BehavioralCorporateFinance:ACurrentSurvey ForthcominginHandbookoftheEconomicsofFinance:Volume2 GeorgeM.Constantinides,MiltonHarris,andReneM.Stulz,Eds. ElsevierPress,2012 MalcolmBaker HarvardBusinessSchoolandNBER BakerHall261 Boston,MA02163 617‐495‐6566 mbaker@hbs.edu JeffreyWurgler NYUSternSchoolofBusinessandNBER 44West4thSt,Suite9‐190 NewYork,NY10012 212‐998‐0367 jwurgler@stern.nyu.edu Abstract: We survey the theory and evidence of behavioral corporate finance, which generally takesoneoftwoapproaches.Themarkettimingandcateringapproachviewsmanagerialfinancing andinvestmentdecisionsasrationalmanagerialresponsestosecuritiesmispricing.Themanagerial biasesapproachstudiesthedirecteffectsofmanagers’biasesandnonstandardpreferencesontheir decisions.Wereviewrelevantpsychology,economictheoryandpredictions,empiricalchallenges, empiricalevidence,newdirectionssuchasbehavioralsignaling,andopenquestions. Keywords: Behavioral, Corporate Finance, Sentiment, Catering, Market Timing, Irrational, Bias, Overconfidence,Optimism,Signaling JELCodes:G14,G30,G31,G32,G34,G35 ThissurveyupdatesandextendsasurveycoauthoredwithRickRubackthatwaspublishedintheHandbook inCorporateFinance:EmpiricalCorporateFinance,editedbyEspenEckbo,in2007.Wethankhimforhis manycontributionsthatcarriedovertothisversion,andwethankMiltHarrisforextensiveandhelpful comments.BakergratefullyacknowledgesfinancialsupportfromtheDivisionofResearchoftheHarvard BusinessSchool. Table of Contents 1. Introduction...................................................................................................................................1 2. Markettimingandcatering......................................................................................................5 2.1. Backgroundoninvestorbehaviorandmarketinefficiency.................................................5 2.1.1. Limitedarbitrage............................................................................................................................................6 2.1.2. Categorizationandinvestorsentiment.................................................................................................8 2.1.3. Prospecttheory,referencepoints,lossaversion,andanchoring...............................................9 2.1.4. Smartmanagers............................................................................................................................................11 2.2. Theoreticalframework:Rationalmanagersinirrationalmarkets.................................12 2.3. Empiricalchallenges.........................................................................................................................18 2.4. Investmentpolicy...............................................................................................................................22 2.4.1. Realinvestment.............................................................................................................................................22 2.4.2. Mergersandacquisitions..........................................................................................................................25 2.4.3. Diversificationandfocus...........................................................................................................................27 2.5. Financialpolicy..................................................................................................................................28 2.5.1. Equityissues...................................................................................................................................................28 2.5.2. Repurchases....................................................................................................................................................33 2.5.3. Debtissues.......................................................................................................................................................34 2.5.4. Cross‐borderissues.....................................................................................................................................37 2.5.5. Financialintermediation...........................................................................................................................37 2.5.6. Capitalstructure...........................................................................................................................................41 2.6. Othercorporatedecisions.............................................................................................................43 2.6.1. Dividends.........................................................................................................................................................43 2.6.2. Earningsmanagement................................................................................................................................45 2.6.3. Firmnames......................................................................................................................................................47 2.6.4. Nominalshareprices..................................................................................................................................48 2.6.5. Executivecompensation............................................................................................................................49 3. ManagerialBiases......................................................................................................................50 3.1. Backgroundonmanagerialbehavior.........................................................................................50 3.1.1. Limitedgovernance.....................................................................................................................................50 3.1.2. Boundedrationality.....................................................................................................................................51 3.1.3. Optimism,overconfidenceandhubris.................................................................................................52 3.1.4. Moreonreferencedependence..............................................................................................................53 3.2. Theoreticalframework...................................................................................................................54 3.3. Empiricalchallenges........................................................................................................................57 3.4. Investmentpolicy..............................................................................................................................58 3.4.1. Realinvestment.............................................................................................................................................58 3.4.2. Mergersandacquisitions..........................................................................................................................62 3.5. Financialpolicy..................................................................................................................................65 3.5.1. Equityissues...................................................................................................................................................65 3.5.2. IPOprices.........................................................................................................................................................66 3.5.3. Raisingdebt....................................................................................................................................................67 3.5.4. Capitalstructure...........................................................................................................................................68 3.5.5. Contractingandexecutivecompensation..........................................................................................69 4. BehavioralSignaling.................................................................................................................71 4.1. TheoreticalFramework...................................................................................................................72 4.2. Applications........................................................................................................................................77 4.2.1 Dividends.........................................................................................................................................................77 4.2.2. Otherapplications........................................................................................................................................78 5. Conclusion.....................................................................................................................................80 1. Introduction Corporatefinanceaimstoexplainthefinancialcontractsandtherealinvestmentbehavior thatemergefromtheinteractionofmanagersandinvestors.Acompleteexplanationoffinancing andinvestmentpatternsthereforerequiresacorrectunderstandingofthebeliefsandpreferences ofthesetwosetsofagents.Themajorityofresearchincorporatefinancemakesbroadassumptions thatthesebeliefsandpreferencesarefullyrational.Agentsaresupposedtodevelopunbiased forecastsaboutfutureeventsandusethesetomakedecisionsthatbestservetheirowninterests. Asapracticalmatter,thismeansthatmanagerscantakeforgrantedthatcapitalmarketsare efficient,withpricesrationallyreflectingpublicinformationaboutfundamentalvalues.Likewise, investorscantakeforgrantedthatmanagerswillactintheirself‐interest,rationallyrespondingto incentivesshapedbycompensationcontracts,themarketforcorporatecontrol,andother governancemechanisms. Researchinbehavioralcorporatefinancereplacesthetraditionalrationalityassumptions withbehavioralfoundationsthataremoreevidence‐driven.Thefieldisnolongerapurely academicpursuit,asbehavioralcorporatefinanceisincreasinglythebasisofdiscussionsin mainstreamtextbooks.1Wedividetheliteratureintotwobroadgroupsandorganizethesurvey accordingly.Roughlyspeaking,thefirstapproachemphasizestheeffectofinvestorbehaviorthatis lessthanfullyrational.Thesecondconsidersmanagerialbehaviorthatislessthanfullyrational. Foreachlineofresearch,wereviewthebasictheoreticalframeworks,themainempirical challenges,andtheevidence.Ofcourse,inpractice,multiplechannelsofirrationalitymayoperate atthesametime;ourtaxonomyismeanttofitthebulkoftheexistingliterature. 1ForexampleseeDamodaran(2011),Shefrin(2006),Shefrin(2008),andWelch(2009). 1 The“markettimingandcateringapproach”assumesthatarbitrageinsecuritiesmarketsis imperfect,andasaresultpricescanbetoohighortoolow.Wereviewthemarketinefficiency literatureinsofarasitisrelevant.Rationalmanagersareassumedtoperceivethesemispricings, andtomakedecisionsthatexploitorfurtherencouragemispricing.Whiletheirdecisionsmay maximizetheshort‐runvalueofthefirm,theymayalsoresultinlowerlong‐runvaluesasprices correcttofundamentals.Inthesimpletheoreticalframeworkweoutline,managersbalancethree objectives:fundamentalvalue,catering,andmarkettiming.Maximizingfundamentalvaluehasthe usualingredients.Cateringreferstoanyactionsintendedtoboostsharepricesabovefundamental value.Markettimingreferstofinancingdecisionsintendedtocapitalizeontemporarymispricings, generallybyissuingovervaluedsecuritiesandrepurchasingundervaluedones. Empiricaltestsoftheirrationalinvestorsmodelfacethechallengeofmeasuringmispricing. Wediscusshowthisissuehasbeentackled.Afewpapersusecleverapproachesthatcanidentify mispricingfairlyconvincingly,butinmanycasesambiguitiesremain.Overall,despitesome unresolvedquestions,theevidencesuggeststhattheirrationalinvestorsapproachhasa considerabledegreeofdescriptivepower.Wereviewstudiesoninvestmentbehavior,merger activity,theclusteringandtimingofcorporatesecurityofferings,capitalstructure,corporatename changes,nominalshareprices,dividendpolicy,earningsmanagement,andothermanagerial decisions.Wealsopointoutgapsthatremainbetweenthetheoryandtheevidence. Thesecondapproachthatwediscussisthe“managerialbiases”approach.Itassumesthat managershavebehavioralbiases,butretainstherationalityofinvestors,albeitlimitingthe governancemechanismstheycanemploytoconstrainmanagers.Followingtheemphasesofthe currentliterature,ourdiscussioncentersonthebiasesofoptimismandoverconfidence.Asimple modelshowshowthesebiases,inleadingmanagerstobelievetheirfirmsareundervalued, encourageoverinvestmentfrominternalresources,andapreferenceforinternaltoexternal 2 finance,especiallyinternalequity.Wenotethatthepredictionsoftheoptimismandoverconfidence modelstypicallylookverymuchlikethoseofagencyandasymmetricinformationmodels. Inthisapproach,themainobstaclesforempiricaltestsincludedistinguishingpredictions fromstandard,non‐behavioralmodels,aswellasempiricallymeasuringmanagerialbiases.Again, however,creativesolutionshavebeenproposed.Theeffectsofoptimismandoverconfidencehave beenempiricallystudiedinthecontextofcorporateandentrepreneurialfinancingandinvestment decisions,mergeractivity,andthestructureoffinancialcontracts. Wealsocoveranewerapproachthatwecall“behavioralsignaling.”Thisisaresponsetothe manysophisticatedsignalingmodelsincorporatefinancetheorythatmaketwoquestionable assumptions.Theyassumefullrationalityandstandardpreferences;and,theyusethedestruction offirmvalueasthecrediblesignalingmechanism—thebetterfirmistheonethatdestroysmore value,anotionrejectedbymanagersinsurveys.Behavioralsignalingmodelsinsteadbasethe signalingmechanismonsomedistortioninbeliefsorpreferences.Wedescribeamodelof dividendswhereinvestorsareloss‐averseoverthelevelofdividends,sothatamanagerthat ratchetsupdividendstodaycansignalthathecanlikelymeetorexceedthatleveltomorrow. Followingthis,wespeculateaboutothertopicsthatmightbeaddressedwhenasymmetric informationiscombinedwithnonstandardpreferencesorbiasedexpectations. Sprinkledthroughoutthesurveyarediscussionsofresearchthatishardtocategorizeinto justoneparadigm.Forexample,mergersarearrangedbybankersandtwosetsofmanagersand approvedbyshareholders;behavioralbiasesthataffecttheoutcomearedifficulttoattributetoone party.Theymaywellbesharedacrossparties.Complicationslikethesesuggestwhythereal economiclossesassociatedwithbehavioralphenomenaincorporatefinancearehardtoquantify, althoughsomeevidencesuggeststhattheyareconsiderable. 3 Behavioralcorporatefinance,andbehavioralfinancemorebroadly,receivedaboostfrom thespectacularriseandfallofInternetstocksbetweenthemid‐1990sand2000.Itishardto explainthisperiod,bothatthelevelofmarketaggregatesandindividualstocksandother securities,withoutappealingtosomedegreeofinvestorandmanagerialirrationality. Themorerecentfinancialcrisisismorecomplex,aswediscuss.Themispricingdidnot involveanewtechnology,butrathermoremundanemortgagefinancemadeopaquethrough financialinnovationandthecreationofseeminglylow‐riskderivatives.Thebuyerswerenotretail investors,butbanksandmoneymarketmutualfunds.Mostimportantly,thesystemicallyimportant banksthatcreatedthesesecuritieshadsomeofthelargestexposures.ItwasasifBankofAmerica hadheldontoalargefractionoftheInternetstocksthatwereunderwritteninthelate1990s. Therewereequalpartstraditionalcorporatefinancefrictions,likeagencyproblems,signaling,and debtoverhang,andbehavioraldistortionsthatledtoboththecreditbubbleandthechallengesof resettingbankbalancesheets.Theeconomicdamagewasfurthermultipliedbecausebanks themselvesshoulderedthelosses. Takingastepback,itisimportanttonotethattheapproachestakeverydifferentviews abouttheroleandqualityofmanagers,andhaveverydifferentnormativeimplicationsasaresult. Forexample,whentheprimarysourceofirrationalityisontheinvestorside,asinthemarket timingandcateringapproachandinourimplementationofbehavioralsignaling,long‐termvalue maximizationandeconomicefficiencyrequiresinsulatingmanagersfromshort‐termshareprice pressures.Managersneedtheflexibilitynecessarytomakedecisionsthatmaybeunpopularinthe marketplace.Thismayimplybenefitsfrominternalcapitalmarkets,barrierstotakeovers,andso forth—manyoftheinstitutionsthataredisdainedbyanagencyperspective.Ontheotherhand,if themainsourceofirrationalityismanifestedthroughmanagerialbiases,efficiencyrequires 4 reducingdiscretionandobligatingmanagerstorespondtomarketpricesignals—asstandard agencytheoryandasymmetricinformationmodelswouldhaveit. Thestarkcontrastbetweenthenormativeimplicationsofdifferentapproachesto behavioralcorporatefinanceisonereasonwhytheareaisfascinating,andwhymoreworkinthe areamayleadtoimportantinsights.Ourever‐improvingunderstandingoftheeconomic implicationsofsocialpsychologyandtheever‐increasingavailabilityofmicrodatawillcontinueto presentnewresearchopportunities.Inthatvein,weclosethesurveywithsomeopenquestions. Andatthispointwewouldalsoliketopointthereadertoexcellentrecentsurveysof individualtopicsinbehavioralcorporatefinance:Ben‐David(2010)ondividendpolicy,Derrien (2010)onIPOs,Dong(2010)onmergersandacquisitions,GiderandHackbarth(2010)on financingdecisions,Gervais(2010)oninvestmentdecisions,andMorck(2010)ongovernance. 2. Market timing and catering Themostdevelopedframeworkinbehavioralcorporatefinanceandlongestsectioninthis surveyinvolvesrationalmanagersinteractingwithirrationalinvestors. 2.1. Background on investor behavior and market inefficiency Therearetwokeybuildingblocksinthemarkettimingandcateringframework.Thefirstis thatirrationalinvestorsmustinfluencesecuritiesprices.Inotherwords,thatsecuritiesmarketsare notentirelyinformationallyefficient.Otherwise,itisnotobviousthatmanagerswouldtakemuch caretopleasesuchinvestors.Forirrationalinvestorstoaffectprices,rationalinvestorsmustbe limitedintheirabilitytocompeteandarbitrageawaymispricings.Wediscussthelimitedarbitrage literaturebelowsincethisissuchacriticalassumption. 5 Irrationaltraders’biasesmustbesystematic,aswell,orelsetheirowntradingmightsimply cancelout,leavingarbitrageurswithlittletodoanyway.Wediscussafewwell‐documentedand robustdeviationsfromstandardutilityandBayesianbeliefsfromthepsychology,economics,and financeliteratures.Theparticulardeviationsthataremostimmediatelyapplicabletocorporate financeinvolvecategorizationandreference‐dependentbehavior.Combinedwithlimitedarbitrage, thesebiasesleadtomarketinefficiencies.2 Thesecondkeybuildingblockofthemarkettimingandcateringviewisthatmanagers mustbe“smart”inthesenseofbeingabletodistinguishmarketpricesandfundamentalvalue—to recognizethemispricingsthatirrationalinvestorshavecreated,especiallyinextreme circumstances.Wereviewseveralreasonswhythisassumptionisplausible. 2.1.1. Limited arbitrage Securitiespricesreflectfundamentalvalueswheninformedinvestorscompeteaggressively toeliminatemispricings.Classicalfinancetheory,includingtheModigliani‐Millertheorem,holds thattheywilldosobecausemispricingsbetweentwocompanieswiththesameoperatingcash flowsbutdifferentcapitalstructures,inasettingofcompleteandfrictionlesssecuritiesmarkets, presentarbitrageopportunities.Theassumptionofmarketefficiencyhasfordecadespermitted corporatefinancetheorytodevelopindependentlyofassetpricingtheory. 2Theliteratureonmarketinefficiencyisvast.Itincludesfairlyconvincingevidenceofinefficienciesincluding theJanuaryeffect;theeffectoftradinghoursonpricevolatility;post‐earnings‐announcementdrift,positive autocorrelationinquarterlyearningsannouncementeffects,andmoregenerallydelayedreactiontonews; momentum;Siamesetwinsecuritiesthathaveidenticalcashflowsbuttradeatdifferentprices;negative “stub”values;closed‐endfundpricingpatterns;bubblesandcrashesingrowthstocks;relatedevidenceof mispricinginoptions,bond,andforeignexchangemarkets;andinterestingnewpatternseveryyear.Thislist excludesanomaliesrelatedtosecuritiesissuancethatwediscusslater.SeeBarberisandThaler(2003)and Shleifer(2000)forclassicsurveysofthebehavioralfinanceandassetpricingliteraturemorebroadly. 6 Theliteratureonlimitedarbitrage,however,concludesthatsecuritiesmarketmispricings oftendonotpresentopportunitiesfortruearbitrage.Asaresult,mispricingscanexistandpersist. Asjustoneexample,thefactthatstocksaddedtomarketindexesseetheirpricesjumphasbeen viewedasprimafacieproofoflimitstoarbitrageinthestockmarket(Shleifer(1986)andHarris andGurel(1986)).Adeeperstudyofspecificarbitragecostsandrisksisuseful,however,because whenthesecostsaremeasurable,theymayleadtoempiricalstrategiesformeasuringmispricing, aswediscusslater. EarlycontributionstotheliteratureincludeMiller(1977),whopointsoutthatshort‐sale constraintscanleadtosecuritiesbeingoverpriced.DeLong,Shleifer,Summers,andWaldmann (1990)highlighttheriskthatirrationaltraderspushpricesfurtherawayfromfundamentalsaftera would‐bearbitrageurtakesaposition.ShleiferandVishny(1997)pointoutthatprofessional investmentmanagers,theenforcersofmarketefficiencyinclassicaltheory,infacthaveaspecial incentivetoavoidthisnoisetraderrisk:intherealisticcasewhereinvestorscannotdistinguish betweenreturnsearnedbyluckandskill,theymayassumetheworstandwithdrawfundswhen facedwithlosses. Thereareanumberofadditionalcostsandrisksofarbitrage.Animportantoneis fundamentalrisk,whichmakesrelative‐valuearbitrageriskybecauseamispricedsecurity’scash flowsarenotspannedbythoseofotherassets(Pontiff(1996)andWurglerandZhuravskaya (2002)).Liquidityriskariseswheneveryonewantstosellatthesametime(AcharyaandPedersen (2004)).Finally,real‐worldinvestorsmustbearsimpletransactioncosts,searchcosts,and information‐gatheringcoststoexploitmispricings. Theideathatsecuritiespricesareaffectedbymorethanjustfundamentalshasbeen examinedinmarketsfrompennystockstogovernmentbonds.Krishnamurthy(2002)findsthaton‐ the‐runTreasuryissuestradeatapremiumtootherbonds,whileDuffee(1996)connectsthe 7 supplyofindividualbillstonon‐fundamentalvariationintheTreasuryyieldcurve.Atahigherlevel ofaggregation,Hu,Pan,andWang(2010)useanomalouspatternsintheshapeoftheyieldcurveto quantifyhowwellcapitalizedoreffectiveisbondmarketarbitrage.Atthebroadestlevel, GreenwoodandVayanos(2010)arguethattheoverallshapeoftheyieldcurveiscausallyaffected bythematuritystructureofgovernmentdebtissues.Thisassertionimpliesmispricingsoffar greatersizethanthoseevidencedbyrelative‐valuedistortionswithintheyieldcurve—large enough,perhaps,tocatchtheattentionofmanagers,ortheirinvestmentbankers,andaffect corporatematuritystructurechoices. Insummary,abodyoftheoryandevidenceindicatesthatcapitalmarketshavealimited capacitytoabsorbdemandshocksthatareindependentoffundamentalnews.Thenexttaskisto understandtheinvestorpsychologythatisbehindsomeofthesedemandshocks. 2.1.2. Categorization and investor sentiment Abasicfeatureofhumancognitionissimplificationthroughcategories.Forexample,the label“BehavioralCorporateFinance”definesasetofpaperswithsimilarmethodologicalthemes andfreesusfromhavingtoenumeratetheindividualmembersoftheset(exceptinthecaseofa surveyarticle,ofcourse).TheclassictreatmentisRosch(1973),buttheprincipleisobviousand needsnotheoreticalpreamble. Investorsandanalystssimplifytheinvestmentuniversethroughcategories(Barberisand Shleifer(2003)).Somecategories,suchassmall‐caps,valuestocks,high‐yieldstocks,andjunk bonds,arefairlytimeless.Othersareephemeral.The“NiftyFifty”isaforgottenmonikerfromthe early1970sforasetoflarge‐capitalizationfirmswithsolidearningsgrowth.Thesedays,“Internet firms”isbecomingalessusefullabel.Itoncedenotedfirmswiththeessentialfeaturethattheir successdependedontheadoptionofanewtechnology;thattechnologyisnowestablished,sothe determinantsofthesefirms’prospectshavebecomemoreindividualized. 8 Investmentcategoriesbecomeinterestingforuswheninvestorstradeatthecategorylevel. Indexfundsprovideanexampleofcategory‐levelinvestinganditsconsequences:Whenastockis addedtotheS&P500Index,itsreturnsbecomemorecorrelatedwithexistingIndexmembers (Barberis,Shleifer,andWurgler(2005)).Itisnowtradedinsyncwiththem,and—arbitragebeing limited—itacquiresacommonfactorinreturns.Overtime,thiscanleadtoadetachmentof categorymembersfromtherestofthemarket(MorckandYang(2001),Wurgler(2011)).Themost dramaticcasesarefrombubblesandcrashes.IntheInternetbubble,someinvestorsdidn’thavethe timeorexpertisetoinvestigateindividualtechstocksandapparentlyjustthrewmoneyatanything Internet‐related.Thecrashinvolvedequallyindiscriminateselling.Aqualitativereviewofstock markethistorysuggeststhatinvestorsentimentoftenconcentratesatthelevelofcategories. Forourpurpose,categorizationwillbeparticularlyrelevanttothediscussionofcatering behavior,inwhichmanagerstakeactionstomovetheirfirmintothein‐voguecategoryandboost itsvaluation.Thisboostmay,inturn,facilitateopportunisticsecuritiesissuance. 