EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE EXACTIONS FOR THE FUTURE Timothy M. Mulvaney* INTRODUCTION The government practice of routinely attaching conditions, or “exactions,” to discretionary development permits is commonly traced to the rapid suburbanization that followed World War II. Local property taxes were insufficient to keep up with the infrastructure needed to accommodate this growth, so municipal governments turned to landowners for support. This resort to developer-financed infrastructure was unsurprising, for it was the developers who were generating the need for these improvements in the first place.1 Originally, state courts exclusively policed exactions in a manner quite deferential to public authorities, warding off only those egregious, indefensible abuses of this important land use tool. That model subsisted with relatively few complaints for several decades, as governments commonly employed exactions quite reasonably as an offset to the infrastructural burdens emanating from new development. However, beginning in 1987 amidst fears that such a discretionary power could be used in an exploitative fashion, a divided U.S. Supreme Court identified more stringent criteria for imposing exactions in the constitutional takings cases of Nollan v. California Coastal Commission2 and Dolan v. City of Tigard.3 Unlike any state court prior, the five-Justice majorities in these two cases demanded that the permitting entity prove that exactions bear an “essential nexus” to and “rough proportionality” with the development project’s impacts to avoid having to pay compensation under the Takings Clause. In this article, I consider how modern exactions might be different from their midtwentieth century predecessors, and quite possibly even different from those *Associate Professor of Law, Texas Wesleyan University School of Law. Thank you to Mark Fenster for helpful comments on the topic of this piece. 1 See, e.g., Mark Fenster, Takings Formalism and Regulatory Formulas: Exactions and the Consequences of Clarity, 92 CAL. L. REV. 609, 615 (2004) [hereinafter Takings Formalism] (“[I]ndividualized . . . exactions constitute a flexible, open-ended set of conditions that serve regulatory and persuasive functions by offering both to internalize at least some of the external costs of development and to make a proposed land use either sufficiently attractive or minimally unattractive to decision makers and the voting public.”); Molly S. McUsic, The Ghost of Lochner: Modern Takings Doctrine and Its Impact on Economic Legislation, 76 B.U. L. REV. 605 662 (1996) (“Many local governments have adopted development exaction programs which require a developer to expend resources on facilities or services for the public as a condition of obtaining a development permit.”). 2 483 U.S. 825 (1987). 3 512 U.S. 374 (1994). EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE contemplated in Nollan and Dolan two decades ago. The distinguishing feature of most intrigue here is the increasing propensity for exactions to take aim at development impacts that are not going to result immediately or in the near term, but rather those impacts that are anticipated to occur at some point further off into the future. An extensive look into the hundreds of reported lower court exaction takings cases reliant upon Nollan or Dolan reveals that where permittees challenge exactions as takings, some courts are finding these “exactions-for-thefuture” less constitutionally palatable—because of the delay between the imposition of the exactions and their curative effects—than exactions that respond to immediate or near term public harms. Below, Part I surveys the historical rise of exactions to situate their role in the context of modern land use planning. Part II defines and analyzes four dimensions of property—theory, space, stringency, and time—that are at issue in exaction takings jurisprudence. The Part draws on this four-dimensional model to isolate the temporal issue of focus here: assessing the relevance of the varying levels of delay between an exaction and the external public impact that exaction is intended to cure. Part III offers several instructive examples of modern disputes involving exactions-for-the-future. This account assesses takings cases involving exactions for: possible future street widening;4 expansion of pipe widths to accommodate future construction;5 the purchase of nearby oceanfront land for public use where the permitted seawall would facilitate erosion and ultimately destroy existing public access;6 a connector road to anticipated adjacent developments;7 and various infrastructural improvements assuming a “worst case scenario”—full build-out of the subdivided lots—where the applicant had no such immediate plans.8 For comparative purposes utilized in Part IV below, this sampling includes some decisions where courts held that an exaction-for-the-future does not amount to a taking, and others where courts reached the contrary conclusion. Part IV, the article’s core, explores what those decisions finding that exactionsfor-the-future constitute takings might reflect on a jurisprudential, theoretical, and normative level. The Part is divided in a manner that highlights four themes. First, judicial predisposition against exactions-for-the-future may expose a 4 McClure v. City of Springfield, 28 P.3d 1222, 1228 (Or. Ct. App. 2001); Goss v. City of Little Rock, 151 F.3d 861, 863 (8th Cir. 1998). 5 McClung v. City of Sumner, 548 F.3d 1219 (9th Cir. 2008). 6 Ocean Harbor House Homeowners Ass’n. v. Cal. Coastal Comm’n, 77 Cal. Rptr. 3d 432 (Cal. Ct. App. 2008). 7 Burton v. Clark County, 958 P.2d 343 (Wash. Ct. App. 1998). 8 Schultz v. City of Grants Pass, 884 P.2d 569, 573 (Or. Ct. App. 1994). EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE fundamental tension with the general direction of land use law towards comprehensive planning. This tension is evident via a relative analysis between the roles of planning in exactions-for-the-future cases and planning’s place in regulatory takings and “public use” jurisprudence. Second, the vitality of some jurisdictions’ apparent requirement that exactions bear immediate fruit seems equivalent to a near per se rule against using exactions to counter an extensive collection of public harms that pose quantification difficulties. Third, requiring in the course of a takings analysis that exactions demonstrate an imminent or nearterm response to a public problem perpetuates the longstanding vagaries at the boundaries of takings and due process review. It allows courts to conduct an assessment of not only the extent and distribution of an economic burden created by regulation—the traditional takings questions—but also the wisdom of the regulatory action itself. Fourth, imputing an immediacy criterion into exaction takings law signals a theoretical vision of private property as creating a barrier between individual interests and permissible government action that is even more significant than that espoused by the majority in the U.S. Supreme Court’s exaction takings cases. In Part V, I conclude that each of the themes identified in the previous Part arguably provides justification for eschewing any distinction between exactionsfor-the-future and more traditional exactions; indeed, they may lend support to the claim that exactions in general should be treated no differently than other regulatory acts. However, to the extent that, in select jurisdictions, exactions-forthe-future will be looked at with disdain in the context of landowners’ takings suits, I present several “second-best” alternatives for local governments that may warrant consideration moving forward. I. THE PRELUDE TO EXACTION TAKINGS Throughout the 19th century and leading up to the Great Depression, one could argue that subdividing land required only a whim, a pen, and a map.9 The increased infrastructural burdens that resulted from an overabundance of subdivided lots dotting the landscape outside city centers were left either to the governing municipality or the developer. Neither were equipped or motivated to provide public improvements in many instances.10 The excess of subdivided lots led to vacancy and tax delinquency, depriving municipalities of the ability to incentivize commercial development with public infrastructural support.11 This 9 See R. Marlin Smith, From Subdivision Improvement Requirements to Community Benefit Assessments and Linkage Payments: A Brief History of Land Development Exactions, 50 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 5, 5 (1987). 10 Id. 11 Id. EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE phenomenon, in turn, impeded orderly growth, for it induced potential developers to skip over these blighted “dead lands” and carve out new subdivisions on the still farther outskirts of town.12 The Standard Planning Act of 1928 sought to, in part, respond to this problem. The Act counseled municipalities to condition land use approval on the developer providing necessities such as “streets, water mains, sewage lines, and other utility structures...” to cope with the increased infrastructural impact in the immediate area.13 These were the first routinely institutionalized exactions, and they typically only took the form of direct infrastructural enhancement; in other words, the first exactions were based on internal impacts the proposed development would be able to remedy on-site and in the near term.14 The Great Depression spurred this early practice of internal exactions, as other sources of infrastructure funding—ad volorem taxes and special assessments—went unpaid under the weight of the economic decline.15 The real estate community fought against these conditional requirements, but almost universally failed to sway the courts in their favor.16 By the middle of the 20th century, imposing mandatory internal exactions on subdividers and developers had become common practice, and additional requirements of an external nature were starting to appear among local governments in conjunction with the mass suburbanization that followed World War II.17 At this point in history, the scope of local government police power was increasing.18 In the 1950s, the U.S. Supreme Court acknowledged that the police power encompassed more than “public health, public safety, [and] morality,” but could also be used to make the “community…beautiful as well as healthy.”19 This reflected the growing trend towards imposing external exactions, which Id. at 5-6 (“new residential developments leapfrogged over … areas of dead land into unsubdivided lands lying beyond the old, moribund subdivisions”). 13 Jennifer Evans-Cowley, Development Exactions: Process and Planning Issues 3 (Lincoln Inst. of Land Policy, Working Paper WP06JEC1, 2006). 14 Id. 15 See Martin, supra note 11, at 6 (explaining a deteriorated cycle whereby incentives to pay special assessments—levied to construct physical improvements on subdivided parcels—arose only when the assessed lot had been improved, and foreclosure proceedings to reap these payments largely proved worthless because of the depreciation in land values). See also Vickie Been, “Exit” As a Constraint on Land Use Exactions: Rethinking the Unconstitutional Conditions Doctrine, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 473, 479 (1991) (suggesting that “exactions are an outgrowth of the centuries-old practice of levying ‘special assessments’…[for] in the 1920s and 1930s, widespread bankruptcies and delinquencies on special assessments… left many local governments unable to recoup the costs of public improvements”). 16 Martin, supra note 11, at 7. 17 See Evans-Cowley, supra note 15, at 3. 18 Id. 19 Berman v. Parker, 348 U.S. 26, 33 (1954). 12 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE broadened what could be done for the sake of public welfare.20 This scope was also broadened by the practical effect of federal and state funding cuts in the 1970s and 1980s to local governments for public projects, leaving exactions borne by the developer as an attractive option to the public when compared with the increased property taxes that they themselves would shoulder.21 Over the course of time, waste water facilities, schools, public parks, precinct houses, fire stations, and even day care services became public welfare projects that developers might be expected to help provide, most likely either through a dedication, an impact fee, or some hybrid between the two.22 As might be expected, developers fought vehemently against the expansion of exactions to include these types of off-site improvements, alleging inequities, inefficiencies, and general ineffectiveness in the piecemeal, ad hoc decisionmaking process of local land use permitting.23 This time, the landowners had some, albeit very limited, success.24 This success came in the form of state supreme courts imposing varying—though rarely stringent—constraints on local government use of exactions.25 Yet beginning with Nollan in 1987 and continuing with Dolan seven years later, the U.S. Supreme Court pronounced a marked shift away from judicial deference to municipal use of exactions. Nollan and Dolan call for a more stringent standard of review than most, if not all, state courts previously employed in the permit condition context.26 As explained in the following Part, however, these exactions takings decisions provide deficient or conflicting guidance on the multiple dimensions of the property interest at stake in exactions takings disputes. 20 See Evans-Cowley, supra note 15, at 3. Id. 22 Id.; Been, supra note 17, at 3-4. 23 See, e.g., Carol M. Rose, Planning and Dealing: Piecemeal Land Controls as a Problem of Local Legitimacy, 71 CALIF. L. REV. 839, 841-46 (1983) (“critics object most to the piecemeal changes in local land regulations [including]…the ‘conditional use permit’”); DUKEMINIER, ET AL., PROPERTY 1042 (6th ed. 2006) (“for local communities, enacting regulations is like printing money, because the legal restrictions can be relaxed in exchange for goods and services”). 24 See Martin, supra note 11, at 8. 25 Compare Hollywood, Inc. v. Broward County, 431 So. 2d 606, 611–12 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1983) (creating a deferential dual “rational nexus” test) and Associated Home Builders v. City of Walnut Creek, 484 P.2d 606, 615 (Cal. 1971) (requiring only a “reasonable” connection between permit conditions and anticipated project impacts), with Pioneer Trust & Sav. Bank v. Village of Mount Prospect, 176 N.E.2d 799, 801 (Ill. 1961) (demanding need for infrastructure-related condition be “specifically and uniquely attributable” to the project’s estimated impacts) and J.E.D. Assocs., Inc. v. Town of Atkinson, 432 A.2d 12, 15 (N.H. 1981) (adopting “uniquely attributable” test). 26 See, e.g., Timothy M. Mulvaney, The Remnants of Exaction Takings, 33 ENVIRONS ENVTL. L. & POL'Y J. 189, __ (2010). 21 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE II. EXACTION TAKINGS AND ISSUES OF TEMPORALITY In Nollan v. California Coastal Commission,27 the state did not meet its burden of proving that a condition requiring a beach access pathway bore an “essential nexus” to the impacts caused by the development.28 Seven years later, Dolan v. City of Tigard29 added an additional requirement to Nollan’s nexus test—it apparently compelled a town to prove that (a) the reduction in social costs attributable to Dolan’s dedication of a strip of land for flood control and a public bicycle path was “rough[ly] proportion[ate]” to (b) the reduction in social costs that the strip would provide to the public in offsetting flooding and traffic resulting from the development.30 Yet while the legal validity of any takings claims depends “upon what [one] consider[s] property, as a substantive matter, to be,”31 neither decision proved a beacon of clarity on this score. In a previous article,32 I illustrated these failings with the assistance of a model espoused by Laura Underkuffler.33 I will only briefly reiterate them here. Underkuffler asserts that property consists of four dimensions: theory, space, stringency, and time. The theoretical dimension involves a decision reflecting the incidents of ownership.34 The spatial dimension identifies those “objects,” or types of interests, to which the chosen theory of rights applies. 