“D eclining levels of legitimacy, good governance, and socioeconomic performance all point in the direction of a disturbing trend: the quality of democracy in Paraguay is extremely low. The absence of collective actors has given rise to parties that are clientelistic, rather than issue-based, in nature. For almost twenty years, these neopopulist parties have dominated Paraguayan politics, implementing particularistic, pork-barrel, and volatile policies that have, in turn, engendered economic stagnation, high levels of poverty, and profound disenchantment. Between the “rock” of low-quality democracy and the “hard place” of neopopulism stands Bishop Fernando Lugo, a likely frontrunner in Paraguay’s 2008 presidential election. Fears that he may be the next Hugo Chávez are misguided. A Lugo presidency could spur much-needed reform in Paraguay. ” —Diego Abente-Brun, June 7, 2007 Between a Rock and a Hard Place: Dilemmas of Democracy in Paraguay by Diego Abente-Brun Reagan-Fascell Democracy Fellow June 7, 2007 National Endowment for Democracy Please note that the views expressed in this presentation represent the opinions and analysis of the speaker and do not necessarily reflect those of the National Endowment of Democracy. The Third Wave of Democracy (1978- ) and its Challenges Electoral democracies, illiberal regimes. Low quality democracies The Emerging Literature on Quality of Democracy O’Donnell, Vargas Cullel, Iazetta, The Quality of Democracy, 2004 Diamond & Morlino, Assessing the Quality of Democracy, 2005 Emphasis on: Conceptual craftsmanship Studies of comparative dyads Missing: A systematic inquiry into the causes Defining Quality of Democracy The question to be addressed… Distinguishes between nature and quality of democracy …NOT how democratic a democracy is, or a polyarchy is … (Rule of law, participation, competition, Accountability, Freedom, Political Equality, Responsiveness) …but what is the quality of regimes that qualify as democratic (or polyarchic) in terms of their ability to address key issues. Three variables taken into account: 1. 2. 3. Legitimacy (Ability to generate support) Effectiveness (Ability to govern well/governance) Efficacy (Ability to deliver) Quality of Democracy in South America: 1) LEGITIMACY OVERALL INDEX DEMOCRACY 2000–2004 1995–2005 SUPPORT FOR SATISFACTION WITH Paraguay 38 34 32 17 Ecuador 38 34 43 14 Bolivia 40 39 40 13 Peru 41 39 49 24 Colombia 41 41 46 29 Brazil 47 43 37 22 Venezuela 53 56 76 56 Chile 53 56 59 43 Argentina 59 57 65 34 Uruguay 66 68 77 63 Sources: Frances Hagopian, 2005 (Support & Satisfaction with Democracy, Importance of voting, Valid votes/VAP, Trust in Gov’t, Democracy is the Best System), Latinobarómetro 2005. Quality of Democracy in South America: 2) GOVERNANCE COUNTRY AVERAGE Political Stability Government Effectiveness Regulatory Quality Control of Corruption Venezuela -0.88 -1.00 -0.92 -0.68 -0.91 Paraguay -0.83 -0.76 -1.06 -0.44 -1.08 Ecuador -0.77 -0.89 -0.92 -0.39 -0.87 Colombia -0.58 -1.87 -0.13 0.11 -0.45 Bolivia -0.38 -0.50 -0.45 0.20 -0.76 Perú -0.28 -0.85 -0.32 0.34 -0.28 Argentina -0.17 -0.14 0.01 -0.13 -0.43 Brazil -0.03 -0.16 -0.07 0.18 -0.07 Uruguay 0.61 0.64 0.56 0.59 0.64 Chile 1.17 0.71 1.27 1.36 1.36 Source: World Bank, Kauffman, Kraay, & Mastruzzi, “Governance Matters.” Data averaged for the period 1996–2005. Quality of Democracy in South America: 3) SOCIOECONOMIC PERFORMANCE COUNTRY POVERTY GAP POVERTY GDP GROWTH PC Bolivia 34.40 62.40 0.90 Paraguay 30.30 61.00 -1.10 Colombia 24.10 50.60 0.30 Venezuela 22.10 48.60 0.90 Ecuador 20.80 49.00 1.10 Perú 20.60 54.70 1.60 Brazil 17.80 38.70 0.70 Argentina 12.20 29.40 1.40 Chile 6.30 18.70 3.00 Uruguay 4.50 15.40 1.00 Source: CEPAL. Data from most recent year available (ranges from 2001 to 2004). The Quest for an Explanation Three hypotheses: 1. STRUCTURAL Socioeconomic matrix Stakeholders and nature of the political game 2. INSTITUTIONAL Nature of the party system Rules of the political game, constitutional and legal 3. SOCIO-CULTURAL “Social capital” of the population Associational predispositions; horizontal relations 1) STRUCTURAL: Socioeconomic Matrix NONAGRICULTURAL WORKFORCE COUNTRY Urban Agric. Workforce Informal Formal PERCENTAGE OF EMPLOYEES WITH SOCIAL SECURITY Informal Formal Overall Bolivia 39.0% 32.3% 66.7% 33.8% 6.5% 46.3% 31.3% Ecuador 48.0% 30.3% 57.6% 42.4% 14.2% 63.4% 47.1% Paraguay 49.6% 31.3% 62.9% 37.1% 4.4% 45.3% 26.5% Peru 55.2% 37.5% 58.0% 42.0% 14.9% 63.9% 48.3% Brazil 58.4% 19.6% 44.6% 55.4% 34.2% 83.8% 69.2% Colombia 59.2% 20.9% 59.9% 40.1% 27.5% 83.9% 65.2% Venezuela 71.5% 9.7% 52.2% 47.8% 16.9% 72.2% 57.0% Chile 72.1% 13.3% 35.8% 61.2% 48.9% 83.3% 76.4% Uruguay 74.3% 4.6% 37.7% 62.3% 32.9% 87.0% 73.1% Argentina 74.9% 1.1% 44.3% 55.7% 17.5% 66.8% 51.5% Sources: CEPAL, Int’l Labor Organization. Data from most recent available (2002–2004). 