The optimal management of wetlands

advertisement
1
The optimal management of wetlands: quantifying trade-offs between flood risks, recreation and
2
biodiversity conservation
3
4
Ekin Birol1, Nick Hanley2, Phoebe Koundouri3, Yiannis Kountouris3
5
1
6
Washington, DC 20006-1002, USA, & Department of Land Economy, University of Cambridge.
7
Email:e.birol@cgiar.org; Fax: +1 202 467 4439
8
2
Economics Department, University of Stirling, Stirling FK9 4LA, Scotland
9
3
DIEES, Athens University of Economics and Business 76, Patission Street, Athens 104 34,
10
Corresponding author. International Food Policy Research Institute, 2033 K Street, NW
Greece
11
12
1
13
The optimal management of wetlands: quantifying trade-offs between flood risks, recreation and
14
biodiversity conservation
15
16
Abstract:
17
This paper employs a simple choice experiment to estimate the value of management options for
18
the Bobrek wetland in Poland. The local public’s valuation of several wetland management
19
attributes, including flood risk reduction, biodiversity conservation and improvement of
20
recreational access, are investigated. A latent class model is estimated to account for
21
heterogeneity in the preferences of the local public. The results reveal that there is considerable
22
preference heterogeneity among the local public; however on average they derive the highest
23
values from reductions in flooding risk. The results of this study are expected to assist policy
24
makers in undertaking effective flood risk reduction measures and formulating efficient,
25
equitable and sustainable wetland management policies in accordance with the European
26
Union’s Water Framework Directive (2000/60/EC).
27
28
Index terms: 6314 Demand estimation, 6324 Legislation and regulations (6615), 0497 Wetlands
29
(1890), 1821 Floods, 0410 Biodiversity
30
31
Keywords: choice experiment, latent class model, flood risk, biodiversity conservation,
32
recreation
33
2
34
1. Introduction
35
Flood risks and the effects of flooding episodes have re-emerged as an important natural hazard
36
concern in central and northern Europe since the 1990’s. These concerns have also been
37
exacerbated as a result of widespread and increasing awareness in global climate change, and
38
significant wetland loss. Global climate change and wetland loss are expected to increase the
39
frequency and extent of floods in the future (Nichols et al., 1999). These floods are expected to
40
cause significant changes in current land use and population patterns, and impose significant
41
economic damages. Contrary to flooding episodes in the past, recent floods in Europe have
42
milder effects in terms of loss of human life. Economic costs of flooding, however, are rapidly
43
increasing as a result of high costs of damages to infrastructure and production, and disruptions
44
to transport.
45
The estimated costs of the damages of the floods of 1997 and 2001 are in the region of
46
one billion USD for Poland, and 250 million USD for the surrounding countries (Brakenridge et
47
al, 1997; 2001). As a consequence of the increasing economic and social costs of floods,
48
European governments have taken a more active approach to flood risk reduction. The Bobrek
49
catchment in the Upper Silesia region of Poland is susceptible to flooding as a result of centuries-
50
long mining activities in this area, which has also had significant effects on its landscape. The
51
projected social, economic and environmental costs of predicted future flooding in this region are
52
extremely high. Paradoxically, land deformation caused by the mining industry and consequent
53
floods have had a beneficial consequence ecologically. Unique ecological habitats have been
54
formed in the flooded areas, harbouring important biodiversity riches that attract increasing
55
scientific interest in terms of their conservation. In addition to the various economic values that
3
56
these biodiversity-rich habitats generate (see for example Pearce and Moran, 1994; Christie et al,
57
2006), the wetland is also of high recreational value to local residents.
58
These habitats are, however, threatened by the current flood control policies, which are
59
based on the construction of artificial barriers and spoil heaps. Under current trends, levels of
60
biodiversity in these habitats will decline. Local authorities and the national government,
61
motivated by EU directives, are attempting to identify a balance between flood risk reduction
62
and biodiversity conservation in this wetland area. The EU is committed to conserving the
63
ecological status and especially the biodiversity riches in the wetlands under the Water
64
Framework Directive (WFD, 2000/60/EC). Article 1(a) of the WFD in particular calls for the
65
prevention of further deterioration of European wetlands, their protection and the enhancement
66
of their status. Wetland conservation is also provided for under the Birds Directive
67
(1979/409/EC) and the Habitats Directive (1992/43/EC).
68
This paper aims to contribute to the EU-wide debate over wetland conservation and flood
69
risk reduction policy, by using a simple choice experiment. The aim of the study is to quantify
70
the tradeoffs between flood risk reduction, biodiversity conservation and improvements in access
71
to the wetland for recreational purposes. The study explicitly accounts for local public’s
72
preference heterogeneity by analyzing choices using a Latent Class Model. To this end, stated
73
preferences over constructed alternatives; data on environmental attitudes, household level
74
social, economic and demographic characteristics, as well as data on households’ past
75
recreational activities in the wetland and flood damages suffered in the past are collected from
76
192 households located in the wetland catchment. Our main conclusion is that households derive
77
the highest benefits from a reduction in flood risks to a ‘low’ level. In terms of the value of
78
changes in attributes, flood risk reduction is followed by either improvements in access to the
4
79
wetland for recreational purposes, or by conservation of high levels of biodiversity, depending
80
on the latent class. These results have important repercussions for the design of efficient,
81
effective and equitable wetland management projects and policies.
82
The following section presents a brief review of the relevant literature. The theoretical
83
underpinnings of the choice experiment method and the econometric model estimated are
84
introduced in Section 3. Section 4 describes the case study and Section 5 explains the survey
85
design and administration. The results of the econometric estimation are reported in Section 6,
86
and the implications of the results are discussed. Section 7 concludes the paper with implications
87
for wetland management policy in the region.
