PRICING RESOURCE EXTRACTION WITH STOCK EXTERNALITIES Sittidaj Pongkijvorasin

PRICING RESOURCE EXTRACTION WITH STOCK
EXTERNALITIES
Sittidaj Pongkijvorasin
Department of Economics, University of Hawaii, HI, USA; sittidaj@hawaii.edu
Basharat Pitafi
Department of Economics, University of Southern Illinois, Carbondale, USA;
pitafi@siu.edu
James Roumasset
Department of Economics, University of Hawaii, HI, USA; jimr@hawaii.edu
Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the American Agricultural Economics
Association Annual Meeting, Long Beach, California, July 23-26, 2006
Copyright 2006 by Pongkijvorasin, Pitafi, and Roumasset. All rights reserved.
Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by
any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies.
PRICING RESOURCE EXTRACTION WITH STOCK EXTERNALITIES
Pricing resource extraction has drawn substantial attention by economists. According
to the “Washington Consensus” on sustainable development, resource owner should
be required to pay extraction fees accordance with the condition that the efficiency
price of resource equals the sum of its marginal extraction cost, marginal user cost
(MUC), and marginal externality cost (MEC) (Pearce and Markandya, 1989). Failing
to take into account of these components will result in underpricing natural resources
and lead to overharvesting. For example, there is an evidence that, in developing
countries, resources are generally underpriced, failing to account for its scarcity rent,
even not include externality cost (World Bank, 1992). Extensive deforestation in
developing countries is one of the most severe environmental problems in the world
(Repetto 1988).
Forest is one of the resources that have multiple functions. Its direct use values
can draw from timber harvesting. Moreover, it has many other indirect values, for
example, on ground water recharge, or biodiversity, which may even turn out to be
more significant than the timber value. In this article, we focus on forest’s role in
watershed conservation. Forest cover is a critical factor for the soil erosion and water
runoff leading to the downstream sedimentation. In case of sedimentation in stream,
lakes, and reservoirs, it can harm aquatic life, decrease water quality, increase the risk
of flooding, and reduce reservoir storage capacity (Dixon 1997, Barbier 1995). For
forest near coastal area, the sedimentation may affect the nearshore resources
including fish and other aquatic lives, and coral reef (Hodgson and Dixon 1988,
Hodgson 1989, and Kaiser et al. 1999).
As forests confer positive stock externalities through the effects on other
pollution stocks (i.e. sediment), marginal external cost of forest harvesting should be
taken into account in pricing the harvest. There arises policy challenges how a
regulatory authority should tax resource extraction in order to internalize the
externalities. The predominant position is the resource owner should be required to
pay the “marginal externality cost.” However, that cost has not been well defined for
the case of stock externalities, inasmuch as accumulation today has welfare
implications for the future. This article shows that, in this case (i.e. forest-sediment),
the marginal opportunity cost concept suggested in the literature is not applicable as
MEC contains as a part of MUC. For private resource owner, unlike famous climate
change model, taxing resource extraction according to the shadow price of pollution
will not yield an optimal outcome because externality is associated with the resource
stock, not its extraction per se. Public concessionaire should be taxed equal to MUC.
The optimal management of resource where resource stock has amenity
services is also considered in this article. For example, forest has scientific,
recreational, and aesthetic values for its existence. Unlike forest-sediment case, these
externalities arise directly from resource stock, not via other pollution stocks. In this
case, as will be shown in the article, marginal externality cost is also embedded in
user cost. Optimal pricing policies for public concessionaire and private owner are
shown.
In the literature, some issues about MUC remain unclear and need to be
clarified. Leaving aside externalities, terms royalty and MUC of resource are often
used interchangeably in resource economics. There are, at least, two problems with
this usage. First, marginal user cost is usually defined as the change in present value
of a resource with unit change in stock. This article shows that, however, the MUC
that equals royalty at the first-best is the current value or inflated to time t one (MUC’
hereafter in this article), not the present value as its definition. Second, royalty and
MUC’ are two separate variables that obtain equal values only at the first-best. If the
resource is being overharvested, royalty may be smaller than MUC’. Repetto (1988)
and Gillis (1988) suggestion that royalty should be used to price a public forest would
work only if the observed royalty was the result of optimal extraction. If the forest
was being overharvested, charging observed royalty will be too low and will not result
in optimal harvesting.
