Income inequality and health S V Subramanian Harvard School of Public Health Acknowledgements: Ichiro Kawachi January 6, 2006 PURE Steering Committee and Operation Meeting Dubai, UAE Income inequality: some facts S V Subramanian 2 World inequality S V Subramanian Source: UNDP, 2005, Human Development Report 3 World inequality trend Source: Milanovic B, World Apart: international and world inequality S V Subramanian 4 What is driving global income inequality? • Largely between-country (rather than withincountry) • BUT, within country contribution not trivial – Of the 73 countries for which data are available, 53 (80% of the world’s population) have seen inequality rise, while only 9 (4% of the population) have seen it narrow. S V Subramanian 5 Income distribution in the US S V Subramanian 6 Is this news? Sources: 1947-79: Analysis of U.S. Census Bureau data in Economic Policy Institute, The State of Working America 1994-95 (M.E. Sharpe: 1994) p. 37.; 1979-2001: U.S. Census Bureau, Historical Income Tables, Table F-3 S V Subramanian 7 S V Subramanian 8 So what? • Economic residential segregation • Crime and rising prison population • Drag on economic growth • Erosion of social cohesion • Worse health status? S V Subramanian 9 Income and health: a typology • Absolute or Relative • Individual or Community S V Subramanian 10 Income and health: absolute and individual interpretation hi f ( yi ) • Where hi is an individual’s level of well-being (for example, years of life), and yi refers to that individual’s own level of income. • The relationship between individual income and individual health is concave, i.e., a $ increase is accompanied by relatively small or even no improvement in health, beyond a particular level of income. S V Subramanian 11 Concavity effect y2 Health y1 x1 S V Subramanian x2 x Income x3 x4 12 Income and health: relative and individual interpretation • Inspired by the concept of relative deprivation formulated by Runciman (1966). It is “the extent of the difference between the desired situation and that of the person desiring it”. • “…we can roughly say that A is relatively deprived of X when (i) he does not have X, (ii) he sees some other person or persons, which may include himself at some previous or expected time, as having X (whether or not this is or will be in fact the case), (iii) he wants X, and (iv) he sees it as feasible that he should have X.” (Runciman 1966) (p.10)” S V Subramanian 13 Income and health: relative and individual interpretation hi f ( yi yr ) • Where health of an individual is a function of the term (yi-yr ) that denotes the relative gap between an individual’s income, yi, and the income of some reference population, yr . The reference population could be the income of co-workers, neighbors, or the national population. S V Subramanian 14 Income and health: absolute and community interpretation hij f (Y j , yij ) • Health of an individual i in community j is a function of their own income (yij) AND the average income levels of community (Yj) in which the individuals reside. S V Subramanian 15 Income and health: relative and community interpretation hij f ( I j , yij ) • Where Ij refers to a summary measure of income distribution (e.g., Gini coefficient) for the community in which the individual resides. S V Subramanian 16 Pollution effect Life expectancy Effect of income redistribution Income S V Subramanian 17 Income inequality hypothesis: intrinsically multilevel hij f ( I j , yij , ( yij yrj ), Yij ) Health of an individual in a community Community Income inequality Individual Absolute income Individual Relative income Community Absolute income For substantive and technical reasons, we need a multilevel regression approach to estimate the above. S V Subramanian 18 What does the evidence using multi-level data-sets suggest? S V Subramanian 19 Detectable patterns in US studies • Positive studies – US states – Wide range of outcomes – Larger samples • Null studies – US counties/metropolitan areas – Smaller samples S V Subramanian 20 Conditions OR 95%CI No individual income effect 1.32 (1.19-1.46) Linear effect of income 1.31 (1.18-1.46) Income transformed into log 1.30 (1.17-1.45) Non-linear (2nd order polynomial) 1.31 (1.17-1.45) Income as deciles 1.29 (1.15-1.43) Income as quintiles 1.29 (1.16-1.44) Income as categories 1.30 (1.17-1.45) OR for Gini based on 0.05 (5%) change in Gini; Note: All models additionally controlled for individual age, sex, marital status, race, years of education, covered by health insurance and state median income. *The equivalized household income categories were as follows: above $75,000: reference, $50,000-75,000, $30,000-50,000, $15,000-30,000, below $15,000. S V Subramanian 21 Conditions OR 95%CI Baseline 1.57 (1.39-1.78) + State median income 1.50 (1.34-1.67) + Age 1.53 (1.37-1.71) + Sex 1.52 (1.36-1.70) + Marital Status 1.51 (1.35-1.69) + Race 1.42 (1.27-1.57) + Years of Education 1.34 (1.21-1.48) + Equivalized household income 1.30 (1.17-1.45) + Health insurance 1.30 (1.17-1.45) OR for Gini based on 0.05 (5%) change in Gini S V Subramanian 22 Detectable patterns in non-US studies • Mostly null, BUT – ALL countries studied thus far are FAR more egalitarian (Sweden, Denmark, Japan, UK) than the US – ALL countries studied are also centralized states, thus raising the issue related to the relevance of a chosen unit of aggregation • Is US an exception; what about societies more unequal than the US? S V Subramanian 23 Income inequality and health in Chile Odds Ratio for poor health 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.22 1.2 1.21 1.17 1.1 1 1 0.9 less than 0.4 (Reference) 0.4 to 0.45 0.45 to 0.50 0.50 and above Com m unity Gini Coefficients Source: Subramanian et.al., 2003 S V Subramanian 24 Income inequality and health in India 1.4 1.3 OR (95% CI) 1.2 1.19 1.11 1.1 1.1 1.05 1 1 0.9 <18.5 18.5-22.9 23-24.9 25-29.9 ≥30 Body Mass Index Source: Subramanian, Kawachi, Davey