Procyclicality and Macroprudential Policy Framework Jan Frait Head of Financial Stability I. Macroprudential Policy Framework What is a macroprudential policy framework? • Following the global financial crisis, on the EU level as well as on the national levels the ways how to establish the additional pillar for financial stability – macroprudential policy framework – is being discussed. • Until the crisis, the concept of macroprudential policy was discussed primarily within the central banking community under the leadership of the Bank for International Settlements (BIS henceforth). The interest of the academic community in the issue was rather limited. • After the crisis, the term “macroprudential” has become a buzzword (Clement, 2010). The establishment of effective macroprudential policy framework has become one of the prime objectives of the G20, EU, IMF and other structures. • In the EU, such a desire has already been reflected in the decision to create the European Systemic Risk Board as the EU-wide authority of macroprudential supervision and by number of iniciatives focusing on defining the EU-wide framework for macroprudential regulation. What is a macroprudential policy framework? • Various issues related to macroprudential considerations have become in the centre of focus of researchers from multinational institutions, central banking community, supervisory authorities and academia. • One of the outcomes of the evolution described above is that the meaning of the multi-facetated concept of macroprudential policy is becoming more and more obscure. The term “macroprudential” is now too embracive and it is often used outside of the scope of its original meaning. • This presentation is going to look at the concept of macroprudential policies from relatively narrow perspective of the original BIS approach (e.g. Borio, 2003, Borio and White, 2004). What is a macroprudential policy framework? • The objective of a macroprudential approach in the BIS tradition is to limit the risk of episodes of financial distress with significant losses in terms of the real output for the economy as a whole. The definition falls within the macroeconomic concept and implicitly involves monetary and fiscal policies (Borio and Shim, 2007, and White, 2009). • In the BIS tradition, the phenomenon of financial market procyclicality (mainly the procyclical behaviour of credit provision) stands centrally (Borio and Lowe, 2001, or Borio, Furnine and Lowe, 2001). • The study of procyclicality has a strong time-series dimension and the gradual build up of vulnerabilties over time has to be the subject of research (Borio, 2009, Brunnermeier et al., 2009, and Borio and Drehmann, 2009). • Macroprudential policies are then defined the set of tools that have a capacity to strenghten the resilience of the financial system as a whole through build up of cushions or potentially reducing its vulnerability via decreasing the amplitude of the financial cycle. What is a macroprudential policy framework? • The other stream is modelling of systemic risk associated with individual institutions. By comparison with canonical models of systemic risk like Diamond and Dybvig (1983) emphasining interlinkages and common exposures among institutions, in the BIS logic, systemic risk arises primarily through common exposures to macroeconomic risk factors across institutions. • The other stream focusing on the cross-section dimension of systemic risk (common exposures among institutions, network risks, infrastructure risks, contagion ...) has been intensively studied by the IMF (see special chapters on systemic risks in the last few Global Financial Stability Reports). What is a macroprudential policy framework? • The ongoing work on macroprudential tools is focusing mostly on the design issues (e.g. Bank of England, 2009, and Drehmann et. al., 2010). • Major progress has been achieved in the design of countercyclical capital buffers. • More focus on the issues of efficiency and feasibility of macroprudential tools should follow. Though there is some certainty that the tools can help to provide the financial sectors with cushions, there is a major uncertainty regarding the potential of the tools to limit the effects of procyclical behaviour in good times. • Should we really believe what the new GFSR says? “The model was also used to investigate the impact of countercyclical capital requirements, and found that a countercyclical rule linked to credit growth might reduce output variability by around one third in the euro area, and by around one-quarter in the United States.“ II. Macrofinancial Framework and Monetary Policy? Should monetary policy be part of macroprudential approach? • Until recently a debate „how should central bank react to asset prices“ only, after the crisis the focus broader (credit and leverage) • Central banks automatically has always been taking the asset price developments into account when setting monetary policy: • asset price movements impact on CPI inflation via demand for goods and services used to create assets, • asset price movements also feed into CPI inflation due to the "wealth“ effect, • asset prices also feed through into spending via the effect of improved balance sheets on borrowing capacity of firms and individuals and willingness of lenders to lend. • Normally asset and consumer prices move together, but • sometimes speculative bubbles develop, • bubbles will burst, potential damage may be huge. CBs do not ignore asset prices • Should central banks try to constrain asset price bubbles? • The economists used to be divided into three groups (Bernanke‘s view) • Group A philosophy: • central bank should pay attention to asset markets’ developments, but cannot and should not try to constrain asset price bubbles on their own. • outspoken speaker - Ben Bernanke • Group B approach: • lean-against-the-bubble (BIS economists) • Group C stance: • aggressive bubble-popping Ben Bernanke‘s view • Bernanke (2002) rule for central bank policy regarding asset-market instability: • Use the right tool for the job! • Fed has two sets of responsibilities: • maximum sustainable employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates, • the stability of the financial system. • Fed has two sets of policy tools: • policy interest rates, • range of powers with respect to financial institutions. • Fed should focus its monetary policy instruments on achieving its macro goals, while using its regulatory, supervisory, and lender-of-last resort powers to help ensure financial stability. Ben Bernanke‘s view • Monetary policy: • to the extent that a stock-market boom causes higher spending on consumer goods and investments, it may indicate future inflationary pressures, policy tightening might be an adequate reaction, • goal of reaction should be to contain the incipient inflation, not the stockmarket boom. • Financial sector policies: • central bank should use its regulatory and supervisory powers to reduce the incidence of bubbles and to protect the financial system. Ben Bernanke‘s view • Group B - leaning-against-the-bubble: • not entirely without merit, the uncertainty regarding the effectiveness. • Group C - Aggressive bubble-popping: • risky and dangerous approach, • identical to Federal Reserve Policy in the 1920s - the Fed was trying to prick the stock market bubble but succeeded only to kill the economy. The case against active stance • General arguments against an activist approach: • a central bank cannot reliably identify bubbles