35 The stringency 27 483 U.S. 825 (1987). Nollan v. Cal. Coastal Comm’n, 483 U.S. 825, 828, 837 (1987). 29 512 U.S. 374 (1994). 30 Dolan v. City of Tigard, 512 U.S. 374, 391 (1994) (holding that “the city must make some sort of individualized determination” regarding the quantitative nature of the condition). In actuality, which variables are appropriate for comparison under Dolan’s “rough proportionality” analysis is not settled. See infra note __. 31 See UNDERKUFFLER, supra note __, at 18. See also Underkuffler-Freund, supra note __, at 165 (“Until we know what the property [interest] at stake is, it is impossible to evaluate whether it has been taken, or whether compensation for its loss should be paid.”). 32 Timothy M. Mulvaney, Proposed Exactions, 26 J. LAND USE & ENVTL. L. 277 (2011). 33 See LAURA S. UNDERKUFFLER, THE IDEA OF PROPERTY: ITS MEANING AND POWER 1533 (2003); Laura S. Underkuffler-Freund, Takings and the Nature of Property, 9 CAN. J.L. & JURISPRUDENCE 161, 16982 (1996). 34 See UNDERKUFFLER, supra note ___, at 16. This dimension requires a universal theory of individual rights (lest any idea of property be void of meaning). See also Susan Eisenberg, Comment, Intangible Takings, 60 VAND. L. REV. 667, 70203 (2007) (discussing the role of a universal theory for defining property rights). Such a theory could, for instance, be grounded in positivist notions of the law, historical understandings, ordinary meaning, custom, or reasonable and justified expectations. See UNDERKUFFLER, supra note __, at 1921. See also Jedediah Purdy, A Freedom-Promoting Approach to Property: A Renewed Tradition for New Debates, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 1237, 1239 n.9 (2005); Joseph William Singer, The Ownership Society and Takings of Property: Castles, Investments, and Just Obligations, 30 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 309, 31014 (2006) (describing conceptions of what “ownership” means to partially define property rights). 35 See UNDERKUFFLER, supra note __, at 21 (“If we choose, for example, the property holder’s ‘reasonable expectations’ as the theoretical dimension for our conception of property, the question arises: ‘reasonable expectations with respect to what?’ If we choose legal rules as the theoretical 28 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE dimension relates to the level of protection afforded to the identified private interest in light of competing societal interests.36 And the temporal dimension, at least according to Underkuffler, reflects whether, and the extent to which, property rights can be modified in light of evolutional societal change.37 dimension for our conception of property, the question arises: ‘legal rules as applied to what?’”). Underkuffler contends that the spatial dimension is relevant on both a conceptual and a geographic scale. See Underkuffler-Freund, supra note ___, at 171 (“The chosen theory of rights has meaning only with reference to a geographically or otherwise conceptually described field of application.”). The “parcel as a whole” debate in regulatory takings jurisprudence provides an appropriate example on the geographic scale. See Penn. Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104, 13031 (1978) (“‘Taking’ jurisprudence does not divide a single parcel into discrete segments and attempt to determine whether rights in a particular segment have been entirely abrogated. . . . [T]his Court focuses . . . on the nature and extent of the interference with rights in the parcel as a whole . . . .”); Keystone Bituminous Coal Ass’n v. DeBenedictis, 480 U.S. 470, 497 (1987) (supporting the statement in Penn Central that the extent of deprivation effected by a regulatory action is measured against the value of the parcel as a whole); Tahoe-Sierra Pres. Council v. Tahoe Reg’l Planning Agency, 535 U.S. 302, 331 (2002) (quoting Penn Cent., 438 U.S. at 130-31) (“in regulatory takings cases [the judiciary] must focus on ‘the parcel as a whole’”). But see Palm Beach Isles Assocs. v. United States, 208 F.3d 1374, 138081 (Fed. Cir. 2000) (declaring the relevant parcel to be the 50.7 regulated acres rather than the entire 311.7 acre parcel owned by the plaintiff); Loveladies Harbor, Inc. v. United States, 28 F.3d 1171, 1181 (Fed. Cir. 1994) (finding that the relevant parcel for takings purposes did not include portions of the parcel sold before promulgation of the regulation at issue). See also Marc R. Poirier, The Virtue of Vagueness in Takings Doctrine, 24 CARDOZO L. REV. 93, 110 n.65 (2002) [hereinafter Virtue of Vagueness] (“In a takings claim based on loss of value, the loss must be examined relative to a ‘before’ picture of what was initially at stake.”); James G. Titus, Rising Seas, Coastal Erosion, and the Takings Clause: How to Save Wetlands and Beaches Without Hurting Property Owners, 57 MD. L. REV. 1279, 1348 (1998) (“A setback of one foot . . . might deny all beneficial use to that first foot of land, yet barely impair the use of the remaining land.”). 36 UNDERKUFFLER, supra note __, at 25. For example, the Supreme Court, having on several occasions chosen a theory of rights grounded in the “bundle of rights” metaphor, has categorized the “right to exclude” as “one of the most essential sticks” in that bundle. Kaiser Aetna v. United States, 444 U.S. 164, 176 (1979). Necessarily, then, there must be sticks within that bundle that are afforded a lesser degree of protection than the right to exclude. See UNDERKUFFLER, supra note __, at 25. Indeed, the Court in another case seemingly acknowledged the same, stating that an ordinance limiting land to single-family dwellings does not “extinguish a fundamental attribute of ownership[.]” Agins v. City of Tiburon, 447 U.S. 255, 262 (1980) (citing Kaiser Aetna, 444 U.S. at 17980). Outside of the real property context, the stringency with which property rights are protected also might differ depending upon the kinds of objects at issue. For example, money is less protected than real property in light of its fungible nature. See, e.g., E. Enters. v. Apfel, 524 U.S. 498, 555 (1998) (Breyer, J., dissenting); United States v. Sperry Corp., 493 U.S. 52, 62 n.9 (1989). It also may differ in light of the different contexts in which ownership rights to a given object appear. For example, a chair with which one has a personal attachment because it is a family heirloom may be more protected than the same chair—from a physical standpoint—that is replaceable with one of equal value. UNDERKUFFLER, supra note __, at 27 (citing Margaret Jane Radin, Property and Personhood, 34 STAN L. REV. 957, 1007 (1982)). 37 See UNDERKUFFLER, supra note __, at 2930. If one chooses a theory of rights grounded in ordinary meaning, however, it is difficult to distinguish Underkuffler’s description of the theoretical dimension with that of the temporal dimension. This Article suggests that the temporal nature of property, particularly in exaction takings cases, consists of several important subelements that separate it from choices surrounding a theory of rights. See infra notes ____ and accompanying text. EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE It appears that, in Nollan, and, by affirmation, Dolan, the Court simultaneously selected two distinct theories of rights—one grounded in “ordinary meaning,”38 the other in the “bundle of rights” metaphor39—without delineating the contours of either theory or suggesting how any distinctions between the two might be reconciled. Similarly, the Court did not definitively interpret the spatial dimension of property rights in the exactions context; rather, it has sent only vague signals in identifying the categories of exactions to which the Nollan and Dolan paradigm apply.40 Only the stringency dimension of property was explicitly addressed in any detail: whatever theory of rights is utilized, in whatever conceptual space those rights apply, Nollan and Dolan command that the judiciary is to review any alleged infringement of those rights via an exaction with an intermediate level of scrutiny; that is, the government bears the burden of establishing compliance with the “essential nexus” and “rough proportionality” tests.41 And even within the stringency dimension, the precise nature of the nexus and proportionality tests remains subject to significant debate. See Nollan v. Cal. Coastal Comm’n, 483 U.S. 825, 831 (1987). Id. (internal citations omitted). 40 See City of Monterrey v. Del Monte Dunes at Monterrey, Ltd., 526 U.S. 687, __ (1999) (emphasizing that the Court “[has] not extended [the Dolan] standard beyond the special context of [the particular types of permit conditions at issue in Nollan and Dolan]”); Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A. Inc., 544 U.S. 528, 546 (2005) (asserting that Nollan and Dolan “began with the premise that, had the government simply appropriated the easement in question, this would have been a per se physical taking”). 41 For scholarly articles referring to the Nollan and Dolan threshold as a form of “intermediate scrutiny,” see, for example, Carlos A. Ball & Laurie Reynolds, Exactions and Burden Distribution in Takings Law, 47 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1513, 1516-17 (2006) (discussing academic debate on the benefits and burdens of applying the intermediate scrutiny required by Nollan and Dolan to exactions); Note, California Court of Appeal Finds Nollan’s and Dolan’s Heightened Scrutiny Inapplicable to Inclusionary Zoning Ordinance.—Home Builders Ass’n of Northern California v. City of Napa, 108 Cal. Rptr. 2d 60 (Cal. Ct. App. 2001), 115 HARV. L. REV. 2058, 205859 (2002) (discussing a California Court of Appeal’s refusal to apply intermediate scrutiny in accordance with Nollan and Dolan to exactions in support of inclusionary zoning); Charles M. Haar & Michael Allan Wolf, Euclid Lives: The Survival of Progressive Jurisprudence, 115 HARV. L. REV. 2158, 218487 (2002) (suggesting that, in Nollan and Dolan, the Rehnquist Court, “lowered the bar . . . for private property owners challenging government regulation of land” by calling for a more significant level of scrutiny than had previously been required in land use cases and placing the burden of proof on the defendant government); Fenster, Takings Formalism, supra note __, at 622 (“Nollan’s and Dolan’s ‘essential nexus’ and ‘rough proportionality’ tests require courts to apply heightened scrutiny to challenged land use regulations”); J. David Breemer, The Evolution of the “Essential Nexus”: How State and Federal Courts Have Applied Nollan and Dolan and Where They Should Go from Here, 59 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 373, 385 (2002) (citing Ehrlich v. City of Culver City, 911 P.2d 429, 439 (1996)) (discussing the need for application of the intermediate standard of scrutiny formulated by the Court in Nollan and Dolan to curtail the government’s abusive use of its discretionary land use and police powers); Otto J. Hetzel & Kimberly A. Gough, Assessing the Impact of Dolan v. City of Tigard on Local Governments’ Land-Use Powers, in TAKINGS: LAND-DEVELOPMENT CONDITIONS AND REGULATORY TAKINGS AFTER DOLAN AND LUCAS 219 (David L. Callies ed., 1996) (stating that Nollan and Dolan “clearly signaled the Court’s determination to provide greater protection for private property rights” through the application of intermediate judicial scrutiny); Andrew W. Schwartz, Deputy City 38 39 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE Not surprisingly, the content afforded by the Supreme Court to these first three dimensions has provoked a significant amount of critical legal scholarship.42 However, the temporal dimension has gone largely undetected within exactions jurisprudence, and, likely as a result, has not been fully explored in the academic literature. The content afforded property’s temporal dimension is important on several fronts. Nearly all takings disputes—regarding exactions or otherwise—at least implicitly involve the temporal inquiry posed in Underkuffler’s model: whether, and the extent to which, property interests may be refined in light of social, political, economic, scientific, or technological developments.43 Yet there are at least two other temporal issues surrounding property’s make-up that are particularly relevant in the realm of exactions. In that earlier article, I analyzed the first of these temporal issues: determining the point in time—be it upon the proposition or imposition of an exaction—when property’s other dimensions attach as to any particular permit applicant.44 I turn here to the second of these temporal issues: assessing the relevance of the varying levels of delay between an exaction and the external public impacts that exaction is intended to cure. Attorney, S.F., Cal., Address at Georgetown Univ. Law Ctr., Litigating Regulatory Takings Claims: The Application of Nollan/Dolan Heightened Scrutiny to Legislative Regulations and “Unsuccessful Exactions,” (Oct. 2829, 1999); Donald C. Guy & James E. Holloway, The Direction of Regulatory Takings Analysis in the Post-Lochner Era, 102 DICK. L. REV. 327, 346 (1998) (stating the Court’s nexus and proportionality tests represent the application of heightened judicial scrutiny). See also STEVEN J. EAGLE, REGULATORY TAKINGS § 7-10(b)(7) (3d ed. 2005). 42 See, e.g., supra notes ___ and accompanying text. 43 Compare Stop the Beach Renourishment, Inc. v. Fla. Dept. of Envtl. Prot., 130 S. Ct. 2592, 2610 (2010) (plurality opinion) (suggesting that a judicial change in the common law could amount to an unconstitutional taking even if that change is predictable), with Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 106970 (1992) (Stevens, J. dissenting) (“[O]ur ongoing self-education produces similar changes in the rights of property owners: New appreciation of the significance of endangered species; the importance of wetlands; and the vulnerability of coastal lands, shapes our evolving understandings of property rights.” (citations omitted)). 44 Mulvaney, Proposed Exactions, supra note __. In that piece, I offered three reasons to suggest that only upon the imposition of an exaction should the existing exaction takings construct attach as to any individual permit applicant: first, where a proposed exaction is refused or withdrawn, no property has been taken; second, judicial speculation on the substantive worth of hypothetical exactions suggests such matters are not suitable for review; and third, burdening governmental entities with possible takings liability for statements made during pre-decisional negotiation sessions places a chilling effect on regulator-landowner coordination. Id. at 30102. EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE III. RELYING ON EXACTIONS TO PREPARE FOR FUTURE CONTINGENCIES Several recent exaction takings cases have addressed claims of takings liability where the proffered exactions will not result in immediate or near-term improvements, but instead respond to an anticipated future harm. For comparative purposes utilized in Part IV below, this section identifies three examples of decisions hold that an exaction-for-the-future does not amount to a taking, before analyzing three that reached the contrary conclusion. A. A Sampling: An Exaction-for-the-Future Does Not Constitute a Taking In McClure v. City of Springfield,45 Robert and Sharon McClure owned a 25,700 square foot lot in Springfield, Oregon, bordered by 8th Street to the east and Main Street to the south.46 The McClures desired to divide their lot into three smaller lots: Parcel 1 would border 8th Street only; Parcel 2 would lie mostly west of Parcel 1, with a twenty-foot panhandle along the northern end of Parcel 1 to provide access to 8th Street; and Parcel 3 would mirror Parcel 2 to the south, with a similar twenty-foot panhandle along Parcel 1’s southern end to provide access to 8th Street.47 Main Street bordered the southern end of Parcel 3.48 The city’s planning director approved this partition request with several conditions. One such condition called for the dedication of a twenty-foot right-ofway along the southern edge of the property to allow for the future widening of Main Street.49 This proposed right-of-way along a portion of Parcel 3’s Main Street border would eliminate the proposed twenty-foot panhandle granting Parcel 3 access to 8th Street and cause Parcel 3 to front entirely upon Main Street.50 The McClures viewed the condition as an excessive, unconstitutional exaction.51 The city commission imposed the planning director’s proposed condition. However, Oregon’s Land Use Board of Appeals remanded the matter, ordering the city to demonstrate that the public cost of increased traffic on Main Street 45 175 Ore. App. 425, 436 (Or. Ct. App. 2001). Id. at 1223. 