THE ROLE OF THE GUAYANA DEVELOPMENT CORPORATION IN VENEZUELAN INDUSTRIALIZATION: Diversification or Vertical Integration. by Antonio J. Azpurua C. Bachelor in Architecture Simon Bolivar University, Caracas Venezuela, 1980. Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements of the Degree of MASTER OF CITY PLANNING at the MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY May 1987 Antonio Azpurua 1987 The author hereby grants to MIT permission to reproduce and to distribute copies of this thesis document in whole or in part. Signature of Author Department of Uban studies and Planning. May 8, 1987. Certified by Lauren Benton. Professor, Urban Studies and Planning. Thesis Advisor. Accepted by e VPhilip L. Cl y. Associate Professor, Urban Studies and Plann rIg. Director, Master's Prog am. MEASSACHUSETT-JS INS'MtyrE OF TECHNOLOGY JUN 0R 1987 LIBRA i:O_ S THE ROLE OF THE GUAYANA DEVELOPMENT CORPORATION IN VENEZUELAN INDUSTRIALIZATION Diversification or Vertical Integration by Antonio J. Azpurua C. Submitted to the department of Urban Planning on May 8th, 1987 in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Degree of Master of City Planning ABSTRACT: examines the Venezuelan Industrialization thesis This that la Corporacion the role Process from 1936-1986 and played in this process. The study (CVG) Venezolana de Guayana weight the relative position of the main players in this process: the government, the state-owned enterprises, and the private sector, in order to understand how these players interact, and help one to recognize the growing importance of the public sector. The current economic crisis is seen as a consequence of the industrial strategy of import substitution followed by the Government since 1961, and the emphasis on resource based industrialization since 1973. CVG and its industrial program for Ciudad Guayana was found to have played a major role in both periods. The thesis describes the political and institutional aspects of the industrial development coordinated by the state and base in Guayana since 1973. It explores the idea that the current industrial strategy is based on previous investments but does not satisfy the expectations of the private sector. The thesis concludes that the role of the CVG has to be seen Social Democratic of the in close relation to the role abandon the never will Democracy Social governments. The the idea, formulated leaders its because Guayana, of development for its responsible feel always will and program, launched the industrial the by expressed are goals party's The progress. strategy used to overcome the current economic recession, while attempting to retain an public image of successful development. The idea of the state as an engine of growth will not be sustained by the current strategy followed by CVG if it does not prove to be the best pathway towards progress and the production of capital goods. THE ROLE OF THE GUAYANA DEVELOPMENT CORPORATION IN VENEZUELAN INDUSTRIALIZATION: Diversification or Vertical Integration. TABLE OF CONTENTS ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS 1) INTRODUCTION 2) INDUSTRIALIZATION IN VENEZUELA 2.1) 1936-1958 period: Towards Democracy. 2.1.1) 1936-1945: Post General Juan Vicente Gomez dictatorship 2.1.2) 1945-1958: Struggle for power and dictatorship. 2.2) 1958-1973 period: Democratic era I. Rise and decline of the political pact. 2.2.1) The political pact 2.2.2) The democracy and the economic plans 2.2.3) The role of "La Corporacion Venezolana Fomento" 2.2.4) The industrial state and role of "La Corporacion Venezolana de Guayana" 2.3) 1973-1983 period: Democratic era II. Political economy of petrodollars. 2.4) 1983-1987 period: Democratic era III. Crisis and devaluation. de 3) THE OUTCOME OF THE INDUSTRIALIZATION PROCESS 4) CORPORACION VENEZOLANA DE GUAYANA 4.1) Introduction 4.1.1) Objectives 4.1.2) Goals 4.1.3) Industrial development 4.2) Organizational evolution. 4.3) New leadership - Leopoldo Sucre Figarella ( 1983- ? ) 4.4) Recent economic objectives. 4.5) Division of Industrial and Mining Promotion ("Gerencia de promocion Industrial y Minero"). 4.5.1) Import substitution committee-CVG and promotion of new industries. 4.5.2) Identification of new investment opportunities, promotion of new industries and the implementation strategy. 5) CONCLUSIONS 6) BIBLIOGRAPHY Annex 1: List of interviews done in Ciudad Guayana, Caracas and Cambridge. Annex 2: List of abbreviations. ii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: This thesis has been help of many people. completed I would with like the to encouragement and thank all those who contributed, in one way or another, to its realization. My advisor, addition to Dr. Lauren Benton, deserves special thanks. In her useful comments on earlier drafts of the thesis, she helped to place many ideas in this perspectives. Dr. Institute for questions that Richard Auty, International led me to project in their correct visiting scholar at the Harvard Development, revise assumptions. Carlos Sosa Franco, or raised fundamental strengthen my original with whom I discussed many of the ideas contained in this thesis also deserves special mention. I must thank the Corporacion Venezolana de Guayana, for giving me their support and help during my visit to their offices in Ciudad Guayana and Caracas, special thanks Delgado and Rafael Pena Alvarez. Mariscal de Ayacucho", go to Maria Engracia de I am grateful to "Fundacion Gran for providing me with financial assistance for the duration of my graduate studies. I also wish to thank Shubhada Bhave, Adela Illarramendi and Susie Macksey, who revised previous drafts and helped me to put the thesis together; Roberto Smith, for his friendship and advice on some of the topics covered in this thesis; Alberto Cantor, for his friendship, for convincing me to iii come to United States of America to study, and for his moral support during the difficult first period of my stay here. I wish to express my appreciation to many others. My friends and classmates among them, Marisela Montoliou, Shubhada Bhave, Anthony K.C. IP, Hideo Obitsu, Jeff Hyman, C.Y. Nunez Ollero; the Professors at the faculty of Urban Studies and Planning for their support during the time of my studies, particulary Alan Strout, Lloyd Rodwin, Al van Huyck, adviser; and the members and Ralph Gakenheimer my academic of the Department of Urban Studies and Planning administrative staff, among them, Rolph Engler, Carol Escrich, Mary Grenham, Kathy Rynn, and Jeanne Winbush. Finally I am especially patience, understanding and making this thesis possible. who supported and encouraged grateful to my wife Vivian, for her support I am me and difficulties that I encountered. iv which were invaluable for also grateful to my parents, helped me to overcome many I) INTRODUCTION: The purpose of this thesis is to explain the current and future role of the State's Guayana Development Corporation (CVG) in the industrialization of Venezuela. In order to understand the CVG's mission it is necessary to examine recent recognize the main players in the process, identify strengths and weaknesses special the Guayana attention to industrialization process and into the strong links the players' and understand how they interact. We will concentrate on paying history, the Development Corporation, political trying between to the dimension of this provide Social some insights Democratic Party, "Accion Democratica", the democratic development of Venezuela and the Guayana Development Corporation. We will see how the success of Venezuela's democratic process the Venezuelan and of government sufficient spur a regional development program beyond the dimensions encountered scope of in of the any projects their for 1980. If it is to industry gave wealth and power enough to in Guayana conservative launched implementation from becoming a major export center, the oil which economic and the went far measure. The difficulties have prevented the region as was initially projected become such an export center in the near future, it will be at a very high cost to the nation. Today, when financial resources have become scarce as a result of the decline in oil prices, Venezuelan industrialization has to accomplish two simultaneous stage of tasks: advance into a next import substitution and achieve vertical integration of the oversized Guayana complex. Even with diminished economic capabilities, the state seeks to promote the reinforcement of the state-owned enterprises, sector, which particularly supported the in Guayana. state in its industrial strategy of import substitution, seems skeptical at this state's goals, new CVG strategy. must In order convince opportunities exist The private the to point regarding the accomplish its industrial private sector that real in the development of Guayana. This would be proved by showing profits from installed plants, prioritizing and facilitating future projects, and providing business guarantees in order to reduce risks for private investors. From the private sector's point required investments is still of so great view, control and the state. In the midst prevalent since the project has yet to projects, where it where it is not completely dependent on of the 1970's, place all investments in magnitude of that it tends to prefer diversifying its investments in alternative has greater the one achieve worldwide there economic uncertainty is a natural reluctance to concentrated sector. The Guayana the profitable results that would encourage the private sector to participate in the process. Also, CVG is in many ways limited by political factors that influence the decision-making process in such a way that guarantees made to private investors remain insufficient, due to the uncertain nature of that political process. The Guayana industrial program is also tied to labor movements, and flexibility must be considered not only in market terms but also in terms of the labor force. The industrial specialization mentioned before must also be seen in terms of its political risks. My research labor movements in Guayana recognized the importance of the but expressly excluded this variable as beyond the scope of the thesis. The occurred interest in 1958 of this when thesis an import is to point out that, as substitution program gained impetus, strong new alliances must be formed in order to advance in a new era of capital goods production and vertical integration of the state-owned industrial complex with the private sector. This will lead to the completion of the great export center which Guayana was meant to be. 2) INDUSTRIALIZATION IN VENEZUELA: What we expect to discover in this first is the historical interrelation between parties and the principal party private in the sector. part of the thesis the state, the political Accion Democratica, Venezuelan democracy, the sought to achieve its political program through the simultaneous promotion of social reforms (mainly a the labor land tenure reform), through inspiring movement, and also through fostering an environment in which the industrial sector could achieve time, based on nationalistic progress. At principles, the the same state has been progressively developing its natural resources. As it became stronger through the success of the democratic process, the state took further steps, nationalizing gas, oil and iron ore mines. When oil prices increased dramatically, beneficiary was the state and its administrators, who channelled an important portion of these new project, the its main development of revenues to their most prized the Guayana region. The return on this investment was meant to be more than simple profit: it would be a signal of democratic system, the state's to provide ability, within the context of a a stable and prosperous economic future for Venezuela. Thus, Guayana is the crucible of Venezuelan democracy, a symbol and image of the democratic experiment. Its progress is integral to the progress of democracy in Venezuela. Venezuelan industrialization parallels the history of the Venezuelan democratic process. The Guayana industrial a manifesto resources, of the decision to manage program is Venezuela's natural and the promise of a diversified economy. 2.1) Towards Democracy: 1936 - 1958. 2.1.1) Post J.V.Gomez-dictatorship: 1936 - 1945. The period from 1936 to 1945 was characterized by an average Per Capita Annual Growth of 7 per cent and an average annual Real Gross Domestic Product growth moderate rate of growth of was more than 3 per cent. This principally based on the dynamic expansion of petroleum investments, production and exports. After sluggish industrial growth Venezuela experienced in the late 19th century, Venezuelan industrialization process gained a renewed impetus in the second half of the 1920's and in the early 1930's. Researchers agree that an internal market was forming during the period previous to 1936, due to the impact produced by the development of the oil industry. This period also showed a reduced contribution of agriculture, and its social consequences (such as the growing migration from rural to urban areas). After the death of the Dictator Juan Vicente Gomez, during the presidency of General Lopez Contreras started to develop explicit (1936-1941), the State policies on industrialization. In 1937 the State (Venezuelan founded Industrial the Banco Bank), Industrial attached to de the Venezuela Ministry of Development, which was geared to providing capital for industrial activity within the country. During this period, important sector was the commercial one, which was of contacts with foreign most the initiator capital and closely related to banking interests. At roughly the sector was the same time (1936-45), the industrial slowly growing in size and economic power. It further increased its volume and World War II certainly production capacity after 1940, when spurred the expansion of industry in the country. Sonntag and de la constant growth of Venezuela's previous to formulating an 1936 Cruz provided (1985) internal the Industrial Plan have market objective that the in the years basis to start for Economic Development. Such a plan would make lucrative certain economic then had suggested been only crudely developed. activities that until Authors Sonntag and de la Cruz further suggest that the state seems to have understood the expectations of the growing industrial sector, and in consequence President Medina Angarita direction was put into at its disposal 60 Bs/$ at that time) created a Production Council, whose the hands of the private sector and had million Bolivars for industrial (Venezuelan currency 3.30 and agricultural investment. This was one of the first verifiable measures of direct financing of industrialization by the State. Sonntag and de la Cruz (1985) also point out that power but still especially the Venezuela's industrial experienced commercial sector increased its resistance sector. It from would other be areas, several years before the industrial sector would become dominant. The industrial during this sector must be seen as a growing force which, period, was becoming more clearly defined and starting to make specific demands of the government. 