Business Case and Intervention Summary Intervention Summary Title: Innovation Prizes for Environment and Development (IP4ED) What support will the UK provide? DFID will provide £15m over five years to a new innovative programme, supporting research and development (R&D) on climate technologies in developing countries. The programme will launch a number of innovation / incentive prizes to encourage further research to develop and deploy technologies for low income consumers. These technologies will improve poor people’s access to affordable clean energy, safe drinking water and other climate/environmental services. Prize competitions have been used as a mechanism to spur innovation for centuries – dating back to the Longitude Prize in 1714. Innovation prizes offer a prize pot (money) to successful teams that achieve a pre-defined outcome. They focus on a well-defined ‘problem statement’ – a problem with no existing solution, or a requirement for a new product that may use a combination of existing technologies. They are considered an efficient and effective mechanism for promoting innovation, and ‘crowd in’ much larger investments than the original amount offered in prize money (for example, the Ansari X-Prize worth $10m is credited with leveraging $100m in R&D finance from twenty six organisations 1). This ‘crowding in’ of private investment into a specific, unsolved problem is one of the biggest strengths of the prize approach. By offering a financial and reputational reward (on successful achievement of results), the programme aims to encourage new, private investment in environmental technologies that will benefit the poor, while simultaneously helping to build developing country capacity to innovate by actively encouraging participants from developing countries. DFID support will go towards the design and establishment of the prize programme, including research on problem statements and the launch of 5 innovation prizes associated with finding solutions to poor people’s access to affordable clean energy, safe drinking water and other climate/environmental services. Why is UK support required? 1.29 billion people live on less than US$1.25 a day and lack access to basic services including energy, water and sanitation. A number of interconnected global and local challenges are likely to exacerbate their situation further: resources are becoming more scarce and expensive; climate change is threatening communities and livelihoods; population is growing, placing greater demands on the environment; the global economy is becoming more volatile, with more frequent shocks and stresses. 1 http://space.xprize.org/ansari-x-prize 1 In all the above, the poor generally suffer first and most. The scale and urgency of this challenge means a step-change in our response is required – ‘business as usual’ is insufficient to tackle poverty in the face of a rapidly changing world. Step-changes are often driven by innovation. Successful innovation (creation and implementation of new or improved processes, products, methods) can result in significant improvements in impact, outcomes, efficiency, effectiveness or quality. This includes innovation in technologies, business models and policies. However, innovation efforts targeted at solving or addressing the problems of the poorest and most vulnerable often do not happen as they are not a priority for private finance. There are broadly two ways to address this: a. direct intervention – providing direct R&D grants to researchers ex-ante to develop these technologies and business models; b. indirect interventions – to stimulate the market into producing innovative technologies and business models. Innovation or incentive prize competitions are one way of doing this. At present DFID’s approach largely utilises (a) above - the standard approach for commissioning research. This business case illustrates the value in adding a new, marketbased approach to the way we promote R&D for technology development – particularly given the need to effect a step change in addressing poverty. Evidence from previous prize competitions illustrated that the return on investment for prizes has the potential to be impressive. It is therefore deemed good value for money to add prizes to the portfolio of tools DFID uses to stimulate innovation, reaching large numbers of poor beneficiaries and bringing in new socially orientated innovators. The UK is recognised as a leader in climate technology innovation, through our support domestically for innovation and our international efforts in pushing the climate technology negotiations to deliver more for developing countries. The UK is well placed to fill this current gap in support of innovative solutions that address poor people’s needs, build resilience and support wealth creation, through the use of climate technologies. This programme will support UK and DFID commitments, including the UK’s International Climate Fund (ICF) priorities: creating and using new technologies; building knowledge and innovation through research and development; influence the architecture and delivery of finance by piloting new innovative mechanisms; promote private sector investment in low carbon infrastructure and service delivery; and help demonstrate a range of approaches, with a rigorous focus on lesson learning and learning by doing. DFID’s Secretary of State has also highlighted the opportunity of programmes to support technology in a speech in October 2012 saying, “I want to make sure that DFID is at the heart of this technology debate, and doing all it can to pioneer innovation and the use of technology to improve development.” What are the expected results? The expected impact is that 12 million people will have improved access to energy and water services through innovative, affordable technologies and business models for ‘bottom of the 2 economic pyramid’ consumers by 2025. This programme will lead to a range of affordable and accessible technologies being developed, and to business models being researched and tested that will improve the access of poor people to these technologies. The programme will also ‘crowd-in’ new investment. In practical terms, the programme aims to deliver the following results by the end of 2016/17: 1. At least £35m of new private investment in technologies and business models attracted in 2. At least 7 new, affordable and accessible climate technologies developed for poor people 3. At least 5 affordable and accessible climate technologies deployed to poor people 4. At least 50% of entrants applying for prizes are new teams/organisations to DFID’s funding for research in this area 3 Business Case Strategic Case 4 A. Context and need for a DFID intervention What is the problem we are trying to address? 1.29 billion people live on less than US$1.25 a day2 and lack access to basic services including energy, water and sanitation. Global and local challenges exacerbate the problem: resources are becoming more scarce and expensive3 climate change is threatening communities and livelihoods4 population is growing5 the global economy is becoming more volatile, with the poor suffering more frequent shocks and stresses6 Particular needs which require greater attention are: Energy – modern energy services are crucial to human well-being and to a country’s economic development. However globally over 1.3 billion people are without access to electricity and 2.7 billion people are without clean cooking facilities7. The recent launch of the UN’s Sustainable Energy for All targets and goals for 2030 8 provide an opportunity to build on international interest in this field and incentivise innovation and investment in developing countries aimed at addressing the needs of the poor. Water, sanitation and hygiene (WASH) - while major gains have been made, with the MDG drinking-water target being met in 2012, challenges remain, particularly in the area of sanitation. There are likely to be about 800 million people with unimproved water supplies and more than 2 billion lacking sanitation facilities by 20159. Climate change adaptation - the world is already locked into some warming due to past emissions and projected impacts of climate change are severe10. Adaptation solutions are urgently needed in developing countries, particularly areas already prone to erratic rainfall, droughts, floods and cyclones, as climate change will further exacerbate ongoing challenges. The scale and urgency of this challenge means a step-change in our response is required – there is value in adding new tools to the way we help alleviate poverty in the currently rapidly changing world. Step-changes are normally driven by innovation. Successful innovation (creation and implementation of new or improved processes, products, methods) can result in significant improvements in impact, outcomes, efficiency, effectiveness or quality. 2 The World Bank Development Research Group, Global Poverty Indicators 2010. Available at: http://povertydata.worldbank.org/poverty/home 3 Evans, A. & Evans, J. (2011) Resource Scarcity, Wellbeing and Development. NYU Center on International Cooperation, New York and Centre for the History ofthe Emotions, Queen Mary University of London, London. 4 UNFCCC (2007) Climate Change: Impacts, Vulnerabilities and Adaptation in Developing Countries. UNFCCC, Bonn, Germany. 5 UN Department of Economic and Social Affairs (2011) World Population Prospects The 2010 Revision. 6 Farhad, M. (2011) The Global Economic Crisis, Contemporary Protectionism, and Least Developed Countries (LDCs). World Trade Institute, Switzerland. 7 IEA (2011) World Energy Outlook 2011. International Energy Agency, France. 8 More information on the Sustainable Energy for All agenda can be found here: http://www.sustainableenergyforall.org/. 9 Bradley, D. (2012) Water Security and Health Brief No. 3 Oxford University Department of Zoology, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine. 10 All from World Bank 2010 World Development Report - 1-2 billion more facing water shortages p.5 (citing Parry and others 2007, table TS.3, p.66); more frequent and intense extreme events p.5. 5 This includes innovation in: technology (e.g. developing new technologies or modifying currently available ones) service delivery (e.g. new ways of providing health services, like doctors, to people) business models (e.g. new payment plans for consumers) policies and regulations (e.g. tax breaks, intellectual property laws) Whilst the market (including for-profit companies, social enterprises, and civil society organisations) can be expected to respond to some of this challenge, experience indicates that it will not respond to those areas and issues that are of most relevance to the poorest and most vulnerable11. The market for new information (e.g. research and knowledge) is characterised by pervasive market failures. New information is non-rivalrous, meaning that one person’s use of it doesn’t prevent another person from using it, and it is difficult, though not impossible, to stop people accessing new knowledge once it has been created. These public good properties mean private firms are likely to undersupply new knowledge, as they can’t capture all of the benefits. This is exacerbated by the special problem that information is hard to evaluate: you don’t know how much it is worth until you have it. In this case the intended users of new technology are poor. This is important for two reasons. First, the poor have limited purchasing power, leaving firms with little incentive to develop technologies for them. Therefore, there is a distributional argument in favour of incentivising the development of technologies that address the needs of the poor. Moreover, the fact that the poor are a user group that firms are less familiar with means it is difficult to assess the potential demand for new technologies (uncertain/unknown demands and returns), exacerbating the risk involved in developing new products for them. Incentivising and introducing new players into this thin market will reveal more information about poor consumers, reducing risks and potentially encouraging others. Government action to address these issues for poor consumers takes the form of: (1) Direct government intervention e.g. funding ex-ante research efforts; safety nets such as cash transfers to the poor or subsidies on electricity; or (2) Indirect government intervention drawing on and utilising the power of the market and supporting it to address the needs of poor consumers. How can DFID respond – the opportunities DFID works closely with others (donors, multilateral development banks, developing country governments) to support (1) above. We also support (2) in the instance where we procure specific research and development on the open market. However, we tend to use a small number of procurement models. There is an opportunity to broaden our portfolio of procurement models to include approaches that both broaden and deepen our engagement with the private sector and support the growth of sustainable markets that provides for poor consumers in the long-term. There are significant opportunities for developing countries to innovate and leapfrog the developed world’s pattern of technology development and growth. A recent study by the 11 Karnani, A. (2009) Romanticizing the Poor, Standford Social Innovation Review, Standford University, CA. 6 Institute for Integrated Economic Research (IIER) found substantial potential in the agricultural sector, where improved low carbon technologies can enhance well-being, health, and even GDP without significantly raising carbon emissions (or in some cases with reduced carbon-dioxide outputs)12. There are also a number of new innovation approaches that illustrate the potential for building capacity in developing countries for innovation, including13: Inclusive innovation – Brings vast amount of benefits to a large number of people for very little cost. This can be inclusive in outputs (resulting technology or services) and in the process (including bottom of the pyramid consumers in the development, design, dissemination process itself). The Tata Nano is an example – the inexpensive production process produces an inexpensive product that many people can afford. Cheap mobile phone handset and price plans are another. Reverse innovation – Products designed, created, and manufactured in a developing country. The product may initially be designed to meet developing world demands for lower cost, then exported to developed world markets as a cheaper alternative (e.g. Nestlé selling low-cost, low-fat dried noodles originally created for rural India as a healthy product in Australia and New Zealand). Disruptive innovation – New technologies or products for new markets and a different unserved set of consumers. The new products go on to disrupt an existing market as more value is added; displacing an older technology often through lowered prices (e.g. early low cost plastics had very limited use, mainly for electric insulation. As they’ve developed more value, they have replaced many products like household appliances previously made from wood or metal – chopping boards and kettles). Open innovation – A process of linking people with varying expertise working in different institutions and countries, to accelerate the development of a specific technology/idea. However, there is no silver bullet for DFID to support that will ensure innovation in product and service delivery. Instead, a portfolio approach is required where a range of mechanisms target different needs that occur at different times in the innovation process. This business case is part of a package of programmes to address the various weaknesses in the market’s ability to provide solutions for poor people, illustrated in the innovation chain below. The innovation chain/process (see Figure 1) is a process that all new ideas and concepts follow – starting with idea generation; building prototypes, testing the idea; developing it for first entry into the market; early adoption by the market; to finally, full commercialisation of the product/service/idea. The range of initiatives available to address the various individual barriers have been plotted onto the diagram below. Kunz, H., Rembrandt, K., Raettig, T., Balogh, S. (2011) Low Carbon and Economic Growth – Key Challenges, Institute for Integrated Economic Research, Switzerland. 