Analysis of Cartel Duration: Evidence from EC Prosecuted Cartels By Oindrila De Centre for Competition Policy and University of East Anglia Section 1: Introduction In recent years theoretical and empirical literature increasingly focus on the duration of cartels for various reasons. First, cartel duration is seen as a possible measure for cartel success where as other measures of cartel success, e.g. overcharge (cartel’s price over and above a competitive benchmark) is difficult to estimate. Second, it is a possible way to determine the characteristics of a cartel or the distinctive features of the market under which they operate by studying the duration of the agreement as a dependent variable rather than the formation of such agreement since cartel population is unknown to us. Third, information on cartel duration is used in some studies in recent years for estimating cartel detection probabilities or for evaluating success of leniency programmes. It may be worth mentioning here that in the theory, the condition for sustainability of collusion is the same as their initial motivation to form such an agreement, namely satisfying the incentive compatibility constraint (ICC). But satisfying ICC may not be a sufficient condition to form a successful collusion in the presence of multiple equilibria. Therefore, it is often argued that effective communication and coordination among firms are important to reach an agreement. Besides, recent empirical literature on cartel duration has started recognising the importance of coordination for sustaining an agreement as well. But the coordination necessary for maintaining a cartel seems different because of the changing nature of the market as well as the changes in the policy environment under which the agreement has to operate. 1 This paper attempts to explore various issues related to cartel duration. First, it discusses the difficulties associated with a clear definition of the cartel duration. Second, it explores some interesting characteristics of the EU prosecuted cartel duration. Last but not the least, this paper attempts to shed some lights on the market characteristics, policy environment and the characteristics of the cartel itself that facilitate longer duration of an agreement. The organization of this paper is as follows. Section 2 reviews the existing literature on this subject and explains the hypotheses of this study. The section starts with the discussion on the lack of clarity in the existing empirical literature about the concepts of cartel formation, stability and durability and the analysis tries to extract a clear definition of cartel duration. Next, it discusses the previous empirical studies on the cartel duration and results obtained. Section 3 puts together some interesting observation on the EC prosecuted cartels. Section 4 discusses the methodology adopted for this analysis. Section 5 describes the variables chosen for this study and the results obtained. Section 6 concludes the chapter. Section 2: Existing Literature As mentioned in the introduction, the theory of collusion revolves around the question when is collusion profitable for the firms? In the repeated game setting1 cooperation may be a possible Nash equilibrium when punishment strategies are credible and subgame perfect equilibrium at every stages of the game. In real world oligopoly, the market is indeed characterized by repeated interactions which raise the possibility of credible retaliation in response to a deviation by one firm in the previous period (trigger strategy). This threat actually induces the firms to adhere to the price profile agreed upon by all the firms in the first place since forgone profit of cooperation in next periods may outweigh the short run gains from deviation in the presence of credible punishment. In formal notation, Firm’s discounted future profit stream under collusion (C) is ∞ πi = ∑δ t πiC = t =0 1 πiC .......(1) 1 −δ Where δ is the discount rate. If the firm deviates, then his future profit stream comprises of two components, immediate gain from deviation (D) and discounted future loss when 1 The modern economic theory of tacit coordination has drawn heavily from the game theory. Dynamic oligopoly is widely represented by repeated game or super game models. 2 deviation trigger the punishment and all the firms go back to non-cooperative outcome (NC). ∞ π i = π iD + ∑ δ t π iNC = π iD + t =1 δ π iNC .....(2) 1−δ So, the collusive outcome will be supported when the profit stream defined in equation 2 is greater than profit stream defined in equation 1. That is, 1 δ π iC ≥ π iD + π iNC .............(3) 1− δ 1− δ Equation (3) is known as equilibrium condition or incentive compatibility constraint which makes cooperation profitable for the firms. Therefore, when the ICC is violated, the agreement becomes unstable and the firms go back to their competitive equilibrium forever. Friedman (1971) also showed that when firms are sufficiently patient (discount factor close to one), tacit collusion is indeed an optimal outcome. But the problem associated with the theory is the existence of multiple equilibria in repeated games which may or may not involve cooperation. So the firms involved in tacit collusion may or may not reach the joint profit maximizing outcome and practically it is really hard to choose the right equilibrium without communication. But theoretical literature has not yet been successful in analyzing how firms reach a particular agreement through coordination among themselves, tacitly or explicitly. It is important to mention here that explicit collusion definitely has an advantage over tacit collusion in this regard. Effective communication and systematic coordination among firms can achieve the goal of joint profit maximization which is difficult without direct communication. Therefore, what comes out of the above discussion is that the incentive compatibility constraint may very well explain the stability of cartels where the stability can be defined as the cartel’s ability to raise prices above the competitive level; but it can not fully explain the formation of collusive agreement since