2.1.2) The period 1945 - During this 1958: period we will observe how the industrial sector was battling with the commercial sector to achieve growing importance was vital in the attempt hegemony. Its to establish a democratic government, with the common goal of fulfilling the job requirements. At the end of this period we will observe how political leaders as well as the industrial sector came together, collaborating in the effort to launch Venezuela into a new era of democratic government. The struggle for hegemony: 1945 - The Government of Medina 18, 1945, and replaced 1952. Angarita was by a military-civilian President Romulo Betancourt. During middle-income by Democratica" Bentancourt), sectors, (the led Social foresaw a overthrown on October this military Democratic junta led by political officers Party founded event, the and "Accion by Romulo "political reappraisal of the National Plan of the dominant class," which led towards "making industrial development its goal, even when industrial activities did not appear to be the most dynamic" (CENDES, Researchers agree that 1945 was Accion mainly spurred Democratica perhaps Romulo the first by the (AD). The democratic experiment of middle classes and conducted by leaders of that movement, and Betancourt more than any other, understood that a re-arrangement to stabilize the representative 1981). democracy government requi red a and move redefinition towards a of economic planning. The private sector was still at that time controlled by the commercial sector, and they remained indifferent, skeptical, even throughout reticent participated in three-year the conspiracy 1948 military coup and a rise to the power composed new period, that culminated d ictatorship, and finally in the November when a triumvirate by M. Perez Jimenez, C. Delgado Chalbaud and Llovera Paez. During these process of three years of the democratic experiment, the went beyond the initial phase of industrialization implementation. This process was of rural-to-urban experienced was migration primarily in the same type of later by the development growth which reinforced by that began the acceleration in the production 1936. The growth of consumer goods, would be recommended a few years and industrialization policies of the Economic Council of Latin America (ECLA). Clearly this was a type of import substitution understanding of industrialization. For a better the government's actions during this period, we must review Betancourt's ideas. Romulo Betancourt, leader industrialization and satisfy demand. domestic process would AD, of agricultural recognized reform Understanding were that both that necessary the to industrial be a dependant to foreign capital with the implied flight of national capital and the national for him the most important issue was contciousness, obstacles to that industrialization would provide jobs. Also, revenues would accelerate the relation to other developing recognized the he believed, industrialization countries. Even process oil in though Betancourt importance of the industrial process in progress, this recognition was not enough to mentioned before, maintain AD in power. As we the strong commercial sector ultimately joined with the young military forces to conspire against a partnership developing a whose strength was impossible democracy, in for Betancourt and Gallegos to overcome. The military most important government measure was the taken during founding of the the civilianVenezuelan Development Corporation (Corporacion Venezolana de Fomento - CVF) in 1946. Regardless of important state entity purpose was to the political financing implement regime, CVF industrialization. was the most CVF's main the industrial strategy conceived in Betancourt's economic plans, resources from the providing central a channel government to of financial the Industry. Such economic plans envisaged four steps for industrial development: First, the promotion (principally energy) of and basic consumer industries goods (import substitution). Second, the development of industries complementary to the aforementioned. Third, the developmnet of semi-heavy industry. Fourth, the production of machinery and heavy industry. Of the 149 Venezolana allocated de million Fomento towards represented 3.8 bolivars (CVF) in financing percent of handled this by the Corporacion period, 89 million were industrial projects. the National Gross This amount Income, 2.26 percent of which was for promotion of industrialization. However, CVF was not the only entity industrialization, others were the in "Banco charge of financing Industrial" and the Ministry of Development itself. The financing measures protective tariff and tax this State period the described above relief policies. began to were flanked by In addition, during participate more directly in industrialization by investing in various enterprises, a tendency that was to continue throughout the years of the dictatorship and 10 intensify with the advent of representative democracy after January 23, 1958. The skepticism and distrust of the private sector towards in AD's economic plan contributed to shaping the events of the next several years. In November 1948 a coup d'etat preempted the model of representative democracy built in 1945. Although with regime the state became the new more rigid, the ensuing authoritarian government kept in motion the economic development plan that had been forming since the beginning of the 40's. We have to emphasize again between the dominant classes and land ownership, that the existing antagonism traditionally with an related insurgent to commerce class promoting industrialization. Because the state's acceptance of new national objectives, proposed by those who were at the time committed to the industrialization process, would signify a shift in resources to those activities. State and industrialists encountered the resistance of the other sectors: commerce and agriculture proposed industrial plan. precisely here: An attempted leaders of stability Accion for the industrialization to The struggle Democratica government (AD), the those who offering benefits of years was the civilian as a factor of the incipient were able to undertake the task, trying plans, sectors traditional those rapprochement between and the new industrialists with of to the 11 to develop (commerce their industrial and agriculture) resisting change. The message was transmitted the receptivity was not because other reforms reform and Betancourt seems that enough to maintain AD in power, perhaps such various but it as types "oil nationalization", agrarian of social reform announced by Romulo compromised the possible gains of the industrialization process. Although the Venezuelan state became much more politically rigid during the dictatorship followed the of Colonel M. Perez Jimenez that AD government, it should not be assumed that it was incapable of modernizing itself. In fact, the State progressed in its institutional structure, simultaneously allowing the industrialization process to advance. It is mistaken in this case to equate dictatorship with government had been rejected, economic but the stagnation: wisdom of the AD its economic goals remained clear. The industrial plan in action: 1952 - 1958 The several Perez Jimenez Regional industrialization. manufacturing increased from the same administration undertook the creation of Development As sector a to the Banks result, Gross the to promote contribution Industrial Product private of the (GIP) 58.7 per cent in 1950 to 60.3 percent in 1957. At time there was a decrease of from 38.1 percent to a 34.5 percent. the construction sector During this six-year manufacturing surpassed industrialists were in cumulated investments gaining more The more power, particulary and intensive, increasingly dependent on had a commerce. in groups were investing The industrialization process was capital industry. machinery, and investments in international interest since at this time heavily period the relatively high import of inputs and degree of oligopolization and monopolization. At the end of these six-years the State initiated a State such capitalism; a plan reserved development of Venezuela's natural resources, iron, steel, for the plan for State the resources, especially mineral petrochemicals and the hydro-electric power from the Caroni river in the Guayana region. 2.2) The period 1958 - 1973: Rise and decline of the political pact. This period extends government in January 1958 oil shock) in 1973. from the installation of a democratic until the rise of oil prices (first The new government led by Romulo Betancourt promoted the use of the Import Substitution and Tariff Protection policies in the national their capabilities at the industries. These policies exhausted end of this period, but then the government had at its disposal large financial resources steaming from the first oil boom that postponed date. 13 the crisis to a later This saw period two AD consecutive governments and a final COPEI (Christian The two first COPEI the power thanks arrived to democratic) democratic) government. suffered from political instability governments that ended during (Social this government; to divisions last government within AD just before the 1968 elections. The political pact. On January 23, 1958, the dictatorship of Marcos Perez Jimenez was defeated and replaced promised to establish private sector, a a civilian-military junta which by representative guided by democratic and all the party the industrialists leaders, came together to launch a second democratic main party AD was secure industrial class. The in process the approval culminated, regime. The regime; the of the insurgent towards the end of 1957, in a meeting in New York, where capitalists and politicians established a pact. Petroleum-based and international industrial capital quickly sealed the alliance. Three summarize documents sectors: (1) Principles and The "Punto Minimum the Fijo" Program pact Pact, of between the different (2) The Government" "Statement of and Constitution of 1961. In the 'Minimum Program of Government' all parties agreed on a model of development which gave the State the responsibility for economic planning, development of infrastructure, the pursuit of full employment, public housing for the poor, and continuing improvements in 14 (3) the health, education and social security. The for the call not did constitution nationalization of the oil companies or other developers of Venezuelan natural resources; it called instead for a limitation on further concessions and for greater participation in income. In addition it promised protection of domestic industry against foreign competition, and the support of domestic industry through a development corporation.(Scott, 1986) Democracy and the Economic Plans: The young democracy international would The corporations. for retaining established called which be diversification a decline in oil investments by faced achieved and development to be the historical rate of growth, through through plan industrial substantial development and new exports (Ganz and Blanco, 1969). In addition, there was employment opportunities, percent of the Gross cent of an urgent since need for petroleum National Product new productive accounted but supported for 25 only 2 per the nation's employment. Venezuela was thus experiencing the paradox of high unemployment in the midst of a booming economy. The Plans of 1963-1966 and 1965-1968 set ambitious targets for economic growth, with fundamental changes in the structure of production and employment (Sonntag and de Production of goods and services were to rise la at an Cruz, 1985). annual rate of 7 per cent. Industrialization was to provide the main elements 15 for growth in and net to production, productive employment opportunities, savings for investment. Public investments were expected continue to support two fifths of the total industrial development. There investment were to be policy: (Corporacion two The Venezolana main beneficiaries of this national Venezuelan de Fomento, Development Corporation (Corporacion CVG). The former (CVF), was to policy of import- substitution development of new a Development or CVF) Venezolana be responsible and the industrial center latter Corporation and the Guayana de Guayana, or for following a (CVG), for the to produce enriched and pre-reduced iron ore, metals, chemicals, and metal fabrications. The subsidies promised (1957) to the private sector came through the Corporacion Venezolana de Fomento. As was noticed, in discussion of the previous period (1945-58), charge of implementing the industrial financial resources for new enterprises and that implied a high The Industrial this office strategy, was in providing coordinating tariffs level of protection to industry. State and the role of the Corporacion Venezolana de Guayana (CVG). Romulo Bentancourt had achieved launching the new democratic the necessary regime; measured the possible consequences of however, the consensus for this time he aggressive petroleum the past. It is probable that the Government that he policies of one he had envisioned required a "leit motif" different from the postulated a oil be provided by motif" would necessary "leit exploitation. This of control the was which before, decade the development of the natural resources of the Guayana region as a national enterprise. The Guayana project was conceived as an integral Plan, created to help achieve national goals Venezuelan National through the development of construction of part of the a city industry and in power, and through the what was virtually an empty space. (Ganz and Blanco, 1969: 69). The economic plans of the industries would make earnings by 1980. An expected to 1965 1960's one-fourth important come from already up early of portion of predicted that new Venezuela's exchange these earnings was the Guayana region. This region, which in accounted for 7.5 per cent of Venezuela's manufacturing production, was counted on to provide one fifth of Venezuelan output manufacturing and almost a fourth of an expanded level of exports by 1980. To accomplish such targets, the National Plans ("Planes de la Nacion") of the early 60's called for 10 per cent of the nation's investments, public and private, to be devoted to the Guayana- region program in the period 1963-1966. The Guayana share of the national investment was substantially greater than 10 per cent in certain priority areas: 14 per cent and petroleum, 21 per of the investment in mining cent in manufacturing, and 34 per cent in electric power. The main objective of the basis of the the Guayana national economy. project was This new to transform economy was to be based on heavy industry and power. In the context of the resources available in the Guayana region, and taking the specific needs of and targets for the Venezuelan economy set down in the national plan, the planners designed a heavy industry complex with specific targets and programs for the production of steel, enriched iron ore, sponge iron, aluminum, chemicals, pulp and paper, metal fabrications, and electric power. The short term (1965-1968) and the long term (to 1980) regional development program was formulated around this heavy industry complex. From the beginning the major considerations in project selection included (1) modern technology that was related to Guayana's unique resources, (2) domestic and export demand, (3) economic scale to achieve competitive output and pricing, (4) integration and complementation with the Venezuelan economy as a whole, and (5) linkages, external economies, and transportation factors.(Ganz and Blanco, 1969: 66). The Guayana industrialization plan of iron ore to primary targets. aluminum and established the upgrading enriched iron ore, sponge iron, and steel as Following this would pulp. These latter coordinated with the development be areas, of the development of however, electric power had to be and forest reserves respectively. Production of ammonia could take advantage of the availability of nearby natural gas. Later on, the metal fabricating industry could be linked to iron and steel development. As we have noted, Democratica; during the Guayana-CVG was a Betancourt's government, project of Accion AD started Guayana City, initiated the steel factory and constructed the bridge over the Orinoco river. When the COPEI party came into power in 1968, their leaders put a freeze on the development project. Basically, they reduced the budget of CVG, while at the same time increasing the budget for all the public enterprises controlled by CVG, such as EDELCA, the company in charge of the Caroni river development (see table 2.1). COPEI created a new platform for the development of the Guayana region from the Ministry of Public Works (MOP). This new program was called "La conquista del of the South). Industrial Plan The COPEI into an government Sur" thus (the Conquest converted infrastructure program an AD for the Guayana region. In the last five years of the period, between 1958-1973, and during the COPEI government of 1968-1973, the import substitution policies originated in 1961 finally exhausted their capabilities. This was evidenced manufacturing by industry. experienced the first a decrease At the in annual growth in same time, in 1972, oil prices major increase. (see GNP table 2.2). 