(1) Explain what is meant by the GDP share of Health Expenditure. Taken from course link article: Health Expenditure in Canada 1: Looking at the Numbers (2001-0 According to the Canadian Institute for Health Information (CIHI), in 1998, health spending in Canada was about $2600 per capita. That figure includes more than just the costs of physician and hospital care: about 14% of it goes for physician services, 34% for hospital care and another 14% goes for drugs, totalling 62% of the total and leaving 38% for other items. The other items include other professionals (dentists, denturists, optometrists, opticians, chiropractors, massage therapists, naturopaths, osteopaths and private duty nurses), about 12% of the total, other institutions (homes for the aged, facilities for people with alcohol and drug problems) for about 7% of the total, capital spending (about 3% of the total) and a broad “other spending” category, accounting for 13% of the total and including spending on public health, health research, home care, ambulances, hearing aids, training of health workers, occupational health programs designed to promote workplace health and safety. Even the drugs category includes both prescription and over the counter drugs, plus personal health products such as oral hygiene products. Page 7 bottom, Page 9 has some additional information Figure 11 shows, for the period 1960-98, the share of each country’s Gross Domestic Product which it devotes to total health expenditure. Since Canada and the US use similar definitions and similar accounting conventions in calculating their health expenditure series, Canadian and American series are among the most directly comparable of all international series5. In calculating the share of GDP devoted to health, we simply take total health expenditure in each country in each year and divide it by that country’s annual GDP series. (2) Discuss the relation between Canada’s health GDP share and that of the USA. Why has this graph been interpreted as showing the effect of the introduction of Canadian Medicare on Canadian health care costs? (3) Explain how you analyze the change over time in a GDP share figure. (4) Discuss why it is sometimes useful to plot the natural log of a variable like GDP share against time. Relate this to your answer to Q 3. The natural log is plotted on the vertical axis with time located on the horizontal axis. It allows you to create a graph that displays the rate of change per unit of time. The slope of the line is the annual rate of increase, which has always been the case for GDP share of health expenditure. In this sort of graph it allows you to compare rates of growth with straight lines. If you were not to use natural logs you would have to compare rates of growth using rates of curvature or curved lines. Instead using natural logs makes it easier to compare the slopes of straight lines than cuved ones. If the line is steep the rate of growth is going upward, and if the line is horizontal their is no rate of growth. (Still need to relate to Question #3) A logarithmic transformation of a time series data set has the attractive feature that the slope of the graph between any two points shows the percentage rate of increase between the two points, which means that in any periods in which the two countries’ lines have the same slope, the rate of growth of their real per capita GDP series was the same. This relates to Q3 because it helps compare the growth rates of healthcare share of GDP of the two countries while holding the effects of exchange rate and overall GDP size. -Partially taken from: Expenditure on Medical Care in Canada: Looking at the Numbers Brian S. Ferguson Department of Economics University of Guelph Guelph, Ontario Canada September, 2001 (5) Using the results of the previous questions, discuss the factors which affected Canada’s health GDP share from the 1960's to the early 1990s. (6) Comment on the funding of Canadian Medicare from the 1960s to the late 1990s. Funding for the insurance plans comes from the general revenues of the Canadian provinces/territories, assisted by transfer payments from the federal government through the Canada Health Transfer. Some provinces charge health care premiums, but these are in effect taxes (since they are not tied to service use, nor to provincial health expenditures). The system is accordingly classified by the OECD as a tax-supported system, as opposed to the social insurance approaches used in many European countries. Currently, patients do not pay out of pocket costs to visit their doctor. Boards in each province regulate the cost, which is then reimbursed by the federal government. The initial funding agreement for Medicare was 50-50, with federal and provincial governments sharing the cost. In 1977, the federal government dropped its share of medical funding to 20 percent. In Canada, the government pays 70 percent of medical costs, while individuals and private insurance companies pay the rest. (This proportion is reversed in the United States.) 1960 - The Canadian Medical Association opposes all publicly funded health care. 1965 - A Royal Commission appointed by Diefenbaker government and headed by Justice Emmett Hall calls for a universal and comprehensive national health insurance program. 