there is a lack of systematic analysis how the particular agreement is reached. Moreover, the theoretical and empirical literature also sheds some lights on the punishment strategies of the firms. Other than adopting grim strategy, colluding firms may prefer to go back to the collusive phase after the punishment starts without the existence of renegotiation proof mechanism. If we consider the Green and Porter (1984) model for instance, in the presence of imperfect 3 information, the firms will retaliate when the demand is low and will revert back to the collusive equilibrium after certain periods of time. So price wars can be observed in the equilibrium path which may actually sustain cartel agreements. In the empirical studies, we do observe price wars as a reaction of cheating but that does not end the collusion forever. Firms renegotiate through frequent meetings which may take them back to the collusive phase (Genesove and Mullin 2001 for instance). Duration analysis of a cartel provides us this whole picture of a cartel life which may or may not go through these competitive phases and still sustained a long agreement through effective monitoring and coordination mechanism. Therefore as a concept, cartel formation and duration seems to be much closer to each other compared to the concept of cartel stability. Both formation and duration require effective coordination among firms. But the objective of coordination is different in both the cases. In the former case, firm’s objective is to reach a successful agreement and here the coordination is static in nature where as duration of collusion requires dynamic coordination since the objective is to monitor and punish the deviators successfully and renegotiate the terms in the constantly changing market conditions. Very few empirical studies explicitly discuss the difficulties associated with the definition of cartel duration and how it is different from stability and cartel formation. (Connor 2005) mentioned about this lack of clarity in the literature about the possible difference between cartel stability and durability. According to his definition stability refers to the low variation in cartel discipline, where discipline may be the closeness between cartels’ selling price and theoretical monopoly price which is exactly the same as mentioned above. On the other hand, longevity or duration of a cartel measures the lifespan of a cartel or, if it has more than one, the length of time of one episode. But there is practical problem in defining duration as length of an episode, especially for the illegal cartels. As Suslow (2005) points out, the Green and Porter (1984) type equilibrium punishment price war is observationally very similar to the price war arising from actual breakdown of a cartel. So, there is always a possibility of a misjudgement of the length of each episode. That is probably why; the recent empirical studies on private international cartels generally rely on the overall duration of an agreement rather than the length of each episode. 4 Moreover, if we observe the empirical studies closely, this demarcation between cartel stability and duration is not followed consistently. Boltova, Connor and Miller (2006) defined stability as number of cartel episodes in a product market and used cartel duration as an explanatory variable for the analysis. (Dick 1996) on the other hand measured stability by length of each cartel episodes which is actually the measurement of cartel duration according to Connor’s definition. The exceptions are case studies on cartel stability. Though unavailability of sufficient data limit the studies within very few cartels, but the analysis are quite rich in most of the cases Porter (1983), Ellison (1994) on JEC cartel; Levenstein (1996, 1997) on the bromine cartel; Gupta (1997, 2001) on the tea cartel; De Roos (2006) on lysine cartel etc .These studies unequivocally defined stability as the departure from collusive outcome and tried to model and empirically test price war. This lack of clarity in the definition of cartel duration can be problematic in determining the factors responsible for cartel duration and the interpretation of their possible effects. Despite the fact the some studies looked at cartel duration though the primary objective was to study formation or stability of a cartel (Hay and Kelly 1974, Dick 1996 for instance), I will only review the literature where the primary objective is to study cartel duration. (Jacquemin, Nambu at al 1981) first developed a model of cartel duration and tested the model with the data from the Japanese legal export cartels between 1967 and 1972. (Marquez 1994) also tested the same model using international cartel data (active over 1888-1984). Jacquemin et al used simple regression analysis where as Marquez relied on Amemiya’s Maxumum Likelihood (ML) estimates. Their model starts with the incentive compatibility constraint of the firms. According to the model, optimal durability depends on the growth rate of demand and the first period profit relative to the initial cost of cartelization. The condition is that the growth of demand should be less than the growth of cartelization cost and the initial profit level of cartelization should be greater than the initial cost of forming a cartel. Initial cost may depend upon the market concentration, Government encouragement, technical difficulties such as areas of collusion, range of agreements etc and homogeneity of the product. The result shows that the growth rate of the demand is inversely related to the time duration of 5 cartel. But authors did not found this result significant. The four-firm concentration ratio, number of price/quantity agreements relative to the total number of agreements in the sector (representing range of agreements) have negative significant effect on duration where as homogeneous product and the number of cartels from mixed geographic areas to total number of cartels (again representing range of agreements) has positive significant effect on duration. Marquez found positive relationship between concentration, market shares and duration but negative