1) STRUCTURAL (continued): Effects of Invertebrate Society Invertebrate society: Lack of collective actors with collective interests that can structure the political game along issue-based lines This lack of social articulation favors the emergence of clientelistic politics Prevents the development of horizontal ties and furthers vertical, hierarchical, and in essence, exploitative relationships. Incorporates popular sectors as clients, but excludes them as citizens. 2) INSTITUTIONAL: Clientelistic vs. Issue-Based Parties Social Base of Support Policy Bias Identity profile Redistributive Universalistic Progressive pro-labor; or conservative, pro-business Distributive Particularistic Populist, conservative, personalistic Correlates Types of Parties Issue-Based Constituencies Collectives Parties Clientelistic Parties Constituents Individuals Effects of Clientelistic Parties on Quality of Democracy 1. 2. 3. 4. Favors particularistic policies that privilege individual party supporters. Breeds dependence on small but organized groups—mainly public employees—that interact not with each other but with state. Reinforces rent-seeking behavior of powerful socioeconomic actors. Increases both the weakness and centrality of the state. Socioeconomic matrix Types of parties Quality of policies Effects of Low Quality of Democracy GDP per-capita 1980: $1,441 1989: $1,442 2004: $1,382 30% of population is rural and has no access to land 10% of overall population owns 66% of the available land Remaining 60% of population share 6% of the surface 1980–1988 1989–1999 2000–2005 Tax burden 7.7% 10.5% 10.9% Bureaucratic Burden 42.4% 61.3% 75.9% Growth in Public-Sector Employees Total de cargos de la Administración Central (1989 - 1999) 250,000 200,000 150,000 100,000 50,000 0 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2004 Growth in Public-Sector Salaries The Trap of Clientelism On the one hand…. 80% of voters belong to one of two traditional parties On the other hand… 75% of the population considers political parties the least-trustworthy institution 3) SOCIO-CULTURAL FACTORS: Associational Predispositions Inspired by work of Tocqueville Interpersonal trust and associational behavior key to quality of democracy Interpersonal trust in Paraguay very low between 1996 and 2004 (Latinobarómetro) In 2001, 56.9% of population didn’t belong to any intermediate organization; in 2005, 70.3% Are these causes or consequences of low quality of democracy? The Rock and Hard-Place Dilemma Low quality democracy vs. the neo-populist alternative Neo-populism: No longer tied to specific social constituencies or economic policies (e.g. Peron, Vargas), but instead… …tied to a pattern of personalistic and anti-institutionalist politics rooted in the appeal and mobilization of marginalized masses by a charismatic, often authoritarian leader 1996–2003: the neo-populist temptation; authoritarian formulas, Gen. Lino Oviedo. The Unexpected Social-science explanations can never rule out the unexpected The unexpected came in March 2006 with a citizens’ demonstration led by Monsignor Fernando Lugo This confirms the old adage, “There is no ill that lasts 100 years nor a Paraguayan willing to put up with it.” Hope Beyond Hope The chiliastic upsurge of former Bishop Fernando Lugo Lugo, Chavez, Morales Lugo not a military leader, but a pastor who grew up in a tradition of horizontality, collective leadership, and anti-authoritarianism. Lugo not a Marxist or a neo-populist but an exponent of Catholic social progressism. Lugo not a leader of an ethnically divided society. Lugo is a catalyst who gathers support from a wide range of parties, from right to left. Lugo identifies himself as a centrist (“mbytetepe, poncho juruicha”); sees ‘left’ as a movement for change rather than as an ideological platform. Implications Ecuador Similar socioeconomic matrix, similar clientelistic parties (but not deeply rooted) Instability, development of a new politics of identity (Pachacutik) Emergence of populist-authoritarian alternatives Lucio Gutiérrez and Rafael Correa Bolivia Similar socioeconomic matrix, similar clientelistic parties (but not deeply rooted save MNR) Development of new politics of identity Emergence of radical alternatives Evo Morales Corollaries Bolivia: If established political elites do not make reform possible, they make revolutions inevitable. Evo Morales. Ecuador: If established political elites do not make reform possible, they make instability inevitable. Mahuad, Gutiérrez, Palacios, Correa … Paraguay If opposition political elites do not make reforms possible, they make one-party rule inevitable. Lugo? Between a Rock and a Hard Place: Dilemmas of Democracy in Paraguay Diego Abente-Brun Reagan-Fascell Democracy Fellow THE END