2.1.3. Prospect theory, reference points, loss aversion, and anchoring IntheprospecttheorypreferencesofKahnemanandTversky(1979),utilityisdefinednot asasmoothlyincreasingfunctionofthelevelofconsumptionorwealthbutintermsofchanges relativetoareferencelevel.Viaakinkattheorigin,thevaluefunctionalsoembodiesloss aversion—theempiricalphenomenonthatlosses,evensmallones,areparticularlypainful.See TverskyandKahneman(1991)forasurveyoflossaversionresearch. ThedispositioneffectofShefrinandStatman(1985)referstothepatternthatinvestorsare morelikelytorealizegainsthanlosses.Atypicalexplanationinvokeselementsofprospecttheory: thereferencepointisthepurchaseprice,andtheinvestorstrainstoavoidsellingatalossdespite 9 thetaxadvantagetodoingso.3Othersalientreferenceprices,and,importantly,onesthatare commonacrossinvestors,arerecenthighprices,suchasastock’sall‐timeor52‐weekhigh,and recentlowprices.Huddart,Lang,andYetman(2009)findthattradingvolumeandreturnpatterns changeasrecenthighsareapproachedforseasonedissues,andKaustia(2004)findsthattrading volumebehaviorchangesasIPOsreachnewmaximaandminima. TverskyandKahneman(1974)alsoreviewtheconceptofanchoring.Anchoringreferstoa deviationfromBayesianbeliefs,notadeparturefromstandardpreferences.Inanchoring,the subjectformsbeliefsbyadjustingfromapotentiallyarbitrarystartingpoint,andthebiasisthatthe finalbeliefisbiasedtowardthisanchor;adjustmentawayfromitisinsufficient.Forexample, TverskyandKahnemanaskedsubjectstoguesswhatfractionofAfricancountriesweremembersof theUnitedNations.Thosewhowerefirstasked“isitmoreorlessthan10%?”guessedamedianof 25%,whilethosewhohadbeenasked”isitmoreorlessthan65%”guessedamedianof45%. Offeringpayoffsforaccuracydidnotreducetheseeffects.AnotherexamplecomesfromStrackand Mussweiler(1997),whoaskedsubjectstoestimatewhenEinsteinfirstvisitedtheUnitedStates. Implausibleanchorslike1215and1992producedeffectsaslargeasanchorsof1909and1939. Studiesinvolvingreferencepointthinking,lossaversion,andanchoringarefeaturedat severalpointsinthissurvey.Thesephenomenahavebeenusedtoshedlightondividends,earnings management,mergerofferprices,equityissuancetiming,hurdlerates,thecostofdebt,andother patterns. 3BarberisandXiong(2009)andKaustia(2010b)showthatempiricalfeaturesofthedispositioneffectmake ithardtoconnecttoprospecttheoryperse,whichalsospecifiescurvatureinthevaluefunction.SeeKaustia (2010a)forathoroughsurveyofthedispositioneffectliterature. 10 2.1.4. Smart managers Buteveniflimitedarbitrageandsystematicinvestorbiasesadduptoinefficientmarkets, whyisitreasonabletoassumethatcorporatemanagersare“smart”inthesenseofbeingableto identifymispricing?Onecanofferseveraljustifications.First,corporatemanagershavesuperior informationabouttheirownfirm.Thisisevidencedbytheabnormallyhighreturnsonillegal insidertradinginMuelbroek(1992)andevenlegalinsidertradinginSeyhun(1992). Second,managerscanmanufacturetheirowninformationadvantagebymanagingearnings orwiththehelpofconflictedanalysts,asinBradshaw,Richardson,andSloan(2006).Theymay alsobeabletoshapeinvestordemandthroughinvestorrelations,bymarketingtheirsharesinGao andRitter(2010),orallocatingIPOsharesinZhang(2004). Third,corporatemanagershavefewerconstraintsthanequally“smart”moneymanagers. Considertwoclassicmodelsoflimitedarbitrageintroducedabove:DeLongetal.(1990)isbuilton shorthorizonsandMiller(1977)onshort‐salesconstraints.CFOstendtobejudgedonlonger horizonresultsthanaremoneymanagers,allowingthemtotakeaviewonmarketvaluationsina waythatmostmoneymanagerscannot.4Short‐salesconstraintsalsopreventmoneymanagers frommimickingCFOs.Whenafirmorasectorbecomesovervalued,corporationsarethenatural candidatestoexpandthesupplyofshares.5Moneymanagersarenot. Inaddition,managersmightjustfollowintuitiverulesofthumbthatallowthemtoidentify mispricingevenwithoutanyrealinformationadvantage.InBakerandStein(2004),onesuch 4Forexample,supposethemanagerissuesequityat$50pershare.Shouldthosesharessubsequentlydouble, themanagermightregretnotdelayingtheissue,buthewillsurelynotbefired,havingpresidedoverarisein thestockprice.Incontrast,imagineamoneymanagersells(short)thesamestockat$50.Thismightleadto considerablelossesforthefirmandtheexecutive,anoutflowoffunds,and,ifthebetislargeenough,perhaps theendofacareer. 5Conversely,whenthesharescrash,firmsserveasbuyersoflastresort(Hong,Wang,andYu(2008)). 11 successfulruleofthumbistoissueequitywhenthemarketisparticularlyliquid,inthesenseofa smallpriceimpactupontheissueannouncement.Inthepresenceofshort‐salesconstraints—more onthisbelow—unusuallyhighliquidityissymptomaticofanovervaluedmarketdominatedby irrationallyoptimisticinvestors. Finally,inthecaseofdebtmaturity,firmsmayhaveacomparativeadvantageinexploiting distortionsintheyieldcurve.Greenwood,Hanson,andStein(2010)developthislogic.Ina Modigliani‐Millerworld,firmsareindifferenttotheirdebtmaturity,freeingthemtofillinthegapin supplyatvariousmaturitiescreatedbyrestructuringoftheTreasurydebtmaturitystructureor othernon‐fundamentalsupplyanddemandeffectsontheyieldcurve.Bycontrast,mutualfundand institutionalinvestmentmanagersoftenhavelessflexibility,bymandateandotherlimitsof arbitrage,tobeopportunisticintheirmaturitychoice. 2.2. Theoretical framework: Rational managers in irrational markets Weusetheassumptionsofinefficientmarketsandsmartmanagerstodevelopasimple theoreticalframeworkforthemarkettimingandcateringapproach.Theframeworkhasrootsin FischerandMerton(1984),DeLong,Shleifer,Summers,andWaldmann(1989),Morck,Shleifer, andVishny(1990b),andBlanchard,Rhee,andSummers(1993),butourparticularderivation borrowsmostfromStein(1996).Newermodels,suchasBolton,Chen,andWang(2011),add dynamicconsiderationstothisstaticframework. Inthemarkettimingandcateringapproach,themanagerbalancesthreeconflictinggoals. Thefirstistomaximizefundamentalvalue.Thismeansselectingandfinancinginvestmentprojects toincreasetherationallyrisk‐adjustedpresentvalueoffuturecashflows.Tosimplifytheanalysis, wedonotexplicitlymodeltaxes,costsoffinancialdistress,agencyproblemsorasymmetric information.Instead,wespecifyfundamentalvalueas 12 f K , K , wherefisincreasingandconcaveinnewinvestmentK.Totheextentthatanyoftheusualmarket imperfectionsleadstheModigliani‐Miller(1958)theoremtofail,financingmayenterfalongside investment. Thesecondgoalistomaximizethecurrentsharepriceofthefirm’ssecurities.Inperfect capitalmarkets,thefirsttwoobjectivesarethesame,sincethedefinitionofmarketefficiencyis thatpriceequalsfundamentalvalue.Butonceonerelaxestheassumptionofinvestorrationality, thisneednotbetrue,andthesecondobjectiveisdistinct.Inparticular,thesecondgoalisto“cater” toshort‐terminvestordemandsviaparticularinvestmentprojectsorotherwisepackagingthefirm anditssecuritiesinawaythatmaximizesappealtoinvestors.Throughsuchcateringactivities, managersinfluencethetemporarymispricing,whichwerepresentbythefunction , wheretheargumentsofdependonthenatureofprevailinginvestorsentiment.Thearguments mightincludeinvestinginaparticulartechnology,assumingaconglomerateorsingle‐segment structure,changingthecorporatename,managingearnings,initiatingadividend,splittingshares, andsoon.Inpractice,thedeterminantsofmispricingmaywellvaryovertime. Thethirdgoalistoexploitthecurrentmispricingforthebenefitofexisting,long‐run investors.Managersachievethisbya“markettiming”financingpolicywhichsuppliessecurities thataretemporarilyovervaluedandrepurchasesthosethatareundervalued,oratleastless overvalued.Thispolicytransfersvaluefromthenewortheoutgoinginvestorstotheongoing,long‐ 13 runinvestors;thetransferisrealizedaspricescorrectinthelongrun.6Forsimplicity,wefocus hereontemporarymispricingintheequitymarkets,andsoreferstothedifferencebetweenthe currentpriceandthefundamentalvalueofequity.Moregenerally,eachofthefirm’ssecuritiesmay bemispricedtosomedegree.Bysellingafractionofthefirme,longrunshareholdersgain e .7 Weleaveoutthebudgetconstraintandlumptogetherthesaleofnewandexistingshares.Instead ofexplicitlymodelingtheflowoffundsandanypotentialfinancialconstraints,wewillconsiderthe reducedformimpactofeonfundamentalvalue. Itisworthnotingthatothercapitalmarketimperfectionscanleadtoasortofcatering behavior.Forexample,reputationmodelsinthespiritofHolmstrom(1982)canleadtoearnings management,inefficientinvestment,andexcessiveswingsincorporatestrategyevenwhenthe capitalmarketsarenotfooledinequilibrium.8Viewedinthislight,theframeworkhereisrelaxing theassumptionsofrationalexpectationsinHolmstrom,inthecaseofcatering,andMyersand Majluf(1984),inthecaseofmarkettiming. 6Ofcourse,wearealsousingthemarketinefficiencyassumptionhereinassumingthatmanagerialeffortsto captureamispricingdonotfullyandinstantlydestroyitintheprocess,astheydointherationalexpectations worldofMyersandMajluf(1984).Inotherwords,investorsunderreacttocorporatedecisionsdesignedto exploitmispricingbecauseoflimitedarbitrage,attention,etc. 7Forlongrunshareholderstobenefit,weareimplicitlythinkingofsomethinglikethree‐periodmodel.Inthe firstperiod,investmentandfinancingdecisionsaremade,andpricesareabovefundamentalvaluebyan amount.Thereisanintermediateperiodwherepricesdonotchange,butshort‐runinvestorsselltheir shares,andafinalperiodwherefundamentalvalueisrealized.Issuingequitywilltheeffectofreducingprices inthefirstandsecondperiodsife<0,whileincreasingthevaluepershareinthethirdperiodfromwhereit wouldotherwisebe. 8Forexamples,seeStein(1989)andScharfsteinandStein(1990).Foracomparisonofrationalexpectations andinefficientmarketsinthisframework,seeAghionandStein(2008). 14 Puttingthegoalsoffundamentalvalue,catering,andmarkettimingintooneobjective function,wehavethemanagerchoosinginvestmentandfinancingto max f K , K e 1 , K ,e whereisgreaterthanzeroandlessthanorequaltooneandspecifiesthemanager’shorizon. Whenequalsone,themanagercaresonlyaboutcreatingvalueforexisting,long‐run shareholders,thelasttermdropsout,andthereisnodistinctimpactofcatering.However,and interestingly,evenanextremelylong‐horizonmanagercaresaboutshort‐termmispricingforthe purposesofmarkettiming,andthusmaycatertoshort‐termmispricingtofurtherthisobjective. Withashorterhorizon,maximizingthestockpricebecomesanobjectiveinitsownright,even withoutanyconcomitantequityissues. Wetakethemanagerialhorizonasexogenouslysetbypersonalcharacteristics,career concerns,andthecompensationcontract.Ifthemanagerplanstosellequityorexerciseoptionsin thenearterm,hisportfolioconsiderationsmaylower.Careerconcernsandthemarketfor corporatecontrolcanalsocombinetoshortenhorizons:ifthemanagerdoesnotmaximizeshort‐ runprices,thefirmmaybeacquiredandthemanagerfired. DifferentiatingwithrespecttoKandegivestheoptimalinvestmentandfinancialpolicyofa rationalmanageroperatingininefficientcapitalmarkets: f K K , 1 e 1 K ,and f e K , e 1 e . Thefirstconditionisaboutinvestmentpolicy.Themarginalvaluecreatedfrominvestment isweighedagainstthestandardcostofcapital,normalizedtobeonehere,netoftheimpactthat 15 thisincrementalinvestmenthasonmispricing,andhenceitseffectthroughmispricingoncatering andmarkettiminggains.Thesecondconditionisaboutfinancing.Themarginalvaluelostfrom shiftingthefirm’scurrentcapitalstructuretowardequityisweighedagainstthedirectmarket timinggainsandtheimpactthatthisincrementalequityissuancehasonmispricing,andhenceits effectoncateringandmarkettiminggains.Thisisalottoswallowatonce,soweconsidersome specialcases. Investmentpolicy.InvestmentandfinancingareseparableifbothKandfeKareequalto zero.ThentheinvestmentdecisionreducestothefamiliarperfectmarketsconditionoffKequalto unity.Notethat,iffeisequaltozero,thereisnooptimalcapitalstructure.Realconsequencesof mispricingforinvestmentariseintwoways.Eithercapitalstructurehasarealeffectonvalue,when f e and f eK arenotequaltozero,orinvestmenthasadirecteffectonmispricing,when K isnot equaltozero.Thesimplestsituationtoevaluateinthefirstcasehas K and e equaltozero.The simplestsituationtoevaluateinthesecondcaseiswhen f e isequaltozero.Bothchannelsare likelypresent,butanalyzingthetwoatthesametimereducestransparency. InStein(1996)andBaker,Stein,andWurgler(2003),feandfeKarenotequaltozero.There isanoptimalcapitalstructure,oratleastanupperboundondebtcapacity.Thebenefitsofissuing orrepurchasingequityinresponsetomispricingarebalancedagainstthereductioninfundamental valuethatarisesfromtoomuch(orpossiblytoolittle)leverageandtheindirecteffectonfirmvalue throughinvestment,whenfeKisgreaterthanzero.Somewhatmoreformally,equityissueseare increasinginanexogenouslevelofmispricing.(Thisalsorequirestheassumptionthatfeeisless thanzero,whichisnecessaryforaninteriorsolutionforoptimalcapitalstructure.)TomatchBaker, SteinandWurgler(2003),considerthecaseofanundervaluedfirm.Themoreundervaluedthe firm,thelessequitythemanagersells.ThisconstrainsinvestmentwhenfeKisgreaterthanzero,i.e. Kisincreasingine.(ConstraintsofthistypealsorequiretheassumptionthatfKKislessthanzero, 16 whichisnecessaryforaninteriorsolutionforinvestment.)Insum,becauseofundervaluationand financialconstraints,themanagerchoosesacombinationoflowerequityissueseandlower investmentKthanhewouldinthesituationofnomispricing. InPolkandSapienza(2009)andGilchrist,Himmelberg,andHuberman(2005),thereisno optimalcapitalstructure,butKisnotequaltozero:mispricingisitselfafunctionofinvestment. Thepotentialtocreatemispricingdistortsinvestmentinasimple,directway.PolkandSapienza focusoncateringeffectsanddonotconsiderfinancing(eequaltozerointhissetup),whileGilchrist etal.modelthemarkettimingdecisionsofmanagerswithlonghorizons(equaltoone). Financialpolicy.Thedemandcurveforafirm’sequityslopesdownunderthenatural assumptionthateisnegative,e.g.,issuingsharespartlycorrectsmispricing.9Wheninvestmentand financingareseparable,managersactlikemonopolists.Thisiseasiesttoseewhenmanagershave longhorizons,andtheyselldownthedemandcurveuntilmarginalrevenueisequaltomarginal cost–ee.Notethatpriceremainsabovefundamentalvalueevenaftertheissue:“corporate arbitrage”movesthemarkettoward,butnotallthewayto,marketefficiency.10Managerssellless equitywhentheycareaboutshort‐runstockprice(lessthanone,here).Forexample,in Ljungqvist,Nanda,andSingh(2005),managersexpecttoselltheirownsharessoonaftertheIPO andsoissuelessasaresult.Managersalsoselllessequitywhentherearecostsofsuboptimal leverage.Tosomeextent,theshapeofthedemandcurvemaybeendogenous.GaoandRitter (2010)arguethatfirmsactivelymarkettheirsharesinanticipationofanequityofferingwiththisin mind. 9Gilchristetal.(2005)modelthisexplicitlywithheterogeneousinvestorbeliefsandshort‐salesconstraints. SeealsoHong,Wang,andYu(2008)). 10Totalmarkettiminggainsmaybeevenhigherinadynamicmodelwheremanagerscansellinsmall incrementsdownthedemandcurve. 17 Othercorporatedecisions.Thisframeworkcanbeexpandedtoaccommodatedecisions beyondinvestmentandissuance.Considerdividendpolicy.Increasingorinitiatingadividendmay simultaneouslyaffectbothfundamentalvalue,throughtaxes,andthedegreeofmispricing,if investorscategorizestocksaccordingtopayoutpolicyastheydoinBakerandWurgler(2004a). Thetradeoffis f d K , e 1 d , wheretheleft‐handsideisthetaxcostofdividends,forexample,andtheright‐handsideisthe markettiminggain,ifthefirmissimultaneouslyissuingequity,plusthecateringgain,ifthe managerhasshorthorizons.Inprinciple,asimilartradeoffgovernstheearningsmanagement decisionorcorporatenamechanges;however,particularlyinthelattercase,thefundamentalcosts ofcateringwouldpresumablybesmall. 2.3. Empirical challenges Themarkettimingandcateringframeworkfeaturestheroleofsecuritiesmispricingin investment,financing,andothercorporatedecisions.Themainchallengeforempiricaltestsinthis areaismeasuringmispricing,whichbyitsnatureishardtopindown.Researchershave operationalizedempiricaltestsinafewdifferentways. Exantemisvaluation.Oneoptionistotakeanexantemeasureofmispricing,forinstancea scaled‐priceratioinwhichamarketvalueinthenumeratorisrelatedtosomemeasureof fundamentalvalueinthedenominator.Perhapsthemostcommonchoiceisthemarket‐to‐book ratio:Ahighmarket‐to‐booksuggeststhatthefirmmaybeovervalued.Consistentwiththisidea, andthepresumptionthatmispricingcorrectsinthelongrun,market‐to‐bookisfoundtobe inverselyrelatedtofuturestockreturnsinthecross‐sectionbyFamaandFrench(1992)andinthe time‐seriesbyKothariandShanken(1997)andPontiffandSchall(1998).Also,extremevaluesof 18 market‐to‐bookareconnectedtoextremeinvestorexpectationsbyLakonishok,ShleiferandVishny (1994),LaPorta(1996),andLaPorta,Lakonishok,Shleifer,andVishny(1997). Onedifficultythatariseswiththisapproachisthatthemarket‐to‐bookratiooranotherex antemeasureofmispricingmaybecorrelatedwithanarrayoffirmcharacteristics.Bookvalueis notapreciseestimateoffundamentalvalue,butratherasummaryofpastaccountingperformance. Thus,firmswithexcellentgrowthprospectstendtohavehighmarket‐to‐bookratios,andthose withagencyproblemsmighthavelowratios—andperhapstheseconsiderations,ratherthan mispricing,driveinvestmentandfinancingdecisions.Dong,Hirshleifer,Richardson,andTeoh (2003)andAngandCheng(2005)discountanalystearningsforecaststoconstructanarguablyless problematicmeasureoffundamentalsthanbookvalue. Anotherfactorthatlimitsthisapproachisthatapreciseexantemeasureofmispricing wouldrepresentaprofitabletradingrule.Theremustbelimitstoarbitragethatpreventrational investorsfromfullyexploitingsuchrulesandtradingawaytheinformationtheycontainabout mispricing. Expostmisvaluation.Asecondoptionistousetheinformationinfuturereturns.Theidea isthatifstockpricesroutinelydeclineafteracorporateevent,onemightinferthattheywere inflatedatthetimeoftheevent.However,asdetailedinFama(1998)andMitchellandStafford (2000),thisapproachisalsosubjecttocritique. Themostbasiccritiqueisthejointhypothesisproblem:apredictable“abnormal”return mightmeantherewasmisvaluationexante,orsimplythatthedefinitionof“normal”expected return(e.g.,CAPM)iswrong.Perhapsthecorporateeventsystematicallycoincideswithchangesin risk,andhencethereturnrequiredinanefficientcapitalmarket.Anothersimplebutimportant critiqueregardseconomicsignificance.Marketvalue‐weightingorfocusingonNYSE/AMEXfirms mayreduceabnormalreturnsorcausethemtodisappearaltogether. 19 Therearealsostatisticalissues.Forinstance,corporateeventsareoftenclusteredintime andbyindustry—IPOsareanexampleconsideredinBrav(2000)—andthusabnormalreturnsmay notbeindependent.BarberandLyon(1997)andLyon,Barber,andTsai(1999)showthat inferencewithbuy‐and‐holdreturns(foreachevent)ischallenging.Calendar‐timeportfolios, whichconsistofanequal‐orvalue‐weightedaverageofallfirmsmakingagivendecision,have fewerproblemshere,butthechangingcompositionoftheseportfoliosaddsanothercomplication tostandardtests.LoughranandRitter(2000)alsoarguethatsuchanapproachisalesspowerful testofmispricing,sincetheclusteredeventshavetheworstsubsequentperformance.Afinal statisticalproblemisthatmanystudiescoveronlyashortsampleperiod.Schultz(2003)showsthat thiscanleadtoasmallsamplebiasifmanagersengagein“pseudo”markettiming,making decisionsinresponsetopastratherthanfuturepricechanges. Analyzingaggregatetimeseriesresolvessomeoftheseproblems.Likethecalendartime portfolios,timeseriesreturnsaremoreindependent.Therearealsoestablishedtime‐series techniques,e.g.Stambaugh(1999),todealwithsmall‐samplebiases.Nonetheless,thejoint hypothesisproblemremains,sincerationallyrequiredreturnsmayvaryovertime. Butevenwhentheseeconometricissuescanbesolved,interpretationalissuesmayremain. Forinstance,supposeinvestorshaveatendencytooverpricefirmsthathavegenuinelygood growthopportunities.Ifso,eveninvestmentthatisfollowedbylowreturnsneednotbeexante inefficient.Investmentmayhaverespondedtoomittedmeasuresofinvestmentopportunities,not tothemisvaluationitself. Thereareavarietyofwaystoimprovetheidentificationofachannelthatconnectscapital marketmispricingtocorporatefinance.Baker(2009)outlinesanapproachbasedoninstrumenting formispricingwithinvestortastesorothershockstothesupplyofcapital,andapproaches involvingtheinteractionofmeasuresofvaluationormispricingwithlimitstoarbitrageor 20 corporateincentivestotimethemarket.Ofcourse,evenintheseapproachesusinginteraction terms,onestillhastoproxyformispricingwithanexanteorexpostmethod.Totheextentthatthe hypothesizedcross‐sectionalpatternappearsstronglyinthedata,however,objectionsaboutthe measureofmispricinglosesomesteam. Non‐fundamentalinvestordemand.Thefirstapproachistoidentifysupplyeffectswith shiftsininvestordemand.Theideaistofindempiricalmeasuresthatarecorrelatedwithsentiment orthesupplyofcapitalbutnotwithfundamentals.Thisissimpleenoughtowrite,buthardto implement.Ifitwerepossibletoidentifymispricingsoclearly,suchmispricingmightnotarisein thefirstplace.Someexamplesaremeasuresofinvestorinertia(Baker,Coval,andStein(2007)), inattention(DellaVignaandPollet(2009)),localdemand(Becker,Ivkovic,andWeisbenner(2011)), overconfidence(combinedwithshortsalesconstraintsinGilchrist,Himmelberg,andHuberman (2005)),orindexadditions(Massa,Peyer,andTong(2005)).Morebroadly,shockstothecapitalof intermediaries,whilenotnecessarilybehavioral,canbeusedtoassesstheimpactofcapitalmarket inefficiencyoncorporatefinance.Thisistoolargealiteraturetosurveyhere.Thisapproachcomes downtoreplacingadirectmeasureofvaluationwithaninstrumentforinvestordemand. Cross‐sectionalinteractions:Limitstoarbitrage.Insituationswheretradingon mispricingislimitedbyshort‐salesconstraints,transactioncosts,marginrequirements,regulation, andfundamentalrisk,pricesarelikelytobefurtherfromfundamentalvalue,makingtheimpactof capitalmarketinefficienciesoncorporatefinancemorelikely.Forexample,Baker,Foley,and Wurgler(2009)arguethatthelimitsonarbitragearemoresevereinsomecountriesthanothers, leadingtoadifferentialeffectofvaluationsofFDI.LamontandStein(2006)andGreenwood(2007) makesimilarargumentsaboutrelativeefficiencytheimpactonstockissuanceandmergersand acquisitions,andstocksplitsinJapan,respectively.Thisapproachcomesdowntoidentifying marketconditionswheremispricingwillhavethestrongesteffect. 21 Cross‐sectionalinteractions:Corporateopportunism.Theeffectofcapitalmarket inefficienciesoncorporatefinanceshouldbemostpronouncedamongthosefirmsexhibitingthe meansandtheincentivetobeopportunistic.Inthisspirit,Baker,Stein,andWurgler(2003) considerthepredictionthatiffeispositive,mispricingshouldbemorerelevantforfinancially constrainedfirms.Moregenerally,managerialhorizonsorthefundamentalcostsofcateringto sentimentmayvaryacrossfirmsinameasurableway.Forexample,BergstresserandPhillipon (2006)showthatearningsmanagementismorepronouncedwhenmanagersarecompensated withstockandoptions.Gaspar,Massa,andMatos(2005)arguethatmanagersinherittheir investors’incentives,whichmaynotbechosenoptimallytomatchfirmfundamentals.This approachcomesdowntoidentifyingfirmswheremispricingwillhavethestrongesteffect. 2.4. Investment policy Ofparamountimportancearetherealconsequencesofmarketinefficiency.Itisonethingto saythatinvestorirrationalityhasanimpactoncapitalmarketprices,orevenfinancingpolicy, whichleadstotransfersofwealthamonginvestors.Itisanothertosaythatmispricingleadsto underinvestment,overinvestment,orthegeneralmisallocationofcapitalanddeadweightlossesfor theeconomyasawhole.Inthissubsectionwereviewresearchonhowmarketinefficiencyaffects realinvestment,mergersandacquisitions,anddiversification. 2.4.1. Real investment Inthemarkettimingandcateringframework,mispricinginfluencesrealinvestmentintwo ways.First,investmentmayitselfbeacharacteristicthatissubjecttomispricing(thishappens whenKisgreaterthanzeroabove).Investorsmayoverestimatethevalueofinvestmentin particulartechnologies,forexample.Second,afinanciallyconstrainedfirm(thiscanhappenwhen feKisgreaterthanzeroabove)maybeforcedtopassupfundamentallyvaluableinvestment opportunitiesifitisundervalued. 