relationship between demand growth and duration. Previous attempt to cartelize had no significant effect on the cartel duration. These two papers reveal that cartel duration is very much dependent upon the coordination mechanism and changes in the market conditions as discussed earlier. But it is hard to interpret these variables in terms of illegal cartels. But the analysis of legal cartels provides us useful information about the market conditions under which they operate. It also indicates that the policy environment is very crucial for the working of a cartel. Moreover, more sophisticated econometric methods are now available for the duration analysis. Next, we will move to the studies those employ the survival analysis for studying cartel duration. In recent years, Suslow (2005), Zimmerman and Connor (2005), Levenstein and Suslow (2006) used Cox proportional hazard regression (discussed later) for this purpose. Brenner (2005) used weibull hazard model for evaluating the success of leniency programme. The explanatory variables used in his study are number of firms, number of countries, industry dummies and leniency and self reporting dummies and found no significant result. One of the reasons may be it was too early to evaluate the effect of leniency policy, especially the improvement that happened in 2002. Suslow (2005) used the data of the inter-war international cartels where as Zimmerman and Connor (2005), Levenstein and Suslow (2006) used recently prosecuted international cartels data. Since the survival analysis is also used in this study, the detailed methodology for estimation has been provided in the methodology section. It is interesting to discuss the results found from the studies involved recent international cartels. Zimmerman and Connor found that the seller concentration, large number of buyers, business downturn and antitrust sanctions have positive, significant effect on the duration where as number of firms (dummy for more than five firms), overcharges and cultural diversity (number of countries per firm) have significant negative impact on the duration. 6 The most important recent paper is by Levenstein and Suslow. 33 cartels prosecuted in EU, 20 cartels prosecuted in US and 19 cartels prosecuted in both jurisdictions are included in their dataset. They highlighted on the cartel organization as the most important factor for duration. The most interesting finding of their study is that firms’ patience (measured by the average annual interest rate of the US treasury bills with 3 months maturity) has positive effect on the duration. Discussing cartel organization, they have developed an organization index by summing up 11 dummies representing different aspects of cartel organization (bid rigging, market sharing, standardized product, terms other than price, distribution chain, trade association, information exchange, retaliation, compensation, exclusion, organizational hierarchy). They found organizational index has a significant positive effect on cartel duration. But the problem is that the elements of this index are so diverse that it is really difficult to interpret the result. The authors also found that negative GDP trend gap (measured by the demand instability) has negative effect on the duration. It is important to mention here that both the papers used aggregate level GDP or GNI data for the demand variable which may not always represent industry performance. Section 3: EU Prosecuted Cartel Cases The sample database consists of explicit collusion cases from 1990 to 2007. The number of cases in this database is 94. The definition of explicit collusion used here is much broader than what is defined in the law. The database includes Article 81 (1) infringements, Article 81 (3) exemptions with conditions, negative clearance, readopted cases. Moreover I have included the cartel cases under Article 65 of the European Coal and Steel Treaty 1951. This database does not include other horizontal agreements like joint ventures etc without any clear objective to collude or exemptions without any conditions cases. The data are collected from the Commission’s decisions published in the Official Journals, press releases, Court of First Instance and European Court of Justice Judgments. For the purpose of this analysis, I have dropped one renewal and 4 radopted cases from my analysis. Moreover, the cartel members in the French beer case (2004) negotiated an armistice agreement which never came into effect. I have dropped 7 this case from my duration analysis. Four understanding, we can divide the remaining 88 cases in five different groups on the basis of Commission’s decision type: Table 1: Types of Decisions Category Number of Cartels Exemption With Conditions/ Obligations 9 Infringement Art. 65 ECSC treaty 3 Infringement Art.81 with fine 63 Infringement Art.81 with fine and Infringement Art. 82 5 Infringement Art.81 without fine 8 Total 88 So, there are total 76 cases with Article 81(1) infringement 8 of them did not pay any fine (ANSAC soda ash case in 1990, Quantel International, Scottish Salmon board and UK agricultural tractors in 1992, CNSD in 1993, Trans-Atlantic Agreement in 1994 and COAPI in 1995, EATA in 1999). There are two reasons behind this. Either the cartels involve only associations of under takings (4 cases) or the firms applied for notification but did not fulfil the requirements (4 cases). 5 out of 76 cartels are also charged with infringement of Article 82 as one of the undertakings or association of undertakings abused its dominant position in the market. There were 15 cases came before Commission with notifications for negative clearance. Commission cleared 7 cases with changes in the proposed agreements (termed as conditions/obligations) where as 8 cases infringed Article 81. Next, I will consider the duration of EC prosecuted cartels which is the centre of our analysis. For the purpose of imposition of fine or granting exemption, it is very much important for the Commission to define the duration of the infringement. On the basis of this information, we have extracted data on the duration which is proven by the Commission in the court2. It is to be noted that it is not always necessary that the cartel is in operation when the Commission heard about the agreement. So my sample includes the cases where the cartel died naturally but later detected by the authority. I have used the natural life time of the cartel as duration, not the time till it was detected. For the 2 There are few changes in the duration of the individual cartel members ruled by CFI and ECJ. We have not taken those into consideration since it did not affect the overall duration of the cartels. 