Next section reviews the previous literature on the related topics. The
discussion of marginal user cost concept and royalty is in section 2.3. In section 2.4,
the optimal condition for forest-sediment, as an example of extracting resource with
stock externality, will be shown. Optimal taxes for public concessionaire and private
owner are derived. The results are compared to the traditional marginal opportunity
cost concept. In section 2.5, the model is adapted to present the case where resource
stock itself has an amenity value. The conclusion is in section 2.6.
Review of Literature
Reppetto (1988) and Gillis (1988) are among those who study the forest policies in
developing countries. Both suggest that stumpage value – the difference between
price and extraction cost – is the economic rent of forest resource. Forest policies
should be such that transfer this rent back into government revenue (i.e. by royalties,
land rents, license fee, or harvest taxes). Thus, their suggestions imply that
government should charge stumpage value of forest. This will be discussed in next
section.
Pearce and Markandya (1989) suggest using marginal concept for measuring
resource value. Marginal cost of using resource consists of three components:
marginal direct cost, marginal external cost, and marginal user cost. Direct cost deals
with cost associating with the resource extraction. Second component, marginal
external cost, refers to the cost of externalities resulted from resource usage. Marginal
user cost, raised from intertemporal considerations, is the cost from incapability of
using the resource in the future. The efficient level of resource use can be specified by
equating the marginal cost and marginal benefit of its use. However, the article neither
specifies the expressions for MUC and MEC explicitly nor discusses the corrective
policy dealing with externalities that may occur from resource use.
Stock characteristic of externality has drawn economists’ consideration since
the pioneer works by Keeler et al. (1972), and Plourde (1972). This group of studies,
including Nordhaus (1991), however, emphasizes its scope on dynamic framework of
externalities and ignores the linkage between externalities and the resource use. This
type of models applies to the case where resource use is of a sufficiently small scale
and its scarcity is unimportant, for example, waste accumulation and disposal, the
build-up of chemical from pesticides in agricultural land. In many cases, however,
limited natural resource plays an important role in determining how much to use. In
these situations, ignoring the linkage between resources and externalities will fail to
capture the essences of the problem. This relationship has been incorporated into the
consideration in 1990s, mostly in climate change studies.
Since climate change problem becomes more popular, there have been many
studies modeling fossil fuel use and greenhouse gases accumulation. This group of
models emphasizes the linkage between resource use and accumulated pollution, as
fossil fuels are limited. The beginning attempts to integrate resource use with stock
externality issue can be found in Sinclair (1994) and Ulph and Ulph (1994). Both
studies analyze the evolution of optimal carbon tax rate. Sinclair (1994) calls for
declining fossil fuel tax over time. Ulph and Ulph (1994), however, show that there
are different factors causing a rise or a fall in tax rate. Under some circumstances (e.g.
quadratic benefit and damage function, constant extraction cost), optimal tax can be
such that it rises first and then falls later. The model is extended in many ways. For
example, Hoel and Kverndokk (1996) consider also the case where damages depend
on rate of change in stock of carbon. They also allow non-polluting backstop
technology in the model. Farzin (1996) considers threshold effects of stock
externalities and finds that optimal tax is required even in the initial period where
there is no damage. Farzin and Tahvonen (1996) study the model by relaxing the
assumption on constant rate of decay of carbon. Lately, Perman et al. (2003) provide a
article on stock externality in their book. A comprehensive model on stock externality
arise from nonrenewable resource use is discussed. Three-part taxes including utility
damage tax, pollution flow damage tax, and stock damage tax are suggested in order
to internalize the externality problem. In the climate change case, as private resource
owner ignores environmental external effect, corrective tax equal to shadow price of
pollution stock must be taxed. Nevertheless, this article will show that this is not the
general rule and it is not applicable to forest-sediment case.