47 Id. at 1223-24. 48 Id. 49 Id. at 1224. The other conditions—which ultimately were deemed exaction takings under the Dolan standard—included the dedication of “a 10 foot by 10 foot triangular area on the southeast corner of the property to ensure adequate sight visibility and turning radius for the intersection at M[ain] and 8th streets” and “a five-foot strip along the 8th Street frontage to widen the 8th Street right-of-way for construction of a curbside sidewalk and street lighting, as well as sidewalk and street lighting improvements along 8th Street. Id. 50 Id. 51 Id. 46 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE caused by the McClures’ development was roughly proportional to the required dedication of the twenty-foot right-of-way.52 The city adopted additional findings to justify requiring the conditions,53 and the Land Use Board of Appeals ultimately upheld the dedication condition in a subsequent proceeding.54 The McClures appealed, arguing that the city’s evidence did not indicate that Main Street would ever be improved because the city had not acquired dedications from all of the other owners whose property abutted Main Street.55 The McClures insisted that since the city lacked all of the required dedications to expand Main Street, any benefits that the city claimed would stem from the McClures’ dedication would be illusory, at least in the near-term.56 The court responded to this contention by asserting that “[i]f each property owner could avoid an exaction because the city had not yet obtained all dedications necessary to improve the street, no improvement would be possible.”57 To this appellate panel, the timing of planned improvements to Main Street did not affect whether the proposed conditions withstood Dolan’s roughly proportionality strictures.58 The exaction at issue in Ocean Harbor House Homeowners Ass’n v. Cal. Coastal Comm’n59 did not involve future traffic accommodation but rather an assurance that the public could continue accessing a public trust resource after projected erosion eliminated an existing access way to it. Ocean Harbor House is a condominium complex on Del Monte Beach in Monterey, California.60 The Ocean Harbor House Homeowners Association (“Association”) employed several “soft” methods to combat higher-than-usual tides and coastal erosion that threatened its seaward buildings, but none of them proved adequate.61 To achieve more permanent protection, the Association sought permission from the California Coastal Commission (“CCC”) to construct a 585-foot seawall.62 52 Id. at 1224-25. Id. at 1225. 54 Id. at 1226. 55 Id. at 1228. 56 Id. 57 Id. 58 Id. 59 Ocean Harbor House Homeowners Ass’n v. Cal. Coastal Comm’n, 77 Cal. Rptr. 3d 432 (Cal. Ct. App. 2008). 60 Id. at 435. 61 Id. 62 Id. 53 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE The CCC prepared a report stating that the seawall ultimately would cause a loss of one acre of beach with attending loss of lateral beach access and recreational use.63 Though a California statute allowed seawalls to protect existing structures, the CCC report noted that no feasible method existed to mitigate the beach loss at that site with a seawall in place.64 To reconcile this conflict, the CCC report recommended granting the permit to build the seawall on the condition that the Association pays a mitigation fee, to be used for the purchase of beachfront property elsewhere for public recreational use.65 The CCC calculated that the beach in front of the Association’s buildings would erode at a rate of 870 square feet per year for fifty years, at which point the relevant portion of beach would be eliminated.66 It then estimated the recreational value of the beach per person and used that figure, combined with the rate of erosion, to set the cumulative recreational value of the beach until it completely eroded at $5.3 million.67 The Association brought suit against the CCC, arguing that the mitigation fee, which represented the cumulative value of the beach over fifty years, was an unconstitutional taking because there was no nexus or rough proportionality between the fee and the impact of the seawall.68 After the trial court concluded that the mitigation fee both shared a nexus and rough proportionality with the seawall, the Association appealed.69 In drawing a nexus between the mitigation fee and the seawall’s impact, the California appellate court emphasized the inevitability of beach erosion the seawall would cause.70 Because the resultant loss of recreational use would occur as the beach erodes, the court reasoned, a fee to increase recreational beach use elsewhere has a “logical tendency” to mitigate the problem.71 Although the Association could do nothing at its particular location to remedy the loss of public beach, it could alleviate the general loss of public beach through the fee.72 It bore little mind to this California appellate court that the public benefits of the exacted fee at issue rested on fifty years of foresight. As in McClure, this 63 Id. at 436. Id. 65 Id. 66 Id. 67 Id. at 437, 439. 68 Id. at 440. 69 Id. at 441. 70 Id. at 445. 71 Id. at 446. 72 Id. 64 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE temporal delay proved inconsequential to determining the exaction’s nexus or rough proportionality with the stated development impact. McClung v. City of Sumner73 represents a third case upholding an exaction-forthe-future in the face of a takings challenge. To combat considerable flooding it had experienced in prior years, the City of Sumner adopted an ordinance (the “diameter ordinance”) requiring all new developments to install storm pipes with a minimum of twelve-inch diameters.74 The city also developed a plan (the “trunk line plan”) for a storm drainage “trunk line” consisting of pipes even larger than twelve inches in diameter that ultimately would receive discharge from a series of future development sites and convey that discharge to an outfall.75 Daniel and Andrea McClung sought a permit from the city to (1) construct a Subway restaurant on their property, and (2) pave an alley behind the restaurant for parking.76 The alley already contained four feet of twelve-inch storm water pipes and 350 feet of six-inch pipes.77 The city requested that the McClungs replace all of the pipes with twenty-four-inch pipes to adhere to the city’s plans for the storm drainage trunk.78 As the requesting pipes would exceed the diameter ordinance’s minimum requirement, the city offered several concessions to offset the additional cost of the pipes.79 The McClungs accepted these concessions and developed their property with twenty-four-inch pipes.80 After construction had begun, the McClungs filed a complaint in Washington state court alleging that the city’s efforts to upgrade its storm drains through the trunk line plan amounted to a compensable taking.81 After a lengthy procedural history, the case made its way to the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit. The court ultimately held that the McClungs “contracted” for the twenty-four inch pipes by accepting the conditional permit and engaging in construction, and thereby waived their exaction takings claim.82 However, in dicta, the court implied that, had the McClungs challenged the exaction pre-construction, the fact that the twenty-four inch pipes would service anticipated but as yet un- 73 McClung v. City of Sumner, 548 F.3d 1219 (9th Cir. 2008). Id. at 1222. 75 Id. The city funded this trunk line plan in large part by increasing the stormwater general facility charge imposed on property owners. 76 Id. 77 Id. 78 Id. 79 Id. at 1223. These concessions included the waiver of permit and inspection fees. 80 Id. 81 Id. 82 Id. at 1229-30. 74 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE contemplated neighboring development would not affect the exaction takings analysis. B. A Sampling: An Exaction-for-the-Future Does Constitute a Taking In Burton v. Clark County,83 Lance Burton owned a 0.78-acre plot of land in a relatively undeveloped area outside of Vancouver, Washington. 84 The parcel adjoins existing subdivisions to the west and north, and high-voltage electrical transmission lines on the south.85 “A parcel of raw land,” owned by one Maddux, lay to the east.86 Burton proposed to subdivide his property into three wedge-shaped parcels for construction of a residential cul-de-sac. The county’s apprehensions with Burton’s project centered on traffic circulation and emergency vehicle access associated with “pocket neighborhoods” that lack access to adjoining developments.87 Northeast 65th Street runs east-west, and dead-ends into Burton’s western boundary.88 Northeast 20th Avenue runs north-south, and dead-ends into the northern boundary of Maddux’s property.89 Clark County planners had desired since the 1980s to connect the two roads by extending them across Burton and Maddux’s properties.90 The relevant portions of the county code stated: Where a public road has been created in such a manner as to be able to be extended …in accordance with adopted road plans….then: (1) All residences…shall be constructed in such a position on the property that they will not interfere with the extension of the roadway…to adjacent areas and shall be so situated that such extension will make orderly and planned development for additional road installations to meet the reasonable minimum requirements of good and safe traffic circulation…, and, (2) Right-of-way…necessary to such extension…and falling within parcels being developed, shall be granted or created as a condition of development approval.91 83 Burton v. Clark County, 958 P.2d 343 (1998). Id. at 345. 85 Id. at 34546. 86 Id. at 345. 87 See id. at 356. 88 Id. at 346. 89 Id. 90 Id. at 346 91 Clark County Code 12.05.370 (1998) (repealed by Sec. 1 of Ord. 1999-05-20). 84 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE In the case of Burton’s proposed development, the county specifically wanted to assure that, in the future, emergency vehicles responding to one of the homes in Burton’s area could quickly exit “if called to another emergency elsewhere.” 92 It produced a report estimating that Burton’s proposed development would generate an additional thirty automobile trips per day on the nearby roads. 93 Therefore, the county conditioned Burton’s approval on a 50 foot roadway dedication for the extension of Northeast 65th Street that, when ultimately connected to a projected future extension of Northeast 20th Avenue, would alleviate the county’s concerns.94 In effect, the county’s decision to impose the noted exaction supports the premise that, where a developer contributes to a changing landscape—here, the conversion of a rural area to an urban area—it is the developer’s onus to contribute in appropriate degree to curing the cumulative public problems associated with that conversion.95 After some procedural irregularities,96 the trial court ultimately re-instated an order of the county hearing examiner approving Burton’s short plat without the exacted road.97 The county, the trial court affirmed, had not demonstrated that the Id. at 356. According to the county hearing examiner, who rejected Burton’s initial appeal of the County’s exaction imposition, “[c]onnectivity [of streets] also reduces trip distances and thereby helps reduce pollution, makes it easier for pedestrians and bicyclists to go from one point to another more directly, and provides for less isolation between neighborhoods.” Id. at 349. 93 Id. at 350. Road impact fees and dedications are commonly upheld where the governmental entity establishes the fee based on the projected increase in motor vehicle trips associated with the new development. See, e.g., N. Ill. Home Builders Ass’n, Inc. v. County of Du Page, 621 N.E.2d 1012, 1017 (Ill. App. Ct. 1993); Home Builders & Contractors Ass'n v. Palm Beach County, 446 So. 2d 140, 142 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1984). 94 Id. (“When . . . the exacted road connects with Northeast 20th Avenue, it will tend to alleviate the identified public problems. Traffic will be able to circulate to the east as well as to the west; not all traffic will have to use the roads to the west; police and fire vehicles will be able to enter the neighborhood from either direction; and fire trucks will be able to exit the neighborhood without needing to turn around.”). 95 See, e.g., David M. Driesen, The Societal Cost of Environmental Regulation: Beyond Administrative Cost-Benefit Analysis, 24 ECOLOGY L.Q. 545, 59394 (1997) (identifying the commonality of regulatory officials failing to separate, and account for, incremental individual contributions to what ultimately amount to significant cumulative impacts). 96 Id. at 349350. 97 Where a court determines that the reviewed exaction violates Nollan and Dolan, it seems appropriate that the regulating entity should have the ability to choose among the assuredly many other conditions that would be enough to offset the development’s external effects. Mulvaney, Proposed Exactions, supra note __, at 305. But see William J. Jones Insurance Trust v. City of Fort Smith, 731 F. Supp. 912, 914 (W.D. Ark. 1990) (finding exaction takings liability and ordering the government “to issue the requested permit unconditionally”); St. Johns River Water Mgmt. Dist. v. Koontz, 5 So. 3d 8 (Fla. Ct. App. 2009) (finding exaction takings liability, and ordering that the government (a) pay compensation for the lost rent of his entire underlying parcel and (b) issue the permit the government had originally denied with only the applicant’s selfproposed permit condition attached thereto). 