in asset prices, • even if a central bank could identify bubbles, monetary policy does not posses appropriate tools for effective use against them, • once a central bank becomes sure that a bubble has emerged, it will probably be too late to act, • pursuing a separate asset price objective could mean having to compromise on normal inflation objective. What Bernanke seemed to ignore? • What if the bubble is emerging without any signs of inflationary pressures? • inflation measured in terms of consumer prices has not always signalled that imbalances in the economy have been building up. • prevailing monetary policy models used to forecast inflation pressures derive demand pressures from current inflation pressures. • A „dilemma“ scenario (small open economy case): • higher economic growth excessively optimist expectations nominal appreciation of domestic currency a very low inflation can prevail even under a rapid credit growth and asset price acceleration for rather a long time when the open inflation pressures finally appear, it may be too late for monetary policy to react. Note: these points were taken from CNB‘s 2005 presentation. BIS economists disagreed • BIS economists (mainly W. White) argued for a „leaning“ approach to the monetary policy in treating the credit and asset prices boom. • The summary of the approach is best covered by White‘s "post-BIS" paper "Should Monetary Policy "Lean or Clean": • It has been contended by many in the central banking community that monetary policy would not be effective in “leaning” against the upswing of a credit cycle (the boom) but that lower interest rates would be effective in “cleaning” up (the bust) afterwards. • These two propositions (can’t lean, but can clean) are examined and found seriously deficient. In particular, it is contended that monetary policies designed solely to deal with short term problems of insufficient demand could make medium term problems worse by encouraging a buildup of debt that cannot be sustained over time. • .... monetary policy should be more focused on “preemptive tightening” to moderate credit bubbles than on “preemptive easing” to deal with the after effects. How to cope with a „dilemma“ scenario (CNB‘s experience)? • BIS approach (to which the CNB subscribed a lot), untill recently the minority one, was and still is was supportive of leanging-against-the-cycle. • In this approach, if financial stability analyses identify the risk of emerging bubble, central bank may act at an early stage when asset prices are starting to accelerate and before the expansion in credit has become too sharp. • By raising interest rates CB may help to avoid a subsequent collapse in asset prices that could lead to considerably lower output and inflation in the longer term. • At least, central bank policies should be conducted in a way that does not promote build-up of asset market bubbles. • Central banks in small open economies must be ready to use monetary policy steps as a kind of insurance against adverse effects of exchange rate bubbles. • However, there might be a conflict created by the simultaneous impact of monetary policy on both interest rates and exchange rate. The optimal policy therefore may not be available and second-best policies have to be considered. Will BIS approach become a mainstream? • M. Woodford (2010) in recent presentation in Prague (Inflation Targeting and Monetary Policy) summarized growing consensus on the need of leaning: • One needn't be able to predict exactly when crises will occur, only whether the risk of a crisis increases under certain circumstances. • Nor is the real issue whether assets are overvalued rather, the degree to which the positions taken by leveraged investors pose a risk to financial stability. • Real issue not controlling mis-pricing of assets, but deterring extreme leverage and maturity transformation - even modest changes in short-term rates can affect incentives for highly leveraged investing, excessive shortterm funding. • Really need to recognize financial stability as independent stabilization objective. Will BIS approach become a mainstream? • M. Woodford (cont.): • ... one can introduce a financial stability objective into a flexible IT framework - financial stability considerations only affect the near-term transition path to that invariant medium-run infation rate. • The proposed procedure is related to calls for a target for credit growth, but • what matters for the target criterion is leverage of intermediaries, not credit as such, • not solely a leverage target: target criterion still involves price level, output gap, • what matters is marginal crisis risk, rather than leverage as such. • Inflation should be allowed to undershoot normal target in a period of elevated marginal crisis risk • but there should be a commitment to make up the insufficient inflation later, so that the long-run price level is unaffected, • credible commitment of this kind would eliminate risk of deflationary spiral. III. Procyclicality and Provisioning Procyclicality • Financial system procyclicality means the ability of the financial system to amplify fluctuations of economic activity over the business cycle via procyclicality in financial institutions’ lending and other activities. • The procyclical behaviour of financial markets transmits to the real economy in amplified form through easy funding of expenditures and investments in good times and financial restrictions leading to declining demand in bad times. • Procyclicality have increased over the last few years due to (i) the greater use of leverage in the financial and real sectors, (ii) closer ties between market and funding liquidity e.g. through increased use of collateral in secured financing, (iii) increased contagion effects in integrated markets as well as (iv) the (unintended) effects of some regulations, including accounting standards. (EFC WG Report 2009) To provision or not to provision • Debate about the instruments that might reduce the potential procyclicality of regulation is not a new one. • Borio and Lowe (2001) – To provision or not provision • paper written just prior to the setting and implementation of current regulations, • describes a conflict between the interests of supervisors and accountants, • financial supervisors have tended to emphasise the role that provisions can play in ensuring that banks maintain adequate buffers against future deteriorations in credit quality, • accounting authorities have stressed the importance of provisions in generating fair and objective loan valuations. • The accountants won the battle … but after a few years we seem to be at the start back again. To provision or not to provision, to buffer or not to buffer • After the crisis - to provision or not to provision, to build capital buffers or not to build capital buffers • bank supervisors have always been more supportive of liberal general provisioning regimes and reserves than have accounting and securities authorities • this time the supervisors may use the opportunity, but it is not so easy to win a war … • Procyclicality may be caused by broad spectrum of factors going much beyond accounting and capital regulation framework of financial institutions‘ regulation. • The very idea that central bank will do its best by focusing its monetary policy instruments on achieving its macro goals, while using its regulatory, supervisory and lender-of-last resort powers to help ensure financial stability should probably be reconsidered. Procyclicality