Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Oligopoly E. Glen Weyl University of Chicago Clase 8 Teoría Avanzada de Precios y Estructuras de Mercado Escuela de Verano 2012 Departamento de Economía Universidad de los Andes Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Introduction So far firms either price-takers or monopoly Today imperfect competition or oligopoly 1 2 Static oligopoly solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusive oligopoly Incentives for collusion Factors facilitating and hampering collusion 3 Conjectural variations as a summary of collusion The consistent conjectures solution concept 4 5 6 7 8 Incidence in oligopoly: symmetric v. asymmetric Selection and cream-skimming distortions Cournot’s Theorem in theory and practice Competition policy: institutions and policies Merger analysis: the first-order approach Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Cournot and oligopoly solutions Most basic oligopoly model is that of Cournot Demand P(Q); individual firm costs Ci (qi ); MCi ≡ Ci0 Each firm takes others’ q’s as given; P − MCi = qi P 0 Mark-up over cost because of infra-marginal quantity But natural reaction: why take others’ quantity as given? Let to long, complicated debate on solution concepts We’ll start by giving a flavor of what this was like: Price competition, differentiated products, collusion, etc. Can get very confusing and Byzantine In the end, though, details not so important What really matters is overall competitiveness How far off from monopoly do firms behave? This can often be measured, reasoned about more directly =⇒ Everything else just input to basic summary statistics Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations The Bertrand-Edgeworth paradox To give flavor of debate, though, let’s go through bit of history Bertrand and Edgeworth: firms take others’ price given =⇒ Profits discontinuous! If I charge a bit below, get everyone Suppose all have same, known cost? =⇒ Positive mark-up cannot be equilibrium; undercut Bertrand and Edgeworth’s Paradox With N > 1, only equilibrium is P = c! Called Bertrand-Edgeworth paradox or critique Two firms enough for competition? Many think absurd Unlikely sales change discontinuous; possible resolutions? 1 2 3 Firms differ in their costs, costs may not be known Firms’ products are not the same (inherent or search) Firms collude or don’t take others prices as given Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Cost heterogeneity and the Bertrand paradox Simplest response is that firms differ in costs This case like first-price auction Each firm tries to just beat next firm =⇒ P 6= min{ci }; rather P = E [c2 ], cost of 2nd lowest Clearly not quite the average cost, but a lot less sensitive As we get more firms, second lowest closer to first (?) =⇒ Predictions more similar to Cournot than simple Bertrand =⇒ Major virtue of Cournot greater robustness (and simplicity) Broader: absurd conclusions indicate model problem Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Differentiated products: the most popular solution Another, more popular, response is product differentiation If one firm increases price, demand only falls continuously 1 Consumers view products as differentiated 2 Identical, but consumers have to search Non-price characteristics as last week Prices are not transparent, costly to go to store =⇒ Once in store, monopolist competing against cost of 2nd visit Either way we can write for firm i, Q i (p1 , . . . , pi , . . . , pN ) So long as nice, smooth, no Bertrand-style discontinuities Each monopolist on own product, but others substitute ∂Q i ∂pj > 0 for i 6= j Very broad model, could quantities as strategies However “Nash-in-prices” or “Bertrand” has become central Called “Differentiated Products Nash-in-Prices” or (DPNiP) Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Pricing with differentiated products Same basic principles hold for pricing in this case We can define residual demand elasticity: Elasticity of demand holding fixed other prices? i pi ri = ∂Q ∂pi Q i Then just follow Lerner rule: pi −MCi pi = 1 ri Nothing special about prices as strategies 1 Just as easily defines firm’s optimal quantity 2 Could also do à la Cournot/Nash-in-quantities Key is holding fixed other firms’ prices Then residual elasticity is holding fixed other quantities Less common so we won’t get into math, but very similar =⇒ No reason differentiated products needs price strategies This is used extremely broadly in industrial economics Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations How oligopolists benefit from a cartel Oligopolists create (pecuniary) externalities on one another? 