13 Described in: Morey, J., Milford, L., Madeira, L., Stori, V. (2011) Moving Climate Innovation into the 21st Century: Emerging Lessons from other Sectors and Options for a New Climate Innovation Initiative. Clean Energy Group, US. 12 7 Figure 1: the technology innovation chain or process Technology Prizes Business model prizes National Climate Innovation Centres Results-based financing Early-stage fund for SMEs and entrepreneurs Deployment research questions Source: Sagar A (2011)14 As highlighted in Figure 1 above, there are two funding and support gaps (‘valleys of death’) where an idea or technology can fail due to a lack of finance as well as a lack of knowhow or skills to take the idea to the next stage. This business case aims to test a new approach to addressing both these gaps through an incentive prize – providing a cash incentive for organisations to invest in R&D in technologies and different business models that serve the bottom of the pyramid market. Most global R&D is focused on high-end developed world products and services because the demand and people’s willingness to pay is well understood. This is not the case with bottom of the pyramid consumers in developing countries. As such, the vast majority of public and private spending on technology development pays little attention to the needs of the poor. In addition to technology development (and/or adaptation of existing technologies for use in different situations and locations), testing and trialling of different business models that help scale up and socialisation of technologies to reach poor consumers is also needed (including how social uses shape and re-shape the nature of technology). Often what is restricting deployment is related to social aspects of the market, for example social barriers (behavioural or cultural issues) and financial barriers (consumers ability to purchase and pay for goods and services provided by the technology). There are opportunities to further understand which new, innovative business models might help reach more consumers in a sustainable, longterm manner. However, supporting R&D and innovation can be unpredictable and risky – some ideas/inventions will succeed and some will fail. An effective response to the uncertainty of 14 Menon, J., Sagar, A. (2012) Prize-Driven Innovation for Development. X PRIZE Foundation, US and IIT Delhi, India. 8 returns may be to develop a portfolio or menu of approaches and of technologies/ideas to reduce the impact of individual failures15. As such, DFID is working on a number of programmes (illustrated on the innovation chain above): National climate innovation centres: national hubs in developing countries to support climate technology SMEs by providing some finance ($10k-$500k) and technical assistance (e.g. developing a business plan, linking to universities to build prototypes, etc.). Centres will help organisations network with local supply chains and distribution networks and potential financiers16. Low carbon results-based financing: a programme to support deployment of renewable energy technologies by providing a cash payment to the project developer when they achieve results (e.g. 10,000 solar lanterns sold; 2,000 new households connected to a renewable mini-grid). The cash payment tapers off each year until the project is earning revenues and sustainable without the extra support. Early-stage flexible fund: flexible fund to support early-stage entrepreneurs and SMEs to develop and test their business models. The fund will support various climate technologies in a range of countries and aims to build these enterprises into a position that they are attractive to private investors, such as venture capitalist. Deployment research questions: commissioning a series of key questions on innovation and deployment of climate technologies – why has it worked in some context and not others; what are the social, cultural and institutional issues; how do we measure innovation in the informal sector; etc. Innovation prizes – for technology and business models – the focus of this business case. A series of stakeholder consultations (private sector, academics, donors, civil society, Foundations, colleagues from other sectors) and two reports commissioned by DFID (described below) illustrate that an innovation prize programme is a valuable addition to traditional approaches to stimulate innovation and address climate change. Innovation prize programme – the proposed intervention Developing countries suffer not only from an inadequate pipeline of adapted and/or new technologies and products to suit their needs, but also from market demand incapable of exerting the kind of ‘pull’ that might solve that problem without public intervention. Developing market consumers generally do not have the collective purchasing power that would stimulate such innovation. Innovation, incentive or inducement prizes serve as a means to induce, or “pull” innovation and are one tool increasingly used to incentivise R&D in markets where uncertainty of returns stifle innovation. Prizes offer rewards (generally financial, but sometimes business development assistance) for pre-specified scientific or technological achievements, such as the development of a device or method to perform a particular function within given parameters17. Prizes are well understood and have been used for centuries to encourage innovation. Perhaps the most well-known early prize was the Longitude Prize of 1714 – the winning technology is still used today. However, to date they have not generally been used to 15 Stern, N. (2006) The Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, United Kingdom. For more information see infoDev’s Climate Technology Program: http://www.infodev.org/en/Topic.19.html 17 Adler, J. H. (2010) Eyes on the Climate Prize: Rewarding Energy Innovation to Achieve Climate Stablization. Prepared for the Rethinking the Foundations of Climate Change Law and Policy workshop, October 23, 2009. 16 9 encourage innovation that addresses the needs of the poor. Prizes work best in situations where there are clear, objective goals and a well-defined ‘problem statement’, with many participants who are willing to bear risks 18. McKinsey’s report on philanthropic prizes (2009) identifies when prizes are more likely to be effective (i.e. clear, achievable goal; many solvers; and solvers willing to accept outcome risk) – illustrated in Figure 2 below. The pull mechanism of prizes can be deployed either on its own; as a complement to other pull mechanisms such as advance market commitments (AMCs) (e.g. commitments to buy a percentage of the prize winning solution); or in conjunction with “push” mechanisms such as research grants (e.g. grants to allow individuals to compete in the competition – the hybrid prize-grant option identified below). Figure 2: decision tree – when to use prizes McKinsey (2009) The economic characteristics and functions of prizes, as identified by Vivid Economics19 are: 1. They provide a financial incentive, which serves to lever investment towards specific purposes 2. In the process of competing for a prize, investors, entrepreneurs, inventors, and potential future customers are brought together; 3. They encourage commercialisation of innovations, both through by linking and networking potential funders, competitors, audience, and through signalling the most promising innovations; McKinsey & Company (2009) ‘And the winner is’… Capturing the promise of philanthropic prizes. Vivid Economics (2007) The Economics of Climate Change Prizes: Synthesis. Vivid Economics, UK. 18 19 10 4. They have broader sociological impacts, such as the popularisation of a particular challenge, which may further strengthen the financial, matching, and commercialisation effects of prizes. Further evidence from DFID’s commissioned reports highlight the case for exploring the use of innovation prizes to develop and deploy technologies for environmental problems in developing countries. These reports have been drawn on considerably in designing this programme and are referenced throughout this business case. An evidence review commissioned through the DEW Point resource centre20 on the value for money and effectiveness of prizes for development. This study found that prizes can be effective when appropriately designed and targeted, and that potential payoffs and value for money of adding prizes to a toolkit for encouraging innovation are considerable. A report by the X-Prize Foundation and the Indian Institute of Technology (IIT-Delhi)21 on the use of prizes to address market failures in developing countries. The report highlights the importance of the research, design and planning process, and includes guidance on designing and operating prizes and eleven stakeholder-suggested prize concepts, spanning energy, agriculture, buildings, water and sanitation. There has been a recent resurgence of interest in the use of prizes to spur innovation in areas considered to be socially and economically important (see: http://keionline.org/prizes/cites for a list of articles and books). This is because traditional innovation tools are sometimes inadequate, particularly in least developed countries with less sophisticated science and technology systems. Traditional innovation policy has relied on a combination of regulation, subsidies, the patent system and government research. A growing body of evidence suggests that prizes can similarly support innovation, but with additional benefits. For example, prizes can be targeted to more specific challenges than regulation, while being open and flexible to the full range of possible solutions. Compared to subsidies they ensure the risks of failure fall on the private sector where they can be managed most efficiently. The patent system has received criticism on its ability to stimulate innovation, particularly for small businesses22. In addition, in developing countries the Intellectual Property (IP) system is nascent and not well enforced. In addition, it recognised that prizes can create significant leverage, crowding in private sector investment to solve specific problems. Everett (2011) found that returns on investment (RoI) for innovation awards range from 2:1 to 33:1 benefit cost ratios; and around 8:1 to 16:1 for market stimulation (grand) prizes. Finally, unlike traditional public R&D spending, prizes can help in the creation of new markets through greater public awareness and potential investment opportunities for future deployment. Everret, B. (2011) Evidence Review – Environmental Innovation Prizes for Development. DEW Point Enquiry No.A0405. Commissioned by DFID. Available at: http://teamsite/sites/policydivision/srvm/lowcarbon/Renewable%20Energy%20Technology/Evidence% 20Review%20Environmental%20Innovation%20Prizes%20for%20Development%20(July%202011).p df 21 See endnote 14 – Prize-Driven Innovation for Development. 22 This varies depending on the sector. For example, it could be argued that much R&D for pharmaceutical drugs would not go ahead without the ability to apply for patents for resulting products. See Macdonald, S. (2004) When means become ends: considering the impact of patent strategy on innovation. Information Economics and Policy 16: 135-158. 20 11 Prizes are not a universal solution and are most effective where they complement existing policies23. There are functions which other policies might perform better than a prize e.g. once a technological breakthrough has been achieved, regulation may be more effective at encouraging wide roll-out and technology diffusion through, for example, imposing sectorwide standards. As such, regulation and prizes may complement each other when deployed in succession. Vivid Economics (2007) finds prizes well suited to achieving certain public policy goals, in particular triggering key bottleneck innovations that may be held back by a variety of market failures, at low costs. Everett (2011) points out that, while the optimal level of resources that should be devoted to prizes may not be clear, it is ‘surely much larger than at present’. Both sources indicate that prizes are not an alternative to other public policy interventions, and that combinations of instruments may be needed to address certain challenges, including climate change. Types of prizes Everret (2011) categorised the types of prizes into: Market stimulation – large international, highly publicised prizes with one large prize purse (typically greater than US$1m) e.g. X PRIZE Challenges24. These prizes can run for more than four years until the successful ‘solution’ is awarded. Innovation awards – prizes typically awarded for new start-up business ideas or technologies e.g. the annual Shell Springboard25 and the annual Ashden Awards for Sustainable Energy26. Open innovation – posting a specific problem to a wide audience, taking advantage of a large pool of potential problem solvers – the successful solver wins the prize e.g. InnoCentive27 and NineSigma28 platforms. Social challenges – design to engage with and benefit communities e.g. the Nirmal Gram Pursakar Total Sanitation Campaign in India29. In addition, a single prize can be designed and disseminated in a variety of ways, including: Single, large: one, large prize directed toward a specific, measurable, ex ante target with one irrefutable prize winner. Stage-gate: a framework for dividing product development into discrete stages which are separated by decision points or 'gates’. The purpose of gates is to ensure that the successful project is on track and to make a “go/kill” decision for continuation. Gate reviews are based on established criteria that must be met in order to proceed to the next stage in the process. One option is to progress fewer and fewer successful projects after each gate, until a final one or two win a final prize. 