Stephanie: Within the Eurozone, there are two distinct groups of countries, often referred to as the Core (aka North) and the Peripheral (aka South) countries. The Core is composed of countries such as Germany, France, and Austria, who are characteristically net savers and run account surpluses, while the peripheral countries of Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece, and Spain are net consumers who run account deficits. The graph below provides a clear illustration of the disparities between the two sets of countries, as evidenced by their divergent current account balances. Given these differences, existence under a common monetary system makes effective policy decisions nearly impossible. These differences are particularly important to the stability of a common financial system, as was established over the decades leading up to the European Monetary Union’s formation. The integration and deregulation of European financial markets effectively began with the Single European Act of 1987. A revision of the previous Treaty of Rome from 1957 enacted by the precursor to the European Union countries, the European Economic Community (EEC), became the true leap-board for the financial integration and removal of trade barriers among European countries. Over the course of the 1990s, European countries deregulated more and more of their financial sectors, while allowing them to become more intertwined, through the adoption of the European Directions and later the Single Market Program of 1993. The Financial Services Action Plan of 1999 (FSAP) effectively established a common set of rules for the financial sectors of all European Union members. These actions led to an unprecedented growth in the size of European capital markets, and a convergence of interest rates. Although these policies expanded the available markets and significantly reduced the transaction costs of trade among member countries, the financial liberalization of European Union members also fostered a false sense of security of the prosperity and riskiness within their common financial system. Antonio: The European financial crisis was exacerbated by the accumulation of three types of debt; private, public, and foreign. Between the introduction of the Euro and the beginning of the global crisis, private debts grew rapidly (as a percentage of GDP) in several of the member states. Figure 1 shows that the three countries that would face the most turmoil suffered the highest increases of private debt-to-GDP after their induction to the EU. Figure 1: Private Debt as Percentage of GDP (Source: OECD) This became a major issue when the financial crisis struck because most of the household debt was ultimately owned by foreign investors. Once the bubbles started to burst, the GDP of many countries fell while simultaneously the fiscal responsibilities of the governments rapidly rose. The governments had two obligations; first, they had social welfare obligations which were quickly overexploited by citizens who had negligible savings to draw from. This increased the amount of public debt each country held, which was drawn from short-term and expensive sources of credit. Second, the government guaranteed several of their largest corporate debts. The end result was that these nations had high amounts of foreign-held public and private debt, which tied up the availability of credit for their entire economies. Figure 2: Public Debt as Percentage of GDP (Source: OECD) Figure 3: Interest Rate, GDP Growth, and Public Debt/GDP Ratio (Source: Vox EU) The explosion of private and public debt in the fiscally irresponsible countries (i.e. Greece, Italy, Ireland) damaged the financial health of more stable countries, because most of the foreign investors who owned the debts were German, French, American and UK citizens. Worse, the governments of the stable countries in the EU were the primary sources of the ECB bailout. Their economies were suffering from both ends; their private sectors were underperforming because they lacked the liquidity expected from the defaulted investments, and their public sectors were overspending due to the unforeseen bailout expenditures. For example, since 2008 Germany alone contributed “22 billion euros in the first Greek bailout, 253 billion euros to the European Financial Stability Facility and 94 billion euros to ECB purchases of sovereign bonds, and that's only a few of the highlights. Add it all together, and Germany's commitments to its neighbors could top 30% of its GDP.”[1] What are the financial effects of diverting approximately a third of the EU’s (not only Germany’s) GDP towards repaying debts? We will focus on two areas. First, investors are much more hesitant about investing in the fringe EU nations. For example, since December 2014 the Athen’s Stock Exchange has dropped a further 30% as investors divert their funds toward safer options. Second, exchange rates and interest rates are still very much in flux. This has hurt the current account balances of the very countries who need to be engaging in trade the most. [1] http://www.investopedia.com/financial-edge/1112/will-germanys-bailout-save-europe.aspx David: It became obvious in 2007 that the global financial system was very fragile. Martin Wolf gives five reasons to this fragility: changes in liberalization, globalization, innovation, leverage, and incentives. There has been a movement towards free markets during the past decades and it has allowed all of this crazy borrowing and lending. Funding has gone global and the interconnection of the global financial system creates a domino effect when a financial crisis hits one country. New complex financial assets such as derivatives were created along with shadow banking and too many people were unfamiliar with them. There was no lender of last resort or any competent regulator. Many borrowers also leveraged themselves intensely during the years leading up to the crisis. Finally, there was a big change in incentives as investors became willing to take on more risk than earlier. All these factors helped set off some times of wild lending and borrowing in the Eurozone. Before the crisis broke out, all Eurozone government bonds were considered equally risky. Part of this problem is a regulation, Basel I, which allows all banks to consider government bonds as risk free. The interest rates on these bonds were very similar throughout all of Europe and investors imagined it was just as safe to invest in Greek government bonds as in German. This resulted in major private capital flows streaming to southern Europe but also Ireland. The capital came mostly from countries with excess savings and low