8 negative clearance/ exemption cases, we have defined duration as from the starting of the agreement till the end of exemption period. The Commission divides the active years of cartels in three different categories for the purpose of fines- short duration (less than one year), medium duration (one to five years) and long duration (more than 5 years). In the figure below we have presented the duration of cartels in years. If a cartel existed for more than 6 months, it is considered to be live for one year. Though the graph is showing four cases with 1 year duration, in fact three of them lasted for less than one year which can be considered as short duration according to the Commission’s definition. 30 cases had medium duration (1-5 years) and majority of the cartel cases (55) have duration more than five years. The average duration of the cartels is 8.93 years where the median life is 7. Figure 1: Proven Cartel Duration of the DG Competition Cases 0 Number of Cases 5 10 15 EU Prosecuted Cartel Duration (Proven in the Court) 1 5 9 13 17 21 Duration (In Years) 25 29 33 37 Beside the number of years of duration proven in the court, some interesting information is available about the actual duration of the cartels as it may not be the same. The Commission has acknowledged the fact that many cartels have existed before the starting dates finalized by them, but they could not produce hard evidences to prove them in the court. The Commission in fact has reported the suspected starting year for the 18 cartels. 9 Moreover, the Commission has also indicated the existence of the cartels much prior to the proven starting date for 9 cases but could not confirm the actual starting date. On the basis of the information provided by the Commission, we can plot the suspected duration vis a vis the duration proven in the court for these 18 cases. Figure 2: Proven duration vis-à-vis Suspected Duration Proven vis-a-vis Suspected Duration 100 90 Suspected Duration (in years) 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 Proven duration (in years) As we can see from this scatter, suspected duration in many of these 18 cases are significantly higher than the proven duration. In fact the suspected duration on an average is 2.5 times more than the duration proved legally by the Commission. Another interesting aspect of the EC cartel duration is that it is not symmetric across the firms or across the agreements (market sharing, information exchange etc) or the subproduct/ geographic markets. Within one cartel, different firms entered into or exit from the cartels at different points of time. Similarly, firms added or subtracted some agreements within the overall agreement concerned. For example, they may start information exchange agreement or other horizontal restrictions long after the main price 10 fixing agreement has started working. The cases may also involve different sub products or sub-geographic markets. Duration can be different for these dimensions as well. The table below reveals the number of cases with such special characteristics. There are five cases where sub-agreements came into operation after the main agreements started operating. They are Jahrhundertvertrag, Cement, Dutch Industrial Gases, Dutch Electrotechnical Equipments and Spanish Tobacco. The reason may be more agreements became necessary other than only price fixing or market sharing agreements to enforce the cartels successfully. The database also contains three cases where the cartel has different duration for different sub-product markets (Vitamin, Haberdashery needle, Specialty graphite) and one cases where there is different duration for different geographic markets (industrial thread) Table 2: Different Dimensions of Duration Duration Different members with different duration Number of Cases 33 Different sub-agreements with different duration Different sub-product markets with different duration 5 3 Different geographic markets with different duration 1 As mentioned before, 33 out of these 88 cases, some cartel members either entered into the cartel late or exit from the cartel early or both. The table below shows that entry occurred in 29 cases, exit in 24 cases and both simultaneously occurred in 21 cases. Late entry or early exit or both can have a destabilizing effect on the collusion. So it will be interesting to see whether frequent entry or exit had any affect on the overall duration of the EC cartels. Table 3: Entry into and Exit from the Cartel Entry/ Exit Number of Cases Entry into Cartels 29 Exit from the Cartel 24 Both Entry and Exit 20 Last but not the least, Table 4 summarizes the different causes of detection of these cartels. I have reported the primary method of detection reported in the documents. As we know, Commission mostly initiates investigation because of some unofficial complains, from the consumer associations or competitors outside the cartel or press reports. These primary sources are rarely mentioned in the documents. So the complain category in the 11 table strictly implies the formal complaint made by these organisations. Also, the firms may reveal another secret cartel during the investigation (For example, information for the Carbon and Graphite and Specialty Graphite cartel from Graphite Electrodes cartel case, information for the Netherlands beer and the French beer cartels from the Belgium Beer cartel investigation and information for the PVC cartel from a prior investigation in another thermoplastic product market). Since Amnesty plus reward is not available in the EU, it is not clear whether this reveals the success