22 Mostresearchhaslookedatthefirsttypeofeffect.Ofcourse,anecdotalevidenceofthis effectcomesfrombubbleepisodes;itwaswiththelate1920sbubblefreshinmindthatKeynes (1936)arguedthatshort‐terminvestorsentimentis,atleastinsomeeras,amajorordominant determinantofinvestment.MorerecentUSstockmarketepisodesgenerallyviewedasbubbles includetheelectronicsboomin1959‐62,growthstocksin1967‐68,the“niftyfifty”intheearly 1970s,gamblingstocksin1977‐78,naturalresources,hightech,andbiotechnologystocksinthe 1980s,andtheInternetinthelate1990s;seeMalkiel(1990)forananecdotalreviewofsomeof theseearlierbubbles,andOfekandRichardson(2003)ontheInternet.SeeKindleberger(2000)for anattempttodrawgenerallessonsfrombubblesandcrashesoverseveralhundredyears,andfor anecdotalremarksontheirsometimes‐dramaticrealconsequences. Anearlywaveofstudiesinthisareatestedwhetherinvestmentissensitivetostockprices overandabovedirectmeasuresofthemarginalproductofcapital,suchascashfloworprofitability. Ifitisnot,theyreasoned,thentheunivariatelinkbetweeninvestmentandstockvaluationslikely justreflectsthestandard,efficient‐marketsQchannel.Thisapproachdidnotleadtoaclear conclusion,however.Forexample,Barro(1990)arguesforastrongindependenteffectofstock prices,whileMorck,Shleifer,andVishny(1990b)andBlanchard,Rhee,andSummers(1993) concludethattheincrementaleffectisweak. Themorerecentwaveofstudiestakesadifferenttack.Ratherthancontrollingfor fundamentalsandlookingforaresidualeffectofstockprices,theytrytoproxyforthemispricing componentofstockpricesandexaminewhetheritaffectsinvestment.Inthisspirit,Chirinkoand Schaller(2001,2004),Panageas(2003),PolkandSapienza(2009),Gilchrist,Himmelberg,and Huberman(2005),Massa,Peyer,andTong(2005),andSchaller(2011)allfindevidencethat investmentissensitivetoproxiesformispricing.Ofcourse,thegenericconcernisthatthe mispricingproxiesarestilljustpickingupfundamentals.Torefutethis,PolkandSapienzaaswell 23 asMassaetal.,forexample,considerthefinerpredictionthatinvestmentshouldbemoresensitive toshort‐termmispricingwhenmanagerialhorizonsareshorter.PolkandSapienzafindthat investmentisindeedmoresensitivetomispricingproxieswhenshareturnoverishigher,i.e.,where theaverageshareholder’shorizonisshorter;theMassaetal.testissimilar. Thesecondtypeofmispricing‐driveninvestmentistestedinBaker,Stein,andWurgler (2003).Stein(1996)predictsthatinvestmentwillbemostsensitivetomispricinginequity‐ dependentfirms,i.e.firmsthathavenooptionbuttoissueequitytofinancetheirmarginal investment,becauselong‐horizonmanagersofundervaluedfirmswouldratherunderinvestthan issueundervaluedshares.Usingseveralproxiesforequitydependenceandmispricing,Bakeretal. confirmtheprediction. Overall,thereissomeevidencethatsomeportionoftheeffectofstockpricesoninvestment isaresponsetomispricing,butkeyquestionsremain.Theactualmagnitudeoftheeffectof mispricinghasnotbeenpinneddown,evenroughly.Theefficiencyimplicationsarealsounclear. Titman,Wei,andXie(2004)andPolkandSapienza(2009)findthathighinvestmentisassociated withlowerfuturestockreturnsinthecrosssection,andLamont(2000)findsasimilarresultfor plannedinvestmentinthetimeseries.However,sentimentandfundamentalsseemlikelytobe correlated,andso,asmentionedpreviously,eveninvestmentfollowedbylowreturnsmaynotbe exanteinefficient.11Evengrantinganempiricallinkbetweenoverpricingandinvestment,itishard todeterminetheextenttowhichmanagersarerationallyfanningtheflamesofovervaluation,asin catering,oraresimplyjustasoveroptimisticastheirinvestors.Weshallreturntotheeffectsof managerialoptimism. 11Asanexampleofthiscomplication,CampelloandGraham(2007)findthatfinanciallystrappednon‐tech firmsissuedequityduringtheInternetbubbleandusedittoinvest.Theunconstrainednon‐techfirmsdidnot showthispattern.Thissuggestthatbubblesdrivenbyonecategorycanhavepositivespillovereffectson relativelyunrelatedfirms. 24 2.4.2. Mergers and acquisitions ShleiferandVishny(2003)proposeamarket‐timingmodelofacquisitions.Theyassume thatacquirersareovervalued,andthemotiveforacquisitionsisnottogainsynergies,butto preservesomeoftheirtemporaryovervaluationforlong‐runshareholders.Specifically,by acquiringless‐overvaluedtargetswithoverpricedstock(or,lessinterestingly,undervaluedtargets withcash),overvaluedacquirerscancushionthefallfortheirshareholdersbyleavingthemwith morehardassetspershare.Or,ifthedeal’svaluepropositioncaterstoaperceivedsynergythat causesthecombinedentitytobeovervalued,asmighthavehappenedinthelate1960s conglomerateswave(seebelow),thentheacquirercanstillgainalong‐runcushioneffect,while offeringalargerpremiumtothetarget. Themarkettimingapproachtomergershelpstounifyanumberofstylizedfacts.The defensivemotivefortheacquisition,andtheideathatacquisitionsarefurtherfacilitatedwhen cateringgainsareavailable,helptoexplainthetime‐serieslinkbetweenmergervolumeandstock prices,e.g.,GolbeandWhite(1988).12Themodelalsopredictsthatcashacquirersearnpositive long‐runreturnswhilestockacquirersearnnegativelong‐runreturns,consistentwiththefindings ofLoughranandVijh(1997)andRauandVermaelen(1998). Recentpapershavefoundfurtherevidenceformarkettiming‐motivatedmergers.Dong, Hirshleifer,Richardson,andTeoh(2003)andAngandCheng(2005)findthatmarket‐level mispricingproxiesandmergervolumearepositivelycorrelated,and(withinthis)thatacquirers tendtobemoreoverpricedthantargets.13Theyalsofindthatoffersforundervaluedtargetsare 12SeeRhodes‐KropfandViswanathan(2004)forasomewhatdifferentmisvaluation‐basedexplanationof thislink. 13ArelatedpredictionoftheShleifer‐Vishnyframeworkisthatanovervaluedacquirercreatesvalueforlong‐ termshareholdersbyacquiringafairlyvaluedorsimplylessovervaluedtarget.SavorandLu(2009)tests thispropositionbycomparingthereturnsofsuccessfulacquirerstothosethatfailforexogenousreasons, 25 morelikelytobehostile,andthatoverpricedacquirerspayhighertakeoverpremia.Rhodes‐Kropf, Robinson,andViswanathan(2005)alsolinkvaluationsandmergeractivity.Bouwman,Fuller,and Nain(2003)findevidencesuggestiveofashort‐termcateringeffect.Inhigh‐valuationperiods, investorswelcomeacquisitionannouncements,yetthesubsequentreturnsofmergersmadein thoseperiodsaretheworst.Baker,Foley,andWurgler(2009)findthatforeigndirectinvestment (FDI),whichisoftencross‐borderacquisitions,increasewiththecurrentaggregatemarket‐to‐book ratioofthesourcecountrystockmarketanddecreasewithsubsequentreturnsonthatmarket.All ofthesepatternsareconsistentwithovervaluation‐drivenmergeractivity. AnunresolvedquestionintheShleifer‐Vishnyframeworkiswhymanagerswouldprefera stock‐for‐stockmergertoanequityissueifthemarkettiminggainsaresimilar.Oneexplanationis thatamergermoreeffectivelyhidestheunderlyingmarkettimingmotivefrominvestors,because theequityissueandinvestmentdecisionarebundled.Baker,Coval,andStein(2007)consider anothermechanismthatcanalsohelpexplainagenericpreferenceforequityissuesviamerger.14 Thefirstingredientisthattheacquiringfirmfacesadownwardslopingdemandcurveforits shares.Thesecondingredientisthatsomeinvestorsfollowthepathofleastresistance,passively acceptingtheacquirer’ssharesasconsiderationevenwhentheywouldnothaveactively participatedinanequityissue.Withthesetwoassumptions,thepriceimpactofastock‐financed mergercanbemuchsmallerthanthepriceimpactofanSEO.Empirically,inertiaisamajorfeature ininstitutionalandespeciallyindividualholdingsdatathatisassociatedwithsmallermerger announcementeffects. suchasaregulatoryintervention.Successfulacquirersperformpoorly,asinLoughranandVijh(1997),but unsuccessfulacquirersperformevenworse. 14Forexample,inthecaseofS&P100firmsover1999‐2001,FamaandFrench(2005)findthattheamountof equityraisedinmergersisroughly40timesthatraisedinSEOs. 26 2.4.3. Diversification and focus Standardexplanationsforenteringunrelatedlinesofbusinessincludeagencyproblemsor synergies,e.g.,internalcapitalmarketsandtaxshields.Likewise,movestowardgreaterfocusare ofteninterpretedastriumphsofgovernance.Whileourmaintaskistosurveytheexisting literature,thetopicsofdiversificationandfocushaveyettobeconsideredfromaperspective whereinvestorsarelessthanfullyrational.So,wetakeashortdetourhere.Weaskwhetherthe evidenceathandisconsistentwiththeviewthatthelate‐1960sconglomeratewave,whichledto conglomeratessocomplextheywerestillbeingdivestedorbustedupdecadeslater,wasinpart drivenbyeffortstocatertoatemporaryinvestorappetiteforconglomerates. Investordemandforconglomeratesdoesappeartohavereachedapeakin1968. RavenscraftandScherer(1987,p.40)findthattheaveragereturnon13leadingconglomerates was385%fromJuly1965toJune1968,whiletheS&P425gainedonly34%.Diversifying acquisitionswerebeinggreetedwithapositiveannouncementeffect,whileotheracquisitionswere penalized(Matsusaka(1993)).Klein(2001)findsa“diversificationpremium”of36%from1966‐68 inasampleof36conglomerates.Perhapsrespondingtothesevaluationincentives,conglomerate mergersacceleratedin1967andpeakedin1968(RavenscraftandScherer,pp.24,161,218). Conglomeratevaluationsstartedtofallinmid‐1968.BetweenJuly1968andJune1970,the samplefollowedbyRavenscraftandSchererlost68%,threetimesmorethantheS&P425. Announcementeffectsalsosuggestaswitchininvestorappetites:diversificationannouncements weregreetedwithaflatreactioninthemid‐tolate‐1970sandanegativereactionbythe1980s (Morck,Shleifer,andVishny(1990a)).Kleinfindsthatthediversificationpremiumturnedintoa discountof1%in1969‐71and17%by1972‐74,andadiscountseemstohaveremainedthrough the1980s(LangandStulz(1994),BergerandOfek(1995)).Again,possiblyinresponsetothisshift incateringincentives,unrelatedsegmentsbegantobedivested,startingalongtrendtowardfocus 27 (Porter(1987),KaplanandWeisbach(1992)).15Overall,whilesystematicevidenceislacking,the driversofthediversificationandsubsequentre‐focuswavecouldberelatedtocatering. 2.5. Financial policy Thesimpletheoreticalframeworksuggeststhatlong‐horizonmanagersmayreducethe overallcostofcapitalpaidbytheirongoinginvestorsbyissuingoverpricedsecuritiesand repurchasingunderpricedsecurities.Next,wesurveytheevidenceontheextenttowhichmarket timingaffectsequityissues,repurchases,debtissues,cross‐borderissues,financialintermediation (withthoughtsontherecentfinancialcrisis),andcapitalstructure. 2.5.1. Equity issues Severallinesofevidencesuggestthatovervaluationisamotiveforequityissuance.Most simply,intheGrahamandHarvey(2001)anonymoussurveyofCFOsofpubliccorporations,two‐ thirdsstatethat“theamountbywhichourstockisundervaluedorovervaluedwasanimportantor veryimportantconsideration”inissuingequity(p.216).Severalotherquestionsinthesurveyalso askabouttheroleofstockprices.Overall,stockpricesareviewedasmoreimportantthannineout oftenfactorsconsideredinthedecisiontoissuecommonequity,andthemostimportantoffive factorsinthedecisiontoissueconvertibledebt. Empirically,equityissuanceispositivelyassociatedwithplausibleexanteindicatorsof overvaluation.Pagano,Panetta,andZingales(1998)examinethedeterminantsofItalianprivate firms’decisionstoundertakeanIPObetween1982and1992,andfindthatthemostimportantis themarket‐to‐bookratioofseasonedfirmsinthesameindustry.Lerner(1994)findsthatIPO 15InacasestudyofthediversificationandsubsequentrefocusofGeneralMills,Donaldson(1990)writesthat thecompanyspentsomeeffort“toverifythedominanttrendsininvestorperceptionsofcorporateefficiency, asseeninthecompanystudyoftheimpactofexcessivediversificationonthetrendofprice‐earnings multiplesinthe1970s”(p.140). 28 volumeinthebiotechsectorishighlycorrelatedwithbiotechstockindexes.Loughran,Ritter,and Rydqvist(1994)findthataggregateIPOvolumeandstockmarketvaluationsarehighlycorrelated inmostmajorstockmarketsaroundtheworld.Similarly,Marsh(1982)examinesthechoice between(seasoned)equityandlong‐termdebtbyUKquotedfirmsbetween1959and1974,and findsthatrecentstockpriceappreciationtiltsfirmstowardequityissuance.InUSdata,Jung,Kim, andStulz(1996),Hovakimian,Opler,andTitman(2001),andErel,Julio,Kim,andWeisbach(2010) alsofindastrongrelationshipbetweenstockpricesandseasonedequityissuance. Therearemanynon‐mispricingreasonswhyequityissuanceandmarketvaluationsshould bepositivelycorrelated,ofcourse.Morespecificevidenceforequitymarkettimingcomesfromthe patternthatnewissuesearnlowsubsequentreturns.Inoneoftheearliestmoderntestsofmarket efficiency,Stigler(1964)triedtomeasuretheeffectivenessoftheS.E.C.bycomparingtheexpost returnsofnewequityissues(lumpingtogetherbothinitialandseasoned)from1923‐28withthose from1949‐55.IftheS.E.C.improvedthepoolofissuers,hereasoned,thenthereturnstoissuersin thelatterperiodshouldbehigher.Buthefoundthatissuersinbothperiodsperformedabout equallypoorlyrelativetoamarketindex.Fiveyearsout,theaverageissuerinthepre‐S.E.C.era laggedthemarketby41%,whiletheaverageunderperformanceinthelaterperiodwas30%. Othersampleperiodsshowsimilarresults.Ritter(1991)examinesasampleofIPOs,Spiess andAffleck‐Graves(1995)examineSEOs,andLoughranandRitter(1995)examineboth.16And, Ritter(2003)updatestheseandseveralotherempiricalstudiesofcorporatefinancingactivities. Thelastpaper’ssampleincludes7,437IPOsand7,760SEOsbetween1970and1990.Fiveyears out,theaverageIPOearnslowerreturnsthanasize‐matchedcontrolfirmby30%,andtheaverage SEOunderperformsthatbenchmarkby29%.GompersandLerner(2003)fillinthegapbetween 16Updateddataonthelong‐runreturnsofIPOsisavailableonJayRitter’swebsiteat http://bear.warrington.ufl.edu/ritter/ipodata.htm. 29 thesamplesofStigler(1964)andLoughranandRitter(1995).Theirsampleof3,661IPOsbetween 1935and1972showsaveragefive‐yearbuy‐and‐holdreturnsthatunderperformthevalue‐ weightedmarketindexby21%to35%.17Thus,aseriesoflargeandnon‐overlappingsamples suggeststhat,onaverage,USequityissuesunderperformthemarketsomewhereintheballparkof 20‐40%overfiveyears. Inatestthatspeaksespeciallycloselytoopportunisticmarkettimingofequitysalestonew investors,Burch,Christie,andNanda(2004)examinethesubsequentperformanceofseasoned equityissuedviarightsoffers,whicharetargetedtoafirm’songoingshareholders,andfirm commitmentoffers,whicharetargetedtonewshareholders.Intheir1933to1949sample,aperiod inwhichrightsoffersweremorecommon,theyfindunderperformanceconcentratedentirelyinthe lattergroup.Thisfitstheframeworkabove,whichemphasizestheopportunistictimingofequity salestonewinvestors. Muchevidencesuggeststhatinvestorsentimentvariesovertimeinitsstrengthandnature. Forexample,stockmarketbubblescangrowandpopwithincertainindustries.Greenwoodand Hanson(2011)exploitthisobservation.Theyfindthatnetequityissuancebyfirmswithdifferent characteristics—size,shareprice,distressstatus,payoutpolicy,industry,andprofitability—helps topredictreturnsonportfoliosdefinedonthosecharacteristics.Theirpaperisalsoaninteresting contributiontobehavioralassetpricingandshowsthevalueofaunifiedperspective.Thatis,the papersuggestshowthemisvaluationoffirmcharacteristicsatanygivenpointintime,anotherwise difficultconcepttomeasure,isbetrayedbythefinancingactivityandmarkettimingmotivesof firms.Wewillseemoreresultsofthissortinthecateringsection. 17GompersandLerneralsoconfirmwhatBravandGompers(1997)foundinalatersample:whileIPOshave lowabsolutereturns,andlowreturnsrelativetomarketindexes,theyoftendonotdoworsethanstocksof similarsizeandbook‐to‐marketratio.Oneinterpretationisthatsecuritieswithsimilarcharacteristics, whetherornottheyareIPOs,tendtobesimilarlypriced(andmispriced)atagivenpointintime. 30 Ifequityissuesclusterwhenthemarketasawholeisovervalued,thenetgainstoequity markettimingmaybeevenlargerthantheunderperformancestudiessuggest.BakerandWurgler (2000)examinewhetherequityissuance,relativetototalequityanddebtissuance,predicts aggregatemarketreturnsbetween1927and1999.Theyfindthatwhentheequitysharewasinits tophistoricalquartile,theaveragevalue‐weightedmarketreturnoverthenextyearwasnegative 6%,or15%belowtheaveragemarketreturn.Henderson,Jegadeesh,andWeisbach(2006)finda similarrelationshipinseveralinternationalmarketsovertheperiod1990to2001.In12outofthe 13marketstheyexamine,averagemarketreturnsarehigherafterabelow‐medianequityshare yearthanafteranabove‐medianequityshareyear.18 Theequitymarkettimingstudiescontinuetobehotlydebated.Someauthorshighlightthe usualjointhypothesisproblem,implicitlyproposingthatIPOsandSEOsdeliverlowreturns becausetheyareactuallyfarlessrisky(andpricedaccordinglybyinvestors).Thisnotionstrikesus asfanciful,butformoreonthisperspective,seeEckbo,Masulis,andNorli(2000),andEckboand Norli(2004).Onastatisticalpoint,Schultz(2003)highlightsasmall‐sample“pseudomarket timing”biasthatcanleadtoexaggeratedimpressionsofunderperformancewhenabnormal performanceiscalculatedin“eventtime.”Theempiricalrelevanceofthisbiasisunclear.Schultz (2003,2004)arguesthatitmaybesignificant,whileAng,Gu,andHochberg(2007),Dahlquistand deJong(2004),andViswanathanandWei(2008)arguethatitisminor.19Thekeyissueconcerns 18Notethattheseaggregatepredictabilityresultsshouldprobablynotbeinterpretedasevidencethat “managerscantimetheaggregatemarket.”Amoreplausibleexplanationisthatbroadwavesofinvestor sentimentleadmanyfirmstobemispricedinthesamedirectionatthesametime.Then,theaverage financingdecisionwillcontaininformationabouttheaverage(i.e.,market‐level)mispricing,eventhough individualmanagersareperceivingandrespondingonlytotheirownfirm’smispricing. 19Butler,Grullon,andWeston(2005)takeSchultz’sideatothetime‐seriesandarguethattheequityshare’s predictivepowerisduetoanaggregateversionofthepseudomarkettimingbias.Baker,Taliaferro,and Wurgler(2006)replythatthetestsinButleretal.havelittleactualrelevancetothebiasandthatstandard econometrictechniquesshowthatsmall‐samplebiascanaccountforonlyonepercentoftheequityshare’s actualpredictivecoefficient. 31 thevarianceinthenumberofsecurityissuesovertime.Schultzassumesanonstationaryprocess forthistimeseries.Thismeansthatthenumberofsecurityissuescanexplodeorcollapsetozero forprolongedperiodsoftime,andhissimulatedvarianceofequityissuanceexceedstheactual experienceintheU.S. Inanycase,thereturnsstudies,havingbynaturelowpower,shouldnotbeconsideredin isolation.Surveyevidencewasmentionedabove.OtherrelevantresultsincludeTeoh,Welch,and Wong(1998a,b),whofindthattheequityissuerswhomanageearningsmostaggressivelyhavethe worstpost‐issuereturns.JainandKini(1994),Mikkelson,Partch,andShah(1997),andPaganoet al.(1998)findthatprofitabilitydeterioratesrapidlyfollowingtheinitialoffering,andLoughranand Ritter(1997)documentasimilarpatternwithseasonedissues.Insidersellingalsocoincideswith seasonedofferings,Jenter(2005)finds.Inaroundaboutbutnovelapproach,DellaVignaandPollet (2011)hypothesizethatmanagersbutnotinvestorsrecognizetheeffectofdemographicshiftson stockpricesinthenextfivetotenyears.Underamarkettimingpolicy,managerswillwaitforthose shiftstopushup(down)pricestoissue(repurchase)equity;perhapssurprisingly,theyfind evidenceforsuchaneffect. Markettimingcanhelpresolveapuzzleofhoworwhyissuersareabletoraiseoutside equitywhenpotentialagencycostsarehigh.InthetraditionalviewofJensenandMeckling(1976), existingownersbearfutureagencycostsupfrontwhentheyraisenewequity,potentially renderingoutsideequityprohibitivelycostly.Thisassumesofcoursethatoutsideinvestorsare rationallycomputingthesecosts.Chernenko,Greenwood,andFoley(2010)findthatJapanesefirms withthehighestagencycostsappeartoraisecapitalwhenperceptionsofagencycostsarelow.After listing,theirsubsequentperformanceisverypoor,asifinvestorsperiodicallyignoredpotential agencyproblems. 32 Viewedasawhole,theevidenceindicatesthatmarkettimingandattemptedmarkettiming playaconsiderableroleinequityissuancedecisions.Thatsaid,DeAngelo,DeAngelo,andStulz (2010)remindusthatseasonedequityissuancethatisnotassociatedwithmergersisstillan infrequentevent. 2.5.2. Repurchases Undervaluationisaveryimportantmotiveforrepurchases.Brav,Graham,Harvey,and Michaely(2005)survey384CFOsregardingpayoutpolicy,and“themostpopularresponseforall therepurchasequestionsontheentiresurveyisthatfirmsrepurchasewhentheirstockisagood value,relativetoitstruevalue:86.6%ofallfirmsagree”(p.26).Anecdotally,repurchasescluster afterunusualmarketcrashes:Hong,Wang,andYu(2008)highlighttherepurchasewavesthat followedaftercrashesinOctober1987andSeptember11,2001. Atthefirmlevel,repurchasersearnpositiveabnormalreturnsonaverage,suggestingthat managersareonaveragesuccessfulintimingthem.Ikenberry,Lakonishok,andVermaelen(1995) study1,239openmarketrepurchasesannouncedbetween1980and1990.Overthenextfour years,theaveragerepurchaserearned12%morethanfirmsofsimilarsizeandbook‐to‐market ratios.Ikenberry,Lakonishok,andVermaelen(2000)findsimilarresultsinasampleofCanadian firms.Notethatthesereturnsarebenchmark‐adjustedandthereforedonotcountanysuccessful timingofrepurchasesfrom,forexample,thereboundfromtheOctober1987crash.20 Theevidenceisthatmanagerstendtoissueequitybeforelowreturns,onaverage,and repurchasebeforehigherreturns.Withoutknowingjusthowthe“rational”costofequityvaries overtime,itisdifficulttoknowhowmuchthisactivityactuallyreducesthecostofequityforthe averagefirm.However,supposethatrationallyrequiredreturnsareconstant.Byfollowing 20BakerandWurgler(2000)alsostudytheabilityofnetequityissuancetopredictmarketreturns. 33 aggregatecapitalinflowsandoutflowsintocorporateequities,andtrackingthereturnsthatfollow theseflows,Dichev(2004)reportsthattheaverage“dollar‐weighted”returnislowerthanthe averagebuy‐and‐holdreturnby1.3%peryearfortheNYSE/Amex,5.3%forNasdaq,and1.5%(on average)for19stockmarketsaroundtheworld.Putdifferently,ifNYSE/Amexfirmshadissued andrepurchasedrandomlyacrosstime,then,holdingthetimeseriesofrealizedreturnsfixed,they wouldhavepaid1.3%peryearmorefortheequitycapitaltheyemployed. Ofcourse,thisreductioninthecostofequitycapitalisnotevenlydistributedinthecross sectionoffirms.Thecompositionoffirmsinpositiontorepurchase,forexample,variesovertime, asshownbyGreenwoodandHanson(2011),inaccordwithvaluation.Thestaticdifference betweenNasdaqandNYSE/Amexalsogivesahintofthis.Forthemanymaturefirmsthatrarely raiseexternalequity,thegainsmaybenegligible.Forotherfirmsthataccessthecapitalmarkets repeatedlythroughseasonedequityissuesandstock‐financedmergers,thegainsmaybemuch larger. 2.5.3. Debt issues Afewpapershaveexamineddebtmarkettiming—raisingdebtwhenitscostisunusually low.Surveyevidenceofferssupportformarkettimingbeingafactorindebtissuancedecisions. GrahamandHarvey(2001)findthatinterestratesarethemostcitedfactorindebtpolicy decisions:CFOsissuedebtwhentheyfeel“ratesareparticularlylow.”Expectationsabouttheyield curvealsoappeartoinfluencethematurityofnewdebt.Short‐termdebtispreferred“whenshort‐ termratesarelowcomparedtolong‐termrates”andwhen“waitingforlong‐termmarketinterest ratestodecline.”Whiletheformerstatementwouldbeconsistentwiththepreferenceforalow interestratestopumpupearnings(Stein(1989)),thelatterclearlyindicatesaskepticisminthe textbookexpectationshypothesis,whichpositsthatthecostofdebtisequalacrossmaturities.At 34 thesametime,CFOsdonotconfesstoexploitingtheirprivateinformationaboutcreditquality, insteadhighlightinggeneraldebtmarketconditions. Ontheempiricalside,Marsh(1982),inhissampleofUKfirms,findsthatthechoice betweendebtandequitydoesappeartobeswayedbythelevelofinterestrates.GuedesandOpler (1996)examineandlargelyconfirmthesurveyresponsesregardingtheeffectoftheyieldcurve.In asampleof7,369USdebtissuesbetween1982and1993,theyfindthatmaturityisstrongly negativelyrelatedtothetermspread(thedifferencebetweenlong‐andshort‐termbondyields), whichfluctuatedconsiderablyduringthisperiod. Isthereanyevidencethatdebtmarkettimingissuccessful?Inaggregatedata,Baker, Greenwood,andWurgler(2003)examinetheeffectofdebtmarketconditionsonthematurityof debtissuesand,perhapsmoreinterestingly,connectthematurityofnewissuestosubsequentbond marketreturns.Specifically,inUSFlowofFundsdatabetween1953and2000,theaggregateshare oflong‐termdebtissuesintotallong‐andshort‐termdebtissuesisnegativelyrelatedtotheterm spread,justasGuedesandOplerfindwithfirm‐leveldata.Further,becausethetermspreadis positivelyrelatedtofutureexcessbondreturns—i.e.thedifferenceinthereturnsoflong‐termand short‐termbonds,ortherealizedrelativecostoflong‐andshort‐termdebt—soisthelong‐term shareindebtissues.Perhapssimplybyusinganaïveruleofthumb,“issueshort‐termdebtwhen short‐termratesarelowcomparedtolong‐termrates,”managersmayhavetimedtheirdebt maturitydecisionssoastoreducetheiroverallcostofdebt.Ofcourse,suchaconclusionissubject totheusualrisk‐adjustmentcaveats. Greenwood,Hanson,andStein(2008)godeeperintotheeffectofdebtmarketefficiencyon maturitystructure,andwhileitfallswithinthemarkettimingspiritithastheappealingfeaturethat itdoesnotrequirethatfirmshaveadebtmarketforecastingability.Specifically,theyarguethat thereareshockstosupplyofbondsatdifferentpointsintheyieldcurve,forexamplechangesinthe 35 maturitystructureofgovernmentdebt,thatintroducecorrespondingmispricingsalongtheyield curve.Anyonecanobservethese.Givenlimitedarbitrageontheinvestorside,firmsthatare indifferenttotheirdebtmaturity(inthisotherwiseModigliani‐Millerworld)cansupplydebtatthe mispricedterm,limitedonlybytheirsize. Unfortunately,thedataonindividualdebtissuesandtheirsubsequentreturnsdoesnot approachthelevelofdetailoftheIPOandSEOdata.Butoneintriguingpatternthathasbeen uncoveredisthatdebtissues,muchlikeequityissues,arefollowedbylowequityreturns.Spiess andAffleck‐Graves(1999)examine392straightdebtissuesand400convertibleissuesbetween 1975and1989.Thesharesofstraightdebtissuersunderperformasize‐andbook‐to‐market benchmarkbyaninsignificant14%overfiveyears(themedianunderperformanceissignificant), whileconvertibleissuersunderperformbyasignificant37%.Thereisalsoasuggestionthatthe riskiestfirmsmaybetimingtheiridiosyncraticcreditquality,despitethesurveyanswersonthis point:thesharesofunratedissuershaveamedianfive‐yearunderperformanceof54%.Ifthe equitydidsopoorly,thedebtissuespresumablyalsodidpoorly.Inamuchbroaderpanel, RichardsonandSloan(2003)alsofindthatnetdebtissuanceisfollowedbylowstockreturns. Thereareseveralpotentialexplanationsforthispattern.Certainly,equityovervaluation wouldbeexpectedtolowerthecostofdebtdirectly,becausecreditriskmodelsroutinelyinclude stockmarketcapitalizationasaninput,sotherelationshipwithsubsequentstockreturnsmay reflectdebtmarkettimingperse.Or,perhapsmanagerialandinvestorsentimentiscorrelated; managersmaytendtobemostoptimisticpreciselywhencapitalischeap,andthusraiseandinvest asmuchastheycanfromanysource.Thisstorycombinesinvestorandmanagerialirrationalityand sodoesnotfitneatlywithinthemarkettimingframework,butmayhavesometruth.Athird possibility,outlinedinBaker,Stein,andWurgler(2003),isthatequityovervaluationrelaxesa 36 bindingleverageconstraint,creatingdebtcapacitythatsubsequentlygetsusedup.Butdebtis alwayscorrectlypricedinthissetting,sodebtmarkettimingperseisnotpossible. 