Internat. J. Math. & Math. Sci. oi. I0 No. (1987)9-16 A *-MIXING CONVERGENCE THEOREM FOR CONVEX SET VALUED PROCESSES A. de KORVIN Department of Computer and Information Science Indiana University Purdue University at Indianapolis Indianapolis, IN 46223 and R. KLEYLE Department of Mathematical Sciences Purdue University at Indianapolis Indiana University Indianapolis, IN (Received May 27 ABSTRACT. 46223 1986 and in revised form August 27, 1986) In this paper the concept of a *-mixing process is extended to multivalued maps from a probability space into closed, bounded convex sets of a Banach space. The main result, which requires that the Banach space be separable and reflexive, is a convergence theorem for *-mixing sequences which is analogous to the strong law of large numbers. The impetus for studying this problem is provided by a model from information science involving the utilization of feedback data by a decision maker who is uncertain of his goals. The main result is somewhat similar to a theorem for real valued processes and is of interest in its own right. KEY WORDS AND PHRASES. Hausdorf f Decision making, *-mixing process, multivalued maps, metric. 1980 MATHEMATICS SUBJECT CLASSIFICATION CODES. I. 28B20, 60G48, 94A15. INTRODUCTION. Our motivation for the present work arises from our efforts to extend a model of a decision maker using feedback information to decide on an appropriate course of action. [2] This model has been described by R. Alo, R. Kleyle and A. de Korvin in and extended to include goal uncertainty on the part of the decision maker by A. de Korvin and R. Kleyle in [12]. The role of the decision maker in this model is to select an appropriate course of action from a finite set of possible courses of action and to use the information obtained from implementing this course of action to reassess the situation prior to selecting his next course of action. tion process is determined by the decision maker’s utility associated with each course of action. The selec- current estimate of the expected The case in which the decision maker has a well defined utility function for each course of action (goal certainty) is developed in detail in [2]. Some preliminary results for the case in which the decision maker is unable to assign an explicit utility function to each course of action (goal uncertainty) are obtained in [12]. In this paper goal uncertainty is expressed by interval-valued functions. In the present paper we extend the goal uncertainty case to the situation A. de KORVIN and R. KLEYLE i0 in which the decision maker considers a convex set of possible utility functions. This leads us to consider multivalued maps from a probability space to subsets of a Banach function space. The first steps in that direction were taken by A. de Korvin and R. Kleyle in [13]. The key to the results obtained in [13] is that for each course of action the In the context of multi- convex valued expected utilities form a supermartingale. valued maps a supermartingale is a sequence {Fn, H H map and n where F is a multivalued n n an expanding sequence of -fields such that F is H -measurable and n n E[Fn+I Hn]. F n The formal definition for conditional expectations in the present context will be given in the next section. is defined in The above property is a consequence of goal shaping which [12] and in [13]. The purpose of the present work is to obtain a convergence result that would replace the convergence result obtained in [12] for situations in which the goal is a supermartingale. Fn Consequently we wish to remove the condition that shaping condition is removed. Another reason for removing the supermartingale condition is that we do not want to tie the expected utility to the immediate past. F reasonable condition is to assume that the dependence of n A far more on past history becomes To accomplish this we will assume that weaker as past history becomes more distant. the process satisfies the *-mixing condition which will be defined in the next section. This condition is called *-mixing because of its analogy to the *-mixing condition for real valued processes. At each cycle of an ongoing decision process the decision maker hopes to improve It is his estimate of the expected utilities associated with each course of action. reasonable to assume that he will in some sense want to average his estimates of the sets of utility functions obtained so far. In this paper we define such an average and show that it satisfies a strong law of large numbers with respect to a metric to be defined later. 