Smith (Unpublished) S V Subramanian 25 Mechanisms linking income inequality and health • • • S V Subramanian Access to material resources Relative comparisons Social cohesion and social capital 26 Evidence for RD explanation? • Defining reference groups using combinations of state, race, education, and age, Eibner and Evans (2005) found that high relative deprivation is associated with a higher probability of death, self-reported limitations, body mass index, risky health behaviors, and poor self-reported health. – No association between state mean income and the probability of death – One standard deviation (0.022) increase in the Gini coefficient is associated 8 percent increase in the probability of death. – Gini coefficient AND the relative deprivation measure positively related to mortality, but RD attenuates the coefficient associated with Gini. Eibner CE, Evans WN. Relative deprivation, poor health habits and mortality. Journal of Human Resources. 2005;40(3):591-620. S V Subramanian 27 For better or for worse the Gini is out of the bottle…. If recent global and national economic trends provide any indication, research on income inequality and its potential effects on health will probably be more, and not less, important. S V Subramanian 28 FOR (in the US) Authors, Year Source: Subramanian, Kawachi, 2004 Sample population Method Kennedy et al., 1998 205245 adults from 50 U.S. states Marginal Models Self-rated health Soobader and LeClere, 1999 9,637 white males from U.S. counties and tracts (n for counties and tracts not reported) Marginal models Self-rated health Blakely et al., 2000 279066 adults nested within 50 U.S. states Multilevel models Self-rated health Diez-Roux et al., 2000 81,557 adults nested within 50 U.S. states Multilevel models Hypertension, smoking, sedentarism, body mass index Kahn et al., 2000 8285 women from 50 U.S. States Marginal models Depressive symptoms, selfrated health Lochner et al., 2001 546,888 adults from 50 U.S. States Marginal models Mortality Subramanian et al., 2001 144692 adults nested within 39 U.S. states Multilevel models Self-rated health Subramanian et al., 2003 90,000 adults aged 45 and above nested within 50 U.S. states nested within 9 census divisions Multilevel models Self-rated health Subramanian and Kawachi, 2003 201221 adults nested within 50 U.S. states Multilevel models Self-rated health S V Subramanian Outcome 29 AGAINST (in the US) Authors, Year Sample population Method Outcome Fiscella and Franks, 1997 14407 adults from U.S. counties (n for counties not reported) Single-level regression Mortality Daly et al., 1998 About 6500 adults from U.S. states (n for states not reported) Single-level regression Mortality Mellor and Milyo, 2002 309135 adults aged 25-74 from U.S. states and metropolitan areas (n not reported) Marginal models Self-rated health Blakely et al., 2002 18547 respondents and adults nested within 232 U.S. metropolitan areas; and 216 counties Multilevel models Self-rated health Sturm and Gresenz, 2002 8,235 adults from U.S. metropolitan areas (n for metropolitan areas not reported) Marginal models Self-reports of 17 common conditions (e.g., arthritis, depression) Mellor and Milyo, 2003 309135 adults aged 25-74 from U.S. states Marginal models Self-rated health Source: Subramanian, Kawachi, 2004 S V Subramanian 30 Outside of the US Author, Year Sample population Method Outcome Support for income inequality hypothesis Gerdtham and Johannesson, 2001 40,000+ adults from Municipalities in Sweden (n for municipalities not reported) Marginal models Mortality No Jones et al., 2004 8720 adults nested within 207 UK constituency nested within 22 regions Multilevel models Mortality No Osler et al., 2002 25728 adults from parishes within Copenhagen city (n for parishes not reported) Single level regression Mortality No Shibuya et al., 2002 80899 adults from Japanese prefectures (n for prefectures not reported) Marginal models Self-rated health No Blakely et al., 2003 1391118 adults nested within regions within New Zealand (3 alternatives, n=14, n=35, n=73) Multilevel models All-cause and cause-specific mortality No Subramanian et al., 2003 98344 adults nested within 61978 households nested within 285 Chilean communities nested within 13 regions Multilevel models Self-rated health Yes Source: Subramanian, Kawachi, 2004 S V Subramanian 31 Gini coefficient • Most popular measure of inequality developed by the Italian statistician Corrado Gini (1912). • Typically used to measure income inequality, but can be used to measure distribution on any space. • The Gini coefficient is a number between 0 and 1, where 0 corresponds with perfect equality (where everyone has the same income) and 1 corresponds with perfect inequality (where one person has all the income, and everyone else has zero income). • Algebraically, the Gini is defined as half of the arithmetic average of the sum of the absolute differences between all pairs of incomes in a population, normalized to mean income. S V Subramanian 32 Lorenz curve • Developed by Max O Lorenz (1905) as a graphical representation of income distribution. • Portrays observed income distributions and compares this to a state of perfect income equality. • Graphical expression of verbal statements such as, "the bottom twenty percent of all households have ten percent of the total income“. • Shows, for the bottom x% of households, the percentage y% of the total income which they have. Typically, the percentage of households is plotted on the x-axis, the percentage of income on the y-axis. • The Lorenz curve is used to calculate the Gini coefficient. S V Subramanian 33 Lorenz & Gini Ratio of the area between the line of perfect equality and Lorenz curve is {A}, and the area underneath the Lorenz curve {B}. Expressed as a percentage or as the numerical equivalent of that percentage, which is always a number between 0 and 1. {A} {B} Gini index = A/(A+B) S V Subramanian 34