of leniency programme or the efficiency of the Commission in the investigation procedure. I have categorized these “follow up” cases in the Commission’s investigation category. The firms also notify their agreements seeking negative clearance. The Commission investigates the anticompetitive effects of those notices (15 cases). It is important to mention here that it is very difficult to distinguish between the natural causes of death of a cartel from the ones detected by the authorities, especially under the leniency regime. Firms come forward to bust a cartel implies cheating on the other cartel members. Similarly, a cartel can also be termed as a failure if it becomes visible to its competitors or downstream consumers. This is important because it is often argued that the duration analysis of the prosecuted cartels mostly reveal the time till detection, not the actual life-time of a cartel. But it seems from the above discussion, there is a thin line between the two concepts when it comes to the privately enforced collusion. Table 4: Cause of Cartel Detection Causes of Detection Number of Cases Commission’s Investigation US Investigation Leniency Notification Complain Total 29 9 20 15 15 88 Section 4: Methodology for Duration Analysis - Cox Proportional Hazard and Competing Risk Model3 As mentioned earlier, Survival Analysis is the most popular method applied for studying cartel duration. Survival model is known as event history model where the centre of 3 The definitions of the basic survival analysis and Cox Proportional Hazard Model are drawn heavily from Kiefer (1988) 12 analysis is the occurrence of an event of interest (here the end of a collusive agreement) and causes of such occurrence. Now, the question is why simple regression analysis is inadequate for the analysis of cartel duration? Three important reasons are discussed in the literature. First, the data are often censored (mostly right-censored) since the analysis time may end without the occurrence of any event. It implies that for some observations the true value exceeds the observed value. Though earlier literature on the survival analysis put too much emphasis on the censoring as the special feature of the survival data, but now censored normal regression analysis can be used to cope with this problem successfully. Second, for the analysis of life-span data, it makes more sense to condition on the history up to certain point. This is probably the most important reason for using survival analysis instead of simple regression analysis. Third, lifetime data is clearly not normally distributed. Duration data in general are positively skewed, only with positive values and high variation which is clearly not a symmetric distribution like normal. Moreover, occasionally the survival distribution is bimodal. The standard approach that can be used for such data is to apply normal distribution after logarithmic transformation of the duration variable but that often makes the original variable left skewed rather than right skewed. Therefore, for survival data, normal regression may not provide robust results. From the above analysis, it is clear why survival model has increasingly being used to study cartel duration. There is no right censored survival time in our analysis. So, the methodology presented here is based on the non-censored observations. The dependent variable in this survival model is cartel life which is measured in years. Suppose T is a random variable which depicts the length of the spell or the survival time of a cartel. The cumulative distribution function of the survival time is given by F(t) = Pr(T<t) which is also known as failure function.4 The failure function specifies the probability that the random variable T is less than some given value t. The probability density function is given by f(t)= dF(t)/dt. But for duration analysis, we are more interested in the survival function which is given by ∞ S (t ) = Pr ob(T ≥ t ) = ∫ f ( x)dx = 1 − F (t ) …….. (1) t 4 In the discussion of duration data, F(t)= Pr(T<t) is used instead of Pr(T≤ t). See Kiefer 1988, Page 650. 13 It gives the probability that the random variable T will equal or exceed the value t.5As mentioned earlier, the central concept of the duration analysis is not the unconditional probability of an event taking place, but the conditional probability of the occurrence of the event (Kiefer 1988). For example for this analysis, our interest is not in the probability that a cartel lasted for 11 years but in the probability that the cartel breaks down at the 11th year given that it survived 10 years. The event history data uses hazard rate function instead of survivor function for the purpose of regression. This probability that the cartel agreement ends at time t given that it has survived until that time is defined by hazard function h(t ) = Lim ∆t → 0 prob(t ≤ T ≤ t + ∆t | T ≥ t) f (t ) f (t ) = = ……….. (2) ∆t S (t ) 1 − F (t ) Hazard function in fact provides us the rate of instantaneous transition from one state to another. An important characteristic of hazard function is that we can estimate duration dependence by differentiating it. A positive duration dependence (dh(t)/dt>0 at t=t*) implies that hazard rises with time and negative duration dependence means just the opposite. The duration dependence can be observed from the estimation of the integrated hazard or cumulative hazard which is given by t H (t ) = ∫ h(u )du A convex integrated hazard implies that the hazard itself is increasing 0 with time or positive duration dependence where as a concave integrated hazard implies negative duration dependence. Moreover, from equation (2), it is clear that the shape of the hazard function very much depends on the shape of the underlying probability density function. But, one of the advantages of the hazard model is that, it is possible to estimate the hazard rate without assuming any specific probability distribution if the hazards are proportional.6 The proportional hazard assumption states that changing an explanatory variable only has the effect of multiplying the hazard rate by a constant. So, in the proportional