23 The large majority of reviews of innovation prizes include this finding, see: endnote 14; endnote 18; endnote 19; endnote 20. 24 http://www.xprize.org/ 25 http://www.shellspringboard.org/ 26 http://www.ashden.org/ 27 http://www.innocentive.com/ 28 http://www.ninesigma.com/ 29 http://nirmalgrampuraskar.nic.in/ 12 Proportional: pays out in proportion to success, where success is defined as a level of impact. For example, a prize could be paid out to educators in proportion to the number of school children that achieve certain test levels, thus rewarding the most successful techniques. Incremental: similar to stage-gate prizes, these could measure incremental efficiency increases in performance, for example, on an annual basis. The key steps in prize development and implementation illustrated in Figure 3 and described below in greater detail (Annex 1 provides a ‘rule of thumb’ for prize design). Figure 3: broad stages in prize process McKinsey (2009) Detailed consultation and research is required at each stage for each individual prize. 1. Setting the goal to either incentivise: finding a new solution to a problem or an existing solution and apply it to the problem. 2. Identifying the likely competitors – crucial for choosing the type of prize. 3. Selecting the type of prize – e.g. market stimulation; staged; proportional; etc. 4. Designing the type and size of reward – e.g. cash reward; future contract with strings attached; recognition and reputation. 5. Determining an appropriate cost of entry – including admin cost of demonstrating success criteria has been met; effort in developing prize entry; risk the innovation will be copied; etc. 6. Determining entry rules – to minimise admin costs and potentially support other policy objectives (e.g. gender), but balanced to ensure success and effectiveness of prize. 7. Launching the prize to target key audiences and achieve intended results. DFID is proposing to establish a new innovation prize platform to incentivise R&D and support successful solutions that address a set of defined problem statements. This single platform would launch a number of individual prizes (up to five initially) using the various prize types described above (e.g. stage-gate, proportional, etc.). We intend to develop this programme following a competitive tender process for the appropriate prize-running organisation (described in more detail in the Commercial Case). The successful bidder will then embark on a design phase for the programme, which, if approved by DFID, will be implemented. 13 Examples of issues/problems amenable to the prize approach are listed below. These were gathered through research and consultation with DFID Advisers in-country, entrepreneurs, civil society and others working on climate solutions for poor people; and are used for analysis in this business case. The final choice of problem statements might not be exactly the same, but are likely to be similar. Annex 2 contains a list of some of the evidence base for this selection. small-scale waste-to-energy solutions for urban slums quick, cheap, reliable microbiological testing of water low carbon cooling technologies (low energy, low refrigerants for either buildings or food preservation) low-cost (sub U$5) machine-to-machine (M2M) data chip to include in pay-as-you-go products30, and business models for pay-as-you-go ‘basics’ household modern energy services31 household energy storage that doesn't involve batteries What are others doing? The UK is recognised as a leader in climate technology innovation, through our support domestically for innovation (notably through the UK’s Carbon Trust) and our international efforts in pushing the climate technology negotiations to deliver more for developing countries. Few donors are working on similar interventions to support the interconnection of: innovation and R&D; climate technologies; and developing countries. There are a number of organisations that run prizes/competitions both nationally and internationally listed in Section C of the Commercial Case, however, no one organisation is currently running innovation/incentive prizes for climate technologies in developing countries. The US’s interest in prizes was cemented in law in 2010 when Congress expanded authority to use prizes to every government department32. India has also indicated its interest in partnering with the UK on climate innovation more broadly and has launched a number of its own domestic prizes in the past33. In addition, the Clean Energy Ministerial 2013 will be hosted in India in April 2013 and with a strong focus on innovation. Foundations such as Gates, Shell and Rockefeller have also indicated early interest; while AusAID and Norad have growing interest in innovation and climate. It is anticipated that partners may join DFID in funding particular prizes depending on their interest area, once the programme is underway. Other market-based programmes that provide support to test and pilot concepts are often not thematically focused (e.g. USAID’s Development Innovation Ventures 34) and rarely support low carbon energy given the level of real and perceived risks associated. The DFID-supported This is a recent addition to the list of potential problems to be explored and is a ‘problem statement’ which has developed through another DFID-supported project with the Shell Foundation and M-Kopa Solar. 31 This is included as an indication of a ‘business model’ prize. This particularly problem is likely to be addressed by the private sector without the need of an innovation prize as an incentive (pay-as-yougo systems are currently being developed and deployed by M-Kopa, Eight19, etc.). 32 http://www.whitehouse.gov/blog/2010/12/21/congress-grants-broad-prize-authority-all-federalagencies 33 The Nirmal Gram Pursakar; the National Biomass Cookstoves Initiative. 34 http://www.usaid.gov/div/ 30 14 African Enterprise Challenge Fund (AECF) Renewable Energy and Climate Adaptation Technologies (REACT35) programme provides matched-funds to support businesses in East Africa to scale-up their renewable energy or adaptation business. DFID Caribbean is supporting a Caribbean-only contest for any innovative low carbon ideas (IDEAS36). These challenge funds are relatively broad in coverage and do not use a well-defined ‘problem statement’ to incentivise private sector R&D. This programme will contribute to the approaches available to DFID and the wider development community to stimulate R&D, and will build on lessons learnt from the programmes described above and others that stimulate innovation. Supporting HMG and DFID commitments, RED and ICF priorities This work aims to support HMG and DFID commitments, and Research and Evidence Division (RED) and International Climate Fund (ICF) priorities, including building a robust evidence base for policy making, working with the private sector, and supporting innovation in climate change. The intervention will directly support a number of RED and ICF priorities that have been identified as needing a greater focus, including: - Creating and using new technologies (RED Research Strategy 2008-2013) - Demonstrate results in producing pioneering technologies in both traditional and new fields (RED Results Framework) - Building knowledge and innovation through research and development (ICF Implementation Plan) - Influence the architecture and delivery of finance by piloting new innovative mechanisms (ICF LCD objectives) - Promote private sector investment in low carbon infrastructure and service delivery (ICF LCD objectives) - Help demonstrate a range of approaches, with a rigorous focus on lesson learning and learning by doing (ICF Implementation Plan) Contributing to the evidence base There are three key opportunities (outputs) to contribute to the evidence base on climate technology innovation through this programme: 1. Technologies developed and initial deployment The programme will directly incentivise R&D spend and the development/modification of climate technologies by private organisations and research institutions through offering a cash and recognition award if they are the winners of the prize. Examples from other incentive prizes demonstrate how significant this can be: the Ansari X-Prize was a US$10m prize which resulted in US$100m of R&D by private companies striving to win. Although only one company won, seven companies now operate in the market (which didn’t exist prior to the prize). Reporting on both the winners and losers will be an important part of the M&E framework to contribute to the evidence base and understanding innovation for climate technologies for low income consumers. 2. Research of ‘problem statements’ In identifying appropriate problem statements to be addressed by a prize, the programme will conduct in-depth research and consultation with a wide group of 35 36 http://www.aecfafrica.org/react/ http://www.iadb.org/en/topics/energy/ideas/ideas,3808.html 15 stakeholders, mapping the state of play of currently available technologies and active stakeholders. This research is critical to the success of the prize and will result in a high level of publically available information and evidence on real and perceived gaps in the service delivery market for poor consumers. 3. Evaluation of the use of innovation prizes The programme will provide insight into the use of innovation prizes to achieve environmental and development goals, particularly for the bottom of the pyramid consumers, by evaluating each prize and building an understanding of lessons learnt. Empower women and girls, and youth This programme presents an opportunity to help meet DFID’s new strategic vision for girls and women. A recent publication by the UN highlights the importance of both ensuring women’s role in science and technology (women IN science) and developing and implementing science and technology approaches which benefit women (science FOR women). This involves consulting and working with women in the choice, development and application of technologies; providing them access to resources; ensuring their contribution to and benefit from science and technology innovations; and recognising and supporting their local knowledge and innovative practices37. During the design phase analysis will be carried out to determine how the intervention might effectively support the inclusion of women in the programme (to both advise and to compete), while also encouraging the breakdown of intergenerational cycles of poverty by supporting and empowering youth as champions of change. Data on jobs created as a result of the programme will be collected and disaggregated by gender and age. The consequences of not intervening Without DFID’s intervention, it is likely that private investment in climate technologies for low income consumers in developing countries will remain untapped. DFID will continue to use traditional ways to support a select number of researchers ex-ante to develop new and modify existing technologies for deployment. Given the market situation in developing countries (notably the uncertainty of returns and demand), it is unlikely the private sector will invest heavily in R&D and innovation for low income consumers, who will continue to be unable to access clean energy, safe drinking water and sanitation. We will be less likely to achieve the step change required to tackle poverty in the face of emerging threats. 37 Miroux, A. (2010) Mainstreaming a Gender Perspective in Science, Technology and Innovation Policy, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Switzerland. 16 Theory of Change Inputs New international prize platform established DFID funding Other funding (Foundations, donors, private sector) Understanding of poor people’s unmet needs Experienced prize-running organisation Outputs Activities Entrepreneurs, SMEs, large private sector, academia, researchers and civil society collaborate on developing solutions to prize problems End-users (BoP consumers) are involved in prize design and winner selection process to ensure technologies are grounded in reality Developing country innovators (entrepreneurs and researchers) develop partnerships with developed world stakeholders to develop solutions Others recognise opportunity and join UK in establishing the platform Problem statements are identified and articulated clearly and solutions are realisable 5 prizes launched and 3 successfully awarded 5 research papers on chosen prize problem statements grounded in end-user consultation 3 papers demonstrating the value and use of different Prize purse is innovation attractive prizes in enough to supporting incentivise innovation organisations Outcome International and local investors are willing to invest in the deployment of solutions in countries Winning projects are able to be replicated, scaled up and costs reduced Affordable and accessible technologies are developed and deployed; through scaling-up innovation prizes to support innovation and crowd in new investment Impact 12 million people with increased access to low carbon energy, water and sanitation Other key areas to tackle poverty are successfully addressed including: - policies and regulations - institutional requirements - corruption Successful ventures raise public and investor awareness of opportunities to take part = Assumptions A varied group of we expect to achieve B. Impact and Outcome that stakeholders developing and expected impact is that testing solutions poor people water andforsanitation) The 12 million people will have new access to services (energy and through affordable technologies and business models for the bottom of the pyramid consumers by 202538. The outcome is that affordable and accessible technologies are developed and deployed; through scaling-up innovation prizes to support innovation and crowd-in new investment. Outcomes to be achieved by 2016/17 are: 1. Leverage / crowding in of £35m of new investment in the developing and deploying technologies for the poor39 38 This has been calculated and documented in the Appraisal Case that follows. It assumes from 5 prizes: 2 will fail; 2 will be moderately successful; 1 will be transformational in its impacts. Numbers of people are calculated based on an indicative set of prizes and the addressable market associated with each prize. 17 2. At least 7 new, affordable and accessible climate technologies developed for poor people40 3. At least 5 affordable and accessible climate technologies deployed to poor people41 4. At least 50% of entrants applying for prizes are new teams/organisations to DFID funding The outputs for this programme are: 1. 