as a hot issue • ECOFIN roadmap on financial supervision, stability and regulation takes the issue of procyclicality rather seriously: • Valuation and accounting standards: Refinement of the accounting rules in respect of dynamic provisioning • Pro-cyclicality: • Follow-up to the report of the EFC-WG on Pro-cyclicality and the July Ecofin Conclusions Possible measures to address pro-cyclicality of capital requirements in the short term • Identify policy tools to mitigate pro-cyclicality in the financial system and financial regulation, including of capital requirements through countercyclical capital buffers in the CRD - dynamic provisioning, proccyclicality of CRD. • Similar agenda set also by Financial Stability Board. • Projects set by BCBS and IASB to propose what is required and expected. To provision or not to provision • In general principle, banks should set aside provisions to cover their expected losses while their capital should primarily be used to cover unexpected losses. • There generally exist several provisioning systems differing in either when the provisions are created and entered in the accounts or what event triggers provisioning. • Currently prevailing practice is “specific” provisioning. • specific provisions are fixed against losses on predominantly individually assessed loans and start at the moment an evident event occurs; • specific provisioning is backward looking (i.e. it identifies risk ex post). • General provisions • are set against losses from portfolios of loans and can be forward looking (i.e. they identify credit risk ex ante) To provision or not to provision • The key argument for forward-looking provisioning is the inherent tendency of banks to relax excessively lending standards during economic upturns and tighten them excessively during downturns • the risks are underestimated during upturns leading to credit booms with loans extended with prices set too low, • subsequent downturn leads to re-pricing under the impact of higher default rate, potentially ending in credit crunch. • Forward-looking provisioning should therefore help to ensure correct pricing of expected credit risk emerging at time when the credit is extended. To provision or not to provision • The international accounting standards currently in force (IAS 39) allow banks to provision only for loans for which there is clear evidence of impairment (i.e. backward-looking provisioning). • specific provisions are created and entered in the accounts only after credit risk comes to light (which usually occurs in times of recession), • In the general/dynamic provisioning system provisions are also created when credit risk comes into being (i.e. to a large degree in times of boom) • banks provision against existing loans in each accounting period in accordance with the assumption for expected losses: • at times when actual losses are smaller than assumed a buffer is created which can then be used at times when losses exceed the estimated level… • This looks straighforward, but in practice it is not so. Provisioning in Spain • Spain used „traditional“ provisioning up to 2000: general provisions (GP) reflected estimate of average expected loss from total loans: GP = g*ΔL , where L stands for total loans and g for the parameter (between 0.5% and 1%), while specific provisions (SP) were set in a standard way: SP = e*ΔM, where M stands for impaired loans and e for the parameter (between 10% and 100%). total provisions: TP = g*ΔL + e*ΔM. • In 2000, additional compotent was added – statistical provisions: Total provision (TP) = Specific (SP) + General (GP) + Statistical (StP) Provisioning in Spain • Banks sorted loans to six homogenous categories with different risk coefficient s (defined by supervisor as average specific provision rate over the whole cycle). • StP = Lr – SP, where Lr is a latent risk s*L, where s stands for the coefficient of a historical average specific provisions (between 0% and 1.5% in the standard approach), SP < Lr (low impaired loans) StP>0 (building up of the statistical fund), SP > Lr (high impaired loans) StP<0 (depletion of the statistical fund), balance of the statistical fund: StF = StPt+StFt-1, with a limit: 0 ≤ StF ≤ 3 * Lr Provisioning in Spain • System had to be modified with effect from 2005 due to the IRFS – statistical provisions were hidden in newly defined general provisons: Total provision (TP) = Specific (SP) + General (GP) SP: unchanged, 6 GPt i Lit i Lit SPt GP: i 1 i 1 • banks must make provisions against the credit growth according to parameter which is the average ratio of estimated credit losses (“collective assessment for impairment” in a year neutral from a cyclical perspective) and parameter which is the historical ratio of average specific provision (coefficient s in previous version), • 1st component reflects losses in the past, 2nd reflects specific provisions in the past relative to current ones (dynamic component), • limits for fund set as 0,1% ≤ GF ≤ 1,5% of total loans. 6 Provisioning in Spain • Developments in provisioning funds in Spain after 2000 – developments of provisions‘ components Total provisions Especific provisions General provisions million € 60.000 50.000 40.000 30.000 20.000 10.000 0 dic-00 jun-01 dic-01 jun-02 dic-02 jun-03 dic-03 jun-04 dic-04 jun-05 dic-05 jun-06 dic-06 jun-07 dic-07 jun-08 dic-08 Source: Saurina, J. (2009): The Spanish experience of counter-cyclical regulation. Prague, October 23, 2009. jun-09 Provisioning in Spain • Spanish authorities considered a new system IFRS compatible (IFSB not). • Fund was set in good times, buffer was created prior to current crisis • NPLs 200% covered at the beginning of 2008 (EU average 60%), • Nevertheless, at the end of 2008 only 100% covered, • not sure whether the fund will suffice ... still better that nothing. • Spanish system viewed as accounting tool – though BdE considers it as part of toolbox for macroprudential supervision. • BdE does not think it distorts accounting statements: • Banks are required to disclose the amount of the dynamic provision, apart from the specific provision. • Thus, users of accounting statements can “undo” the impact of the dynamic provision on the P&L. Provisioning in Spain • Spanish system was rather simple – a kind of pre-dynamic provisioning: • not optimal, just one of potential solutions, • not sure whether it really restricts excessive lending, • can hardly be adopted in current recessionary conditions, • unilateral attempts to do so might do more harm than gain – see Brunnermeier, M. et al. (2009), • proposal by Commission to use it via CRD supported neither by industry nor by supervisors (including the CNB). Do the Czech banks provision procyclically? Loan loss provisions/total loans and GDP growth (Czech Republic, 1998 - 2008) 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 -2 -3 Source: CNB, CZSO Note: y-axis: GDP growth in %; x-axis: ratio of provisions to loans in % 14 • There is a negative relationship between GDP growth and the ratio of loan loss provisions to total loans in the Czech Republic for the period 1998–2008. • Does it reflect procyclical behaviour? • If yes, how strong are the non-procyclical features of banks‘ behaviour? • For results see Frait and Komárková (2009) Do the Czech banks provision procyclically? ( LLP / TA)i ,t 1 2 ln GDPt 3 UNEMPL _ gapt 4 ( EARN / TA)i ,t 5 ln LOANSi ,t 6 ( LOANS / TA)i ,t 7 (CAP / TA)i ,t i ,t Variables: (i) macroeconomic: the growth rate of real GDP (ΔlnGDP), the unemployment gap (UNEMPL_gap); (i) bank-specific: the ratio of loan loss provisions to average total assets (LLP/TA), loan growth (ΔlnLOANS), the ratio of total loans to TA (LOANS/TA), pre-tax earnings (EARN), the ratio of equity capital to TA; (ii) other: „t“ denotes time and „i“ the individual banks, TA stands for the average total assets for the two periods (0.5(TAt+TAt-1)). Do the Czech banks provision procyclically? • If banks behave procyclically, the rate of economic growth will be negatively correlated with provisioning, unemployment rate gap positively, loans growth and the ratio of total loans to total assets positively if banks behave prudentially, pre-tax profit positively, capital ratio more likely negatively. Results of panel regression for loan loss provisions Variables LLP/TA, lagged by 1Q GDP growth Unemployment gap Pre-tax profit Loans growth Loans/TA Capital/TA No. of observations R2 - within (among banks) R2 - between (over time) Coefficients 0,3390 -0,0003 0,0012 0,6565 -0,0022 0,0118 -0,2230 172 0,942 0,993 375,46 F test of equality of constants for banks (FE) F (3,161) 2,24 Std. Deviations 0,5084 0,0020 0,0006 0,0567 0,0022 0,0048 0.0319 R2 - overall rho Prob > F Prob > F Note: The data were statistically significant at the ***1%, **5% or *10% level. t 6,67*** -1,74** 1,84** 11,57*** -1,00 2,46*** -6,98*** 0,947 0,102 0,000 0,0857 Do the Czech banks provision procyclically? Conclusions: • The negative GDP growth and positive unemployment rate gap suggest that provisioning is significantly procyclical and lacks to a large extent forward-looking assessment of cycle-related risk; …however • The procyclicality is being partly reduced: (i) positive and relative high coefficient of the pre-tax profit = the income smoothing or tax optimization, (ii) positive coefficient of loans to total assets = prudential behaviour confirmed; … but banks set aside fewer provisions to cover their expected losses when their capital buffer is larger (negative capital/TA coeff.). IV. Proposals for taming procyclicality Existing proposals for taming procyclicality • Through-the-cycle expected loss provisioning (TELP) – EU Commission consultation to further changes in CRD from July 2009: • Based on through-the-cycle expected loss – forward looking estimation of losses that should be covered by TELP. • TELP designed in line with Spanish approach – baseline method uses both α and β parameters, more simple method considers parameter β only. • Prudential measure of a „corrective kind“ which nevertheless has impact on the accounting. • Proposal does not address the issue of consistency between IFRS and CRD. • TELP potentially in conflict with regulatory concept of expected loss in Basel II. • IRB institutions (only) apply models to set expected losses and their coverage by provisions is tested (if provisions not sufficient, difference deducted from regulatory capital). Existing proposals for taming procyclicality • Expected loss approach (IASB, June 2009) • The expected cash flow approach - currently being considered as a part of IASB project on replacing IAS 39 Financial Instruments Measurement and Recognition. • A major deviation from incurred loss approach - no trigger for an impairment test required • it should reflect better the economic reality of banks’ lending activities than the incurred loss approach in that it requires an earlier recognition of expected credit losses, • it should help to avoid ‘incurred but not reported losses’. • The present value of the expected future cash flows is measured using an initial internal rate of return calculated on the basis of cash flows actually expected at inception (taking into account expected credit losses), and not on the basis of contractually agreed cash flows. Existing proposals for taming procyclicality • Expected loss approach (IASB, June 2009) cont. • Initial internal rate of return will thus be lower than the contractual rate, with the difference representing the risk premium charged to the borrower in order to cover the statistically foreseeable risk of non-recovery. • Difference between cash flows received that represent contractual interest and interest recognised as revenues on the basis of the (lower) internal rate of return would be recognised in the balance sheet as a credit expected loss provision. • Subsequent or additional impairment loss is recognised through continuous re-estimation of credit loss expectations. Reversal of impairment loss is recognised in profit or loss when there is a favourable change in credit loss expectations. • Would bring subjectivity, number of complex issues, transparency issues. • Spanish approach and economic cycle reserve can serve as complementary tools to it. Existing proposals for taming procyclicality • Economic cycle reserve (ECR) – UK Turner review • An additional non-distributable reserve which would set aside profit in good years to anticipate losses likely to arise in future. • A formula driven method would simple and non-discretionary similarly to Spanish system: • a buffer of the order of magnitude of 2 – 3 % of RWAs at the peak of the cycle, • reserve could vary according to some predetermined metric such as the growth of the balance sheet or estimates of average through-the-cycle loan losses. • A discretionary method would be entity-specific, tailored to the peculiarities of each bank’s portfolios. Existing proposals for taming procyclicality • Economic cycle reserve (ECR) – UK Turner review cont. • The approach has a macro-prudential defensive focus and is meant to be accounting neutral • it is to be shown only as a movement on the balance sheet, rather than on the P&L (is intended to be built and drawn by appropriation of retained earnings), • but there are very strong arguments that it should also appear somewhere on the P&L, • allowing bottom line profit and earnings per share (EPS) to be calculated both before and after its effect, and thus providing two measures of profitability, the ‘traditional’ accounting figure and a second figure struck after economic cycle reserving. • Counter-cyclical capital buffers (under Basel III) – now at the most advanced stage due to its attractiveness to the regulators and supervisors. V. Counter-cyclical capital buffers Capital buffers: nothing new • Borio and Lowe (2001) revisited • One possibility … is a clearer treatment of the relationship between provisions and regulatory capital … • to exclude general provisions from capital and to set provisions so that they cover an estimate of the net embedded loss in a bank’s loan portfolio, • capital could then be calibrated with respect to the variability in those losses (their “unexpected” component). (p. 46) • Another approach … supervisors could supplement capital requirements with a prudential provisioning requirement … • instead of having the annual statistical provisioning charge deducted from a bank’s profit and loss statement, have it added to the bank’s regulatory capital requirement for unexpected losses. (p. 48) Capital buffers: nothing new • Procyclicality of Basel II was widely debated prior its implementation. • There was a clear understanding that risk-sensitive regulatory capital requirements tend to rise more in recessions and grow less during expansions, laying the ground for potentially pro-cyclical effects. • The authors of the framework therefore pretended that they included some mitigating factors to dampen the potential pro-cyclical effect of Basel II's increased risk-sensitivity. • Although improved risk management was one of the