hazard model, the hazard function is given by h(t , z ) = h0 (t ). exp( β z ) 5 6 We are assuming no right censoring in the data. Proposed by Cox (1972) 14 Where as h0 (τ) is the baseline hazard function and exp (βz) is a positive function, independent of time which incorporates number of covariates which affects the hazard ratio. Though other forms can also be used, exponential form is the most widely used one. To obtain the estimate for L1 (β), we need a specific form for baseline hazard rate. Cox (1972) proposed a partial maximum likelihood estimator without imposing restriction on baseline rate. Cox’s estimator allows for right censoring and it maximizes N exp( β z) exp( β Zr ) ∑ L =∑ i= 1 r∈ R (ti ) Where R (t) is the set of cartel’s at risk just prior to t (cartel dissolution). So if there is no information on baseline hazard, only the order of duration provides the information about the unknown coefficients (Suslow 2005). It is important to mention here that the dependent variable in survival model shows conditional probability of failure. So the positive (negative) sign of the explanatory variables imply cartel’s dissolution (durability). The z statistic provides the usual level of significance. As proportional hazard model assumes that the covariates have a proportional effect on relative hazard rate, it is also important to test whether the data satisfies the proportionality assumption or not. Section 5: Results On the basis of theoretical predictions, previous empirical analysis and the unique characteristics found in the EC prosecuted cartels, I have chosen the following variables for the purpose of duration analysis. These variables range from cartel’s internal characteristics (types of industry, number of firms, market shares), range of agreements (number of agreements, type of agreements, choice of the geographic markets), monitoring and enforcement (ringleader/price leader, involvement of association) and external market environment (growth rate and fluctuation in demand). I have also included the late entry into the cartel and early exit of the firms from the cartel to see whether these changes in the cartel structure had any effect on the overall duration of the cartels. It is important to mention here that I have also estimated the model with the total duration (proven+ suspected). The results do not change much. So, I have not reported the models here. 15 Duration of the cartel is calculated in years. NUM variable implies the maximum number of firms involved in the particular cartel. The total number of observations is 73 instead of 88 because 15 cases involved association of undertakings. MKTSHR is the total market share covered by the cartel members. I have data for 70 cartel cases. I have developed two dummy variables to indicate the number of agreements negotiated by the cartel members. SINGLE implies either price fixing or market sharing agreement. MIX implies more than one dimension of the agreements. LEADER is the dummy indicating the cartels those involved a ringleader or price-leader for enforcing the agreement where as TRADEASSO captures the effect of trade association support to the firms. I have used number of entrants and exits per year of cartel duration (ENTPY and EXITPY) to capture the effect of entry and exit. Another important variable that can affect the duration of cartel is the market demand. According to the conventional wisdom, demand growth has a positive effect on the cartel duration with high entry barrier. But a recent paper by Capuano (2002) showed that high demand growth can not rule out the possibility of collusion in the presence of Nash reversion punishment and entry is feasible and sustainable in a growing market. Jacquemin et al and Marquez found non-significant negative relationship between demand growth and duration where as Suslow found significant negative relationship. Moreover fluctuating demand causes cartel breakdown because of the uncertainty in the market. Unfortunately DG competition documents rarely provide relevant data on the demand variables. I have extracted turnover data from Eurostat at the two-digit NACE level. But I only have data starting from 1995-96 till 2005-2006 which does not represent the lifespan of many cartels in my database. But the data do provide a rough picture of the growth/ stagnation in the markets concerned. I have calculated linear demand growth (GROWTH) and the coefficient of variation (CV) in demand (CVDEMAND) for the entire period. The expected sign for both CVDEMAND and STDEVL variables are negative but the expected sign for GROWTH is not known. The next group of explanatory variables considered represents the industry classification. The maximum number of cases comes from the chemical sector (23). During this period of study, many firms in the chemical sectors were part of more than one cartels (ADM, Ajinamoto, Akzo Nobel, Atofina, Aventis, BASF, Cheil, Degussa, Desang, Solvay etc) 16 and some of them are also repeat offenders7 (ADM, BASF, Akzo Nobel, Aventis, Degussa etc). Apart from the four Soda ash cartels in 1990 (including one re-adoption case in 2000), all 19 chemical cartels were detected between 2000 and 2007 after the famous discovery of Lysine cartel in 20008. The service group comprises of wide range of services- communication, real estate and renting, community, social and personal services, electricity, gas and water supply service etc. Out of twelve cases in the transport sector, nine belong to water transport, more specifically maritime transport. This sector enjoyed block exemption from Article 81(1) for certain characteristics of the agreements including permission for uniform rates till quite recently. Most of the cases under the heading of metal come from steel industry. In the EU, coal and steel sector was part of European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC) treaty for quite a long time (1951-2001). Three out of this eight metal sector cases are part of the ECSC treaty. The Raw material sector includes plastic and glass products, non-metallic mineral products, paper and paper board and textile products. For the survival