Ekkehart Boehmer, EDHEC Business School Kingsley Fong, UNSW Julie Wu, University of Georgia Using computer algorithms to generate, monitor, and cancel orders automatically process prices, LOB, news predict flows, liquidity, prices Has been around for at least 25 years (ATD) but saw enormous growth over last decade milestones: Limit order display rules (NYSE 1993, Nasdaq 1997), Reg ATS (1998), Reg NMS (2005) Trading centers and estimated % of share volume in NMS stocks (September 2009) Agency algos – used by buy-side to minimize costs of portfolio turnover Proprietary algos goal is to profit from trading environment rather than investing a subset of these proprietary algo users we consider high frequency trading (HFT) – traders with response times measured in milliseconds Proprietary trading firms, potentially organized as B/D Proprietary trading desk of large B/D firm Hedge funds Passive market making strategies – provide liquidity, earn the spread Arbitrage strategies – seek short-horizon patterns Structural strategies – exploit features of trading protocol or regulation Directional strategies – order anticipation, momentum ignition, … None of these strategies is new, but the technology to implement them is. HFT is for real – between 60% and 80% of volume, depending on the market Proportion of good vs bad strategies is unknown What are consequences of HFT for • • • market quality? welfare (of traders, society, …)? systemic risk? Depends on strategies passive market making should improve liquidity stat arb should improve efficiency structural and directional strategies could be wealth transfers WE DON’T KNOW ACTUAL STRATEGIES, SO THE BEST WE CAN DO IS LOOK AT THE AGGREGATE EFFECT of AT/HFT (Ideally, we should care about aggregate welfare: competition among HFT and with other traders may be desirable, IT arms races are probably not) Standard approach: design a model with (typically slow) liquidity traders and/or market makers, add HFT typically assume that HFT is informed or sees information first not surprisingly, result is a wealth transfer from slow to fast traders (e.g., Cartea and Penalva 2011, Jarrow and Protter 2011) Instead, we may need models where the choice to become HFT is endogenous or liquidity traders can penalize HFT Probably most important: under what conditions can HFT increase welfare Hoffman 2012 lets traders endogenously invest in fast trading technology. Welfare gains when markets are sufficiently efficient. Otherwise IT overinvestment. Biais, Foucault, and Moinas 2010 show that HFT can generate gains from trade and gains from adverse selection, but a social planner would only consider gains from trade, not from adverse selection. Again, HFT overinvest in technology. Ambiguous effects in Jovanovic and Menkveld 2011 Transactions data where we infer the presence of AT/HFT indirectly from periods of very high message traffic Transactions data with trader category information that have a set of transactions attributed to AT/HFT Transactions data with trader account information Hendershott, Jones, and Menkveld 2011 use order-level message counts as a proxy for AT sample covers NYSE activity 2001-2005 algo trading is positively related to market quality (improves spreads and price discovery, and reduces information asymmetry) AT improve price discovery (Hendershott and Riordan 2009) Hasbrouck and Saar 2011 use 2007/2008 INET Itch data infer HFT from millisecond responses to market events such as quote updates identify fast trades that are linked in time to identify episodes of HFT find that HFT improves short-term volatility, spreads, and depth Egginton et al. 2011 use 2010 TAQ data select one-minute intervals where quotes-per- minute exceed 20 historical 20-day s.d. (on days where daily quoting is less than two s.d. away from the mean) discard days with information events Episodic spikes of (TAQ) quoting activity are quite frequent in many stocks are associated with degraded liquidity and elevated short-term volatility Brogaard (2010) uses a 2008-2009 Nasdaq sample covers 120 Nasdaq stocks (selected by academics) 26 HFT firms/traders that account for 77% of trades/74% of dollar volume in this sample (selected by Nasdaq, excludes large prop desks) HFT activity is associated with better liquidity, mixed effect on volatility, better price discovery (Brogaard 2010, Hendershott and Riordan 2011) Problem with the Nasdaq sample: potential selection bias less than sparkling clean traders would rationally veto reporting included transactions do not include same-trader activity on