Downstream sediment can be considered a stock pollution arises from forest
degradation. There are some studies exploring the effects of forest removal on
downstream sedimentation. Logging often causes soil erosion, resulting in the transfer
of soil from one location where it has positive benefits to another where it imposes
cost (Clark 1985, Hodgson 1997, Magrath and Doolette 1990). Water-borne runoff
and sedimentation are off-site result from soil erosion. Runoff and sedimentation, if
occurred in stream, lakes, and reservoir, can create many negative impacts including:
reducing reservoir storage capacity, losses to navigation, negative effects on aquatic
life, increase in risk of flooding, adverse effects on agricultural and industrial
production in lowlands, and decrease in water quality (Barbier 1995, Dixon 1997).
Magrath and Aren (1989) (cited in Barbier 1995) estimate the off-site cost of reservoir
sedimentation in Java, Indonesia. The combined cost of annual hydropower and
irrigation losses is range from $1.62 to 7.48 million. Kaiser et al. (1999) estimate that
significant forest disturbance on Ko’olau forest, located in Hawaii, will increase
runoff and cause damage (estimated from dredging cost alone) ranges from $0.75-1.2
million per year. In case of costal forest, the runoff and sedimentation may affect the
nearshore resources including fish and other aquatic life, and coral reef (Hodgson and
Dixon 1988, Hodgson 1989, Kaiser et al. 1999). For example, a study of coral reefs in
Indonesia indicates that sediment from logging may cause present value net losses
from fisheries and tourism damages of $273,000 per square kilometer of reef (Cesar
1996, cited in Kaiser et al. 1999). This group of studies, however, pays attention more
to monetary estimation of one-time damage and ignores the dynamic accumulation of
sedimentation. Dynamic corrective tax and pricing rules for forest-sediment case have
not been studied in the literature. By comparing to climate change model, one might
suggest optimal tax equal to shadow price of pollution. Unfortunately, this article
shows that it is not true for forest-sediment case.
For the amenity values of forest, there are many studies in this area. Hartman
(1976), Berck (1981), and Krautkraemer (1985) are among the pioneers in the topic.
Hartman (1976) studies the effect of standing value of forest on the optimal harvesting
age under Faustmann framework. He finds that amenity values postpone the optimal
age of forest harvesting. Krautkraemer (1985) shows that resource amenity values will
increase the initial price and decrease rate of growth in resource price. Englin and
Khan (1990) solves for Pigouvian tax when forest has amenity values. Most of the
studies in this field models the forest in Faustmann framework (optimal rotation age),
which is not adaptable to other resources. In term of biomass model, Berck (1981)
gets similar results – with amenity value, steady state of forest stock is higher.
However, there is no study involving Pigouvian tax under biomass model.
MUC vs. Royalty
Before talking about pricing resource with externality, I would like to discuss the use
of term MUC in capital theory and in resource economics. As will be shown, there is
inconsistency in MUC terms used in these two fields. This needs to be clarified. The
appropriateness of interchangeable use of “royalty” and “MUC” will also be discussed
later in this section.
A resource stock at time t is X(t) and is extracted at rate x(t) at a cost of
x (t )
1
c( X (t )) per unit to obtain benefits (consumer surplus) of
∫
p ( z )dz , where p(z) is
0
the inverse demand function or price of resource. The stock increases with natural
2
growth, f ( X (t )) , and decreases with harvest, x(t). Over time, the rate of change in
stock is, therefore, X& (t ) = f ( X (t )) − x(t ) . A hypothetical social planner chooses the
resource extraction path, x(t), to maximize the stream of present value of net social
∞
⎡ x (t )
⎤
benefits, V = ∫ e − rt ⎢ ∫ p( z )dz − c( X (t )) x(t ) ⎥dt where r is the discount rate, i.e.,
0
⎣0
⎦
max
V
x (t )
s.t.