2.3) The period 1973 - 1983: Political Economy of Petrodollars. TABLE 2.1 : COPPORACION VENEZOLANA DE GUAYANA M BUGET 1965 - 1976 ( IN MILLION BOLIVAPS ) % OF TOTAL NATIONAL INVESTMENT INSTITUT CVG EDELCA -----------------------------------------------------------------70.0 86.9 NA 1965 70.0 62.5 NA 1966 90.0 124.9 1,306.0 1967 30.0 124.3 1,:388.7 1960 45.4 122.9 1,494.1 1969 5.0 128.7 1,306.5 1970 33.0 74.0 1,819.2 1971 30.5 70.0 1,494.8 1972 50.0 58.0 1,517.5 1973 INVESTMENT SIDOR Subtotal FROM THE INV INSTITUT 103.1 169.5 90.0 90.0 25.0 NA 34.0 40.0 40.0 260.0 :302.0 294.9 234.3 193.3 133.7 141.0 140.5 148.0 NA 19-00% 16.00% 13.00% 10.00% 9.00% 9.00% 10.00% 19.00% 997.2 598.8 130.5 267.9 5,122.0 1974 28.00% 840.0 1,175.1 24.6 310.5 4,248.1 1975 11.00% 400.0 NA NA 400.0 1976 (Ley) 3,489.7 -------------------------------------------------------------Total 1,777.9 601.9 1,970.3 4,350.1 16.00%(b) 4,787.1 23,186.6 (b) ------------------------------------------------------------Including : "modificacion a la ley de presupuesto". (a) Including 1967-1976 period (b) SOURCES: Ministerio de Hacienda, Direccion Nacional de Presupuesto. en: Izaguirre, Maritza. "Cuidad Guayana y la estrategia de desarrollo polarizado". Ed SIAP-Planteos Table 36. Pg 90. TABLE 2.2 : GROSS DOEsTIC PRODUCT AT MARKET PRICES BY SECTOR 1970-1983 Cbillions of bs st 1968 prices) (1). 1983 1982 1981 1980 1979 1978 1977 1976 1975 1974 1973 1972 1971 1970 ~-----------------~--------------- ---------~-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------72.5 76.1 75.6 75.8 7?.4 76.4 74.8 70.1 64.4 60.7 57.3 53.9 52.1 50.7 TOTAL GOP -4.738 0.66R -0.26% -2.07% 1.31% 2.14Z 6.70% 8.85% 6.10% 5.93% 6.312 3.45% 2.762 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- ---------------------------- ---------5.9 6.1 6.6 6.8 7.4 6.9 7 7.2 7.1 9.1 10.3 9.7 10.6 11.2 Petroleuw -3.28% -7.582 -2.94% -8.11% 7.25% -1.43% -2.78% 1.41% -21.982 6.193 -11.652 -8.492 -5.362 ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- ------------------- --------------70 66.6 69 69 70 69.5 67.8 62.9 57.3 51.6 47 44.2 41.5 39.5 Nonpetroleuw -4.86% 1.45% 0.00% -1.432 0.72X 2.512 7.79X 9.77% 11.052 9.792 6.33% 6.51% 5.06% -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------PRIMRRY SECTOR Agriculture Crude petroleuw Mining SECONDRRY SECTOR Manufacturing Petroleum refining Electricity and mater Construction TERCIRRY SECTOR Comerce Tranport and cow Financial inst Governwnet Other services Subtotal Less imputed 9.8 10.1 10.6 10.9 11.2 10.5 10.5 10.5 10.8 12.2 12.7 12 12.9 -2.97Z -4.72% -2.75Z -2.682 6.67R 0.002 0.00% -2.78% 5.83% -3.94% -11.48X -6.98 -2.27% 4.9 4.8 4.7 4.8 4.7 4.5 4.4 4.1 4.2 4 3.7 3.5 3.6 3.5 2.08 2.13% -2.08% 2.132 4.44% 2.27% 7.32% 5.00% -2.38% 8.11% 5.71F -2.78% 2.86% 4.5 4.8 5.3 5.5 5.9 5.4 5.5 5.7 5.8 7.3 8.3 7.9 8.7 9.1 -6.252 -9.432 -3.64% 9.26% -6.782 -1.82% -3.51% -1.72% 5.062 -12.05% -20.55% -9.20% -4.402 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.00% -16.67% -20.002 0.00% 0.00% 0.002 -12.50% -14.29 16.67% 28.57% -11.11 0.00% 0.00% -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------20 20.4 20.1 20.3 20.8 20.7 19.5 17.9 15.8 14.5 13.9 12.8 11.6 11.1 -1.962 1.492 -0.99% -2.40% 0.482 6.15% 8.94% 13.292 8.972 4.32; 8.592 10.34Z 4.50% 12.3 12 12.5 12.3 11.9 11.4 10.8 10.4 9.3 8.3 7.6 7.2 6.6 6.2 -1.60% 4.172 3.36% -2.44% 4.392 5.56d 3.85a 11.832 12.05% 9.21P 5.562 9.092 6.452 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.3 1.8 2 1.8 1.9 2 7.69% 0.00% -7.14a 0.00% -6.67 0.002 0.00% 15.38% 11.112 -10.00% -27.78Z -5.26Z -5.002 2.7 2.5 2.3 2 1.9 1.7 1.7 1.6 1.5 1.3 1 1.1 0.9 0.9 8.00% 8.70% 15.002 5.262 11.76% 0.00% 6.25% 6.67% 15.382 18.18% 10.00% 11.11Z 0.00% 3.6 4.1 4.5 4.6 5.5 6.1 5.5 4.4 3.7 3.1 3.2 2.8 2.2 2 -8.89% -12.202 -2.17% -9.84% -16.362 10.91% 25.002 18.922 19.352 -3.13N 14.292 27.27% 10.00% -----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------48 46.1 48.3 46.9 48.3 48.3 47.4 43.6 39.3 34.7 31.1 29.4 27.3 25.7 -3.96R -0.62% 2.992 -2.90% 0.00% 1.902 8.72% 10.942 13.26Z 11.58% 5.78% 7.692 6.23Z 6.8 6.9 6.7 6.9 8.2 8.7 8.7 8.3 7.4 6.4 5.9 5.7 5.5 5.4 -1.45% 2.99% -2.90% -5.?5% -15.859 0.002 4.82% 12.16v 15.63X 8.47P 3.51% 3.642 1.85% 8.8 10.5 10.2 9.8 9.9 10.4 9.6 8.7 7.7 7 6.3 6.1 5.5 5.2 2.942 -16.192 4.082 -1.012 -4.81% 8.332 10.34M 12.992 10.00% 11.11% 3.28% 10.91M 5.77% 15 14.6 15.1 14 14.5 14.3 14.2 13.1 11.7 9 10 8.3 7.7 7.2 2.742 -3.312 7.862 -3.45% 2.112 -0.702 9.16a 11.972 17.00% 8.43% 11.11% 7.792 6.942 10.4 10.6 10.6 10.5 10.1 9.4 9.3 8.6 7.9 7.2 6.2 6 5.5 5.1 -1.89% 0.002 0.952 3.962 7.45% 1.08% 8.142 8.862 9.72% 16.131 3.332 9.09% 7.84% 5.1 5.4 5.7 5.7 5.6 5.6 5.5 4.9 4.6 4.1 3.7 3.3 3.1 2.8 -5.562 -5.26% 0.002 1.792 0.002 1.822 12.249 6.52% 12.20% 10.81P 12.12% 6.45 10.712 13.2 50 1 bank charges 51.8 3.602 1 0.00% 54.2 4.63% 1.3 30.00% 57.7 6.46% 1.6 23.082 61.4 6.41P 2 25.00% 65.9 7.332 3.3 65.00% 72 9.26% 3.8 15.15% 77.4 7.50% 4.7 23.68M 79.5 2.712 4.8 2.132 1.? 2.1 2 1.9 1 1.5 1.1 1.3 5.00% -19.05% 5.26X 26.672 50.002 -9.09V -13.332 -15.382 ------------------------------ ------------------------------------------------------------------------ -------14,071 13,590 13,119 12,665 11,632 Population (2). 3.54% 3.59X 3.582 8.882 --------------------------------------- ---------------------------------- ------------------------------(1) Source: Scott-Venezuela 1986 adapted frow Banco Central de Venezuela (2) Source: Minister9 of Energy and Mines. Plus custows duties 1.5 80.3 1.01% 5.2 8.33% 78.1 -2.742 4.8 -7.692 79 1.15% 5.7 18.752 78.5 -0.63% 4.9 -14.04Z 75.9 -3.31% 4.8 -2.042 1.3 2.3 2.3 2.6 2.4 0.002 -43.482 8.33X -11.54% 41.18% -------------- -----------------------------16,394 15,940 15,485 15,024 14,562 2.852 2.942 3.07X 3.24X 3.42% --------------------------------------- brought into power someone with the will to of 1973 in December to the Presidency of AD The election of Carlos Andres Perez government, thanks to innovate, delegate and spend. The now-rich the rising oil prices of the early 70's, purchased the iron mines also provided Venezuela's concessions. It the oil from their foreign owners, and likewise for a vastly expanded effort to develop the funds resource-based industries ("La Gran Venezuela", launched by Perez), all through state-owned corporations. on the Venezuelan economy in an impact bonanza had The oil two waves, 1974 and 1980, which should be differentiated one from the other. Guayana The first program investments), (see and in and the SIDOR steel decade. The and decisive graph owned bauxite indicating the jump in CVG consequence the hydro-electrical Guri dam plant were aluminum smelter to 250,000 tons. New projects million ton 2.1 wave was channelled into the brought forward by more than a of Venalum was raised from 100,000 were announced, among them a 1 state-owned alumina plant and a 3 million ton statemine. Investments in pulp, diesel motors, cement and gold were discussed. The original 1965 projection for 1980 of transforming the Guayana complex, substituting imports during those only into years become were a reality. alumina, as center for well as The decisions based on projected exports of 3 million tons of steel, 200,000 tons of aluminum of a of key industrial products, but also into a major export center could now made not and 350,000 tons many other products. Cement was to be 20 GRAPH 2.1 -5-197 i' CV G 19 BUDGETS $1 .200 $1.100 $1.900 $o.aoa $0.700 $o.ano $B13MI0 .40. 0 $$0.;50a - $0.210 ~V4 * 1.2513 1.9890 4- CvG -9Eddan 9-now 1.872 1.97 A Sidar I -' 1.874 X 1.078 subintal TOTAL INVESTMENT AND CVG SHARE OF TOT4L- (19.".-1976) C/G D.CvD dd to-tal 1871 1 int invearmtitn 4 1G75 Tat d I n - CvX provided for the construction of the Guri dam light the whole central area of and electricity to the country. The main question which arises from these projects and projections is, what has the return of these been, investments and what is their actual contribution to exports today? 2.4) The period 1983 - 1987: Crisis and devaluation. took place at this three major due to This period is significant Venezuela: the first devaluation of time in elections in December the Bolivar in February 1983, presidential 1983 (which were won by events which AD), and a second devaluation of the bolivar in December 1986, when additional exchange controls were introduced. The Venezuelan economy during this period remained stagnant, as the GNP did not grow announced that year). The after the non-oil crisis of this 1980 (in December 1986 it was sector grew 3.5 per cent during that period is partially explained by reduced private investment and flight of capital, consequences of a lack of confidence in the economy, higher interest in foreign capital markets (1980-82) and the overvaluation of the Venezuelan currency (until December 1986). Venezuelan unemployment is now (the Central Bank puts the highest in forty years the figure at 12 per cent and the unions argue that it is around 20 per cent), and inflation is also into double digits. These figures are surprising after the annual growth experienced from the early 50's Venezuela was until the seen as one of the few economic success stories in Latin America. This state of affairs is not of the involves economic the recession very development both responsible mid-70's, when it viability only serious because entails, but of country's the also because it scheme of political and economic. Venezuela's leaders are for having set over-ambitious targets and miscalculated their implementation, and it is the Guayana project which cast a shadow over these figures. The drop in oil prices Venezuela's economic earlier, economy, rather than actually appears to as the the second oil price to a large extent to crisis, but this crisis appears to have had its origins much referred to contributed oil have involving alone. begun most if not Paradoxically, in 1978, all the during of the decline the period "oil bonanza", and to have continued despite rise; the fall of oil prices has only accelerated the process. It is important to note the the period prior to 1973, when strong economic performance in non-oil growth was 6.5 per cent per year in comparison to the period 1973-84, when it grew only 3 per cent. Examining these figures since 1978, we have a 1.1 per cent annual growth. It income grew more than 3 per cent prior to 1973, and rose briefly is important 22 to note as well that real upwards from 1973 to 1977, only to sink in 1985 to lower than the 1973 levels. Private between 1977 sector and 1982. investment went off 75 per cent The creation of jobs, which had averaged about 150,000 per year in the 70's, fell sharply in 1978 and by 1983 was negative. The private sector, with a utilized capacity of around 60 per cent, since the first evaluation was to overcome the crisis. strategy. These groups demanding changes Some private asserted in order groups had proposed a new that if Venezuela wished to regain its forward momentum, the government would have to abandon its strategy of import substitution based on the State as the engine of growth, in favor of a strategy which relied more on the private sector, to achieve a more diversified group of exports, notably manufactured exports. These initiatives are embodied in a book, Proposal to the Nation (E. Quintero and others, 1985): the proposed initiatives were to be supported by a sharp devaluation, as well as reduction in protection industry, a "to open way for and control the creation competitive activities in manufacturing" The recent January 1986), debt, and deterioration the efforts the preferential rate high of for of new, export- (Scott, 1986). prices made since demand of 7.50 oil of the domestic (especially since 1983 to foreign pay off foreign currency at the Bolivars per US dollar established in 1983, combined to put enough pressure on the balance of payments to motivate a new economic strategy and a second devaluation of the Bolivar in December 1986. A per US dollar was established goods and services, with remains unchanged new exchange all Bs. 14.50 for all imports and exports of some exceptions. for rate of imports (The Bs. 7.50/$ rate and exports of the oil and iron-ore industries). This new exchange rate was order to reduce its supported by other measures in effect on national investment, mainly the foreign investment regulations which had been relaxed in order to promote future foreign exchange investors clear-cut guidelines on accorded investments to their contracts. The new laws gave the exchange and treatment to be the remission of dividends abroad. At the same time, in order to stimulate domestic investments, the Venezuelan Development Fund Venezuela") had announced that investment projects through it ("El Fondo de Inversiones de would finance certain private shareholder participation in mixed enterprises, and open overall lines of and development agriculture, of specific industry, and of most credit for high-priority construction the financing sectors of such as tourist infrastructure. The effects implementation of the some recent measures devaluation which were and the announced simultaneously are a source of current debate. Pedro Palma, a Venezuelan economist, gave a presentation to the Mason Fellows at Harvard University (Kennedy School 1987 about the short term effects In his opinion, exporters and the reduce of such devaluation those of of Government) on March 14 a second devaluation. would "generate earnings for importers". In Venezuela, the principal exporter by far is the public sector, while the private sector is basically a that the net importer. recent measures Palma's estimate indicates would add approximately Bs. 35 billion to the Central Government (principally originating profits). The situation, the from private private sector new exchange exports and would face rate reducing increasing a from exchange more difficult the bolivar earnings the cost of imports and foreign debt service. In Palma's national accounts, he forecasts a positive balance of 9,896 billion bolivars for the balance for the private sector of public sector and a negative 35,295 billion bolivars. Even if the government is capable of returning a large portion of this transfer to government the has private at its sector, disposal while only estimating of Bs. 25 billion. In order loss of income on to continue stimulating public spending in the internal economy at the levels of previous years sector, the the 9.9 billion bolivars to invest, the private sector will undergo a net the order that the two and to compensate for the transfers to the public Government must provide some additional Bs. 20 billion or more. Such resources will have to come from new credit sources in an amount equivalent to the country's pnlblic foreign debt service outlays. It is national in this role to administration of perspective play. CVG, The Guayana is being investment and reactivation of in attracting that the Guayana project has a foreign capital. offered the national region, as a under the channel for economy, especially In chapter 3 we will observe why these required new investments tend to keep going to Guayana, and in chapter 4 we will see how CVG is facilitating these transfers to the region. 