other markets and may not include all their activity on Nasdaq (?) exchange may purposely select liquidity suppliers This sample probably contains HFT activity that is more benign than that in a random sample of HFT Kirilenko, Kyle, Samadi, and Tuzun 2011 see individual strategies in S&P500 e-minis find that HFT worsened (but did not cause) the Flash Crash of 2010. Only with trader IDs can we track each trader’s orders across stocks and markets and infer actual strategies overcome endogeneity problem accurately determine triggers and consequences of HFT activity Broad samples (with inferred AT/HFT activity) imply mostly positive effects on average (MQ) mixed results on volatility negative effects during periods of extremely high message traffic and around quote updates Trader type samples positive effect on MQ and efficiency mixed results on volatility selection concerns What are the consequences of AT/HFT for markets, traders, firms, countries? To address gaps in the literature, to answer market structure questions, to evaluate whether LTI or AT/HFT are more important: we need more and broader evidence. from new samples. this paper is a first step in that direction. Use an international sample to measure the impact of AT/HFT on execution cost for different types of traders price discovery volatility Document differences across firms, trading protocols, and countries in these measures (incomplete) • Intraday quote and trade data from Thomson- Reuters Tick History (TRTH) 39 exchanges, 36 countries, 2001-2009 on average about 13,000 stocks will add NYSE and Nasdaq data from TAQ Daily data on returns, volume, high-low prices from Datastream Information about trading protocols from Speedguide, Exchange Handbook, WFE Accounting data from Datastream and WorldScope AT = -trading volume / # messages measures negative of trading volume in USD 100 per message follows Hendershott, Jones, and Menkveld 2011 messages include trades and quote updates Time weighted quoted spreads RQS=(ask-bid)/MQ Trade weighted effective spreads RES=2*|P-MQ|/MQ Amihud = |Return|/volume Ancerno (formerly Abel-Noser) buy-side trading costs RES captures total price impact of a trade. Decompose RES into RPI, the permanent component, the change in MQ from trade to 5 minutes later, measures information content (“toxicity”) RRS, the transient component, measures reward to liquidity providers, RES = RRS + 2* RPI |autocorrelation| for 10-60 minutes intervals for each stock, compute midquote returns for 5, 10, 20, 30 , 60 minute intervals then compute autocorrelation of those returns ignore overnight and zero returns note that there is no bid-ask bounce in this measure The more efficient the stock price (the closer it is to a random walk), the smaller is |ARnn| Use several standard volatility measures |R|, for raw and market-adjusted return R^2, for raw and market-adjusted return Log (Ret10_Var), Log (Ret30_Var) daily relative price range = (High-Low)/Close Have three-dimensional unbalanced panel 39 markets, about 2250 days, about 330 stocks per market standard unobservable firm-level and time effects unobservable market or country effects Use daily standardization of all variables so coefficients are comparable across markets Regress variable of interest on AT and controls All regressions control for Volume (share turnover) Volatility (relative price range, excluded from volatility regressions) price level (1/price) firm size (ln market cap) Volatility regressions additionally control for RES and |AR30| Estimation strategy estimate firm/day panel regression for each market then aggregate across markets Use two different approaches within markets Two-way dynamic panels within each market ▪ use firm and day fixed effects ▪ use Arellano and Bond (1991) standard errors for marketlevel inference Fama-MacBeth within each market (same results, not reported) ▪ For global inference, compute means across markets, use cross-sectional t-test for inference Mean coefficient on AT t-stat %positive RQS RES RPI RRS Amihud -0.013 -9.1 5% -0.013 -7.4 8% -0.002 -0.7 54% -0.018 -9.2 5% -0.009 -6.5 15% More AT activity is associated with lower spreads and smaller temporary and permanent price impacts. How does the effect of AT differ for stocks with different characteristics? Sort within each market according to each characteristic Create dummies LOW and HIGH for low and high tercile Include interactions with AT in regression models 0.070 0.060 0.050 0.040 Solid colors indicate significance at the 5% level Small cap More AT reduces liquidity in