…(1)
X& (t ) = f ( X (t )) − x(t )
3
The present-value Hamiltonian for this optimal control problem is:
x (t )
− rt
H =e [
∫ p( z )dz − c( X (t )) x(t )] + λ (t )[ f ( X (t )) − x(t )]
0
Here, following Dorfman (1969, p. 820), λ (t ) =
∂V *
, i.e., λ (t ) is the increase in the
∂X (t )
maximized value of the objective function (V) due to a unit increase in the stock (X) at
time t. This is the definition of marginal user cost. First-order conditions according to
4
the Maximum Principle are:
∂H
= e − rt [ p( x) − c( X ) ] − λ = 0
∂x
…(2)
∂H
= e − rt [ −c '( X ) x ] + λ f '( X ) = −λ&
∂X
…(3)
From (2), we see that, at the optimum,
λ = e − rt [ p ( x) − c( X ) ]
…(4)
That is, optimality requires that Dorfman’s MUC (or the one used in capital theory)
on the left-hand side equals the discounted present value of royalty on the right-hand
side. Alternatively,
λ ert = p( x) − c( X )
…(5)
current value of royalty equals the value of MUC inflated to time t (MUC’). This
inflated MUC is used in Pearce and Markandya (1989) (and in resource economics) as
MUC. Two points are worth noting here. First, Dorfman’s MUC is not equal to
royalty itself but instead to the present value of royalty. In other words, MUC that is
used by resource economics is not Dorfman’s MUC, but it is current value of
Dorfman’s MUC (MUC’), which is equal to royalty at the first-best.
Second, the equality in equation (5) does not always hold; it is only guaranteed
at the first-best. Therefore, a public concessionaire who ignores the effect of own
extraction on future benefits will need to be taxed equal to the MUC’ (the left-hand
side of equation (5) above), not equal to royalty as suggested by Repetto (1988) and
Gillis (1988). If the resource is, for example, being overused (i.e. not on the optimal
path currently), the observed royalty would be less than the MUC’ and a tax equal to
the royalty will not serve to obtain an efficient outcome, whereas a tax equal to the
MUC’ will. For example, the resource will be overharvested under short-term
concessionaire system. One can imagine that, as concessionaire has only short-term
rights to harvest the resource, his problem is to harvest now or never. The problem
can be viewed as an open-access resource over time. As will be shown later in section
2.5.1, short-term concessionaire, who ignores the user cost in the future, will harvest
resource until price is equal to extraction cost (p=c), or at point x1 in figure 2.1.
Charging observed royalty, which equals to zero, would not improve the efficiency.
The corrective policy is a tax equal to MUC’.
(Insert figure 1 here)
Combining (2) and (3) and rearranging, we get:
p ( x) = c( X ) +
p& − c X f
r − fX
5
…(6)
The left-hand side in equation (6) is the inverse demand function, which represents
the marginal benefit of resource consumption. The right-hand side is the marginal
opportunity cost, which includes unit harvest cost as the first term and MUC’ as the
second term. The two sides are equated at the optimum.
Rearranging (6) further, we get a Hotelling-like equation:
p& = c X f + ( p − c)(r − f X )
…(7)
The first term on the right-hand side is negative since c X < 0 , and the second term is
positive as long as r > f X . Their relative magnitude determines whether price, p, is
increasing or decreasing at any time. The price is increasing if:
p−c > −
cX f
r − fX
Next, we extend the above model to include stock externality for a downstream
environment.
Resource extraction with stock externality (forest-sediment)
Thinking of resource in term of forest, I will follow the same setup as previous
section. With externalities, the forest stock, X(t), is inversely related to the flow of
sediment, h(X(t)), from upland watersheds to nearshore resources, i.e., hX<0. The
sediment stock, S(t), at time t, in nearshore waters grows with input h(X(t)), and
decreases with natural decay and wave action as a constant fraction, δ , of stock S(t),
i.e., S& (t ) = h( X ) − δ S (t ) . The pollution stock causes damage E(S(t)), at time t, with
ES>0. The present value of the net social benefit, therefore, now becomes:
∞
W = ∫e
0
− rt
⎡ x (t )
⎤
⎢ ∫ p( z )dz − c( X (t )) x(t ) − E ( S (t )) ⎥dt . A hypothetical social planner
⎣0
⎦
chooses the forest harvest path, x(t), to maximize W, i.e.,
max
W
s.t.