2.5.4. Cross‐border issues Thestudyofdual‐listedsharesbyFrootandDabora(1999)showsthatevenhighlyliquid marketssuchastheUSandtheUKcanattachdifferentpricestothesamecashflowstream.This raisesthepossibilityoftimingacrossinternationalmarkets.Alongtheselines,GrahamandHarvey (2001)findthatamongUSCFOswhohaveconsideredraisingdebtabroad,44%implicitly dismissedcoveredinterestparityinreplyingthatlowerforeigninterestrateswereanimportant considerationintheirdecision.21 Inpractice,mostinternationalstockandbondissuesaremadeontheUSandUKmarkets. Henderson,Jegadeesh,andWeisbach(2006)findthatwhentotalforeignissuesintheUSortheUK arehigh,relativetorespectiveGDP,subsequentreturnsonthosemarketstendtobelow, particularlyincomparisontothereturnsonissuers’ownmarkets.Inasimilarvein,andconsistent withthesurveyevidencementionedabove,foreignfirmstendtoissuemoredebtintheUSandthe UKwhenratestherearelowrelativetodomesticrates. 2.5.5. Financial intermediation Ourfocusismostlyonthefinancingdecisionsoffirms,butfinancialintermediariesoften playacriticalrolebetweenfirmsandtheultimateinvestors.Totheextentthatcapitalmarket inefficienciesaffectcorporatefinance,aninterestingquestionishowintermediariesaffectissuance andinvestmentpatternsandwhethertheyplayastabilizingordestabilizingrole.Theroleof financialintermediariesinbehavioralcorporatefinanceisaninterestingquestioninitsownright thatdeservesmoreresearchattention.Wementionpapersintheareaofbanking,privateequity, 21AlmostallequityraisedbyUScorporationsisplacedindomesticmarkets,soGrahamandHarveydonot askaboutthedeterminantsofinternationalstockissues. 37 andventurecapital.Thesequestionsobviouslyloomlargeinlightoftherecentfinancialcrisis, whichwediscussnext. Banksarenotdissimilartofirmsinthattheyhavethesamemarkettimingmotivestosell overvaluedsecuritiesandbuybacksecuritiesthatareundervalued.Motivatedbythecrisis,Shleifer andVishny(2010)modelhowfinancialintermediariescantakeadvantageofinvestorsentimentin thiswaythroughsecuritizedlending—creatingandsellingoverpricedassets.Thiscreatesachannel forbankstotransmitsentiment‐drivenmispricingintorealeffects.Intheirmodel,banksretaina fractionoftheirloans.Afterahaircut,thevalueoftheseloansdetermineshowmuchtheycan borrowshort‐term.Whenloanvaluesarehigh,borrowingtomakemoreofthemandexpandthe balancesheetandfinancemorerealinvestmentissoprofitablethatitisworththeriskofhavingto liquidatetheirholdingsifandwhenpricesfallbelowfundamentals.AsCharlesPrince,theCEOof Citigroup,famouslysaidinJuly2007,“Whenthemusicstops,intermsofliquidity,thingswillbe complicated.Butaslongasthemusicisplaying,you’vegottogetupanddance.We’restilldancing.” Asaresult,farfrombeinginapositiontobuyunderpricedloansandstabilizethemarket,or financenewinvestment,bankscandeepenacrisis. Fang,Ivashina,andLerner(2010)findevidenceofopportunisminbankinvolvementin privateequity.Inparticular,banks’shareofprivateequitytransactionspeakswhentheprivate equitymarketisexperiencinglargeinflows.Moreover,transactionsdoneatmarketpeaksaremore likelytoturnoutpoorly.Abroaderviewofprivateequityisthatitprofitsfromtheimperfect integrationbetweencreditandequitymarkets.Occasionally,borrowingtofinancethepurchaseof publicorprivatefirmsischeaprelativetothecostofequitycapital,enticingtheshareofprivate equityinmergersandacquisitionstocheap.Becausethisispurelyatimeseriesview,andprivate equityhasashorthistory,itisdifficulttoprove.However,Axelson,Jenkinson,Stromberg,and Weisbach(2010)providecorroboratingevidenceofalinkbetweenfinancingcostsanddealpricing. 38 Ithasbeensuggestedthatintermediariescancausefinancialmarket“dislocations”to propagatefromonesetoffirmstoanother,affectingrealactivity.Townsend(2011)considersthe caseofventurecapital,whereinformationasymmetrycanleadtotheportfoliofirmbeinglocked intoarelationshipwithonecapitalprovider,e.g.asinRajan(1992).HefindsthataftertheInternet bubbleburst,non‐techfirmshaddifficultygettingfollow‐onfundingiftheirventurecapitalistshad hightechexposure.Thequestioniswhyventurecapitalistsdonotrespondbydiversifyingtheir portfoliosorreservingcapitalforfollow‐onofferings.ThisisinthesamespiritastheShleifer‐ Vishnymodel,whereinthiscasethelureofresellingInternetfirmstoafrothymarketisso profitablethatitisworththeriskofbeingshortofcapitalintheeventofacollapse. Therecentfinancialcrisishasmanydifferentelements,fromthedecisionsofindividual borrowerstotheultimatepurchasersofmortgagebackedsecurities,andtheinvolvementof numerousintermediaries,includingmortgagebrokers,mortgagebanks,investmentbanksand otherunderwritersofmortgage‐backedandothercollateralizeddebtobligations(CDOs),ratings agencies,bondinsurers,andthegovernment‐sponsoredentities,FannieMaeandFreddieMac.Itis nosurprisethatthereisnotatidybehavioral,orrational,explanationtoitscausesoritsultimate realconsequences.Barberis(2011)makessignificantprogressinthisdirection.Wedonothave roomtofullysurveytheburgeoningliteratureonthecrisishere. Abehavioralviewofthecrisisstartswiththeobservationthatlessthanfullyrational demandwastheunderpinningoftwinbubblesinrealestateandthedebtcontractsunderlyingreal estateandothersimilarassets.Thereareavarietyofexplanations.Forexample,investorsand ratingsagenciesneglectedararebutnotzeroprobabilitybadstateandovervaluedquasi‐AAA securitiesinGennaioli,Shleifer,andVishny(2011).Realestateandcreditinstrumentswere difficulttoshort,sodifferencesofopinionmayhaveledtoovervaluation.Or,mostsimply,investors extrapolatedshorthistoriesofhighrealestatereturnsandlowdefaultprobabilities.Greenwood 39 andHanson(2010)findpredictabilityinamuchlongertimeseriesofreturnsoncredit.Aperiodof highreturnsonriskydebtandloosenedcreditstandardsispredictablyfollowedbylowerreturns. Institutionsplayedarole,cateringtoinvestordemandforsafeassets.Investmentbanks createdseeminglylowriskassetswithpoolingandtranching.Thiscombinedinsomecaseswith bondinsuranceincreasedthesupplyforAAAsecurities.CovalandStafford(2010)arguethat ratingsagenciesfocusedondefaultprobabilities,neglectingthepriceofriskforseniortranchesof CDOs.Thisisamoresubtleargumentthantheconflictsofinterestofissuerspayingtheratings agenciesforanopinionthathavebeenhighlightedbypoliticiansandthemedia. Adefiningfeatureofthefinancialcrisiswasthatsystemicallyimportantbanksretaineda significantexposuretoalltypesofmortgagesecurities.Thereareanumberofexplanations.Oneis thattheysimplycarriedinventoryofmortgagesandwereleftwiththesesecuritiesontheirbalance sheetsatthestartofthefinancialcrisis.UnlikeInternetIPOs,CDOsrequiredtimeandbankcapital toassemble.Asecondexplanationisthattheyintentionallytookriskswithlimitedbankcapital, intentionallygamblingonapositiveoutcomeinthemortgagemarkets.Thismoralhazardviewhas shapedthedebateinfinancialreform.AchallengetothisviewisthattheleadershipofBearStearns andLehmanBrotherswhowereinapositiontochangeleveragehadalotatstake,andindeedlost muchoftheirwealthin2008.Athirdexplanationisthattherewereagencyproblemswithinthe firmandthestructuredfinancegroupswiththemostinformationaboutthesemarketsdidnot sharewithmanagement.Afinalexplanationisthattheywereconvincedbytheirownmarketingor, relatedly,theywerefocusedonshort‐termperformanceandthehighpricesofmortgagesecurities thatchangedhandspriortothecrisis.Thisbelongstothesectiononlessthanfullyrational managers.Whetherthiswasoverconfidence,cognitivedissonance,oralargersociological phenomenonishardtopindown. 40 Afewgeneralobservationsareworthmakingaboutrecentfinancialcrises.Boththe Internetcrashandthefinancialcrisisstartedwithsignificantassetpricebubbles,bothalso involvedtheactiveoratleastcomplicitparticipationoffinancialintermediaries,butthefinancial crisisinvolvedmuchmoredirectexposurewithinthebankingsystem—andhencelargerreal consequences.Moreover,bothseemtoinvolveequalpartsofagencyproblemswithininstitutions andinvestorsentiment. 2.5.6. Capital structure Asanaccountingidentity,afirm’scapitalstructureisthecumulativeoutcomeofalong seriesofincrementalfinancingdecisions,eachdrivenbytheneedtofundsomeinvestmentproject, consummateamerger,refinanceorrebalance,orachievesomeotherpurpose.Totheextentthat markettimingisadeterminantofanyoftheseincrementalfinancingdecisions,then,itmayhelpto explainthecross‐sectionofcapitalstructure.Inparticular,ifmarkettiming‐motivatedfinancing decisionsarenotquicklyrebalancedaway,low‐leveragefirmswilltendtobethosethatraised externalfinancewhentheirstockpriceswerehigh,andhencethosethattendedtochooseequityto financepastinvestmentsandmergers,andvice‐versaforhighleveragefirms.22 SuchamarkettimingtheoryofcapitalstructureisoutlinedinBakerandWurgler(2002).In anefforttocapturethehistoricalcoincidenceofmarketvaluationsandthedemandforexternal financeinasinglevariable,theyconstructan“externalfinanceweighted‐average”ofafirm’spast market‐to‐bookratios.Forexample,ahighvaluewouldmeanthatthefirmraisedthebulkofits externalfinance,equityordebt,whenitsmarket‐to‐bookwashigh.Ifmarkettiminghasa persistentimpactoncapitalstructure,thisvariablewillhaveanegativecross‐sectionalrelationship 22Similarly,debtmaturitystructurecouldtosomeextentreflectthehistoricalcoincidenceofdebt‐raising needsanddebtmarketconditionslikethetermspread. 41 tothedebt‐to‐assetsratio,eveninregressionsthatcontrolforthecurrentmarket‐to‐bookratio.In abroadCompustatsamplefrom1968to1999,astrongnegativerelationshipisapparent. Thisevidencehasinspireddebate.Ononehand,Hovakimian(2006)arguesthatequity issuesdonothavepersistenteffectsoncapitalstructure,andthattheexplanatorypowerofthe weightedaveragemarket‐to‐bookarisesbecauseitcontainsinformationaboutgrowth opportunities,alikelydeterminantoftargetleverage,thatisnotcapturedincurrentmarket‐to‐ book.LearyandRoberts(2005),KayhanandTitman(2004),FlanneryandRangan(2006)also arguethatfirmsrebalancetowardatarget.Alti(2006)looksspecificallyatthetimeseriesvariation inIPOleverage,findingthataninitialandstatisticallysignificantresponsetohotissuesmarketsis short‐lived. Ontheotherhand,HuangandRitter(2009)showthatthetendencytofundafinancing deficitwithequitydecreaseswhenthecostofequityislow.Furthermore,Welch(2004)andHuang andRitter(2009),likeFamaandFrench(2002),arguethatfirmsrebalancetheircapitalstructures muchmoreslowly,sothatshockstocapitalstructurearelonglived.And,inanyevent,Chenand Zhao(2007)pointoutthatmeanreversioninleverageisnotdefinitiveevidenceforatradeoff theory.Leverageisaratio,soshockstendtocausemeanreversionmechanically.Inananalysisof thechoicebetweenequityanddebtissues,whichavoidsthisproblem,ChenandZhao(2005)find thatdeviation‐from‐targetproxieshavelittleexplanatorypower,whilemarket‐to‐bookandpast stockreturnsareveryimportant. 42 2.6. Other corporate decisions Inthissubsection,weconsiderwhatthemarkettimingandcateringapproachhastosay aboutdividendpolicy,firmnamechanges,andearningsmanagement.23Wealsodiscussworkthat looksatexecutivecompensationfromthisperspective. 2.6.1. Dividends Thecateringideahasbeenappliedtodividendpolicy.Long(1978)providessomeearly motivationforthisapplication.HefindsthatshareholdersofCitizensUtilitiesputdifferentprices onitscashdividendshareclassthanitsstockdividendshareclass,eventhoughthevalueofthe shares’payoutsareequalbycharter.Inaddition,thisrelativepricefluctuates.Theunique experimentsuggeststhatinvestorsmayviewcashdividendsperseasasalientcharacteristic,andin turnraisesthepossibilityofacateringmotiveforpayingthem. BakerandWurgler(2004a)testacateringtheoryofdividendsinaggregateUSdata between1963and2000.Theyfindthatfirmsinitiatedividendswhenthesharesofexistingpayers aretradingatapremiumtothoseofnonpayers,anddividendsareomittedwhenpayersareata discount.Tomeasuretherelativepriceofpayersandnonpayers,theyuseanexantemeasureof mispricingtheycallthe“dividendpremium,”whichisjustthedifferencebetweentheaverage market‐to‐bookratiosofpayersandnonpayers.Theyalsouseexpostreturns,andfindthatwhen therateofdividendinitiationincreases,thefuturestockreturnsofpayers(asaportfolio)arelower thanthoseofnonpayers.Thisisconsistentwiththeideathatfirmsinitiatedividendswhenexisting payersarerelativelyoverpriced.LiandLie(2006)findsimilarresultsfordividendchanges. 23Weputdividendpolicyinthissectionandrepurchasesinthefinancingsection,because,unlikea repurchase,pro‐ratadividendsdonotchangetheownershipstructureofthefirm,andthereisnomarket timingbenefitorcost.Forthisreason,itfitsmorenaturallywiththecategoryofcorporatedecisionsthat mightinfluencethelevelofmispricing,butdonotbythemselvestransfervalueamonginvestors. 43 Time‐varyingcateringincentivesshedmuchlightonthe“disappearance”ofdividends. FamaandFrench(2001)documentthatthepercentageofCompustatfirmsthatpaydividends declinesfrom67%in1978to21%in1999,andthatonlyapartofthisisduetothecompositional shifttowardssmall,unprofitable,growthfirmswhicharegenerallylesslikelytopaydividends. BakerandWurgler(2004b)documentthatthedividendpremiumswitchedsignfrompositiveto negativein1978andhasremainednegativethrough1999,suggestingthatdividendsmayhave beendisappearinginpartbecauseoftheconsistentlylowervaluationsputonpayersoverthis period.Ananalysisofearlier1963‐77dataalsolendssupporttothisidea.Dividends“appeared,” “disappeared,”andthen“reappeared”inthisperiod,andeachshiftroughlylinesupwithaflipin thesignofthedividendpremium.InUKdata,Ferris,Sen,andYui(2006)findthatdividendshave beendisappearingduringthelate1990s,andthatadividendpremiumvariableformedusingUK stockslinesupwiththispattern. Supposingthatdividendsupplydoesrespondtocateringincentives,whydoesinvestor demandforpayersvaryovertimeinthefirstplace?Onepossibilityisthat“dividendclienteles” varyovertime,forexamplewithtaxcodechanges.However,inUSdata,thedividendpremiumis unrelatedtothetaxdisadvantageofdividendincome,asistherateofdividendinitiation.Shefrin andStatman(1984)developexplanationsforwhyinvestorspreferdividendsbasedonself‐control problems,prospecttheory,mentalaccounting,andregretaversion.Perhapstheseelementsvary overtime.BakerandWurgler(2004a)arguethatthedividendpremiumreflectssentimentfor “risky”nonpayinggrowthfirmsversus“safe”dividendpayers,sinceitfallsingrowthstockbubbles andrisesincrashes;FullerandGoldstein(2011)showexplicitlythatpayersoutperforminmarket downturns.Anecdotalevidencesuggeststhatsomeinvestorsflocktotheperceivedsafetyof dividendsingloomyperiods,andbiduppayers’prices,atleastinrelativeterms,intheprocess. 44 Therearelimitationstoacateringtheoryofdividends.Forone,itisadescriptivetheoryof whetherfirmspaydividendsatall,nothowmuch—inUSdata,atleast,thedividendpremiumdoes notexplainaggregatefluctuationsinthelevelofdividends.DeAngelo,DeAngelo,andSkinner (2004)reportthattheaggregatedollarvalueofdividendshasincreasedinrealterms,asdividends havebecomeconcentratedinasmallerfactionoftradedfirms.Also,thetheoryworksbetterfor explaininginitiationsthanomissions,andithaslittletosayaboutthestrongpersistencein dividendpolicy.Catering,likeagencyorasymmetricinformationortaxes,isbestviewedasone elementinanoveralltheoryofdividendpolicy.Aswewillseelater,itisnoteventheonlyapproach todividendsthatbehavioralcorporatefinanceoffers. 2.6.2. Earnings management Thequarterlynetincomefigurethatmanagersreporttoshareholdersdiffersfromactual economiccashflowsbyvariousnon‐cashaccruals,somediscretionary.Thisbecomesinteresting when,asdocumentedinthesurveybyGraham,Harvey,andRajgopal(2005),CFOsbelievethat investorscaremoreaboutearningspersharethancashflows. Indeed,certainpatternsinreportedearningsnumbersareclearlyshapedbycatering concerns.MostprominentamongthesearethereferencepointsdocumentedbyDegeorge,Patel, andZeckhauser(1999).Earningsaremanagedtoexceedthreesalientthresholds.Inorderof importance,thesearepositiveearnings,pastreportedearnings,andanalysts’expectations. Interestingly,theshapeoftheearningsdistributionsshowthatthethresholdisgenerallymetfrom below:firmsnearthethresholdsstretchtomeetthem,nottreatingthemaslowerboundsand shiftingearningstothefuture.24Carslaw(1988)andBernard(1989)findthatreportedearnings andearningspershareclusteratsalientroundnumbers,suchasmultiplesoffiveortencents. 24Inthebehavioralsignalingsectionofthepaper,wediscussamoredynamicmodelwithbothfeatures. 45 Thesepatternsdonotholdfornegativeearnings,however;apparently,managersdowhateverthey cantodistractattentionfrombadresults. Thesepatternshaveaflavorofcateringtoshareholderlossaversionrelativetosalient earningsreferencepoints.Atthesametime,therearenon‐behavioralcontributorstothese patterns.First,earningsmanagementcanbeaNashequilibriumresult(Stein(1989))under asymmetricinformation.Second,managerialbonusesordebtcontractsmaybeconditionalon earningsperformancerelativetosimplebenchmarks.Ofcourse,theuseofsuchcontractsbegsthe questionwhyshareholdersandfinanciersshouldcareaboutsalientbenchmarksovercontinuous measuresofperformanceinthefirstplace. Consistentwithcatering,managerswith“shorthorizons”areespeciallylikelytomanage earnings.BergstresserandPhilippon(2006)findthataccrualsmanagementisgreaterincompanies whoseCEO’scompensation,viastockandoptionsholdings,issensitivetocurrentshareprices. Sloan(1996)findsthatfirmswithhighaccrualsearnlowsubsequentreturns,whichsuggeststhat earningsmanagementmaybesuccessfulinboostingshareprice,oratleastinsustaining overvaluation.Consistentwiththeviewthatmanagersuseearningsmanagementtofoolinvestors andissueovervaluedequity,Teoh,Welch,andWong(1998a,b)findthatinitialandseasonedequity issuerunderperformanceisgreatestforfirmsthatmostaggressivelymanagepre‐issueearnings. Animportantquestioniswhetherearningsmanagementhassignificantconsequencesfor investment.Graham,Harvey,andRajgopal(2005)presentCFOswithhypotheticalscenariosand findthat41%ofthemwouldbewillingtopassupapositive‐NPVprojectjusttomeettheanalyst consensusEPSestimate.Directevidenceofthistypeofvaluelossisdifficulttodocument,but Jensen(2005)presentsseveralanecdotes,andsuggestiveempiricalstudiesincludeTeohetal. (1998a,b),EricksonandWang(1999),Bergstresser,Desai,andRauh(2006),andMcNicholsand 46 Stubben(2008).Oneprovocativefindingisthatearningsmanagementactivityincreasespriorto stockacquisitions. 2.6.3. Firm names Namechangesprovidesomeofthesimplestandmostcolorfulexamplesofcatering.In frictionlessandefficientmarkets,ofcourse,firmnamesareasirrelevantasdividends.Butthereis atleastamodestfundamentalcostofchangingnames,andperhapsthroughanamechangeafirm cancreateasalientassociationwithatemporarilyoverpricedcategoryofstocks. Evidenceofacateringmotiveforcorporatenamesismostprominentinbubbles.Inthe 1959‐62erawhichMalkiel(1990)referstoasthe“tronicsboom,”firms“oftenincludedsome garbledversionoftheword‘electronics’intheirtitleevenifthecompanieshadnothingtodowith theelectronicsindustry”(p.54).SystematicevidencehasbeenassembledfortheInternetbubble. Cooper,Dimitrov,andRau(2001)findthat147(generallysmall)firmschangedto“dotcom”names betweenJune1998andJuly1999,asInternetvaluationswererapidlyrising.CateringtoInternet sentimentdidseemtodeliverashort‐termpriceboost:Cooperetal.reportaremarkablylarge averageannouncementeffectof74%fortheirmainsample,andanevenlargereffectforthesubset thathadlittletrueinvolvementwiththeInternet. Interestingly,Cooperetal.(2005)documentthatnameswerelaterusedtodissociate companiesfromtheInternetsectorwhenpricescrashed.BetweenAugust2000andSeptember 2001,firmsthatdroppedtheirdotcomnamesawapositiveannouncementeffectofaround70%. TheeffectwasalmostaslargeforfirmsthatdroppedthedotcomnamebutkeptanInternet businessfocus,andforthedoubledipperswhichdroppedthenametheyhadnewlyadoptedjusta fewyearsearlier. Mutualfundcompaniesalsoappeartobeawareofthepowerthatnameshaveoninvestor demand.Cooper,Gulen,andRau(2005)findthatfundnamesshiftawayfromstylesthatexperience 47 lowreturnsandtowardthosewithhighreturns.Theauthorsfindthatnamechangesdonotpredict fundperformance,yetinflowsincreasedramatically,evenforcosmeticnamechangerswhose underlyinginvestmentstyleremainsconstant.Presumably,then,thenamechangedecisionis driveninpartbythedesiretoattractfundinflowsandthusincreasethefund’sfeeincome.Indeed, Cooperetal.findthattheinfloweffectincreaseswhenmoneyisspenttoadvertisethe“new”styles. 2.6.4. Nominal share prices Theaveragesharepricehascenteredaround$25sincetheDepression,asnotedbyDyland Elliott(2006)andWeld,Benartzi,Michaely,andThaler(2009).Thisisdespiteadramaticdeflation inthevalueofadollaroverthelastcentury.Inmarketsthatarerisingbecauseofinflationorreal growth,thisaverageismaintainedbysplits.Weldetal.arguethatstandardexplanationsbasedon signalingoroptimaltradingranges,whicharemostnaturallythoughtofinrealnotnominalterms, areunabletoexplaintheconstancyofnominalprices,andseveralotherrelatedfactsaboutactive sharepricemanagement.Forexample,bothIPOpricesandthesharepricesofopen‐endmutual fundshavealsoremainedrelativelyconstant.Theyproposeinsteadthatmanagersaresimply followingnorms,adheringtoanarbitraryhistoricalconventionfromwhichthereisnoparticular reasontodeviategiveninvestorexpectations. Weldetal.studythestabilityofstockpricesrelativetothebenchmarkofnoprice management.Pricesarenotmanagedcontinuously,ofcourse—onaverageandforindividual stocks,pricesarequitevariablerelativetotheotherextremebenchmarkofaconstantnominal price.Baker,Greenwood,andWurgler(2009)studynotthestationarityofaveragenominalprices butwhytheyvarybyafactoroftwoormoreovertime. Bakeretal.proposethatsharepricesareusedasanothertooltocatertotime‐varying shareholdersentiment.Inanalogytothedividendpremium,theyforma“low‐pricepremium”as theaveragemarket‐to‐bookratioofstockswhosepricesfallinthebottomthreedecilesminusthe 48 averageofthosewithpricesinthetopthreedeciles.Theyfindthatwhenexistinglow‐pricefirms havehighvaluations,morefirmssplit,andthosesplitterssplittolowerprices.IPOsalsomakefora powerfultest,astheyarefreetolistatalmostanyprice.Consistentwithcatering,IPOs’average pricesvarycloselywiththelow‐pricepremium. Thisleavesaquestionofinterpretation.Onederivesfromthestrongcross‐sectional relationshipbetweenfirmcapitalizationandnominalprice.Ifshareholderstakepriceasshorthand forsizeorgrowthpotential,firmsmaysplitinorderto“actsmall”whenstocksthataresmallare especiallyhighlyvalued.Theycannotchangecapitalization,buttheycanchangeshareprice. 2.6.5. Executive compensation Intheframeworkatthebeginningofthissection,weassumedthatmanagershavethe incentivetocatertoshort‐termmispricing.Onequestioniswhyshareholdersdonotsetup executivecompensationcontractstoforcemanagerstotakethelongview.25Bolton,Scheinkman, andXiong(2005)suggestthatshorthorizonsmaybeanequilibriumoutcome.Theystudythe optimalincentivecompensationcontractforthedynamicspeculativemarketofScheinkmanand Xiong(2003),inwhichtwogroupsofoverconfidentinvestorstradesharesbackandforthastheir relativeoptimismfluctuates.Thesharepriceinthismarketcontainsaspeculativeoption component,reflectingthepossibilitythatnonholdersmightsuddenlybecomewillingtobuyata highprice.Boltonetal.findthattheoptimalcontractmayinducetheCEOtotakecostlyactionsthat exacerbatedifferencesofopinion,thusincreasingthevalueoftheoptioncomponentofstockprices, attheexpenseoflong‐runvalue. 