credit demand. Instead of investing at home, they turned to countries where the credit demand was higher and rate of return seemed to be higher. The crisis would probably have been easier on us if the importing countries had invested the borrowed money in projects that would have yielded a rate of return similar to the interest rate they were paying. This was not the case, though, and the Greek government especially spent their borrowed money on unsustainable projects. They gave out ridiculous bonuses to employees, had a very low retiring age, which created a casual working environment in the country. So when the lenders realized the risk and came to get their money, the borrowing countries were standing there with close to empty pockets. Brett 1: The Ireland housing bubble started in the 1990’s. The government had lowered interest rates to stimulate the economy. During that time people wanted to find a safe and sustainable long term asset, so they turned to real estate. In addition, banks were encouraging people to take out loans by offering 100% mortgages. Knowing full well that those taking out the loans couldn’t pay them back causing the people to foreclose, which helped keep the supply stable. Although when others started realizing that housing was the industry to enter the supply began to increase. By 2006 the bubbled ballooned and supply and demand stabilized. When 2007 rolled around housing prices dropped because property prices are unsustainable,and rental yields have fallen below the risk free rate of over 3.5% offered by Government bonds. Allyson: A major factor in the account imbalances experienced by many Eurozone countries was the common belief that the euro was equal among member states as if the Eurozone were its own independent country. In the early years of the euro, capital largely flowed from richer countries to poorer countries (especially those in southern Europe) based on gamble that returns would be higher in these areas. The recipient economies became very reliant on the large capital inflows and thus, when the financial crisis of the late 2000’s hit, the sudden turnaround of capital inflows caused deep economic turmoil. The chart below illustrates the increased spending of the euro area by plotting the ratio of foreign assets plus foreign liabilities to GDP. Notice the graph peaks around 2007. Another major factor contributing to the widening imbalances was that the newly found capital making its way through southern Europe was placed in the non-tradable sector, and as a result many countries experienced construction and housing booms. Additionally, when the turnaround of capital used to finance many of the construction projects seemingly evaporated during the financial crisis, it caused financial devastation in the respective countries. What remained was severe account imbalances due to the increased demand for capital that fueled an increase in imports while exports did not raise enough to maintain a balance. The above graph depicts the current account to GDP in relation do a particular country’s growth rate. The countries further to the right experienced positive balances while also achieving growth. The countries to the left (note, mostly southern countries) were experiencing similar growth, only their accounts show that the growth was funded through debt. Ireland stands out as achieving remarkable growth in the years spanning 1999-2007, this is explained by a massive housing bubble, funded by shady loans, which severely inflated the Irish housing market. The graph below is a snapshot of the imbalances in 2007. Stephanie: Many viewed the differences in the balances as a result of the convergence hypothesis. According to this theory, countries with lower GDP per capita are attractive investments as they represent greater potential for growth and large rates of return. Anticipating their own future growth, such countries save less and consume more, assuming they will be able to finance their foreign debt through their increased future productivity. Unfortunately, empirical evidence has not supported this theory in the context of the periphery countries of Europe (Holinski, Kool, Muysken 2010, Despite the blatant discrepancies among the current account balances of the Eurozone countries, up until 2009, Spain, Germany, and Ireland were given the same AAA rating. Once investors began recognizing the riskiness of the countries began being downgraded, it became a self-fulfilling prophecy. Credit downgrades led to higher expected bond yields due to their increased riskiness, which resulted in short-term losses for current bonds holders. These losses then made it more expensive and difficult to issue new debt or for governments to refinance, which in turn led to ever greater risk-aversion by investors, and higher costs, leading to eventual insolvency. ● “in 2007 the spread between 10-year government bond yields of Greece and Germany was only 0.27 percentage point” Credit default swaps--meant to spread risk better, but ended up just concentrating it ● Herding Effect: ○ Herding during the boom drove prices away from fundamentals in the Peripheries ■ consumers ■ investors ■ financial institutions ○ Herding in debt and currency markets may result in self-fulfilling prophecy ■ The role of rating agencies ■ The role of hedge funds Brett 2: The Portugal account balance was dominated by non-trade factors. Remittances started to come down in the mid 90’s this was due to two factors. The first factor was outward migration during the 60’s, then attracting inward migration from places like Brazil and Eastern Europe. The second factor was the rising disposable income levels and ability to receive cheap credit reducing the need for transfers from the Portuguese; however, some of the decline was due to the accounting feature of moving official EU structural adjustment funds from the current to capital account. Portugal had a lot of money flowing into it and ran up a deficit that was not sustainable over the long run. Eventually in 2014 Portugal created and followed through with a bailout plan to stabilize their deficit and return growth to the economy. · In response to the myriad of financial failures and inadequacies of Eurozone countries, several corrective measures have been taken. To address issues of financial supervision and inaccurate risk assessment, the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) was established in 2010. They work in conjunction with the European Supervisory Authorities and the European System of Financial Supervision. The overarching goal of each of these is to regain and maintain future financial security within the European Monetary Union.