2. BACKGROUND AND PRELIMINARIES. The main purpose of this section is to define the important concepts necessary for understanding the results. The most fundamental concept needed is that of Banach- valued martingales. Let (,E,P) be a probability space, and let sequence of integrable Y-valued functions and of E. The sequence Y Fi be a Banach space. (Xi,Fi) is called a martingale if E[XI+ F i] X i Let X i be a an expanding sequence of sub -flelds X i is Fi-measurable and (2.1) a.s. For properties of real-valued martingales the reader is referred to [8] and for the Banach-valued case to [6]. We now focus attention on multivalued functions defined on closed, bounded, convex subsets of Y. define a new map (F S)() Let F and G whose values are denote any such maps. cl{a + b / a e F(), b e G()} norm. where cl denotes the closure with respect to the R We now CONVERGENCE THEOREM FOR CONVEX SET VALUED PROCESSES Ii We set where Of course 6 6(F,G)() Max{sup d(x,G()), sup d(y,F())} x e F() y e F() d(x,G()) x-t inf t e G() II In F i=l E F i=l II d(x,F()) inf x-t t e F() is just the Hausdorff distance of F() to confusion, we will write 6(F,G). and I i G(), and when there is no F For a finite sequence of maps $ F $ F i E n F i=l L i $ F n 2 denotes the limit, if it exists, of We define the analog of an II. in the i 6-metric. distance by I 6(F,G)dP A(F,G) In this context the notations 6, A and $ were first introduced by Debreu in [7].. Finally we define IFI Note that IFi 6(F,{0}). R. is a non negative function defined on A multivalue F map E-measurable if for any open set is B Y, F -I (B) E E where F-I(B) { e R / F() n B # @ }. It is shown in Himmelberg [II] that sequence {f n of D(F) { e R / F() # @} and there exists a E-measurable functions such that F(m) cl{f (m) n for all m e D(F)}. In fact the above property can be used to define measurability for Banach spaces. For an equivalent definition of measurability the reader is referred to [II], [5],.and [7]. We define F to be integrable if I The space L2wk(Y) IFI dP < will refer to all multivalued maps is a weakly compact non empty convex subset of Y and I F: R 2 FI 2 Y such that F() dP < By a selector of F we mean a function f: R Y such that f() e F() for all F If (F) will denote all F-measurable and integrable is integrable S F selectors of F. will simply be written as For related kinds of e SIF SIF(E) selectors see Alo, de Korvin and Roberts [I]. F E-measurable I From now on E(F) FdP I f dP / f e S Following Aumann [3] we define, for IF }. will denote the Aumann integral of F. 12 A. de KORVIN and R. KLEYLE We now define the concept of conditional expectation for an integrable, multiWe assume that Y is separable, and the values of F are valued function F. Following Hial and Umegakl [I0] (Th. 5.1, p. 169), the Y. weakly compact subsets of F conditional expectation of SIE{FIF] relative to a sub o-fleld (F) cl{ E[flF] F E of is defined by / f e S F The lhs of the above llne indicates that the conditional expectation of F respect to is the set of integrable selectors of this set which are F with F-measurable. For notational convenience we denote this set as Now that the conditional expectation of multivalued functions has been defined, the concept of a martingale can be extended to these functions by replacing Y-valued in (2.1) with convex set valued functions F i. For convergence theorems i multlvalued pertaining to martingales the reader is referred to the work of Hia and X functions Umegakl [I0] and for multivalued supermartingales to A. de Korvln and R. Kleyle [13]. Let F be a sequence of integrable multivalued functions whose values are weakly i compact subsets of Y where Y is separable. We say that the sequence is *-mixing if there exists some positive integer that N and some function we have (n)E]Fn+ml. Fm]], E[Fn+m]] A[E[Fn+m defined on [N, ) such # N and m is strictly decreasing to 0, and for all n (2.2) A law of large numbers was shown for a somewhat similar real-valued process by Blum et al [4]. The concept of a *-mixing sequence is central to our result. says is that on the average the dependence of EIFn+ml provided is reasonably bounded. Fn+ on Fm What (2.2) really grows weaker as