arguments for the introduction of Basel II, it now appears that neither regulatory capital nor economic capital has been set adequately to capture actual risk, particularly the risk contained in the trading book. Capital buffers: nothing new • High (perceived) costs of scraping Basel II down have been reflected in the desire of regulators/supervisors to continue relying on Basel II framework in dealing with procyclicality. • First, they hoped, after the current crisis, micropolicies might become easier for implementation including „theoretical“ tools within current Basel II-Pillar 2: • Internal Capital Adequacy Assessment Process, Supervisory Review and Evaluation Process • Stress testing with scenarios and methodology from supervisors • Backward testing of PDs and LGDs, downturn LGDs, conservative margins, tests of adequacy of provisions ... • Second, they struggled to add some procyclicality-mitigating factors into the concept. CEBS proposal • CEBS (CEBS, 2009) proposed practical tools for supervisors to assess under Pillar 2 the capital buffers that banks have to maintain under the Basel II/CRD framework (focusing on procyclicality of banking book of IRB banks). • CEBS was considering the use of mechanisms that adjust probabilities of default (PDs) estimated by banks, in order to incorporate recessionary conditions. • Current PD: the long-term average of the default rates (either at the grade or • • • • portfolio level). Downturn PD: the highest PD over a predetermined time-span. The scaling factor is: SF = PD_downturn / PD_current (close to 1 in a recession and higher than 1 in expansionary phases). The size of the buffer decreases in recession and increases in an upswing. CEBS says proposal might easily be adapted in a Pillar 1 context, but ... Countercyclical capital buffers • BCBS‘s Countercyclical Capital Buffer proposal (2nd stage, issued for comments in September 2010) • The CCB proposal is designed to ensure that banking sector capital requirements take account of the macro-financial environment in which banks operate. • The primary aim is to use a buffer of capital to achieve the macroprudential goal of protecting the banking sector from periods of excess credit growth that have often been associated with the build up of system-wide risk. • Protecting the banking sector in this context is not simply ensuring that individual banks remain solvent through a period of stress. Rather, the aim is to ensure that the banks in aggregate has the capital on hand to maintain the flow of credit in the economy without its solvency being questioned, when the financial system experiences stress after a period of excess credit growth. • This focus on excess aggregate credit growth means that jurisdictions are likely to only need to deploy the buffer on an infrequent basis, perhaps as infrequently as once every 10 to 20 years. Countercyclical capital buffers • The starting point is Basel III new regulatory capitalization minimums: 1. New common equity ratio (Core Tier1, CT1) of 7%, split between a 4.5% • • minimum requirement and a conservation buffer of 2.5%. 2. A countercyclical buffer of up to 2.5% of common equity, implemented according to national circumstance. 3. A supplementary, non-risk-based leverage ratio, to be tested at 3%. 4. Systemically important banks to carry loss-absorbing capacity “beyond the standards announced”. The CCB is thus presented as an add-on to the capital conservation buffer, effectively stretching the size of the range in which restrictions on distributions of profits are applied. To allow banks time to adjust to a buffer level that exceeds the fixed capital conservation range, they would be given 12 months to get their capital levels above the top of the extended range, before restrictions on distributions are imposed. Countercyclical capital buffers • The starting point is Basel III new regulatory capitalization minimums (cont.): • Goldman Sachs view of Basel III (GS Global Investment Research): 1. CT1 ratio of 7% as the new regulatory minimum for banks of non-systemic importance - for banks deemed to be of systemic importance, the CT1 minimum is subject to an additional surcharge and is therefore to be set at a level above the 7% CT1 minimum. 2. A regulatory minimum is just that: a minimum. In practice, banks will aim to exceed the minimum to be on the safe-side; and exceeded it further, before capital return to shareholders is considered. 7% is not the “magic” number; rather, it is a floor. 3. From an equity investor’s perspective, the relevant level of capital is not the regulatory minimum but rather one above which all key parties—bank managements, regulators, debt holders, “the market”—would not object to capital being returned to shareholders. This level—the GS target capitalization—will also differ among banks. Countercyclical capital buffers • The starting point is Basel III new regulatory capitalization minimums (cont.): Goldman Sachs view of Basel III Countercyclical capital buffers • The essence of CCB: • Calibration of CCB should be based on credit-to-GDP ratio and its deviation • • • • from its long-term trend. The proposal uses a broad definition of credit that will capture all sources of debt funds for the private sector (including funds raised abroad) to calculate a starting buffer guide. Ideally the definition of credit should include all credit extended to households and other non-financial private entities in an economy independent of its form and the identity of the supplier of funds. . Conversely, the buffer would be released when, in the judgment of the authorities, the released capital would help absorb losses in the banking system that pose a risk to financial stability. This would help reduce the risk that available credit is constrained by regulatory capital requirements. Authorities in each jurisdiction will be responsible for setting the buffer add-on applicable to credit exposures to counterparties/borrowers in its jurisdiction. The buffer that will apply to an internationally active bank will reflect the geographic composition of the bank’s portfolio of credit exposures. Countercyclical capital buffers • The essence of CCB (cont.): • By design, the constraints imposed on banks with capital levels at the top of the range would be minimal. • The buffer range is divided into quartiles determining the percentage of earnings to be conserved (calibration not finished yet). Countercyclical capital buffers • The essence of CCB (cont.) - the example: • Minimum CT1 requirement for all banks is 4,5% of RWA + the capital conservation buffer is set at 2,5% of RWA. • Under this setting a bank with a CT1 ratio of 7,5% or higher would not be subject to any restrictions on distributions of capital as restrictions are only imposed in the range of 4,5% – 7%. • If this bank becomes subject to a CCB add-on of 2%, the range in which restrictions on distributions are imposed becomes 4,5% – 9%. • CT1 capital ratio of 7.5% is in the third quartile of this range and so, using the numbers in the table above, would be required to conserve 60% of earnings. Countercyclical capital buffers 56 • The CCB gives a national regulator wide discretion: • Calibration of CCB should be based on credit-to-GDP ratio and its deviation from its long-term trend, but this will be common reference point only. • The calculated long-term trend of the credit/GDP ratio is a purely statistical measure that does not capture turning points well. Authorities will form their own judgments about the sustainable