5 new, innovation prizes launched and 3 successful awarded 2. At least 10 research papers on the ‘problem statement’ (e.g. microbiological testing of water). These will be published for each prize in two stages: (1) at the time of the launch providing evidence of problem and analysis of opportunities; and (2) postevaluation of the prize providing an evaluation of the response, including details on failures 3. At least 3 evaluation reports on the use and value of different types of innovation prizes tested for development and environment problems 39 This has been calculated as the average return on investment figures from of Shell Springboard (RoI 1.96) and OmniCompete Global Security Challenge (RoI 6.49) (as calculated in Everett (2011) – endnote 20). 40 Assuming 5 prizes: 1 transformational (5 new technologies developed); 2 mildly successful (2 new technologies developed); and 2 failures. 41 Assuming 5 prizes: 1 transformational (3 technologies deployed); 2 mildly successful (2 technologies deployed); and 2 failures. 18 Appraisal Case A. What are the feasible options that address the need set out in the Strategic case? The alternative options to be appraised are: 1. Counterfactual – do nothing additional 2. More funding through traditional grants targeting the identified issues 3. Establish a new innovation prize platform targeting the identified issues Option 1: Counterfactual – do nothing additional DFID would not provide any additional support to incentivise R&D and innovation for climate technologies and would continue with our current programmes only. Option 2: Increase funding for innovation through current portfolio of approaches DFID would increase funding for traditional R&D grants to support innovation for climate technologies and business models. This would require DFID to commission external researchers using standard procurement models to develop solutions to the problem statements identified. Option 3: Add innovation prizes to the mix of current approaches DFID funding would support the establishment of a new innovation prize platform as an alternative way of incentivising R&D and supporting successful solutions only that address a set of defined problem statements. This would complement existing initiatives funded through option 2 approach. B. Assessing the strength of the evidence base for each feasible option Option Evidence rating 1 Medium: evidence on counterfactual / ‘business as usual’ exists, although it is limited for the bottom of the pyramid market 2 Low – Medium: evidence tends to suffer from sample bias and a lack of reporting of failures 3 Low – Medium: evidence tends to suffer from sample bias and a lack of reporting of failures What is the likely impact (positive and negative) on climate change and environment for each feasible option? Option 1 2 3 Climate change and environment risks Climate change and environment and impacts, Category (A, B, C, D) opportunities, Category (A, B, C, D) C C B B B B On the basis of the evidence provided in this business case, it can be assumed that the three options proposed would not generate any unmanageable risks associated with the environmental impact of the intervention, or its effects on global climate. Option 1 (the counterfactual – do nothing option) would generate no risks to the environment or climate change as it would lead to no additional funding to support innovation in climate technologies and therefore no impacts. It would also result in no opportunities to support environmental management or mitigate/adapt to climate change. 19 Option 2 (increase funding for innovation through our current portfolio of commissioning models) could result in a medium risk to the environment or climate change if multiple delivery partners were chosen to conduct the research and analysis. Multiple organisations will likely increase the travel associated with the programme, as well as the necessary outputs (reports, online communication materials, etc.), therefore increasing the environmental footprint of the work. This option creates medium opportunities for the environment and climate change, given grant funding will support innovation in climate technologies. It can be assumed that some of these grants would result in successful solutions that support climate mitigation/adaptation and environmental management (some will also fail and not provide worthwhile results). In addition, there is a mild risk associated with unpredictability of specific climate and/or environment conditions in the future that could reduce the impact of the final research output and could, in turn, impact on the programme’s overall success. For example, the researchers may invest a significant amount of time and resources into developing a product which is suited to a pre-determined set of environmental and climate conditions that are consistent with current predictions that do not turn out to be accurate. Such a scenario would reduce the applicability and impact of the product in question as well as the success of DFID’s support. This is difficult to mitigate against, but is important to flag. Option 3 (a new innovation prize programme to support innovation for climate technologies) will have similar impacts to Option 2, but may result in a smaller carbon and environmental footprint through more limited travel associated with the programme. The programme should intend to use, where possible, in-country experts and delivery agents to limit the need for international flights. Recommendations to minimise operational impacts of the programme include: Reducing the need to travel by using teleconference / videoconference facilities and locally based staff where appropriate. If flights are required ensure individuals travel in economy class and offset flights with through a verifiable carbon offset project42. Business class travel will also have a negative impact on the value for money of the programme. Reduce the carbon footprint of the outputs through, for example, use of online communications, recycled paper, and minimising printing and printing waste. There is a risk that the research financed as a result of the programme (e.g. particular products and technologies built) could have direct or indirect impacts on the environment and/or future climate. For example, the development of a new way of storing household energy through environmentally unfriendly batteries may have negative impacts for other resources (e.g. water). This is a risk as we may not have any oversight of environmental and social safeguards employed by the organisations competing for each prize. To mitigate this risk a condition of participating could include a limit on negative environmental impacts. The prize-running organisation will need to define environmental and social safeguards all competitors must adhere to (using the World Bank and ICF standards as a minimum). In addition, this will need to be carefully appraised as part of the individual prize appraisal process (i.e. the choice of prize should attempt to limit this risk where possible) and impacts should be monitored on an ongoing basis. Similarly to option 2, there is a risk that the unpredictability of future environment and climate conditions could affect the impact of the product and therefore the programme. C. What are the costs and benefits of each feasible option? 42 On average, business class passengers are responsible for up to 2.1 times the emissions of an economy traveller. Kollmuss, A., Lane, J. (2008) Carbon Offsetting & Air Travel, Stockholm Environment Institute Discussion Paper, Part 1: CO2-Emissions Calculations, 28 May 2008. http://www.co2offsetresearch.org/PDF/SEI_Air_Travel_Emissions_Paper1_%20May_08.pdf 20 Option 1: Do nothing This option would involve no additional funding from DFID to support innovation in climate technologies for poor people. As such, there are no additional financial costs to DFID of this option. However, this misses an opportunity to support innovation and potentially support some highly transformational technologies. The Global Innovation Index 201243 can be used to understand the current level of innovation in developing countries. The GII is a composite indicator that ranks countries/economies in terms of their enabling environment to innovation and their innovation outputs, published annually by INSEAD. This year’s GII highlights that, on average, high-income countries outpace developing countries by a wide margin across the board in terms of scores. In addition, the report suggests that in developing countries there is often an excessive focus on basic research without diffusion to innovation actors in the private sector. Accurate data on innovation (including diffusion) and R&D in developing countries suffers from a number of challenges, including the fact that much innovation happens in the informal economy - a vital source of employment and income for the poor. As such, data on innovation (where data collection exists) is often an underestimate of the activity in the country. Data collated as part of the Global Innovation Index 2012 illustrates the severe lack in R&D in developing countries, notably subSaharan Africa (with 12 countries scoring an n/a due to lack of information). Without DFID’s intervention it is likely that private investment in technologies for low income consumers in developing countries will remain untapped and innovation will continue to be underutilised. Without new technologies and/or new service delivery models, low income consumers will continue to be unable to access clean energy, safe drinking water and sanitation, and we will be less likely to achieve the step change required to tackle poverty in the face of emerging threats. Option 2: Traditional R&D grants Under this option, DFID would increase financial support to innovation in climate technologies through our current portfolio of research commissioning methods – and provide a selection of R&D grants to various organisations to produce the innovation we are aiming to achieve. Pros of traditional grants A grant could be awarded to an organisation to develop (and potentially deploy) a technological solution to meet a specified need. This could be in the form of small scale grants for concept development and prototyping; grants for proof-of-concept including demonstrating and trialling; and funding for dissemination and scale-up. This is perhaps the traditional, and often perceived as the lowest risk approach (see costs below). The benefits are that this approach is well-understood and accountability lines are clear. The use of research grants can provide return on investment (RoI) if funders have a clear objective in mind and can identify the best way to achieve this objective. In this case, funders have suitable knowledge to evaluate proposals and to rationally choose the one with the best chance of achieving their goal. Cons of traditional grants Under a tradition grant arrangement, the funder would pay upfront for the R&D, whether or not the R&D produces anything of value in return. Allocating grant money effectively requires the grantmaking entity to pick “winners” and “losers” in advance, which they may not be best placed to do. 43 http://www.globalinnovationindex.org/gii/ 21 There is a perception that governments are bad at picking technology winners, with the media quick to report on failures44. DFID would need be confident in its ability to select the most appropriate organisation to develop and deliver the technology at the onset. This could also limit the number new and unproven organisations from non-conventional fields in participating in solution generation as the ‘usual suspects’ are likely to be more effective at providing winner grant applications. Grants can also lead to conservatism and be top-down in nature. Comparing the average cost of problem resolution for developing world technologies posted under the Rockefeller InnoCentive initiative (in which 10 challenges were posted via an open innovation network and 6 solved in 18 months), with the average cost of grant contracts under DFID Renewable Natural Resources Research Programme (with a typical grant being £70,000 per annum for three years), Everett (2011) found that the open innovation approach by InnoCentive could represent a 48% cost saving. This is a crude calculation, which doesn’t include how practical the solutions from InnoCentive were compared to RNRRS solutions. In addition, Lakhani (2006)45 who studied 166 discrete scientific problems posted to the open innovation platform InnoCentive, and found that: “the broadcasting of problem information to a diverse community of solvers can yield effective solution rates. We do not yet have an empirical basis for comparing this outcome with the effectiveness of traditional problem solving activities within academic or commercial laboratories for similar discrete problems. However many of the R&D laboratories posting these problems had been unsuccessful in creating solutions to these problems, thus implying a noteworthy outcome”. Options 3: Innovation prize platform Prizes are an effective, alternative tool for solving problems where the objective is clear, but the way to achieve it is not. Pros of prizes Innovation prizes, offer many advantages including: 1) New players – a prize can induce competitors from around the world to join the search for a solution. One metric of a prize’s impact is the number of contestants that it attracts. A study reviewed problems solved on InnoCentive’s website and found people from outside the scientific or industry discipline in question were more likely to solve a challenge46. Successful solvers solved problems at the boundary or outside of their fields of expertise, indicating a transfer of knowledge from one field to others. In addition, the new solvers/applicants then become part of the wider network; approximately 80% of companies applying to the Global Security Challenge (a prize for new technologies in security services from start-ups and SMEs) had not previously submitted funding applications to the prize promoter. After participating in the GSC, applicants subsequently go on to apply to the prize promoter for future funding opportunities. 2) New ideas – new players bring new thinking to an old problem. One of the main advantages of prizes is that by defining the problem not the solution, it is possible to access a much 44 The well-publicised Solyndra experience (a solar panel manufacturer who received a $535m US federal loan) highlighted that public money is often better spent on relatively inexpensive R&D across a vast number of exciting but still-too-expensive ideas, maintaining the R&D risk on the private sector, more effective at making decisions on where they envisage market demand. 45 Lakhani, K. R., Jeppesen, L. B., Lohse, P. A., Panetta, J. A. (2006) The Value of Openness in Scientific Problem Solving. Harvard Business School; Copenhagen Business School; InnoCentive. Available: http://www.hbs.edu/research/pdf/07-050.pdf 46 See endnote 41 – The Value of Openness in Scientific Problem Solving. 