1 Purely pecuniary under Cournot; why? Believe all other firms’ quantities are given 2 Purely real under DPNiP; why? Believe other firms’ prices are fixed, quantities change =⇒ Quantities always too high under Cournot but...? May be too high under DPNiP if other mark-ups larger Regardless of social benefits or costs, firms benefit by avoiding Because substitutes, q ↓ /p ↑ always benefits competitor In fact, let’s define two firms competing by being substitutes If they act to internalize this (pecuniary) externality we say? They are “colluding” or “forming a cartel” or my favorite: “Combination in the restraint of trade” Denounced since Adam Smith, illegal under Sherman Act Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations A cartoon that help catalyze the antitrust act Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Legal restrictions on cartel formation Once upon a time, cartel agreements were legally enforceable 1 In the US prior to the Sherman Act 2 In Continental Europe prior to the EU reforms 3 Hardly illegal in many developing countries (like Perú) 4 Britain all the way back to 18th century made illegal Luckily the United States now leads the world on enforcement 1 Explicit agreement about prices/service illegal Only competitors; complements are different as we’ll see 2 Even without communication (“tacit”) can be prosecuted 3 Criminal (jail time) and civil penalties In practice much less because hard to prove Usually “treble damages”: probability of detection ≈ =⇒ Many practical challenges in running a cartel today =⇒ Collusion difficult, only possible in limited settings Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly 1 3 Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Incentives to defect from a cartel The basic problem is that cartel benefits all but... Each firm has incentive to betray; why? This is what it means to be an (pecuniary) externality By reducing price/increasing quantity each benefits Can steal business, from others, benefit from higher prices =⇒ The more ambitious cartel is, the less stable? Higher is the price, more incentive to steal the sales Near competitive level, little or no incentive to cheat =⇒ Extent of collusion is ability to deter cheating Every cartel needs to create expectations of punishment =⇒ Policy related to cartels all about this interplay 1 2 Goal of cartel is to ensure credible punishment of cheaters Goal of agency, customers is to catch and prevent Stigler bases oligopoly theory on this back-and-forth Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Detection, punishment and cartel enforcement In order for the cartel to deter cheating it must? 1 Be able to determine what the optimal agreement is Diffuse information, as in other externality problems Hindered further here by government breathing down neck 2 Have clear what does and does not constitute cheating Firms should be given some flexibility (private information) But if too much flexibility then cartel does not function 3 Be able to detect cheating, distinguish from background Many things might look like cheating but be innocent 4 Have cost-effective means of punishment If you could tax and redistribute ideal Shifting market share across firms works well Price wars harm everyone so less effective 5 Be able to do this quickly (patience and frequency) Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Stigler’s factors facilitating/deterring collusion Stigler’s theory is based on these necessities; factors? He emphasizes factors facilitating/hindering these 1 Large, heterogeneous buyers hurt, small homo help Hard to track, easy to extract undermining concession 2 Heterogeneity of product/firms hurts Harder to define optimum, more incentive for one defect 3 Price transparency helps track defections Ability to offer secret price cuts key Case against collecting industry, offering info to consumers 4 5 6 7 Industry concentration helps reduce tracking, temptation Variability of demand hurts monitoring Frequency of interaction helps detect soon Growing demand helps, declining hurts If declining, grab what you can while you can Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Summarizing collusion through conjectures All of these determine the extent of deterrence Most deterrence happens through price cuts/wars So simple way to summarize is firms’ conjectures If I lower price, how much will rival lower (or raise?) hers? Also works with quantity...how do they respond? This varies depending on Stigler’s factors =⇒ Models incorporating called