92 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE road conditions required by the county’s standards were justified in light of the impacts caused by Burton’s proposed development.98 Clark County appealed.99 The appellate court affirmed the trial court’s ruling in favor of Burton.100 The appellate court’s decision has been identified by several scholars supportive of limited governmental land use controls as a prescient presentation of what the cryptic nexus and proportionality standards of Nollan and Dolan actually mean.101 The court suggested that, in the context of conditioning land use permits, “Nollan, Dolan, and their Washington progeny stand for at least four propositions.”102 According to the court, Nollan and Dolan require the government to prove: (1) there is a public problem;103 (2) the proposed development will create or exacerbate that problem;104 (3) the exaction tends to alleviate that problem;105 and (4) by complying with the exaction, the developer will fix no more of that problem than he has created.106 According to the court: When combined, these four propositions boil down to two relationships: a relationship between the project and the identified public problem, and a relationship between the identified public problem and the proposed solution to that problem. … The ultimate goal is [for the government] to show that the … exaction … is reasonably related to all or part of an identified public problem that arises from … the development project. Unless the government makes this showing, it lacks a ‘legitimate state interest’ …in imposing the … exaction.107 The court found that the government had identified a public problem—traffic— “to at least a slight degree.”108 But it was concerned that the record failed to indicate “when, if ever, the road being exacted from Burton will extend across the 98 Burton, 958 P.2d at 350. Id. 100 Id. 101 See David L. Callies, Regulatory Takings and the Supreme Court: How Perspectives on Property Rights Have Changed from Penn Central to Dolan, and What State and Federal Courts Are Doing About It, 28 STETSON L. REV. 523, 570-71 n.309 (1999); David L. Callies & Glenn H. Sonoda; Providing Infrastructure for Smart Growth: Land Development Conditions, 43 IDAHO L. REV. 351 (2007); Richard Duane Faus, Exactions, Impact Fees, and Dedications—Local Government Responses to Nollan/Dolan Takings Law Issues, 29 STETSON L. REV. 675 (2000). 102 Burton, 958 P.2d at 353 103 Id. 104 Id. at 354. 105 Id. at 355. 106 Id. 107 Id. 108 Id. at 356. 99 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE Maddux’s parcel and connect with Northeast 20th Avenue.”109 This concern about speculative activity on the part of the government planners peculiarly spurred the court to engage in its own speculation: The court compared the effects of the exaction if the connector road ultimately is constructed versus the effects of the exaction if the connector road is never constructed.110 If the connector road ultimately is constructed, said the court, “it will tend to alleviate the identified public problems.”111 Furthermore, the court said Burton’s conferral of the easement would tend to alleviate those problems “in a way that is ‘roughly proportional’ to the project’s effect on those problems.”112 The court stated that even though Burton’s development will exacerbate the traffic circulation and emergency access problems to a small degree, the exaction represents “only a small part of the solution to those problems.”113 But if the road is never connected, the exacted right-of-way obviously “will lack any tendency to solve or alleviate any of the identified public problems.” 114 The court found the crucial question, then, to be just when the exacted roadway will extend across Maddux’s property.115 The appellate court “assume[d]” that the government “may sometimes rely on the future as well as the present when attempting to establish” the required nexus and proportionality between the impacts of the development and the relevant exactions.116 However, it also somewhat contradictorily asserted that the government “may not rely on the future unless the record furnishes a basis for inferring what the foreseeable future holds.”117 In probing the evidence for what the “foreseeable future” might hold, the court found insufficient a staff report stating that the exacted road “shall be surveyed and designed to eventually connect with Northeast 20th Avenue.”118 Yet at the same time, it noted that a statement from a planner that “‘infill’ parcels like Maddux’s are usually developed within a certain time after the urbanization 109 Id. Id. 111 Id. 112 Id. 113 Id. The court asserted that the solution to the identified problems is “the creation of an overall street grid as the area changes from rural to urban.” Id. It is not clear that the court selected the appropriate variables for conducting the comparison required by Dolan’s rough proportionality requirement. For a discussion on the variables appropriate for comparison in the course of a “rough proportionality” analysis, see infra note __. 114 Id. at 357. 115 Id. 116 Id. at 355 n.52. The court acknowledged, however, that the extent to which the government may rely on future events is “not well settled.” Id. 117 Id. at 355. 118 Id. at 357. 110 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE process starts” could be sufficient.119 With no such statement in the record, the court concluded that the exaction could amount to “a road to nowhere,” and thus violated Dolan’s proportionality test.120 Goss v. City of Little Rock121 involved a rezoning request by one Charles Goss. In September 1971, Goss purchased 3.7 acres in an unincorporated area outside Little Rock.122 Goss operated a convenience store, gas station, laundromat, and car wash on the premises since soon after that purchase.123 In 1985, Little Rock annexed an area that included Goss’s property.124 In accordance with the city code, the annexed area was classified for single-family residential use.125 However, the city permitted Goss to continue his operations pursuant to a nonconforming use exception.126 Still, he requested that the city rezone the property for commercial use to make it easier for him to sell it.127 The City of Little Rock denied this commercial rezoning request in light of the applicant’s refusal to dedicate a portion of his property for highway expansion as a condition thereto.128 This denial, according to the city, sought to protect the public from the increased traffic that would result from rezoning the property from its current residential-only classification.129 Both the District Court and the 119 Id. at 357 n. 60. Id. at 357. A small selection of state courts rejected exactions-for-the-future of a similar nature prior to Nollan and Dolan. See, e.g., Unlimited v. Kitsap County, 750 P.2d 651 (1988) (rejecting, pre-Dolan, an exaction where the government intended to hold the property “until undefined future time” when the anticipated roadway “can be extended to connect with other, as yet unbuilt, roads” and “[t]here is no expectation that the property that could use the anticipated roadway “is to be developed at the same time” as the applicant’s development); Simpson v. N. Platte, 292 N.W.2d 297 (1983) (rejecting, prior to both Nollan and Dolan, a condition requiring the provision of a right of way where “[n]o project was immediately contemplated whereby the street [which would be partially constructed on the right of way] would be constructed nor is there any evidence regarding what the particular project would involve”). The decision in Burton seems to sit in contrast with a Washington appellate court opinion handed down in Isla Verde International Holdings, Inc. v. City of Camas, 990 P.2d 429 (Wash. Ct. App. 1999) just one year after Burton. As one scholar describes it, the court upheld “a road dedication requirement for emergency vehicles in the absence of evidence concerning the cost of the road and its effects on the subject property.” Callies & Sonada, supra note __, at 363. Yet, peculiarly, two of the three judges that decided Burton also concurred in the holding in Isla Verde. Judge Dean Morgan authored Burton, an opinion in which Judge Karen G. Seinfeld joined. Burton, 958 P.2d at 345. Their roles simply were reversed in Isla Verde. 990 P.2d 429. 121 Goss v. City of Little Rock, 151 F.3d 861, 863 (8th Cir. 1998). 122 See Goss v. City of Little Rock, 90 F.3d 306, 307 (8th Cir. Ark. 1996). 120 123 124 125 126 127 Id. 128 129 Id. at 862. EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE Court of Appeals agreed that the traffic problem could be remedied by the requested dedication of land, assuming the dedication was in fact used to expand the highway presently adjoining Goss’s property.130 However, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Eighth Circuit affirmed a district court ruling that found the city’s proposed assessment of the impact of rezoning Goss’s property for commercial use “too speculative,” and thus violative of Dolan.131 The court derided the city for conditioning the rezoning request on alleviating traffic concerns, for any significant additional traffic would only be generated “at some unknown point in the future” if Goss’s buyer or his successors actually used the property as rezoned and erected a strip mall on the land.132 In Schultz v. City of Grants Pass,133 the petitioners submitted an application for a development permit to partition their 3.85-acre property in two.134 One lot would measure ninety-feet by two hundred and one-feet at the corner of Savage Street and Beacon Drive, while the other would consist of the land that remained.135 The city conditioned approval of the subdivision on the provision of several rights-of-way for public roads.136 The city reasoned that the division of the property would increase street use and, therefore, improvement and expansion of the streets was essential. 137 With respect to the extent of the dedications, the city pointed to the potential build-out of Schultz’s parcel to include the construction of twenty homes, as authorized under the city’s comprehensive community development plan.138 130 Id. Id. at 863. For an analysis of whether the exaction takings construct that is ordinarily applied when an exaction is imposed is also applicable at the point in time when, as in Goss, an exaction is merely proposed, see Mulvaney, supra note __. For purposes of discussing Goss herein, it is assumed that such an application is appropriate. 132 Id. Goss is a peculiar holding, for the court stated, “Little Rock has a legitimate interest in declining to rezone Goss’s property, and the city may pursue that interest by denying Goss’s rezoning application outright, as opposed to denying it because of Goss’s refusal to agree to an unconstitutional condition . . . .” Id. at 864. Thus, the court said that a taking occurred, but no remedy—compensation or otherwise—was due. Id. at 866. See also David L. Callies, Regulatory Takings and the Supreme Court: How Perspectives on Property Rights Have Changed from Penn Central to Dolan, and What State and Federal Courts Are Doing About It, 28 STETSON L. REV. 523, 570-71 n.309 (1999) (“[w]hile finding the highway dedication a taking, the court held the city could avoid any takings claims by simply refusing to rezone the subject property without the invalid dedication, pursuing its legitimate interest in declining to rezone property”). 133 Schultz v. City of Grants Pass, 884 P.2d 569 (Or. Ct. App. 1994). 134 Id. at 570. 135 Id. 136 Id. 137 Id. at 571. 138 Id. 131 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE As in Goss, while the court agreed that the city had established the sufficient nexus, it rejected the city’s position regarding proportionality. 139 The court criticized the city for establishing conditions based on anticipated impacts that could result from maximization of the property’s development potential.140 The court found nothing in the record to indicate that the petitioners intended to develop the property to its full potential in the near term. It declared that this “worst-case scenario” was improperly based only on “the city’s speculation as to what other construction could take place at some time in the future.”141 C. Summarizing the Exaction-for-the-Future Samples In sum, this Part has identified six examples where courts have faced takings claims challenging the imposition of exactions-for-the-future. The cases demonstrate the commonality of local government usage of exactions to counter development impacts beyond those expected to occur in the present or near-term. The disparate results on the takings question necessitate a deeper look into the jurisprudential, theoretical, and normative themes underlying those decisions that seemingly treat exactions-for-the-future as presumptively less constitutionally palatable than more traditional exactions. IV. EXACTIONS-FOR-THE-FUTURE AS TAKINGS: JURISPRUDENTIAL, THEORETICAL, AND NORMATIVE THEMES This Part explores four themes underlying those lower court decisions finding that exactions-for-the-future amount to compensable takings. First, judicial predisposition against exactions-for-the-future exposes a fundamental tension with the direction of land use law towards additional comprehensive planning. Second, the vitality of some jurisdictions’ apparent requirement that exactions bear immediate fruit arguably is equivalent to a near categorical rule against using exactions to counter a broad collection of public harms that pose precise quantification difficulties. Third, requiring in the course of a takings analysis that exactions demonstrate an imminent or near-term response to a public problem perpetuates the longstanding vagaries at the boundaries of takings and due process review. Fourth, incorporating an immediacy criterion into exaction takings law signals a theoretical vision of private property as creating a barrier between individual interests and permissible government action that is even more 139 Id. at 572. Id. 141 Id. (emphasis added). 140 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE significant than that espoused in the U.S. Supreme Court exaction takings decisions in Nollan and Dolan. A. Tension with Planning Demands Land use planning broadly guides property development by establishing the type and degree of allowable intensification of real property. It typically reflects a community’s long term vision, economic conditions, geography, and environmental resources. The existence of comprehensive planning in a given jurisdiction has long served as a basis for deference in regulatory takings cases.142 More recently, its import has been recognized in disputes surrounding whether an outright exercise of eminent domain is conducted for a “public use.”143 This section first surveys the impact of planning in these two areas of takings law. It then distinguishes the prominent role of planning in regulatory takings and “public use” jurisprudence from its peculiarly limited role in exaction takings case law and, in particular, in those cases involving exactions-for-the-future. i. Planning and Regulatory Takings The U.S. Supreme Court routinely has pointed toward governmental planning efforts in support of judicial deference to ordinary regulatory acts in regulatory takings disputes.144 This tack is no more evident than in the “polestar” of modern regulatory takings jurisprudence, Penn Central Transportation Co. v. City of New York.145 In dissent, then-Justice Rehnquist chided New York’s historic landmarks ordinance as singling out select property owners to bear the economic burdens of the public’s preservation ideals.146 Yet Justice Brennan’s opinion for the majority asserted that “New York City law embodies a comprehensive plan to preserve structures of historic or aesthetic interest wherever they might be found in the city.”147 The Penn Central Court went on to establish a multi-factor balancing test centered on the economic impact individual landowners bear in light of the reasonable expectations associated with their investment.148 In subsequent application, this test has proven quite deferential to the government, particularly 142 See infra notes __ and accompanying text. See infra notes __ and accompanying text. 144 Nicole Stelle Garnett, Planning as a Public Use?, 34 ECOLOGY L.Q. 443, 448 (2007). 145 Penn. Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104 (1978). 146 Id. at 147 (Rehnquist, J., dissenting). 147 Id. at 132. 148 Id. at 12428. 