000 -0.033 -0.040 -0.084 0.004 0.725 0.794 0.255 0.083 0.164 -15.703 1.564 -1.524 2.759 -1.397 -2.296 -3.676 -2.025 0.219 3.342 6.831 1.065 1.590 1.161 -8.429 0.471 0.673 0.586 0.420 -1.773 0.033 0.000 -0.030 -0.039 -0.083 0.009 0.690 0.772 0.279 0.117 0.166 -15.896 0.473 0.679 0.591 0.472 0.674 0.587 Expectation represented with leads of partner GDP 1yr 2yr coefficient t statistic coefficient t statistic Expectation FTA RELGNIPH GDPGROWTH INFLATION BUDGETBAL CURRENT ACCT WORLD GROWTH US 1Y TBILL EXPORTS FDI WORLD GDP FTAGDP INTEGRATION CONSTANT 3yr coefficient t statistic 0.000 -1.740 0.033 0.000 -0.033 -0.040 -0.080 0.008 0.723 0.791 0.249 0.091 0.171 -15.853 1.905 -1.465 2.842 -1.347 -2.328 -3.624 -1.953 0.387 3.339 6.822 1.038 1.734 1.209 -8.512 0.472 0.679 0.596 2.600 -1.499 2.924 -1.224 -2.077 -3.598 -2.024 0.450 3.183 6.663 1.168 2.156 1.181 -8.553 0.475 0.681 0.593 3yr coefficient t statistic 0.000 -1.745 0.033 0.000 -0.033 -0.039 -0.080 0.010 0.727 0.799 0.242 0.097 0.165 -15.895 1.949 -1.470 2.892 -1.308 -2.326 -3.547 -1.936 0.474 3.354 6.874 1.010 1.821 1.167 -8.532 0.472 0.684 0.591 62 Appendix 4. Computing an upper estimate of NAFTA’s contribution to FDI growth. In the body of the paper we found that a conservative estimate of NAFTA’s contribution to FDI growth was 94 percent, or roughly a doubling of this type of investment relative to what would be observed in the absence of the trade agreement. This estimate is conservative since it excludes any effects from the growth in exports, which is lumped with other “size” effects. In the paper we also suggested that a more reasonable estimate of our estimation of the “FTA effect” was an increase of about 70 percent of FDI over its counterfactual, NAFTA-less hypothetical level. In this appendix we explain how we arrived at this back-of-the-envelope estimate. The main idea is to assess the overestimation of the “size” effect, and then to transfer this quantity to our estimation of the FTA effect. We assume that the effect of NAFTA on exports has been to stimulate the growth of nonoil exports beyond its traditional rate of growth. Thus, we take the rate of growth of real nonoil exports between 1980 and 1991 (9.6 percent), and use it to project a NAFTA-free level of exports in 1999 from the starting point of 1991 –that is, just before we start measuring any anticipation effects of NAFTA. The projected amount is US$ 35 billion less than the level of exports observed in 1999. We then subtract this difference from total exports (US$127,774 million) to obtain counterfactual exports (US$89,736 million). With this counterfactual it is easy to calculate the overestimation of the size effect as the product of the coefficient of Ln(exports) in the regression (0.6897 in the case of regression 2, Table 6) and the difference between the logs of actual and counterfactual exports. The resulting quantity is 0.22735, which we add to our estimate of FTA’s contribution of 0.316. The sum, 0.543, yields the net increase of 72.1 percent upon exponentiation. 63