Conjectural Variations (CV) Usually capture by “parameter” of conjectured adjustment Note this idea is useful to change price v. quantity models Cournot is price model with conjectured “accommodation” Price is quantity with conjectured “aggression” =⇒ Thus CV is broad framework incorporating all theories Good because it can be used to talk about all them But to be useful requires more structure Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Cournot pricing with conjectural variations Let’s consider simplest Cournot model Again profits [P (Q−i + qi ) − c] qi But now extra term, as other quantities not fixed: Optimal pricing given by? dQ P + P 0 qi 1 + dq−ii = c If dQ−i dqi dQ−i dqi > 0 then MR further below P Therefore called a “conjectured accommodating reaction” If you are nice and reduce quantity, others follow you This is how collusion is facilitated On the other hand, if aggressive, dQ−i dqi < 0, lower prices This case was on your exam; if dQ−i dqi = −1 then Bertrand Also starting from Bertrand, DPNiP Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Estimating conjectures Natural question is how much Stigler’s factors impact Factors are all qualitative; CV parameter quantitative Natural question is how much these change Determines impact on amount of collusion Natural approach: regress CV parameter on factors Astonishingly, I don’t think anyone has ever done this! To do this, though, we need to measure the CV parameter This is difficult, but two approaches have been taken 1 Measure c, P 0 and solve for CV parameter Works pretty well, but sometimes cost data difficult “New empirical IO” (NEIO) tries to avoid using cost data... 2 Measure by comparing different types of demand shifts If demand curve rotates, affects price ∝ market power Thus size of impact measures CV parameter Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations T F. Bresnahan / The oligopoly solution Twisters v. shifters (Bresnahan 1981) concept is identified P MRl Q Fig. 2. Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations A hypothesis for measuring conjectures This suggests another natural way to measure conjectures Presumably, firm forms conjectures based on experience In past, when c ↑ =⇒ p ↑, what happened? Did my rival’s price rise or fall? By how much? This seems a reasonable way to determine conjecture This is called consistent conjecture hypothesis Due to work by Bresnahan (1981) and others If you think about it, other models a bit strange In Cournot, if I change quantity, so does rival... But I don’t take this into account!? Also very convenient from empirical perspective =⇒ If we observe shocks, we can measure conjecture Similar: shock to firm cost shows relevant demand For positive purposes, shocks to firm don’t move demand Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Static solution concepts Stigler’s theory of collusion Conjectural variations Consistent conjectures: estimating residual demand This lets us isolate the part of the market we want to consider 1 Residual demand facing a single firm Measured by Baker and Bresnahan (1988) Use firm-specific cost shocks (changes in factor prices) Apply to brewing industry; breweries in different locations Changes in transport costs, simple, easy methodology 2 Merger between two rival firms Next class we’ll talk more about mergers But key here is the effect of two firms merging Useful to separate from rest of the industry... Under consistent conjectures, you can do exactly this! 3 Could be applied more broadly (quality, antitrust) This approach, for historical reasons, largely go lost Great opportunity for a senior thesis! Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Incidence in symmetric oligopoly Is market power all bad? Cream-skimming and selection Conduct and incidence in symmetric oligopoly Simple way to summarize total industry conduct: All have price P(Q), each qi = Q n; cost C(Q) = nc Q n P MC = C 0 (Q) = c 0 ; = QP 0 P−MC · = θ; summarizes competitiveness D P θ = 0 in perfect competition; θ = 1 under monopoly Model nests/simplifies wide range of settings Suppose that θ constant in tax, price Same analysis as in monopoly shows ρ = 1 1+ D +θMS S In between monopoly and competition, indexed by θ If θ ↑ (↓) with tax or price, ↑ (↓) pass-through Incidence mix as well? 1 2 ρ dPS dCS dt = −(1 − θρ)Q, dt = −ρQ, I = 1−θρ ; w constant MC: θρ dDWL dPS d q̃ = −θρM, d q̃ = − [1 + (1 − θ) ρ] M, Ĩ = 1+(1−θ)ρ Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Incidence in symmetric oligopoly Is market power all bad? Cream-skimming and selection Graph of general oligopoly pricing Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Incidence in symmetric oligopoly Is market power all bad? Cream-skimming and selection Application to specific models Model a bit abstract; let’s note how others fit in 1 Cournot? 