X& (t ) = f ( X (t )) − x(t )
S& (t ) = h( X (t )) − δS (t )
x≥0
…(8)
The current-value Hamiltonian for this optimal control problem can be written as:
H% =
x (t )
∫
p ( z )dz − c( X (t )) x(t ) − E ( S (t )) + λ (t )[ f ( X (t )) − x(t )] + α (t )[ h( X (t )) − δ S (t )]
0
where λ is the shadow price of resource stock, X, and α is the shadow price of
6
pollution stock. First-order conditions according to the Maximum Principle are:
~
∂H
= p−c−λ = 0
∂x
p =c+λ
…(9)
∂H%
= − xc X + λ f X + α hX = r λ − λ&
∂X
…(10)
∂H%
= − ES − δα = rα − α&
∂S
…(11)
Manipulating and rearranging (9) – (11), we get:
p =c+
p& − c X f
α hX
+
r − fX
r − fX
…(12)
Comparing equation (12) to equation (9), the combination of second and third term on
the right-hand side of equation (12) is MUC’. Even extracting forest creates
downstream sedimentation, however in this case, we cannot write pricing equation in
term of p = c + MUC '+ MEC , as suggested in the literature. In this case, externality
cost is embedded in user cost term. The interesting question is how government
should price the resource in order to achieve the social optimal outcomes.
Pricing policy for public concessionaire
Public concessionaire usually has short-term rights to harvest the forest. As a result,
public concessionaire normally fails to take into account both externality and user
costs (the future effects of extracting resource now, i.e. higher extraction cost in the
future and forgone benefit from increased price). Many instruments can be
implemented in order to internalize the externalities. The most direct one, in this case,
is to subsidize forest stock, as it creates the externalities. Forest stock subsidies are,
however, difficult to administer. The difficulties in measuring forest stock in every
period and the budget limitation are the main problems. From these reasons, harvest
tax, which is the easiest and most practical tax, will be the major concern in this
article. To achieve optimal outcomes, a public concessionaire need to be charged a
unit tax, T(t), equal to the MUC’. This is because the concessionaire chooses x(t) to
maximize the present value of net after tax benefits:
∞
⎡ x (t )
⎤
Y = ∫ e − rt ⎢ ∫ ( p( z ) − T (t ))dz − c( X (t )) x(t ) ⎥dt
0
⎣0
⎦
…(13)
Without having to consider change in forest stock (an equation of motion of resource
stock), the maximization will imply: p = c + T . Comparing this with (12), we get:
T =λ =
p& − c X f
αh X
+
r − fX
r − fX
…(14)
Solving differential equation in (10) with transversality condition:
lim e − rt λ (t ) X (t ) = 0 , we can solve for λ or optimal tax:
t →∞
τ
∞
T = λ (t ) = ∫ e
∫
− ( r − f X )dv
t
[αhX − xc X ]dτ ,
…(15)
t
In conclusion, public concessionaire should be taxed at MUC’ level in order to
internalize user cost and externality cost. This contrasts to the thinking that public
concessionaire should be taxed both MUC’ and MEC because, under this situation,
externality cost is included in user cost.
Pricing policy for private owner
This subsection examines the optimal tax when the resource is owned by a private
owner. Private owner should be taxed because he ignores the environmental damage,
E(S(t)); however, he takes into account the effect of resource stock on extraction cost
in the future. Suppose the tax rate is T(t) per unit of harvest, x(t). The owner chooses
x(t) to maximize the present value of net after tax benefits:
∞
Z = ∫e
− rt
0
max
⎡ x (t )
⎤
⎢ ∫ ( p ( z ) − T (t ))dz − c( X (t )) x(t ) ⎥dt , i.e.,
⎣0
⎦
Z
x≥0
…(16)
X& (t ) = f ( X (t )) − x(t )
s.t.
The current-value Hamiltonian for this optimal control problem can be written as:
x (t )
H% =
∫ ( p( z ) − T (t ))dz − c( X (t )) x(t ) + λ (t )[ f ( X (t )) − x(t )] ,
0
7
where λ(t) is the shadow price of the resource stock , X(t). First-order conditions
8
are:
∂H%
= p −T − c −λ = 0
∂x
…(17)
∂H%
= − xc X + λ f X = r λ − λ&
∂X
…(18)
Manipulating and rearranging (17) – (18), we get:
p =c+
p& − c X f ⎛
T& ⎞
+ ⎜T −
⎟
r − fX ⎝
r − fX ⎠
…(19)
Comparing (12) and (18), we see that the tax must be chosen such that
T−
α hX
T&
=
r − fX r − fX
…(20)
τ
∞
T (t ) =
∫ α (τ )h
X
( X (τ )) e
− ∫ ( r − f X ( X (υ ))) dυ
t
dτ
…(21)
t
Equation (20) and (21) specify optimal tax for private owner. Unlike
concessionaire, private owner already takes into account user cost, therefore should be
taxed only the externality part. Nevertheless, optimal tax is not equal to the shadow
price of pollution (α), as it is in climate change case. Intuitively, this is because the
externality is determined by the stock of forest, whereas the tax is imposed on the
harvest. If the externality were being caused by harvest and not by the stock, taxing
shadow price of pollution will restore the optimum. The last term in (19) represents
the fact that tax will also affect the future producer price. Designing optimal tax also
has to consider effect of tax in the future price. Next section shows that this logic
applies for the case where stock of resource has amenity values.