88
89
2. Previous literature
90
A number of non-market valuation techniques have been employed to estimate the value of flood
91
risk reductions in Europe. Brouwer and van Ek (2004) employed an integrated impact
92
assessment method to estimate the benefits of flood risk reduction in the Netherlands. Ragkos et
93
al. (2006) carried out a contingent valuation study to estimate the value of flood control in the
94
Zazari-Cheimaditida Wetland in Greece. To our knowledge, however, no study has so far
95
employed the choice experiment method to estimate the benefits of flood risk reduction.
96
Previous choice experiment studies implemented in Europe have investigated the value of
97
conserving biodiversity, either in terms of its components (e.g., a certain species) (see for
98
example, Hanley et al., 2003; Horne and Petajisto, 2003; Bennett and Willis, 2007) or in terms of
99
conserving biodiversity as a part of a wider ecosystem (e.g., wetland or forests) (see for example,
100
Carlsson et al., 2003; Birol et al., 2006a; 2006b; Birol and Cox, 2007). In addition, Christie et al.
101
(2006) have used the method to estimate the relative importance of different aspects of
5
102
biodiversity to the general public. The choice experiment method has also been applied to
103
estimate recreational demand in Europe. For example, Hanley et al. (2002), employed a choice
104
experiment to model the demand for rock-climbing in Scotland, whilst Horne et al. (2005) used
105
this method to inform forest management at recreational sites in Finland (see Birol et al. (2008)
106
for a thorough review of the choice experiment studies undertaken in Europe).
107
108
3. The choice experiment method
109
The choice experiment method is a survey based non-market valuation method that has become
110
increasingly popular over the past decade for valuation of public goods and environmental
111
policies. The method involves creation of a hypothetical market and asks survey respondents to
112
perform sequential choices among different bundles, described in terms of the good’s
113
characteristics, or of policy characteristics. The theoretical basis for the choice experiment
114
method is therefore provided by Lancaster’s characteristics theory of value, according to which
115
demand is defined over the characteristics of the good rather than on the good itself (Lancaster,
116
1966). The econometric specification is derived under the assumption of random utility as a
117
theory of how people choose between discrete alternatives (Manski, 1977).
118
The conditional logit model has been the primary model for analyzing stated preference
119
data from choice experiments. However it has been recognised to have a major shortcoming
120
namely the fact that it imposes homogenous preferences for all respondents (unless these can be
121
adequately represented using interactions with observable socio-economic characteristics). To
122
take into account possible preference heterogeneity among respondents a number of models
123
alternative to the standard conditional logit model have been proposed. In this paper we employ
6
124
the Latent Class Model (LCM) to capture underlying preference heterogeneity within responses
125
to the choice questions.
126
In the LCM approach, preference heterogeneity is accounted for by a discrete distribution
127
over unobservable endogenous (latent) classes of respondents (Wedel and Kamakura, 2000).
128
Preferences are assumed to be homogeneous within each class but are allowed to differ across
129
classes. The population is thus represented as consisting of a finite number of segments, or
130
classes. Respondents are allocated to segments simultaneously with the analysis of choices. The
131
number of the segments is endogenously determined by the data while membership to a segment
132
depends probabilistically on the respondent’s observable socio-economic or attitudinal and
133
behavioural characteristics.
134
In the random utility framework for the LCM the utility a respondent i who belongs to
135
segment s derives from option j is given by
136
U ij s   s X ij   ij s
137
where  s is the segment specific vector of coefficients, X ij is the vector of attributes associated
138
with each alternative and  ij s is the random component of utility for each segment. Since the
139
vectors of coefficients differ between segments, preference heterogeneity across segments is
140
captured. Under the assumption of independently and identically distributed (iid) error terms that
141
follow a Type 1 extreme value distribution, the probability option j is selected by a respondent i
142
belonging to segment s is given by:
143
Prij s 
exp(  s X ij )
 exp( 
s
X ih )
(1)
(2)
h
144
Membership to a specific segment is determined by a likelihood function M that classifies
145
respondents to one of the segments with probability Pis . The membership likelihood function is
7
146
given by M is  a s Z i   is where Zi is a vector of socio-economic and other observed
147
characteristics of the respondent and ξis is an error term. Assuming that this error term is also iid
148
and follows a type 1 extreme value distribution, the probability that a respondent i belongs to
149
segment s is given by
150
Pris 
exp( a s Z i )
 exp( a s Z i )
(3)
s
151
The joint probability that individual i belongs to segment s and chooses alternative j is given by
152
Pijs  ( Pij / s ) * ( Pis )  [
exp(  s X ij )
 exp(  s X ih )
h
] [
exp( a s Z i )
]
 exp( as Z i )
(4)
s
153
154
4. The case study
155
The choice experiment study reported in this paper was implemented in the city of Sosnowiec,
156
located in the Bobrek catchment, in the Upper Silesia Region of Poland. The region is an
157
important industrial center located within the Upper Silesian Coal Basin. Five rivers run through
158
the wider area, including the Biala, Brynica, Jaworznik, Wielonka and Rawa, making the region
159
susceptible to flooding episodes (Figures 1 and 2).
160
Insert Figure 1 here
161
Insert Figure 2 here
162
The main economic activities in the area include heavy industry and mining with some
163
of the world’s largest bituminous coalmines located in the region. The mines are concentrated
164
close to the region’s rivers, and have ongoing impacts on their morphology. Mining activities
165
have been taking place in this area for over two centuries. Scientific evidence from Central
166
Mining Institute, Silesian University, AGH University of Science and Technology, and Krakow
8
167
University of Technology shows that the mining industry has significantly deformed the local
168
landscape and the riverbeds, thereby rendering the region extremely vulnerable to floods even
169
after light rainfall. Given the size of the local communities, it is estimated that approximately
170
50,000 individuals are currently at risk from flooding.
171
In 1992 the Polish government facilitated the construction of concrete barriers on the
172
rivers’ banks in order to minimize the risk of flooding in the region. Mining industries were
173
deemed responsible for protecting their mines by constructing spoil heaps on the rivers’ banks.