m If the interpretation of is the estimate of the average utility at trial n Fn+m n+m when goal uncertainty is present, then it is reasonable to expect that the dependence of this average on the early history of the process (i.e. the history up to trial m) grows weaker as For technical reasons we will need the following o-flelds. Let w n n . be a family of E-measurable selectors of F; then F[Wn(.) GF(Wn) / n(’) e N That is, we consider the o-fleld generated by all functions obtained from allowing If F denote G is a family of measurable multlvalued maps, t F (w n t Gt(Wn,t) will be used to k F I, F F Ft2 E-measurable of 2 E o t E U U i--I 3. by t). By the o-fleld generated by a sequence w n to be a variable index. n Ftk we mean o[ U G (Wn,tl)]. t i=l i multivalued maps, we will replace E Given by Gi(wn i) ]. RESULTS. From now on sequence with Y F is a separable, reflexive Banach space and e L n the previous section. 2 wk(Y). We replace E F n by the larger o-fleld denotes a *-mixing E as defined in We start by listing a result on martlngales known to be true for the real valued case [9]. CONVERGENCE THEOREM FOR CONVEX SET VALUED PROCESSES LEMMA I. S b Let be a sequence of Y-valued random variables such that fi n 13 E f is a martingale relative to the expanding sequence of o-fields F n i i=l Then if be an increasing sequence of positive reals such that limb n n n . E b i=l it follows that -2m[llfill2 i Sn/b n lim Fi_l] , < 0 (a.s.). For details the The proof is essentially the same as for the real case. PROOF Let reader is referred to [9], Theorem 2.18, pp. 35-36. F F I, F 2, be any finite q are weakly compact subsets of integrable multivalued functions whose values Let We now obtain an important inequality. sequence Y, and let of a separable Banach space H H 2, H denote an arbitrary q sequence of expanding o-fields in E’. LEMMA 2. fi > O, there exists a sequence For every f fl’ f2’ is an integrable selector of F i, and such that for each A( .q F i, f i, fi such that q Hi-measurable, is and i=l PROOF. 2 .E q i=l {v m -Eq E[FilHi_l]) i=l RI Let 1" Here E[FilHi_ I] is I i=lEq(f i m[filHi_l])II dP + E q F i) {m/Sup d(s, q ranges over .E s Sup d(t,. i=l s i=l E[Fi]Hi_I], q E[FilHi_I])}, and let i=l t q and t ranges over .E F i. i=l Since a measurable multivalued function, it has a sequence of selectors such that cl {Vm The sequence "Eq {Vm () .E q F i) () a.s. Vm(.)(’), Now there exists functions E-measurable. is which we continue to denote by d(Vm’ m[FilHi-i i=l vm, such that --> Sup d(s, .l i=l q i=l s F i) e Thus I 6( r. q Fi, .E q I i=1 i=1 E[FilHi_I])dP < I d(vm, .I q i--1 i Fi)dP + e By Theorem 5.1 of [I0] there exists H i measurable functions gmi which are selectors of F such that the right hand side of the above inequality is dominated i by I i I vm Eq i=l m[gmilHi_l II de + d(E q q m[gmilHi_l ],.E Fi)de i=l + i i=l -< I II i=Eq (E[gmilHi_ I] gmill dP + and where, moreover, i=l Hence (. Eq F i, i= Eq i= E[FilHi_I])dP 2 . 14 A. de KORVIN and R. KLEYLE Now if 2’ m .E q .E of selectors of Um q F i=l E[FilHi_I]) i=l Um(.)(’), E-measurable, we can pick a sequence is i=l which we denote by d(Um, .E q F i since q d(t, .E > sup t such that i E[Fi[Hi_I]) i=l Hence q I 6(.E q F i, .E q E[F i[Hi_ l])dP =< I d(um, .E E[F i[Hi_ l]dP + i=l i=l 2 2 i=l I i=lEq (Umi Y < n2 where are Uml E[ Uml Hi- ])II dP selectors of F Hi-measurable fl Thus the lemma is proved by picking + E i. I’ on gml and fl Uml 2" on We are now ready to prove the main result. Let THEOREM. F be a *-mixing sequence with n separable and reflexive Banach space. E (1) (ll) where b n EIFn 12 -2 b n n=l sup b n n -I En L2wk(Y) n -I n is a < is a sequence of positive constants increasing to infinity. A(b Y where < mlFi i=l F Assume .En Fi i=l b -I n E n i=l E(FI)) Then O. By the *-mixing property, there exists N such that the *-mixing N large inequality (2.2) holds for n >= N and m >= I. Given E > 0, pick n o PROOF. enough so that and j (n 0) < Thus since we have by theorem 5.4 of Y is reflexive for all positive integers [I0], (3.1) (E(Fin0+j Fn0+J F (i_l)n0+j ),) E (Fino+j )) F(i-1)no+J G(i_l)no+j],E[E(Fino+J G(i_l)no+J )]} j. A{E[E(Fino+ A where (i-l)no+J (i_l)n0+j is the o-fieid generated by Fn0+J, F2no+j is generated by F1 F2 F(i_l)n0+j and F(i_l)n0+J. By theorem 5.2 of [i0] the right hand side of (3.1) is dominated by A[E(FIn0+ F(i_l)n0+J), E(Fin0+j)] j -< (n 0) E Fin0+ The last inequality is a consequence of the *-mixing inequality. .zn F i, A(bn A(bn i=l -I .Eno i= Fi (3.2) j Now bn-I .zn E(Fi)) i=l b -i n .Eno E(FI)) i= + A(b n-I .Eq-I i=l .Eno-I Fino+j j=l CONVERGENCE THEOREM FOR CONVEX SET VALUED PROCESSES b .lq-i .lno -I -I n + A(b n -i where for any 0 n r n F -I .lr E(F j=l qn0+J where q n qn 0 + r n O b qn0+J’ (3.3) )) and are positive integers such that r The inequality (3.3) holds because I. o .Er j=l n E(Fin0+J )) j=l i= 15 B, C $ D) A(A A(A,C) + A(B,D). (See p. 162 of [I0]) The first term of the right hand side in (3.3) can be written as A(.7.n0 Fi .zn0 E(Fi)) b-I n i=l i=l and goes to zero when since n n O is fixed and It remains to show bn that the second and third term of the right hand side of (3.3) goes to zero as We give the proof for the second term, the third term is handled similarly. n . By the triangular inequality the second term is dominated by A (b -I n q-i Z i=l n0-1 =i + b -I n n0-1 .E .l i=l b b Fin0+ j=l q-I + A(D n -I E Z n0-1 E(Fin0+ j=l q-i -I Fin0+ i=l (n0) E no-i Z Z i=l j=l G(i_l)n0+j) E(Fin0+ G(i-l)no+j b n -I .E q-i .Z i=l no-i j=l" E (Fino+j q-i A(.E n q-i -i n n0-1 j, i=l E[Fin0+j G(i-l)no+J]) q-i E j=l i=l EIFin0+Jl (3.4) The last inequaltiy follows from (3.1) and (3.2). The second term on the right hand side of (3.4) can be made arbitrarily small by the *-mixing condition and condition (il) of the theorem. It remains to show that the first term on the right hand side of (3.4) goes to 0 as r (and therefore q) goes to infinity. By Lemma 2, this term is dominated by Z no-i j=l where fin0 + j b -i f n is a I q-i (fin0+ E[fin0+J G(i_l)n0+J])ll Z i=l Gin0+j-measurable integrable selector of de + 2 Fino+j. e Furthermore, it is easy to show that q-i Sq-i Z i=l is a martingale with (fin0+j E[fin0+J G(i_l)no+J] respect {G(q_l)no+j} q -> to Condition (i) of the theorem implies that the hypothesis of Lemma holds, so that A. de KORVIN and R. KLEYLE 16 for each fixed n b-i II n and j, o q-I (f 7. i=l G E[fin0+ in0+J (i-l)n0+J ])li 0 (3.5) a.s. The left hand side of (3.5) is dominated by b -I q-i q-I [I (fin0+j E[fln0+J G(i_l)no+J])ll 7. i= q-I -I + bq_l Since the map bq_ q-I -i i=17. i=iI Fin0+ Fin0+ E[Fin0+J G(i_l)n0+J] j IE[ Fin0+ G(i-l)n0+J j is non-expanslve, (see Th. 5.2 of [I0]), it follows that the right hand side of the above inequality has L norm less than or equal to 2b q-I -i Z q-I E i= Fin0+Jl. Thus q-l bn-I f I i=IZ (fin0+ E[fin0+J G(i_l)n0+J])ll j by condition (ii) and the dominated convergence theorem. dP 0 This completes the proof of the theorem. ACKNOWLEDGEMENT. This Research was supported in part by national Science Foundation Grants IST-83-03900 and IST-8518706. REFERENCES I. ALO, R., de KORVIN, A., and ROBERTS, C. "p-lntegrable Selectors of Multimeasures," Internat. J. Math. and Math. Scl. (1979), pp. 209-221. 2. ALO, R., KLEYLE, R., and de KORVlN, A. Times in a Generalized Information "Decision Making Mechanisms and Stopping System," Math Modellln (1985), pp. 259-271. AUMANN, R.J. "Integrals of Set-Valued Functions," J. Math. Anal. Appl. I_2(1965), pp. 1-12. 4. BLUM, J.R., HANSON, D.L., and KOOPMANS, L., "On the Strong Law of Large Numbers for a Class of Stochastic Processes," Z. Wahrsch. Verw. Geblete 2(1963), pp. I-II. 3. 5. CASTAING, C. "Le Theoreme de Dunford-Pettls Generallse," C.P. Acad. Sci. (Paris) Ser. A. 268(1969), pp. 327-329. 6. CHATTERJI, S.D. 7. Spaces," Math. Scand. 22(1968), pp. 21-41. DEBREU, G. "Intergratlon of Correspondences," Proc. Fifth Berkeley Smp. on Math. 8. DOOB, J. 9. HALL, P. and HEYDE, C.C. Martingale Limit Theory and Its Application, Academic Press, New York, 1980. I0. HIAI, F. and UMEGAKI, H. "Integrals, Conditional Expectations, and Martingales of Multivalued Functions," J. Multivariate Anal. 7(1977), pp. 149-182. Ii. HIMMELBERG, C.J. 12. de KORVIN, A. and KLEYLE, R. "Goal Uncertainty in a Generalized Information System: Convergence Properties of the Estimated Expected Utilities," Stochastic Anal. and AppI. 3(1984), pp. 437-457. 13. de KORVIN, A. and KLEYLE, R. "Martingale Convergence and the Raydon-Nikodym Theorem in Banach Stat. and Prob. 2(1966), pp. 351-372. Stochastic Processes, Wiley, New York, 1953. "Measurable Relations," Fund. Math. 87(1975), pp. 53-72. Supermartingales," "A Convergence Theorem for Convex Set Valued Stochastic Anal. and Appl. 3(1985), pp. 433-445.