Resource with amenity values
In many cases, resource stock has its own amenity values. The obvious example is a
forest, which has many values for its appearance, for example, biodiversity, scientific,
recreational, or aesthetic values. Without considering these external benefits, forest
will be overexploited.
Instead of externality damage from sediment stock, we assume that there is
externality benefit derived directly from forest stock, B(X), where BX>0. The present
value of the net social benefit, therefore, now becomes:
∞
⎡ x (t )
⎤
V = ∫ e − rt ⎢ ∫ p( z )dz − c( X (t )) x(t ) + B( X (t ))⎥dt . A hypothetical social planner
⎢⎣ 0
⎥⎦
0
chooses the forest harvesting path, x(t), to maximize V, i.e.,
max
V
s.t.
X& (t ) = f ( X (t )) − x(t )
x≥0
…(22)
The current-value Hamiltonian for this optimal control problem can be written as:
~
H=
x (t )
∫ p( z )dz − c( X (t )) x(t ) + B( X (t )) + λ (t )[ f ( X (t )) − x(t )]
0
where λ is the shadow price of resource stock, X, for this case. First-order conditions
9
according to the Maximum Principle for interior solution are:
~
∂H
= p−c−λ = 0
∂x
…(23)
~
∂H
= −c X x + B X + λf X = rλ − λ&
∂X
…(24)
lim e − rt λX = 0
…(25)
t →∞
Manipulating (23) and (25), we can get
p =c+
p& − c X f
BX
+
r − fX
r − fX
…(26)
From equation (23) and (26), we can arrange optimal condition as p = c + MUC ' ,
where MUC’ is the second and third term on the right-hand side of equation (26).
Even extracting resource effects externalities, marginal externality cost does not
explicitly appear. The intuition is similar to forest-sediment case; externalities are not
explained directly by the resource extraction, but the remaining forest stock. Like the
previous case (forest-sediment), MEC is embedded in MUC’. If government can
impose tax/subsidy base on resource stock, static Pigouvian tax equal to damage cost
occur at each period will yield the optimum. However, government can practically
impose tax on amount of timber harvested. From this reason, dynamic aspect of
resource must be taken into account.
Pricing policies for public concessionaire
In order to find the optimal tax for public concessionaire, this section will follow
section 4.2. A public concessionaire will maximize his benefit, without considering
external benefit or scarcity of resource, i.e. maximize;
∞
V = ∫e
⎡ x (t )
⎤
⎢ ∫ ( p( z ) − T )dz − c( X (t )) x(t )⎥dt
⎣⎢ 0
⎦⎥
− rt
0
…(27)
This maximization problem will give first-order condition;
p −T − c = 0
…(28)
Comparing (28) with (23), optimal tax for public concessionaire is expressed by
T =λ =
p& − c X f
BX
+
r − fX
r − fX
…(29)
In other words, the optimal tax equal to MUC’ should be imposed in order to
internalize resource scarcity and externality. In this case, externality effects are
included in user cost.
Private Owner
Private owner, who takes into account resource scarcity, but not externality, will
maximize
∞
∫e
max
x≥0
0
− rt
⎡ x (t )
⎤
⎢ ∫ ( p( z ) − T )dz − c( X (t )) x(t )⎥dt
⎣⎢ 0
⎦⎥
…(30)
X& (t ) = f ( X (t )) − x(t )
s.t.