174
This plan, however, was not successful since it increased the speed of water flow, thereby
175
generating negative externalities for downstream communities. Moreover, recreational activities
176
in the catchment were limited as a result of the blocking of the river access by concrete barriers.
177
Furthermore, this policy was not successful in providing flood control as the extensive floods of
178
1997 and 2001 can attest.
179
The high economic and social costs of flooding episodes are borne mainly by the local
180
residents, but also by the overall national economy and the nearby countries. Despite these costs,
181
past floods have also brought about benefits: unique ecological wetland habitats have been
182
formed on those lands that have been flooded by the rivers. New species of both flora and fauna
183
have colonised these habitats. Ecologists recognise these biodiversity riches and assert that they
184
should be conserved. In addition, these habitats are now of high recreational value, with the
185
potential to serve as an attractive tourism destination. The ecological health of these habitats is
186
currently under threat from pollution caused by the spoil heaps created by the mining industry.
187
188
5. Survey design and administration
9
189
A choice experiment crucially relies on the definition of the good to be valued in terms of its
190
attributes and levels. The attributes need to be those that the public considers important regarding
191
the proposed policy change or resource, whilst attribute levels should be achievable with and
192
without a proposed policy change (Bateman et al., 2003). The good valued in this choice
193
experiment study is a “wetland management plan”. Following discussions with scientists from
194
the Central Mining Institute, the Silesian University, the AGH University of Science and
195
Technology and the Krakow University of Technology, and drawing on the results of focus
196
group discussions with randomly selected members of the local population, a simple
197
experimental design to include three wetland management plan attributes was chosen. These
198
were surface and underground flooding risks; biodiversity found in the wetland; and access to the
199
river bank for recreational purposes. All three of these attributes were specified to have one of
200
two levels.
201
The flood risk attribute refers to the predicted risk of flooding in the area in the next 10
202
years. At present, the risk of flooding is high. If, however, both underground and surface barriers
203
are improved, the flow of water will slow down and the risks of flooding will be reduced. The
204
materials proposed for this improvement are wood for surface barriers, and concrete for
205
underground ones. This choice of materials would not spoil the aesthetic beauty of the wetland.
206
The river access attribute refers to the public’s access to the riverbank for recreational purposes
207
(e.g., walking, cycling, fishing). At the moment access to the riverbank is difficult, as a result of
208
the concrete vertical walls that were built a few years earlier as an (unsuccessful) flood risk
209
reduction measure. If however, these concrete walls are demolished and the river is re-canalised
210
similarly to its natural state by using natural materials, such as wood rather than concrete, the
211
riverbank could easily be accessed for recreational purposes. Finally, the biodiversity attribute
10
212
refers to the number of different species of flora and fauna, their population levels, number of
213
different habitats and their size in the wetland ecosystem in the next ten years. As a result of past
214
flooding biodiversity levels have increased to higher levels than before. Present regulations,
215
however do not protect this biodiversity, as they allow mining companies to create spoil heaps
216
and discharge mine drainage water into the river. This practice poses a considerable threat to the
217
newly formed habitats, and it is expected to decrease the biodiversity levels to a low level within
218
the next ten years. If, however, mining companies are prohibited from creating spoil heaps and if
219
in addition reclamation activities, such as afforestation take place, biodiversity levels can reach a
220
higher level in the next ten years.
221
The attributes described above represent an adequate simplification of the aspects of
222
wetland management in this particular case study. Wetland management will be affected by the
223
permitted extent of flooding. In other words the area and quality of the wetland habitats are the
224
immediate effects of the extent of flooding. Furthermore the design of the flood defences will
225
have impacts on the level of biodiversity that the wetland habitat will be able to support. The
226
same flood defences will define the nature of the recreational activities and the degree of access
227
to the wetland.
228
The payment vehicle used was a percentage change in the local taxes paid by the
229
households in the next ten years. A percentage change in the household’s present tax level was
230
preferred over fixed changes in the tax levels, since the former allows for a continuous monetary
231
variable. Furthermore, allowing for higher and lower tax levels compared to the status quo level
232
enables understanding of whether the households are willing to pay to have higher/lower levels
233
of these attributes or willing to accept compensation to let go higher/lower levels of these.
234
Finally, taxation was preferred as a payment vehicle over voluntary donations since households
11
235
may have the incentives to free-ride with the latter (Whitehead, 2006). Table 1 summarizes the
236
definition of the attributes and their levels.
237
Insert Table 1 here
238
Using experimental design techniques (Louviere et al., 2000) an orthogonalization
239
procedure was used. This procedure resulted in a simple choice experiment design which
240
consisted of 32 pair-wise comparisons of wetland management plans. These were randomly
241
blocked into four versions, each containing eight choice sets consisting of two wetland
242
management plans and an opt-out alternative, which represented the status quo, in which case no
243
management actions would be undertaken and tax rates would not change. Inclusion of the status
244
quo or another baseline scenario is important for the welfare interpretation of choice experiment
245
estimates and for their consistency with demand theory (Louviere et al., 2000; Bennett and
246
Blamey, 2001; Bateman et al., 2003).
247
Insert Figure 3 here
248
The choice experiment survey was implemented in March and April 2007 in the city of
249
Sosnowiec, using in-house face-to-face interviews. Time and budget constraints allowed for a
250
sample of 200 households from the local population. A quota sample was collected and the
251
survey was administered to be representative of the local population in terms of income and
252
geographical distribution (i.e., distance from the river). Those household members who took
253
part in the survey were by and large those who were the main household decision makers. In
254
total 96 percent of those approached, i.e., 192 households agreed to be interviewed.
255
The choice experiment survey started with the enumerators reading a statement
256
identifying the current issues in the area regarding flood risks, biodiversity conservation and use
257
of the riverbank for recreational activities. Subsequently the households were presented with a
12
258
description of the attributes used in the choice experiment and they were asked to state their
259
preferred wetland management plan among three such plans in eight choice sets. Overall a total
260
of 1536 choices were elicited from 192 households.
