Some prices from 1987 The Mathematics of Finance MEI conference 2012 © MEI Introduction to the Retail Prices Index (RPI) A. Mars bar 20p B. Pint of milk 25p C. Litre of petrol 38p D. Paperback book £2.50 E. Glastonbury Festival ticket £21 F. Average house £44 000 • How much do you think these items cost today? From the 1956 RPI proposal • The Retail Prices Index looks at changes in the price of a shopping basket of goods. • RPI is short for Retail Prices Index. • In 1987 the shopping basket cost £100. • In January 2011 the cost of the same shopping basket was £229. • If all prices increased by the same rate from 1987 to 2011, what would each item above cost? The weightings in the RPI are based on household spending • In 1956, the average household spent £350 out of every £1000 on food. • The weightings in the RPI are changed on a regular basis and new categories introduced. • The actual items priced are also kept under regular review to keep the RPI representative of average spending. Collection of prices • Prices are collected from a sample of shops. • Collection takes place on the second or third Tuesday of each month. • To allow all the prices to be collected, some are collected on the Monday or Wednesday. 1 Calculating the RPI • The total price in a base year is taken to be 100. • The current base year is 1987. • Indices are calculated in this order – Item – Section – All items Item index • January 1987 Mars bar price 20p • July 2011 Mars bar price 49p • Price now is 2.45 times higher than in January 1987. • Taking the index in Jan 1987 as 100, the Mars bar index now is 245. 1 A Problem Mathematical Modelling in Economics 2 Make assumptions to allow work to begin 3 Represent the problem in mathematical form 8 Review assumptions No 4 Solve to produce theoretical results 5 Select information from experiment, experience or observation Barack Obama Only government can break the cycles that are crippling our economy -- where a lack of spending leads to lost jobs which leads to even less spending; where an inability to lend and borrow stops growth and leads to even less credit. That's why we need to act boldly and act now to reverse these cycles. That's why we need to put money in the pockets of the American people, create new jobs, and invest in our future. 7 Is the solution satisfactory? 6 Compare with theoretical results Yes 9 Present findings The problem • In an economic crisis, is it better to spend or to save? 2 Some assumptions • When a person has money, he either spends or saves it. • Each person spends the same fraction of their money. A simple example Suppose everyone spends half their income and saves half. Person A earns £100 and spends £50 with person B. £50 £100 A B £25 C £12.50 D The total amount of income is more than A’s original £100. Marginal propensity to consume • The fraction of their income which each person spends is called the marginal propensity to consume. • Suppose the marginal propensity to consume is 0.5 for each person. • The next slides show the total income building. What will happen to the total income eventually? This square represents the initial increase in income spent Income for others If marginal propensity to consume is 0.5; half is spent If the propensity to consume is 0.5 • Eventually the total income is twice the intial income. It is more difficult to see this visually for other values of the propensity to consume. • What happens if the propensity to consume is some other value? 3 The idea in a nutshell • Money circulates in an economy. • If the amount spent in the economy increases, some of the money spent will be paid to other people and then be spent by them. So the total increase in spending is more than the initial increase in spending. • The injection is the initial increase in spending. Multiplying the injection by the multiplier gives the total increase in spending. Comparing to reality • Economists vary in their estimates of the size of the multiplier. • It is also very difficult to measure how much of an impact government spending has on the economy A quote Another problem “All models are wrong, but some are useful.” George Box, statistician • How does demand for a product change when the price changes? • Is the economic multiplier model useful? UK consumption of petrol and diesel (tonnes millions) How do you think the graph looks? • For petrol? • For beer? • For a product of your choice? 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Petrol 18.14 17.59 16.68 15.76 14.99 Diesel 20.15 21.07 20.61 20.06 20.87 Total 38.29 38.66 37.29 35.82 35.86 Year 2006 Petrol price (p per litre) 88.9 2007 87.9 2008 103.9 2009 89.9 2010 111.9 4 UK Petrol 2006-2010 A simple demand curve 20 Demand (million tonnes) 19 18 17 16 15 14 13 12 11 10 80 Price (p per litre) 90 100 110 120 130 140 150 Price Elasticity of Demand (PED) PED = % change in quantity demanded Price elasticity of demand = % change in price PEDdemand Geogebra file % change in quantity demanded % change in price In general, the equation of a line of this form is P = a – bQ . Can you find a formula for the PED at point A with coordinates (P, Q), in terms of a, b, P and Q? HMRC research on price elasticity of demand for alcohol UK Alcohol Studies Beer Wine Spirits Median Mean ‐0.40 ‐0.56 ‐0.86 ‐0.90 ‐0.72 ‐0.75 Maximum Minimum Std Deviation ‐0.09 ‐3.20 0.57 ‐0.14 ‐2.42 0.57 ‐0.20 ‐1.60 0.37 A challenge • What would the demand curve look like if PED was constant? • How would revenue depend on price for such a curve? 5 Maximising Revenue R = Q(a – bQ) where R is the total revenue. Why does the graph of R against Q have this shape? What are the coordinates of A, B and C on the Q-axis? What value of Q gives a maximum value of R? P = a − bQ What is the value of P when R is a maximum? PED = − 1P bQ What is the value of PED when revenue is a maximum? © MEI 2011