3) THE OUTCOME OF THE INDUSTRIALIZATION PROCESS: As we have seen in the preceding chapter, it has become clear that important time, and new economic changes are strategies growth. consideration must These the taking new relative government, state-owned labor force. The study Guayana Development be place in Venezuela at this provided strategies positions of enterprises, the of in the order must the to spur take main into players: private sector and the industries associated with the Corporation can't be separated from analysis of the role of the other players. In this Venezuelan chapter I have made industrialization a special from political point of view. This would economic more variables are main players in the economic help us important Venezuelan industrialization and to of the an effort to reexamine rather to determine which for weigh the the analysis of relative position economic arena. Understanding which are the more important economic variables will help the relative than a us to define position of the players and will allow us to make a better assessment of this case. We can easily recognize that exporter since the beginning Venezuela has been of the century (table 2.2 provides information for 1970-83). Today, as it was 25 years ago industrialization process and a primary when the the Guayana project started, the economy is still Venezuela been highly dependent unable to on oil exports. reduce its dependence on oil revenues? countries which How has Venezuela performed in relation to other were primary Why has exporters 25 years ago? How has Venezuela performed in relation to other oil-exporters in the last decade? Studying the experience help us of other the understand industrialization process. developing deficiencies For the countries may of Venezuela's "different developing world, factors seem to suggest a balanced investment in heavy as well as light industry and a reduced share of manufactured imports in the gross national product". Venezuela, as (Chenery, we noted industrialization under pg 2, 1986). in Chapter the 2, began influence of its process of specific economic theories. During the decade of the 50's Presbisch and Singer were advocating industrialization disadvantages of in specialization associated secular deterioration order in in to offset the supposed primary production and the the terms of trade. This ideology was based on two fundamental points: The clearly limited world demand for domestic demand a general exports of primary products and the rising for manufactured goods. These realities promoted import substitution strategy among Latin American countries that called for a balanced growth of the industrial and primary sectors. Venezuela, like other Latin American countries, import substitution would conflict practiced an policy. It can be argued that such a policy the with neoclassical concept of comparative advantages, which suggests that Venezuelan advantages were in the oil industry (World Bank industries as suggested report of after the 1961) or appraisal region. This economic concept of comparative progressive appraisal natural resource Guayana region has of the been in tremendously iron related of the Guayana advantages and the endowment of the influential among policy makers during the entire democratic period. Referring again to economic industrial process must take into natural resources available, capital resources in manufactured goods, order but or to also theory, any evaluation of an consideration the not allocation exploit them or only the of human and to produce the global changes in demand and supply as ways of guaranteeing transfers of modern technology. In addition, trade policies factor of economic growth have proved among the to be more successful developing countries. Venezuela can't escape the temptation these successful have have arisen of referring to countries to reexamine its industrial strategy. What Venezuela must keep in economies an important faced from international economy a mind is that these trade-oriented completely different world economy and different historical those countries 29 backgrounds. dealt with The in the period 1950-70 was a world of expansive international trade. Venezuela today faces a radically altered world, one where restrictions and protectionism are the order years the US and of the Spain have day. For example, in recent imposed a voluntary steel quota on Venezuela. The argument for shifting from an inward-oriented to an outward-oriented strategy has been strengthened by the success of a small group of by the "newly industrialized four East Asian economies economies", particularly in this group: Hong Kong, the Republic of Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan. Although these successful outward-oriented policies have received great attention in recent years, they have been only one of several Japan for ingredients example has in Venezuela because it development strategies. been more notable for attaining a great than having particularly open increase in productivity economy (the successful for a "microchips-war" in March 1987 is is different owns this from these a clear example). successful super-exporters natural resource endowment which includes oil, iron ore, cheap energy, gas and others. The general tendency of countries such endowments and strategies of as primarydelayed Venezuela, exporter which have large economies, industrialization, where, start, manufacturing increases rapidly in response of domestic demand. It is important is resource to follow after a late to the growth to notice that at the same time Venezuela has the resources. The power timing to and decide scale when of to such developments would be a fundamental issue in the general development in the hands of develop such resource base analysis of the and industrialization of Venezuela. What was international corporations two decades ago, is today in hands of many independent producers such as Venezuela. In addition to natural important factors such as resource endowments and trade, other the role of the Government and human resources have also to be considered in evaluating the actual and future capabilities of the Venezuelan economy. We would expect Venezuela, like any other developing economy, to experience process of evaluating relative structural changes industrialization. the industrial contribution However, using of a broader In in its a process, different economy neoclassical during the approach to we would only focus in the sectors perspective, should account the failure to reallocate resources to total growth. further take into efficiently in order to increase exports or replace imports. STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION: Structural not only demographic transformation changes in analysis takes into consideration agriculture, transformation, but industrialization also incorporates and the transformation of demand, trade, production and employment into a single framework. among sectors adjustments theory. The structural approach focuses oA differences of in the resource Neoclassical maintained over is time, a which allocation theory factors on the supply Venezuela economy which limits example inhibit equilibrium as implied by neoclassical assumes side. The good may that the equilibrium sources of growth to evidence seems of the is to suggest that failure efficient allocation of resources as implied to achieve an by the neoclassical theory. In an equilibrium growth perspective as suggested by Chenery, competitive equilibria that underline neoclassical theory are a convenient starting point for growth analysis because they permit any group of inputs to be aggregate on the basis of their marginal productivity (Chenery, 1986: 16). In equilibrium growth theory, all primary inputs are categorized as either capital or labor. Each of these can then be consolidated on the basis of its share in the total difference between the growth of total average growth of capital and labor increase in product. The output and the weighted serves as a measure of the Total Factor Productivity (TFP) for the economy as a whole. Comparative studies designed capital, labor and to productivity, several economies, including measure have Venezuela. 32 been These the importance of carried out for studies indicate that the growth of capital, labor, and comparable importance for the whole, but the structure productivity are of vary significantly with of a specific economy and the effectiveness of its policies. In his analyzed comparative the study different for different different contributions growth of outputs, inputs, and elaborated of and Total to economies, Chenery growth; analyzed the Factor Productivity (TFP); a table from which I extracted the averages given groups of countries: developed, developing and centrally planned economies. We can compare these values with the Venezuelan figures. Table 3.1 The Growth of Output, Inputs, and Total Factor Productivity. TFP Economy Years Growth value added (Gv) Developed Centrally planned Developing Venezuela 50-60 60-74 Total Factor input 5.4 8.2 6.3 7.85 5.1 Growth Growth Growth share Growth share of of rate rate capital labor (Ga) (Gf) (Gk) (Gl) 2.7 2.5 2.0 2.15 0.6 49.0 35.0 31.0 27.4 11.8 2.7 5.7 4.3 5.7 4.4 51.0 65.0 69.0 72.6 88.2 5.2 8.0 5.5 7.2 4.5 1.1 4.5 3.3 3.7 3.3 Source: Extracted from Chenery, table 2-2, (1986). From the averages given, developed economies are characterized by the small growth of labor inputs (1.1 per cent), moderate growth cent), and of capital a relatively (5.2 per cent) and large contribution 33 output (5.4 per of TFP to aggregate growth (50 per cent). The developing economies, in contrast, have a high growth of labor inputs (3.3 per cent), a higher total factor growth (4.3 per cent) and a relatively of Total Factor Productivity (TFP) to small contribution aggregate growth (30 per cent). The Venezuelan position between experience is the countries remarkable in studied. Figure relationship between total factor its relative (3.1) shows the productivity growth and total factor input growth. We see here that the developed countries fit within a smaller growth , cluster, with TFP A, defined relative low factor accounting for between 50% and 70% of overall growth. Developing countries are large one by divided into two clusters: the , B is characterized by TFP growth between 0.5 and 2.0 percent. The smaller economies plus one, C, is composed of five developing Japan, with aggregate growth (Gv) of more than 10 per cent. (See Figure 3.1). Venezuela stands with a total growth of 5.1 per cent, where such growth was basically spurred by total factor input growth (4.4 contribution to per cent), total growth and where increase of TFP was practically insignificant (0.6 per cent). Grouping the countries in those categories and performing mentioned before, a regression analysis, we arrive at Figure (3.2). It is interesting to note that both sets of regressions the relative point to inefficiency of the growth processes of the typical 34 FIC=0M 3. z 4t1+,owmpI awrtJ&e" TorsrAsc. -Tom rs2oDUCiucr'r &4t.OvPrl+ *MP rOr*L. Foca-m imP\r fr*OSwri*. I I to 7 7 tOrAlL. froTort INPT 4ftoIwflo (.Y SOur'* UC MCCY~ AMP OMS~r. 'O1t4PO&TVRJA TTiOP -AMP developing country in cluster B (where Venezuela stands of the lowest functions productivity represented economy with in rates). In terms of the production Figure relatively high can expect aggregate growth countries or with one (3.2) a factor input of 6 efficient economies per typical developing growth of 5 per cent cent, whereas developed predict growth of about 9 per cent. The question that immediately such inefficiencies in the arises is, Venezuelan important increase in its total factor Venezuelan economy increase how do we explain economy? Having had an input growth, why didn't proportionally? Equilibrium growth can't explain this imbalance. Several factors suggest the effects of disequilibrium into importance of the study of Venezuela's growth. The structural variables we should look rates are: (1) Reallocation incorporating the to in explaining growth of labor and capital; (2) Growth of exports; (3) Capital inflows; and, (4) Level of development. It would seem that one of these variables, or a combination of them, can help us to explain Venezuela's disappointing performance. The structural transformation approach used by researchers to evaluate the performance of a specific economy proposes studying the structural transformations of This approach provides both an economy the aggregate in a time series. data available for a W.A1-ONrT llJPS B&ThICSM VhU'.'S APe PFmr.TtDx iNevr avitotorO. 6eo.rt t 7000 S% Pmz~r,1000"OOOO ALL DILOP g L> r0000 L Foil le'LLJT~ (~~pI&~ >4o ± 2 3 4 PICTOK 5 ( 7 (/. lNpLtrI* Rowtt large number of countries and the detailed time series of individual countries. We can define the structure of an economy by its supplies of productive factors - labor, capital and natural resources their employment in different - and sectors. We can then define the structural transformation of a developing country as, the set of changes in the composition of demand, trade, production, and factor use that takes place as the per capita income increases. A main thesis is that to understand country differences in sources and rates of growth , the transformation as a whole must be analyzed. More specifically, changes in demand and trade may affect the sources of growth as much as the changes in factor supply (Chenery, 1986: 32). Cross-country studies between developing and developed countries yield two general results: First, they identify several aspects of structural changes that affect the rate that have development. country a varying Secondly, regressions importance the are at structural all more of growth and different factors significant in levels of the cross- for developing countries than for developed ones. Investment is the only source of growth shown to be important for both groups. In order to compare different colleagues have proposed to by sectors first and then break down countries, Chenery and his the supply-side analysis to combine it with a corresponding breakdown of demand and trade. The result is a demand side view of the factors leading consistent to structural change and growth that is with the supply-side analysis. An analysis of the Venezuelan economic structure and the role of the Guayana regional require the use of inter- industry economy input-output relations. in the analysis, Including global economy will which demand will describe and production functions which depend on relative prices, we will have a general equilibrium approach as proposed by Johansen's 1960 study of the Norwegian economy. PATTERN OF TRANSFORMATION: Growth processes of a developing country can be best understood as a part of the overall transformation of its economic structure. This interdependence works in both directions: income growth causes changes in the composition of domestic demand and production, and conversely, rising investment rates and the reallocation of labor trend to increase aggregate growth (Chenery, 1986: 37). Taking into growth, and account applying this both demand approach to and supply the analysis analysis for of a small developing economy such as Venezuela, we would expect to see many of the structural changes observed in other developing countries. The most common feature of industrialization among developing economies is the shift from agriculture to other, more productive sectors, such related to last the as urbanization, has absorbtion of population has part this of 80 reached in Venezuela during been observed The decades. three This process, which is always manufacturing. Guayana global project foresaw phenomenon. The the urban of the total population in percent recent years. Another characteristic of Venezuelan industrialization is the high level of its exports, and in consequence the high level of its imports. This is a common pattern among small countries which are rich in natural resources; they tend to have a high level of trade and this high level of population size trade would increase. Increased tend to reduce with income from favorable terms of trade would shift domestic demand. In the case of Venezuela, with respect to domestic demand, one reason for changes in the productive structure is the decline of the share of food in private consumption as income rises. This shift in the components to increased after overall rise. pattern In of Venezuela, the first demand domestic oil boom, allows all other demand definitely and there is some evidence that the second oil boom was absorbed mainly by increased demand. After the effect of declining oil prices and the agricultural policies which followed from increased dramatically. this We would decline, agricultural prices expect domestic consumption to be affected in such a way that the private capacity to save will probably be affected; capacity for private investment for the other sectors must also be diminished by implication. A basic concept to be analyze the to order in remembered Venezuelan industrialization experience is that industrialization is commonly measured by the rise in the share of manufacturing in GNP. In a general equilibrium context, as presented by Chenery in his comparative study (1986), industrialization is the system a property of as a whole, in which the fall in the share of primary production is offset by a rise in social manufacturing. Generally overhead as well as in the causes of the rise in manufacturing differ considerably from those of the decline in primary output. Venezuela is a good example of this independent process, increase of primary exports we saw an increase in manufacturing, as well as a decrease in the primary exports without in manufacturing. In today's world, with the an increase unlike Presbish's world, volatility also affects primary production. As we have shown, Venezuela has comparative advantages in the production of crude oil, energy production industries, and we would expect that and the away expansion of from the characteristic tendency towards through import substitution manufactured exports, Venezuela would move specialization of and iron related early shifts in stages in primary of products development. comparative that is Although the advantages ultimately affects all developing countries, their magnitude and timing vary greatly. As we mentioned before countries as such Venezuela have with