261
Data were also collected on the households’ social, demographic and economic
262
characteristics, as well as information on whether the household uses the riverbank for
263
recreational activities, and on flooding episodes that have affected the household in the past
264
decade. Descriptive statistics for the key variables are presented in Table 2.
265
Insert Table 2 here
266
Even though on average households are located almost half a kilometre (462 meters)
267
away from the river, almost 13% have been flooded an average of 2.5 times in the past decade.
268
The total average damages suffered by flooded households in the past ten years is 7115.8 zloty
269
(€1871), and for some as high as 25000 zloty (€6574). Less than a third of these flooded
270
households have been compensated, most of whom (49%) by the mining industry, some (28%)
271
by the government and a minority (13%) by an insurance company. Over a half of the sample are
272
regular visitors of the riverbanks and rivers. They stated that they engage in a wide array of
273
recreational activities ranging from walking and sailing to appreciating its aesthetic beauty and
274
bird watching, as well as for educational purposes. 66.7% of the respondents stated that they
275
would like to visit the wetland in the future to engage in recreational activities.
276
In addition to these social, economic, demographic, flood related and present and future
277
recreational wetland use data, several attitudinal and behavioural questions were asked in order
278
to understand respondents’ behaviour and consciousness with regards to environmental issues.
279
Households’ actual environmental behaviour was assessed via questions eliciting their purchase
280
of organic produce, environmental publications and fair-trade products; their donations to
13
281
environmental organisations, and shopping at environmentally friendly shops. These were
282
measured on a five point scale ranging from “never” to “always” and an environmental
283
behaviour index (EBI), ranging from 5 to 20, was calculated. The level of the respondents’
284
environmental consciousness was measured through questions eliciting how concerned they are
285
with regards to several environmental issues such as the scarcity of environmental resources,
286
ecological crisis, human interference with the environment and the current situation of wetlands
287
in Poland. An environmental consciousness index (ECI) was calculated by using a Likert scale
288
which ranged from 5 to 30. The sample averages for ECI and EBI are also reported in Table 2.
289
290
6. Results
291
6.1. Latent class model
292
In addition to the Latent Class Model (LCM) the data were also analysed by random parameter
293
logit (RPL) model, which accounts for unobserved, unconditional heterogeneity at the individual
294
level, and also by Covariance Heterogeneity (Cov Het) model, which investigates heterogeneity
295
in the random component of utility. Ben-Akiva and Swait (1986) test for comparing non-nested
296
probabilistic choice models is employed to investigate whether RPL model, Cov Het model or
297
the LCM is the true specification for this data set. The idea behind this test is to examine whether
298
the systematic preference heterogeneity in this particular data set can be better explained at the
299
individual level or at the segment level. The Ben-Akiva and Swait test results rejects the null
300
hypothesis that the RPL and Cov Het models are the true specification. Similar to Birol et al.
301
(2006b) and Colombo and Hanley (2007), preference heterogeneity in this specific data set is
302
better explained at the segment level that at the individual level.
14
303
In the best fitting Latent Class Model (LCM) the heterogeneity among segments is
304
captured by social and economic variables indicating whether the household’s property has been
305
flooded in the past; whether the household visits the rivers for recreational purposes; whether the
306
household has a child living in the household and whether the respondent has a university
307
degree. The LCM was estimated with 2, 3, 4 and 5 segments. The log likelihood, 2, Bozdogan
308
Akaike Information Criterion (AIC3) and Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC) statistics were
309
computed for each of the models and are reported in Table 3.
310
Insert Table 3 here
311
Determination of the optimal numbers of segments requires a balanced assessment of the
312
statistics reported in Table 3 (Louviere et al. 2000; Wedel and Kamakura 2000; Andrews and
313
Currim 2003). The log likelihood decreases and 2 increases as more segments are added,
314
indicating the presence of multiple segments in the sample. The BIC and AIC3 statistics decrease
315
monotonically as the number of segments increases, but for all four statistics, the marginal effect
316
becomes very small after the three-segment model. The BIC statistic is minimized at three
317
segments, indicating that a model with three segments is the optimal solution in this empirical
318
application. AIC3, on the other hand is minimized at the five segments. Andrews and Currim
319
(2003) have demonstrated that the BIC and AIC3 statistics never under-fit the number of
320
segments but may sometimes over-fit, and that over-fitting the true number of segments produces
321
larger parameter bias (Andrews and Currim 2003). Moreover, when respondents where assigned
322
to each segment, none was allocated to the third segment. Therefore, we chose the two-segment
323
model, as shown in Table 4.
324
Insert Table 4 here
15
325
The first part of Table 4 displays the utility coefficients associated with the wetland
326
management plan attributes, while the second part reflects the coefficients for membership in the
327
various segments. The membership coefficients for the second segment are normalized to zero,
328
allowing us to identify the remaining coefficients of the model. All other coefficients are
329
interpreted relative to this normalized segment (Boxall and Adamowicz 2002).
330
For segment one, the utility coefficients reveal that all of the wetland management plan
331
attributes are significant determinants of choice. Respondents in this segment prefer those
332
wetland management plans which provide lower levels of flood risk, and easy riverbank access.
333
The coefficient on flood risk reduction is twice that of easier access to the riverbank for
334
recreational purposes (although recall that these attribute levels are qualitatively described). The
335
coefficient on ASC is insignificant, whereas the coefficient on tax is negative and significant as
336
expected a priori. The segment membership coefficients for this segment reveal that having been
337
flooded at least once in the past, having visited the wetland for recreational activities and having
338
a university degree decreases the probability of a given respondent belonging to this first
339
segment. Interestingly, these respondents seem to prefer lower levels of biodiversity to higher
340
levels.