0 P − MC = −P 0 q = − PnQ so θ = n1 ; constant 2 Differentiated Bertrand? P−MC P ∂Q ∂P i n ∂qi ∂p = = 1 r ∂q i ∂pi =− q +(n−1) ∂q i ∂pi = − P Q∂Q ∂P " i P ∂qi ∂p ∂q i ∂pj ∂Q ∂P =⇒ θ = # i i n ∂qi ∂p ∂Q ∂P i n ∂qi ∂p ∂q j ∂p = 1 + (n − 1) ∂q i ≡1−D ∂pi ∂q i j ∂q j i ∂pi ∂pi ∂p ∂p D ≡ −(n − 1) ∂q i = −(n − 1) ∂q i aggregate diversion ratio Fraction of sales lost to me that go to one of my rivals Measure of real externalities per sale, so makes sense Not constant; usually falls with price so ρ bit overstated As prices higher, diversion to rivals products less attractive Everything earlier about incidence again applies here! Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Incidence in symmetric oligopoly Is market power all bad? Cream-skimming and selection Asymmetric oligopoly and misallocation Why less DWL in oligopoly (θMdq) than monopoly (Mdq)? Mdq = consumers substituting to perfectly competitive good =⇒ No real externalities from sales But if consumers instead substitute to good with mark-up =⇒ Subtract off real externality: M − M dq M is average mark-up of substituted-to good Directly (Bertrand) or indirectly (strategic under Cournot) Symmetric oligopoly: just reduces DWL proportionally Captured by θ But more interesting when not symmetric Then some firms may have higher mark-ups than others? 1 2 3 Differences in cost structure Differences in conduct, sophistication, conjectural parameters Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Differentiated product quality Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Incidence in symmetric oligopoly Is market power all bad? Cream-skimming and selection Misallocation in standard models 1 Cournot Each firm sets M = P 0 q so M ∝ q =⇒ Beneficial to reallocate to largest firms =⇒ Merger of big and small firm not always bad 2 Differentiated Bertrand Firm mark-up inversely proportional to own-elasticity Suppose one firm inelastic to outside good, other elastic =⇒ If close substitutes, may be good to merge, shut-down elastic Favoritism towards high mark-up firms 3 Monopolistic competition (Dixit-Stiglitz 1977) Constant elasticity, all firms same elasticity =⇒ Same (relative) mark-ups for all firms If perfectly competitive numeraire, too little production, entry But if whole economy, no distortion, first-best! =⇒ Harm of overall market power is retreat to autarky Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Incidence in symmetric oligopoly Is market power all bad? Cream-skimming and selection Beneficial market power Changes perspective on market power especially: Heterogeneity of market power, not level, key problem This leads to very different perspective on many issues 1 Strategy, collusion and conjectures in oligopoly Very harmful if one firm acts more competitively than others Persistent traitor to cartel arrangement can be bad! 2 Strategic behavior in mechanisms Many mechanisms (e.g. Budish): strategy like market power Lack of sophistication =⇒ inefficiency not just inequity Unsophisticated do worse, but harm sophisticated more! Who is the “bad guy” here? 3 Entry into industry with market power Trade-off of infra-marginal surplus and business stealing Keep out firms that are just copying, bring in really new Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Incidence in symmetric oligopoly Is market power all bad? Cream-skimming and selection Selection distortions in oligopoly So market power not all bad: real externalities Another case of real externalities is selection Before we studied free entry/average cost pricing Now let’s put into oligopoly model Suppose each firm gets representative sample, symmetric Profits P(Q)qi − QE [c|u ≥ P(Q)] Let AC ≡ E [c|u ≥ P(Q)] and MC ≡ E [c|u = P(Q)] What is first-order condition? P−[θMC+(1−θ)AC] P = θ =⇒ Weighted average of demand and MR, AC and MC What is optimal market structure? 