The current-value Hamiltonian for this optimal control problem is written as:
~
H=
x (t )
∫ ( p( z ) − T (t ))dz − c( X (t )) x(t ) + λ (t )[ f ( X (t )) − x(t )]
0
10
where λ(t) is the shadow price of the resource stock , X(t). First-order conditions
11
are:
~
∂H
= p −T −c −λ = 0
∂x
…(31)
~
∂H
= −c X x + λf X = rλ − λ&
∂X
…(32)
Manipulating and rearranging (31) – (32), we get:
p =c+
p& − c X f
T&
+ (T −
)
r − fX
r − fX
…(33)
Comparing (26) and (33), we see that the tax must be imposed such that
T−
BX
T&
=
r − fX r − fX
…(34)
Solving the differential equation (34), we get:
τ
∞
T (t ) = ∫ B X e
∫
− ( r − f X ) dv
t
dτ
…(24)
t
For private owner, as he takes into account the user cost, government only needs to
internalize externalities. Like forest-sediment case, the optimal tax for a private owner
is only a part of MUC’. The effect of tax on future producer price is considered in
designing optimal tax.
Conclusion
When resource extraction creates environmental externalities, market equilibrium is
not socially optimal. In case of climate change, where fossil fuel extraction causes
greenhouse gas accumulation in the atmosphere, charging resource owner for his
extraction equal to the shadow price of pollution will restore the optimum. This,
however, does not hold generally for all case. Considering the case where forest
determines growth in sediment accumulation, optimal tax for forest owner is not equal
to the shadow price of pollution. The differences arise because in forest-sediment
case, pollution stock is determined by the forest stock, not forest extraction. However,
practical policy is to impose taxes on timber harvested, not subsidies on remaining
forest area. This causes the complexity in tax formula. From the same reason,
externality cost from resource extraction is embedded in the user cost. Marginal
opportunity cost concept may be not well applicable in this case. This logic also
applies to the case where resource has amenity values, for example, forest has amenity
values including biodiversity, recreational, aesthetic values. While private owner is
taxed only externality part from user cost; public concessionaire must be taxed the
whole user cost (including externality cost). This is because public concessionaire
fails to take into account both externality and future effects of current extraction.
The marginal opportunity cost concept suggested in the literature is still a
powerful concept. In some cases, nonetheless, externality cost may not appear
explicitly, but as a part of user cost. When externalities arise from resource stock, not
resource extraction, user cost consists of foregone benefits of increase in price, higher
extraction cost in the future, and externality cost.
Another interesting issue is to find the time path of optimal taxes and compare
it with the other cases, for example, carbon taxes in climate change model. Dynamic
solution of the problem of interacting resources has never been studied in the
literature. The model setup discussed in this article can serves as a good beginning for
the problem.
This article shows at the beginning that the interchangeable use of term
“MUC” and “royalty” in resource economics is not exactly correct; it is true only with
some underlying understands. There are two things need to be clarified. First, MUC
that equal to royalty at first-best is a current value MUC (MUC’); while MUC that
used in capital theory is a present value one, by definition. Second, the equality holds
only at the first-best. So, at first-best, optimal tax can be set at either MUC’ or royalty.
However, if the resource is being over-harvested or under-harvested, charging royalty
will not restore the optimum, while charging MUC’ will.
References
Barbier, E., 1995, “The Economics of Soil Erosion: Theory, Methodology and
Examples,” Special papers presented in the Fifth Biannual Workshop on
Economy and Environment in Southeast Asia,
(http://203.116.43.77/publications/specialp2/ACF2B4.html).
Berck, P., 1981, “Optimal Management of Renewable Resources with Growing
Demand and Stock Externalities,” Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management 8, 105-117.
Cesar, H., 1996, Economic Analysis of Indonesian Coral Reefs, IBRD, Environment
Department.
Clark, E., 1985, “The off-site costs of soil erosion,” Journal of Soil and Water
Conservation 40(1), 19-22.
Dixon, J., 1997, “Analysis and Management of Watershed,” The Environment and
Emerging Development Issues Vol.2, In Dasgupta and Maler, eds., Clarendon
Press, Oxford, 371-398.
Dorfman, R., 1969, “An Economic Interpretation of Optimal Control Theory,” The
American Economic Review 59(5), 817-831.
Englin, E., and M. Klan, 1990, “Optimal Taxation: Timber and Externalities,” Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management 18, 263-275.