25Aseparatebutrelatedquestionishowmanagerscompensatelower‐levelemployees.BergmanandJenter (2007)arguethatrationalmanagersmayminimizecostsbypayingoptimisticemployeesinovervalued equity,intheformofoptionsgrants.Benartzi(2001)offersafoundationforthissortofoptimism,showing thatemployeeshaveatendencytoextrapolatepastreturns,andasaconsequenceholdtoomuchcompany stock.SeealsoCoreandGuay(2001)andOyerandSchaefer(2005). 49 3. Managerial Biases Asecondstrandofbehavioralcorporatefinancestudiesthebehaviorofirrationalmanagers operatinginefficientcapitalmarkets.Byirrationalmanagerialbehaviorwemeanbehaviorthat departsfromrationalexpectationsandexpectedutilitymaximizationofthemanager.Wearenot interestedinrationalmoralhazardbehavior,suchasempirebuilding,stealing,orplainslackingoff. Weareconcernedwithsituationswherethemanagerbelievesthatheisactuallycloseto maximizingfirmvalue—and,intheprocess,somecompensationscheme—butisinfactdeviating fromthisideal.26Webeginwithaquickoverviewoftherelevantpsychology,thendevelopasimple theoreticalframework,andfollowwithareviewofthisliterature. 3.1. Background on managerial behavior Thepsychologyandeconomicsliteraturesrelevanttounderstandingmanagerialbehavior arevast.Forus,themainthemesarethatindividualsdonotalwaysformbeliefslogically,nordo theyconvertagivensetofbeliefsintodecisionsinaconsistentandrationalmanner.Theserecall thedefinitionsofinvestorsentimentandirrationalbehaviorthatareassumedinmarkettimingand cateringstudies.Followinganoteaboutcorporategovernance,weintroduceandmotivatethe biasesandnonstandardpreferencesthathavebeeninvestigatedinthecontextofmanagerial decisions. 3.1.1. Limited governance Forless‐than‐fully‐rationalmanagerstohaveanimpact,corporategovernancemustbe limitedinitsabilitytoconstrainthemintomakingrationaldecisions.Thisisanalogoustothe requirementoflimitedarbitrageforthemarkettimingapproach. 26Ourfocusisoncorporatefinance.CamererandMalmendier(2009)discusstheimpactoflessthanfully rationalbehavioronotherpartsoforganizations. 50 Assuminglimitedgovernanceisnolessreasonablethanassuminglimitedarbitrage.Indeed, intheUS,asignificantelementofmanagerialdiscretioniscodifiedinthebusinessjudgmentrule. Takeoverbattlesandproxyfightsarenotoriouslyblunttools.Boardsmaybemoreapartofthe problemthanthesolutioniftheyhavetheirownbiasesorarepawnsofmanagement.Forinstance, Gompers,Ishii,andMetrick(2003)findthatfirmsthatelectedpoliciestodiminishshareholder rightsexperiencelowerstockreturns.Andunlikeinatraditionalagencyproblem,whicharisesout ofaconflictofinterestbetweenmanagersandoutsideinvestors,standardincentivecontractshave littleeffect,becauseanirrationalmanagermaywellthinkthatheismaximizingvalue. Itisobviousfromcasualobservationthattopmanagers“matter,”inthattheyhavethe powertomakedecisionsthataffectinvestmentandfinancingpolicyandfirmvalue.Thereisalso systematicevidence.BertrandandSchoar(2003)findthatindividualmanagershaveinvestment andfinancingstylesandpreferences,possiblyinherentandpossiblybasedonbeliefsshapedby beliefs,thattheybringfromprevioustonewemployers.Forexample,CEOsthatusebigger mortgagesfortheirownhomepurchasesalsousemoreleverageintheirfirms(Cronqvist,Makhija, andYonker(2011)),althoughpartofthiseffectcanbeattributedtoendogenousfirm‐manager matching.Kaplan,Klebanov,andSorensen(2011)findthatcertainexecutiveabilitycharacteristics arecorrelatedwithfirmperformance.Asonemightexpect,theexpressionofindividualmanagerial decisionsisstrongerwhentheCEOispowerfulor,similarly,whengovernanceisweaker(Adams, Almeida,andFerreira(2005)andCronqvistetal.). 3.1.2. Bounded rationality Perhapsthesimplestdeviationfromthebenchmarkoffullrationalitygoesbythenameof boundedrationality,introducedbySimon(1955).Boundedrationalityassumesthatsometypeof cognitiveorinformation‐gatheringcostpreventsagentsfrommakingfullyoptimaldecisions. Boundedly‐rationalmanagerscopewithcomplexitybyusingrulesofthumbthatensurean 51 acceptablelevelofperformanceand,hopefully,avoidseverebias.Conlisk(1996)reviewstheolder boundedrationalityliterature;seeGabaix(2011)foramorerecentmodelingapproach.Bounded rationalityoffersareasonablycompellingmotivationforthefinancialrulesofthumbthatmanagers commonlyuse.Wenotesomeoftheseandconsiderthedistortionsthattheycreate. 3.1.3. Optimism, overconfidence and hubris Mostresearchinthemanagerialbiasesliteraturehasfocusedontheillusionsofoptimism andoverconfidence.Illustratingoptimism,Weinstein(1980)findsthatsubjectsbelievethemselves morelikelythanaveragetoexperiencepositivefuturelifeevents(e.g.owningownhome,living past80)andlesslikelytoexperiencenegativeevents(beingfired,gettingcancer).Illustrating overconfidenceinone’sownskills,andpossiblyoptimismaswell,Svenson(1981)findsthat82% ofasampleofstudentsplacedthemselvesamongthetop30%safestdrivers. Therearegoodreasonstofocusontheseparticularbiasesinamanagerialsetting.First, theyarestrongandrobust,havingbeendocumentedinmanysamples,includingsamplesofactual managers(LarwoodandWhittaker(1977),MarchandShapira(1987),andBen‐David,Graham,and Harvey(2010)).Second,managerialdecisionstendtobehighlycomplex,asettingwhere overconfidenceismostpronounced,andidiosyncratic,whichreducesthepotentialfordebiasing throughlearning(Gervais(2010)).Third,thesebiasesarealsooftenfairlyeasytointegrateinto existingmodels.Optimismisusuallymodeledasanoverestimateofameanabilityoroutcomeand overconfidenceasanunderestimateofavariance.Inthisfashionwemodeltheconsequencesof optimism,below,andalsonotesituationsinwhichanalternativeassumptionofoverconfidence couldleadtodifferentconclusions. Finally,overconfidencealsoleadsnaturallytomorerisk‐taking.Evenifthereisno overconfidenceonaverageinthepopulationofpotentialmanagers,thosethatareoverconfident aremorelikelytoperformextremelywell(andextremelybadly),placingthemdisproportionately 52 intheranksofupper(andformer)management.Andevenifanindividualmanagerisbornwithout bias,anattributionbias—thetendencytotakegreaterresponsibilityforsuccessthanfailure(e.g., LangerandRoth(1975))—mayleadsuccessfulmanagerstobecomeoverconfident,asmodeledin GervaisandOdean(2001). 3.1.4. More on reference dependence Referencepointsandanchoringareequallycompellingpsychologicalfoundations,when comparedtooverconfidence,andoffersomeempiricaladvantagesinidentifyingbehavioraleffects incorporatefinance.Section2.1describesthepsychologicalunderpinningsofreferencepointsand anchoring.Theseholdspecialinterestwithinafirm.Afirmiscollectionofimplicitandexplicit contractsbetweenmanagersandemployees,thefirmanditscustomers,creditors,underwriters, shareholders,andotherstakeholders.Itisnaturaltothinkoftheseasformingreferencepointsin negotiations,anddeterminingexpostthesatisfactionofthevariousparties.Forexample,whether themanagementissatisfiedwiththeperformanceofitsunderwritersdependsontheir performancerelativetoareferenceprice.Whethershareholdersaresatisfiedwithamergeroffer dependsonthepricerelativetorecenttransactionprices;wewillseespecificevidenceofthislater. Hart(2008)usesreferencepointsmorebroadlyastheunderpinningforatheoryofthe firm.Usingcontractsasreferencepointstowhichpartiesfeelentitledisasubstituteforthe assumptionsofincompletecontractsandexpostbargainingoverthesurplusthatdrivetheresults inGrossmanandHart(1986)andHartandMoore(1990).Becausewedonotobservethissortof bargainingwithinrealfirms,thereferencepointapproachmayoutlivetheexistingarchitectureof thepropertyrightstheoryofthefirm.Sofar,however,muchoftheempiricalevidenceisfocusedon narrowerapplicationsofreferencepointpreferences. 53 Forthemoment,weuseoverconfidence,insteadofreferencepoints,asanexampleofan organizingframeworkinthenextsection.Thesectiononbehavioralsignalingattheendofthe surveywilldevelopamodelusingreferencepoints. 3.2. Theoretical framework ThederivationbelowisinthespiritofHeaton(2002)andMalmendierandTate(2005), modifiedtomatchthenotationinthemarkettimingandcateringmodelasmuchaspossible.We assumethemanagerisoptimisticaboutthevalueofthefirm’sassetsandinvestmentopportunities. Hebalancestwoconflictinggoals.Thefirstistomaximizeperceivedfundamentalvalue.Tocapture this,weaugmentfundamentalvaluewithanoptimismparameter, 1 f K , K , wherefisincreasingandconcaveinnewinvestmentK.Notethathere,themanagerisoptimistic aboutboththeassetsinplace(fcanincludeaconstantterm)andnewopportunities.Onceagain,if traditionalmarketimperfectionscausetheModiglianiandMiller(1958)theoremtofail,financing mayenterfalongsideinvestment. Themanager’ssecondconcernistominimizetheperceivedcostofcapital.Weassumehere thatthemanageractsonbehalfofexistinginvestors,becauseofhisownstakeinthefirmand fiduciaryduty.ThisleadstoasimilarsetuptothemarkettimingobjectiveinSection2.2,exceptthat anoptimisticmanagerneverbelievesthereisagoodtimetoissueequity.Inparticular,sincethe capitalmarketisefficientandvaluesthefirmatitstruefundamentalvalueoff‐K,themanager believesthatthefirmisundervaluedbyf,andthusinsellingafractionofthefirmeheperceives thatexisting,long‐runshareholderswilllose ef K , . 54 Puttingthetwoconcernstogether,theoptimisticmanagerchoosesnewinvestmentand financingtosolve max1 f K , K ef K , . K ,e Wedonotexplicitlyincludeabudgetconstraint.Instead,againtokeepthenotationsimple,we consideritsreduced‐formimpactonf. DifferentiatingwithrespecttoKandegivestheoptimalinvestmentandfinancialpolicyof anoptimisticmanageroperatinginefficientcapitalmarkets: f K K , 1 ,and 1 1 e 1 f e K , f K , ef e K , . Thefirstconditionisaboutinvestmentpolicy.Insteadofsettingthemarginalvaluecreated frominvestmentequaltothetruecostofcapital,normalizedtobeonehere,managersoverinvest, tothepointwherethemarginalvaluecreationislessthanone.Themoreoptimistic()isthe managerandthelessequity(e)heisforcedtoraiseinfinancinginvestment,thegreaterthe problem.Totheextentthatthemanagerhastoraisecapitalbyissuingequity,thecostofcapitalis scaledupbythesamefactorasthemanager’sover‐optimismscalesupthemarginalproductof capital,soraisingequityoffsetsthedistortionininvestmentcausedbyover‐optimism.If100%of thecapitalisraisedbyissuingequity,forexample,investmentisfirst‐best.Thesecondconditionis aboutfinancing.Themarginalvaluelostfromshiftingthefirm’scurrentcapitalstructureaway fromequityisweighedagainsttheperceivedmarkettiminglosses.Asintheanalysisofirrational investors,weconsidersomespecialcases. 55 Investmentpolicy.Ifthereisnooptimalcapitalstructure,sothatfeisequaltozero,the managerwillnotissueequity,settingetozero,andthereisnointeractionamongfinancing, internalfunds,andinvestment.Inthiscase,theoptimisticmanagerwillclearlyoverinvest:fKisless thanunity.InHeaton(2002)andMalmendierandTate(2005),thereisanoptimalcapitalstructure, ormorepreciselyanupperboundondebt.Ifthemanagerneedsequitytoinvest(here,fegreater thanzero),thedegreeofoverinvestmentfalls. Needingequityisakintohavinglittlecashorcashflowavailableforinvestment.Thusin thissetup,investmentcanbestronglyrelatedtocurrentcashflowandprofits,controllingfor investmentopportunities.ThisleadstoabehavioralfoundationfortheJensen(1986)agencycosts offreecashflow.Butinsteadofreceivingprivatebenefitsofcontrol,managersaresimply optimisticandoverinvestfromcurrentresourcesasaresult.Leveragereducesthedegreeof overinvestmentbyincreasingfe,therebyincreasingequityissueseandreducingK. Inamorecomplexspecification,theseconclusionsmaychange.Onemighthavethe manageroptimisticonlyaboutassetsinplace,inwhichcasethereisnooverinvestment,andthere willtypicallybeunderinvestmentasafirmapproachesitsdebtcapacity.Also,itisworth emphasizingthatweareexaminingoptimisminisolationhere.Layeringonotherimperfections, suchasriskaversion,maymeanthatoptimismmovesinvestmentfromaninefficientlylowlevel towardthefirstbest,asinGervais,Heaton,andOdean(2010)andGoelandThakor(2002).Wewill revisitsomeoftheseinteractionswhenwediscussexecutivecompensation.Hackbarth(2009) discussesanothersettinginwhichmultiplebiasescanworkinopposition,arguingthatthe combinationofmanagerialoptimismandoverconfidencecanreducetheunderinvestmentdueto debtoverhang(Myers(1977)). Financialpolicy.Anoptimisticmanagerneversellsequityunlesshehasto.Ifthereisan upperboundonleverage(fegreaterthanzero,here),optimismpredictsapeckingorderof 56 financingdecisions:Themanagerreliesoninternalcapitalanddebtandusesoutsideequityonlyas alastresort.Again,otherimperfectionsmaymitigatetheaversiontoequity.Ifthemanagerisrisk aversewithanundiversifiedpositioninthefirm’sequity,forexample,hemaywishtoissueequity eventhoughitisbelowwhathethinksittobeworth. Managerialoverconfidencecanhavedifferenteffectsoncapitalstructurethanoptimism, Hackbarth(2009)argues.Ifoverconfidenceismodeledasunderestimatingtheriskofearnings, managersmayviewtheirdebtasundervaluedandtooexpensiveasasourceofcapital.The convexityofequity,ontheotherhand,leadsmanagerstoviewtheirequityasovervalued.This reversesthepeckingorderthatobtainsunderoptimism.Sufficetosaythattheoreticalpredictions abouttheeffectofoptimismandoverconfidenceoncapitalstructurearesomewhatsensitivetothe modelingframework. Othercorporatedecisions.Itisnotaseasytoincorporateotherdecisionsintothis framework.Considerdividendpolicy.Ifthemanagerismoreoptimisticaboutfuturecashflowand assetsinplacethanoutsideinvestors,hemightviewadividendpaymentasmoresustainable.On theotherhand,ifheviewsfutureinvestmentopportunities,andhencefundingrequirements,as greater,hemightbereluctanttoinitiateorincreasedividendsandretaininternalfundsinstead. Thisanalysisrequiresamoredynamicmodelofinvestmentandcashflowandadecompositionof firmvalueintoassetsinplaceandgrowthopportunities. 3.3. Empirical challenges Ifthemainobstacletotestingtheirrationalinvestorsapproachisfindingaproxyfor misvaluation,thechallengehereistoidentifyoptimism,overconfidence,orthebehavioralbiasof interest.Withoutanempiricalmeasure,theirrationalmanagersapproachistypicallydifficultto distinguishfromstandardagencytheory.Thatis,inStein(2003),anempire‐buildingmanagerwill 57 max1 f K K ce , K ,e wherereflectsthepreferenceforortheprivatebenefitsthatcomewithpresidingoveralarger firm,asinJensenandMeckling(1976)orGrossmanandHart(1988),ratherthanoptimism. Rationalinvestorsrecognizetheagencyproblemupfront,socreflectsthecostofraisingoutside equity,andmanagementandexistingshareholdersbeartheagencycosts. Thisreducedformisalmostidenticaltotheobjectivefunctionofanoptimisticmanager. Bothcangenerateoverinvestment,underinvestment,cashflow‐investmentsensitivities,pecking orderfinancing,andsoforth.Moreover,Steinpointsoutthattheagencymodelisitselfhardto distinguishfrommodelsofcostlyexternalfinancebuiltonasymmetricinformation.Thus,totest thebehavioraltheories,onemustseparatetherelatedtooverconfidenceandoptimismfromthe thatarisesfromagencyorasymmetricinformationproblems. 3.4. Investment policy Despitethedifficultyofobtainingdirect,manager‐levelmeasuresofoptimismand overconfidence,evidenceisaccumulatingthatthesebiasesdoaffectbusinessinvestment. 3.4.1. Real investment Theevidencedoessuggestthatentrepreneurialstartupsareoftenmadeunderahaloof overconfidenceandoptimism.Cooper,Woo,andDunkelberg(1998)findthat68%of entrepreneursthinkthattheirstartupismorelikelytosucceedthancomparableenterprises,while only5%believethattheiroddsareworse,andathirdofentrepreneursviewtheirsuccessasallbut guaranteed.ThesurveyofFrenchentrepreneursbyLandierandThesmar(2009)givesthesame message:Atstartup,56%expect“development”inthenearfuturewhileonly6%expect“difficulty.” 58 Theactualperformanceofstartupinvestmentsismoresobering.LandierandThesmarfind thatwhensurveyedthreeyearsintotheirendeavor,only38%ofFrenchentrepreneursexpect further“development”while17%anticipate“difficulty.”Leavingprofitabilityasideentirely,only halfofallstartupssurvivemorethanthreeyears(Scarpetta,Hemmings,Tressel,andWoo(2002)). MoskowitzandVissing‐Jorgensen(2002)arguemoregenerallythatthereturnonprivateequityin theUSbetween1952and1999islowerthanseemsjustifiedgiventheundiversifiednatureof entrepreneurialinvestment.Asawhole,theevidenceonstartupinvestmentsseemsconsistentwith theoverconfidencethatCamererandLovallo’s(1999)experimentalsubjectsdisplaywhenmaking entrydecisions. Optimismalsomayinfluenceinvestmentinmorematurefirms.Merrow,Phillips,andMyers (1981)compareforecastandactualconstructioncostsforpioneerprocessplantsintheenergy industry.Thereisastrongoptimismbiasinprojectcostforecasts,withactualcoststypicallymore thandoubletheinitialestimates.StatmanandTyebjee(1985)surveyseveralotherstudiesofthis sort,involvingmilitaryhardware,drugs,chemicals,andotherdevelopmentprojects,andconclude thatoptimisticbiasesincostandsalesforecastsarefairlywidespread. MalmendierandTate(2005)performcross‐sectionaltestsoftheeffectsofoptimismon investment.Theyformamanager‐levelproxyforoptimismbasedonthepropensityforamanager tovoluntarilyholdin‐the‐moneystockoptionsinhisownfirm.Theirintuitionisthatsincethe CEO’shumancapitalisalreadysoexposedtofirm‐specificrisk,voluntarilyholdingin‐the‐money optionsisastrongvoteofoptimism.27UsingthisoptimismproxyforalargesampleofUSfirms 27MalmendierandTatefindthatthepropensitytovoluntarilyretainin‐the‐moneyoptionsisnotsignificantly relatedtofutureabnormalstockreturns,supportingtheirassumptionthatsuchbehaviorindeedreflects optimismratherthangenuineinsideinformation.SenandTumarkin(2010)modeltheCEO’sportfoliochoice andoptionexerciseprobleminmoredetailandarguethatamorerobustmeasureofoptimismissimply whethertheCEOsellsorretainsthesharesreceiveduponexercise.SeeGiderandHackbarth(2010)foran overviewofoptimismandoverconfidenceproxies. 59 between1980and1994,MalmendierandTatefindthatthesensitivityofinvestmenttocashflowis higherforthemoreoptimisticCEOs.ItisespeciallyhighforoptimisticCEOsinequity‐dependent firms,thatis,insituationswhereperceivedfinancialconstraintsaremostbinding.Theirresults supportthepredictionsofthebasicoptimismmodel. Ben‐David,Graham,andHarvey(2010)testwhethersurvey‐basedmeasuresof overconfidenceandoptimismhelptoexplainthelevelofinvestmentasopposedtoitssensitivityto cashflow.Theyaskfinancialexecutivestoestimatethemeanandvarianceoftheirfirm’sstock return.Thisallowsthemtoformseparateoptimismandoverconfidencemeasures.Astrikingresult isthatfinancialexecutivesare,indeed,extremelyoverconfident:theirsubjective80%confidence intervalsaboutthefirm’sone‐yearstockreturncontainstherealizedreturnonly33%ofthetime. Theyalsoconnectthesemeasurestothelevelofinvestment,andfindthatbothoptimismand overconfidenceareassociatedwithhigherinvestment. Onecategoryofinvestmentthatwouldseemparticularlyinvitingtooverconfident managersisresearchanddevelopment,wherethepayoffisinherentlyquiteuncertain.Hirshleifer, Low,andTeoh(2010)findthatoverconfidentmanagers—measuredusingoptions‐basedproxies, asabove,andthecharacterofdescriptionsoftheCEOinthepress,similartoMalmendierandTate (2004)—investmoreinR&Dandtranslatethistohigherpatentandpatentcitationcount.Atthe sametime,thereislittlerelationshipbetweentheiroverconfidencemeasuresandfinancialorstock marketperformance. Inadditiontotheevidenceabove,keepinmindthatoptimism,asdiscussedearlier,shares manypredictionswithmoreestablishedtheories,andthusisacandidatetoexplainvariousearlier results.Forexample,thefactthatmanagersinvestratherthanpayoutcashwindfalls(Blanchard, LopezdeSilanes,andShleifer(1994))lookslikeamoralhazardproblem,butisalsoconsistentwith optimism.Likewise,someinvestmentpatternsthatlooklikeadverse‐selection‐drivencostly 60 externalfinancemaysimplyreflectamistakenmanagerialbeliefthatexternalfinanceiscostlier.A possibleexampleisthehigherinvestment‐cashflowsensitivitiesofyoungerentrepreneurialfirms (Schaller(1993)),whichasnotedaboveappeartoberunbyespecialoptimists. Movingawayfromoptimismandoverconfidence,a“bias”ofboundedrationalityappearsto beaplausibleexplanationforsomecommoncapitalbudgetingcriteria.Forexample,whilethenet presentvaluecriterionistheoptimalcapitalbudgetingrule(inefficientmarkets),realmanagers tendtoemploysimplerrules.Surveyingpracticeinthe1970s,GitmanandForrester(1977)find thatlessthan10%of103largefirmsuseNPVastheirprimarytechnique,whileover50%usethe IRRrule,whichavoidsacostofcapitalcalculation.TheGrahamandHarvey(2001)surveyofCFOs alsofindsthattheIRRruleismorewidelyusedthanNPV.Over50%ofCFOsactuallyusethe paybackperiodrule,anevenlesssophisticatedrulethatrequiresneitheracostofcapitalinputnor cashflowforecastsbeyondacutoffdate. GrahamandHarveyalsofindthatamongmanagerswhodouseadiscountingprocedure tendtoapplyafirm‐widediscountrateratherthanaproject‐specificrate,againincontrastto normativeprinciples.28Kruger,Landier,andThesmar(2011)suggestthatthispracticeintroduces significantinvestmentdistortions.Takingtheproject‐specificCapitalAssetPricingModelasa normativebenchmark,Krugeretal.pointoutthatmultidivisionfirmsthatsimplyapplyaweighted‐ averagediscountratetoallprojectswilloverinvestinhighbetadivisionsandunderinvestinlow betadivisions.Consistentwiththisprediction,theydocumentthatdivision‐levelinvestmentis positivelyrelatedtothespreadbetweenthedivision’smarketbetaandthefirm’saveragebeta. 28Agoodquestioniswhethertheuseofsuchrulesisbetterunderstoodasanagencyproblemthanas boundedrationality.Thatis,executivesmightusesimplerulestoshortentheworkdayandsavetimeforgolf. However,GrahamandHarveyfindthathigh‐ownershipmanagersareifanythinglesslikelytouseNPVand morelikelytousethepaybackperiodrule. 61 Lossaversionhasalsoappearedasanexplanationforcertaininvestmentpatterns,suchas inthewidelyasserted,butlessdocumented,managerialpropensityto“throwgoodmoneyafter bad.”Suchbehaviorismostrelevantforustotheextentthatitreflectssomethingmorethan rationalcareerconcerns,e.g.asituationwherethemanagertriestodistorttheupdatingprocessto maintainhighcompensation.Shefrin(2001)offersseveralanecdotesconcerningmajorcorporate investmentsthathavetheflavorofgoodmoneyafterbad.StatmanandSepe(1989)findthatthe marketreactiontotheterminationofhistoricallyunprofitableinvestmentprojectsispositive, suggestingthatinvestorsrecognizethatexecutiveshaveatendencytocontinuepoorprojects. RelatedevidencecomesfromtheGuedjandScharfstein(2008)studyofdrugdevelopment decisions.Theyfindthatsingle‐productearlystagefirmsappearhighlyreluctanttoabandontheir onlyviabledrugcandidates,evenwhentheresultsofclinicaltrialsarelessthanpromising.Some combinationofagency,managerialoptimism,andagambling‐to‐get‐back‐to‐evenattitudeseems likeaplausibleexplanationfortheseresults. 3.4.2. Mergers and acquisitions Inaseminalcontributiontobehavioralcorporatefinance,Roll(1986)outlinesahubris‐ basedtheoryofacquisitions.Hesuggeststhatsuccessfulacquirersmaybeoptimisticand overconfidentintheirownvaluationofdealsynergies,andfailtoproperlyaccountforthewinner’s curse.Rollinterpretstheevidenceonmergerannouncementeffects,surveyedbyJensenand Ruback(1983),Andrade,Mitchell,andStafford(2001),andMoeller,SchlingemannandStulz (2005),aswellasthelackofevidenceoffundamentalvaluecreationthroughmergers,asconsistent withthistheory. MalmendierandTate(2004)developthisargumentandusetheiroptions‐basedproxyfor CEOoptimismtotestit.Theyfindpatternsconsistentwithoptimismandoverconfidence.First, optimisticCEOscompletemoremergers,especiallydiversifyingmergers,typicallysuggestedas 62 beingofdubiousvalue.Second,optimismhasitsbiggesteffectamongtheleastequitydependent firms—whenmanagersdonothavetoweighthemergeragainstanequityissuethatthey,as optimists,wouldperceiveasundervalued.Third,investorsaremoreskepticalaboutbid announcementswhentheyaremadebyoptimisticCEOs.SchneiderandSpalt(2010)findsimilar results,includingthatofferpricesarehigher,butacquirerannouncementreturnsarelower,when thetargethas(had)skewedreturns.Theannouncementreturnsevidenceisconsistentwiththe themeofirrationalmanagersoperatinginefficientmarkets.29 ManagerialbiasesresearchhastakenaFreudianturnwithAktas,deBodt,Bollaert,and Roll’s(2010)studyofCEOnarcissism.Theymeasurenarcissism,atraitrelatedtobutdistinctfrom overconfidence,astheratiooffirstpersonsingularpronounstototalfirstpersonpronounsusedin CEOs’transcribedspeeches.Thusly‐definednarcissistCEOsaremorelikelytobeacquirers,and morelikelytohaveinitiatedtheirtransactions.Thisisinterpretedasconsistentwiththehigh‐ stakesactivityrequiredtomaintainthenarcissisticego.Targetsrunbynarcissists,meanwhile, securehigherbidpremia.Aktasetal.speculatethatthisarisesbecausenarcissisticCEOsdemand extracompensationforthelossofegoassociatedwithlosingcontrol. Ifmanagerialbiasesaffectdecisionsbecausegovernanceislimited,cross‐sectionalvariation ingovernancemaybeusefulforidentifyingtheeffect.Yermack(1996)findsthatfirmswithsmaller boardsofdirectorshavehigherfirmvalue;KolasinskiandLi(2010)findthatsmallboards dominatedbyindependentdirectorsreducetheimpactofCEOoverconfidenceonacquisition frequency.TheyusenegativefuturereturnsonCEOpurchasesasexpostevidenceofexante overconfidence. 