1 2 With adverse selection? Competition as before! With advantageous selection? do at home: θ? = Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly MC−AC MS+MC−AC Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Incidence in symmetric oligopoly Is market power all bad? Cream-skimming and selection Optimal market structure with selection Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Incidence in symmetric oligopoly Is market power all bad? Cream-skimming and selection Cream-skimming and market collapse Now design distortions: differentiated Bertrand Cost same, given ρ; symmetric utility distribution Symmetric equilibrium/optimum in ρ, P Two margins: switching S between, each expansion X By symmetry, same for each, size M S and M X By symmetry, social optimum just change uniformly: NE [u 0 − c 0 |Θ] = M X Cov (u 0 , c|X ) Competition applies profit maximization to both margins 0 |X ∪S] −E[c 0 |Θ]=M X Cov(u 0 ,c|X )+ N E[u | {z } Spence distortion M S Cov(u 0 ,c|S) | {z } Rothschild-Stiglitz cream-skimming “Skim cream” from competitor; blows up as M S → ∞ Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Incidence in symmetric oligopoly Is market power all bad? Cream-skimming and selection Applications of cream-skimming This distortion may be important in some contexts 1 Erodes coverage in insurance markets Skim off the best customers 2 Inefficient hazing and workplace regulation Finance firms work long hours to skim from competitors Potential reason for workplace regulations I don’t think anyone has ever measured! 3 Informational racing in financial markets Try to get out ahead on buying stocks Wasteful tunnel from New York to Chicago 4 Competitive price-discrimination (Holmes 1989) Grandma’s and student may not stay home, just search This is just cream-skimming; general issue in discrimination Important and neglected downside of competition! Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis A simple case of Cournot’s theorem So competition perhaps not so great... But return to world where competition good Think about Cournot’s model: n → ∞ =⇒ θ → 0 P−MC → 0; efficient marginal cost pricing P =⇒ As long as bounded above 0 at P = MC Cournot’s Theorem As the number of competing firms grow arbitrarily large, price converges to marginal cost. One of the most fundamental results in economics Foundation of perfect competition Basis of most antitrust/competition policy When not Cournot, other definitions of θ → 0 Differentiated Bertrand: things become very substitutable... Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Entry with a distribution of costs Or with distribution of marginal costs ci May represent Bertrand competition or auction Optimal prices pi ≈ E [c2 |c1 = ci ] I “bid” my guess of second bid, conditional on me winning Exactly for inelastic demand, but lower with elastic I won’t go through proof, but pretty intuitive I “just try to beat” the next guy As the number of firms grow, what happens? Lots of firms near the lowest cost Thus lots of firms close to lowest-cost firm =⇒ E[c2 |c1 = ci ] → ci , c1 → c, lowest cost Thus price converges to lowest constant marginal cost Intuitive, as more firms, I am less necessary =⇒ As firms increase, again price to lowest cost Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Cournot’s theorem with Bertrand competition So again, in different setting, we obtain: Cournot’s Theorem with Bertrand competition As firms increase, prices gradually converge to lowest constant marginal cost. If all costs were not constant marginal... Then we would need everyone with different quantities This becomes efficient too, with competition =⇒ In very different model, same basic result Thus we can take this general rule about competition 1 2 Eventually, but not immediately, competition drives to cost With “enough” firms, price should be efficient =⇒ Natural question: how much is enough? Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Empirical study of the effect of entry Bresnahan and Reiss (1991) proposed clever way to study As market grows larger, can support more firms Call number of people to support N firms SN , sN = SNN Represents customers per firm at different numbers If prices same, only fixed cost, constant in N If price falls, then should decline, more for second guy s3 < s2 < s1 , etc. Could be other reasons as well: heterogeneity But pretty smart first pass, easy to implement 1 2 3 Found 5 professions in many rural towns How many people and professionals in each town? When does s start to level out? Interpret as convergence to perfect competition Around 3-5 professionals Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Bresnahan and Reiss (1991)’s data 996 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY to- v * (N co z Druggists Tire Dealers * Doctors * Dentists + Plumbers _N U) L0 C/ 0 4 5 12 Number of Firms FIG. 4.