143 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE amidst evidence of comprehensive planning. For instance, in Tahoe-Sierra Pres. Council v. Tahoe Reg’l Planning Agency,149 planning efforts to preserve the water quality of Lake Tahoe proved central to the Court’s rejection of property owners’ claims that a thirty-two month development moratorium required the payment of compensation.150 Six Justices stressed the critical function of “interim development controls,” favorably citing “consensus in the planning community” that such devices “are an essential tool of successful development.”151 I am in the process of incorporating additional examples and analysis here. For the most up-to-date version of this section, or to provide comments or make suggestions of particularly apt examples, please contact the author at tmulvaney@law.txwes.edu. ii. Planning and “Public Use” There also is a significant body of U.S. Supreme Court takings jurisprudence outside the regulatory context, including a triumvirate of cases surrounding the Fifth Amendment’s command that the government shall not take private property “for public use” without providing just compensation.152 In the first of these cases, Justice Douglas wrote for a unanimous court that “blighted or slum area[s]…must be planned as a whole. . . . If owner after owner were permitted to resist[,] . . . integrated plans for redevelopment would suffer greatly.”153 In the second of the Court’s celebrated “public use” decisions, the Court—again, unanimously—upheld the condemnation of landlords’ reversions for the purpose of transferring them to tenants as part of a comprehensive “land reform” program aimed at breaking an oligopolistic land market.154 Planning took on increasing significance in the third installment of the Court’s public use jurisprudence in 2005 in Kelo v. City of New London.155 Justice Stevens’ opinion for the Court emphasized that the comprehensive nature of New Tahoe-Sierra Pres. Council v. Tahoe Reg’l Planning Agency, 535 U.S. 302, 331 (2002) Tahoe-Sierra, 535 U.S. 302 (2002). 151 Id. at 33839. 149 150 152 153 Berman v. Parker, 348 U.S. 26, 30 (1954) (upholding the National Capital Planning Commission’s condemnation of non-blighted department store building because of, in part, the comprehensive nature of the Commission’s redevelopment plan). 154 See Hawaii Hous. Auth. v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229 (1984). 155 Kelo v. City of New London, Conn., 545 U.S. 468 (2005). As one scholar notes, “The Kelo majority mentioned the words “plan” and “planning” forty times; Justice Kennedy’s separate opinion brought the tally to nearly fifty.” See Garnett, supra note __, at 444. EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE London’s planning process provided support for the finding that the condemnation of the residential properties at issue furthered a public economic redevelopment purpose.156 Justice Kennedy, who provided the deciding vote to uphold the city’s condemnation of residential properties for purposes of economic redevelopment, authored a separate opinion.157 This separate opinion—of considerable import for lower courts and litigants moving forward given the Court’s 5-4 split—arguably went even further than the majority with respect to the import of planning. Justice Kennedy suggested that planning very well may be the determining factor in separating presumptively impermissible government acts from valid public takings.158 While he would not engage in “conjecture” as to when such a presumption might apply, he explained his comfort with the conclusion that Kelo did not present such an instance.159 iii. Planning and Exaction Takings Given this consistent emphasis on land use planning in the U.S. Supreme Court’s regulatory takings and “public use” jurisprudence, it is surprising that any discussion of planning is mysteriously absent in the Court’s principal exaction takings cases of Nollan and Dolan.160 The Nollan majority makes no mention of the fact that the claimant purchased property in an area with an existing Id. at 48387 (“The City has carefully formulated an economic development plan that it believes will provide appreciable benefits to the community. … [A] one-to-one transfer of property, executed outside the confines of an integrated development plan would certainly raise a suspicion that a private purpose was afoot.”). 157 Id. at 49093. (Kennedy, J., concurring) 158 Id. See also Garnett, supra note __, at 444. Kennedy’s perspective echoes that of the Illinois Supreme Court’s opinion in Southwest Illinois Development Authority v. National City Environmental, 768 N.E.2d 1 (Ill. 2002). In that case, the Illinois Supreme Court rejected a proposed condemnation of land that would be used for parking as part of an alleged economic redevelopment plan. Id. at 10. The Court declared: The [Southwest Illinois Development Authority] did not conduct or commission a thorough study of the parking situation at Gateway. Nor did it formulate any economic plan requiring [the] additional parking …. Clearly, the foundation of this taking is rooted not in the economic and planning process with which the [Authority] has been charged. Rather, this action was undertaken solely in response to [a private company’s] expansion goals …. It appears [the Authority’s] true intentions were to act as a default broker of land for [that private company’s] proposed parking plan. Id. Southwest Illinois Development Authority provides the converse of W. Seafood Co. v. U.S., 202 F. App’x 670 (5th Cir. 2006), where the Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit rejected a landowner’s claim that the government’s asserted public purpose was pretextual because the government’s significant planning measures mirrored those of New London in Kelo. 159 Kelo, 545 U.S. at 493 (Kennedy, J., concurring) (“[T]his taking occurred in the context of a comprehensive development plan meant to address city-wide depression, and the projected economic benefits of the project cannot be characterized as de minimis.”). 160 But see Garnett, supra note __, at 450 (“When a property owner challenges a regulation as confiscatory, courts must … determine whether the government is asking owners to bear a disproportionate burden of providing public benefits [in the exactions context).”). 156 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE comprehensive government policy of requiring all similarly situated owners to facilitate the exercise of public trust rights by conferring a public walking corridor along the water’s edge as a condition to development.161 While the Dolan majority offered surface praise to long-term planning—“[c]ities have long engaged in the commendable task of land use planning …. The city's goals . . . are laudable…”162—it simultaneously ignored the longstanding judicial deference to the practice. The Dolan Court explicitly pronounced what was implicit in Nollan:163 it departed from the general rule applicable to zoning and other use restrictions that the burden properly rests on the party challenging the regulation to prove that it arbitrarily restricts a property right.164 Instead, the Court declared that the government bears the burden to justify the required exactions.165 The Dolan majority’s decision to abandon the traditional standard of deference afforded to local governments that have conducted considerable planning was not lost on Justice Stevens. In dissent, Justice Stevens asserted, “The Court has made a serious error by abandoning the traditional presumption of constitutionality and imposing a novel burden of proof on a city implementing an admittedly valid comprehensive land use plan.”166 iv. Planning and Takings Cases Involving Exactions-for-the-Future In those lower court decisions finding that exactions-for-the-future amount to takings, planning is not ignored, as largely occurred in Nollan and Dolan. Indeed, the lower courts’ consideration of planning in the Burton, Goss, and Schultz decisions outlined in the previous Part is quite explicit. It is, however, peculiar— these decisions actually demonstrate an affirmative aversion to long-term planning. In Burton, Clark County had identified the connector road on its comprehensive plan, and the development, as proposed, would eliminate the 161 David A. Dana, Land Use Regulation in an Age of Heightened Scrutiny, 75 N.C. L. REV. 1243, 1263-65 (1997). 162 Dolan v. City of Tigard, 512 U.S. 374, 396 (1994). 163 Fenster, Takings Formalism, supra note __, at 627 (explaining that Nollan did not affirmatively indicate that it was shifting the burden of proof to the government). 164 See Dolan, 512 U.S. at 405 (Stevens, J., dissenting) (“The Court has made a serious error by abandoning the traditional presumption of constitutionality and imposing a novel burden of proof on a city implementing an admittedly valid comprehensive land use plan.”). 165 Id. at 391, n.8 (“Justice Stevens’ dissent takes us to task for placing the burden on the city to justify the required dedication. He is correct in arguing that in evaluating most generally applicable zoning regulations, the burden properly rests on the party challenging the regulation to prove that it constitutes an arbitrary regulation of property rights. Here, by contrast, the city made an adjudicative decision to condition petitioner’s application for a building permit on an individual parcel. In this situation, the burden properly rests on the city.”). 166 See id. at 405 (Stevens, J., dissenting). EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE possibility of that road ever being constructed; in Goss, the landowner could continue personally operating his commercial outfit only in light of the City of Little Rock’s decision to grandfather this use despite its non-conformance with a longstanding city-wide scheme; and, in Schultz, the City of Grants Pass, through its community development plan, authorized the landowner to build up to twenty homes on the relevant parcel and, in light of this authorization, merely sought roadway easements to accommodate it. In effect, the finding of takings liability in these types of cases faults governmental entities for over-planning. Land use planning can inform the courts of the genuine-ness of the government’s interest. In that sense, a comprehensive plan directly counters other types of “plans” that so frightened the Nollan majority—those “out-and-out plans of extortion.”167 And as one scholar reliably predicts, “Since Kelo encourages planning, more planning will occur.”168 But in those jurisdictions where courts express significant skepticism about exactions-for-the-future, governmental entities seeking to preserve the exactions tool have to walk a dizzying line: they presumably must search for a level of planning that is enough so as not to trigger traditional regulatory takings or “public use”169 concerns, but at the same time not too much so as to avoid triggering exactions takings liability. B. Per Se Exaction Takings? Prior to Nollan and Dolan, permitting entities admittedly were required to make some effort to quantify their findings in support of an exaction beyond mere conclusory statements, whether guided by a comprehensive land use plan or not.170 However, not all anticipated burdens can be precisely temporally defined. This section suggests that the “immediacy” criterion, at least as applied in cases like Burton, Goss, and Schultz, almost serves as a per se rule against using exactions-for-the-future to counter certain development impacts. This nearcategorical rule emanates from the fact that it is impossible for governmental entities to meet the level of proof required where there necessarily is some See, e.g., Nollan v. Cal. Coastal Comm’n, 483 U.S. 825, 837 (1987) (internal quotations omitted) (suggesting exactions may be "an out-and-out plan of extortion"). 168 See Garnett, supra note __, at 461. 169 See Garnett, supra note __, at 454 (suggesting that, post-Kelo, “government officials will view planning as a constitutional safe harbor and private litigants will consider a lack of planning a constitutional red flag”). 170 See, e.g., Collis v. City of Bloomington, 246 N.W.2d 19 (Minn. 1976); Simpson v. City of N. Platte, 292 N.W.2d 297, 301 (Neb. 1980); City of Coll. Station v. Turtle Rock Corp., 680 S.W.2d 802, 807 (Tex. 1984); Call v. City of West Jordan, 606 P.2d 217, 220 (Utah 1979); Jordan v. Vill. of Menomonee Falls, 137 N.W.2d 442 (Wis. 1965); Wald Corp. v. Metro. Dade County, 338 So. 2d 863, 866-67 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1976). 167 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE uncertainty in projecting the specific amount of the public burdens forecast to occur. It bears admission that requiring exactions to exhibit an immediate or near-term curative effect may have little impact in some exaction disputes.171 For instance, Nollan involved an example of an external community impact that could be immediately “cured.” Once the majority settled on a narrow definition of “public access,”172 it had little difficulty concluding that the imposed exaction (a public walking easement along the ocean) did not—and could never—“cure” the development’s impact (blockage of the public’s view of the ocean).173 The Court, however, suggested that a condition restricting the height or width of the proposed structure, prohibiting fences, or requiring the provision of a public “viewing spot” would cure the view loss immediately.174 For Justice Brennan in dissent, walking access and view access are one in the same; thus, in his eyes, the access required via the California Coastal Commission’s walking easement exaction would cure the access lost due to the development without delay.175 But in other circumstances, the demand that exactions offset development impacts in short order makes the utilization of conditional development approvals a challenging proposition.176 Literature on the difficulties in proving causation is voluminous, and it is these difficulties that make is quite unlikely that the party bearing the burden of proof will prevail. Dolan itself is instructive here. First, Dolan’s development—expansion of a hardware store and construction of a new parking lot—would increase impervious cover, thereby preventing the infiltration Faus, supra note __, at 703 (“traditional regulatory dedications and improvements are imposed because there is a well-established cause-and-effect relationship between the property dedication and improvements required by the regulations and social evils of congestion, safety, and health problems that the regulations seek to remedy.”). 172 Nollan v. Cal. Coastal Comm’n, 483 U.S. 825, 849-50 (1987) (Brennan, J., dissenting) (suggesting the majority’s has a “unrealistically limited conception of what measures could reasonably be chosen to mitigate the burden produced by a diminution of visual access.”). 173 Id. at 838. 174 Id. at 836. However, the public record does not reveal that the permitting agency later required any such viewing spot or like condition. Many scholars have noted that, if presented a choice between providing a public viewing spot on one’s upland property and an access corridor along the water, many might very well select the access corridor. See, e.g., Jerold S. Kayden, Zoning for Dollars: New Rules for an Old Game? Comments on the Municipal Art Society and Nollan Cases, 39 Wash. U. J. Urb. & Contemp. L. 3, 47–48; Dana, supra note __, at 127782. 175 Id. at 84950 (Brennan, J., dissenting). Molly McUsic explains that the California Coastal Commission had enumerated public goals beyond the provision of visual access that were “at least rationally related to the permit condition,” but that the Court ignored. See McUsic, supra note __, at 63738. 176 Fenster, Takings Formalism, supra note __, at 653 (“Takings rules impose external formality on local regulatory decision making, requiring local governments to demonstrate nexus and proportionality when those metrics are difficult to find, prove, and negotiate. In some instances, such formality will work as intended; in others, it will not.”). 