29Formoreanecdotalevidenceontheroleofhubrisintakeovers,seeHietala,Kaplan,andRobinson(2003) andShefrin(2000,chapter16). 63 Tobeusefulinempiricalwork,thesegovernancemechanismsneedtobeexogenous. Unfortunately,asHermalinandWeisbach(2003)andHarrisandRaviv(2008)pointout,theseare typicallyendogenoustofirmperformance.Nonetheless,thepredictionsherearetypically concerningcoefficientsoninteractionterms,sotheendogeneityproblemcouldbemitigated. Referencepointthinking,inparticularinvolvingtheofferprice,alsoplaysaroleinmerger activity.Anoffermustbemadeatapremiumtothetarget’scurrentprice,andthemostsalientand specificsuchpricesarerecentpeaks,suchasthetarget’s52‐weekhigh.Thereareanumberofways suchsalientbuteconomicallyunremarkablepricescouldenterthepsychologyofmerger negotiations.Valuingacompanyisasubjectivetask,andvaluingacombinationisdoublyso.One couldeasilyimaginethatrecentpeakpricesserveasanchorsinsuchcalculationsonboththe bidderandthetargetside.Thetargetmayusepeakpricesasastartingpointfornegotiations.Or, targetshareholdersmayresistsellingata“loss”toarecentpeak,akintoadispositioneffect.30 Baker,Pan,andWurgler(2011)findthatdealparticipantsdoindeedfocusonrecentprice peaks.Thereisaspikeinthedistributionofofferpricesatthetarget’s52‐weekhighandother historicalpeaks.Bidding‐firmshareholdersreactnegativelytothecomponentoftheofferpricethat isdrivenbythe52‐weekhigh,whichsuggeststhattheyrationallyviewthisportionas overpayment.Theprobabilitythatanoffergoesthroughincreasesdiscontinuouslywhentheoffer exceedsthe52‐weekhigh.Thisisanimportantresultinthatitrepresentsunusuallycleanevidence oftherealeffectsofbehavioralcorporatefinance. Finally,Bakeretal.findthatreferencepointthinkingmayhelptoexplainwhymergersand stockmarketvaluationsarepositivelycorrelated:theofferpremiumrequiredtoexceedarecent pricepeakissmallerwhenvaluationshaveincreased.Conversely,whenvaluationshave 30Notethatwhilesomeoftheseeffectsinvolvemanagerialbiases,othersrepresentinvestorbiasesandthus theevidencebelowcouldalsobeincludedinourearliersectionsaboutinvestorirrationality. 64 plummeted,targetsmayfailtoadjustfrompriorpeakanchorsand,asaresult,askforvaluations thataresimplyimplausibletobidders. 3.5. Financial policy Thereisagrowingbodyofevidencethatmanagerialbiasesaffectfinancingpatterns. Existingworkaddressesthetimingandpricingofequityissues,featuresofIPOs,capitalstructure anddividendpolicy,andfinancialcontracting.Referencedependenceplaysaprominentrolein thesestudies. 3.5.1. Equity issues DoestheCEOdriveafirm’sstockreturns?Ifso,thenaCEOwouldrightlybeproud,and shareholdersshouldtakenotice,whenshehascreatedvalueandraisedthesharepriceabovethe levelthatprevailedwhenshetookthehelm.Ifnot,forexampleifsharepricesaredominatedby aggregatemoves,thenthathistoricalpricedoesnotserveasaparticularlymeaningfulreference pointforCEO‐specificvaluecreation. BakerandXuan(2011)findevidencethatCEO‐specificsharepriceperformancedoes indeedaffectfinancingactivity.Equityissuanceisresponsivetorecentstockreturns,but considerablymoresowhentheyoccurduringthecurrentCEO’stenure.Inparticular,the probabilityofequityissuanceinafollow‐onofferingincreasesdiscontinuouslywhentheshare priceexceedstheinheritedprice. Apparently,somemarketparticipantsinvolvedinequityissuanceattribute“valuecreation” totheCEOandherteam.Tobeclear,thisbyitselfisnotnecessarilyabehavioralphenomenon;the intriguingresultistheeffectoftheinheritedsharepriceleveleventhoughsubsequentmarket‐level movementsbeyondtheCEO’scontrolcomplicatetheattributionofvaluecreation.Theattribution errorcouldbeontheinvestorside,withmanagementhavingtowaituntilthispointinorderto 65 convinceinvestorsthatissuetermswereappealing.Insteadofthateffect,orinadditiontoit,the managementteammayviewcrossingtheinheritedpricethresholdasanopportunitytotimethe equitymarket. 3.5.2. IPO prices IPOunderpricingcanalsobeunderstoodfromtheperspectiveofreference‐point managerialpreferences.LoughranandRitter(2002)developanexplanationthatcombines reference‐pointpreferencesandmentalaccounting(Thaler(1980,1985)).Animportantfacetof IPOpricingisthattheinvestmentbankersunderwritingtheofferingformaninitialfilepricerange, astheyshopthedealtoinstitutionalinvestors.Ifdemandforthenewsharesishigh,thebankers willpricetheofferingatthehighendofthisrange.Ifitislow,theywillpricetheofferingatthe midpoint,orsometimeslower.Onthefirstday,pricesareamarketoutcomeofthenewsupplyand demand. LoughranandRitterassumethatissuingmanagersmentallyaccountfortwoquantitiesin judginganoffering’ssuccess:the(perceived)gainfromthegapbetweenthefirstdayclosingprice andanaturalreferencepoint,themidpointofthefilepricerange;andthe(real)lossfromthe dilutiveeffectoftheunderpricing.Ifthegainisjudgedtooutweightheloss,whereeachisevaluated separatelywiththeprospecttheoryvaluefunction,theexecutivesaresatisfied.Intuitively,they maybetoooverwhelmedbythe“windfallgain”tocomplainmuchaboutunderpricing.31 Thissetupisdesigned,inpart,toexplainthepatternthatunderpricingisgreaterwhenthe offerpriceisabovetheinitialfilepricerange.LoughranandRitter(2002)findthatinissueswhere theofferpriceisbelowtheminimumofthefilepricerange,first‐dayreturnsarearelativelysmall 31LoughranandRitterassumethattheunderwriterprefersunderpricing,perhapsbecauseitgenerates profitablerent‐seekingactivitiesamonginvestors,e.g.tradingwiththeunderwriter’sbrokeragearm,or becauseitreducesmarketingcosts. 66 4%,onaverage,whilethosepricedabovethemaximumhaveaveragefirst‐dayreturnsof32%.This isconsistentwithissuersacquiescinginsevereunderpricingonlywhentheyaresimultaneously gettinggoodnewsintheformofupwardrevisionsfromthefilingrange.32 LjungqvistandWilhelm(2005)testsomeofthebehavioralunderpinningsoftheLoughran andRitterview.UsingdataontheownershipstakesofexecutivesinIPOfirms,theycrudelyproxy fortheproposednotionofissuersatisfactionbytakingthedollaramountofexecutives’perceived “gain”fromrevisionsfromthemidpointofthefilepricerangeandsubtractingthedollaramountof dilutionduetounderpricing.Theyfindthatexecutiveteamsthataremore“satisfied”withtheir IPOsbythiscriterionaremorelikelytousethesameunderwriterforseasonedofferings,andto payhigherfeesforthosetransactions. 3.5.3. Raising debt Borrowersandlendersusepasttermsasanchorsorreferencepointsforcurrentterms. Dougal,Engelberg,Parsons,andVanWesep(2011)findthatthenominallevelofhistorical borrowingcostsexertsastronginfluenceonthetimetcostofdebt,controllingforavarietyoftime tborrowercharacteristics.Theeffectappearsforallcreditratingcategories.Forexample,firms thattookoutcreditfromabankingsyndicatebetween2005and2007sawtheinfluenceofthe 2008financialcrisishaveamutedimpactontheir2008borrowingcostsfromthesamesource.For firmswhosecreditratingremainedconstantoverthisperiod,one‐thirdreceivedexactlythesame borrowingratesasinthepre‐crisisperiod.Comparablefirmsthathadn’testablishedsuchanchor termssawhigherborrowingcosts. 32SeeBenvenisteandSpindt(1989)foranalternativeexplanationforthisasymmetrybasedoninformation gatheringinthebook‐buildingprocess,andEdelenandKadlec(2003)foronebasedonsampletruncation biasrelatedtothewithdrawlofIPOswhoseprospectsdeteriorateduringthewaitingperiod. 67 Itiseasytounderstandhowpriortermsarenaturalstartingpointsforthinkingaboutand negotiatingnewterms.Theneedforafixedstartingpointcouldbeparticularlyhighinperiodsof dramaticchangeinthefinancialenvironment.Dougaletal.findadditionalpatternsthatfurthertie theirresultstoanchoring:specificmanagersandbankersappeartoformrelationshipsthatare mostaffectedbythebias;whenafirmchangesleadbanks,theeffectofpasttermsdeteriorates; and,whenafirmchangesCEOorCFO,theeffectofpasttermsdeteriorates.33 Similartohowreferencepointpricesaffectmergeractivityormanager‐specificreference pointpricesonequityissues,thisexperimentprovidesfurtherevidencethathighlysophisticated actors—inthiscase,managers,bankers,andinvestorsjointly—areunableto“integrateout”the past.Futureresearchmaybetteridentifytherealeffectsofthis.Anaturalhypothesis,forexample, isthatborrowerswhoarebeingofferedadealbecauseofthehappenstanceoffavorablepastterms willraisemoreandinvestmore. 3.5.4. Capital structure Themostbasicoptimismmodelpredictsapeckingorderfinancingpolicy,aspointedoutby Heaton(2002).Thus,muchoftheexistingevidenceofpecking‐orderpolicies,fromDonaldson (1961)toFamaandFrench(2002),isatfacevalueequallyconsistentwithpervasivemanagerial optimism.Andthenotionofpervasivemanagerialoptimismdoesnotseemfarfetched.InGraham’s (1999)survey,almosttwo‐thirdsofCFOsstatetheirstockisundervaluedwhileonlythreepercent stateitisovervalued.Suchresponsesareallthemorestrikinggiventhatthesurveywastaken shortlybeforetheInternetcrash. Todistinguishoptimismfromotherexplanationsofpeckingorderbehavior,suchas adverseselectionasinMyersandMajluf(1984),anaturaltestwouldusecross‐sectionalvariation 33Theauthorsarguethatcostlyrenegotiationoftermscannotexplaintheseresults. 68 inmeasuredoptimismtoseewhethersuchbehaviorismoreprevalentinfirmsrunbyoptimists.To ourknowledge,exactlythistesthasnotbeenconducted,butcertainresultsinMalmendierandTate (2004,2005)havearelatedflavor.First,andasnotedabove,firmsrunbyoptimists(asidentified bytheiroptions‐basedproxiesforoptimism)displayahighersensitivityofinvestmenttointernal cashflow.Second,managersclassifiedasoptimisticshowadifferentiallyhigherpropensitytomake acquisitionswhentheyarenotdependentonexternalequity. Boundedrationalityalsomakesanappearanceinfinancialpolicyintheformoftheuseof simpletargetsforcapitalstructuresandpayouts.GrahamandHarvey(2001)findthat10%ofthe CFOsintheirsampleusea“verystrict”targetdebt‐equityratioand34%usea“somewhattight” targetorrange.Suchleveragetargetsaretypicallydefinedintermsofbookvaluesofequityand debt,andWelch(2004)confirmsthatmarketleverageislargelyallowedtofloatwithstockprices. Whetherthisisaruleofthumb,aboundedlyrationalfocusonslowermovingbookvalues,ora rationalrecognitionthatbookvaluesareabetterproxyforliquidationvaluethanmarketvalueis hardtoprove.Likewise,andasmentionedbefore,Lintner’s(1956)fieldinterviewsrevealasetof commonrulesofthumbinpayoutpolicythatleadtoareasonablyaccurateempiricalspecification fordividends.Brav,Graham,Harvey,andMichaely(2005)findthatsomeoftheserulesstillapply fiftyyearslater. 3.5.5. Contracting and executive compensation LandierandThesmar(2009)examinefinancialcontractingbetweenrationalinvestorsand optimisticentrepreneurs.34Theyhighlighttwoaspectsofcontractingwithoptimists.First,because optimiststendtoinefficientlypersistintheirinitialbusinessplan,theoptimalcontracttransfers controlwhenchangesarenecessary.(KaplanandStromberg(2003)findthatcontingenttransfers 34ManoveandPadilla(1999)alsoconsiderhowbanksseparateoptimistsandrealists.Theyfocusonthe overallefficiencyofthecreditmarket. 69 ofcontrolarecommonfeaturesofventurecapitalcontracts.)Second,becauseoptimistsbelieve goodstatestobemorelikely,theyarewillingtotradesomecontrolandownershiprightsinbad statesforgreaterclaimsingoodones;inthissense,theoptimalcontract“paystheentrepreneur withdreams.”Ultimately,optimistsmayself‐selectintoshort‐termdebt,asittransferspayments andcontroltotheinvestorinstatesthattheythinkareunlikely,whilerealisticentrepreneurs preferlessriskylong‐termdebt. LandierandThesmarfindsomeempiricalevidenceofthisseparationindataonFrench entrepreneurs.Amongotherresults,theyfindthattheuseofshort‐termdebtispositivelyrelated toanexpostmeasureofoptimisticexpectations,thedifferencebetweenrealizedgrowthandinitial growthexpectations.Theyalsofindthattheuseofshort‐termdebtispositivelyrelatedto psychologically‐motivatedinstrumentsforexpectations,suchasregionalsunlightexposureand ratesofmentaldepression. Somerelatedphenomenaappearinthecontextofbiasedexecutives’compensation contracts.StandardcontractingmodelsseemunabletoexplainbasicaspectsofCEOcompensation. Forexample,HallandMurphy(2002)andDittmanandMaug(2007)pointoutthatconvex incentivesarecommonlyinducedthroughstockoptions.Yettheseturnouttobehardtocalibrate tostandardmodelswithrisk‐neutralshareholdersandrisk‐averse,undiversifiedexecutives. DittmanandMaugarguethatsuchsetupsactuallytendtopredictnegativebasesalaries. Gervais,Heaton,andOdean(2010)derivetheoptimalcompensationcontractforarisk‐ aversebutoverconfidentmanager.Themanageroverweightshisprivateinformation,sothe optimalcontractbalancesthestandardissueofovercominghisriskaversionwiththeneedtoavoid rashinvestments.Themostbasiceffectisthatifthemanagerishighlyoverconfident,shareholders’ wealth‐maximizingcontractishighlyconvex,becausethemanagerovervaluesit.Thiseffectis reminiscentofpayingwithdreams. 70 Theprospecttheoryvaluefunctionprovidesanotherexplanationforstockoptionsand positivebasesalariesasoptimalcontracts.Dittman,Maug,andSpalt(2010)showthatimplausible parametersarenotrequired;forexample,themanager’sreferencewagecanbeclosetolastyear’s salaryandbonus.Themanager’srisktoleranceisnearzeroaroundthereferencepointbut increasesrapidlyaspayoutincreases.Thisnecessitateshigh‐powered,convexcontractsevenwith optimalrisksharing.Thisisconsistentwithhighsalariesandpositivestockandstockoption holdingsthatweobserve. 4. Behavioral Signaling Anotherbehavioralapproachtocorporatefinanceisinanembryonicstage.Weincludeit alongsidemorematureresearchframeworksbecauseofitstheoreticaldistinctivenessandseeming promise.Wealsohappentofinditinterestingourselves;ourdiscussionherewillfocusonBaker andWurgler(2011).Themodelinvolvesquasi‐rationalinvestors,soinaconceptualsenseitfalls betweenthemarkettimingandcateringresearch,whichassumesirrationalinvestors,andthe managerialbiasesresearch,whichassumesfullyrationalinvestors. ThecoreideaofsignalingmodelssinceSpence(1973)isthat“good”typescanseparate themselvesbytakingsomeactionthatislesscostlyforthemthanitisfor“bad”types.Incorporate finance,classicapplicationsincludethecapitalstructuremodelsofLelandandPyle(1977),Ross (1977),andMyersandMajluf(1984);thedividendmodelsofBhattacharya(1979),Johnand Williams(1985),andMillerandRock(1985);theconvertibledebtmodelofHarrisandRaviv (1985);and,theIPOunderpricingmodelsofAllenandFaulhaber(1989),GrinblattandHwang (1989),andWelch(1989).Althoughthenatureofthesignalingmechanismvaries,allofthese modelsfeatureparticipantswithstandardpreferencesandrationalexpectations. 71 Thedefiningcharacteristicofbehavioralsignalingmodelsisthatthesignalingmechanism derivesfromnonstandardpreferencesorjudgmentalbiases.Themodelofdividendpolicywe discussbelowisanexample.Itreliesonprospecttheorypreferencesandnarrowframing. 4.1. Theoretical Framework Thereisnostandardtheoreticalframeworktooutlinehereatthistime.Indeed,thereare manybehavioraldistortionsonecouldimaginebasingasignalingmodelupon,andeachmighthave asomewhatdifferentimplementationandapplication.Wewillreviewaspecificmodelofdividend signalingbasedonBakerandWurgler(2011). Themaingoalofthisdividend‐signalingmodelis,asusual,toexplainwhyfirmspay dividendsatall.Secondarygoalsaretoshedlightonotherfactsofdividendpolicy.Theseinclude thefactthatdividendsareoftennotraisedorloweredforlongstretches;thatdividendcutsare greetedverynegatively;and,thatdividendscanbedescribedusingtheLintner(1956)partial‐ adjustmentmodel.Weoutlinethemodelandthenreturntomoredetailedempiricalimplications. Thesignalingmechanismisbasedonnonstandardinvestorpreferences,notwillful destructionoffirmvaluethroughinvestmentdistortionsortaxes.Inparticular,itisbasedonthe referencedependenceandlossaversionfeaturesoftheprospecttheoryvaluefunctionof KahnemanandTversky(1979).Referencedependencereferstothepropensitytojudgeutility basedonlossesandgainsrelativetoacontext‐specificreferencepoint.Lossaversiondenotesthe tendencytoperceivemoredisutilityfromlossesthanutilityfromequal‐sizegains.Sufficeittosay thatagreatdealofresearchfrompsychologyandeconomicssupportstheseeffects—see,e.g., Kahneman(2003). Themodel’sfirstkeyingredientisthatareferencepointlevelofdividendsappearsinthe investor’sobjectivefunction.Perlossaversion,thereisakinkinutility,sothatthenegativeeffectof 72 a$0.01dropindividendsjustbelowthereferencepointisgreaterthanthepositiveeffectofa$0.01 increaseindividendsjustabove.Thesecondkeyingredientisthatthemanagercaresaboutthe currentestimateoffirmvalueaswellasthelong‐termwelfareofinvestors. Themodelfocusesontwoperiods:t=1and2.Therearetwoplayers:abenevolent managerandaninvestortowhomdividendcutsfromthecurrentreferencepointlevelare discontinuouslypainful.Inthefirstperiod,theinvestorarriveswithanexogenousreferencepoint d*.Themanageralsoreceivesprivateinformationaboutcashearnings1andpaysadividendd1in thefirstperiod.Giventhisdividend,theinvestorlearnssomethingaboutthemanager’sprivate informationandhencethevalueofthefirm.Thisdividend,whichmaybebelow,above,orequalto d*,inturnformsanewreferencepointfortheliquidatingdividendd2.Insomeways,thismodelcan beviewedasasnapshotofamulti‐periodmodel. Inthismodel,referencepointsshapedividendpolicyinmultipleways.Ontheonehand,to theextentthattoday’sdividendisthereferencepointagainstwhichfuturedividendpaymentswill bejudged,themanagerwouldliketorestraincurrentdividends,savingsomeresourcesforthenext periodtomakeupforapossibleshortfallinfutureearnings.Ontheotherhand,settingasideeffects onfutureinvestorwelfare,themanagerwouldliketopayadividendtodaythatexceedsthecurrent referencepoint.Moreover,becausethemanageralsocaresaboutthecurrentestimateoffirmvalue, whichforsimplicitywetaketomeantheestimateoffirstperiodcashearnings,hemightalso increasedividendsbeyondthecurrentreferencepointtosignalprivateinformationaboutthe firm’sabilitytopay.Thissignalingmechanismworksbecausefirmswithlimitedresourcesare unwillingtoincurtheexpectedfuturecostofmissinganendogenousreferencepoint.Comingback totheformalities,wehave: 73 Managerutility.Themanagercaresaboutwhattheinvestorthinksabout1todaybecause thatdeterminestoday’sstockprice.Healsocaresabouttheinvestor’slongrunutility.The simplifiedobjectivefunctionis: E m Ei 1 1 u d1 , d 2 | d * , whered1andd2aretheperiod‐specificdividendsofthefirm,uistheinvestor’sutilityfunction, givenanexogenousinitialreferencepointofd*,andEmandEiaretheexpectationsoperatorsforthe managerandtheinvestor,respectively.35 Investorutility.Themanager’sobjectiveisstandard.Theinterestingaspectofthis signalingmodelisthattheinvestorhasakinkinhispreferencesfordividendsd1andd2.Thefirst kinkisaroundanexogenousreferencepointforfirstperioddividendsd*andthesecondkinkis aroundanendogenousreferencepointforsecondperioddividends: u d1, d2 | d * d1 b d1 d * d1 d * d2 b d2 d1 d2 d1 . Inotherwords,theinvestorcaresaboutfundamentalvalue,ortotaldividendpayments,but withatwist.Thelevelofthereferencepointcomesfromhistoricalfirmdividendpolicy,andbis greaterthanzerotoincorporatelossaversion.Thisutilityfunctionisinthespiritofprospecttheory withakinkatareferencepoint.Thesecondperiodreferencepointequalsfirstperioddividendsd1 byassumption.Inreality,thereferencepointandtheintensityofthereferencepointbmaybe determinedbyalonghistoryoflevelsandchangesindividendpolicy.Thefactthateachdividend paymentformsaseparatereferencepointalsorequiresnarrowframing.Thisisnotareference 1appearsdirectlyintothemanager’sobjectiveisaninnocuous assumption,becauseinequilibriumthestockpricewillbealineartransformationofthisexpectation. 35Thefactthattheinvestor’sexpectationof 74 pointappliedtototalendingwealth,butmuchmorenarrowlybothacrossstocksandtime,inthe spiritofBarberis,Huang,andThaler(2006). Information.Forsimplicity,themanagerhasnocontroloverthecashearningsofthefirm. Thisisabitdifferentfromatraditionalsignalingmodelwherethemanagermustdestroyfirmvalue toimpressthecapitalmarkets.Thereisalsonoagencyproblem;themanagerisnotabletokeepthe cashforhimself,andnorealvalueiscreatedordestroyedwithdividendpolicy.Thefundamental valueofthefirmappearsintwoinstallmentsandtotals 1 2 .Thinkoftheseascashearningsthat arenotobservabletotheinvestor.Thisisanextremeassumptionofasymmetricinformationthat highlightstheintuition.Forsimplicity,assumethatthesecond‐periodcashearningshaveauniform distribution, 2 ~ U 0,2 . Budgetconstraint.Thereisnonewequityordebtavailabletofinancethepaymentof dividendsandnoexcesscashbalancesavailableinthefirstperiod.Themostthemanagercanpay inthefirstperiodis1,andthemosthecanpayinthesecondperiodis2plusanysavingsfromthe firstperiod.Givenabenevolentmanagerandtheabsenceofnewfinancing,thisimpliesconstraints: 0 d1 1 and d 2 1 2 d1 . Equilibrium.Combiningtheabove,therearethreeimportanteffectsthatappearinthe manager’sobjectivefunction.First,thereissometimesanadvantagetopayingoutdividends immediately.Considerafirstperioddividendbelowthereferencepointd*.Settingasidetheeffect onthesecondperiodreferencepoint,thesedividendswillbevaluedonthemarginatb+1timesthe payout,insteadofsimplythepayout.Aboved*,thereisnomarginalbenefitfrommerelyshifting payoutfromthesecondperiodforward.Second,byincreasingthedividendtoday,theinvestor’s estimateEi[1]oftheunobservablecashearningsrisesthroughanequilibriumsetofbeliefsthat mapdividendpolicytocashearnings.Thisentersintothemanager’sutilityfunctiondirectly.Third, 75 increasingthedividendinthefirstperiod,foreitheroftheserationales,producesanexpected futurecosttoinvestorutilitythatcomesfromthepossibilityoffallingshortofthereferencepoint setforthesecondperiod. Thesethreemotivationscombinetosimplifythemanager’sutilityfunction: 2 1 b d1 d * d1 d * Ei 1 | d1 1 b d1 1 d1 1 2 2 Thefirsttermreflectsstrivingtoavoidfallingshortoftheinitialreferencepoint.Thesecondterm reflectsconcernaboutshareprice.Thethirdtermreflectstheexpectedcostoffallingshortofanew referencepoint;thereisnocostifthemanageradoptsaveryconservativedividendpolicyofpaying halfoffirst‐periodearnings.Giventheuniformdistributionof2,theexpectedcostisquadraticas dividendsrisefromthispointandincreasingintheintensityofthereferencepoint. Intuitively,theseconsiderationssuggestthreerangesofdividendpoliciesinequilibrium. Thereisahighpayoutratioforfirmswiththeextramotivationduetosignalingtocleartheinitial referencepointofd*.Next,managersclusteratd*oncethismarginaleffectdropsout,i.e.they maintaintheirexistingdividendlevelexactly.Finally,thereisalowerpayoutratioforfirmswith first‐periodearningswellabovetheinitialreferencepoint.Theseluckyfirmsnonethelesspay higherdividendstoseparatethemselvesfromeachotherandfromthepoolatd*.Specifically,there existsanequilibriumwhere: d1=1if1<d*, =d*ifd*<1<*,and = 12 1 1 1b if1>*, 76 with*satisfying 12 *d * 1 b 1 1b d * 12 * 0 , 2 2 and equilibrium beliefs of: Ei[1 | d1]= d1 if d1 < d*, = 1 2 * d * if d1 = d*,and = 2 d1 1 1b if d1 > 12 * 1 1b . Thereareintuitivecomparativestaticswithrespecttob,thecostoffallingbelowthe referencepoint.Inthisequilibrium,itcanbeshownthatasbincreasesanddecreases,thereis moreclusteringofdividendsatthereferencepointd*(*increases),andthemarketreactiontod1< d*increases,becausethereismoreinformationrevealedinanearmiss. 4.2. Applications Wewilldiscusstheempiricalrelevanceofthisdividend‐signalingmodelandthenspeculate abitaboutpotentialfutureapplicationsofbehavioralsignaling. 4.2.1 Dividends Animportantfeatureofthereferencepointsmodelisthatitisconsistentwithwhat managerssayaboutdividendpolicy.IntheBravetal.(2004)survey,executivesdisavowthenotion thattheypaydividendsbecauseitdestroysfirmvalueandthereforesignalsstrength.Thisisthe basis,however,ofnumerousnon‐behavioralsignalingmodels.Atthesametime,managersdoagree withthenotionthatdividendsarea“signal”ofsomesort.Thebehavioralsignalingmodelwith dividendsasreferencepointscansignalfinancialsoundnesswithoutburningmoney. 