22 broader range of innovation. In addition, as mentioned, the risk taking and decision making is not with the funder, who often lacks the technical knowledge and abilities required to make the most effective judgements – particularly of importance when investing public funds. The Longitude Prize (1714) was offered by the British Government for a simple and practical method for the precise determination of a ship's longitude while at sea. Conventional wisdom at the time was that the answer lay in the stars; however the prize was awarded to John Harrison who solved the problem by an improved measurement of time. 3) Payment on results – by rewarding prizes after successful and demonstrated completion of the prize target, funders don’t waste money by providing all funding up-front before the goal has been achieved. This provides an opportunity for value for money compared to up-front R&D grants. For example, through competition for the best high definition television standards the US established an advanced standard at much lower public cost than the subsidised cooperative R&D programmes in Europe and Japan47. 4) Risk stays with the competitor – linked to above, the risk of delivering a successful result remains with those competing (e.g. private sector, researchers, etc.). The Cheap Access to Space (CATS) Prize challenged entrants to launch a 2kg load to altitudes of 120km and 200km48. Both prizes went unclaimed as the teams did not come as far as anticipated when the prize was established, but did make demonstrable progress. The greater-than-expected difficulty of the challenge did not leave the sponsor out of pocket since the teams bore the risk themselves. Given the private sector is better able to bear delivery risk this is attractive for both the public sector and advantageous for social allocation of risk. 5) Return on Investment – prizes can create significant leverage. Everett (2011) found that returns on investment (RoI) for innovation awards range from 2:1 to 33:1 benefit cost ratios; 50-80% cost reductions and RoI up to 182% from open innovation prizes; and benefit costs ratios around 8:1 to 16:1 for market stimulation (grand) prizes, e.g. the Ansari X-Prize, which is credited with leveraging $100m in R&D finance to achieve the $10m prize. Since the award of the prize, public and private expenditure in support of the private space flight industry has topped $1.5bn49. In addition, while only one company ‘won’ the prize, seven companies are in operation today due to the market stimulation impacts of the prize. The approaches used to estimate longer term benefits, beyond just leveraged investment, are highly dependent on the nature of the prize. The X-Prize Foundation have through various prizes demonstrated that competitors have been collectively willing to spend up to 10–16 times the cash value of a prize on relevant research to meet the objectives. 6) Speed of problem solving – the competitive spirit can bring out the best innovations. Many technological developments were discovered when individuals were competing with each other. The race to sequence the human genome between a group of international scientists (the Human Genome Project) and a company, Celera, resulted in the goals for both competitors being reached sooner50. 7) Headlines and attention – the media spotlight around a prize can bring an important problem to the attention of millions. Shell’s Springboard programme, considered highly successful, has awarded £1.98m in no-strings attached prizes and generated some significant media attention. In the first month after the 2011 awards, the prizes generated 92 pieces of coverage in one month, reaching an audience of 24 million for 10 winners. Coverage included 47 Eisenmann, T. R. (2005) High-Definition TV: The Grand Alliance, Harvard Business School Case 804-103, October 2005. (Revised from original December 2003 version.) 48 For information see: http://archive.spacefrontier.org/Projects/CatsPrize/ 49 See endnote 20 - Evidence Review – Environmental Innovation Prizes for Development. 50 Adams, J. (2008) Sequencing human genome: the contributions of Francis Collins and Craig Venter. Nature Education 1(1). 23 local, regional and national broad sheet press and trade publications as well as activity on twitter51. Cons of prizes Counter arguments against prizes include52: 1) Might not result in a solution – if designed inappropriately, a prize competition might not result in the desired outcome (i.e. no winners). Netflix’s $1m prize to build recommendation software for their online movie website did not result in a solution that was implemented as the additional gains did not justify the engineering effort53. 2) Fixed cost of running a prize – prizes have only been shown to be effective if they are both of the right financial size and designed well. Designing a prize well can be challenging and requires an initial level of finance to support research and consultation. This is a necessary fixed cost and there will be a limit to how much this can be reduced before impacting on the effectiveness of the prize itself. 3) Widespread adoption cannot be guaranteed by a prize – even if a prize has succeeded in stimulating a desired innovation, widespread adoption of this innovation may be hindered by other obstacles. Widespread deployment is often limited by different factors than those holding back innovation activity. 4) Prizes are not a silver bullet – they are not a universal solution and there are functions which other policies might perform better than a prize. For example, regulation may be more effective at encouraging wide roll-out and technology diffusion through imposing sector-wide standards. 5) Should not operate as stand-alone – they are an addition (rather than a substitute) to innovation policies, such as up-front R&D grants, the patent system, regulations and often work best when aligned with other support to help winners take their winning idea forward and into the marketplace. The Carbon Trust’s Accelerator programme is a good example which begins with a prize and ends with seed investment into the winning enterprise from the Carbon Trust, matched by private investors54. 6) High level of financial resources required to compete – researchers may need to obtain significant funding for their research in order to compete and prizes may lead to duplication of effort, more so than with government grants. One example is the large, market stimulation Ansari X-Prize, with a high level of financial resources required to compete. Only twenty-six teams competed and on average, they each invested over $3 million into their attempts. The high cost of involved in being a credible competitor may limit the playing field and directly reduced the number of teams participating in the competition. 7) Limited developing country participation – given the high profile and funding that may be required to participate, developing country representatives might find it difficult to develop their ideas and inventions, particularly when up against large, wealthy multinational players. 8) Budgeting and forecasting can be tricky – given the uncertainty of the winner (including whether there will even be a winner!) it can be difficult to forecast accurately what the spend profile will be. The indicative comparison in Table 3 below looks at the traditional welfare gains (e.g. a net gain for consumers or producers) as well as whether the benefit is likely to achieve a gain for the poor in a See endnote 20 - Evidence Review – Environmental Innovation Prizes for Development. Some of these could be applicable to traditional grants – depending on the way the grant is designed, notably: 1, 3, 4 and 5. 53 Holiday, R. (2012) What the Failed $1m Netflix Prize says about Business Advice. Forbes online article: http://www.forbes.com/fdc/welcome_mjx.shtml 54 For more information see: http://www.carbontrust.com/our-clients/o/offshore-wind-accelerator 51 52 24 developing country context. The options are ranked 1 to 5. A higher ranking implies better outcome. This is a qualitative ranking but informed by previous research. The benefits and costs of the options are not weighted as this will need to be informed by the individual well-developed the prize criteria. Table 3: welfare benefits of prizes v grants Welfare Benefits of Prizes Enhancing Benefits Competition Information Incentives Risk Positive Spillovers Managing Negative Externalities Addressing public good needs TOTAL Prizes will spur competition, often bringing in competitors from outside the sector, supporting the diffusion of innovation Prizes encourage publicity information sharing Prizes encourage adaptation of existing technologies – flexibility Prizes can be designed to manage the risk of failure through a ‘staged’ process – failed projects do not pass through to next stage and therefore further funding Prizes allow you to learn from failures (cost savings for others). Not all prizes produce winners -but nevertheless have benefits as the expose the possibilities with a range of technologies and build up knowledge. They can also help to address coordination failures and prize contestants seek partners to deliver a prize and spur new alliances Prizes can manage common pool problem (overfishing) by adding enhanced management to minimise duplication and encourage cooperation. They can also be used to exploit opportunities in the area of nonpatented able technologies. Where there was no prize no innovation would take place Benefits of Grants Rank 4 4 This is less likely – grants applicants tend to be known to the grantor Rank 1 Depends on the ToR but could well engage widely but is not their comparative strength Responds to the ToR 3 4 Depends on the ToR – but rarely a condition for grants 1 3 Limited – based on universities apply their research outputs in developing countries 2 2 Well managed 4 4 Can specifically address this need 4 3 24 2 17 In summary, prizes have are better positioned to offer a wider range of benefits. Costs of prizes As with other prize competitions (e.g. run by organisations such as the Technology Strategy Board, X-Prize Foundation, InnoCentive) costs are anticipated to be similar to the breakdown below. We anticipate a number of key cost drivers can be used to drive down the direct costs of the programme. These include: location of the prize running organisation; input of lessons learning from other prizes; ability to utilise pro bono expertise for technical advice and prize judging. These cost drivers will be requested during the tender process for the prize-running organisation and will be one factor bids will be judged against. In addition, we anticipate other funders (donors, Foundations, etc.) to support the 25 programme where it aligns with their own objectives. As such, it is anticipated that direct programme costs will be shared amongst 1-2 other donors depending on the prize. Table 1: cost of prize programme Types of costs Admin Spend: Percentage 5% Indirect costs (e.g. overheads to support maintenance of organisation: electricity, rent, office services, etc.) Direct costs (e.g. salaries for those involved in managing the prize process – secretariat costs of transferring funds, booking travel, etc.) Programme Spend: 95% Direct costs – costs against actual activities. - Prize idea generation (research and consultation) - Ongoing consultation with beneficiaries, private sector, researchers - Prize design based on research (including stakeholder identification, launch, operation and awarding of prize) - Launch and run individual prizes (including expert panel to review and reward) Monitoring and Evaluation (M&E) Prize funds available for winning participants 35% 7% 53% It is difficult to be precise about the required programme design funds and reward funds for each prize at this stage, as this will be determined during the prize design process and will depend on various factors e.g. how large a prize purse is required to incentivise investment; the number of potential participants; appropriate prize model (e.g. multiple stages, one large). As such, individual cost-benefit analyses will be included in the design phase for each prize. This will quantify anticipated costs and benefits and make an assessment of the value for money for each individual prize. It will also inform the results logframe for individual prizes and ensure strong targets to monitor and evaluate against. As an indication, below we have estimated feasible costs for the five potential prizes identified in the Strategic Case. The prize pot for each individual prize is anticipated to be in the range of £2-5m, which would be dispersed between up to 5 winners and at various stages as they achieve predefined results. Table 2: estimated costs for potential prize ideas Prize Costs Small-scale waste-to-energy solutions for urban slums Staged prize: 1. Build a working prototype (up to 5 winners) 2. First three successful tests of technology in three sites with different needs and inputs over a specified period of time (up to 3 winners) Total: £5m Admin costs: £250,000 Research of market and design of prize: £1.75m M&E: £350,000 Prize funds provided to prize winners: (£3.25m) Round 1: £352,000 ea (total £1.625m) Round 2: £541,660 ea (total £1.625m) Scale of Challenge & potential outputs 1bn people live in slums (projected to grow to 2bn by 2030) Increased number people with access to affordable energy services Decrease in waste accumulation in slums Local job creation – particularly in slums (both direct – suppliers and distributors and indirect – energy power allows new businesses) 26 Low carbon cooling Total: £4m technologies (for air-con and Admin costs: £250,000 fridges) Research of market and Staged prize: design of prize: £1.75m 1. Build a working prototype M&E: £350,000 that meets specific criteria Prize funds provided to using locally sourced prize winners: (£3.25m) materials (up to 4 Round 1: £406,250 ea winners) (total £1.625m) Round 2: £812,500 ea 2. First two successful (total £1.625m) delivery models used to deploy technology (up to 2 winners) Quick, cheap, reliable Total: £2m microbiological testing of Admin costs: £100,000 water Research of market and Awarded to the two quickest, design of prize: cheapest, and most reliable £700,000 means of microbiological testing M&E: £140,000 of water (with various conditions: Prize funds provided to price, reliability, speed, etc.) prize winners: £650,000 ea (total £1.3m) Development of locallyrelevant technologies for the poor World sales in 2011 up 13% 3bn more middle class consumers by 2030 Reduction in/avoidance of carbon emissions from refrigerants Development of locallyrelevant technologies for the poor Local job creation (both direct and indirect) 780m people do not have access to safe drinking water Development of locallyrelevant technologies for the poor Local job creation (both direct and indirect) Safer drinking water for poor people Technologies and business Total: £4m models for pay-as-you-go Admin costs: £200,000 ‘basics’ household modern Research of market and energy services55 design of prize: £1.4m Prize for a cheap machine-to M&E: £280,000 machine data chip to allow pay Prize funds provided to as-you-go business models, prize winners: (£2.6m) followed by prizes for top two Round 1: £1m successful ‘pay-as-you go’ Round 2: £800,000 ea businesses that provide 200 (total £1.6m) households with modern energy services in 3 months (95% success rate for households meeting payments) 1.3bn people without access to modern energy services Increased number of people with access to affordable energy services Local job creation (both direct and indirect) Deployment of locallyrelevant technologies for the poor Household energy storage that doesn't involve batteries Staged prize: 1. Build a working prototype (up to 2 winners) 1.3bn people do not have access to the grid and use batteries for energy storage Development of locallyrelevant technologies for the poor Total: £5m Admin costs: £250,000 Research of market and design of prize: £1.75m M&E: £350,000 Prize funds provided to This is included as an indication of a ‘business model’ prize. This particularly problem is likely to be addressed by the private sector without the need of an innovation prize as an incentive (pay-as-yougo systems are currently being developed and deployed by M-Kopa, Eight19, etc.). 