analysis, I have used sector dummies for chemical (CHEM), services (SERVICE), Transport (TRANS), raw materials (RAWMATER), metal (MET), food, beverages and tobacco (FBT), Machinery (MACH) and finance (FINANCE). I have used CHEM as the reference group. Every other dummy should be compared around it. Table 5 summarizes the variables used for the study and the expected sign. Table 5: The Variables Used for Survival Analysis ______________________________________________________________________________________ Variable Description Expected Sign (duration) ______________________________________________________________________________________ DURY Duration (in years) TOTALDURY Proven plus suspected duration (in years) NUM (73*) Number of firms - 7 Repeated offenders are those individual or firm who has committed the crime twice (but not simultaneously) 8 ADM’s junior manager informed FBI about the price fixing cartel when FBI was investigating into a possible corporate spying by the Japanese competitor against ADM in 1992. 17 MKTSHR (70*) Total Market share of the cartel + SINGLE Single agreements - MIX More than one agreements + LEADER Ringleader/ Price leader + ASSO Association involved + TRADEASSO Trade Association Support + ENTPY Number of Entrants per year - EXITPY Number of Exit firms per year - DGROWTH Demand Growth (%) ? CVDEMAND Coefficient of Variation in Demand - PROPLENY Proportional of cartel life spent under new policy regime - CHEM Chemical FBT Food, Beverage and tobacco FINANCE Financial services MACH Machinery MET Metals RAWMATER Raw Material SERVICE Services TRANS Land, Water and Air Transport _______________________________________________________________________ _ * Number of observations As revealed from the histogram in section 2, the duration data is bimodal (5, 28). The normality test rejects the null hypothesis. Under this circumstance, Cox proportional hazard function seems a preferred model since it does not assume any underlying distribution. I have also tried censored normal regression taking into account the leftcensored variables (right-censored in the normal regression because the true value is higher than the observed value). The dependent variable is the log of duration because duration can not be negative. The result changes significantly. So, for this purpose, I have relied on the Cox model since normal regression may not provide robust result in the presence of bimodality. Table 6 summarizes the result of the Cox proportional hazard model. The results are given in hazard ratio. Model 1 is estimated with the full set of observations (88). Model 2 includes number of firms (so the number of observations has been reduced to73) and Model 3 is with market share of the cartels (70 observations). Z statistics are provided in the parentheses. The significant variables are markets with asterisk. 18 Table 6: Cox Proportional Hazard Model Variable Model1 Num Model2 (With Firm Model3 (With Number) .9830 (-1.07) Market Share) Mktshr 1.006 (0.92) Leader .7437 (-1.23) .8486 (-0.68) .4693 (-2.47*) Single 1.9148 (2.29)* 1.6194 (1.57) 2.2581 (2.51*) Entpy 4.6802 (4.25*) 4.9783 (3.57*) 5.1236 (4.27*) Expy .2318 (-2.15*) .2540 (-2.03*) .1265 (-2.23*) Propleny 3.8558 (3.68*) 3.9183 (3.06*) 4.6987 (2.91*) Dgrowth 3.5900 (2.76*) 6.820 (2.04*) 3.0804 (3.28*) Cvdemand .0003 (-1.93) .0001 (-1.28) .0000 (-1.23) Fbt 4.6632 (2.87*) 3.2883 (2.05*) 4.2746 (2.36*) Finance 1.8321(1.15) 2.40004 (0.99) 1.7687 (0.80) Mach .8181 (-0.62) .8268 (-0.52) .8146 (-0.54) Met .7369 (-0.80) .8798 (-0.35) .5402 (-1.29) 19 Rawmater 1.0095 (0.02) 1.0225 (0.05) .7281 (-0.63) Service .3181 (-2.25*) .5794 (-0.99) .1359 (-2.70*) Trans 3.4926 (1.89) 4.8149 (2.22*) 11.9609 (2.87*) The important result of this analysis is that it reveals that the cartel external shocks do have a disruptive effect on cartels where as structure of the cartelized market do not have a significant effect on cartel duration. Growing demand has a higher hazard. Stricter policy regime increases the hazard in the market. Number of firms and market share does not have any significant effect on cartel duration. But the changes in the number of firms over the lifetime of the cartel do affect cartel life. The late entry has a disruptive effect where as early exit of some cartel members actually decreases hazard. If the cartels have a price leader or ringleader, the hazard decreases and this result is significant in the last model. The cartels with single agreement as opposed to the mixture of agreements (price fixing, market sharing etc) have shorter duration. Before I conclude, it is important to mention that I had included many other variables in the analysis (number of agreements in a cartel, price fixing, market sharing dummies, association and trade association, geographic market such as global, national or regional cartel and various interactive terms). But the variables were insignificant so I dropped them from the analysis considering low degrees of freedom. The analysis also revealed that the industry specific characteristics also play a major role. I have used these set of dummies as control variable and the variables become insignificant if I drop them from the analysis. Moreover, food, beverage, tobacco cartels and cartels in transport sector reveal significantly higher hazard compared to chemical sector where as service cartels have significantly lower hazard. Section 6: Conclusion This study provides an analysis of the cartel duration of the EC prosecuted cartels. To my knowledge, this is the first study which focuses extensively on the European cartels apart from Brenner (2005) which mainly focussed on the evaluation of the leniency programme. 