77 BehavioralsignalingcanalsogivefoundationstotheLintner(1956)model,whichhas provedadifficulttaskusingtraditionalapproaches.Intheequilibriumdescribedabove,firmswith goodearningsrealizations(1>*)followapartial‐adjustmentpolicyandaremoregenerally smoothedrelativetoearnings.TheLintnermodeltakesthepreviousdividendasthestartingpoint foranyadjustmentinthisperiod;thebehavioralsignalingmodelpredictsthatthedividendlevel willbeconstantformanyfirmsandadjustedonlywhenearningsaresufficientlyextreme.On averageforallfirms,dividendsincreaselessthanone‐for‐onewithearnings,consistentwithpartial adjustment. Thereactiontodividendchangesisasymmetric,withcutsbeingparticularlypainful (AharonyandSwary(1980)).Moststandardsignalingmodelsdonotincorporatethisasymmetry. Ontheotherhand,itimmediatelyfollowsfromamodelwithloss‐averseinvestorswhouselagged dividendsasareferencepoint—therelevanteffectisthatcuttingdividends,evenslightly,fully revealsthatthefirm’sfinancialstrengthislow. Afundamentalthemeofthemodelisthatthelevelofdividendsneedstobesalientand memorableinordertomaximizethestrengthofthesignal.Ifinvestorsdon’tnoticetheirdividend ordon’tnoticechanges,thereference‐pointmechanismfails.Infact,similartowhatThomas(1989) findsinearningslevels,dividendlevelsandchangestendalsotobeineasy‐to‐digestround numbers,suchasmultiplesoffiveandtencentspershare.Thisfeatureofdividendpolicyagainhas nonaturalinterpretationwithintraditionalsignalingtheories. 4.2.2. Other applications Earningsmanagementpresentsanotherpotentialapplicationforbehavioralsignaling. Importantfeaturesofthereportedearningsprocessarereminiscentofthedividendprocess. BurgstahlerandDichev(1997)andDegeorgeetal.(1999)findthatearningsaremanagedtomeet orexceedsalientreferencepoints.Asdiscussedearlier,theseincludezeroearnings,lagged 78 earnings,andanalystexpectations.Inaddition,reportedearningsaresmoothedversionsoftrue earnings,involvingapartial‐adjustmentprocessnotunliketheLintnermodel. Aloss‐aversionbasedmechanismisn’tasnaturalintheearningscontext,however. Reportedearningsarelesstangibleandvisibletothemassofinvestorsthandividends;loss aversiontoreportedearningsperseisunnatural.36Amorerealisticsignalingmechanismmightbe basedonirrationalbeliefs. Forexample,supposethatinvestorsoverreactifreportedearningsfallbelowthethreshold ofpriorearnings.(SkinnerandSloan(2002)findthatgrowthfirms,forwhichinformationopacity ishighestandsignalingmostuseful,doexhibitanasymmetricresponsetoearningssurprises.) Reportedearningscanthenbecomeasignal:Managerswithfavorableprivateinformationcan aggressivelymanipulateearningsupwardandestablishhigherreferencepointsforfutureearnings. Distinguishingbetweentwotypesofinvestors—noisetraderswithincorrectbeliefsand arbitrageurswithrationalexpectationsbutlimitedcapitalandrisk‐bearingability—allowsoneto preservearationalexpectationsequilibriumconcept.Inthissetup,managersareessentially signalingtothearbitrageurs;thenoisetradersprovidethemechanism. Stocksplitshavealsobeenmodeledassignalsinrationalexpectationsframeworks,without clearsuccess.ThecostlysignalingmechanismsinBrennanandCopeland(1988)andBrennanand Hughes(1991)involvetransactioncosts:roughlyspeaking,firmssplittolower‐pricedsharesto increasetradingcostsontheirinvestors.Unfortunately,BakerandPowell(1993)surveymanagers andtheysaythatsplitsareifanythinganefforttoimproveliquidity. 36Ontheotherhand,Degeorgeetal.proposethatexecutivesthemselvesmayderivepersonalutilityfrom meetingthresholds. 79 Itisnothardtosketchasimplebehavioralsignalingmodelofsplitsthatismoreintuitive. Forexample,supposethatnoisetraderscoarselycategorizelow‐nominal‐pricefirms,allelseequal, asgrowthfirms(Baker,Greenwood,andWurgler(2009)).Inthisenvironment,splitterscan crediblyseparatethemselvesintheeyesofrationalarbitrageursbecausetheyknowtheycan deliverhigherearningsnextperiodandnotriskthewrathofthenoisetraders.SkinnerandSloan’s (2002)resultsarealsocompatiblewiththissimplemodel. 5. Conclusion Thebehavioralcorporatefinanceliteraturehasmaturedtothepointwhereonecannow sketchoutahandfulofcanonicaltheoreticalframeworksandusethemtoorganizemanydozensof empiricalstudies.Ourreviewofthisevidenceindicatesthatbehavioralapproachesofferauseful complementtotheothercorporatefinanceparadigms.Theydeliverintuitiveandsometimesquite compellingexplanationsforimportantfinancingandinvestingpatterns,includingsomethatare difficulttoreconcilewithexistingtheory. Initscurrentstateofflux,thefieldoffersanumberofexcitingandimportantresearch questions.Weclosebyhighlightingjustafew.Innoparticularorder,wewonder: Arebehavioralfactorsattherootofwhymanagersdonotmoreaggressivelypursuethetax benefitsofdebt,asinGraham(2000)?Hackbarth(2009)developsatheoreticalargument alongtheselines. Whiletheexistingliteraturehasgenerallyconsideredthetwoapproachesseparately,the irrationalmanagerandirrationalinvestorstoriescancertainlycoexist.Wouldamodel featuringacorrelationbetweeninvestorandmanagerialsentimentleadtonewinsights? 80 Whatotherphenomenacanbemodeledwithbehavioralsignaling?Howcansuchmodelsbe tested? Whatarethedeterminantsofmanagerial“horizons,”andhowcantheybemeasuredand appropriatelygoverned? Towhatextentshouldinvestmentbankersbeviewedasinstitutionswhosebusinessmodel istoidentifyandcatertoemergingpocketsofinvestorsentiment? Towhatextentshouldprivateequityfundsbeviewedasfirmswhosebusinessmodelisto capitalizeonequityanddebtmarketsthatarenotfullyintegrated,withseparateinvestor demandshocksandinconsistentpricing? Whatarethebehavioralexplanationsfortherecentfinancialcrisis?Barberis(2011)starts toconnectthedots. Howisthebankingsystemaffectedbyinefficienciesinthecapitalmarkets?Should regulationaimtoinsulatebanksfrombubbles?Shouldthisoperatethroughbroadcapital regulations,ormorenarrowly? Arederivativeinstruments–mostnoteworthyinrecenthistory,creditdefaultswaps(CDS) andCDOs–pronetomisvaluation?Towhatextentdotheymakecorporateoutcomesmore efficientbyloweringtheexantecostofcapitalthroughefficientrisksharingorby predictingdefault?Towhatextentaretheythesourceofmispricingsthatpropagateinto debtandequityprices? Whatdeterminesinvestorsentiment,andhowisitmanagedthroughcorporateinvestor relations(BrennanandTamarowski(2000))?Potentialavenuestoconsiderareinteractions 81 withpaststockmarketreturns,technologicalchangeandthevaluationofnewindustries, mediacoverage,financialanalystsandfinancialreporting,andinvestmentbanking. Doequityanddebtmarkettimingreducetheoverallcostofcapitalbyasmallamountora largeamount?Dichev(2004)offersanapproachhere. Towhatextentcanfeaturesoffinancialcontractsandsecuritiesbeunderstoodasa responsetoassortedbehavioralbiases?Williamsontookfirststepshere.Inthecontextof consumercontracts,DellaVignaandMalmendier(2004)suggestthatcreditcardsand healthclubcontractsareshapedbynaïveexpectationsandtime‐inconsistentpreferences. Whatistheimpactofinvestorinertiaandlimitedattentiononcorporatefinance?Baker, CovalandStein(2007)andDellaVignaandPollet(2009)considerstockswapsandthe timingofcorporatedisclosure.HirshleiferandWelch(2002)developimplicationsfor organizations. Howshouldoneapproachtheproperregulationofinefficientmarketsandfinancial reporting?ThefinancialcrisishasgenerateddiscussionabouttheroleoftheFedandthe SECwithregardtoidentifyingandmanaginginvestorsentimentandbubbles. Whatarethelimitsofcorporatearbitrage,includingdetectingandgeneratingmispricing, maintainingreputation,andavoidingfraud? Canacateringapproachhelptoexplainthediversificationandsubsequentre‐focuswave thathastakenplaceintheUSsincethelate‐1960s? Howsignificantistheeconomy‐widemisallocationofcapitalcausedbycollectedbehavioral distortions,andinparticularhowdothesedistortionsinteractwithtraditionalcapital marketimperfections?Forexample,ifthereisunderinvestmentduetoagencyor 82 asymmetricinformation,bubblesmaybringinvestmentclosertotheefficientlevel—or overshoot. Ifboundedrationalityorinvestorpressuresleadmanagerstorelyonspecificperformance metrics,willthirdpartiesexploitthis?Themarketingoftakeoversandfinancingvehiclesas EPS‐improvingtransactionsbyinvestmentbanksisapotentialexample.Moregenerally, whatprofitopportunitiesarecreatedbybehavioralbiasesofinvestorsandmanagers? Towhatextentarecorporate“hedging”policiesactuallydirectionalbets?Theevidencein Brown,Crabb,andHaushalter(2002)andFaulkender(2005)suggeststhatinmany companies,interestrateriskmanagementandtheuseofderivativeshaslittletodowith textbookhedging. Whatarethenormative,legal,andethicalimplicationsofmarket‐drivencorporatefinance? Shouldmanagersbeencouragedtorespondtomovementsinpricesandinterestratesthat donotreflectunderlyingfundamentals?Jensen(2005)explorestheagencyproblemsthat arisefromovervaluedequity. IntheIntroduction,wepointedoutthatthenormativeimplicationofassumingirrational investorsistoinsulatemanagersfromshort‐termmarketpressures,whiletheimplication ofassumingirrationalmanagersapproachistoobligatethemtofollowmarketprices.What, intherealworld,istherightbalancebetweendiscretionandmarketpressure? 83 References Acharya,Viral,andLassePedersen,2005,Assetpricingwithliquidityrisk,JournalofFinancial Economics77,375‐410. Adams,Renee,HeitorAlmeida,andDanielFerreira,2005,PowerfulCEOsandtheirimpacton corporateperformance,ReviewofFinancialStudies,1443‐1432. Aghion,Philippe,andJeremyStein,2008,Growthvs.margins:Destabilizingconsequencesofgiving thestockmarketwhatitwants,JournalofFinance63,1025‐1058. Aharony,Joseph,andItzhakSwary,1980,Quarterlydividendandearningsannouncementsand stockholders’returns:Anempiricalanalysis,JournalofFinance35,1‐12. Aktas,Nihat,EricdeBodt,HelenBollaert,andRichardRoll,2010,CEOnarcissismandthetakeover process,UCLAworkingpaper. Allen,Franklin,andGeraldFaulhaber,1989,SignalingbyunderpricingintheIPOmarket,Journalof FinancialEconomics23,303‐323. Alti,Aydogan,2006,Howpersistentistheimpactofmarkettimingoncapitalstructure?,Journalof Finance61,1681‐1710. Andrade,Gregor,MarkL.Mitchell,andErikStafford,2001,Newevidenceandperspectiveson mergers,JournalofEconomicPerspectives15,103‐120. Ang,Andrew,LiGu,andYaelV.Hochberg,2007,IsIPOunderperformanceapesoproblem?,Journal ofFinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis42,565‐594. Ang,JamesS.,andYingmeiCheng,2006,Directevidenceonthemarket‐drivenacquisitiontheory, JournalofFinancialResearch29,199‐216. AxelsonUlf,TimJenkinson,PerStromberg,andMichaelWeisbach,2011,Borrowcheap,buyhigh? thedeterminantsofleverageandpricinginbuyouts,Workingpaper. Baker,H.Kent,andGaryE.Powell,1993,Furtherevidenceonmanagerialmotivesforstocksplits, QuarterJournalofBusinessandEconomics32,20‐31. Baker,Malcolm,2009,Capitalmarket‐drivencorporatefinance,AnnualReviewofFinancial Economics1,181‐205. Baker,Malcolm,JoshuaCoval,andJeremyStein,2007,Corporatefinancingdecisionswhen investorstakethepathofleastresistance,JournalofFinancialEconomics84,266‐298. Baker,Malcolm,C.FritzFoley,andJeffreyWurgler,2009,Multinationalsasarbitrageurs:Theeffect ofstockmarketvaluationsonforeigndirectinvestment,ReviewofFinancialStudies22. 337‐369. 84 Baker,Malcolm,RobinGreenwood,andJeffreyWurgler,2003,Thematurityofdebtissuesand predictablevariationinbondreturns,JournalofFinancialEconomics70,261‐291. Baker,Malcolm,RobinGreenwood,andJeffreyWurgler,2009,Cateringthroughnominalshare prices,JournalofFinance64,2559–2590. Baker,Malcolm,XinPan,andJeffreyWurgler,2011,Theeffectofreferencepointpricesonmergers andacquisitions,NYUworkingpaper. Baker,Malcolm,JeremySteinandJeffreyWurgler,2003,WhenDoestheMarketMatter?,Stock PricesandtheInvestmentofEquity‐DependentFirms,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics118, 969‐1006. Baker,Malcolm,andJeremyStein,2004,Marketliquidityasasentimentindicator,Journalof FinancialMarkets7,271‐299. Baker,Malcolm,RyanTaliaferro,andJeffreyWurgler,2006,Predictingreturnswithmanagerial decisionvariables:Isthereasmall‐samplebias?,JournalofFinance61,1711‐1730. Baker,MalcolmandJeffreyWurgler,2000,Theequityshareinnewissuesandaggregatestock returns,JournalofFinance55,2219‐2257. Baker,Malcolm,andJeffreyWurgler,2002,Markettimingandcapitalstructure,JournalofFinance 57,1‐32. Baker,Malcolm,andJeffreyWurgler,2004a,Acateringtheoryofdividends,JournalofFinance59, 271‐288. Baker,Malcolm,andJeffreyWurgler,2004b,Appearinganddisappearingdividends:Thelinkto cateringincentives,JournalofFinancialEconomics73,271‐288. Baker,Malcolm,andJeffreyWurgler,2011,Governmentbondsandthecross‐sectionofstock returns,NYUworkingpaper. Baker,Malcolm,andYuhaiXuan,2011,Undernewmanagement:Equityissuesandtheattribution ofpastreturns,HBSworkingpaper. Barber,BradM.,andRichardLyon,1997,Detectinglong‐runabnormalstockreturns:Theempirical powerandspecificationofteststatistics,JournalofFinancialEconomics43,341‐372. BarberisNicholas,2011,Psychologyandthefinancialcrisisof2007‐2008,in:FinancialInnovation andCrisis,M.Haliassosed.,forthcoming. Barberis,Nicholas,MingHuang,andRichardH.Thaler,2006,Individualpreferences,monetary gambles,andstockmarketparticipation:Acasefornarrowframing,AmericanEconomic Review96,1069‐1090. 85 Barberis,Nicholas,andAndreiShleifer,2003,Styleinvesting,JournalofFinancialEconomics75, 283‐317. Barberis,Nicholas,AndreiShleifer,andJeffreyWurgler,2005,Comovement,JournalofFinancial Economics75,283‐317. Barberis,Nicholas,andRichardH.Thaler,2003,Asurveyofbehavioralfinance,in:George Constantinides,MiltonHarris,ReneStulz,eds.,HandbookoftheEconomicsofFinance, (Amsterdam:North‐Holland). Barberis,Nicholas,andWeiXiong,2009,Whatdrivesthedispositioneffect?AnAnalysisofaLong‐ standing,Preference‐basedExplanation,JournalofFinance64,751‐784. Barro,RobertJ.,1990,Thestockmarketandinvestment,ReviewofFinancialStudies3,115‐132. BeckerBo,ZoranIvkovic,ScottWeisbenner,2011,LocalDividendClienteles,JournalofFinance66, 655‐684. Benartzi,Shlomo,2001,Excessiveextrapolationandtheallocationof401(k)accountstocompany stock,JournalofFinance56,1747‐64. Ben‐David,Itzhak,2010,Dividendpolicydecisions,in:BehavioralFinance,H.KentBakerandJohn Nofsinger,eds.(Hoboken:Wiley). Ben‐David,Itzhak,JohnR.Graham,andCampbellR.Harvey,2010,Managerialmiscalibration,Duke Universityworkingpaper. Benveniste,Lawrence,andPaulSpindt,1989,Howinvestmentbankersdeterminetheofferprice andallocationofnewissues,JournalofFinancialEconomics24,343‐362. Berger,Philip,andEliOfek,1995,Diversification’seffectonfirmvalue,JournalofFinancial Economics37,39‐65. Bergman,NittaiK.,andDirkJenter,2007,Employeesentimentandstockoptioncompensation, JournalofFinancialEconomics84,667‐712. Bergstresser,Daniel,MihirDesai,andJoshuaD.Rauh,2006,Earningsmanipulation,pension assumptions,andmanagerialinvestmentdecisions,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics121, 157‐195. Bergstresser,Daniel,andThomasPhilippon,2006,CEOincentivesandearningsmanagement, JournalofFinancialEconomics80,511‐529. Bernard,Victor,1989,Post‐earningsannouncementdrift:delayedpriceresponseorriskpremium? JournalofAccountingResearch27,1‐36. Bertrand,Marianne,andAntoinetteSchoar,2003,Managingwithstyle:Theeffectofmanagerson firmpolicies,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics118,1169‐1208. 86 Bhattacharya,Sudipto,1979,Imperfectinformation,dividendpolicy,andthebirdinthehand fallacy,BellJournalofEconomicsandManagementScience10,259‐270. Blanchard,Olivier,FlorencioLopez‐de‐Silanes,andAndreiShleifer,1994,Whatdofirmsdowith cashwindfalls?,JournalofFinancialEconomics36,337‐360. Blanchard,Olivier,ChanyongRhee,andLawrenceSummers,1993,Thestockmarket,profit,and investment,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics108,115‐136. Bolton,Patrick,HuiChen,andNengWang,2011,Markettiming,investment,andriskmanagement, Workingpaper. Bolton,Patrick,JoseScheinkman,andWeiXiong,2005,Payforshort‐termperformance:Executive compensationinspeculativemarkets,JournalofCorporationLaw30,721‐747. Bouwman,Christa,KathleenFuller,andAmritaNain,2003,Theperformanceofstock‐pricedriven acquisitions,UniversityofMichiganworkingpaper. Bradshaw,MarkT.,ScottA.Richardson,andRichardG.Sloan,2006,Therelationbetweencorporate financingactivities,analysts’forecastsandstockreturns,JournalofAccountingand Economics42,53‐85. Brav,Alon,2000,Inferenceinlong‐horizoneventstudies:ABayesianperspective,Journalof Finance55,1979‐2016. Brav,Alon,andPaulA.Gompers,1997,Mythorreality?,Thelong‐rununderperformanceofinitial publicofferings:Evidencefromventurecapitalandnonventurecapital‐backedcompanies, JournalofFinance52,1791‐1822. Brav,Alon,JohnGraham,CampbellR.Harvey,andRoniMichaely,2005,Payoutpolicyinthe21st century,JournalofFinancialEconomics77,483‐528. Brennan,MichaelJ.,andThomasE.Copeland,1988,Stocksplits,stockprices,andtransactioncosts, JournalofFinancialEconomics22,83‐101. Brennan,MichaelJ.,andPatriciaJ.Hughes,1991,Stockpricesandthesupplyofinformation,Journal ofFinance46,1665‐1691. Brennan,Michael,andClaudiaTamarowski,2000,Investorrelations,liquidityandstockprices, JournalofAppliedCorporateFinance12,26‐37. Brown,Greg,PeterCrabb,andDavidHaushalter,2002,Arefirmssuccessfulatselectivehedging?, JournalofBusiness79,2925‐2950. Burch,TimothyR.,WilliamG.Christie,andVikramNanda,2004,Dofirmstimeequityofferings?, Evidencefromthe1930sand1940s,FinancialManagement33,5‐23. 87 Burgstahler,David,andIliaD.Dichev,1997,Earningsmanagementtoavoidearningsdecreasesand losses,JournalofAccountingandEconomics24,99‐126. Butler,AlexanderW.,GustavoGrullon,andJamesP.Weston,2005,Canmanagersforecastaggregate marketreturns?,JournalofFinance60,963‐986. Camerer,Colin,andDanielLovallo,1999,Overconfidenceandexcessentry:Anexperimental approach,AmericanEconomicReview89,306‐318. Camerer,Colin,andUlrikeMalmendier,2009,Behavioraleconomicsoforganizations,in:P. DiamondandH.Vartiainen,eds.,BehavioralEconomicsandItsApplications,(Princeton: PrincetonUniversityPress). Campello,Murillo,andJohnGraham,2007,Dostockpricesinfluencecorporatedecisions?Evidence fromthetechnologybubble,NationalBureauofEconomicresearchworkingpaper. Carslaw,C.A.P.N.,1988,Anomaliesinincomenumbers:Evidenceofgoalorientedbehavior,The AccontingReview63,321‐327. Chen,Long,andXinleiZhao,2005,Profitability,meanreversionofleverageratios,andcapital structurechoices,WashingtonUniversityworkingpaper. Chen,Long,andXinleiZhao,2007,Mechanicalmeanreversionofleverageratios,EconomicsLetters 95,223‐229. Chernenko,Sergey,C.FritzFoley,andRobinGreenwood,2010,Agencycosts,mispricing,and ownershipstructure,NationalBureauofEconomicResearchworkingpaper. Chirinko,RobertS.,andHuntleySchaller,2001,Businessfixedinvestmentand‘bubbles’:The Japanesecase,AmericanEconomicReview91,663‐680. Chirinko,RobertS.,andHuntleySchaller,2004,Glamourvs.value:Therealstory,EmoryUniversity workingpaper. Conlisk,John,1996,Whyboundedrationality?,JournalofEconomicLiterature34,669‐700. Cooper,ArnoldC.,CarolynY.Woo,andWilliamC.Dunkelberg,1988,Entrepreneurs’perceived chancesforsuccess,JournalofBusinessVenturing3,97‐108. Cooper,MichaelJ.,OrlinDimitrov,andP.RaghavendraRau,2001,Arose.combyanyothername, JournalofFinance56,2371‐2388. Cooper,MichaelJ.,HuseyinGulen,andP.RaghavendraRau,2005,Changingnameswithstyle: Mutualfundnamechangesandtheireffectsonfundflows,JournalofFinance60,2825‐ 2858. 88 Cooper,MichaelJ.,AjayKorana,IgorOsobov,AjayPatel,andP.RaghavendraRau,2005,Managerial actionsinresponsetoamarketdownturn:Valuationeffectsofnamechangesinthedot.com decline,JournalofCorporateFinance11,319‐335. Core,John,andWayneGuay,2001,Stockoptionplansfornon‐executiveemployees,Journalof FinancialEconomics61,253‐287. Coval,JoshuaD.,JakubW.Jurek,andErikStafford,2009,Economiccatastrophebonds,American EconomicReview99,628‐666. Cronqvist,Henrik,AnilMakhija,andScottYonker,2011,Behavioralconsistencyincorporate finance:CEOpersonalandcorporateleverage,ClaremontMcKennaCollegeworkingpaper. Dahlquist,Magnus,andFrankdeJong,2008,Pseudomarkettiming:Areappraisal,Journalof FinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis43,547‐580. Damodaran,Aswath,2011,AppliedCorporateFinance,3rded.(NewYork:Wiley). DeLong,J.Bradford,AndreiShleifer,LawrenceH.Summers,andRobertWaldmann,1989,Thesize andincidenceoflossesfromnoisetrading,JournalofFinance44,681‐696. DeLong,J.Bradford,AndreiShleifer,LawrenceH.Summers,andRobertWaldmann,1990,Noise traderriskinfinancialmarkets,JournalofPoliticalEconomy98,703‐738. DeAngelo,Harry,LindaDeAngeloandDouglasJ.Skinner,2004,Aredividendsdisappearing?, Dividendconcentrationandtheconsolidationofearnings,JournalofFinancialEconomics 72,425‐456. DeAngelo,Harry,LindaDeAngeloandReneStulz,2010,Seasonedequityofferings,markettiming, andthecorporatelifecycle,JournalofFinancialEconomics95,275‐295. Degeorge,Francois,JayenduPatel,andRichardZeckhauser,1999,Earningsmanagementtoexceed thresholds,JournalofBusiness72,1‐33. DellaVigna,Stefano,andUlrikeMalmendier,2004,Contractdesignandself‐control:Theoryand evidence,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics119,353‐402. DellaVigna,Stefano,andJoshPollet,2009,Investorinattention,firmreaction,andFridayearnings announcements,JournalofFinance64,709‐749. DellaVigna,Stefano,andJoshPollet,2011,Capitalbudgetingvs.markettiming:Anevaluationusing demographics,JournalofFinance,forthcoming. Derrien,Francois,2010,Initialpublicofferings,in:BehavioralFinance,H.KentBakerandJohn Nofsinger,eds.(Hoboken:Wiley). Dichev,IliaD.,2007,Whatarestockinvestors’actualhistoricalreturns?Evidencefromdollar‐ weightedreturns,AmericanEconomicReview97,386‐402. 89 Dittman,Ingolf,andErnstMaug,2007,Lowersalariesandnooptions?Ontheoptimalstructureof executivepay,JournalofFinance62,303‐343. Dittman,Ingolf,ErnstMaug,andOliverSpalt,2010,Sticksorcarrots?OptimalCEOcompensation whenmanagersarelossaverse,JournalofFinance65,2015‐2050. Donaldson,Gordon,1961,CorporateDebtCapacity:AStudyofCorporateDebtPolicyandthe DeterminationofCorporateDebtCapacity,(Boston,MA:DivisionofResearch,Graduate SchoolofBusinessAdministration,HarvardUniversity). Donaldson,Gordon,1990,Voluntaryrestructuring:ThecaseofGeneralMills,JournalofFinancial Economics27,114‐141. Dong,Ming,2010,Mergersandacquisitions,in:BehavioralFinance,H.KentBakerandJohn Nofsinger,eds.(Hoboken:Wiley). Dong,Ming,DavidHirshleifer,ScottRichardson,andSiewHongTeoh,2006,Doesinvestor misvaluationdrivethetakeovermarket?,JournalofFinance61,725‐762. Dougal,Casey,JosephEngelberg,ChristopherA.Parsons,andEdwardD.VanWesep,2011, Anchoringandthecostofcapital,UniversityofNorthCarolinaworkingpaper. Duffee,GregoryR.,1996,IdiosyncraticvariationofTreasurybillyields,JournalofFinance51,527‐ 551. Dyl,Edward,andWilliamB.Elliott,2006,Thesharepricepuzzle,JournalofBusiness79,2045‐ 2066. Eckbo,B.Espen,RonaldA.Masulis,andOyvindNorli,2000,Seasonedpublicofferings:Resolutionof the‘newissuespuzzle’,JournalofFinancialEconomics56,251‐292. Eckbo,B.Espen,andOyvindNorli,2004,Liquidityrisk,leverage,andlong‐runIPOreturns,Journal ofCorporateFinance11,1‐35. Edelen,RogerM.,andGregoryB.Kadlec,2005,IssuersurplusandthepartialadjustmentofIPO pricestopublicinformation,JournalofFinancialEconomics77,347‐373. Erel,Isil,BrandonJulio,WoojinKim,andMichaelS.Weisbach,2011,Macroeconomicconditionsand thestructureofsecurities,ReviewofFinancialStudies,forthcoming. Erickson,Merle,andShiing‐wuWang,1999,Earningsmanagementbyacquiringfirmsinstockfor stockmergers,JournalofAccountingandEconomics27,149‐176. Fama,EugeneF.,1998,Marketefficiency,long‐termreturns,andbehavioralfinance,Journalof FinancialEconomics49,283‐306. Fama,EugeneF.,andKennethR.French,1992,Thecross‐sectionofexpectedstockreturns,Journal ofFinance47,427‐465. 90 Fama,EugeneF.,andKennethR.French,2001,Disappearingdividends:Changingfirm characteristicsorlowerpropensitytopay?,JournalofFinancialEconomics60,3‐44. Fama,EugeneF.,andKennethR.French,2002,Testingtradeoffandpeckingorderpredictions aboutdividendsanddebt,ReviewofFinancialStudies15,1‐37. Fama,EugeneF.,andKennethR.French,2005,Financingdecisions:Whoissuesstock?,Journalof FinancialEconomics76,549‐582. Fang,Lily,VictoriaIvashina,andJoshLerner,2010,Unstableequity?Combiningbankingwith privateequityinvesting,HarvardBusinessSchoolworkingpaper. Faulkender,Michael,2005,Hedgingormarkettiming?,Selectingtheinterestrateexposureof corporatedebt,JournalofFinance60,931‐962. Ferris,StephenP.,NilanjanSen,andHoPeiYui,2006,GodsavetheQueenandherdividends: CorporatepayoutsintheUK,JournalofBusiness79,1149‐1173. Fischer,Stanley,andRobertC.Merton,1984,Macroeconomicsandfinance:Theroleofthestock market,Carnegie‐RochesterConferenceSeriesonPublicPolicy21,57‐108. Flannery,Mark,andKasturiRangan,2006,Partialadjustmenttowardtargetcapitalstructures, JournalofFinancialEconomics79,469‐506. Froot,KennethA.,andEmilM.Dabora,1999,Howarestockpricesaffectedbythelocationoftrade?, JournalofFinancialEconomics53,189‐216. Fuller,KathleenP.,andMichaelA.Goldstein,2011,Dodividendsmattermoreindecliningmarkets? JournalofCorporateFinance17,457‐473. Gabaix,Xavier,2011,ASparsity‐BasedModelofBoundedRationality,NYUSternSchoolofBusiness workingpaper. Gao,Xiaohui,andJayRitter,2010.TheMarketingofSeasonedEquityOfferings.JournalofFinancial Economics97,33‐52. Gaspar,José‐Miguel,MassimoMassa,andPedroMatos,2005,Shareholderinvestmenthorizonsand themarketforcorporatecontrol,JournalofFinancialEconomics76,135‐165. GennaioliNicola,AndreiShleifer,andRobertVishny,2011,Neglectedrisks,financialinnovation, andfinancialfragility,JournalofFinancialEconomics,forthcoming. Gervais,Simon,2010,Capitalbudgetingandotherinvestmentdecisions,in:BehavioralFinance,H. KentBakerandJohnNofsinger,eds.