341
For the second segment the ranking of the attributes and the sign of some of their effects
342
on utility change. All the estimated coefficients for the second segment are statistically
343
significant. The positive and significant ASC points to the possible existence of status quo bias
344
(Adamowicz et al., 1998). Respondents in this segment are more likely to choose wetland
345
management plans which reduce flood risk, and generate high levels of biodiversity conservation
346
and easier riverbank access. The coefficient on the flood risk attribute is the largest, indicating
347
that this attribute is the most important determinant of wetland management plan choice. This
16
348
attribute is followed by biodiversity and riverbank access in order of magnitude (again, with the
349
caveat that these level changes are qualitative). The segment membership coefficients of this
350
segment can be implicitly interpreted in relation to the signs of the estimated statistically
351
significant parameters for segment one. Consequently, households who have been flooded in the
352
past, as well as those with a university degree and those who visit the wetland for recreational
353
purposes are more likely to belong to this segment.
354
The relative size of each segment is estimated by inserting the estimated coefficients into
355
equation (3), which generates a series of probabilities that a given household belongs to each of
356
the two segments. Households are then assigned to a segment based on the largest probability
357
score among the three segments. Using this procedure, we find that 62.5% of the sample belongs
358
to the first segment and 37.5% to the second. Descriptive statistics for the characteristics of each
359
segment are given in Table 5.
360
Insert Table 5 here
361
Respondents in the first segment have a significantly higher environmental behaviour
362
index (EBI), although the environmental consciousness index (ECI) is not statistically
363
significantly different across the two segments. Households in segment one have significantly
364
lower income levels and pay significantly less local taxes than those in the second segment. In
365
segment two, respondents, who are the main household decision makers, are more likely to have
366
a university degree, which might explain their higher household income levels. In addition,
367
households in segment one are less likely to own their own home and cars, which might explain
368
the lower levels of local taxes they pay. Households in the second segment are larger, though the
369
percentage of households with at least one child does not significantly differ across the two
370
segments. The two segments’ average distances to the rivers do not statistically significantly
17
371
differ, however those households in segment two are more likely to visit the wetland for
372
recreational purposes (both at present and in the future), and also more likely to have had their
373
property flooded at least once in the past.
374
375
6.2. Welfare estimates for wetland management plan attributes
376
The choice experiment method is consistent with utility maximization and demand theory
377
(Bateman et al. 2003). Compensating surplus (CS) welfare measure for changes in the wetland
378
management plan attributes can be derived from the estimated parameters by using the following
379
formula (Hanemann, 1984; Bateman et al., 2003).:
ln  exp(Vi1 )  ln  exp(Vi 0 )
380
CS 
381
where ,  localtax, the coefficient on the monetary attribute, gives the marginal utility of income and
382
Vi 0 and Vi1 represent indirect utility functions before and after policy change under
383
consideration.
i
i
(8)
 localtax
384
The marginal value of change in a single wetland management plan attribute can be
385
estimated as a ratio of coefficients. The ratio represents the marginal rate of substitution between
386
local tax and the wetland management plan attribute in question, or the marginal welfare
387
measure (willingness to pay (WTP)) for a change in any of the attributes:
388
 2 x attribute 

WTP  

 localtax 
389
where  attribute is the coefficient on the river management attributes (level of flood risk,
390
biodiversity and river access). This coefficient on the wetland management plan attributes are
391
multiplied by two since their binary levels were effects coded (see, Hu et al., 2004).
(9)
18
392
Table 6 reports the implicit prices, or marginal WTP values, for each of the wetland
393
management plan attributes estimated using the Wald procedure (Delta method) in LIMDEP 8.0
394
NLOGIT 3.0. For comparison purposes, WTP estimates are reported for the two segments of the
395
LCM, as well as for the weighted average of these two segments. Poe et al. (1994) convolutions
396
process reveals that WTP estimates for the two segments are different at the 95% confidence
397
level.. The ranking of attributes also differs across the two segments. Therefore the distributional
398
impacts of benefits generated by wetland management plan attributes should be taken into
399
consideration.
400
Table 6 here
401
The implicit prices reported in Table 6 do not provide estimates of CS for the alternative
402
management scenarios. In order to estimate the households’ CS for improvements in wetland
403
management over the status quo, three possible management scenarios are created:
404
405
406
407
408
409
Scenario 0- Status quo, this is the baseline situation where the flood risk level is high,
biodiversity level is low and the access to the river for recreational purposes is difficult.
Scenario 1- In this scenario flood risk is reduced to a low level and the access to the
riverbank for recreational purposes is improved.
Scenario 2- In this scenario conservation actions are undertaken to generate a high level
of biodiversity, while access to the riverbank for recreational purposes is improved.
410
Scenario 3- In this scenario flood risk is reduced to a low level, conservation actions are
411
undertaken to generate a high level of biodiversity and the access to the riverbank for
412
recreational purposes is improved.
413
CS estimates for these scenarios are reported in Table 7. These estimates reveal local
414
households’ average WTP in terms of higher local taxes to move from the status quo (Scenario
19
415
0) to Scenarios 1, 2 and 3. Similarly to the single attribute estimates reported above, the CS
416
estimates for the two segments, as well as for the weighted average of the two segments differ
417
significantly at the 95% confidence level. These findings highlight the necessity to take social
418
equity issues into account while designing wetland management plans.
419
Insert Table 7 here
420
As indicated in Table 7, the highest welfare improvement, i.e. CS, for respondents in the
421
first segment is generated by the first management scenario, followed by the third and second
422
management scenarios, respectively. Specifically the welfarem improvements for households in
423
the first segment is 9.4 zloty per month for the first scenario, 6.9 zloty per month for the third
424
scenario and 0.7 zloty per month for the second scenario. This indicates that the welfare of
425
households in the first segment is improved the most under reduced flood risk and easier access
426
to the wetland’s recreational amenities, while the lowest improvement in welfare results from
427
improving biodiversity level and wetland access. For respondents in the second segment the
428
improvement in welfare is the highest for the third scenario (161.6 zloty per month), which
429
proposes to reduce flood risk while improving biodiversity. On the other hand, at 73.4 zloty per
430
month, the second scenario which proposes to improve biodiversity and wetland access while
431
maintaining high flood risk, generates the lowest impact on welfare.