171 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE of water into the underlying soil.177 Second, the expansion of the store would bring more customers into the downtown area, and with more customers comes more cars.178 The majority had little difficulty concluding that exacting a strip of the applicant’s land for floodplain preservation and a bicycle path could cure the development’s flooding and traffic impacts.179 However, the Dolan Court’s rather elusive remand apparently tasked the trial court with determining this difficult proportionality question: will the exaction ultimately “cure” more flooding and traffic than the flooding and traffic that the applicant’s proposed development will cause, such that the government has asked for too much?180 It is a far simpler task to measure if an exaction alleviates blockage of a public access way, as in Nollan, than it is to measure if an exaction alleviates anticipated traffic or flooding in a case like Dolan.181 It is true that traffic impact analyses routinely are utilized to measure problems associated with roadway congestion, including the economic costs linked to prolonged travel time, the environmental and health effects of air pollution, and public safety.182 Yet accurately assessing the future societal utilization of pedestrian and bicycle alternatives is a difficult undertaking.183 And assessing the impact of floodplain degradation associated 177 Dolan v. City of Tigard, 512 U.S. 374, 382 (1994). Id. 179 Id. at 387. Whether the walking easement exaction in Nollan cured too much—the proportionality question—proved irrelevant to the Nollan majority, for no amount of walking access, even if quite small, would cure the loss of viewing access. 180 Id. at 39596. Which variables are appropriate for comparison under Dolan’s “rough proportionality” analysis is not settled. See Thomas W. Merrill, Dolan v. City of Tigard: Constitutional Rights as Public Goods, 72 DENV. U. L. REV. 859, 885 (1995); McUsic, supra note __, at 631. There are at least four values that could be relevant: (A) the public cost of those harms attributable to the proposed development; (B) the reduction in those public costs that are anticipated to result from the permit conditions; (C) the market value of the “property” acquired through the permit condition; and (D) the financial benefits the applicant will realize from the permit. One could make a colorable argument that the relevant comparison is between (A) and (B), (A) and (C), or (B) and C), and quite possibly even (A) and (D). 181 See, e.g., Robert H. Freilich, & Terry D. Morgan, Municipal Strategies for Imposing Valid Development Exactions: Responding to Nollan, in EXACTIONS, IMPACT FEES AND DEDICATIONS 2829 (Robert H. Freilich & David W. Bushek eds., 1995) (suggesting that “incremental needs for public services and facilities generated by new development” are “susceptible to reasonably precise measurement” when compared to the difficulties in measuring the adverse effects of development on the affordable housing supply and the environment). 182 See, e.g., JAMES C. NICHOLAS, THE CALCULATION OF PROPORTIONATE-SHARE IMPACT FEES 2334 (1988); Roger Dahlstrom, Development Impact Fees: A Review of Contemporary Techniques for Calculation, Data Collection, and Documentation, 15 N. ILL. U.L. REV. 557 (1995); Mary Edwards, Traffic Impact Analysis, under Community Guide to Development Impact Analysis, UNIV. OF WIS. LAND INFO. & COMPUTER GRAPHICS FACILITY http://www.lic.wisc.edu/shapingdane/facilitation/all_resources/impacts/analysis_traffic.htm (last visited Aug. 27, 2011). 183 See, e.g., U.S. DEP’T OF TRANSP., PEDESTRIAN AND BICYCLE DATA COLLECTION IN UNITED STATES COMMUNITIES: QUANTIFYING USE, SURVEYING USERS, AND DOCUMENTING FACILITY EXTENT, January 2005, 178 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE with development akin to that proposed by Dolan is all the more challenging. While scientific tools are being developed that more accurately measure the curative benefits of preserving a stream bank (or, say, re-creating wetlands or species habitat),184 precisely measuring the curative effect of such measures remains a grave difficulty given the vast complexity of ecological systems. 185 Indeed, Dolan’s claim drew on these very difficulties, for she asserted “that the city…has not identified any ‘special quantifiable burdens’ created by her new store that would justify the particular dedications required from her which are not required from the public at large.”186 This is a calculated litigation strategy: advocate that a court adopt a standard (here, requiring the government to identify “special quantifiable burdens”) that the opposing party could never meet (here, in light of the types of impacts at stake). But, as Chief Justice Rehnquist’s opinion for the Dolan majority attests, because the burdens are not specifically quantifiable does not mean they do not exist. This understanding is evident, for instance, where the Court indicates its concern only that the City of Tigard may have demanded too much—a dedication—when an easement would suffice to address the city’s concerns.187 http://www.pedbikeinfo.org/pdf/casestudies/PBIC_Data_Collection_Case_Studies.pdf; Robert H. Freilich, and Terry D. Morgan, Municipal Strategies for Imposing Valid Development Exactions: Responding to Nollan, in EXACTIONS, IMPACT FEES AND DEDICATIONS 21 (Robert H. Freilich & David W. Bushek eds., 1995); Fenster, supra note __, at 658. See also Keith Hirokawa, Three Stories About Nature: Property, the Environment, and Ecosystem Services, 62 MERCER LAW REVIEW 541 (2011) (discussing the commoditization of ecosystem services); James Salzman & J.B. Ruhl, Currencies and the Commodification of Environmental Law, 53 STAN. L. REV. 607 (2000). 184 See, e.g., Impervious Cover, U.S. ENVTL. PROT. AGENCY, http://www.epa.gov/athens/research/impervious (last updated July 27, 2011); CHRISTIAN LAYKE, MEASURING NATURE'S BENEFITS: A PRELIMINARY ROADMAP FOR IMPROVING ECOSYSTEM SERVICE INDICATORS, 4 (World Research Institute Working Paper, 2009), available at http://www.wri.org/publication/measuring-natures-benefits (compiling and assessing current ecosystems services indicators in order to inform and advance efforts to inform policy-makers’ understanding of ecosystem services). But see FRANK ACKERMAN AND LISA HEINZERLING, PRICELESS: ON KNOWING THE PRICE OF EVERYTHING AND THE VALUE OF NOTHING (2004) (emphasizing the limits of contingent valuation of natural resources) and James Salzman, Creating Markets for Ecosystem Services: Notes From the Field, 80 N.Y.U. L. REV. 870, 872 (2005) (identifying many obstacles to establishing markets and payment programs for ecosystem services such as biodiversity protection). 185 See, e.g., Holly Doremus, Lesson Learned, in The Endangered Species Act at Thirty: Renewing the Conservation Promise, Vol. 1 195, 20304 (Dale D. Goble et al. eds., 2006) (“Despite thirty years of experience, what we don’t know about dwindling species and their protection could still fill volumes.”). 186 Dolan v. City of Tigard, 512 U.S. 374, 38586 (1994) (emphasis added). 187 See Id. at 393 (“The city has never said why a public greenway, as opposed to a private one, was required in the interest of flood control.”). On remand, however, even after the city no longer was asking for a dedication of property but rather only an easement, an Oregon trial court concluded that the city could not meet its burden under the “rough proportionality” test. The city EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE Even where the benefits of a responsive action to development impacts are accurately measureable, those benefits still may be far off in the future. One area of contemporary concern where these quantification challenges are magnified surrounds attempts to counter the delayed harms of coastal development as sea levels inevitably rise. Plainly, the rate and timing of sea-level rise remain uncertain.188 Therefore, the benefits of any measures taken today to counter its effects are also uncertain. This uncertainty, however, does not reflect the absence of long-term costs, or the lack of any need to take responsive action in the nearterm.189 To the contrary, it may suggest that at least for certain types of sea-level rise impacts, exactions-for-the-future are quite prudent when compared to the expected cost of reacting later.190 For example, preemptive individualized setbacks on undeveloped properties could allow for future coastal wetland migration at a fraction of the cost of removing approved development in the future to facilitate such migration.191 For another, designing and funding coastal ultimately forewent an appeal, instead agreeing to pay Dolan nearly $1.5 million for the relevant strip of property as part of a settlement agreement. See, e.g., Randall T. Shephard, Takings Law: Do We Really Want More Judicial Intervention in State Land Use Regulation?, 1 GEO. J.L. & PUB. POL’Y 99, 102 n.22 (2002) (citing City of Tigard Will Pay Dolans $ 1.5 Million in Bikepath “Takings” Case, BUS. WIRE, Nov. 21, 1997); Faus, supra note __, at 67677; Samuel H. Weissbard & Camellia K. Schuk, Taking Issue with Taking by Regulation, COM. INVESTMENT REAL ESTATE (Nov.–Dec. 1998), available at http://www.ccim.com/cire-magazine/articles/takingissue-taking-regulation; Dolan v. Tigard: Owner Gets $1.4 Million From City—at Last!, REALTOR MAG., (July 1, 1998), available at http://www.realtor.org/archives/lawyoujul1998b. 188 See INTERGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE CHANGE, CLIMATE CHANGE 2007: SYNTHESIS REPORT, SUMMARY FOR POLICYMAKERS 7 (2007), available at http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar4/syr/ar4_syr_spm.pdf (“Because understanding of some important effects driving sea level rise is too limited, this report does not assess the likelihood, nor provide a best estimate or an upper bound for sea level rise.”); JAMES G. TITUS, U.S. ENVTL. PROT. AGENCY, COASTAL SENSITIVITY TO SEA-LEVEL RISE: A FOCUS ON THE MIDATLANTIC REGION, IMPLICATIONS FOR DECISIONS 141 (2009), http://www.epa.gov/climatechange/effects/coastal/pdfs/ccsp_part3.pdf. 189 See Dana, supra note __, at 126884. 190 These anticipatory exactions could address the concern that, with increased storm surge due to sea level rise, land previously not at risk of flooding previously will be in the future. See, e.g., CSA International, Inc., supra note __, at 24. See also COASTAL SENSITIVITY TO SEA-LEVEL RISE: A FOCUS ON THE MID-ATLANTIC REGION, supra note __. 191 See, e.g., JON KUSSLER, ASSOCIATION OF STATE WETLAND MANAGERS, INC., COMMON QUESTIONS: WETLAND RESTORATION, CREATION, AND ENHANCEMENT 15 (2006), available at http://old.aswm.org/propub/20_restoration_6_26_06.pdf. There are some instances where the economic impact of an exaction to a developer could be postponed until the relevant problem arises in the future. See Titus, supra note __, at 1313 (discussing the concept of rolling easements). Waiting until coastal land loss is imminent to establish setback requirements has elicited concerns of significant (and constitutionally compensable) economic impacts to coastal landowners, as evident in Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Commission, 505 U.S. 1003 (1992). But the notion of a rolling easement, which imperceptibly “rolls” as sea levels rise, seemingly raises fewer takings concerns. As one scholar states, “[R]olling easements would not deny all productive use. Although productive use would eventually end if and when the sea level rises to a particular elevation, the regulation itself does not prevent productive use when implemented.” Titus, supra note __, at 1357. In other words, rolling easements allow the targeted activity to EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE infrastructure in a manner that accounts for rising sea levels may be more cost efficient than retrofitting such infrastructure at a later date.192 The demanding criterion of the exactions-for-the-future cases, in practice, allows the imposition of exactions for only those burdens that are quantifiable in the present or near term. Demanding that local governments on limited budgets pay just compensation for the safety-inducing emergency connector right-of-way in Burton and the traffic-reducing rights-of-way in Goss and Schultz necessarily allows certain impacts of intensified land uses to go unmitigated. C. Delineating Takings and Due Process Review This section first explains that the U.S. Supreme Court’s exaction takings decisions have long stood atop a jurisprudentially uncomfortable fence that traditionally divides due process and takings analyses. It then recounts how the Court recently sought to justify this rather peculiar exaction takings/due process hybrid. Yet even making two weighty assumptions—(1) that exactions-for-thefuture are not per se takings, as discussed in the prior Part, and (2) the Supreme continue, at least for a time. Id. at 1352. Imposition of a rolling easement is less likely a taking than imposition of a setback requirement because the coastal landowner can continue to maintain a structure on the property until that maintenance threatens elimination of the public’s flowed lands, destruction of public infrastructure, or other detrimental public effects. Regulatory actions regarding subsurface mining have produced a similar dichotomy. The foundational, if cryptic, regulatory takings case of Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393 (1922), involved Pennsylvania’s Kohler Act that prohibited mining activities when such activities threatened homes with subsidence. The U.S. Supreme Court declared that the Kohler Act immediately destroyed the subsurface estate held by the plaintiff, the Pennsylvania Coal Company, which sat below residences at risk. See id. at 41216. Yet sixty years later the Court found that Pennsylvania’s Bituminous Mine and Land Conservation Act—which also sought to minimize the risk of subsidence by limiting the amount of coal that could be mined—did not amount to a regulatory taking because mining could continue until subsidence became a threat. See Keystone Bituminous Coal Ass’n v. DeBenedictus, 480 U.S. 470, 498501 (1987). That some ability to mine remained proved material, though that ability grew only out of the legislature’s preemptive approach to a public safety problem that would inevitably arise in the future. Amortization schemes provide another analogy. A municipal zoning scheme that phases out nonconforming uses through a lengthy amortization period often has only a trivial impact on the present economic value of private property. See Titus, supra note __, at 132223). Therefore, such regulatory efforts are unlikely to require the payment of just compensation to affected landowners when compared to the immediate removal of a non-conforming use. See, e.g., Oswalt v. Cnty. of Ramsey, 371 N.W.2d 241, 246 (Minn. Ct. App. 1985) (declaring that a municipality can phase out non-conforming uses over a reasonable period of time without paying compensation). 192 See, e.g., James G. Titus et al., Greenhouse Effect, Sea Level Rise, and Coastal Drainage Systems, 113 J. WATER RESOURCES PLAN. & MGMT. 216, 216227 (1987) (asserting that retrofitting or rebuilding a drainage system can cost ten to twenty times as much as including larger pipes in the initial construction). EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE Court’s rationalization for the exaction takings/due process hybrid in the realm of exactions is justifiable—this section asserts that those lower courts imputing an immediacy criterion into exaction takings analyses have produced a rather remarkable consequence: economic regulations taking the form of exactions-forthe-future are susceptible to invalidation in a manner akin to the judicial dissolution of economic regulations in the now-discredited Lochner era. i. The Due Process Footing of Exaction Takings Jurisprudence At the dawn of modern regulatory takings jurisprudence in Penn Central, the U.S. Supreme Court suggested in dicta that substantive review of a regulation’s validity might be appropriate in takings analyses.193 Two years later, in Agins v. City of Tiburon,194 the Court drew on Penn Central’s dicta to declare that a land use regulation restricting development density did not constitute a taking. 