-Industry ratios Of S5 to sN by N Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly 56 Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Other arguments for and against competition policy This theory and empirical findings basis of competition policy Tries to make sure enough competition in markets We’ll talk a lot about this, but first arguments pro/con Pro: 1 2 3 Stop from assembling too much political, cultural power Screening out real externalities: don’t with competition and close substitutes; like screening willingness-to-pay “Too big to fail” in financial markets Con: 1 2 3 4 Cream-skimming and adverse selection Impedes economies of scale, profits from innovation Complementarities and coordination (Monday) Dynamic entry prevents problems; policy too late/slow Usually policy ignores other factors Lots of work to be done to include! Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis The Clayton Act and the US infrastructure In US, authority from Clayton Antitrust Act Sherman prevented illegal combinations (cartels) Clayton regulates legal combinations Why not block all mergers? Economies of scale! Efficient, may even benefit consumers Growing the ATT network may make reception better Thus agencies have to weigh v. anticompetitive effect Several agencies, but two primary share by industry? 1 2 Department of Justice Antitrust Division Federal Trade Commission Merging companies must pre-notify of intentions 1 2 3 Agencies subpoena data in several stages Analyze with team of ≈ 150 PhD economists Most survive, some settle and a few go to court Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Comparative international infrastructure Perhaps most sophisticated economic regulation in world Has been copied by most developed countries 1 2 European Commission now a major leader Also commonwealth: UK, Australia, New Zealand, etc. Much more primitive, unstructured in developing world 1 In many, no law against mergers even exists! 2 In others, law, but minimal infrastructure Perú is leading example Effectively no control, ineffective without cartel enforcement 3 Others have structure, but limited economics Colombia still writing guidelines, institution-building 4 A few aspire to developed sophistication China, Brazil, Chile, etc. Very heterogeneous across world Much to be gained by improving quality where weak Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Market definition and industry concentration Traditional evaluation based on “industry concentration” 1 Treat industry as single product; how? Requires “defining” boundaries of industry: which products? Start with merging products, adds closest substitutes? Both geographic and type of product Stop when a monopolist would raise prices by 5% for 1 year SSNIP: “Small but Significant and Nontransitory Increase in Price” 2 Measure industry concentration? Classic measure is Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index (HHI) P Let σi ≡ qQi , then H = i σi2 , sometimes multiply by 1000 1 H approximate number of firms; from above < 3 − 5 danger Also related to collusion (Stigler) and Cournot performance P − MCi = P 0 qi = 3 P σ i =⇒ P i i σi P−MC = P H Mergers causing H > 1800 and/or raising by > 300 flagged Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Current real-world merger policy Unfortunately this approach has proved very cumbersome: 1 Market definition often quite cumbersome: totally 0-1 2 Relevance of concentration somewhat ambiguous In Cournot, mergers increasing most the best (reduce cost) Thus merger guidelines issued by agencies moved away Represent official policy, guide to merging businesses Issued roughly each 10 years since 1980, latest in 2010 I was closely involved with this, similar in UK and EU 1992 all based on HHI and market definition New ones emphasize logic above (no need for definition!) Explicitly us differentiated products model Designed by Carl Shapiro and Joe Farrell, creators of UPP Progress on-going, new guidelines may reflect ideas above UK report on conjectural variations for merger review Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis A merger between differentiated products firms Let’s look at the approach from these reforms Idea: competition often between differentiated products =⇒ Merger doesn’t eliminate product, just consolidates Does competition help (merger hinder) in this case? Simplest case just focus on two merging firms A bit like monopoly: minimum of moving parts possible Other firms later; also assume Nash-in-Prices Demand Q i (pi , pj ), profits pi Q i pi , pj − C i Q i pi , pj Denote partial derivatives wrt own price by Q1i other Q2i 0 0 FOC pi Q1i + Q i − C i Q1i = 0; let MC i ≡ C i , divide by Q1i : pi = MC i + Qi : −Q1i price = MC + Cournot distortion If now merge, profits p1 Q 1 + p2 Q 2 + C 1 Q 1 + C 2 Q 2 FOC for p1 : Q 1 + p1 − MC 1 Q11 + p2 − MC 2 Q22 = 0 Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Upward Pricing Pressure and intuition Divide by Q11 , obtain: p1 = MC 1 + Q1 −Q11 + p2 − MC 2 Q22 −Q11 First two terms on right-hand side exactly as before Third term is new (effect of merger) so let’s focus on that: UPP2→1 ≡ p2 − MC 2 | {z } × mark-up on partner’s product:M 2 Q22 −Q 1 | {z 1} “diversion ratio” from 1 to 2:D12 Called the “Upward Pricing Pressure” from product 1 to 2 Always positive if substitutes: Q22 is positive if substitutes D: every burger BK sells, how many sales does MD lose? If they merge, BK internalizes the profits lost: M 2 D12 Exactly UPP: new opportunity cost created by merger Like any other cost, passed-through to prices! =⇒ All else equal, merger of competitors raises prices Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis A general model of oligopoly This gives us basic flavor but we left out: Other firms in the industry, conjectures (non-NiP) Adding these is relatively simple given our work: Define my residual demand taking into account conjectures Qii ≡ dQ i dpi = ∂Q i ∂pi + j ∂Q i dp j6=i ∂pj dpi P Qi Qii Then pre-merger optimum just like before: pi = MC i + Post-merger, though, we want to hold fixed other price If FOC’s for price, partial derivative makes us hold fixed But conjectures don’t allow this; need to define to shut down ei, Q e j hold fixed pj ; skip messy math =⇒ If i and j merger, let Q i i Then FOC as above: pi = MC i + Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Qi ei −Q i + pj − MC j ej Q i ei −Q i Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Generalized pricing pressure What are differences now? Well, two rather than one? 1 1 i i j j i e − − i p g ≡ Dj p − MC e i {z } | {z } | generalized UPP (GUPP) end of accommodating reactions (EAR) Two changes: e i holds fixed e i pj − MC j where D 1 GUPP: D j j Merging prices pj and whatever firm believes for others 2 EAR: merger partner reaction no longer anticipated More accommodating reactions =⇒ offsets GUPP more First term larger with reactions, but second more negative Different from (simplifies to) UPP: GUPP - EAR but... Result relatively robust to conjectures because offset Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Measuring pricing pressure How can we actually measure all this? Several approaches: 1 Internal company documents If we can get access, may discuss reactions, diversion Companies have to think about these things 2 Surveys and internet data Ask consumers about their second choice; like diversion Better: data from online, what other people bought etc. 3 Win-loss studies for auctions Who are most common first and second in auction? 4 Econometrics Estimate demand using changes in cost Difficult under NiP: need changes to all firms’ costs 5 Consistent conjectures (Baker and Bresnahan 1986) With consistent conjectures, residual demand for partners Thus only need changes in merging firm costs Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Pass-through and price impact We may want not just opportunity cost, but also price change But we know very well how to translate! If only one firm raised price, just multiply by pass-through This is basically right, but two (small) complications 1 2 Merger pushes up both merging firms’ prices Rise (strategically or otherwise) affects other firms’ prices All this covered by pass-through matrix ρ Each element is effect of one firm’s cost on another’s price Then if g is GePP for merging firms, 0 elsewhere: ∆p ≈ g> × ρ Don’t worry, you don’t really need to follow these matrices Key point is pass-through can be used to covert here This is lucky, because we use it for everything else Makes easy to measure: same cost shocks as for diversion Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly Oligopoly and Solution Concepts Incidence and the Downside of Competition Competition Policy Cournot’s theorem and other rationales The institutions of competition policy Merger analysis Prices and welfare impact How much do these changes in price hurt consumers? As always, by envelope, just multiply by quantity ∆CS ≈ −g> × ρ × Q Quantities particularly easy to measure Price index (percent increase) by dividing by p × Q How about social welfare? Need to find quantity changes: ∆Q ≈ g> × ρ × ∂Q ∂p Then multiply by mark-ups: ∆SS ≈ g> × ρ × ∂Q ∂p × M Longer, but all stuff we had from before (demand, etc.) Just like monopoly comparative statics, simple principles Benefit of normative: can incorporate other effects: 1 2 Platforms, quality and Spence distortion Selection and cream-skimming distortions Very active area of research Weyl Summer Course Oligopoly