432
The welfare estimates reported in Table 7 indicate that the primary policy
433
recommendation resulting from this particular case study is the reduction of flood risk to a low
434
level. If the target is to maximize aggregate welfare, then flood risk reduction should be coupled
435
with improving biodiversity. The implementation of this scenario (scenario 3) requires a
436
compromise between the protection of human settlements and livelihoods from potential floods,
437
and the conservation of the biodiversity rich wetland habitats.
20
438
439
7. Conclusions and policy implications
440
This paper reports the results of a choice experiment study undertaken in the Bobrek wetland,
441
located in the Upper Silesia region of Poland. The aim of this study was to investigate the local
442
public’s preferences for alternative wetland management scenarios, defined by their impacts on
443
flood risk, biodiversity conservation and riverbank access for recreational purposes. The data are
444
analysed with the Latent Class Model (LCM) which enabled capturing of heterogeneity in the
445
local public’s preferences at the segment level.
446
The results reveal that the population consists of two different segments. Overall the
447
local public derives the highest values (that is economic benefits) from flood risk reduction. This
448
result is not surprising considering that the catchment area is susceptible to flooding episodes, as
449
extensive floods of 1997 and 2001 and the social and economic damages these have caused can
450
attest.
451
There is however considerable heterogeneity with regards to the local public’s valuation
452
of biodiversity conservation and improvements in access to the riverbank for recreational
453
purposes. The ranking of these two attributes changes depending on the segment. The first
454
segment derives negative values from biodiversity attribute, i.e. this segment would need to be
455
compensated if the wetland management plan were to generate higher levels of biodiversity.
456
There are therefore important distributional equity issues that need to be taken into consideration
457
while designing wetland conservation and flood risk reduction plans.
458
Compensating surplus (CS) measures for different wetland management scenarios are
459
also calculated for the two segments and for the weighted average of the two segments. The
460
results reveal that according to the weighted average, the local public are WTP the most for a
21
461
wetland management scenario that reduces flooding risk, generates higher levels of biodiversity
462
conservation as well as easy access to the riverbank for recreational purposes. The estimated CS
463
for this scenario is as much as 161.6 zloty per household per month, which is almost 88% of the
464
current monthly local taxes paid by an average household in the area. Overall the main finding
465
of this study is that the primary policy goal should be the reduction of flood risk, however in
466
order to maximise total social welfare, a compromise should be reached between reducing flood
467
risk and conserving biodiversity rich wetland habitats.
468
The European Union's Water Framework Directive (WFD) requires regulators to
469
compare benefits and costs in terms of whether waters should be designated as “heavily
470
modified”, and thus qualify for lower environmental targets than “Good Ecological Status”. The
471
estimated benefits generated by the wetland management plan attributes should be compared to
472
their costs, in order to investigate which one of the wetland management plans introduced in this
473
study would improve total net welfare in this region of Poland. With the use of the benefits
474
transfer method, this study could also provide policy-makers with useful information for the
475
management of other similar wetlands in Poland, as well as in Europe, given the current mandate
476
under the WFD.
477
22
478
479
8. Acknowledgements
480
We gratefully acknowledge the European Union's financial support through the AQUASTRESS
481
project under the 6th Framework Programme. We would like to thank Elzbieta Druzynska and
482
Andrzej Potocki for valuable comments, suggestions and fruitful discussions. We would also like
483
to thank Haris Gianniakidis and Nickolaos Syrigos for their assistance in data collection.
484
23
485
9. References
486
Adamowicz, W., P. Boxall, M. Williams, and J. Louviere (1998), Stated preference approaches
487
for measuring passive use values: choice experiments and contingent valuation. American
488
Journal of Agricultural Economics, 80: 64-75.
489
Andrews, R.L., and I.S. Currim (2003), A comparison of segment retention criteria for finite
490
mixture logit models. Journal of Marketing Research, 40 (2): 235-243.
491
Bateman, I.J., R.T. Carson, B. Day, W. M. Hanemann, N. Hanley, T. Hett, M. Jones-Lee, G.
492
Loomes, S. Mourato, E. Ozdemiroglu, D.W. Pearce, R. Sugden, and S. Swanson (2003),
493
Guidelines for the Use of Stated Preference Techniques for the Valuation of Preferences for
494
Non-market Goods. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
495
Ben-Akiva, M. E., and J. D. Swait (1986), The akaike likelihood ratio index. Transportation
496
Science, 20: 133-136.
497
Bennett, J.J., and R.K. Blamey (2001). The Choice of Modelling Approach to Environmental
498
Valuation. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
499
Bennett, R., and K. Willis (2007),
500
Tuberculosis in Cattle in England and Wales: A Note. Journal of Agricultural Economics,
501
58(1): 152-156.
502
Birol E., M. Smale, and A. Gyovai (2006a), Using a choice experiment to estimate farmers'
503
valuation of agrobiodiversity on Hungarian small farms. Environmental and Resource
504
Economics, 34(4): 439-469.
505
Birol, E., K. Karousakis, and P. Koundouri (2006b), Using a choice experiment to account for
506
preference heterogeneity in wetland attributes: The case of Cheimaditida wetland in Greece.
507
Ecological Economics, 60: 145-156.
The Value of Badger Populations and Control of
24
508
Birol, E., and V. Cox (2007), Using Choice Experiments to Design Wetland Management
509
Programmes: The Case of Severn Estuary Wetland, UK. Journal of Environmental Planning and
510
Management, 50(3): 363-380.
511
Birol, E., P. Koundouri, and Y. Kountouris (2008), Applications of the choice experiment
512
method in Europe: A review. In E. Birol and P. Koundouri (Editors), Choice experiments
513
informing environmental policy: A European Perspective. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
514
Boxall, P.C., and. W. L. Adamowicz (2002), Understanding heterogeneous preferences in
515
random utility models: A latent class approach. Environmental and Resource Economics, 23:
516
421-446.