195 The Court explained that its holding rested on the finding that the regulation at issue “substantially advanced” the legitimate state interest of discouraging “premature and unnecessary conversion of open-space to urban uses.”196 The Court asserted that its “substantially advance” test derived from three prior momentous land use cases involving not takings, but substantive due process challenges.197 Agins’ fusion of these two constitutional clauses produced the following result: the judiciary could invalidate and enjoin state economic legislation on the basis that the law does not “substantially advance a legitimate state interest,” without regard to whether the challenged legislation diminishes the economic value or usefulness of any property. This judicial power threatened a reinstitution of the intrusive, late-nineteenth and early twentieth century review of economic regulatory efforts through the backdoor of the Takings Clause. After more than two decades of scholarly commentary describing Agins’s errant mixture of due process and takings analyses,198 the Court finally—and Penn. Cent. Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104, 127 (1978). (“[I]t is, of course, implicit . . . that a use restriction on real property may constitute a ‘taking’ if not reasonably necessary to the effectuation of a substantial public purpose . . . . ”). 194 Agins v. City of Tiburon, 447 U.S. 255 (1980). 195 See id. at 260–62. 196 Id. at 261. 197 Id. at 26162. 198 See, e.g., Michelman, supra note __, at 160514; Richard L. Settle, Regulatory Taking Doctrine in Washington: Now You See It, Now You Don't, 12 U. PUGET SOUND L. REV. 339, 35152 (1989); John D. Echeverria & Sharon Dennis, The Takings Issue and the Due Process Clause: A Way out of a Doctrinal Confusion, 17 VT. L. REV. 695 (1993); Glen E. Summers, Comment, Private Property Without Lochner: Toward a Takings Jurisprudence Uncorrupted by Substantive Due Process, 142 U. PA. L. REV. 837 (1993); Kenneth Bley, Substantive Due Process and Land Use: the Alternative to a Takings Claim, in TAKINGS: LAND-DEVELOPMENT CONDITIONS AND 193 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE unanimously—admitted its error.199 In the 2005 case of Lingle v. Chevron, the Court explicitly abandoned the Agins test for regulatory takings purposes. The decision disentangles at least some of the longstanding vagaries at the boundary of due process and takings review in this way: Lingle largely eliminates “substantial advancement” takings claims, relegating challenges to the merits of governmental action to the judiciary’s substantive due process jurisprudence and the attendant deferential rational basis review.200 Though the Court had not regularly cited to the “substantially advance” test after Agins, the test did serve a principal role in both Nollan and Dolan.201 One might REGULATORY TAKINGS AFTER DOLAN AND LUCAS 289, 291 (David L. Callies ed., 1996); John D. Echeverria, Does a Regulation That Fails to Advance a Legitimate Governmental Interest Result in a Regulatory Taking?, 29 ENVTL. L. 853 (1999); Jerold Kayden, Land-Use Regulations, Rationality, and Judicial Review: The RSVP in the Nollan Invitation, 23 URB. LAW. 301 (1991); Kenneth Salzberg, “Takings” as Due Process, or Due Process as “Takings”?, 36 VAL. U. L. REV. 413 (2002); Ronald J. Krotoszynski, Jr., Expropriatory Intent: Defining The Proper Boundaries of Substantive Due Process and the Takings Clause, 80 N.C. L. REV. 713 (2002); D. Benjamin Barros, The Police Power and the Takings Clause, 58 U. MIAMI L. REV. 471 (2004). Justice Kennedy had, a decade before Lingle, suggested the same. Eastern Enterprises v. Apfel, 524 U.S. 498, 546 (1998) (Kennedy, J., concurring in judgment and dissenting in part) (suggesting that in instances where “the legitimacy of Congress’ judgment rather than on the availability of compensation, the more appropriate constitutional analysis arises under general due process principles rather than under the Takings Clause. … [The Court should] “reserv[e] takings analysis for cases where the governmental action is otherwise permissible.”). See also id. (Breyer, J., dissenting) (“at the heart of the [Takings] Clause lies a concern, not with preventing arbitrary or unfair government action, but with providing compensation for legitimate government action that takes ‘private property’ to serve the ‘public’ good. … [There is] no need to torture the Takings Clause [to house claims of arbitrariness that have a] “natural home in the Due Process Clause…”). 199 At oral argument, Justice Scalia suggested the court was going to have to “eat crow” in rejecting the twenty-five year-old Agins test. See Transcript of Oral Argument at 21, Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A., Inc., 544 U.S. 528 (2005) (No. 04-163). Justice O’Connor’s opinion for the unanimous Court opened, “On occasion, a would-be doctrinal rule or test [here, the “substantially advance” test] finds its way into our case law through simply repetition of a phrase – however fortuitously coined.” Lingle, 544 U.S. at 531. The decision concludes, “Twenty-five years ago, the Court posited that a regulation of private property "effects a taking if [it] does not substantially advance [a] legitimate state interest." The lower courts in this case took that statement to its logical conclusion, and in so doing, revealed its imprecision. Today we correct course.” Id. at 548 (internal citations omitted). 200 Of course, takings must be for a “public use” in accord with the text of the Fifth Amendment. However, the court’s “public use” inquiries are quite narrow. See infra notes __ and accompanying text. The differences between the Takings Clause’s public use requirement and the traditional substantive due process inquiry of whether a government action is rationally related to advance a legitimate state interest have provided fodder for an interesting academic discussion. See, e.g., _______. For purposes herein, suffice it to say that the refuted “substantial advancement” language of Agins is markedly stricter than the substantive due process rational basis review. 201 Nollan stated that the government’s access corridor condition “utterly failed to further the end advanced as the justification for the prohibition.” Nollan v. Cal. Coastal Comm’n, 483 U.S. 825, 837 (1987). Likewise, Dolan asserted, “A land use regulation does not effect a taking if it ‘substantially advances legitimate state interests’ and does not ‘deny an owner economically viable use of his land.’” Dolan v. City of Tigard, 512 U.S. 374, 385 (1994). There was no claim EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE imagine, therefore, that Lingle necessitated the Court’s overruling Nollan and Dolan, as well. However, Lingle, if cryptically, largely left the Court’s exactions takings jurisprudence intact. The Lingle Court suggested that the Nollan and Dolan tests are “worlds apart” from the Agins test.202 The Court’s attempt to distinguish the Nollan and Dolan tests from the Agins test rested on the fact that the latter assessed whether some state interest is substantially advanced by a given regulation, while the former two assess only whether the proffered exaction substantially advances the same public interest that is threatened by the proposed development project.203 ii. Due Process and Exactions-for-the-Future The import of the Court’s distinguishing between “some” and “same” is debatable, for both inquiries presumably require scrutinizing the means and ends of a legislative decision beyond the traditional deference afforded to legislative acts under longstanding substantive due process jurisprudence.204 Yet even assuming that this is an appropriate distinction that supports the Lingle Court’s preservation of Nollan and Dolan, the exactions-for-the-future takings findings cannot be similarly justified. Take the Burton v. Clark County example described in Part III. Same-ness was not at issue. The question of interest to the court was whether the requested rightof-way would serve any (i.e., some) state interest at all. The court ultimately answered this question in the negative, concluding that the uncertainty surrounding the development of those parcels adjacent to Plaintiff’s proposed in Nollan or Dolan that the development condition at issue denied the property owner all economically viable use of her land; indeed, no evidence was presented of any economic impact at all. 202 See Lingle, 544 U.S. at 545–48. 203 See Lingle, at 547 (“In neither [Nollan or Dolan] did the Court question whether the exaction would substantially advance some legitimate state interest. Rather, the issue was whether the exactions substantially advanced the same interests that land-use authorities asserted would allow them to deny the permit altogether.”) (internal citations omitted). In an amicus brief filed in support of the State of Hawaii, the Solicitor General of the United States pressed this very distinction. See Solicitor General Brief, Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A., Inc., 544 U.S. 528 (2005) (No. 04-163), available at http://supreme.lp.findlaw.com/supreme_court/briefs/04-163/04163.mer.ami.usa.html (“Because the governmental bodies in Nollan and Dolan sought to use the landowners' planned development activities to justify uncompensated exactions that would otherwise have violated the Constitution, the Court required a heightened showing, not simply that the permit conditions would advance some state interest, but that they would alleviate germane problems, i.e., problems caused by the permitted development activities themselves.”). 204 Timothy M. Mulvaney, The Remnants of Exaction Takings, 33 ENVIRONS ENVTL. L. & POL'Y J. 189, 213 n.141 (2010). One commentator pondered whether the preservation of Nollan and Dolan in Lingle was a “force[d]…distinction.” See, e.g., Sarah B. Nelson, Case Comment: Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A., Inc., 30 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 281, 290 (2006). EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE subdivision rendered the demanded exaction too speculative in nature.205 The Court suggested that it “need not reach” Burton’s substantive due process claim because the “takings claim is dispositive.”206 But it is difficult to understand how an exaction could survive rational basis review, as required by the Due Process Clause, where that exaction did not withstand the significantly more probing “substantially advance” test of its merit.207 This assumes, however, that the Burton court believes rational basis review is indeed an appropriate standard for assessing the validity of government’s proposed solutions to perceived public problems. And, indeed, this assumption may be incorrect. The court stated, “In passing, we observe that the ideas inherent in the federal Takings Clause may be the same as those … that determine whether a regulation violates substantive due process.”208 On the “propriety of substantive due process” review, the court remarkably and unapologetically cited only to (1) a vague statement in a U.S. Supreme Court plurality opinion with which five Justices did not concur, and (2) Lochner itself.209 D. Visions of Property While this entire draft is an early work-in-progress, this particular section will be completely restructured and revised. For the most up-to-date version of this section, or to provide suggestions, please contact the author at tmulvaney@law.txwes.edu. 205 Burton v. Clark County, 958 P.2d 343, 35657(1998). Id. at 357. 207 Id. 208 Id. 209 Id. (“Regarding the propriety of substantive due process as an overall concept, see Eastern Enter., 524 U.S. at ---, 118 S. Ct. at 2153 (section IV-D of plurality opinion); Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45, 25 S. Ct. 539, 49 L. Ed. 937 (1905).”). In Eastern Enterprises, the Justices addressed a constitutional claim against a federal law requiring coal operators to pay premiums toward pension plans based upon the number of miners whom they had previously employed. While five Justices found the legislation at issue unconstitutional, they did not agree on a rationale. A plurality opinion asserting that any law that retroactively creates unanticipated and nonconsensual monetary liability does not implicate the Due Process Clause but rather takes “property” in violation of the Takings Clause. Justice Kennedy, concurring in the result, declared the legislation violative of only the Due Process Clause. The divided opinion raised the question of whether a concurrence in part and dissent in part by Justice Kennedy on due process grounds, coupled with a four-Justice dissent also on due process grounds, resulted in a precedential rejection of the takings theory cited by a four-Justice plurality. See, e.g., Commonwealth Edison Co. v. United States, 271 F.3d 1327, 133940 (Fed. Cir. 2001) (“[F]ive justices of the Supreme Court in Eastern Enterprises agreed that regulatory actions requiring the payment of money are not takings. . . . [W]e are obligated to follow the views of that majority.”); John D. Echeverria, Lingle, Etc.: The U.S. Supreme Court’s 2005 Takings Trilogy, 35 ENVTL. L. REP. 10,577, 10,583 n.52 (2005) (“[A] majority of the Court (Justice Kennedy and the four dissenters) indicated that a monetary assessment should not be viewed as falling within the scope of the Takings Clause.”). 206 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE It is a common error to begin discussion of differing visions of property, and the constitutional limits on land related laws in particular, with the U.S. Supreme Court’s 1922 opinion in Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon. Indeed, significant public land use controls were prevalent at America’s dawn. And not all early land use controls were negative; many imposed affirmative duties on property owners. Eric Freyfogle asserts that, for the drafters of the Declaration of Independence, “it was collective liberty that was the primary issue of the day…the power of the colonists as a people to govern themselves without interference [from the outside], not the rights of individuals to resist constraint.”210 A vision of property limitations steeped only in a narrow set of common law principles did not arise until the nineteenth century, when “America’s insatiable desires to develop the continent, expand markets, widen choices and multiply the nation’s wealth” prompted a narrower conception of land use controls.211 Landowners started envisioning industrial, intensified land uses, which would require a property regime that defined a landowner’s rights and obligations in a way that allowed activities that instilled harm on others.212 In turn, the judiciary began to favor not the community-centered, agrarian society of the colonial days but the rise of industrial development. This judicial shift set the stage for a probusiness theory of property; from this perspective, property was no longer considered a product of the state, but a natural, abstract right free of communal obligations.213 It was this individualistic perception that took center stage in Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, and continues in the modern day to fuel regulatory and exaction taking claims demanding that “the community … compensate landowners whenever it ask[s] them to halt community-harming activities.”214 In Mahon, the Pennsylvania Coal Company contested a statute that prohibited the mining of subsurface coal if it spoiled the stability of the overlying land. 215 Writing for the Id. at 59. See also WILLIAM J. NOVAK, THE PEOPLE’S WELFARE: LAW AND REGULATION IN 19TH CENTURY AMERICA 11 (1996) (“[L]iberty was never absolute, it always had to conform to the superior power of self-governing communities to legislate and regulate in the public interest.”); Anderson, Commodity and Propriety, 29 (asserting that the central dilemma of America politics of the day was not “the protection of individual freedoms against collective action but rather, the protection of the public rights of the people against aristocratic privileges and power”). 