small populations relatively specialized economies and a high share of trade in GNP, and we would expect that trade share to decline markedly with increasing population. In a country like Venezuela, with access to large amounts of natural resources, the way in which these resources are exploited has a substantial impact on the country's comparative advantages. To trading show the importance patterns, classification of Chenery of size and resource endowments in and Syrquin countries, based proposed a two-way on their population size and their relative specialization in primary or manufactured exports. The typical small Venezuela's, seems and the these cases increased demand in the composition of reallocation manufacturing such as transformation of its domestic exports make little or no contribution to the rise of industry. In result of economy to maintain a strong comparative advantage in primary exports'throughout demand, while primary-oriented of and industrialization with and capital services. structural transformation largely the produced by rising income. The shift output labor is In of this rising a income reflects the from primary production to dynamic analysis of the type of economy, manufactured imports are replaced much more slowly. The comparative advantages in primary development of manufactured the delays production exports. TYPOLOGY OF INDUSTRIALIZATION. In the is emphasis special presented analysis comparative on placed by Chenery (1986), strategies trade rather than internal policy (resource mobilization). This emphasis leads to a three-way of specialization (large - L; pattern classification small, primary oriented - SP; and small, industry oriented - SM). This typology of semi-industrial economies recognizes the effect of structural features such as size and resource endowment as well as trade policy. If we Venezuela evidence take is the trade an outward importance Following a policy tried to policy of into account, primary-oriented of primary industrial we can say that economy, taking as exports in total exports. protectionism, Venezuela has accelerate growth while at the same time making exports earnings entirely dependent on impact share on the enormous rise industrial in the price primary of products. The negative in output associated with the energy in the 1970's (Dutch disease) will be apparent in Venezuela. Chenery (1986) points out that, "development strategies try to accelerate growth through either supply of the increasing labor and capital, or through a more efficient use of resources". As we noticed before, Venezuelan growth is explained basically by the labor and input capital insignificant contribution relative with importance of show differences importance of how in efficiency in sources of trade levels growth rates among countries. Using estimates of TFP has in strategies factor explaining both time inputs, the series and cross-country growth, the efficiency of an economy is that its the growth comparative analysis shows us the average and differences in growth observed growth from could be of efficiency, and the measured by the difference between its predicted had an to growth. Chenery and his colleagues constructed figure 3.3 to associated where growth, efficiency of of factor that Venezuela the entire rate and inputs. This is not only below sample but also below the group average (I) of the inward oriented economies. In short, the relative efficiency of the Venezuelan economy in relation to what could have been expected from its factor inputs growth is very low. To growth aid explaining between the countries, differences it has been in sectoral sources of established that the principal sectoral sources of growth are: shifts in final demand, increased use of industrial advantage away within products, and shifts in comparative from primary production. In case we are concerned Venezuela, as in other 42 primary-oriented economies, F=161U eE 3.b Fft.XDW. i1rV~T~ I NPgjTj.AL.- AND IDULA)VE: Sf:fi-66NC~ F.ot4COiEt..5. OP 5"11- -3 -4 Amy 7.0 6.0 4.o 0 f4%AJ&W- o lmsw&?T- 6.0 ca~LTE OftikTg Cvy (aoowtrt eAIE '14 ft-mCHT souaZcc: cHek~vzx ptw> vmmc/~ ( c'o4) C0 . - 9.0 effects (the manufacturing the of of growth exports primary (Chenery, accelerated growth of domestic income". than is level. "But the outweighed are disease) Dutch growth to same income at the typical for other countries inhibited less contributes uniformly manufacturing by on the 1986: 99). will affect virtually all aspects of development Timing also strategy. As in the Venezuelan case, "the exploitation of natural resources for exports tends to slow down the development of other tradable goods" tendency, we those natural (Chenery, 1986: 99). If this is a general can imagine what will happen if the exploitation of resources is done in excess of the estimated requirements. TRANSFORMATION OF PRODUCTION IN VENEZUELA. Because industrialization of manufacturing the tradable dimensions. in the sectors, is characterized by a rising share production, exports, the figures and employment of shown concentrate on these Figure 3.5 Figure 3.4 Per capita exports added value Per capita primary products vs manufacturing Transformation of production and exports during period 1953-73. ~4hLL St4p1 ~ .L. ~Wh~OMIE~ &WNOW~iE6 If,000 ,V,-=Vm vs.~~e w6Lb~ oo 90,0 100 61 A- j~,. \.* .% .A~. .9 in too -4 ~ **~'- 1%~ %.~~'L l- -- 00 I I 3~ U \ *~fiOtjL~ l1~WAN I ' I~I ~ ~ I' 1 1 ' I II 00 200 10 fr c-rqi& VP& APPOD d ii 500 IO0O MU FAC Tvt i6 so PFg i i I I I I I ' I I 1 I I I * so 1oo too soo to chriTA-# CyroPT. oF w <TL e~P Source: Chenery, (1986), pg 104 and 105. Ve~nezuela's characterized by transformation a large (1953-1973) increase in capita value seems that Venezuela has shows a shift toward exports and intensified after primary exports exporters (dotted line SP), which higher manufacturing shares of production, employment. by Venezuela has intensified added in primary products in comparison to the average for small-primary explained same time, constant structure (value added) in its production. But for the same period it its per particulary per capita value added in manufacturing (see figure 3.4). At the maintained a is This increasing 1973. Due (oil), the bias in dependance to Venezuela's on improved composition of 44 oil terms case revenues of is that trade for exports in Venezuela er. has temporarily reversed the tendency to shifts towards manufactured exports. (see figure 3.5). In general we observe a somewhat slower transformation of production in primary oriented countries such as Venezuela, and a rapid transformation countries. The producers is in mentioned most of slower the manufacturing-oriented transformation known as the "Dutch Disease" (DD). among primaryVenezuela is not exempt from this phenomenon. In 1973, Venezuela had capital inflow (10% of 1972 non-oil GNP) that could have spurred a corresponding GNP growth. In order happen, we have to observe where to explain OPEC oil why this didn't Venezuela invested the income from its oil exports. This case is important of the a tremendous because the success cartel is not paralleled by any of the primary- producer countries. The first objective in the "windfalls" produced by economy between mining and oil segments. order to This evaluate the higher oil prices is to divide the non-mining, rather approach Following table 3.2, Gelb gives importance of than oil and non is proposed by Alan Gelb (1986). us an indication of the base absorbtion structures of seven oil economies and compares them to Chenery-Syrquin norms for countries at a similar level of non- mining income per capita. Venezuela, Iran and Algeria "with large and long-established oil sectors", stand out as the most mineraldependent. The breakdown of 45 extra absorbtion indicates particulary strong investment biases Trinidad. What kind of in Algeria, investment biases Venezuela and is Gelb referring to, and how important are they in relation to the entire economy? Table 3.2 Composition of absorbtion: 1970-2 in relation to the Chenery norm Algeria Ecuador Indonesia Iran Nigeria Trinidad Venezuela Pri C A/N-M Norm Pub C A/N-M Norm Invest A/N-M Norm Absor A/N-M Norm 64.5 66.0 75.5 68.0 83.5 75.0 72.2 64.0 80.2 70.0 80.9 78.0 62.8 62.0 18.0 14.0 10.6 14.0 9.8 12.0 23.4 14.0 8.6 14.0 n.a. n.a. 16.4 15.0 40.8 20.0 20.6 19.0 17.5 15.0 27.0 22.0 22.1 17.0 31.0 22.0 36.6 23.0 123.3 100.0 106.7 101.0 110.9 102.0 122.7 100.0 111.0 101.0 119.0 100.0 115.8 100.0 24 n.a. 76 5 9 86 78 91 Breakdown of extra absorbtion (%) Pri C Pub C Inves -6 17 83 132 -60 28 96 -25 28 36 41 44 102 -54 51 %oil/ex 79 77 51 90 82 Pri C = Private consumption. %oil/ex = Share of oil in Pub C = Public consumption. exports (1972). Inves = Investment. Source: Gelb, Alan. (1986), Table 2.3 A/N-M = Actual /non-mining GNP The Venezuelan oil windfall cent of Venezuela's non-mining of 1974-78 represented GNP, while the oil windfall of 1978-81 represented 8.7 per cent. After 1979, slower of oil sectors reduced 3.6 indicates the average 11 per real growth the impact of the price windfall. Figure time profile during 1973-1981 of the windfall as measured above for six countries, expressed relative to their non-mining economies each year. Figure 3.6 The oil windfall and its use Algeria, Ecuador, Indonesia, Venezuela , 1973-1981. (Unweighted average: Nigeria, Trinidad and Tobago, and 0.5 0.4 1-~M:C 4D PEF4 C4 T 0.,5 4910-7Z Oi L W a%1 RLL lb 7o 1D 15 Source: Gelb, Alan (1986), 7 75 79 90 I figure 2.1. In Venezuela, the impact of the oil windfall was reflected in fiscal revenues, and we find that central government revenues jumped from 25% of non-mining GNP to 36%. Total revenues in terms of the percentage of non-oil GNP accrued progressed as follows: From 25.2% in the period 1970-72, to 42.1% in the period 1974-1978, to 36.3% in the period 1979-1981. to the government Public oil income in Venezuela had led the importance over a long period of of the public sector to gain time. As in the case of other oil exporters, Venezuela experienced the size state's role an "unparalleled growth in after 1973 and this sector most experienced a considerable extension of its role, towards direct participation in industrial production". In this chapter we evidence capital shows inflows, 1986). have sought for a better sense of how to explain the success or The (Gelb, failure of us that Venezuela Venezuelan industrialization. in spite of having had tremendous did not use them efficiently to further its economic growth. Two main explanations for this problem can be advanced: First, that exchange rates made manufacturing non-competitive and promoted flight of capital. Second, that policies regarding utilization of capital inflows were mistaken; the figures suggest that such investments were production, steel and aluminum in the Guayana region -- placed -- all principally in energy- of them over-concentrated without allowing resources for other sectors. Although non-oil private investment boomed in Venezuela, increased 1974-78 investment public was overwhelmingly investment absorbed about public. In the period half of windfall surpluses. In the next period of 1978-81, the use of windfall was generally similar except that private the expense of domestic investment. 48 consumption increased at As 1986), predicted exchange by the Salter-Swan neoclassical model (Gelb, rates production structure appreciated, towards the and be low if "the impact the quality accelerated spending" The impact the shift in non-traded sectors, dependence on oil for foreign exchange increased. expect that with At the same time, we can of higher public spending on growth may of (Gelb, investment projects declines with 1986: 76). of expanded investment on Venezuela's growth has been, at first glance, disappointing compared to the record of other oil-producers, as we see in the table following: Table 3.3 Algeria Ecuador Indonesia GROWTH TRENDS (%) in the oil exporters, 1967-81. Non mining GNP Domestic investment Goods and non-factor serv Exports Imports 67-72 72-81 67-72 72-81 67-72 72-81 67-72 72-81 9.5 4.7 8.5 8.6 7.6 8.2 17.7 3.2 24.3 10.8 10.2 13.0 5.7 15.9 15.7 (1.0) 6.0 4.3 11.6 6.0 16.7 Iran (a) 10.1 Nigeria 9.2 Trinidad 5.3 Venezuela 6.5 10.8 9.7 19.1 13.3 5.3 5.4 5.1 10.2 (b) 6.1 11.9 21.1 8.7 9.3 3.5 12.9 (b) 2.5 (1.3) (0.3) (4.2) (6.5) (8.7) 17.7 (b) 6.6 7.7 23.7 15.3 8.4 12.8 MEAN (d) 7.3 6.7 12.4 Middle 5.8(c)5.1(c) 8.2 income oil importers 9.3 5.6 7.7 6.7 (1.7) 4.0 9.7 7.4 12.7 1.5 (a) 1967-72 and 1972-7 (b) Deflated data unreliable before 1970. (c) GNP (d) Excluding Iran Source: World Bank in Alan Gelb's "Adjustments to windfall gains" On average, real private were larger than public the next consumption and public investment consumption in period a further rise in a substantial cut in of Gelb's 1974-78. For consumption aggregates implied investment. The example was the period non-oil growth performance exceptional in the 1967-72 period. At 7.3 per cent, it was some 1.5 per cent higher than the average growth of GNP in middle income developing countries. Also, average non- oil growth after 1972 was still 0.6 per cent more rapid than oilimporting developing countries through the favorable period the Venezuela non-oil growth was 1970's. In the during the case of period 1967-72 6.5 per cent and 5.1 per cent for the period 1972- 81. During the latter period economic growth was the same average for middle-income countries, and it should be noted that domestic investment for the period 1972-1981 3.5 per as the cent not only lower than other was on the average oil producers but also lower than middle income oil importers. As we studied analysis of later in examining Chenery's comparative developing countries, growth in income is associated with a shift from and before, on primary production from tradable -agriculture construction. In the and table 3.4 sectors to industry and services, conventionally considered as manufacturing- towards services and we can see that Venezuela had one of the most severely skewed economies in 50 sectoral terms before the oil price rise, that is skewed in terms of the size of the service sector (67 per cent in 1972). Table 3.4 Sectoral Structure. Initial conditions 1972. Alger Ecuad Indone Iran Niger Trinid A N A N A N A N A N A N Agriculture Manufacturing Construction Services (MI) 11 16 13 60 18 25 20 5 50 4 23 26 20 19 5 5 52 50 2 4 Source: Gelb (1986). pg 81. 45 46 11 11 4 3 39 40 12 6 22 18 18 25 6 6 53 51 28 3 39 38 5 15 11 4 45 43 15 5 6 16 22 26 8 6 64 52 9 2 Venez A N 8 14 19 27 6 7 67 52 20 2 A = Actual N = Norm (Chenery, 1975) Venezuela, with Algeria and Indonesia, managed to strengthen their non-oil tradable sectors. These three countries also managed to raise domestic food and agricultural supplies. Despite a policy objective of reducing oil-dependence, non-oil exports contracted on average 1.7 per cent annually during the period 7281. Venezuela, Nigeria and Trinidad did not experience a sharp decline in agriculture and manufacturing. As we noted several the countries studied by petrochemicals and times before, Gelb, heavy metals, and communications systems. and complex and following table). frequently Venezuela, like most of channelled windfall gains into as well as developed transport Public projects tended to be large were highly capital-intensive (see Table 3.5 Macroprojects in oil-exporting countries (a). Country No.of Cost proj. ($b) Aver. Cost Cost Rank Hydro Metal Other Infra Cost 1980 1980 amo. carbon Ind. struc ($m) GNP wind devel. ture. fall countries. Iran 108 119.6 1,107 Algeria 69 38.7 561 Venezuela 27 27.4 1,015 Mexico 59 26.0 441 Nigeria 19 14.4 758 Indonesia 44 14.4 327 1.57 1.07 0.51 0.18 0.17 0.23 10.2 4.2 5.4 5.1 0.9 1.1 Trinidad(b) 7 1.35 4.5 6.9 983 2 5 10 .2 15 16 30 36 33 46 26 41 7 7 41 17 11 18 9 33 7 12 16 16 54 23 19 25 47 25 -- 61 29 -- -- (a) Projects with costs exceeding $100 million. (b) Gas-based industrial projects only. Includes Tenneco-Midcon LNC project proposed for 1988. (c) 1977 GNP and oil windfall. Sources: Murphy (1983) table 2.5; Auty and Gelb (1984) and table 2.13 in Gelb's "Adjustments to windfall gains" (1986). Venezuela's investment program placed heavy emphasis on metals (steel and aluminum), representing five times its 1980 oil windfall or half Principally in its the 1980 Guayana accumulated in this region?. partially put GNP. forth in Where are these investments? region. Why have those investments The answer to this chapter 2, where we studied the linkages between the Accion Democratica party, which was the the first question was recipient of and decisive oil windfall, and the Guayana Development Corporation. In my opinion these described set the precedent the (Black-hole effect), arrangements within region institutional huge investments previously of the current large investments in 52 which CVG in turn caused in order to achieve the industrial support required by the industries already in place. This restructuring will be the focus of chapter 4. 