20 This research tried to explore the duration of the EC prosecuted cartels and identifies certain characteristics that may have affected the duration of these cartels. The hazard model analysis reveals that the changing nature of the market, i.e. demand growth and changes in the policy regime (leniency specially) had significant negative effect on the cartel duration. Moreover cartel’s monitoring mechanism like market leadership or ring leadership improves duration where as single agreement as opposed to multi-dimensional agreements have increased hazard. Another interesting aspect is that the structure of the market (number of firms, market share, nature of agreements) etc does not have any significant effect on the cartel duration. In fact the duration increases with the number of the firms within this sample thought the result is not significant. But it is clear tat the changes in the market structure over the cartel life time do have an effect on cartel duration. Where as late entry of the firms into the cartel have significantly higher hazard, the early exit actually increases the duration of the cartel. Secondly, in recent years, major changes have occurred in the antitrust regime in the Europe, especially within the time period of my research. Leniency policy was introduced in 1996 and amended in 2002 and 2006. Guidelines for fines were introduced in 1998 and modified in 2002 and 2006. Almost no studies have systematically analyzed the impact of new antitrust regime on EC cartel duration. (Brenner 2005) only used time dummy for the period before or after leniency and found no significance on duration. (Harrington and Change 2007) developed a theoretical model which evaluates effect of antitrust policy on cartel duration. The model provides a ground to infer about the unobserved population of cartel from observing the duration of discovered cartels. The result shows more aggressive the detection and conviction policy is, duration of discovered cartels increase in the short run. The preliminary analysis in the present analysis also shows that if higher proportion of cartel life is spent in the stricter policy regime, it has a negative effect on cartel duration. I want to extend this study to incorporate correlated competing risk model for the causes of cartel detection. I want to especially focus on the cartels detected by the leniency application. 21 References Brenner, S. (2005). “An Empirical Study of the European Corporate Leniency Program.” http://www.fep.up.pt/conferences/earie2005/cd_rom/Session%20VII/VII.G/brenner.pdf Bolotova, Y, Connor, J. M. and Miller, D. J. (2006) “Cartel Stability: An Empirical Analysis.” International Industrial Organization Conference. Boston, Massachusetts. 22 Capuano, C (2002). “Demand Growth, Entry and Collusion Sustainability.” Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract_id=326522 Combe, E., Monnier, C. and Legal, R. (2008) Cartels: the Probability of Getting Caught in the European Union. Bruges European Economic Research papers No. 12. Connor, J. M. (2005) "Price-Fixing Overcharges: Legal and Economic Evidence." Staff paper, Purdue University: Cox, D.R. (1972) “Partial Likelihood.” Biometrika. 62(2): 269-276 De Roos, N. (2006). "Examining models of collusion: The market for lysine." International Journal of Industrial Organization 24(6): 1083-1107. Dick, A. R. (1996). "When Are Cartels Stable Contracts? ." Journal of Law and Economics Vol. 39(No. 1 ): 241-283. Ellison, G. (1994). "Theories of Cartel Stability and the Joint Executive Committee." The RAND Journal of Economics 25(1): 37-57. Fine, J.P and Gray, R.J. (1999). “A Proportional Hazards Model for the Subdistribution of a Competing Risk.” Journal of American Statistical Association. 94 (446): 496-509. Friedman, J. W. (1971). "A Non-cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames." The Review of Economic Studies 38(1): 1-12. Genesove, D. and W. P. Mullin (2001). "Rules, Communication, and Collusion: Narrative Evidence from the Sugar Institute Case." The American Economic Review 91(3): 379-398. Green, E. J. and R. H. Porter (1984). "Noncooperative Collusion under Imperfect Price Information." Econometrica 52(1): 87-100. Gupta, B. (1997). "Collusion in the Indian Tea Industry in the Great Depression: An Analysis of Panel Data." Explorations in Economic History 34: 155-173. Gupta, B. (2001). "The International Tea Cartel during the Great Depression, 19291933." The Journal of Economic History 61(1): 144-159. Hay, G. A. and D. Kelley (1974). "An Empirical Survey of Price Fixing Conspiracies " Journal of Law and Economics 17(1): 13-38. 23 Harrington, J and Chang, M.H. (2007).“Modelling the Birth and Death of Cartels with an Application to Evaluating Antitrust Policy." Journal of the European Economic Association, forthcoming. Jacquemin, A., T. Nambu, et al. (1981). "A Dynamic Analysis of Export Cartels: The Japanese Case." The Economic Journal 91(363): 685-696. Kiefer, N. M. (1988). “Economic Duration Data and Hazard Functions” Journal of Economic Literature 26(2): 646-679 Levenstein, M. C. (1996). "Do Price Wars Facilitate Collusion? A Study of the Bromine Cartel before World War I." Explorations in Economic History 33: 107-137. Levenstein, M. C. (1997). "Price Wars and the Stability of Collusion: A Study of the PreWorld War I Bromine Industry." Journal of Industrial Economics 45: 117-137. Levenstein, M. C. and V. Y. Suslow (2006) "Determinants of International Cartel Duration and the Role of Cartel Organization." Ross School of Business Working Paper Series. Lunn, M. and MacNeil, D. (1995). “Applying cox regression to competing risks.” Biometrics. 51:524–532. Marquez, J. (1994). "Life expectancy of international cartels: An empirical analysis." Review of Industrial Organization 9(3): 331-341. Porter, R. H. (1983). "A Study of Cartel Stability: The Joint Executive Committee, 18801886." The Bell Journal of Economics 14(2): 301-314. Posner, R. A. (1970). "A Statistical Study of Antitrust Enforcement." Journal of Law and Economics 13(2): 365-419 Schinkel, M. P. (2007) "Effective Cartel Enforcement in Europe." Amsterdam Centre for Law and Economics Working Paper: Stigler George, J (1964) “Theory of Oligopoly” Journal of Political Economy, Vol.72, No.1, 44-61. Suslow, V. Y. (2005). “Cartel contract duration: empirical evidence from inter-war international cartels.” SSRN. 24 Zimmerman, J. E. and J. M. Connor (2005) "Determinants of Cartel Duration: A CrossSectional Study of Modern Private International Cartels." Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University, West Lafayette, Indiana: 25