level of credit in the economy. • Authorities in each jurisdiction will be free to emphasise any other variables and qualitative information that make sense to them for purposes of assessing the sustainability of credit growth and the level of system-wide risk, as well as in taking and explaining buffer decisions. • Particular consideration was given to the question of how to take account of jurisdictions with financial systems at different stages of development. Each jurisdiction will have the discretion to impose buffers above or below the guide buffer add-on level, subject to appropriate transparency and disclosure requirements. Where will this lead? • There is a risk that combination of redrafted Basel II combined with capital buffering, leverage limits and expected-loss-provisioning will produce something unexpected … • There is a visible lack of coordination of authorities in terms of simultaneous considerations of both regulatory and accounting aspects. • D. Tarullo (2008): „ … there is a strong possibility that the Basel II paradigm might eventually produce the worst of both worlds—a highly complicated and impenetrable process (except perhaps for a handful of people in the banks and regulatory agencies) for calculating capital but one that nonetheless fails to achieve high levels of actual risk sensitivity”... • Still, if the cycle is driven by overly optimistic expectations, only combined effect of several other policies could do the job. Money, regulation and supervisors courage • The imbalances leading to current crisis were developing in a very complex manner due to the combined effect of globalization, financial market deregulation and increases in productivity that seemed to be more than temporary. • Such a process was reflected in a build-up of optimistic expectations leading to „this time it will be different“. • Monetary policy was really not much helpful, but not the major source of asset price booms (see IMF World Economic Outlook, October 2009). • There was no “key source“, “major policy fault“, “most important wrongdoer“ behind the sources of crisis and a major difference in a single policy could not prevent it. • Or, do we really think that central bankers and supervisors were strong enough to stop a high speed train with a massive political support? • Or even, how strong would be the support of policy-makers in one country who would try to cut off the music when the whole world was still dancing? Money, regulation and supervisors courage • The lesson for myself – if the international economy in the future starts undergoing a dynamic drive again, accompanied by credit and asset price booms, the authorities should apply concerted set of microprudential and macroprudential measures to tame the immoderate optimism. • Factors mitigating procyclicality embodied in regulation should ensure accumulation of buffers and better supervision should prevent the bank managers from taking excessive risks. • Monetary policies might need to step in directly via interest-rate channel or indirectly via macroprudential/microprudential tools changing its transmission. • Still, plenty of courage, luck and communication skills would be needed to succeed. VI. Policy Reactions to Credit Expansion Policy reaction to credit expansion • Prior to crisis some central banks believed in bening neglect scenario while some other viewed credit dynamics as a risk (especially these with foreign currency lending and large external deficits). • Potential impact of lending boom on quality of banks’ balance sheets is hard to assess: • new loans tend to dilute the old loans including the bad ones, • vulnerability indicators are thus strongly lagging. • The risks were not ignored by the authorities, some countries even adopted prudential, supervisory and administrative measures: • special reserve requirements for foreign exchange liabilities, • marginal reserve requirements based on credit growth, • higher liquidity requirements on foreign exchange liabilities, • tighter capital requirements related to foreign currency lending, • increasing the risk weighting of housing loans in capital, adequacy calculations. Policy reaction to credit expansion Policy reactions to fast credit growth in the EU economies Countries with fixed/ pegged exchange rate BG EE LT LV Monetary policy tools: Interest rate increase Reserve requirements Regulatory measures: Higher risk weights Restrictions on LTV Provisioning rate Tighter regulation on higher risk/large exposures Quantitative restrictions on lending growth Limits on inclusion of bank profits into capital Rules on collateral value of mortgage backed covered bonds Administrative measures: Eligibility criteria for borrowers Restrictions on payment-to-income ratio Introduction of first down-payment III & XI 2004; VII & XI 2006; III & V 2007 Source: ECB 20042008 2004; VII 2004; I 2005; 2005; X 2006 V 2002 XII 2005; V 2006 VII 2007 X III 2006 II 2007 I 2008 IV 2006 VII 2007 XI 2005 I 2008 Euro area countries CY ES GR IE VI 2006 V 2008* I 2005 I 2007 V 2009; III 2010 II 2004 SI X X I 2006; I 2007 XI 2003; VII 2007 2006 XII 2007 IV 2005 XII 2006 IV 2005 I 2008 XII 2007 X VI 2010 IX 2007 II 2004; VIII 2005 X XII 2005 VII 2007 VII 2008 II 2006 MT IX 2006 IV 2006 Submition of income statement from State Revenue Service Tighter rules on taxes related to real estate transactions and governmentsubsidised mortgage conditions Guidelines/recommendations for banks or customers Countries with floating exchange rate HU PL RO 2003; 2004 X 2006 IV 2006 2003; 2004 X I & VII 2007 VIII 2008 2003; 2009 2004 VIII 2006 Policy reaction to credit expansion Policy reactions to fast credit growth in various economies Source: ECB Source: Borio and Shim (2007) Policy reaction to credit expansion CNB‘s list of potential policy reactions (1) Monetary policy tools o Hike in policy interest rate o Increase in minimum reserve requirements o FX interventions in appreciation direction Regulatory tools o Introduction of marginal reserve requirements selective for various ways of financing o Increase in risk weights for loans collateralized by real estate, for loans with higher LTV or for loans extended without an income check o Direct regulation of LTV – setting the limit for mortgage loans – for individual loans or for the whole portfolios o Instruction of higher provisioning to the NPLS according to the days overdue or setting the filters according to supervisory and accounting provisioning o Higher provisioning for large exposures or higher capital requirements for more risky loan segments o Reduction of possibility to add current year profit to regulatory capital o Increased limit of excessive collateral for covered bonds o Direct or indirect pressure for keeping higher capital adequacy o Specific requirements for liquidity buffers for selected sources of funding (especially sources from abroad). Policy reaction to credit expansion CNB‘s list of potential policy reactions (2) Administrative tools oTightening of eligibility criteria for borrowers – through on-site inspections or via stricter stress testing of individual applications for mortgage loans oIntroduction of restrictions on installment to income ratios oSetting the minimum share of downpayment when using mortgage loan for buying real estate (de facto different way of LTV regulation) oRequirement to substantiate the income by government acknowledgment if high mortgage loan is applied for oRecommendations and warnings towards bank customers Macroprudential tools of „built-in“ sort oThe change in regulation of provisions in a pre-emptive direction (through-the-cycle provisioning or other form for building a buffer in good times) oThe change in capital regulation making banks build capital buffers or reserves in good times. Strenghtening of coordination of fiscal and other government policies oStricter tools of taxing the real estate (for 2nd and further ownerships), removal of tax deductability of interest on mortgage loans (regulator pressures on the government) oReduction of government expenditures aimed at reducing the optimistic expectations and preventing overheating in boom times oJoint campaign of central bank, supervisor and government aimed at explaining risks of excess borrowing oRestrictions on capital mobility and introduction of transaction taxes on selected foreign finance flows Policy reaction to credit expansion • These measures were not fully supported by the international community in the „old“ days. • IMF World Economic Outlook (September 2005, p. 13): • "in cases where house price inflation remains robust, a combination of moral suasion and if necessary prudential measures could help limit potential risks; over the long term, regulatory features - including those that potentially constrain supply - that may exacerbate price pressures need also to be addressed"…. • prudential measures: higher and differentiated capital requirements, tighter loan classification and provisioning rules, dynamic provisioning to dampen cyclical fluctuations in lending activity, stricter assessment of collateral, tighter eligibility criteria for certain loans (like loan-to-value ratio); • supervisory measures: increasing disclosure requirements, closer inspection, periodic stress testing. Policy reaction to credit expansion • Paul Hilbers, Inci Otker-Robe, and Ceyla Pazarbaşıoglu: Going too Fast? Finance & Development, Volume 43, Number 1, March 2006: • Prudential measures are not generally viewed as first best option. • „ … measures should be used when there are financial stability risks or when there is room to bring a country's prudential and supervisory framework in line with international best practice. That said, there are limits to what prudential policies can do in the absence of prudent fiscal policies or if monetary or fiscal regimes create incentives that encourage credit growth.“ • „The ability to further tighten prudential and supervisory policies varies across the CEE countries. In many of them, the frameworks have been strengthened, meaning there may be limited room for further tightening.“. Policy reaction to credit expansion in reality • During the last decade micropolicies were increasingly difficult to apply in reality. The experience suggests that the EU and international regulatory framework presents tough limits for national macroprudential discretions. The existence of the limits is indicated by the findings that the instruments now viewed as macroprudential ones were used in the last decade much more frequently in emerging market economies than in developed countries (see for example CGFS, 2010). • It means that for the especially for EU economies, some tools were not and can still not be available due to the potential non-compliance now (after all, nowadays appraised dynamic provisioning applied in Spain was declared as non-compliant prior to the crisis, see Saurina, 2009). • Restrictions imposed on local banks were got around by providing loans directly from parent banks. And on some occasions the non-bank institutions (even these set by the banks) took the part of the restricted banks. Policy reaction to credit expansion • We were also quite sceptical – we viewed various recommendations as dispensing advice from on high – advise of rather limited value. • „Measures“ are difficult to apply in reality due to competition from non-banking subjects and foreign banks and their local branches. • Basel II rules together with the international accounting standards made the application of some nonstandard measures not so easy. • High demand for credit was linked to international macroeconomic environment, macroeconomic-policy approach should therefore be attempted. • Distortive administrative regulations surely have undesirable side effects. They are harming newcomers to the market, may create perverse incentives for banks to bias their lending into riskier ends of the lending spectrum. • Temporary success of „measures“ can conceal real sources of problems. VII. Links between monetary policy, financial supervision and financial stability in a small open economy – the CNB case Monetary policy, exchange rate and financial stability • There is an old “truth” that central bank will do its best by focusing its monetary policy instruments on achieving its macro goals, while using its regulatory, supervisory and lender-of-last resort powers (micro policies) to help ensure financial stability. • CNB‘s approach was somehow different – reflection of specific features of small and converging economy. • Monetary policy worked also against the potential sources of financial instability. If real appreciation pressures emerge, tightening of monetary conditions via stronger currency should be viewed as a potential way of slowing the growth of optimism in the economy down. • At the same time, the authorities should be ready to use their regulatory and supervisory powers for macroeconomic stabilization providing the monetary tools lack the effect. Correcting macroeconomic imbalances would also reduce the risks for financial stability. Monetary policy, exchange rate and financial stability • Due to the fact that the major central banks were keeping policy rates at a very low level after September 11, in the face of appreciation pressures, the Czech National Bank naturally had to keep its policy rate also at a similar or even a lower level. • Your first impression might be that such a policy must lead to a credit boom. In reality this policy has served more as a shield against the risks coming from the external environment. • There was no best solution – low interest rates could support credit boom while high interest rate would create risk of even much faster appreciation and deterioration of external imbalance. • We opted for second best solution – low interest rate environment combined with sustained „mild“ nominal currency appreciation. • It may sound as a strange idea to use policy of low interest rates in small emerging economy to shield country from risks stemming from developed countries policies. But monetary scene in recent years has been strange indeed. Monetary policy, exchange rate and financial stability • Sustained nominal appreciation of the Czech koruna has served as a key stabilization „tool“ after 2001 in a following way: • Besides the downside impact of currency appreciation on inflation, reaction of private agents to it contributed to the flexibility of the economy. • The CNB was explaining that these were the global pressures behind nominal appreciation that a small economy could not avoid. • The public gradually accepted the idea that exchange rate is not something that the central bank should try to manage. • Exporters and their workers gradually adjusted to the appreciation trend: • The exporters factored in future development of ER into their expectations. • The labour unions realized that currency appreciation improves the purchasing power of workers’ wages which helped to discipline the wage dynamics. Monetary policy, exchange rate and financial