55 27 2. First successful tests of technology (1 winner) prize winners: (£3.25m) Round 1: £812,500 ea (total £1.625m) Round 2: £1.625m Local job creation (both direct and indirect) Indirect increase in access through new methods of storing energy at a household level Decreased environmental impact from batteries It is anticipated that as the prizes are won and the concept is proven successful at incentivising innovation for development problems, more funders will join the programme, reducing the need for DFID funding. DFID may then wish to exit the programme, making room for other donors and funders. Table 4 below illustrates these costs as compared with grant costs. In terms of costs, prizes are likely to fare worse. Table 4: costs of prizes v grants Costs Prizes High – a successful prize needs a strong management process to increase the probability of success. These associated costs can be as high as 50%, including administration costs, preprize research and evidence gathering, and management of the prize process (consultation, launch, awarding, etc.). Grants Low – administration and management of the grant process is often lower as it does not include the requirement for robust initial research and evidence gathering on the problem. Estimate from other large RED grant programmes can be up to 15 to 20%. D. What measures can be used to assess Value for Money for the intervention? The value for money for the programme can be measured with reference to the following critical success criteria: - Numbers of poor beneficiaries of resulting products / services - Private sector invests in resulting products / services to ensure access by the poor (measured by Return on Investment or RoI) - Numbers of new players / solvers whom crowd-in to solve old problems – including numbers of developing country participants - The challenges / problem statements are accurately identified and the prize designed appropriately to ensure the best solution for beneficiaries - Lessons are learnt by DFID and others on the prize model for development Social rates of return of successful innovations have not been measured for this appraisal, given the uncertainty around choice of prize problem statements; however, this will be conducted as part of the individual prize appraisal prior to each prize launch. These are important to attempt to measure as they may be significant. Lichtenberg (1992) illustrated that the social rate of return from privately funded R&D in equipment can be up to seven times as high as the private returns56. Research commissioned for DFID on the value for money and effectiveness of prizes over other instruments (Everett 2011) concluded that value for money from prize programmes is evident across prize types, but the extent of value obtained is often dependent on externalities and other initiatives. 56 Lichtenberg, F. R. (1992) R&D Investment and International Productivity Differences. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 4161 in Economic Growth in the World Economy, Symposium 1992, edited by Horst Siebert, pp. 89-110. 28 The research provided the following examples of value for money for prizes. RoI Innovation awards range from 2:1 to 33:1 benefit cost ratios Open innovation prizes, RoI up to 182%, with payback in 2 months and 50-80% cost reductions Market stimulation prizes range from 8:1 to 16:1 benefit costs ratios New solvers As described earlier, approximately 80% of companies applying to the Global Security Challenge were new solvers. Similarly, of teams that competed in the Progressive Automotive X-Prize 35% of the teams did not exist before the prize, and of those teams that did exist, 30% were informal and 17% were non‐vehicle‐related. People with resulting product The evidence base is weak on numbers of people with resulting prize products, likely due to the fact that prizes have focused more on technology development, rather than deployment. However, notably, the technology awarded through the Longitude Prize is still in use today. Additionally, a Rockefeller and InnoCentive prize programme was able to deploy 300,000 solar torches (can be roughly equated to 1 per person) by using a ‘buy one, give one to a developing country free’ in the US57. While support for innovation and R&D is risky and unpredictable, the opportunities are often worth the risk, particularly if the potential impact is significant. Prizes encourage a maximum amount of innovation by not pre-defining the technological solution; therefore there are greater opportunities for success and for a significant, transformational impact. However, there will be failures and some prizes will not result in a transformational impact. Based on a conservative assumption, of the 5 prizes: 2 will fail or will not result in any significant addition to the marketplace and therefore opportunities for poor consumers; 2 will result in some innovation, but will not ‘take-off’; and 1 will result in a transformational change with significant impacts for poor consumers. Value for money and expected impact assessments will be carried out once the focus of the prizes has been determined, but an estimate can be given at this stage, based on the possible prize ideas listed in Table 2 and assuming indicative successes and failures as follows: - 1 transformational impact: waste-to-energy in slums - 2 mildly successful: water testing and batteries - 2 failures: energy business model and air-conditioning prizes Using the addressable market indicated in Table 2 and the assumptions of prize successes/failures, the estimated impact of this programme is calculated as 12 million people, broken down as follows: Waste-to-energy: transformational impact estimated at reaching 1% of the problem (1 billion people currently living in urban slums) o 10 million people Water testing: mildly successful impact estimated at reaching 0.1% of the problem (780 million people without access to safe drinking water) o 0.8 million people Batteries: mildly successful impact estimated at reaching 0.1% of the problem (1.3bn people without access to the grid and use batteries for storage) o 1.3 million people 57 See endnote 20 - Evidence Review – Environmental Innovation Prizes for Development. 29 E. Summary Value for Money Statement for the preferred option The total estimated impact is 12 million people as a result of DFID’s £15 million investment, equivalent to a cost of £1.25 per person enabled to access energy/water services. Based on the limited evidence available, while the optimal level of investment in prizes is not clear, it is likely to be much larger than at present, and the potential payoffs of adding prizes as a new mechanism to the toolkit for encouraging innovation are immense58. While there is anecdotal evidence on the effectiveness and return on investment from traditional methods, this is by no means conclusive59. The return on investment for various types of prize competitions has the potential to be impressive. It is therefore deemed good value for money to complement our portfolio of tools to stimulate innovation through a new innovation prize programme, while maintaining high returns of investment, reaching large numbers of poor beneficiaries and bringing in new socially orientated innovators. See endnote 20 - Evidence Review – Environmental Innovation Prizes for Development. The Prize Summit: Summary of key debates (2011), InnoCentive and London Business School. Available at: http://theprizesummit.com/previous_summits.php 58 59 30 Commercial Case Direct procurement A. Clearly state the procurement/commercial requirements for intervention Direct procurement A restricted procurement process will be adopted to select the effective organisation (or consortium) to manage and run the prize platform (prospective bidders are listed in section C below). DFID will advertise the contract requirement on the DFID website and in the OJEU and all interested suppliers will be invited to notify DFID of their interest in tendering for the services through a short expression of interest. DFID will then be able to select, from amongst the interested suppliers, those who are to be invited to respond to the more detailed Invitation to Tender (ITT). This is the procedure that DFID adopts in most cases as it provides: Clear transparency around choice of partner, chosen by fair and open competition Competition can drive down costs, particularly administration costs of the programme DFID can design the programme to accurately meet our priorities as opposed to negotiating with an already established programme In addition, this limits the administrative burden on DFID staff (both programme and procurement staff) through a more restricted process (e.g. staff may only need to review and score a limited number of responses to the ITT as opposed to all responses). Shortlisted suppliers will compete on the basis of delivering maximum impact for our stated budget. DFID funding will cover both administration costs for running the programme and programme costs for managing and deploying prize funds. Some funding will be required up front to the successful bidder to allow them to establish the platform and launch and run the first prize. Award money to the successful prize winner/s will be provided when the specific, identified objectives have been met (i.e. on delivery of results). If there is no clear winner, funding will not be disburses and therefore not wasted on unsuccessful outputs. Indirect procurement Prize money will be awarded to the successful prize winner/s only when the specific, identified objectives (defined clearly at the beginning of the prize launch) have been met. As such, this programme is an example of results-based financing - a new form of aid financing that makes payments contingent on the independent verification of results, a major theme of the UK Government’s reform agenda. The three key elements of this programme is therefore: payments based on results recipient discretion (the recipient has space to decide how results are achieved) verification of results as the trigger for disbursement DFID funds for the prize winners (i.e. the majority of funding for this programme - £7.95m) will only be transferred from DFID to prize-running organisation to disburse to the winners, when it is verified that there is a clear winner and the required results have been achieved. If there is no winner, funding will not be dispersed and therefore not wasted on unsuccessful outputs. Award payment will be made to the winner participant/s from the prize-running organisation as an unconditional grant. The length of running time for the prize will depend on the type of prize chosen (e.g. staged, proportional, etc.). Suitable ‘end dates’ will be determined during the prize design phase. It is anticipated that most prizes will be ‘open’ for 12 months. If there is no successful winner at the end of the open period, the prize winning funds will not be spent and will remain with DFID (as DFID will only transfer funds when a successful competitor is identified). B. How does the intervention design use competition to drive commercial advantage for DFID? 31 This programme is fundamentally about the use of competition to deliver results. The innovation prize model is essentially about driving R&D and innovation through a focused and competitive approach. Prizes attract a wide range of participants, from traditional researchers to maverick thinkers, and from large companies to entrepreneurs (compared to a typical government grant which finances only one competitor in one location using one approach). As illustrated early, a review of problems solved on InnoCentive’s website found that people from outside the scientific or industry discipline in question were more likely to solve a challenge60. The new solvers then become part of the wider network, so to keep aware of future opportunities. Through a competitive procurement process (the restricted process described above) to select the successful prize-running organisation, DFID will challenge potential organisations to deliver our intended results in the most effective, economic and efficient way. C. How do we expect the market place will respond to this opportunity? There is a growing body of evidence that illustrates the value in the use of prizes for spurring innovation and private sector activity (referenced throughout this business case). Previous work commissioned by DFID (Everett, 2011) identified a number of competition/prize-running organisations. The list below also contains additional organisations based on our own research and analysis. We anticipate a high standard of responses to run the prize platform from a variety of organisations including those listed below. As no one existing organisation is deemed to have all the skills required to deliver this programme effectively alone. As such, we anticipate and welcome consortium bids. Organisations / programmes Global Village Energy Partnership (GVEP) Carbon Trust UK Grand Challenges Canada Technology Strategy Board (TSB) 60 Applicability An international NGO that supports sustainable energy solutions (notably access) in developing countries, working with entrepreneurs, financiers, donors, distribution networks, etc. Designed and facilitated the IDEAS innovation contest in Latin America and the Caribbean focusing on innovative proposals to promote renewable energy, energy efficiency and energy access in the region. A former UK public body (now limited company) providing advice to companies and government on energy and carbon savings. Designed and facilitated technology challenges and competitions based on specific problem statements. A not-for-profit organisation focused on improving the health of people in developing countries through innovation. Has launched a number of health-related global challenges including: Saving Lives at Birth (DFID partnering); Point-of-Care Diagnostics; and Saving Brains. The UK’s national innovation agency with experience in running competitions for business-led innovation and technological solutions (including low carbon vehicles). DFID RED is exploring a partnership with the TSB on a number of potential ‘problems’. We are excluding climate See endnote 41 – The Value of Openness in Scientific Problem Solving. 