small Mid cap stocks Large cap 0.030 0.020 0.010 0.000 -0.010 -0.020 RQS RES Amihud 0.020 Pale colors indicate no significance at the 10% level AT does not benefit low-priced stocks According to Amihud, liquidity even declines significantly for low priced stocks 0.015 0.010 0.005 Low price Mid price High price 0.000 -0.005 -0.010 -0.015 RQS RES Amihud 0.005 Volatility is SD of the 20 most rcent daily returns AT only benefits liquidity of low and mid volatility firms There is no AT effect on high volatility firms 0.000 -0.005 -0.010 -0.015 -0.020 Low volatility Mid volatility High volatility Mean coefficient on AT t-stat Percent positive |AR10| |AR30| -0.017 -6.1 5% -0.006 -4.5 23% More AT activity is associated with better informational efficiency. 0.010 Pale colors indicate no significance at 10% AT does not improve efficiency for small, low priced firms 0.008 0.006 0.004 0.002 Small Mid High 0.000 -0.002 -0.004 -0.006 -0.008 -0.010 Market cap Price Volatility Mean effect of AT t-stat %positive |ret| Ret^2 0.033 7.4 87% 0.025 6.6 85% Ln(Ret10_ Ln(Ret30_ PriceRange Var) Var) 0.045 7.9 87% 0.017 3.4 67% 0.029 4.9 79% • More AT activity is associated with higher volatility. • We control for efficiency and liquidity of each stock. • Thus, the volatility increase does not represent “good” volatility that may arise with very efficient markets. Effect on relative intraday price range (Results are robust for several other volatility measures) 0.090 0.080 0.070 0.060 0.050 0.040 0.030 0.020 0.010 0.000 Small Mid High Market cap Price Volatility Volatility increases most for stocks that are small, low priced, or have volatile returns to begin with We do not observe what strategies algo traders use Liquidity provision for mid and large cap stocks implies that at some AT supply liquidity How resilient is this liquidity supply over time? MMs dislike one-sided order flow that moves price. E.g., consider sell imbalance: price moves down, MM is long, faces inventory losses Will cut back on liquidity provision on such one-way days Will cut back more when imbalance continues through the next day Select all days where daily return has the same sign as on the previous day Set HARD dummy to one on these days if the cumulative return exceeds one 20-day standard deviation Interact with AT as before Price Range AT increases volatility and efficiency more AT still increases liquidity, but significantly less than on regular days AT significantly increases the information content of trades If AT use MM strategies on average, they tend to resort to other strategies when market making is unusually difficult Contrasts to traditional MM with affirmative obligations |AR30| RRS RPI Amihud RES -0.020 0.000 0.020 Change on HARD days Mean coefficient on AT 0.040 Use co-location within each market as an instrument for AT Estimate IV regression at the market level 1. compute value-weighted daily averages for each market 2. estimate first stage regressions of AT on CL dummy and market-day fixed effects 3. estimate second-stage IV model with market and day fixed effects using predicted values from (2) Liquidity Dependent RQS RES RPI RRS Amihud Efficiency Estimate -1.0087 -1.1546 -0.9285 -0.2718 -0.0001 t -6.6 -6.2 -7.4 -1.8 -6.0 Dependent |AR10| |AR30| Estimate t -0.0006 -4.5 -0.0001 -0.5 Volatility PriceRange |Ret| Ret^2 0.0002 10.0 0.0001 3.2 0.0000 0.1 Results are largely unchanged with IV – evidence that causality originates with AT. We contribute evidence from 39 countries to shed some light on how algo trading affects market quality Algo trading improves liquidity and informational efficiency worsens volatility, even when controlling for efficiency and liquidity But AT worsens liquidity of the smallest third of firms in each market AT increases volatility the most for firms that are small, low priced, and more volatile on days when market making is more difficult, AT provides less liquidity, increases information content of trades, and increases volatility more. Results are amazingly consistent across markets Volatility increases with more algo trading – what exactly are the implications? In assessing the current market structure, market observers should take into account that the effects of AT are not uniform. Will higher volatility discourage investors in the long run and thus increase firm’s cost of capital? Or affect its ability to raise new capital? We will use our 11-year panel to assess longer-term effects of AT on firm/country characteristics distribution of benefits and costs over good/bad times and across stocks