211 FREYFOGLE, supra note __, at __. 212 Id. at 70. 213 Id. at 81. 214 Id. at 84. See Singer & Beerman, supra note __, at 218 (suggesting that the U.S. Supreme Court’s takings jurisprudence of the 1980s and 1990s disregards the issue of unfair distributions of social obligations as defined by difficult value judgments in favor of a more naturalized and formalized conception of property based on the individual Justices’ intuition and “biased by preexisting common law definitions”). 215 Pa. Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393, 412 (1922). 210 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE Court in Mahon, Justice Holmes first declared that government “could hardly go on” if it had to pay for every modification that negatively impacts the value of certain properties.216 Of course, however, the opinion is most commonly cited for distinguishing ordinary regulations from those that go “too far.”217 The Court’s conclusion that the statute at issue did implicate this “test,” whereby the government must provide compensation, can only stem from the then-prevailing individualistic vision of private property: in assessing the statute’s effect, the Court started from the baseline that the coal company had the right to do as it wished. Clashes between land use controls and an alleged absolute, essential right to build became particularly contentious when, beginning in earnest in the 1950s, the ecological degradation and public health effects associated with industrial and other intensified land uses came into focus. And slowly, common law courts began to sympathize with landowners harmed by the land uses of their fellow community members.218 But, still, many courts saw the legislature as best equipped to address comprehensive environmental and social problems. This produced at least two effects. First, political stalemate in the legislature would lead to continued ecological degradation and social ills in the face of judicial inaction. Second, and more importantly, property owners could point to the outdated common law as the baseline of the vested rights in challenging legislation that affected those alleged rights.219 In Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council in 1992,220 and Dolan soon thereafter in 1994, the U.S. Supreme Court would address high-profile clashes between (A) the industry-promoting vision of property that had first gained prominence in the nineteenth century and (B) a re-developing vision of the collective interest as a protected public component of the institution of property. In Lucas, the U.S. Supreme Court declared that just compensation is categorically required where such laws deny a property owner all economically viable use of 216 Id. at 413 Id. at 415. 218 Waschak v. Moffat, 109 A.2d 310, 31824 (Musmanno, J., dissenting); Just v. Marinette Cnty., 201 N.W.2d 761 (Wis. 1972) (upholding ordinance prohibiting the filling of wetlands, for it would “prevent a harm from the change in [the property’s] natural character”), Prah v. Maretti, 321 N.W.2d 182, 188 (1982) (asserting that the reasons for rejecting the common law “ancient lights” doctrine in the nineteenth century—including allowing relatively unhindered private development—were no longer applicable in an age of increasing land use regulation and the social priority on developing alternative energy sources, such that a landowner had standing to challenge her neighbor’s development that would block the sunlight that otherwise would reach her solar panels). 219 Id. at 96. 220 505 U.S. 1003 (1992). 217 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE her property.221 But it is by now well-documented that the Court’s opinion in Lucas had ramifications well beyond, and arguably much more significant than, its creation of this narrow categorical rule demanding compensation for total economic takings. That is, Lucas’s per se test is subject to one important caveat: regulations merely re-stating “background principles,” such as those emanating from state law, are immune from takings liability.222 In fashioning this caveat, the five-Justice majority in Lucas explicitly favored old rules to new rules, and common law rules to regulation.223 And in the eyes of those Justices, regulation is always new (and thus may very well implicate the Takings Clause) if it does not directly mirror what nuisance law or some other common law doctrine already implicitly commanded.224 But the decision reflected a vision of property as defined only by the common law of the nineteenth century. It was as if the early common law intact at the time of the drafting of the Declaration of Independence and the U.S Constitution, as well as almost two centuries of state and federal legislative acts that override the common law, had no impact on the meaning of land ownership.225 Dolan continued this trend. Dolan, in essence, presents a cause-and-effect test that prohibits any governmental effort that potentially might redistribute some of the landowner’s economic wealth to the public. Taken to its logical end, because all government actions affect the status quo distribution of wealth, a broad application of this cause-and-effect test could threaten every form of government 221 In other words, where a regulation deprives a property owner of all economic value of her property, takings liability is automatic, i.e. the Penn Central balancing test pertinent in most regulatory takings disputes is inapplicable. 222 In the twenty years since Lucas, many lower courts have rejected claims challenging governmental regulations as working unconstitutional takings in light of the “background principles” defense. Michael C. Blumm & J.B. Ruhl, Background Principles, Takings, and Libertarian Property: A Reply to Professor Huffman, 37 ECOLOGY L. Q. 805 (2010). Therefore, whether the regulation at issue reflects a “background principle” now serves as a threshold inquiry in every takings case. 223 Lucas, 505 U.S. at 101516 (“Any limitation so severe cannot be newly legislated or decreed (without compensation), but must inhere in the title itself, in the restrictions that background principles of the State’s law of property and nuisance already place upon land ownership. A law or decree with such an effect must . . . do no more than duplicate the result that could have been achieved in the courts . . . under the State’s law of . . . nuisance, . . . or otherwise.”). As I discuss below, any good will respecting a state’s development of its common law exhibited by the Justices in the Lucas majority arguably has been significantly constrained by an opinion recently signed by several of those same Justices in Stop the Beach Renourishment. 224 This despite the fact that, as detailed above, “colonial governments regulated land use extensively for purposes other than preventing harm.” Hart, Colonial Land Use Law, supra note __, at 1253, 1257 (“Contrary to the conventional image of minimal land use regulation, government in the colonial period often exerted extensive authority.”) 225 See Byrne, supra note __, at __; FREYFOGLE, supra note __, at 261 (“Private property is a creature of the law…it is the sum total of all applicable laws, not merely a subset of them, that shapes it.”). EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE services because government benefits reaped by one individual or group almost necessarily impose costs on another individual or group.226 The U.S. Supreme Court’s exaction takings decisions have not, however, resulted in a wholesale dissolution of a broad swath of economic regulations. Still, as noted in the previous section,227 they have placed significant, Lochner-like constraints on the amount the government can “charge” for a specific “government benefit:” permission to intensify land uses.228 This constraint arguably is due in large part to the view of the Nollan and Dolan majorities that the right to intensify the use of real property is not actually a government benefit at all. Instead, it appears that, according to the Court, the ability to build is an essential, inherent right protected by the Constitution. The underlying premise of the U.S. Supreme Court’s exactions takings jurisprudence, then, is rather straightforward: When stripped to its core, the public is only permitted to offset what the landowner, upon construction, seizes for himself through the imposition of public harms. Under this view, since the right to build already is in the owner’s possession, the owner cannot be asked to pay anything for it. The exactions-for-the-future decisions that impute an immediacy criteria into exaction takings law go well beyond echoing Nollan and Dolan’s claim that a landowners’ right to build is an essential component of constitutionally protected property. However, Nollan and Dolan at least allow the public, in theory, to offset the external harms attributable to the exercise of that right. Burton, Goss, Schultz, and like decisions supplement that right to build with a right to commit or contribute to future public harms. ….. V. CONCLUSION This article has sought to highlight the increasing propensity for exactions to take aim at development impacts that are not going to result immediately or in the near term, but rather those impacts that are anticipated to occur at some point further off into the future. It suggests that, because of the delay between the imposition of these exactions-for-the-future and their curative effects, some courts are finding them less constitutionally palatable for Takings Clause purposes than See, e.g., McUsic, supra note __, at 647 (“Residents of a wealthy neighborhood, for example, could conceivably demand compensation from the city if they can show that a city-sponsored housing project for low-income people lowered their property values, and that they did not cause the project’s inhabitants to be poor.”). 227 See infra notes __ and accompanying text. 228 McUsic, supra note __, at 652 (“The government can never sell this benefit, the right to build, for a price greater than the harm caused by the owner’s proposed development.”). 226 EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE exactions that respond to immediate or near term public harms. I assert that this line of decisions reflects four important themes. First, judicial predisposition against exactions-for-the-future exposes a fundamental tension with the general emphasis on long-term planning in land use law. Second, the vitality of some jurisdictions’ apparent requirement that exactions bear immediate fruit arguably is equivalent to a per se rule against using exactions to counter a broad collection of public harms that pose quantification difficulties. Third, requiring in the course of a takings analysis that exactions demonstrate an imminent or near-term response to a public problem perpetuates the longstanding vagaries at the boundaries of takings and due process review. Fourth, imputing an immediacy criterion into exaction takings review signals a theoretical vision of private property that fortifies the already strong barrier between individual interests and permissible government action that has been erected in modern takings jurisprudence. Each of the noted themes arguably provides jurisprudential, theoretical, and normative justification for eschewing any distinction between exactions-for-thefuture and more traditional exactions; indeed, they may lend support for the claim that exactions in general should be treated no differently for takings purposes than other regulatory acts. However, to the extent that, in select jurisdictions, exactions-for-the-future will be looked at with disdain in the context of landowners’ takings suits, the next-best alternatives for local governments will need to be considered. For a sampling of potential alternatives that could serve as fodder for future scholarship, I return to the matter of Burton v. Clark County, first taken up in Part III above.229 In Burton, the County conditioned a subdivision approval on the developer’s conferral of a right-of-way for an emergency connector road in the event that—as anticipated by emerging development patterns—similar subdivisions arose on adjacent lands in the future.230 An appellate panel held this constituted an exaction taking because, since the planned road and adjacent development might never be constructed, the right-of-way could amount to what the court called a “road to nowhere.”231 In light of this result, municipalities might consider conditioning development permits not on a dedication or easement, but rather on an option for an easement. In Burton, the developer sought to construct a built-out residential cul-de-sac that necessarily would be infeasible were he to retain vacant land for the County’s 229 230 231 See infra notes __ and accompanying text. EARLY WORK-IN-PROGRESS --------- PLEASE DO NOT CIRCULATE OR CITE later potential exercise of its option. Therefore, if the developer were to continue with the cul-de-sac project, the County might retain the option of demanding the easement if and when the connector road becomes a necessity. At that point, the developer would be charged with buying out the property owner, presumably based on a formula to which the property owner previously consented at the time of purchase. This alternative may encourage the developer to limit the use of that end-lot for rental purposes only from the beginning, for selling the property with such an option attached could (A) be difficult, and (B) lead to complicated valuation problems should that new owner make significant improvements to the land prior to the County’s exercise of the option. Still, however, the developer would reap some economic return, which likely is preferred to the more draconian response that municipalities presumably have the discretion, if not always the political will, to take: denial of the subdivision approval outright. This abbreviated summary of alternatives conceivably available in Burton presents a springboard for future scholarship aimed at fashioning creative exactions that are responsive to future development harms and simultaneously able to survive takings scrutiny. When all was said and done in Burton, the County may have taken some solace in the events that unfolded following Burton’s takings victory. Following the Washington Supreme Court’s denial of the County’s petition for certiorari, the County purchased the end lot of Burton’s proposed cul-de-sac for near market value.232 As the County had expected, the adjacent lands were soon developed for residential use, and the once projected need for connectivity became starkly real.233 Yet, at least for takings purposes, it is of little import that the government’s plan proved prescient in this particular case; indeed, there are other instances where comprehensive land use plans arguably have erred.234 For purposes of takings law, it is the front-end deference accorded to municipalities— or, in the exactions-for-the-future context in cases like Burton, the lack thereof— that will shape the role of land use planning, and the concomitant line between alleged constitutionally-protected private development interests and anticipated public harms, moving forward. 232 Conversation with Clark County Prosecuting Attorney Christopher Horne, August 21, 2010. Id. 234 See, e.g., Patrick McGeehan, Pfizer to Leave City that Won Land-Use Case, N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 13, 2009, at A1, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2009/11/13/nyregion/13pfizer.html. 233