32 Ashden Awards for Sustainable Energy Nesta X-Prize Foundation (XPF) USAID Development Innovation Ventures (DIV) Saltire Prize InnoCentive and environment problems from this discussion at this stage, as it is uncertain how this will be taken forward and in what timeframe. A recognition award for UK and developing country sustainable energy solutions. The categories are broad and do not rely on achieving a specified outcome. There is little evidence that this drives and spurs innovation as it rewards concepts after they have been implemented. Alternatively, we would like to incentivise innovation and R&D through the opportunity of a cash prize/reward for achieving a specified outcome. A UK non-profit focused on supporting innovation by mobilising investments and grants, and building networks. Have recently launched the Centre for Challenge Prizes and plan to launch two prizes in the summer on carbon data collection and cycling. No developing country experience. An international non-profit working with private sector organisations to develop incentive prizes to address global challenges. Their history is in high-profile, large-scale concepts – including the Ansari X-Prize to develop a commercial space-flight carrier (which launched Virgin Galactic). Work completed for DFID by XPF does not instil confidence that they could design suitable prizes for household/community developing country problems. In addition, a change in leadership has resulted in XPF limiting their relationship with public sector organisations. A grant-based ‘challenge fund’ for innovative ideas across the spectrum of development issues. Funds available for anything from ‘proof of concept’ through to scale-up (new geographies etc.). Awarded to concepts, not for achievement of results. Potential for DFID to join this programme as a pilot/testing of this approach, however, it is not an incentive or inducement prize model that awards R&D achievements. The Scottish Government’s £10 million market stimulation challenge to accelerate the commercial development of marine energy. It will be awarded to the team that can demonstrate in Scottish waters, a commercially viable wave or tidal stream energy technology that achieves the greatest volume of electrical output over the set minimum hurdle of 100GWh over a continuous 2 year period using only the power of the sea. An open innovation platform based in the US but recently acquiring OmniCompete (UK-based prize-running organisation). InnoCentive have run prizes in the areas of security, energy and healthcare (including energy storage and off-grid lighting). Currently working with Rockefeller and GlobalGiving on a water platform for developing countries which matches funders with solutions (matched by Rockefeller). Solutions along the value chain (i.e. design new technologies, through to deployment). 33 NineSigma Shell Springboard An open innovation platform that establishes partnerships amongst industry organisations seeking a solution from external sources (academic, research institutions, private laboratories, etc.). Often results in ongoing collaboration or partnerships with the solver/s. A corporate social responsibility / social investment initiative fully funded and managed by Shell. A prize programme that provides a financial boost to innovative, low carbon business ideas from across the UK by providing 8 awards of £40,000. We also anticipate strong responses to the individual prize competitions, with results dependant on their target stakeholders (i.e. specific to location; sector (WASH, household energy); technology development versus deployment; etc.). Through strong awareness raising the prizes will likely receive interest from a vast array of stakeholders, inside and outside the area of expertise. As evidence suggests, prizes can bring an important problem to the attention of millions, including people from outside the scientific or industry discipline in question. These newcomers are often more likely to solve a long running challenge given their ‘outsider’ perspective, illustrated in Lakhani (2006) who found that: The broadcasting of problem information to outside scientists to a diverse community of solvers can yield effective solution rates (29.5 resolution rate) for problems that previously remained unsolved inside R&D laboratories of well-known science-driven firms. D. What are the key cost elements that affect overall price? How is value added and how will we measure and improve this? Administration costs (overheads, salaries for managing process) and programme costs (costs of research, design, launch, reward and outreach for individual prizes) are the key costs drivers for this programme. In the Invitation to Tender (ITT) DFID will provide an upper limit for these costs and request organisations provide a thorough breakdown of their intended management and administration costs. Value is added through the competitive bidding process where organisations (private, civil society) will be challenged to minimise costs in order to be competitive with others. The ITT will request bidders to be transparent on costs and explore opportunities to reduce direct programme costs through, for example: seeking pro-bono support; location of main activities; build on lessons from former and existing prize competitions; and linking to existing networks; civil society, researchers, and DFID country offices with an understanding of the problem area (prize topic) to take advantage of work already undertaken and reduce the need for additional research. These costs will be monitored throughout programme implementation and efforts will be made to reduce these costs wherever possible. It is anticipated that scope for reducing these costs significantly will be limited. The prize funds available for the winning prize competitors are the other substantial cost drivers for this programme. Funds available for each prize winner will be determined by the appraisal undertaken before each prize is launched. As such, it will be set at what is considered the optimal level to incentivise action without providing an opportunity for excessive profits, and will be evaluated as part of the post-prize evaluation process. In addition, winners will be independently verified to ensure they met the success criteria before receiving prize funds. E. What is the intended Procurement Process to support contract award? A restricted procurement process will be adopted. A Contract Notice will be advertised on the DFID website and in the Official Journal of the European Union (OJEU) in alerting potential suppliers to DFID’s requirement. The full Invitation to Tender (ITT) package including final Terms of Reference (TOR), evaluation criteria (technical and commercial), and any supplementary documents will be 34 available electronically from the date of publication of the Contract Notice. This will allow a reduced timescale for receipt of tenders from 40 days to 35 days. The Contract Notice will be placed on the DFID website and in the OJEU requests information, in the form of an Expression of Interest (EOI), to allow DFID to shortlist suppliers who will be invited to tender for the overall contract (to design and implement the prize platform). Shortlisted suppliers will compete on the basis of delivering maximum impact for our stated budget. The criteria against which the shortlisted suppliers will be evaluated against currently includes: Experience in running open innovation prizes/competitions/challenges. Experience in developing a ‘problem statement’ to be addressed. Presence and experience in developing country, particularly with entrepreneurs, small enterprises, academics and research institutions, and civil society. Demonstrated understanding of the technology innovation process, including social and business model innovation. Experience in environment, energy, climate change and water issues and their relationship to development goals. Ability to leverage additional funds. Wide network including academics, research institutions, multinationals, entrepreneurs, civil society in both developed and developing countries. Strong skills in marketing and awareness raising amongst a diversity of networks will be required. Links and networks with private investors an advantage (e.g. venture capital, angels, etc.). Experience in dealing with donor/government/philanthropic funding. In addition, given DFID’s interest and priorities, the requirements of this prize platform (of which the successful organisation will need to prove they can deliver on) are: Consultation will be essential to develop a strong ‘problem statement’ to be addressed by the prize. This must include consultation with the demand side / end users of the product/service to assist successful uptake of the product/service once awarded. Prizes to be developed for problem statements across the length of the innovation process (e.g. new technology developed through to new business model to reach BoP consumers). Most notably, some prizes will be designed to tackle the deployment/commercialisation valley of death. Some prizes may use a stage-gate approach: e.g. initial competition/prize – prize money available to 15 successful competitors; successful companies open to compete for prize two: prize money available to top 5 successful competitors; until 1 competitor successful at large prize purse (focused on outcomes desired i.e. x people with access to clean energy through x technological solution). Some prizes will be best applied locally, nationally, regionally or internationally. The successful bidder must have the ability to do all of these (in time) as the need arises. To encourage collaboration and lesson learning, there may be a need to stipulate a condition that ensures a sufficient amount of input from developing country stakeholders (i.e. 70% of the work must be led/conducted by a developing country partner). There must be a strong evaluation and lesson learning process. All failures should be regarded as ‘public goods’, providing open access knowledge on why these have failed ensuring the international community can learn from these efforts. To take advantage of the reduced timescale, the full ITT package including final TOR, evaluation criteria (technical and commercial), and any supplementary documents must be available electronically from the date of publication of the Contract Notice. F. How will contract & supplier performance be managed through the life of the intervention? 35 The organisation who wins the tender for the programme will report directly to DFID. Expected results, with measurable indicators, are set out in the logical framework, which will form the basis for monitoring the performance of the programme. Reviews (according with DFID’s reporting requirements) will be conducted annually. An independent mid-term review will also be conducted. The evaluation will collate the value for money metrics (described in the Appraisal Case section D above) across the launched prizes. DFID may then take relevant decisions (e.g. providing more/less funding to individual prizes based on results) on the basis of evidence. 36 Financial Case A. What are the costs, how are they profiled and how will you ensure accurate forecasting? The total is £15m for five prizes of various sizes. £7.5m will fall within the CSR period where 1-2 prizes are likely to be awarded. Spend profile will need to be negotiated alongside the winner tender, but is anticipated to be similar to the table below: Description 2012/13 Total 100,000 Admin costs total Programme costs: Direct – research, design, develop, manage prize Programme costs: Direct – M&E 5,000 85,000 10,000 Programme costs: Funds to winner(s) 2013/14 2014/15 2015/16 2016/17 Total 3,600,000 3,700,000 3,600,000 4,000,000 15,000,000 180,000 185,000 180,000 200,000 1,550,000 1,345,000 1,255,000 1,075,000 160,000 170,000 165,000 500,000 1,710,000 2,000,000 2,000,000 2,225,000 750,000 5,310,000 1,005,000 7,935,000 Up to £50,000 may be used following approval of this business case to help further refine some of the high priority problem/challenge definitions identified in this business case. This will enable the competitively tendered programme, once established, to launch its initial prize(s) without a significant time delay. Accurate forecasting will be an essential part of the contract. Payment requests will be quarterly, with the prize-running organisation providing DFID with a description of activities to be carried out in the forthcoming quarter. A quarterly meeting with the DFID programme management team (including finance management) will be required to be scheduled one month prior to the invoice due date to ensure forecasted spend is accurate and on target. B. How will it be funded: capital/programme/admin? Funding will be DFID programme funds from the Climate and Environment team in the Research and Evidence Division. It will be a part of the UK’s International Climate Fund (ICF). Prize money will be given for results which take physical form in terms of access to low carbon energy, water and adaptation products or services. Although the final portfolio of products and services cannot be known in advance, these could include equipment/appliances such as lanterns and cookstoves, as well as, potentially infrastructure installations such as biogas digesters. The funding is likely to be all RDEL, however, prize funds for winning participants could potentially be classified as CDEL given the reasons above. Full review of the CDEL/RDEL split will likely be possible once the initial prizes are designed. Funding for this programme is considered ODA. £7.5m will be disbursed during the current spending round. Since the final recipients may be private firms, it will be a requirement for the successful prizerunning organisation to maintain the conditions for ODA in the terms of the prize incentives offered, and the eligibility of participating prize competitors. C. How will funds be paid out? Implementation finance will be needed by the prize-running organisation to design and establish the platform and undertake the prize development and design process. These will be required to launch the 37 initial prizes in 2012/13-2013/14. Funds will then be dispersed to the prize winners via the prize-running organisation (to streamline finance from potentially multiple donors to the prize winners). The proposed mechanism for facilitating the funds will be a contract with the successful tender. In the event of a consortium bid, the consortium will be required to be established as an individual entity to receive DFID funds. Implementation payment to the prize-running organisation will be paid out in quarterly tranches, based on the achievement of agreed quarterly milestones. D. What is the assessment of financial risk and fraud? Financial risk and fraud can be identified at two levels: Risk of fraud by the prize-running organisation/consortium Risk of fraud by the prize winning organisations Fraud will be mitigated against by ensuring robust and transparent monitoring and reporting procedures and by ensuring a clear, robust, transparent and independent method for approving prize winners. The successful prize-running organisation will be required to have an anti-corruption policy. Where subcontractors are required, the prize-running organisation will be required to undertake due diligence on suppliers to mitigate against financial risk and fraud. E. How will expenditure be monitored, reported, and accounted for? Details of expenditure will be required on a quarterly basis measured against agreed milestones and forecasts. Quarterly disbursements will be linked to activity / progress reports and annual financial statements. This reduces the risk of potential abuse of the funds and is a check that ensures DFID funds are not being used for purposes other than what they were originally intended. Financial reports will be required to be sent to DFID within three months of the end of the organisation’s financial year and report receipt of DFID funds and associated disbursements, together with unspent funds. In addition, the prize winners will be independently verified to ensure they met the success criteria before receiving prize funds. 