4) CORPORACION VENEZOLANA DE GUAYANA (CVG): In order to understand fully the chapter we should briefly recapitulate significance what we have of this seen thus far. Chapter Two covered the following points: First, we outlined the progress the end of a of the successful import substitution process, from 40's up to mid-70's, and how this model seems to have become exhausted. We also saw how the and industry collaborated during observed how the government, Venezuelan economy launched the linkages Guayana between AD and AD an and We Guayana's for explain attempt to economic growth development. becoming a strong image Guayana the democratic era. Second, we in and balance Venezuelan government the noticed in the country, the ideological development, former. The the latter linkages between the large investments in Guayana since 1973. Third, we observed the current situation of economy, where diversify the the Venezuelan the Government is faced with reduced incomes and, in its urgent necessity to reactivate the economy (no real growth from 1980 to 1985), it seeks investment from private or foreign investors or through added new debt. These additional investments have many new funds: investments prospective clients the in state-owned order to who wait enterprises get a share in these scarce which require more out of the red, and the private- sector partners. 54 Later on, importance of in the third chapter, These performed so took note of the the investments made in the heavy metal industries complex of Guayana in relation to increases. we investments poorly in the gains help from the explain comparison to why many oil price Venezuela has other developing countries. In this chapter I will explain how CVG is implementing an import substitution industrial strategy installed industrial substitution policy This time CVG is complex. This for consumer designed to is not goods as an support the simple import it was in the 60's. attempting a more difficult and delicate one: the substitution of industrial inputs and capital goods complex. For this next period, CVG is depending participation of the private sector, but the private alternative having investments and distrusts for this on the sector has the state-owned enterprises as a principal client. This key variable of alternative investments for the private sector is the dilemma the integration of the sector. This that CVG has to solve in order to promote state-owned enterprises with the private chapter will investigate the steps CVG is taking to accomplish this delicate task. In doing so we must remember that the expectations in 1965 for the Guayana region in 1980 were that it would be a main export center. With this in mind we will then into enter conclusions the of this thesis with regard to Venezuela's economic crisis. 4.1) Introduction. The implementation of CVG's new industrial objectives cannot be fully understood without presenting the internal restructuring of CVG and the evolution of its previous goals within a historical framework. 4.1.1) Original Objectives: The Guayana Development Corporation was created by presidential decree No. 430, enacted on December 29, 1960, in the form of an Autonomous Institute of the Venezuelan State, attached to the Office of the President of the Republic. Said decree assigned to the CVG the following objectives: a) To study the resources of Guayana, both within the zone of development and outside of it when required by their nature. b) To study, develop and organize the exploitation of the Caroni river's hydroelectrical potential. c) To program the development of the region in accordance with, and within the scope of, the National Plans. d) To promote the development of the region in both the private and the public sector. e) To coordinate the economic and social activities carried out in the region by various official organizations. f) To contribute to the organization, planning, development and operation of the public utilities required for the development of the area. g) task which Executive, any other the National To carry out, by fiat of may be connected to operations outside the zone, in cases where there exists a close relationship to those being performed within the zone. 4.1.2) Goals: The activity of the Guayana Development Corporation is set out by the guidelines of the Regionalization No action of the Amazon and VI National 478, which Corporation to Plan and expanded the spatial scope of the the Federal in Territories of the Delta Amacuro. In this sense, CVG participates in the formulation, coordination, and evaluation and by Decree of the execution of of plans projects related and programs to physical infrastructure, urban regulation, mining, agricultural and forest developments, promotion and execution of technical improvements and training programs. According to Decree number the Republic on February coordination of the region. It State was necessary 2, issued 2, 1984, enterprises by the Presidency of CVG is entrusted with the located in to amend its organic statutes to adapt its organization and operation to this new mandate. CVG work through two the Guayana To this end, kinds of managerial units: the enterprises and the Office of the these two Vice President for Development. Through units, CVG fulfills its responsibilities: the integral development of the region, the coordination of the public sector agencies and the coordination of the State Enterprises. 4.1.3) Industrial Development: The Guayana by their region has variety and of good development a at its disposal of resources which, quantity, part of are ideally the industries needed by the suited for the country for a first rate development: a) Abundant water, both for the production of energy and for industry, navigation, agriculture and human consumption. b) A port, capable of handling an intense river traffic of more than 700 ships per year, through the use of the existing wharves in Cuidad Guayana. c) High content of iron and bauxite ores as well as other minerals; abundant and low-cost hydroelectric power, oil and gas in the neighboring Eastern region which includes the Orinoco bituminous oil belt, and the most extensive forest reserves in the country. Moreover, its advantageous location on the Orinoco navigation channel gives products from Guayana a ready access to international markets. The Guayana program was conceived contribution to the diversification of the means of as an important Venezuelan economy by the development of an industrial complex based on these 58 extraordinary resources, and this is goal creation consists of the competition with Caracas and center of balanced for attraction national its main objective. A second of a pole of development, in other cities and country, as a so as to lead to a more population, development of the incorporate to into the Venezuelan economy an immense region which, although historically important, has remained underpopulated When speaking and practically marginal. of the Industrial Development of Guayana, one must take into account that it has been oriented not only national market, but also the importance towards the towards the full realization of its export potential. To reaffirm suffices to mention the 1975-1979 period sector, which both bolivar investment by the 42 public to quote two Guayana program, it sector and the private billion bolivars. The Plan IV steel represents while by the production increase amounted to only the investment plans carried out during the exceeded production expansion of itself investment 3.5 billion outstanding examples, only in a 15 billion the aluminum bolivars. These are without mentioning investments in specialty steels, ferrosilicons, cements, forging, castings and other products. The 240 meter drop second largest river - in confluence with of its the Orinoco the Caroni - which is Venezuela's last 210 kilometers before its river, represents a hydroelectrical potential of more than 17 million kilowatts, one of the largest of any river in the world. A general perspective of the main achievements and plans of CVG is given in table (4.1). 4.2) Organizational evolution. CVG has industrial progressed program, from to a corporation the State region. its creation, enterprises the located of an in the Guayana in charge of the the Caroni River hydroelectrical plant, the steel plant and the new Government charge Corporation had gone through various stages; at the beginning it was mainly development of in Regional Development Corporation and coordinator of Since a city. (1978-83), During CVG the last Christian Democratic suffered from a certain degree of financial constraints. One reason for these financial constraints may be that the Guayana project has never been a priority for the leaders of this party. This is demonstrated by the actions of the Ministry of Public Works in the previous Christian Democratic government, which was mentioned in Chapter 1. Having no political support, CVG had three different Presidents during that government (1978-83). The reduced income from the oil industry has moved public opinion against the actual government. As we noted, the resources TABLE 4. 1 * ** *.* *** * *.*:** *.**** ** * **** * **** * ** * ************** GUAY ANA DEVELOPMENT CORPORAT ION (CVG) *** ** * *** ** **** *** Program of developments RESOURCE ENERGY ALUMINUM STEEL FOR 196) Macagua I 3.60 000 KW Non existant Sidor 1, 000, 000 tons FOR 1986 FOR 2010 Guri 10,000 MK Bajo Caroni Macagua II Tocoma Caruachi 18,000 MK Capac i ty 40).())C) tons 2nd plant + 3th complex Capacity 2, 000, 000 tons Si dor 4,800., 000 Pellets Si dor tons 6,600 , 000 Direct reduction 4 , 00C) 000 tons GOLD Free explotation Mi nerven 1., 500 Ks. WOOD & PAPER Pellets FMO 10 , 0v0,00 tons New modul -recov. 5, 500, 000 tons Minerven new plant & ref of 3,000 Ks. Caribe pine 190., 000 Has. Pulp plant proj. Caribe pine 400, 000 Has. Pulp plant CTMP 200, 000 tons. Pulp plant Kraft 200,000 tons. Lumber mill Widening of the chanel to Pto Ordaz Widening and signalization of the chanel from Pto. Ordaz to el Jobo (BauXiven) Bux iven projectterminal P. OrdazEl Jobal project Navegation: - Middle Orinoco - High Orinoco - Apure - Orinoco resot..trces Widening hydroelectric resources Widening hydroelectric resources Ferry boat betwwen Pto. OrdaZ y San Fel i x Free explotation OR INOCO Chanel up to Pto. Ordaz Ferry boat between: Bolivar-Monagas in Los Fajardos Bol :i var-Anzoategui in Soledad CARONI 4, 800, 000 tons Utilization hydroelectric of URFJAN Inteoration of urban centers. Roads Ferv boats System af roads and avenues Bridges: - Two bridges over Caroni INTRA-REGION Ferry boat: - Rio Aro Rio Caura Rio Cuc:hivero Railroad: - El Pao-Palua Piar City-PtoN Or d a INTERREGION Ferry boat: Bolivar to Monagas between San FelixLos Barrancos Bolivar to Anzoategui between 'Bolivar-Soledad Bolivar to Guarico between CaicaraCabruta POPULAT ION Guayana 115,000 habs river Widening of road Highways: C. Bolivar-P.Ordaz S. Felix-Upata Fery boats: Rio Caura R. Cuchivero Bridges: Rio Aro Rio Caura & Rio Cuchivero (const) Bridges R asphapt: El Dorado-S. Elena Caicara-Pto Ayacuchc Widening of road system Angosturita bridge and rail (mix vial Express system between S.FelixGuayana City. Highways: S. Felix-Upata Integrated road sy Conclusion DoradoSta. Elena and Caicara-P.Ayacucho Bridges: Caura and Cuchivero (conclusion) Express system (S. Felix P. Ordaz) sys-Widening of the Integrated vial system. vial tem. Bridges: Bridges: IInd bridge over Angostura-Orinoco the Orinoco river. between C. Bolivar bridge over IInd and Anzoategui the Orinoco (rail) Ferry boats mainRailroad system between: tained joining Bolivar st S. Felix-Los with the rest of Barrancos the country. Cai cara--Cabruta 978,068 habs 2,300),000 habs habs 1 ,200,C00 350,000 (1979) Guayan a (1985) 554,704 Guayana City *** ***** ** * ******* ****** ************* *** ************* **** ******** * Sources: CVG - Oficina para el nuevo enlace sobre el Orinoco Maria Engracia de Delgado (1986) * .......... ZONA DE DESARROLLO POR EL ESTATUTO CAPITALES DE ESTADO LIMITE DE ESTADO LIMITE DE DISTRITO VIALIDAD ESTABLECIDO C.V.G. PRIMARIA VIALIDAD SECUNDARIA -- CARRETERA DIQUE DIGUES DIGUES EN PROYECTO OLEODUCTOS GASDUCTO AEROPUERTOS DESARROLLO ISLA PROYECTO RECURSOS AGROPECUARIO GUARA AGROFORESTALES ZONA DE MANGLARES (3% PETROLEO HIERRO DIAMANTE ORO CARBON SAL MANGANESO MAGNESITA DOLOMITA KAOLIN CAL YESO ZONA DELTA ? * CAW0 -4 14$A IAAA -U ''4,ov CAN' il 434~~ . UNCION tP A ** INVO LEAGU CRUZ0 x/ -0 "usLm */.... I.. CO .,O $ 99841 *Plo 4 EA4 CUA4ANI ~4 0 11. A A- PITA 4 a 4I 4 44 a >4-,- 7 ... ~7 if- ~ \((~'~ \ Ky t~\ d 04 d a a. a K... - . limlopw. or 4 444 4P4*. 7e J\~ -e .M4..A4d.~j 0! .44-44--S 1)1 (~ \ /4. K: .4 .j~i 4 7 t 4 A. A& All -4 S ~f. / .. 4 %cm UWl 1 K /7 444 {j\4~ - a 0 I V / - - N 4- Ilj vi, = 4 X * A, 4- It -7 4,444 (44 0:1 to achieve economic growth at the State's disposal are the public (basically industries and oil complex) Guayana the and the private sector (industry and agriculture). to the again given priority (1983-1988) has The new AD government Guayana project, and some changes have been made in order to increase CVG's autonomy in relation to the executive branch of government. of One the major in made changes 1984 was the decision that the President of CVG will also be a Minister of the Government. directly to difficulties This means the that President that a of rose President of CVG will report Venezuela, when Ministry of Development. At State enterprises the CVG the same located in bypassing was subordinated time, CVG the Guayana previous to the coordinates the region, since some of the state-owned enterprises had major equity participation by the Venezuelan Development Fund (for example, Alcasa). At present, after the institutional renovated political commitment to the Guayana coming directly from the and the project, funds are Inter-American Bank and the Venezuelan Development Fund through the These resources changes Industrial Credit Fund (FONCREI). have been principally addressed to the aluminum industry, for projects such the "Los Pidiguaos" bauxite smelters of ALCASA from as the opening and exploitation of mine, the expansion of the aluminum 125,000 to 200,000 tons, amplification of VENALUM from 250,000 to 400,000 tons. and the 4.3) New leadership - Leopoldo Sucre Figarella. Now that of CVG, Figarella has become the new leader Lepoldo Sucre to advance from its goals will pursue the corporation of an industrial park to acquiring responsibility mere promotion for the development of the entire region and coordinating all the activities. Figarella, whose leadership skills are indisputable, descendants of is a native of the Guayana region. His family are a group of Corsican families who have played a strong role in the economy and leadership of Bolivar) through its the region from Bolivar Figarella history. City (Ciudad was also Minister of Public Works throughout the AD period from the dictatorship until the Christian Democratic government of 1969-1973. This position provided him with local support and technocracy. His achievements programs. leadership since and The resources set the support broad-based institutional aside for 1983 is local of the national evident in the rapid support for the regional changes achieved and the financial the region since 1983 are examples of Figarella's executive abilities. 