Types of equilibrium: The state of equilibrium is found in several aspects of economics. Any economy where equilibrium condition prevails is said to prosper well. Major types of equilibrium are as follows: Market equilibrium Market equilibrium is referred to as a state in which the goods produced is equal to the goods consumed. Price here remains same and continues to remain same until there is change in supply or demand of goods. Partial equilibrium Partial equilibrium is a state in economy where market is cleared of some specific goods. The clearance is obtained irrespective of influences of prices and quantities of goods that are either demanded or supplied in other markets. Thus, it can be said that the market clearance is obtained when the prices of all substitutes and complements, as well as income levels of consumers are invariable. General equilibrium General equilibrium is study of supply, demand, and prices. This is a branch of microeconomics. Here consumers are assumed as price takers. They decide the price of the commodity. General equilibrium can be explained by using several theorems. First Fundamental Theorem, Second Fundamental Theorem and Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu Theorem are the major theorems of general equilibrium. General equilibrium theory is a branch of theoretical neoclassical economics. It seeks to explain the behavior of supply, demand and prices in a whole economy with several or many markets, by seeking to prove that equilibrium prices for goods exist and that all prices are at equilibrium, hence general equilibrium, in contrast to partial equilibrium. As with all models, this is an abstraction from a real economy; it is proposed as being a useful model, both by considering equilibrium prices as long-term prices and by considering actual prices as deviations from equilibrium. The difference is not as clear as it used to be, since much of modern macroeconomics has emphasized microeconomic foundations, and has constructed general equilibrium models of macroeconomic fluctuations. General equilibrium macroeconomic models usually have a simplified structure that only incorporates a few markets, like a "goods market" and a "financial market". In contrast, general equilibrium models in the microeconomic tradition typically involve a multitude of different goods markets. They are usually complex and require computers to help with numerical solutions. Properties and characterization of general equilibrium: Fundamental theorems of welfare economics Basic questions in general equilibrium analysis are concerned with the conditions under which an equilibrium will be efficient, which efficient equilibria can be achieved, when an equilibrium is guaranteed to exist and when the equilibrium will be unique and stable. First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics The First Fundamental Welfare Theorem asserts that market equilibria are Pareto efficient. In a pure exchange economy, a sufficient condition for the first welfare theorem to hold is that preferences be locally nonsatiated. The first welfare theorem also holds for economies with production regardless of the properties of the production function. Implicitly, the theorem assumes complete markets and perfect information. In an economy with externalities, for example, it is possible for equilibria to arise that are not efficient. The first welfare theorem is informative in the sense that it points to the sources of inefficiency in markets. Under the assumptions above, any market equilibrium is tautologically efficient. Therefore, when equilibria arise that are not efficient, the market system itself is not to blame, but rather some sort of market failure. Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics While every equilibrium is efficient, it is clearly not true that every efficient allocation of resources will be an equilibrium. However, the second theorem states that every efficient allocation can be supported by some set of prices. In other words, all that is required to reach a particular outcome is a redistribution of initial endowments of the agents after which the market can be left alone to do its work. This suggests that the issues of efficiency and equity can be separated and need not involve a trade-off. The conditions for the second theorem are stronger than those for the first, as consumers' preferences now need to be convex (convexity roughly corresponds to the idea of diminishing rates of marginal substitution, or to preferences where "averages are better than extrema"). Existence Even though every equilibrium is efficient, neither of the above two theorems say anything about the equilibrium existing in the first place. To guarantee that an equilibrium exists we once again need consumer preferences to be convex (although with enough consumers this assumption can be relaxed both for existence and the second welfare theorem). Similarly, but less plausibly, feasible production sets must be convex, excluding the possibility of economies of scale. Proofs of the existence of equilibrium generally rely on fixed point theorems such as Brouwer fixed point theorem or its generalization, the Kakutani fixed point theorem. In fact, one can quickly pass from a general theorem on the existence of equilibrium to Brouwer’s fixed point theorem. For this reason many mathematical economists consider proving existence a deeper result than proving the two Fundamental Theorems. Competitive market equilibrium Competitive market equilibrium is referred to the state of stability that prevails in a market where there are flexible prices and many traders. Competitive market equilibrium includes a vector of prices and allocation is done in such a way that each trader maximizes his profit function.