517
Brakenridge, G.R., E. Anderson, and S. Caquard (1997), Flood Archive table 1997. Dartmouth
518
Flood Observatory, Hanover, USA, digital media,
519
http://www.dartmouth.edu/~floods/Archives/1997sum.htm
520
Brakenridge, G.R., E. Anderson, and S. Caquard (2001) Flood Archive table 2001, Dartmouth
521
Flood Observatory, Hanover, USA, digital media,
522
http://www.dartmouth.edu/~floods/Archives/2001sum.htm
523
Brouwer, R., and R. van Ek (2004), Integrated ecological, economic and social impact
524
assessment of alternative flood control policies in the Netherlands. Ecological Economics, 50:1-
525
21.
526
Brouwer, R., S. Akter, L. Brander, and E. Haque (2007), Socioeconomic Vulnerability and
527
Adaptation to Environmental Risk: A Case Study of Climate Change and Flooding in
528
Bangladesh. Risk Analysis, 27: 313-326.
529
Carlsson, F., P. Frykblom, and C. Liljenstolpe (2003), Valuing wetland attributes: an application
530
of choice experiments. Ecological Economics, 47: 95-103.
25
531
Christie M., N. Hanley, J. Warren, K. Murphy, R.Wright, and T. Hyde (2006), Valuing the
532
diversity of biodiversity. Ecological Economics, 58(2): 304-317.
533
Colombo S., and N. Hanley (2007), Modelling preference heterogeneity in stated choice data for
534
environmental
535
www.economics.stir.ac.uk.
536
Greene, W.H. (1997), Econometric Analysis. Fourth Edition, Prentice Hall.
537
Hanley, N., R. Wright and W. Adamowicz (1998), Using Choice Experiments to Value the
538
Environment. Environmental and Resource Economics, 11(3-4), 413-428.
539
Hanley N., R.E. Wright, and G. Koop (2002), Modelling recreation demand using choice
540
experiments: rock climbing in Scotland. Environmental and Resource Economics, 22: 449-466.
541
Hanley, N., D. MacMillan, I. Patterson, and R. Wright (2003), Economics and Design of Nature
542
Conservation Policy: A Case Study of Wild Goose Conservation In Scotland Using Choice
543
Experiments. Animal Conservation, 6:123-129.
544
Hanley, N., S. Colombo, H. Johns, and P. Mason (2007), The reform of support mechanisms for
545
upland farming: paying for public goods in the Severely Disadvantaged Areas of England.
546
Journal of Agricultural Economics, 58 (3), 433-453.
547
Hanemann, W.M. (1984), Welfare Evaluations in Contingent Valuation Experiments with
548
Discrete Responses. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 71(4): 1057-1061.
549
Hensher, D., J. Rose, and W. Greene (2005), Applied Choice Analysis: A Primer. Cambridge
550
University Press.
551
Horne P., and L. Petajisto (2003), Preferences for alternative moose management regimes among
552
Finnish landowners: A choice experiment approach. Land Economics, 79(4): 472-482.
goods.
Discussion
papers
in
Economics,
University
of
Stirling.
26
553
Horne, P., P.C. Boxall, and W.L. Adamowicz (2005), Multiple-use management of forest
554
recreation sites: a spatially explicit choice experiment. Forest Ecology and Management, 207:
555
189-199.
556
Hu, W., A. Hünnemeyer, M. Veeman, W. L. Adamowicz, and L. Srivastava (2004), Trading off
557
health, environmental and genetic modification attributes in food. European Review of
558
Agricultural Economics, 31: 389-408.
559
Lancaster, K. (1966), A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of Political Economics, 74,
560
217–231.
561
Louviere, J.J., D. Hensher, J. Swait, and W. Adamowicz (2000), Stated Choice Methods:
562
Analysis and Applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
563
Manski, C. (1977), The Structure of Random Utility Models. Theory and Decision, 8:229-254.
564
Nicholls, R.J., F. Hoozemans, and M. Marchand (1999), Increasing flood risks and wetland
565
losses due to global sea-level rise: regional and global analyses. Global Environmental Change,
566
9: S69-S87.
567
Pearce, D. and D. Moran (1994), The Economic Value of Biodiversity. Earthscan, London.
568
Poe, G. L., E.K. Severance-Lossin, and M.P. Welsh (1994), Measuring the difference (X-Y) of
569
simulated distributions: a convolutions approach. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
570
76: 904 – 915.
571
Ragkos, A., A. Psychoudakis, A. Christofi, and A. Theodoridis (2006), Using a functional
572
approach to wetland valuation: the case of Zazari-Cheimaditida. Regional Environmental
573
Change, 6: 193-200.
574
Wedel, M., and W. Kamakura (2000), Market segmentation: Conceptual and methodological
575
foundations. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.
27
576
Whitehead, J.C. (2006), A practitioner's primer on contingent valuation. In: A. Alberini and J.
577
Kahn (Editors), Contingent Valuation Handbook. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham.
578
28
579
580
9. Tables
581
582
Table 1: Selected wetland management plan attributes, their definitions and levels
Attribute
Definition
Levels
Flood Risk
Risk of flooding in the area in the next 10 years
Low, High*
Riverbank Access
Public’s access to the riverbank for recreational Easy, Difficult
purposes in the next 10 years
Biodiversity
Number of different species of plants and animals, Low, High
their population levels, number of different habitats
and their size in the wetland ecosystem in the next
10 years.
Local Tax
Percentage change in the monthly local tax paid by -10%, -5%, 0, +5%
every household in the area in the next 10 years
583
+10%
*Status quo attribute levels are underlined
584
29
585
586
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of respondents and their households, Sample Size=192
Household and respondent level characteristics
Mean (s.d.)