(Hoboken:Wiley). Gervais,Simon,J.B.Heaton,andTerrenceOdean,2010,Overconfidence,compensationcontracts, andcapitalbudgeting,JournalofFinance,forthcoming. 91 Gervais,Simon,andTerrenceOdean,2001,Learningtobeoverconfident,ReviewofFinancial Studies14,1‐27. Gider,Jasmine,andDirkHackbarth,2010,Financingdecisions,in:BehavioralFinance,H.Kent BakerandJohnNofsinger,eds.(Hoboken:Wiley). Gilchrist,Simon,CharlesHimmelberg,andGurHuberman,2005,Dostockpricebubblesinfluence corporateinvestment?,JournalofMonetaryEconomics52,805‐827. Gitman,LawrenceJ.,andJohnR.Forrester,Jr.,1977,Asurveyofcapitalbudgetingtechniquesused bymajorUSfirms,FinancialManagement6,66‐71. Goel,AnandM.,andAnjanV.Thakor,2008,Overconfidence,leadershipselection,andcorporate governance,JournalofFinance63,2737‐2784. Golbe,DevraL.,andLawrenceJ.White,1988,Atimeseriesanalysisofmergersandacquisitionsin theUSeconomy,in:AlanJ.Auerbach,ed.,CorporateTakeovers:CausesandConsequences (NBER:UniversityofChicagoPress). Gompers,PaulA.,JoyIshii,andAndrewMetrick,2003,Corporategovernanceandequityprices, QuarterlyJournalofEconomics118,107‐155. Gompers,PaulA.,andJoshLerner,2003,Thereallylong‐runperformanceofinitialpublicofferings: Thepre‐Nasdaqevidence,JournalofFinance58,1355‐1392. Graham,JohnR.,1999,DukeUniversityCFOoutlooksurvey1999Q2, http://www.duke.edu/~jgraham/99q2/q299ind.htm Graham,JohnR.,2000,Howbigarethetaxbenefitsofdebt?,JournalofFinance55,1901‐1941. Graham,JohnR.,andCampbellR.Harvey,2001,Thetheoryandpracticeofcorporatefinance: Evidencefromthefield,JournalofFinancialEconomics60,187‐243. Graham,JohnR.,CampbellR.Harvey,andShivaRajgopal,2005,Theeconomicimplicationsof corporatefinancialreporting,JournalofAccountingandEconomics40,3‐73. Greenwood,Robin,2008,Excesscomovementofstockreturns:Evidencefromcross‐sectional variationinNikkei225weights,ReviewofFinancialStudies21,1153‐1186. Greenwood,Robin,SamuelHanson,andJeremyC.Stein,2010,Agap‐fillingtheoryofcorporatedebt maturitychoice”,JournalofFinance65,993‐1028. Greenwood,Robin,andSamuelHanson,2010,Issuerqualityandcorporatebondreturns,Working paper. Greenwood,Robin,andSamuelHanson,2011,Shareissuanceandfactortiming,JournalofFinance, forthcoming. 92 Greenwood,Robin,andDimitriVayanos,2010,Pricepressureinthegovernmentbondmarket, AmericanEconomicReview100,585‐590. Grinblatt,Mark,andChuanYangHwang,1989,Signalingandthepricingofnewissues,Journalof Finance44,393‐420. Grossman,SanfordJ.,andOliverD.Hart,1988,Oneshare‐onevoteandthemarketforcorporate control,JournalofFinancialEconomics20,175‐202. Guedes,Jose,andTimOpler,1996,Thedeterminantsofthematurityofcorporatedebtissues, JournalofFinance51,1809‐1833. Guedj,Ilan,andDavidScharfstein,2008,Organizationalscopeandinvestment:Evidencefromthe drugdevelopmentstrategiesofbiopharmaceuticalfirms,MITSloanworkingpaper. Hackbarth,Dirk,2009,Determinantsofcorporateborrowing:Abehavioralperspective,Journalof CorporateFinance15,389‐411. Hall,BrianJ.,andKevinJ.Murphy,2002,Stockoptionsforundiversifiedexecutives,Journalof AccountingandEconomics33,3‐42. Harris,Lawrence,andEitanGurel,1986,Priceandvolumeeffectsassociatedwithchangesinthe S&P500list:Newevidencefortheexistenceofpricepressures,JournalofFinance41,815‐ 829. Harris,Milton,andArturRaviv,1985,Asequentialsignalingmodelofconvertibledebtcallpolicy, JournalofFinance40,1263‐1281. Harris,Milton,andArturRaviv,2008,Atheoryofboardcontrolandsize,ReviewofFinancial Studies21,1797‐1832. Hart,Oliver,2008,EconomicaCoaselecture:Referencepointsandthetheoryofthefirm, Economica75,404‐411. Hart,Oliver,andJohnMoore,1990,Propertyrightsandthenatureofthefirm,JournalofPolitical Economy98,1119‐1158. Heaton,J.B.,2002,Managerialoptimismandcorporatefinance,FinancialManagement31,33‐45. Henderson,BrianJ.,NarasimhanJegadeesh,andMichaelS.Weisbach,2006,Worldmarketsfor raisingnewcapital,JournalofFinancialEconomics82,63‐101. Hermalin,BenjaminE.,andMichaelS.Weisbach,2003,Boardsofdirectorsasanendogenously determinedinstitution:Asurveyoftheeconomicliterature,EconomicPolicyReview9,7‐ 26. Hietala,Pekka,StevenN.Kaplan,andDavidT.Robinson,2003,Whatisthepriceofhubris?Using takeoverbattlestoinferoverpaymentsandsynergies,FinancialManagement32,1‐32. 93 Hirshleifer,David,AngieLow,andSiewHongTeoh,2010,AreoverconfidentCEOsbetter innovators?,UniversityofCaliforniaatIrvineworkingpaper. Hirshleifer,DavidandIvoWelch,2002,Aneconomicapproachtothepsychologyofchange: Amnesia,inertia,andimpulsiveness,JournalofEconomicsandManagementStrategy11, 379‐421. Holmstrom,Bengt,1982,Managerialincentiveproblems–adynamicperspective,republishedin 1999,ReviewofEconomicStudies66,169‐82. Hong,Harrison,JiangWang,andJailinYu,2008,Firmsasbuyersoflastresort,JournalofFinancial Economics88,119‐145. Hovakimian,Armen,2006,Areobservedcapitalstructuresdeterminedbyequitymarkettiming?, JournalofFinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis41,221‐243. Hovakimian,Armen,TimOpler,andSheridanTitman,2001,Thedebt‐equitychoice,Journalof FinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis36,1‐24. Hu,Xing,JunPan,andJiangWang,2011,NoiseasInformationforIlliquidity,PrincetonUniversity workingpaper. Huang,Rongbing,andJayRitter,2009,Testingtheoriesofcapitalstructureandestimatingthe speedofadjustment,JournalofFinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis44,237‐271. Huddart,Steven,MarkLang,andMichelleH.Yetman,2009,“Volumeandpricepatternsarounda stock’s52‐weekhighsandlows:Theoryandevidence,”ManagementScience55,16‐31. Ikenberry,David,JosefLakonishok,andTheoVermaelen,1995,Marketunderreactiontoopen marketsharerepurchases,JournalofFinancialEconomics39,181‐208. Ikenberry,David,JosefLakonishok,andTheoVermaelen,2000,StockrepurchasesinCanada: Performanceandstrategictrading,JournalofFinance55,2373‐2398. Jain,BharatA.,andOmeshKini,1994,Thepost‐issueoperatingperformanceofIPOfirms,Journalof Finance49,1699‐1726. Jensen,MichaelC.,1986,Agencycostsoffree‐cash‐flow,corporatefinance,andtakeovers,American EconomicReview76,323‐329. Jensen,MichaelC.,2005,Agencycostsofovervaluedequity,FinancialManagement34,5‐19. Jensen,MichaelC.,andWilliamMeckling,1976,Theoryofthefirm:Managerialbehavior,agency costsandownershipstructure,JournalofFinancialEconomics3,305‐360. Jensen,MichaelC.,andRichardS.Ruback,1983,Themarketforcorporatecontrol:Thescientific evidence,JournalofFinancialEconomics11,5‐50. 94 Jenter,Dirk,2005,Markettimingandmanagerialportfoliodecisions,JournalofFinance60,1903‐ 1949. John,Kose,andJosephWilliams,1985,Dividends,dilution,andtaxes:Asignallingequilibrium, JournalofFinance40,1053‐1070. Jung,Kooyul,YongCheolKim,andReneM.Stulz,1996,Timing,investmentopportunities, managerialdiscretion,andthesecurityissuedecision,JournalofFinancialEconomics42, 159‐185. Kahneman,Daniel,2003,Mapsofboundedrationality:Psychologyforbehavioraleconomics, AmericanEconomicReview93,1449‐1475. Kahneman,Daniel,andAmosTversky,1979,Prospecttheory:Ananalysisofdecisionunderrisk, Econometrica47,263‐291. Kaplan,StevenN.,MarkKlebanov,andMortenSorenson,2011,WhichCEOcharacteristicsand abilitiesmatter?,JournalofFinance,forthcoming. Kaplan,StevenN.,andPerStromberg,2003,Financialcontractingtheorymeetstherealworld:An empiricalanalysisofventurecapitalcontracts,ReviewofEconomicStudies70,281‐315. Kaplan,StevenN.,andMichaelWeisbach,1992,Thesuccessofacquisitions:Evidencefrom divestitures,JournalofFinance47,107‐138. Kaustia,Markku,2004,Market‐wideimpactofthedispositioneffect:EvidencefromIPOtrading volume,JournalofFinancialMarkets7,207‐235. Kaustia,Markku,2010a,Dispositioneffect,in:BehavioralFinance:Investors,Corporations,and Markets,H.KentBakerandJohnR.Nofsinger,eds.,(Hoboken,NJ:Wiley) Kaustia,Markku,2010b,Prospecttheoryandthedispositioneffect,JournalofFinancialand QuantitativeAnalysis45,791‐812. Kayhan,Ayla,andSheridanTitman,2004,Firms’historiesandtheircapitalstructures,NBER workingpaperno.10526. Keynes,JohnMaynard,1936,TheGeneralTheoryofEmployment,Interest,andMoney,(London: Macmillan). Kindleberger,Charles,2000,Manias,Panics,andCrashes,(NewYork:Wiley). Klein,PeterG.,2001,Weretheacquisitiveconglomeratesinefficient?,RANDJournalofEconomics 32,745‐761. Kolasinski,Adam,andXuLi,2010,DoindependentdirectorsrestrainoverconfidenceCEOs?, UniversityofWashingtonworkingpaper. 95 Kothari,S.P.,andJayShanken,1997,Book‐to‐market,dividendyield,andexpectedmarketreturns: Atime‐seriesanalysis,JournalofFinancialEconomics44,169‐203. Krishnamurphy,Arvind,2002,Thebond/oldbondspread,JournalofFinancialEconomics66,463‐ 506. Kruger,Philipp,AugustinLandier,andDavidThesmar,2011,TheWACCfallacy:Therealeffectsof usingauniquediscountrate,ToulouseSchoolofEconomicsworkingpaper. LaPorta,Rafael,1996,Expectationsandthecross‐sectionofstockreturns,JournalofFinance51, 1715‐1742. LaPorta,Rafael,JosefLakonishok,AndreiShleifer,andRobertVishny,1997,Goodnewsforvalue stocks:Furtherevidenceonmarketefficiency,JournalofFinance52,859‐874. Lakonishok,Josef,AndreiShleifer,andRobertW.Vishny,1994,Contrarianinvestment, extrapolation,andrisk,JournalofFinance49,1541‐1578. Lamont,Owen,2000,Investmentplansandstockreturns,JournalofFinance55,2719‐2745. Lamont,Owen,andJeremyStein,2006.Investorsentimentandcorporatefinance:Microandmacro, AmericanEconomicReview96(2),147‐151 Landier,Augustin,andDavidThesmar,2009,Financialcontractingwithoptimisticentrepreneurs, ReviewofFinancialStudies22,117‐150. Lang,Larry,andReneStulz,1994,Tobin’sq,corporatediversificationandfirmperformance, JournalofPoliticalEconomy102,1248‐1280. Langer,EllenJ.,andJaneRoth,1975,HeadsIwintailsit’schance:Theillusionofcontrolasa functionofthesequenceofoutcomesinapurelychancetask,JournalofPersonalityand SocialPsychology32,951‐955. Larwood,Laurie,andWilliamWhittaker,1977,Managerialmyopia:Self‐servingbiasesin organizationalplanning,JournalofAppliedPsychology62,194‐198. Leary,Mark,andMichaelR.Roberts,2005,Dofirmsrebalancetheircapitalstructures?,Journalof Finance60,2575‐2619. Leland,Hayne,andDavidPyle,1977,Informationalasymmetries,financialstructure,andfinancial intermediation,JournalofFinance32,371‐387. Lerner,Joshua,1994,Venturecapitalistsandthedecisiontogopublic,JournalofFinancial Economics35,293‐316. Li,Wei,andErikLie,2006,Dividendchangesandcateringincentives,JournalofFinancial Economics80,293‐308. 96 Lintner,John,1956,Distributionofincomesofcorporationsamongdividends,retainedearnings andtaxes,AmericanEconomicReview46,97‐113. Ljungqvist,Alexander,VikramNanda,andRajdeepSingh,2006,Hotmarkets,investorsentiment, andIPOpricing,JournalofBusiness79,1667‐1702. Ljungqvist,AlexanderandWilliamWilhelm,2005,DoesprospecttheoryexplainIPOmarket behavior?,JournalofFinance60,1759‐1790. Long,John,1978,Themarketvaluationofcashdividends:Acasetoconsider,JournalofFinancial Economics6,235‐264. Loughran,Tim,JayRitter,andKristianRydqvist,1994,Initialpublicofferings:International insights,Pacific‐BasinFinanceJournal2,165‐199. Loughran,Tim,andJayRitter,1995,Thenewissuespuzzle,JournalofFinance50,23‐51. Loughran,Tim,andJayRitter,1997,Theoperatingperformanceoffirmsconductingseasoned equityofferings,JournalofFinance52,1823‐1850. Loughran,Tim,andJayRitter,2000,Uniformlyleastpowerfultestsofmarketefficiency,Journalof FinancialEconomics55,361‐389. Loughran,Tim,andJayRitter,2002,Whydon’tissuersgetupsetaboutleavingmoneyonthetable inIPOs?,ReviewofFinancialStudies15,413‐443. Loughran,Tim,andAnandM.Vijh,1997,Dolong‐termshareholdersbenefitfromcorporate acquisitions?,JournalofFinance52,1765‐90. Lyon,Richard,BradM.Barber,andChih‐LingTsai,1999,Improvedmethodsfortestsoflong‐run abnormalstockreturns,JournalofFinance54,165‐201. Malkiel,Burton,1990,ARandomWalkDownWallStreet,(NewYork:W.W.Norton). Malmendier,Ulrike,andGeoffreyTate,2005,CEOoverconfidenceandcorporateinvestment, JournalofFinance60,2661‐2700. Malmendier,Ulrike,andGeoffreyTate,2008,Whomakesacquisitions?CEOoverconfidenceandthe market’sreaction,JournalofFinancialEconomics89,20‐43. Manove,Michael,andA.JorgePadilla,1999,Banking(conservatively)withoptimists,RANDJournal ofEconomics30,324‐350. March,JamesG.,andZurShapira,1987,Managerialperspectivesonriskandrisktaking, ManagementScience33,1404‐1418. Marsh,Paul,1982,Thechoicebetweenequityanddebt:Anempiricalstudy,JournalofFinance37, 121‐44. 97 Massa,Massimo,UrsPeyer,andZhenxuTong,2005,Limitsofarbitrageandcorporatefinancial policy,INSEADworkingpaper. Matsusaka,JohnG.,1993,Takeovermotivesduringtheconglomeratemergerwave,RANDJournal ofEconomics24,357‐379. McNichols,MaureenF.,andStephenR.Stubben,2008,Doesearningsmanagementaffectfirms’ investmentdecisions?TheAccountingReview83,1571‐1603. Merrow,EdwardW.,KennethE.Phillips,andChristopherW.Myers,1981,Understandingcost growthandperformanceshortfallsinpioneerprocessplants,(SantaMonica,CA:Rand). Mikkelson,WayneH.,MeganPartch,andKenShah,1997,Ownershipandoperatingperformanceof companiesthatgopublic,JournalofFinancialEconomics44,281‐307. Miller,EdwardM.,1977,Risk,uncertainty,anddivergenceofopinion,JournalofFinance32,1151‐ 1168. Miller,MertonH.,andKevinRock,1985,Dividendpolicyunderasymmetricinformation,Journalof Finance40,1031‐1051. Mitchell,MarkL.andErikStafford,2000,Managerialdecisionsandlong‐termstockprice performance,JournalofBusiness73,287‐330. Modigliani,Franco,andMertonH.Miller,1958,Thecostofcapital,corporationfinance,andthe theoryofinvestment,AmericanEconomicReview48,655‐669. Moeller,Sara,FrederikSchlingemann,andRenéStulz,2005,Wealthdestructiononamassive scale?,Astudyofacquiring‐firmreturnsintherecentmergerwave,JournalofFinance60, 757‐782. Morck,Randall,2010,Loyalty,agencyconflicts,andcorporategovernance,in:BehavioralFinance, H.KentBakerandJohnNofsinger,eds.(Hoboken:Wiley). Morck,Randall,AndreiShleifer,andRobertW.Vishny,1990a,Domanagerialobjectivesdrivebad acquisitions?,JournalofFinance45,31‐48. Morck,Randall,AndreiShleifer,andRobertW.Vishny,1990b,Thestockmarketandinvestment:Is themarketasideshow?,BrookingsPapersonEconomicActivity2:1990,157‐215. Morck,Randall,andFanYang,2002,ThemysteriousgrowingvalueofS&P500membership, UniversityofAlbertaworkingpaper. Moskowitz,TobiasJ.,andAnnetteVissing‐Jorgensen,2002,Thereturnstoentrepreneurial investment:Aprivateequitypremiumpuzzle?,AmericanEconomicReview92,745‐778. Muelbroek,Lisa,1992,Anempiricalanalysisofillegalinsidertrading,JournalofFinance47,1661‐ 1699. 98 Myers,StewartC.,1977,Determinantsofcorporateborrowing,JournalofFinancialEconomics5, 147‐175. Myers,StewartC.,andNicholasS.Majluf,1984,Corporatefinancingandinvestmentdecisionswhen firmshaveinformationthatinvestorsdonothave,JournalofFinancialEconomics13,187‐ 221. Ofek,EliandMatthewRichardson,2003,DotComMania:TheriseandfallofInternetstocks,Journal ofFinance58,1113‐1138. Oyer,Paul,andScottSchaeffer,2005,Whydosomefirmsgivestocktoallemployees?,Anempirical examinationofalternativetheories,JournalofFinancialEconomics76,99‐133. Pagano,Marco,FabioPanetta,andLuigiZingales,1998,Whydocompaniesgopublic?,Anempirical analysis,JournalofFinance53,27‐64. Panageas,Stavros,2003,Speculation,overpricing,andinvestment:Theoryandempiricalevidence, MITworkingpaper. Polk,Christopher,andPaolaSapienza,2009,Thestockmarketandcorporateinvestment:Atestof cateringtheory,ReviewofFinancialStudies2009,187‐217. Pontiff,Jeffrey,1996,Costlyarbitrage:Evidencefromclosed‐endfunds,QuarterlyJournalof Economics111,1135‐1151. Pontiff,Jeffrey,andLawrenceD.Schall,1998,Book‐to‐marketratiosaspredictorsofmarket returns,JournalofFinancialEconomics49,141‐160. Porter,MichaelE.,1987,Fromcompetitiveadvantagetocorporatestrategy,HarvardBusiness Review65,43‐59. Rajan,Raghuram,1992,Insidersandoutsiders:Thechoicebetweeninformedandarm’s‐length debt,JournalofFinance47,1367‐1400. Rau,P.Raghavendra,andTheoVermaelen,1998,Glamour,valueandthepost‐acquisition performanceofacquiringfirms,JournalofFinancialEconomics49,223‐253. Ravenscraft,DavidJ.,andFredericM.Scherer,1987,Mergers,Sell‐Offs,andEconomicEfficiency, (Washington,DC:BrookingsInstitution). Rhodes‐Kropf,Matthew,DavidRobinson,andS.Viswanathan,2005,Valuationwavesandmerger activity:Theempiricalevidence,JournalofFinancialEconomics77,561‐604. Rhodes‐Kropf,Matthew,andS.Viswanathan,2004,Marketvaluationandmergerwaves,Journalof Finance59,2685‐2718. 99 Richardson,ScottA.,andRichardG.Sloan,2003,Externalfinancingandfuturestockreturns, UniversityofPennsylvaniaworkingpaper. Ritter,Jay,1991,Thelong‐runperformanceofinitialpublicofferings,JournalofFinance42,365‐ 394. Ritter,Jay,2003,Investmentbankingandsecuritiesissuance,in:GeorgeConstantinides,Milton Harris,ReneStulz,eds.,HandbookoftheEconomicsofFinance,(Amsterdam:North‐ Holland). Rosch,E.H.,1973,Naturalcategories,CognitivePsychology4,328‐350. Roll,Richard,1986,Thehubrishypothesisofcorporatetakeovers,JournalofBusiness59,197‐216. Ross,Stephen,1977,Thedeterminationoffinancialstructure,BellJournalofEconomics8,23‐40. Savor,Pavel,andQiLu,2009,Dostockmergerscreatevalueforacquirers?,JournalofFinance64, 1059‐1095. Scarpetta,Stefano,PhilipHemmings,ThierryTressel,andJaejoonWoo,2002,Theroleofpolicyand institutionsforproductivityandfirmdynamics:Evidencefrommicroandindustrydata, OECDworkingpaper. Schaller,Huntley,1993,Asymmetricinformation,liquidityconstraintsandCanadianinvestment, CanadianJournalofEconomics26,552‐574. Schaller,Huntley,2011,Theeconomiceffectofsentiment,CarletonUniversityworkingpaper. Scharfstein,David,andJeremyStein,1990,Herdbehaviorandinvestment,AmericanEconomic Review80,465‐479. Scheinkman,Jose,andWeiXiong,2003,Overconfidenceandspeculativebubbles,JournalofPolitical Economy111,1183‐1219. Schneider,Christoph,andOliverSpalt,2010,Acquisitionsaslotteries:Domanagerialgambling attitudesinfluencetakeoverdecisions?UniversityofMannheimworkingpaper. Schultz,Paul,2003,Pseudomarkettimingandthelong‐rununderperformanceofIPOs,Journalof Finance58,483‐517. Schultz,Paul,2004,Pseudomarkettimingandthestationarityoftheevent‐generatingprocess, UniversityofNotreDameworkingpaper. Sen,Rik,andRobertTumarkin,2010,Stockingup:Executiveoptimismandshareretention,Hong KongUniversityofScienceandTechnologyworkingpaper. Seyhun,H.Nejat,1992,Whydoesaggregateinsidertradingpredictfuturestockreturns?,Quarterly JournalofEconomics107,1303‐31. 100 Shefrin,Hersh,2000,BeyondGreedandFear,(Boston,MA:HarvardBusinessSchoolPress). Shefrin,Hersh,2001,BehavioralCorporateFinance,JournalofAppliedCorporateFinance14,113‐ 124. Shefrin,Hersh,2006,BehavioralCorporateFinance,(NewYork:McGraw‐Hill). Shefrin,Hersh,2008,EndingtheManagementIllusion,(NewYork:McGraw‐Hill). Shefrin,HershandMeirStatman,1984,Explaininginvestorpreferenceforcashdividends,Journal ofFinancialEconomics13,253‐282. Shefrin,Hersh,andMeirStatman,1985,Thedispositiontosellwinnerstooearlyandrideloserstoo long:Theoryandevidence,JournalofFinance40,770‐790. Shleifer,Andrei,1986,Dodemandcurvesforstocksslopedown?,JournalofFinance41,579‐590. Shleifer,Andrei,2000,Inefficientmarkets:Anintroductiontobehavioralfinance,(Oxford,UK: OxfordUniversityPress). Shleifer,Andrei,andRobertVishny,1997,Thelimitsofarbitrage,JournalofFinance52,35‐56. Shleifer,Andrei,andRobertVishny,2003,Stockmarketdrivenacquisitions,JournalofFinancial Economics70,295‐312. Shleifer,Andrei,andRobertVishny,2010,Unstablebanking,JournalofFinancialEconomics97, 306‐318. Simon,HerbertA.,1955,Abehavioralmodelofrationalchoice,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics69, 99‐118. Skinner,DouglasJ.,andRichardG.Sloan,2002,Earningssurprises,growthexpectations,andstock returnsordon’tletanearningstorpedosinkyourportfolio,ReviewofAccountingStudies7, 289‐312. Sloan,Richard,1996,Dostockpricesfullyreflectinformationinaccrualsandcashflowsabout futureearnings?,TheAccountingReview71,289‐316. Spence,A.Michael,1973,Jobmarketsignaling,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics87,355‐379. Spiess,Katherine,andJohnAffleck‐Graves,1995,Underperformanceinlong‐runstockreturns followingseasonedequityofferings,JournalofFinancialEconomics38,243‐267. Spiess,Katherine,andJohnAffleck‐Graves,1999,Thelong‐runperformanceofstockreturns followingdebtofferings,JournalofFinancialEconomics54,45‐73. Stambaugh,RobertF.,1999,Predictiveregressions,JournalofFinancialEconomics54,375‐421. 101 Statman,Meir,andJamesF.Sepe,1989,Projectterminationannouncementsandthemarketvalue ofthefirm,FinancialManagement18,74‐81. Statman,Meir,andTyzoonT.Tyebjee,1985,Optimisticcapitalbudgetingforecasts:Anexperiment, FinancialManagement14,27‐33. Stein,JeremyC.,1989,Efficientcapitalmarkets,inefficientfirms:amodelofmyopiccorporate behavior,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics104,655‐669. Stein,JeremyC.,1996,Rationalcapitalbudgetinginanirrationalworld,JournalofBusiness69, 429‐455. Stein,JeremyC.,2003,Agency,informationandcorporateinvestment,in:GeorgeConstantinides, MiltonHarris,ReneStulz,eds.,HandbookoftheEconomicsofFinance,(Amsterdam:North‐ Holland). Stigler,GeorgeJ.,1964,Publicregulationofthesecuritiesmarkets,JournalofBusiness37,117‐142. Strack,Fritz,andThomasMussweiler,1997,Explainingtheenigmaticanchoringeffect:Mechanisms ofselectiveaccessibility,JournalofPersonalityandSocialPsychology73,437‐446. Svenson,Ola,1981,Arewealllessriskyandmoreskillfulthanourfellowdrivers?,Acta Psychologica47,143‐148. Teoh,SiewHong,IvoWelch,andT.J.Wong,1998a,Earningsmanagementandthelong‐runmarket performanceofinitialpublicofferings,JournalofFinance53,1935‐74. Teoh,SiewHong,IvoWelch,andT.J.Wong,1998b,Earningsmanagementandthe underperformanceofseasonedequityofferings,JournalofFinancialEconomics50,63‐99. Thaler,RichardH.,1980,Towardsapositivetheoryofconsumerchoice,JournalofEconomic BehaviorandOrganization,1,39‐60. Thaler,RichardH.,1985,Mentalaccountingandconsumerchoice,MarketingScience4,199‐214. Thomas,Jacob,1989,Unusualpatternsinreportedearnings,TheAccountingReview64,773‐787. Titman,Sheridan,K.C.JohnWei,andFeixueXie,2004,Capitalinvestmentsandstockreturns, JournalofFinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis39,677‐700. Townsend,RichardR.,2011,Propagationoffinancialshocks:Thecaseofventurecapital,Dartmouth TuckSchoolofBusinessworkingpaper. Tversky,Amos,andDanielKahneman,1974,Judgmentunderuncertainty:Heuristicsandbiases, Science185,1124‐1130. Tversky,Amos,andDanielKahneman,1991,Lossaversioninrisklesschoice:Areference‐ dependentmodel,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics106,1039‐1061. 102 Viswanathan,S.,andBinWei,2008,Endogenouseventsandlongrunreturns,ReviewofFinancial Studies21,855‐888. Weinstein,NeilD.,1980,Unrealisticoptimismaboutfuturelifeevents,JournalofPersonalityand SocialPsychology39,806‐820. Welch,Ivo,1989,Seasonedofferings,imitationcosts,andtheunderpricingofinitialpublic offerings,JournalofFinance44,421‐449. Welch,Ivo,2004,Stockreturnsandcapitalstructure,JournalofPoliticalEconomy112,106‐131. Welch,Ivo,2009,CorporateFinance:AnIntroduction,(NewJersey:Prentice). Weld,WilliamC.,RoniMichaely,RichardH.ThalerandShlomoBenartzi,2009,Thenominalprice puzzle,JournalofEconomicPerspectives23(2),121‐42. Wurgler,Jeffrey,2011,Ontheeconomicconsequencesofindex‐linkedinvesting,in:W.T.Allen,R. Khurana,J.Lorsch,andG.Rosenfeld,eds.,ChallengestoBusinessintheTwenty‐First Century:TheWayForward(Cambridge:AmericanAcademyofArtsandSciences). Wurgler,Jeffrey,andEkaterinaZuravskaya,2002,Doesarbitrageflattendemandcurvesforstocks?, JournalofBusiness75,583‐608. Yermack,David,1996,Highermarketvaluationofcompanieswithasmallboardofdirectors, JournalofFinancialEconomics40,185‐211. Zhang,Donghang,2004,WhydoIPOunderwritersallallocateextrashareswhentheyexpecttobuy themback?JournalofFinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis39,571‐594. 103