4.4) Recent economic objectives: There is no doubt important role in the order to that industrial the Guayana region must play an reactivation of Venezuela in keep pace with the new job requirements added each year and even to absorb some of the present unemployment. The region offers the resources natural (principally which achieve a diversified economy, resources) to help reduce may dependence on oil. The decline promoted of oil revenues and the economic situation that devaluation reexamination of in 1983, have the national the industrial government, nine months after required industrial strategy. the Guayana region, the first redefining obviously available strategy In terms of from document came from devaluation and a the the CVG previous one month before new elections. The new strategy proposed: - Linking the basic industry to the medium and small by import industries. - Reducing the vulnerability of basic industry substitution. - Expanding present regional development to include new territory. - Use of industry to take advantage of the primary sector. - Complementing the industrialization process with a commercialization process. Linking basic industry to medium and small industry. At the end of 1982 CVG was aware that commercial and other industries were closely related to basic-industry fact between that such a dependency necessarily mean that it is a the two exists does not correct model 63 activity. The to follow. At the time it would occur that harmony was projected when small and medium size industry produced the majority of the inputs required by basic industry. Reducing the industry of vulnerability means by of import substitution. The next step in opportunities which Currently, it could be promotion industrial arose when the cheaper to results bolivar from the was devaluated. produce locally some of the inputs for industry. Large amounts (60 per cent) of inputs to the Guayana complex were imported was to reduce such in 1982, imports. For will no longer import as much and the first challenge example, the aluminum industry bauxite, once the development of the bauxite mines is completed (BAUXIVEN). Integrating regional development with regional spatial region must not only development. The industrial process in the Guayana take advantage of the large resources of the region but also promote the extension of this development to marginal areas, even those regions where there these reasons it seemed is no significant State presence. For necessary to flank the economic and financial decisions with considerations of regional strategy. Use of the industry in the development of the primary sector. This was of understood as agriculture and certain the development to a certain degree organizational development of also the agro-industry, and for the exploitation of precious models minerals in an industrialized and profit way. Complementing the industrialization with process a commercialization process. The purpose of this step was to establish support for those industries which, because of commercialization process their could size, not develop a themselves. Its goal was to allow such industries to place their products abroad. In this way, the small and medium sectors will benefit their own international sales import substitution model even though they do not have organizations. started to At this time the show the possibility of exports. 4.5) Division of Industrial and Mining Promotion (Gerencia de of the strategy promocion Industrial y Minero). Especially after the devaluation 1983, explained previously, needed a channel for its implementation. In consequence the division of Industrial and Mineral Promotion was created (or reformulated its previous goals). One of the first ideas developed create an information service 65 to by be this division used by all was to of CVG, especially by the industry offered to promotion division to be Servicio de informacion para el (SIDI or the public itself and desarrollo industrial). Such an was designed information system to cover the following subsystems: 1) Access and information recovery. 2) (SIMA); Aluminum the information related to all including Bauxite, alumina and aluminum. 3) Industrial inputs (Subsistema de insumos industriales SII). 4) Legal information (Subsistema de informacion legal SIL). 5) Financial information SIAF), related to (Subsistema de informacion financiera mechanism, financial entities disposable for industrial promotion. 6) Industrial projects and information register (Subsistema de informacion y registro de proyectos industriales). This subsystem includes a project bank Development Division. which This bank was initially has now the Industrial become public. At that time, an initiative to identify potential new industrial projects called project-ideas characteristics of was the also region promoted and to to take consider the advantage the potentially become industrialized. Also, the Division of Industrial serious effort to initiate an industrial Promotion proposed input survey, a not only covering basic industry, but also the whole industrial complex of the region. All these new ideas Division and of Industrial led Mineral to the promotion Promotion of the (Gerencia de promocion industrial y minero) as the responsible agent for the new strategy in the government. 4.5.1) Import substitution committee and the promotion of new industries: There will be two focuses of the new division: first, import substitution for the Guayana complex, and second, promotion of new industries. In the context of Guayana, the import substitution and export-oriented issue. Most of the actual effort by CVG appraisal of the input state-owned enterprises industries is a crucial is oriented requirements industrial complex. The corporation trade-off between of the towards the Guayana is collaborating heavy with other such as PDVSA (oil corporation) in order to measure an aggregate demand and develop a coordinated import substitution strategy in such industries. The CVG objective promote, could have a the state has defined is certain export capacity. In other words, certain areas where private investors can obtain definite guaranteed there excess that the industries which they will sales to CVG industries, and from capacity can be transferred to exports. Even though there have been no policies for specific export industries, some export industries have appeared. What does not seem to be defined is a strategy for promoting export oriented industries per se. 4.5.2) Import substitution committee: Since the first attempts to the evaluate demand of basic industry, there has been resistance from the purchase departments of Guayana the about information principally from to industries inputs; the the the Regional (1983) made evident the necessity to input. The requested have come Private Industries. of industry. The policy since 1983 in produce locally the basic- private industries demanded information in order to address their basic complaints such Chamber of industries increased their claims when devaluation These private industry provision efforts reality the to is supply that Guayana the requirements of the import substitution complex has had relatively little success. It is from this perspective that we must analyze the import substitution strategy for the Guayana complex. the Import Substitution Committee Importaciones) was created with CVG industries. (Comite In September 1985 de Sustitucion de representatives from all of the This committee's principal goal is to coordinate actions in order to achieve a progressive and effective import substitution. The committee's main goals were determined as: - Diminishing the dependency on foreign supplies of raw 1) materials, machinery, equipment, spare parts and technology. 2) - Joining efforts to diminish the negative effects related to the flight of foreign currency. 3) - Contributing to the increase of the private industrial park, through consolidation of the installed facilities and the creation of new investment opportunities. In 1986, the achievements of this committee could be summarized as follows: - Creation of a unique register of suppliers, in order to achieve common technical standards for imported inputs. - Disseminate the import substitution policy. - Evaluation of metal-related industries installed in the region, in order to estimate their capacities for import substitution. - Exchanges among the different importsubstitution committees in the different CVGindustries. - Evaluation of the progress/status of the import substitution industry. program for each CVG- - Development of product specifications for common products in the basic industries. - Presentation of a list of project-ideas to the "Gerencia de Promocion Industrial". - Presentation of the achievements to different governmental agencies, chambers of commerce, PDVSA (oil corporation), and Engineers' professional association. - Establishment of guidelines for an information register for each industry. - Utilization of common experience and specific information to evaluate common objectives, such as qualification of suppliers. - Organization of a forum national entrepreneurs substitution. - Support of a with local and interested in import special South-West trade (Guayana-Andean) for the experimental transport of metallurgic coke to the Guayana complex via the Orinoco river. - Establishment and utilization of a continuous process of providing information among national agencies in order to facilitate information on the exchange of common objectives and experiences. - Provision of a list of requirements for parts and pieces actually local chambers of commerce. - Attendance by substitution import the to the imported committee and the personnel of the basic industries at a presentation organized by PDVSA to present the unified register of PDVSA-suppliers to the oil and petrochemical industries. - Coordinate meetings CVG- the with Corporative Planning Vice-presidency and the for the committee, substitution import analyzing import substitution purpose to problems and studying possible alternatives to advance in the process. 4.5.3) Identification of new investment opportunities, promotion of new industries and the implementation strategy. The promotion of new industries can from implementation the strategy. beginning of 1983 CVG initiated a not be seen separately As was noted before, at the compilation of the project- ideas that the Corporation had accumulated since 1960 and decided to amplify this project-idea-register (pre-investment). Then, with the creation of the Industry and Mineral Promotion Division, CVG selected consulting seven companies Marshall y Asociados, financing of of the largest (Inelectra, Cavein, feasibility and studies Venezuelan engineering Technoconsult, Vepica, Otepi, Proyecta) to be and proposed the done by one of these companies (sharing the expenses and the risks). Once the project-idea is identified, the makes a proposal for a feasibility study at market prices. Once an agreement on such a study is achieved, cent of costs of consulting company CVG then gives 50 per the study to the consulting firm. The other 50 70 per cent is the consulting the consulting practiced by places capital and or utilities, by covered the money. firm is firm can Then, if consulting company will be a not important participate the The modality company. study stockholder in to CVG; CVG with its labor, is favorable, the the new industry. does not have to come exclusively from CVG, This project-idea it can come from any source. The most important result is that use of the local in this way an efficient "know-how" is guaranteed, because no one else has a better understanding of the national engineering capacities than these firms. This practice manages to combine two worlds, one with the financial resources and one with the resources of information and "know how" (Interview with Rafael Pena, Manager of la Division de Promocion Industrial y Minero, January 1987). This practice was well most of them having received by the Consulting firms, been in precarious situations prior to this initiative. In 1984 CVG CORPOINDUSTRIA enterprises) and The interest signed (in two charge the other of these important of medium One with and small FONCREI (Industrial Fund). agreements is to reinforce collaboration and grant Guayana to promoting one with between CVG and the small resources agreements: the previously accorded with the medium size region. industries, Such agreements were Venezuelan Development 71 and to Fund. Also, collaborative activities were undertaken between CVG, CI and other industries without formal written agreements. the industrial park survey Examples are realized in 1986 and the exchanges with the Industrial Chamber of the Zulia region. the After all this effort on outcome of the strategy part of import of CVG, which is the substitution, the next table gives us the value and quantities substituted in by the different enterprises: Table 4.2 Results in the process of import substitution in CVG's state owned enterprises. Concept A Quantity (1) 1983 B A - 503 1984 B 964 A - 1985 B 2,538 3 1986 A B 3,514 6 (accumulated) Amount (M bs) at Bs 7.5/$ at Bs 14.5/$ increase 74 $9.9 $5.1 119 $15.9 $8.2 60% 190 $25.3 $13.1 60% (1) Quantity of inputs substituted. A = Material and spare parts 312 $41.6 $21.5 64% B= Raw materials Source: Committee on Import Substitution (1986). Firms: Sidor, Venalum, Alcasa, Interalumina, Fesilven, and Ferrominera del Orinoco (Iron ore mines). This table is the theaction of the new only information strategy. The available to evaluate information provided is useless since we can not refer to the total amount of imports to ire TOTAL AND PER CENT EXPORTS: : TABLE 5.1 = = = . ==m= Mmmm= = = = === = = == = of SDRs) 1975 1974 1973 Year === Millions ==mu= = ======== = CoMModi ty breakdawn: - 18 0.2% AluMinuM e.ports per cent of total interawual change - Iron 109 1.5p ore esports per ceut of total interawual change - 247 3.4% Other 1 I exports per cent of total interams.al change change EXPORTS IN GNP C4> interaual SHARE OF 30. 3% Sour-ce: 1> C4) 'Balance of Payment-s Statistics". Ministery of Energy and Mines. TABLE 5.2 : NET EXPORTS OF THE GUAVANA mm 1972 1971 Yea-. EXPORTS: Aluminum: ==== =========== m = 114 0.8% 5.6% 108 1. 0 1>1 Aount Value C1) TAP CMT3 (1> <2> & C3> Value 27.9% REGION mmmmumm 326 2.2% 14.4P 265 2.6% 15.4% 16,930 14,638 10,959 15.7% 33.6% 51.1t 29.7 32.2% 30.5% 24.6% 1975 1974 1973 1976 1978 1977 ==== 14,793 1 -12.6%1 24.3I 1983 1982 1981 ==m==m ========m===m====== ====m===== 14.3 14.0 10.4 10.1 11.3 11.4 6.3 7.6 17.0 18.7 102.7 143.7 209.1 335.3 233.9 366.1 208.6 275.4 I 1 I 292.2 386.0 924 1,127 1,063 1 1,031 1,069 941 868 696 21.3 <:2>^ 1,495 54.3 C2>^ 2,077 113.1 <2>^ 2,030 159.7 C2)>- 2,278 I 2,320 13,600 6,500 600 149.7 4.0 15,260 12,400 700 139.1 5.1 16,103 11,800 2,900 279.1 10.4 15,531 13,600 2,900 334.4 8.7 189.7 336.1 727.5 860.2 179.3 2 281.5 24,772 9,106 250 274.5 0.9 18,685 8,457 575 229.4 2.5 13, 683 6,338 250 171.7 1.5 i W m===M nmmmmm==am=mwmm= w=mmum =0 a==== w" ===mum mmmumftmm 15.5 2.6 15.3 2.6 ======= m wminawmm wwmmMmam 9.2 2.2 0.3 12.6 2.2 0.4 6.0 1.4 0.6 66.7 15.3 6.9 34.3 7.9 3.3 32.7 7.5 4.4 17.1 1 3.0 1 41.2 7.6 31.2 6.7 60.0 13.4 52.0 11.6 75.5 26.5 191.9 70.0 251.9 94.5 348.3 141.5 323.0 1 129.4 1 330.0 122.9 8.1 7 1!.7 145.9 135.5 I 128.2 =======m=m=mm m m=m==== ===---====-==-====--==-===----=-=mm =nmm 76.9 27.1 12 ======== =m ==m ==m==== = 97.0 ======= ======= 259.2 629.7 =u==m======i== C1995>, United Nations. C>) Yearbook of International CoMModities Statistics - Yearbook, 1984. Voloune I. C.2) Trade Statistics Original source Sanco Central de Venezuela. Country profile. C3> EIU. Uenezuela 86-87. C4> Ministory of Energy and Mines. Lagouen "Data on Petroleum and EconoMy of Venezuela". 1984 ==== 784 5.6% 11.4P 67.0 11,121.0 15.9 1 264.5 5.3 6.1 1 ======i===m=== ======= 370.0 C3>^ 411.0 C3> ^ 134.0 C3)^1 192.0 <3>)^ 13,3 10 16, 107 4,686 81.0 C3> - 15,481 19,050 5,102 108.0 C3!)^ TAP 711.0 no Own own , ==m=m===m 714.3 ============-= ------------= Total Amount Produced =n =========== 1985 ========= 585.0 3.5 0.8 0.3 ===n=== 704 4.5% 31.31 wwmammmwmwmwwmwnam a=*m=amownminnn 6.6 2.3 0.5 162.6 ===== winmmmmmmm 11,200 1 9,449 12,900 1 12,250 4,000 1 3,542 186.8 I 161.6 21.9 21.4 I 2.3 1 0.7 I 0.1 1 3.1 a w======== 106 0.OP 34.2% 13,963 15,577 13,631 14.3% -10.4% -7.9% 24.8 27.5% 22.3% 1 ======= 79 0.5% 5.3 1986. 1980 1979 m===m==== ==m====m=m m==== ===========m=mm TOTAL DIFFERENCE: ============== 536 3.9% 29.5% 414 1 2.81 -4.2%1 432 2.6% 32.5% 10.5 5.8 TOTAL: ==== = 405 2.97 12.2% ~12.2% 75 0.6% 0.0W 75 1 0.5% Sp -47.6%! 143 0.4? 2 5. 4% 7.9 5.0 A IMPORTS Bausite AMount Gross CMT3 C1> AMount Al CMT3 C1> IMportsCS3 <1) ========n 3 1985 == = 361 2.3% 411 3.0% 43.2% 287 i 1.9pli -. = == 10.6 6.7 mmw== Alumina AMount CMT3 Cl IMportst*3 <1> = of US dollars> Cin Million TOTAL: mm m mmmmmmmm = = 347 2.0% 12.3% 309 2.1% 128.9% 135 1.2,% 650.0% = 1984 1983 1982 1991 = == Monetary Fund. Volume 3?, Yearbook, part I, International Lagoven "Data on Petroleum and Economy of Venezuela". =======m= ===== Iron Ore: TAP CMT3 C:4> Dom Cows CBs2 C4> ExportsCBs3 <4> 138.7 154.3 Esportst*3 C1> 8s/* Emports Check ratio source: = 7,255 TOTAL ======== = 14,433 12,668 14,017 I 12,609 16,008 13,889 6,881 10,431 90.7% 92.7p 94.8eI 94.6% 94.9% 94.8% 95.2% 92.5 ; 14.5% -12.2% - 10. 