1966 - Pearson minority government creates a national Medicare program (Medical Care Act of 1966) with Ottawa paying 50% of provincial health costs. Prior to this point, doctors charged whatever they wanted and bankruptcy to pay for health care was common. Now citizens would receive portable, comprehensive and universal access to necessary physician and hospital services, regardless of ability to pay. 1977 - Trudeau Liberals retreat from 50:50 cost-sharing and replace it with block funding. 1978 - Doctors begin “extra-billing” to raise their incomes. 1984 - Canada Health Act introduced by Trudeau’s health minister, Monique Begin, is passed unanimously by parliament. Extra-billing is banned. The act allows the federal government to deduct one dollar from federal transfers to any province for every dollar of direct patient charges in that province, and ended userfees for insured physicians and hospital services. 1995 - Paul Martin Jr. introduces Canada Health and Social Transfer (CHST), causing massive cuts in transfer payments to health and social programs. Health Care spending drops from 10.2% (in 1992) to 9.2% of GDP. 2000 - Ralph Klein introduces legislation to allow private hospitals. Alberta Friends of Medicare mount major campaign to protect Medicare from Bill 11 1997 -- National Forum on Health calls for Medicare to be expanded to include home care, pharmacare and a phasing out of fee-for-service for doctors. (7) What is meant when we say that Medicare was introduced as a cost-sharing program. Explain the formula which was used to determine federal transfers to the provinces for Medicare in the cost-sharing period. Explain what was meant by the 50-cent dollar. Why was this term misleading? A cost-sharing basis meant that if a province was to set up a health system than they would receive a significant amount from the Federal government to help cover the costs When Medicare was introduced it was suppose to be controlled by the provinces but receive financial support from the federal government This cost-sharing implies that the provincial government will receive a certain amount which would go towards their health care program depending on the size of the population that is using it Explain the formula which was used to determine federal transfers to the provinces for Medicare in the cost-sharing period. Per capita formula: Per capita grant x Provincial population = amount provinces received The amount received is based on the total physician expenditure in Canada, divided by Canada’s population times 50% Cost – sharing formula: =.5 (Ec/Nc) Ni, Where; Ec is the total expenditure Nc is Canada’s population Ni is the provinces population Later Federal contribution was calculated by: =.5 [∑(Ei/Ni) (Ni/Nc)] Where; Ei is the provinces expenditure This equation based the amount each province received strictly on the provinces population percentage out of the total countries population percentage; shows the unfairness of how much some provinces got in comparison to others (i.e. some would get more than 50% of one dollar spent, while others got less) Explain what was meant by the 50-cent dollar. Why is this term misleading? The 50-cent dollar was put in place to ensure that the federal government would pay 50% of the insured costs (no drug costs out of hospital) 50 cents for every dollar spent would be covered by the federal government and transferred to the provinces This was established in 1968 when Medicare was first introduced At no time did the Federal government pay with a cheque, they calculated the amount the provinces received based on the per capita formula basis Created bias in provincial spending because you would spend more on health care because you’ll get 50% back, but if you put it into education you would get nothing in return from the Federal government Was misleading because Federal government did pay 50% of total cost in Canada, but not 50% of individual provinces costs o Some provinces put more into health care than others, which they didn’t get back from Feds o For example: Ontario would only get back about 33% of what they spent whereas New Brunswick would receive up to almost 75% of what they spent per dollar (based on the total they spent and population differences in these provinces) o This caused a transfer of wealth between the rich provinces to the poor, allowing poor to spend more on needed medicine (8) Discuss why both the provincial and federal governments wanted to change the formula by which Medicare was originally funded. What do we mean when we refer to the shift to Established Programs Financing? (9) The provinces often claim that, after the shift to EPF the share of Medicare costs paid by the federal government fell from 50% to about 15%. The federal government argues that this share stayed at about 50%. Discuss. (10) Discuss the Coyte-Landon argument about the effect of the change from cost-sharing to block-funding (EPF). What do they say was the result of the shift in terms of provincial government spending patterns? General Note from in Class: Cost sharing is a conditional grant. The grant is Conditional on the level of spending by the local government on certain services. Under