stability • Combination of currency appreciation and low interest rates environment helped to maintain financial stability. • Sustained appreciation worked against the formation of overly optimistic expectations in the corporate sector which tamed the potential for a corporate sector credit boom. • Currency appreciation was also shifting part of existing domestic demand from nontradeables to tradeables along the long-term trend towards higher consumption of non-tradeables, contributing to a more balanced macroeconomic and structural dynamics. • Households did not have any incentive to borrow in foreign currencies which had made their balance sheets insulated from exchange rate risk. • Households had strong incentives to save and deposit in domestic currency. Monetary policy, exchange rate and financial stability • The Czech case confirms that the key driver behind demand for foreign currency loans is differential between lending rates in home and foreign currency. • Fixed exchange rate regime is what drives people to ignore the exchange rate risk. • The share of FX loans provided to households is the lowest in two countries with a history of profound and sustained nominal currency appreciation - Czech Republic and Slovakia. • This is despite the fact that taking a loan in foreign currency if the domestic currency appreciates is ex post „cheaper“. • The effect might go via currency denomination of deposits - currency structure of borrowing must be linked to the one of saving. If people have long-term incentive to save in domestic currency, they will also view as natural to borrow in it. Foreign currency loans – interest differential is what matters • Number of EU countries tried to do something, while the CR not – we won anyway. Countries with fixed/pegged exchange rate BG EE LT LV Countries with floating exchange rate HU PL RO Euro area countries AT CY GR SI III 2007 VII 2006; XII 2007 Monetary policy tools: VIII 2004; VIII 2005; I & III 2006 Higher reserve requirements on bank liabilities in FX Regulatory measures: Higher risk weights V 2008*; V 2009 I 2008 Higher provisioning rate Restrictions on LTV for FX loans IX 2005 III 2010 Quantitative restrictions on FX lending Administrative measures: Eligibility criteria for borrowers IX 2005 VI 2010 Restrictions on payment-toincome ratio Guidelines/recommendations for banks or customers Source: ECB X VIII 2008 I 2007; VII 2007; IX 2006 X 2008 VII 2006 X 2003; X 2008 XI 2006 Thank You for Your Attention Contact: Financial Stability Department in the CNB: financial.stability@cnb.cz CNB: Financial Stability Reports, various issues available at http://www.cnb.cz/en/financial_stability/ Jan Frait Financial Stability Dept. Czech National Bank Na Prikope 28 CZ-11503 Prague Tel.: +420 224 414430 E-mail: jan.frait@cnb.cz References • • • • • • • • • • • BANK OF ENGLAND (2009): The Role of Macroprudential Policy. Discussion Paper, November 2009. BIKKER, J. A., METZEMAKERS, P. A. J. (2003): Bank Provisioning Behaviour and Procyclicality, DNB Staff Reports No. 111, De Nederlandsche Bank BORIO C., FURFINE C. AND LOWE, P. (2001): Procyclicality of the fi nancial system and financial stability: issues and policy options”, in “Marrying the macro- and microprudential dimensions of financial stability”, BIS Papers, No. 1, March, pp. 1–57 BORIO, C – SHIM, I. (2007): “What can (macro)-prudential policy do to support monetary policy. BIS Working Papers, no 242, December. BORIO, C. - P. LOWE, P. (2001): To provision or not to provision. BIS Quarterly Review, September 2001, pp. 36-48. BORIO, C. - WHITE, W. (2004): Whither monetary and financial stability? The implications of evolving policy regimes. BIS Working Paper, No. 147, February 2004. BORIO, C. (2003): Towards a macroprudential framework for financial supervision and regulation? BIS Working Paper, No. 128, February 2003. http://www.bis.org/publ/work128.pdf. BORIO, C. (2009), Implementing the macro-prudential approach to financial regulation and supervision, Banque de France Financial Stability Review, No. 13 — The Future of Financial Regulation, September 2009. BORIO, C.-DREHMANN, M. (2009), Towards an operational framework for financial stability: fuzzy measurement and its consequences. BIS Working Paper, No. 284, June 2009. BRUNNERMEIER, M. et al. (2009): The Fundamental Principles of Financial Regulation. Geneva Reports on the World Economy 11. International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies, January 2009 CARUANA, J. (2005): Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Asset Prices. Banco de Espaňa, Documentos Ocasionales No. 0507/2005 References • • • • • • • • • • CEBS (2009): Position paper on a countercyclical capital buffer. 17 July 2009. http://www.cebs.org/getdoc/715bc0f9-7af9-47d9-98a8-778a4d20a880/CEBS-position-paper-on-a-countercyclical-capital-b.aspx CGFS (2010): Macroprudential instruments and frameworks: a stocktaking of issues and experiences. Report published by the Committee on Global Financial Systems, BIS, May 2010. CLEMENT, P. (2010): The term “macroprudential”: origins and evolution. BIS Quarterly Review, March 2010, pp. 59-67 DE LIS, F.S. - MARTINEZ PAG´ES, J. - SAURINA, J. (2003): Credit growth, problem loans and credit risk provisioning in Spain. BIS Papers no. 1, pp. 331–353. DIAMOND, D - DYBVIG, P. (1983): Bank runs, deposit insurance and liquidity”, Journal of Political Economy, 91(3), pp 401-19. DREHMANN, M. et al. (2010): Countercyclical capital buffers: exploring options. BIS Working Papers No 317, July 2010 FRAIT, J., KOMÁRKOVÁ, Z. (2009): Instruments for curbing fluctuations in lending over the business cycle. Financial Stability Report 2008/2009, Czech National Bank, pp. 72-81. FRAIT, J.-KOMÁREK, L.: Monetary Policy and Asset Prices: What Role for Central Banks in New EU Member States? Prague Economic Papers, Volume XVI, No. 1, 2007, pp. 3-23, ISSN 1210-0455 GERŠL, A., JAKUBÍK, P. (2010): Procyclicality of the financial system and simulation of the feedback effect. FSR 2009/2010, CNB, pp. 110-119. GORDY, M. – HOWELLS, B. (2006): Procyclicality in Basel II: Can we treat the disease without killing the patient? Journal of financial Intermediatin, 15, 395-417. References • • • • • • • • HLAVÁČEK, M., KOMÁREK, L. (2009): Housing Price Bubbles and their Determinants in the Czech Republic and its Regions. CNB WP 12/2009. JIMÉNEZ, G. – SAURINA, J. (2006): Credit Cycle, Credit Risk, and Prudential Regulation. International Journal of Central Banking, Vol. 2, No. 2, pp. 65-98 MANN, F. - MICHAEL, I. (2002): Dynamic provisioning: issue and application. Financial Stability Review, Bank of England, December 2002. SAURINA, J. (2009): Loan loss provisions in Spain. A working macroprudential tool, Revista de Estabilidad Financiera, 17, Bank of Spain, pp 11–26. TARULLO, D. (2008): Banking on Basel - the Future of International Financial Regulation. Institute of International Economics, October 2008, http://www.petersoninstitute.org/publications/briefs/tarullo4235.pdf WHITE, W. (2006): Procyclicality in the financial system: do we need a new macrofinancial stabilisation framework?, BIS Working Papers, no 193, January. WHITE, W. (2009): Should Monetary Policy "Lean or Clean"? Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute, Working Paper No 34 (August 2009). WOODFORD, M. (2010): Inflation Targeting and Financial Stability”. Presentation at the conference “The Future of Monetary Policy,” EIEF, Rome, September 30-October 1, 2010. http://www.columbia.edu/~mw2230/EIEF10_slides.pdf