Farzin, Y., 1996, “Optimal pricing of environmental and natural resource use with
stock externalities,” Journal of Public Economics 62, 31-57.
Farzin Y., and O. Tahvonen, 1996, “The global carbon cycle and the optimal time
path of a carbon tax,” Oxford Economic Papers 48, 515-536.
Gillis, M., 1988, “Indonesia: public policies, resource management, and the tropical
forest,” In R. Repetto, and M. Gillis, eds., Public policies and the misuse of
forest resources, World Resources Institute, 43-114.
Hartman, R., 1976, “The Harvesting Decision when a Standing Forest Has Value,”
Economic Inquiry 14, 52-58.
Hodgson, G. and J. Dixon, 1988, Logging versus fisheries and tourism in Palawan:
an environmental and economic analysis. EAPI Occasional Paper No. 7.
Honolulu, Hawaii, USA, East-West Center.
Hoel, M., and S. Kverndokk, 1996, “Depletion of fossil fuels and the impacts of
global warming,” Resource and Energy Economics 18, 115-136.
Kaiser, B., N. Krause, and J. Roumasset, 1999, “Environmental Valuation and the
Hawaiian Economy,” UHERO working paper,
(http://www2.hawaii.edu/~uhero/).
Keeler, E., M. Spence, and R. Zeckhauser, 1971, “The Optimal Control of Pollution,”
Journal of Economic Theory 4, 19-34.
Krautkraemer, J., 1985, “Optimal Growth, Resource Amenities and the Prreservation
of Natural Environments,” Review of Economic Studies, 153-170.
Magrath, W., and P. Arens, 1989, “The Costs of Soil Erosion on Java: A Natural
Resource Accounting Approach,” Environment Department Working Paper
No.18, The World Bank, Washington D.C.
Magrath, W. B., and J. B. Doolette, 1990, “Strategic Issues in Watershed
Development,” in Magrath W.B., and J.B. Doolette, Eds., Watershed
Development in Asia: Strategies and Technologies, World Bank Technical
Paper no.127. The World Bank: Washington D.C.
Nordhaus, W., 1991, “To Slow or Not to Slow: The Economics of the Greenhouse
Effect,” The Economic Journal 101(407), 920-937.
Pearce, D., and A. Markandya, 1989, “Marginal opportunity cost as a planning
concept,” in Schramm, G. and J. Warford, Eds., Environmental Management
and Economic Development, Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
Perman, R., Y. Ma, J. McGilvray, and M. Common, 2003, Natural Resource and
Environmental Economics 3rd edition, Pearson Addison Wesley, New York.
Plourde, C., 1972, “A Model of Waste Accumulation and Disposal,” Canadian
Journal of Economics 5, 119-125.
Repetto, R., 1988. The Forest for the Trees? Government Policies and the Misuse of
Forest Resources., World Resources Institute.
Sinclair, P., 1994, “On the trend of fossil fuel taxation,” Oxford Economic Papers 46,
869-877.
Ulph, A., and D. Ulph, 1994, “The optimal time path of a carbln tax,” Oxford
Economic Papers 46, 857-868.
World Bank, 1992, World development report, Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK.
price
c + MUC’
c (extraction cost)
MB
x*
x1
extraction
Figure1. Charging observed royalty is not always an optimal policy
Footnote:
1
c(X) is assumed to be a decreasing function in X. Rising cost given lower resource
stock may be explained by difficulties in finding the resource when its stock is low,
the use of farer resource, or the use of lower quality resource.
2
f(X) is assumed to have the tradition properties; strictly concave that attain a maxima
at a finite value of X
3
Please note that we use present-value Hamiltonian, not current-value Hamiltonian as
the definition of MUC is in present-value term. This may be the source of confusion.
4
Time as function argument has been ignored to avoid notational clutter.
5
Function arguments have been ignored to avoid notational clutter.
6
Function arguments have been ignored to avoid notational clutter.
7
Note that λ here is different from the one in social planner case.
8
Function arguments have been ignored to avoid notational clutter.
9
Function arguments have been ignored to avoid notational clutter.
10
Again, this λ is different from the one in social optimal case.
11
Function arguments have been ignored to avoid notational clutter.