Age of the respondent (in years)
45.6 (16.2)
Household size
Monthly gross household income (in zloty)
2.8 (1.1)
2478.1 (1253)
Monthly household local tax (in zloty)
183.9 (11.8)
Household’s distance from the river in meters
462 (249.8)
Number of flood episodes suffered in the last decade
2.52 (2.99)
Total damages to the household from floods in the last decade (in
7115.8 (6611)
zloty)
Percentage
Respondent with a University degree and above
26
Household with at least one child
70.8
Household uses the riverbank for recreational purposes
54.6
Household would like to use the riverbank in the future for
66.7
recreational purposes
587
Household’s property flooded
13
Flooded households compensated
28
Source: Upper Silesia River Management Choice Experiment, 2007
588
30
589
590
Table 3: Selection of Number of Segments
Number of
Number of
Log
Segments
Parameters
Likelihood
ρ2
AIC3
BIC
(LL)
1
5
-1498.71
0.11186
3012.414
1517.049
2
14
-1359.11
0.19458
2760.226
1410.472
3
23
-1274.58
0.24468
2618.156
1358.953
4
32
-1246.46
0.26134
2588.918
1363.850
5
41
-1227.49
0.27258
2577.982
1377.898
591
The sample size is 1536 choices from 192 households (N); ρ2 is calculated as 1-(LL)/LL(0);
592
AIC3 (Bozdogan AIC) is (-2LL+3P); BIC (Bayesian Information Criterion) is –LL+(P/2)*ln(N).
593
31
594
595
Table 4. Two-segment LCM estimates for wetland management plan attributes
Segment 1
Segment 2
Utility function: Wetland management plan attributes
Coeff. (s.e.)
ASC
-0.150 (0.105)
1.267***(0.130)
Flood Risk
0.288***(0.057)
0.550***(0.039)
Biodiversity
-0.116**(0.054)
0.255***(0.037)
Riverbank Access
0.149***(0.058)
0.192***(0.040)
Local Tax
-0.093***(0.005)
-0.008***(0.003)
Segment membership function: Household and respondent
characteristics
Constant
0.660* (0.380)
-
-2.310*** (0.874)
-
Recreationalist
-0.616*(0.356)
-
University degree
-0.709* (0.393)
-
Child
-0.073 (0.378)
-
Property Flooded
Log Likelihood
-1359.113
ρ2
0.195
Observations
1536
596
Source: Upper Silesia River Management Choice Experiment, 2007.
597
Two-tailed tests showed 10% (*), 5% (**) and 1% (***) significance levels.
598
599
32
600
Table 5. Characteristics of the households belonging to the two segments
Respondent Characteristics
Segment 1
Segment 2
Mean. (s.d.)
ECI
15.392
(2.511)
13.694 (3.045)
EBI
16.289
(2.424)
16.551 (2.131)
Age
46.483 (17.057)
44.222 (14.516)
Local tax *
172.660 (112.762)
202.539 (109.504)
Income***
2189.46 (1006.764)
Household size*
2.683
(1.0956)
Distance from the
466.75
(244.396)
2959.062
3
(1451.881)
(1.163)
454.167 (256.815)
catchment
Percentage
University degree***
0
69.4
Child
68.3
75
Own Home***
50.8
83.3
Own Car**
59.2
73.6
Property Flooded***
0
34.7
Recreationalists***
47.5
66.7
Future visit***
63.3
72.2
Sample size
120
72
601
Source: Upper Silesia River Management Choice Experiment, 2007
602
T-tests and Pearson Chi square tests show significant differences among the segments at (*)10%
603
significance level; (**) at 5% significance level, and (***) at 1% significance level.
604
33
605
Table 6. Marginal willingness to pay (implicit prices) and 95% confidence intervals for river
606
management attributes (all figures are in zloty per household per month).
Attribute
Flood Risk
Biodiversity
Riverbank
access
607
LCM
608
Segment 1
Segment 2
Weighted
6.194
137.5
88.26
(4.714-7.04)
(92.9-235.6)
-2.495
63.75
42.17
(-3.864- -1.265)
(39.864-116.8)
612
(23.466-72.526)
3.204
48
31.202
(2.469-4.705)
(27.636-92.8)
614
(18.199-59.764)
609
610
(59.83-149.86)
611
613
615
616
Source: Upper Silesia River Management Choice Experiment, 2007.
617
Welfare measures are calculated with the Delta method of the Wald
618
procedure contained within LIMDEP 8.0 NLOGIT 3.0.
619
620
34
621
Table 7. Compensating surplus and 95% confidence intervals for three river management
622
scenarios (all figures are in zloty per household per month).
Attribute
Scenario 1
Scenario 2
Scenario 3
623
LCM
Segment 1
Segment 2
Weighted
9.4
185.5
119.5
(7.2- 11.8)
(120.5- 328.4)
0.7
111.8
(-1.4- 3.4)
(67.5-209.6)
6.9
249.3
(3.3- 10.5)
(160.4- 445.2)
624
625
626
(78- 209.6)
73.4
627
628
(41.7-132.3)
161.6
629
630
(101.5- 282.2)
631
632
Source: Upper Silesia River Management Choice Experiment, 2007.
633
634
635
636
35
637
10. Figures
638
639
Figure 1. Location of the study site in Poland
640
641
642
643
644
645
646
Upper Silesia
647
648
Sosnowiec
649
650
651
652
36
653
Figure 2. Map of the Bobrek catchment
654
655
Source: Krakow University of Technology, (Elzbieta Druzynska, Personal
656
communication, 2007)
657
37
658
Figure 3. Example choice set
Assuming that the following three wetland management plans were the only choices you
had, which one would you prefer?
Management plan
Characteristics
Management plan
Management plan
Neither
A
B
Management plan:
Status Quo
Flood risk
Low
Low
High
Biodiversity
Low
High
Low
River access
Difficult
Easy
Difficult
5% decrease
5% decrease
Same as now
Management plan
Management plan
Neither management
A
B
plan
Monthly local tax
I prefer
(Please tick as appropriate)
659
660
38
Download