0% 15. 3% -12.4P.1 33.2% 51.6% Oil Steel = ~0-9101 eiports per cent of total interahual change - = mi === 1980 1979 1978 1977 1976 ==== = M= ==== ==m == evaluate the success or failure of the policy. Knowing that CVG industries are capital intensive, technology, and judging committee and the new would seem that the with large amounts of foreign action of the import substitution the industrial strategy by these numbers, it substitution has been quite modest in real terms. In my understanding, the actual implementation appears to be somewhat effective. But even though the implementation might be the right one, that does not mean that the correct; again the question substitute ? Are we is, at certain that strategy itself is what price these inputs we are going to are going to be produced cheaply in the country? Assuming that the amounts substituted are not significant, we can explain the failure of this strategy in one of three ways: (1) the strategy is so recent that it results; (2) the strategy has not the main problems confronted hasn't had time to show been directed by (import substitution); (3) it is a the towards solving goal to be accomplished right implementation but a wrong mandate (import substitution). Exploring the second and third options together, we saw that CVG industries were oversized and the logical interest of CVG is to reduce foreign dependance in its industries; at the same time, the private sector industries. This oriented is mainly will explain industries and why interested why CVG the 73 in export-oriented is not promoting exportprivate sector is not more collaborating with intensively suggest substitution. Also, this strategy is government Venezuelan entirely intensive industry development against preference for allocate the industry, where resources among government in import to biased me that towards the capital light manufacturing. This industries was acquired in its capital intensive relation with the oil the a benefits from one or two of them. 74 few it was easy for them to industries, and reap the 5) CONCLUSIONS: How should we industrial program? analyze We can the performance express of Guayana's our evaluation in political terms, in economic terms, in financial rentability or in social terms. Starting with the political played an important role in the democratic process. CVG possible; generous with state is when A strong approach, we can say that CVG strengthening of government, in conditions permitted AD and in the turn made a strong the government was the program. Today, even with scarce resources the giving additional funds to the CVG program. If the period 1974-79 was biased towards the Guayana Industrial program, today this tendency is maintained. Even with program, what investments proportion in the political are the accumulated support financial there? enjoyed and We economic should IMF (table 5.1) show gains of the look at the 1965. The figures that oil still contributed 91 per cent of export earnings, although that the first the Guayana which Guayana is contributing to total exports and compare these figures with projections made in provided by by in 1965 planners promised Guayana region would account for 25 per cent of exports earnings by 1980. 75 actual investments I have made an estimate of actual exports. relate to total 45,000 From this accumulated investments in The total were spent mm Bs billion US dollars. equals 16,3 Guayana are 70,000 mm Bs, which and how they in the 1974-79 period distributed in the following way: 15,000 mm Bs / $3,5 billions Steel (Plan IV Sidor) 3,500 mm Bs / $0,8 billions Aluminum 30,213 mm Bs / $7,0 billions Electricity 22,019 mm Bs I $5,1 billions - Guri Dam 8,194 mm Bs I $1.9 billions - Transmission These figures are ones the by provided normally CVG; overruns suggest higher amounts. In relation to power generation, EDELCA, the operator of the Caroni River hydroelectric dams not covering the power of Macagua and Guri (1OMK), is generation costs. The Guri dam expansion decided on during the oil bonanza optimistically assumed domestic demand doubling every six years, but the dam is now being utilized at mere 60 per cent capacity mainly for problems in the construction of the distribution system. In relation to the Aluminum industry we can say that the original investment estimates for the three aluminum projects was $1.2 billion (Auty, 1986) that would have an value added millions. However, the implementation the capital of those of $400 projects doubled cost, eroding competitiveness of all plants. Despite the experiences of the first expansions, further growth is foreseen in order to absorb additional Guri power. As for steel, the worst investment, the planned expansion from 1 million to 15 millions tons over the period been contained at the provided by Plan IV. tons in present This design of 4.8 million tons capacity reached 2.32 million 1983, and today, eight years after the initiation of the expansion, output has yet despite capacity 1975-1990 has an expenditure to reach of -$ 5 half of the 4.8 target billions, which represents an overrun of 50 per cent. We can temporarily easily say drained the country. And there is through current the that the Guayana diversification a risk that such development possibilities has of the tendencies will remain industrial strategy of import substitution and vertical integration of the industries in place. For example, we can mention the following current investments to be directed towards the region: ALUMINUM: Bauxite mines total cost foreign exch. requirements (IDB) ALCASA - Expansion 120 m to 220 m ton $460 mm (2) $108 mm (2) - $720 mm (1) $15 mm (1) 5th line of smelter Purchase of Belgian mill $640 mm (1) VENALUM - 110 m ton expansion - Purchase of US downstream facilities. CONARE, wood industry development foreign exchange req. (IDB) 77 ? ? $86 mm (2) $34 mm (2) EDELCA, expansion of electric syst. foreign exchange req. (IDB) TOTAL $1,750 mm (2) $350 mm (2) $3,671 mm 1,500 mm Bs. or $100 mm (3) Orinoco Bridge Sources: (1) EIU, Venezuela Country report No 1, 1987. (2) Interamerican Development Bank. (3) El Universal, Caracas. Assuming 14.5 Bs/US$ Assuming that these will will not be overruns, be the final costs we can see that once oversize investments in energy production are in place, all related and aluminum) ambitioning industries (steel become oversize in consequence. The steel industry 15 million forward linkages, of the and that they tons. The industry pursuing and minimum sizeable plants pushed up the size entire chain (aluminum smelters, bauxite exploitation). alumina production and From a minimum of 3 million tons for the bauxite mine, CVG is immediately production. Making aluminum tempted to increase alumina less questionable further increase in alumina production, and in consequence aluminum. Other reasons for the One, the voracity of miscalculation of implementation process, due to partners and cost a lack the overconfidence owned enterprises participation of are characterized foreign capital for domestic and region are: scheduling in the of adequate international of the local ones. CVG's state- technology and efficiency during would compensate the Guayana by a very low level of that will would provide modern the implementation phase, and gaps in technical, managerial and 78 a similar Second, operations. plant marketing skills during overconfidence in the stability of high oil prices, which led our policy to makers even justifiable at the that think of development Guyana was costs, because there would always be high available funds derived from oil exports. at element dramatic most The is present that, in my understanding, the private sector prefers to participate with the oil sector instead of that emphasis great the of spite with CVG, joint ventures investing in CVG is giving to in the implementation of an innovative import substitution strategy. The new exchange measures taken by Venezuela since the improved climate 1986 and foreign investments (Nov 1986) might for improve the actual trends, but there is no doubt that the success of the strategy new will depend on convincing of the private sector the opportunities offered by CVG. We can easily see strategy industrial intensive, in other that I gave sufficient mainly the the Venezuelan thesis that based on industrial projects. a few capital- This strategy of industrialization was inefficient and concentrated in Guayana; preventing or is (1973-87) resource-based resource base projects through this resources from diversifying manufacturing industries. reasons political input to in the 79 explain why in smaller I am convinced that happened, decision making process that launched overambitious targets, "overestimating benefits and underestimating difficulties" (Auty, It is without this input have been impossible to create this completely new pole of development, building an employs 1986). clear to me that a major political input was vital to the launching of the Guayana project and that it would the potential half a million entirely city inhabitants plants. However, the time has come for a the political component in which now and houses and scores of industrial changing of the guard: the decision making process must now give way to a managerial style less encumbered by the political power accumulated by the Venezuelan government. It is not merely a question of the government stepping back, it is also that the private sector must step forward and assume responsibility for the future growth of the Venezuelan economy. 6) BIBLIOGRAPHY Resource based Industralization and Country Auty, Richard M., Size: Venezuela and Trinidad y Tobago. Geoforum, Vol 17, No 3. pp 325-338, 1986. Azpurua, Antonio, The Guayana democratic process, MIT, May 1986. project in the Venezuelan Center for Latin American Development Studies, Boston University, La ventaja comparativa de corto y mediano plazo en la produccion manufacturera de Venezuela, May 1986. Convenio CVG - Corpoindustria, Mayo 1984. Convenio CVG - FONCREI, Julio 1984. Corporacion Venezolana de Guayana, Gerencia de Desarrollo Regional, La CVG y su enfoque regional, Exposicion del Dr. Rafael Pena Alvarez y de la Dra. Elba Vicentelli de Mago, Jefe de al Oficina de Coordinacion de la Corporacion Venezolana de Guayana ante los integrantes del XII Curso del Instituto de Altos Estudios de la Defensa Nacional, Cuidad Guayana, Marzo 1983. --------------------------------, Gerencia de Planificacion, Actualizacion del estudio sobre la estructura economica de al nacion y la estrategia de desarrollo de al region Guayana hacia el ano 2,000, Marzo 1983. --------------------------------Gerencia de Promocion Industrial y Minero , La experiencia de la Corporacion de Guayana y sus Empresas basicas en materia de sustitucion de importaciones y la promocion industrial, ponencia presentada en la primera jornada regional de sustitucion de importaciones, Cuidad Guayana 5,6 y 7 de Febrero, 1987. --------------------------------Gerencia de Promocion Industrial y Minero, La sustitucion de importaciones en las empresas basicas se Guayana, Abril 1986. ECLA/UNIDO, Industrial Developmnet Division, Thoughts on industrialization, linkage and growth, Cepal review No. 28, April 1986. Pags 50-65. Gaceta oficial de la Republica de Venezuela, numero 33.546, Normas para orientar la demanda de obras, bienes y servicios en los proyectos ejecutados o financiados por el estado, a objeto de promover el desarrollo industrial y technologico del pais, Caracas, martes 2 de septiembre de 1986. ------------------------------------------, numero 3.881 Extraordinario, Reglamento del regimen comun de tratamiento a los capitales extrangeros y sobre marcas, patentes, licencias y regalias aprobado por las decisiones Nros. 24, 37, 37A, 70, 103, 109 y 169 de la comision del acuerdo de cartagena, Caracas: viernes 29 de Agosto de 1986. Friedman, John, Regional Development Policy. A Venezuela, MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts. case study of Friedman, John, Venezuela. From Doctrine to Dialogue, Syracuse University Press. New York, 1965. Ganz and Blanco in Rodwin, Lloyd and Associates, Planning Urban Growth and Regional Developmnet: The experience of the Guayana Program in Venezuela, MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts. Gelb, Alan, Adjustments to windfall gains: a comparative analysis of oil-exporting countries, in Natural Resources and the Macroeconomy, edited by J. Peter Neary and Swedwe Van Wijnbergen, The MIT Press, Cambridge Massachusetts, 1985. Izaguirre P., Maritza, Cuidad Guayana y la estrategia desarrollo polarizado, Ediciones SIAP - Planteos, 1977. del Karl, Terry, The Political Economy of Petrodollars: Oil and Democracy in Venezuela, Phd disertation submitted to the department of political sciences of Stanford University, Jannuary 1982. Karl, Terry, Petroleum and political pacts: The transition to democracy in Venezuela, Paper numer 107 presented at June 1981 conference on "Transitions from Authoritarism and Prospects for Democracy in Latin America and Latin Europe", Latin American program of the Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars, Smithsonian Institute. Sachs, Jeffrey, External debt and macroeconomic performance in Latin America and East Asia, Brooking papers on Economic activity 2, William C. Brainard and George L. Perry, Editors, 1985. Scott, Bruce, Venezuela 1986, Harvard Business School. Sonntag, Heinz R. and de la Cruz, Rafael, The State and Industralization in Venezuela, Latin American perspectives, Issue 47, Vol 12 No 4, Fall 1985. Quintero, Eduardo, and others, In search of an economic strategy, Chap I: Learning from the past, Chap II: The world environment and its implications for Venezuela, this paper was prepared by representatives of the private sector under the auspicies of the Foundation "Dividendo Voluntario para la Comunidad" for submimission on Institucional Reform of the Presidential Commision of the Reform of the State. Translation provided in the course 'Country Analysis'-Harvard University, 1985. The International Bank of Development, The Economic Development of Venezuela, John Hopkins Press, Baltimore, 1961. ANNEX 1. List of interview realized in Ciudad Guayana and Caracas. ALCASA: Martinez, Celestino - President. Rodriguez Pulido, Rafael - Vicepresident Development. Hermoli, Victor - Construction Division. Escobar, Victor Hugo - Proyect of extension. for Marketing BANCO DEL ORINOCO: Useche, Aurelio - Vicepresident. COMISION PARA LA REFORMA DEL ESTADO (COPRE): Gabaldon, Arnoldo - President. Sosa, Carlos - State Enterprises. CORPORACION VENEZOLANA DE GUAYANA: Presidency: Arreaza, Roberto - Vicepresident. Gerencia de Promocion Industrial y Minero: Pena Alvarez, Rafael - General Manager. Vicentelli de Mago, Elba Ing. Suarez, Veira Ing. Ortiz, Daniel Soc. Sanz, Maria A. Lic. Morillo, Marbelia Gerencia de Planificacion fisica: Chemello, Andres - Gerente General Oficina para el nuevo puente sobre el rio Orinoco: Delgado, Maria Engracia. INTERALUMINA: Ing. Robles - President. SULFORCA: Monteverde, Jose Antonio - Site engineer. List of interview realized in Cambridge. Sosa, Carlos - February 3th, March 18th, 1987. HARVARD INSTITUT FOR INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENT (HIID): Auty, Dr. Richard - March 17th, March 30th, 1987. 84 and ANNEX 2 List of abbreviations AD. Accion Democratica, Social Democratic Party. ALCASA. Aluminum smelter, previous a 50%-50% joint venture with Reynolds Aluminum. BAUXIVEN. CVG-Company in charge of the exploitation bauxite mines of "Los Pidiguaos". CONARE. CVG-Company in charge of the exploitation of the planted Cariba pine areas in Monagas State. CARONI. River, that cross Ciudad Guayana. COPEI. Christian Democratic Party. of CORPOINDUSTRIA. Institut in charge of developing small size enterprises. and medium CVG. Corporacion Venezolana de Guayana. CVF. Corporacion Venezolana de Fomento. ECLA. Economic Council for Latin America. EDELCA. CVG-Company in charge of the development of Caroni river Hydroelectricity. Macagua I & II, Guri dam. FONDO DE INVERSIONES DE VENEZUELA. Fund created to invest the oil windfall. FONCREI. Industrial Fund (Fondo de Credito Industrial). IDB. Inter-American Development Bank. INTERALUMINA. Interamericana de Aluminios. Alumina producer. MINERVEN. CVG-Company in charge of Callao" gold mines. SIDOR. Steel producer. Participation of CVG. VENALUM. Aluminun smelter. Joint venture Japan-CVG-Fondo de Inversiones de Venezuela. the exploitation of "El