38 Management Case A. What are the Management Arrangements for implementing the intervention? The management arrangements will be agreed with the successful bidder. However, there are a few key elements that are essential described below. Governing Board A high-level governance and accountability board will keep an overview of strategic focus and progress towards funder’s requirements (milestones, M&E, reporting). Representatives will include funders (DFID; other donors; Foundations; etc.) The Board will have ultimate responsibility over ensuring the administration and financial requirements of funders are being met accurately and to time. Operational Team The day-to-day management of the programme will be overseen by the Operational Manager. The team will be split into the following sub-teams: o Finance, procurement and reporting o Research, stakeholder engagement and technical assistance o Communications and outreach o Monitoring and Evaluation Advisory/Technical Committee This committee would advise on the thematic elements of each prize, as such, it would include experts in the chosen ‘problem statement’ – such as WASH experts; off-grid energy experts; etc. Beneficiaries (end-users of the technology: poor consumers) would also be represented at this level by an appropriate representative (civil society, community groups, etc.). The individuals making up the technical committee will therefore be different for each individual prize. The committee should will provide a quality assurance role at the problem definition stage and may also act as the judging panel for each prize. Independent Assessor/s An independent and suitably qualified assessor/auditor will assess, verify and rank the results of those competing for the prizes. DFID programme management The programme will be managed by DFID’s Climate and Environment research team (Innovation Adviser) with inputs on energy, water and adaptation from colleagues in both Research and Evidence Division and Policy Division. Financial management will be provided by the Climate and Environment Team in RED. The prize-running organisation will be required to report on progress once a year at an annual meeting with other donors and stakeholders (as and when they join the programme). DFID’s Annual Review will also be completed at this time. B. What are the risks and how these will be managed? Below is a list of identified risks and associated mitigating action. Risk 1. High financial resources required to compete Mitigating action Costs to entry can be limited, simplifying entry and winning conditions (e.g. location of award ceremony etc.). Prizes for second and third place may be used to spread rewards more evenly and to lower the Risk rating M Impact L 39 2. Might not result in a solution 3. Limited developing country participation 4. Does not result in adoption of solution risks of entry for small entrants. Also, a staged contest with increasing rewards between stages can help to overcome financial constraints faced by small but promising innovators. The research and consultation required as part of the prize design process will hopefully ensure problem statements with a fair likelihood of success will be taken forward. However, the nature of innovation is to test different options with some failures and some success therefore, to fully mitigate this risk is against the purpose of this programme. Conditions of prize may include a required amount of developing country participation for competitors (encouraging collaboration). One option would be to ensure a prize concept will only be taken forward and developed if the managing organisation has secured interest to purchase (e.g. an AMC) or invest (e.g. by a venture capitalist) in the successful winners to ensure sustainability of outputs. A prize that supports business models (and therefore deployment of the technologies) can also help mitigate this risk. M H M L M M In accordance with DFID’s Design & Implementation Guidance, the design and implementation of the programme will be taken forward under a single tender to ensure value added and to reduce costs of multiple contracts. Other advantages include: Reduces the risk of complaint where a separate Design consultant takes part in the subsequent competition for Implementation (creating the perception of unfair advantage). Reduces the timescales resulting from two separate competitions / contracts. Reduces the risk of the Implementation supplier disagreeing with the Design Consultant and reduced commitment to delivery. Reducing the risk of disputes around the assessment of results that warrant awarding a prize – by including an independent and qualified assessor who assess and ranks the results and certifies that the results meet the set criteria. This will require a break clause at the end of the Design Phase, to ensure DFID are content that Design work is satisfactory and the proposal for Implementation represents VfM. The Design phase will provide further confirmation on: Final logframe with milestones and targets Programme’s cost profiles M&E process and reporting dates Management structure of the programme Risk register to be monitored throughout the life of the programme Steps for cost-benefit analysis to be completed for each prize 40 C. What conditions apply (for financial aid only)? Not applicable. D. How will progress and results be monitored, measured and evaluated? Results and progress will be monitored annually by the M&E team in the prize-running organisation and provided to DFID’s programme manager (in the Climate and Environment research Team) as part of the annual review process. An independent mid-term evaluation will be conducted in 2014/15 and an independent final evaluation in 2016/17. The evaluations will identify lessons learned and feed into any follow-on programme design. If in the mid-term review it is revealed that the programme is not meeting targets, the programme will not receive any further funding. The costs of these reviews have been included in the programme. As described in the Appraisal Case, each individual prize will require a cost-benefit analysis and its own M&E process to measure and monitor its impact and sustainability – to be completed during the design phase. Crucial to the success of the prize will be how the resulting technology or business model is deployed to ensure the long-term sustainability and use of the product. This will be part of the research and design phase and will include the establishment of baselines and targets and will require an understanding of the cultural and behavioural elements of the chosen prize concept. We will encourage the prize organisation to develop mini-logframes to measure outputs and success and include an indicator on long-term sustainability of prize winning ideas. Logframes will also need to measure the relevant International Climate Fund (ICF) Key Performance Indicators (KPIs) below and the measures of Value for Money (as described in section E of the Appraisal Case). ICF Key Performance Indicators 1. Numbers of people supported by ICF programmes to cope with the effects of climate change 2. Number of people with improved access to clean energy as a result of ICF programmes Primary Secondary Depends on the ‘prize problem statement’. Not likely to be primary or secondary. To be measured through the M&E framework. Target: 12 million people with improved access to energy and water services Depends on the ‘prize problem statement’. Not likely to be primary or secondary. Y 3. Number of forest dependent people with livelihoods benefits protected as a result of avoided deforestation and degradation 4. Value of assets/economic activities protected or made less vulnerable 5. Number of net jobs created Not primary or secondary. Likely to be difficult to measure. Y 6. Tonnes of CO2 equivalent reduced or avoided (including forestry) 7. Level of installed capacity of clean energy 8. Number of hectares where Expected results Y Y To be measured through the M&E framework (disaggregated by gender & income). To be measured through the M&E framework. Difficult to determine prior to prize problem statement definition. To be measured through the M&E framework. Difficult to determine prior to prize problem statement definition. Depends on the ‘prize problem 41 deforestation and degradation avoided 9. Number of domestic low carbon [and climate resilient] technologies supported Y 10. Value of (non-carbon) ecosystem goods and services generated/protected 11. Volume of public finance mobilised for climate change purposes as a result of ICF funding 12. Volume of private finance mobilised for climate change purposes as a result of ICF funding Y Y 13. Improved capacity of developing countries to tackle climate change 14. Increase in number and quality of climate change related knowledge products to support global & national decision making on shifting to low-carbon development paths 15. Extent to which ICF interventions are being transformational statement’. Not likely to be primary or secondary. To be measured through the M&E framework. Target: 7 innovative technologies developed and tested; 5 of these deployed61 Not primary or secondary. Likely to be difficult to measure. Y Y To be measured through the M&E framework. Target: At least £5m public finance leveraged (including donors/foundations)62 To be measured through the M&E framework. Target: £35m additional funds invested by private sector as result of the prize63 To be measured through the M&E framework. Target: At least 5 partnerships between developed and developing country private sector and researchers64 Not primary or secondary. Likely to be difficult to measure. To be measured through ongoing and end of programme evaluation. Potential to be highly transformational through the development and demonstration of new technologies and business models replicable across geographies, reducing costs and risks, and encouraging private investment. 61 Assuming 5 prizes: 1 transformational (5 new technologies developed, 3 technologies deployed); 2 mildly successful (2 new technologies developed, 2 technologies deployed); and 2 failures. 62 Assuming 25% of implementation and prize funding is secured from other public funders – likely to be a conservative estimate. 63 Average of return on investment figures from Shell Springboard (RoI 1.96) and OmniCompete Global Security Challenge (RoI 6.49), which assumes 10% discount rate and that prize is attributable for 20% of new investment into technologies/enterprises. As calculated in Everett (2011) – endnote 20. 64 Partnerships will be formed as part of the prize platform, which will likely include a condition for partnerships across the developing and developed world. Assume a minimum of one partnership per prize. 42 Lograme Quest No of logframe for this intervention: 3594111 43 Annex 1 Overview of rule-of-thumb in prize policy design – Vivid Economics (2007) 44 Annex 2 Evidence of need / R&D gap and opportunities Small-scale waste-to-energy solutions for urban slums Katukiza, A.Y., Ronteltap, M., Niwagaba, C.B., Foppen, J.W., Kansiime, F., Lens, P.N. (2012) Sustainable sanitation technology options for urban slums. Biotechnology Advances 30(5): 964-78. ESMAP (date unknown) Innovative Approaches to Energy Access for the Urban Poor: Summaries of Best Practices from Case Studies in Four Countries Kuick Research (2012) India Urban and Industrial Waste to Energy Market UN-Habitat (2009) Promoting Energy Access for the urban poor in Africa: Approaches and Challenges in Slum Electrification Business models for pay-as-you-go household modern energy services Ferris, D. (2012) Cleantech Startup Finds Poor Villagers are More Profitable than Mobile Telecom. Forbes Magazine blog. Available at: http://www.forbes.com/sites/davidferris/2012/09/13/cleantech-startup-finds-poorvillagers-are-more-profitable-than-mobile-telecom/ The Economist Technology Quarterly Q3 2012 Lighting the way Energy technology: Cheaper and better solar-powered electric lights promise to do away with kerosene fuelled lanterns. Available at: http://www.economist.com/node/21560983 Quick, cheap, reliable microbiological testing of water Rahman, K., Khush, R., Gundry, S. (2010) Aquatest: Expanding Microbial Water Quality Testing for Drinking Water Management in Drinking Water Safety International, April 2010. International Water Association. Low carbon cooling technologies (low energy, low refrigerants for either buildings or food preservation) Koizumi, S. (2007) Energy Efficiency of Air Conditioners in Developing Countries and the Role of CDM. IEA Information Note, International Energy Agency. McNeil, M. A., Letschert, V. E. (2008) Future of Air Conditioning Energy Consumption in Developing Countries and what can be done about it: The Potential of Efficiency in the Residential Sector. Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory. Rosenthal, E. (2012) The Costs of Keeping the Tropics Cool. The New York Times, Sustainability News Analysis, Saturday 8 September 2012. International Institute of Refrigeration (2002) Refrigeration report. Part of the Industry as a partner for sustainable development series, facilitated by UNEP. Household energy storage that doesn't involve batteries Nissen, W. (2012) Energy Storage R&D Key to Renewables. Minnesota 2020. Available at: http://www.mn2020.org/issues-that-matter/economicdevelopment/energy-storage-rd-key-to-renewables. Dell, R. M., Rand, D. A. J. (2001) Energy storage – a key technology for global energy sustainability. Journal of Power Sources 100: 2-17. Ali, H., Ali-Oettinger, S. (2012) Advancing Li-ion. PV Magazine. Available at: http://www.pv-magazine.com/archive/articles/beitrag/advancing-li-ion_100006681/501/#axzz27NnpdmAp 45