cost sharing provincial governments claimed that the federal government was only paying for 15% of the total physician costs. However the feds were actually paying 80% due to the cost sharing from EPF. Feds pay Provincial = per capita grant * provinces population Actual Formula: Provincial Grant = [50% * (Ec/Nc)] * Ni Ec = physician expenditure Nc = Canadian population Ni = Prov. Population Block Funding is an unconditional grant. The grant is determined in a manner that is independent of the pattern of local spending. The two are methods used by the federal government to determine the size of their transfer $ to local governments (states or provinces). A shift from cost to block would alter the relative price of different services to local governments. What they did? Coyte-Landon Article Coyte and Landon analyzed the shift in Canada from cost-sharing to block funding of provincial expenditures on hospital care, medical care, and post secondary education. There tests indicated the data are consistent with two key implications of the model (homogeneity and symmetry). A test for structural change confirmed that the behaviour of the provinces differed under the two methods. What Coyte and Landon did to compare the results of the cost sharing to the block funding grant: cost sharing values needed to be estimated after the year 1981 when block funding was applied for provincial governments. Two adjustments were made to account for differences among the provinces in finding the estimated values. The constant term αi in the share equation is allowed to differ across provinces and the addition of variables which reflect preference differences across observations are added. Result of the shift: The results indicated that by changing the system from cost sharing to block funding there was a negative effect on real spending by the provinces on hospital care and post secondary education. Fourteen of the eighteen provincial forecasts for these services indicate that there was a negative effect on spending. Their test of structural change indicated there was a significant difference in the behaviour of the provincial governments. There was a real impact on social service spending as a result of the change in the transfer from cost sharing to block funding. (11) Discuss, using standard micro-economic theory, the difference in earnings of Male and Female GPs under fee for service medical practice. 11) Discuss using standard micro-economic theory, the difference in earnings of Male and Female GP’s under fee for service medical practice. - Male Doctors tend to have different income/leisure preferences than female doctors. Female doctors tend to offer a narrower scope of services than male doctors but at the same price. I M F L - The red curve above is the indifference curve of male General Practitioners and the blue one is that of female doctors. The straight black line is the budget constraint which is equal for both male and female doctors. The graph shows that male doctors tend to work more and take less leisure time than female doctors. This implies that male doctors make more money than female doctors. Doctors working under a fee for service system are always looking for fuller part-time work. 15% of male paediatric doctors are looking for part time work and 45% of female paediatric doctors are looking for part time work Opportunity costs are a big chunk of costs and must be accounted for by looking at how much they must earn in order to persuade them to give up 1 hour of leisure and work 1 hour more - - MC P AC F MR MR’ Q - The graph above shows that the optimal price and quantity is where MC=MR. If price falls then the MR curve shifts downwards to MR’ and a lower price and quantity equilibrium is reached. The MC curve acts as the supply curve for perfectly competitive firms. - Both male and female practitioners are price takers. Female doctors are faced by the same fees as male doctors (same budget line) but have a higher MC curve. The male practitioners have a higher indifference curve which implies that male and female doctors have a different marginal rate of substitution between income and leisure. P MCF MCM MR Q Qf - - Qm Therefore females and male make different decisions on how much time to spend working when they have the same costs. Female doctors offer fewer services but have higher marginal costs than males. The opportunity cost of a female doctor’s time is higher due to the marginal rate of substitution. This implies that it would require more money for a female doctor to give up one more hour of leisure to work 1 more hour as leisure is more valuable to the female doctor. Empirical evidence—USA-- GPs are having to decide whether to be salary employees or solo based. If salary is above opportunity cost they will enter salary employment. (12) Discuss, using standard micro-economic theory, the results of the 2004 NHS contract in the UK permitting GPs to opt out of providing out of hours care in exchange for a reduction in their NHS pay. (13) Up until 2005, fee-for-service doctors in Ontario were faced with reduction in the fees they were paid if their OHIP billings exceeded certain levels. For example, as of April 1, 2002, when a GP’s billings reached $350,000, fees were scaled down by 33%, at billings of $375,000 the reduction was 66.7% and at $400,000 the reduction was 75%. When this system was first introduced in the early 1990s it was claimed that as doctors reached the first threshold, late in the calendar year, they would simply shut their offices for the rest of the calendar year and re-open in January when they would once again be paid at 100% of the listed fee, with no scaling down. Analyze this policy, using standard microeconomic theory, and explain why very few doctors would, if they were profit maximizers, shut their offices. Up until 2005, fee-for-service doctors in Ontario were faced with reduction in the fees they were paid if their OHIP billings exceeded certain levels. For example, as of April 1, 2002, when a GP’s billings reached $350,000, fees were scaled down by 33%, at billings of $375,000 the reduction was 66.7% and at $400,000 the reduction was 75%. When this system was first introduced in the early 1990s it was claimed that as doctors reached the first threshold, late in the calendar year, they would simply shut their offices for the rest of the calendar year and re-open in January when they would once again be paid at 100% of the listed fee, with no scaling down. Analyze this policy, using standard microeconomic theory, and explain why very few doctors would, if they were profit maximizers, shut their offices. I apologize in advance for writing such a long answer, but it’s a pretty long question that I thought needed a lot of explanation if you had missed the class when he discussed it. Under a fee-for-service pay schedule, doctors will act in a perfectly competitive manner as a price taker, supplying a quantity of services where their marginal costs of the last service performed are equal to the marginal revenue received from that service. Assuming doctors only perform one single service, and OHIP’s fee schedule pays $100 for that service, the first graph depicts how both medicare and doctors observe the quantity of this single service that physicians are willing to supply for the price offered to them. Since the amount physicians are reimbursed lowers after they surpass a total billing threshold, the amount billed and the amount they receive will be as follows; Total Billings <$350,000 $350,000-$375,000 $375,000-$400,000 >$400,000 % of Total Billings to be Reimbursed 100% 66.7% 33.3% 25% Total Amount Reimbursed to Doctors $350,000 $350,000 + $16,675 = $366,675 $366,675 + $8,325 = $375,000 $375,000+ A doctor will receive 100% of his total billings submitted up until $350,000, but for billing beyond that and up to $375,000 the doctor will only receive 66.7% of that $25,000 beyond the $350,000 which they are reimbursed. On the graph, the red line is at the base amount which OHIP is willing to pay doctors per service performed, $100. The yellow area on the graph represents $350,000 in total billings by a doctor, as well as the total amount of revenue a doctor will receive for performing up to quantity Q1 of the single service (which is equal to $350,000/$100=3500). The yellow + green + orange areas represent the physician billing up to a total of $375,000 to OHIP for Q2 (3750) services performed. However, since physicians only receive 66.7% of billings they file beyond Q1, the total revenue received by physicians does not include the orange area, and is made up of the yellow + green areas. The yellow + green + orange + pink + blue area represents a physician billing up to a total of $400,000 to OHIP for Q3 (4000) services performed. Physicians are reimbursed only 33.3% of the list fee for performing the service if their total billings exceed $375,000, so the revenue physicians receive is represented by the yellow + green + blue areas on the graph. And beyond $375,000, their revenue is only the yellow + green + blue + purple areas. Assuming this occurs in the short run, physicians will only be able to change the variable costs in their practice, which are primarily made up of costs related to performing their single service each time. The physician will also have fixed costs related to rent and utilities and the such. In an example where the physician is initially billing above a threshold level when this policy is introduced, a physician will supply a quantity of services until their marginal cost for performing that service equals the amount per service OHIP reimburses them with (marginal revenue). Before this policy is introduced, OHIP reimbursed 100% of the $100 fee a doctor submits to them, so they will supply services until their marginal cost equals $100. After the policy is introduced, the physician is only reimbursed with $66.7 for every $100 claim he submits to OHIP for each service performed above billing a total of $350,000. This means that the marginal revenue physicians receive will also lower once they exceed each total billing bracket when this policy is introduced. Because of this, the quantity of services supplied by a doctor will decrease until his marginal cost once again equals his marginal revenue. Since doctors still have fixed costs in their practices (rent, utility bills, secretary wages, etc.), the costs incurred while performing a medical service are not the only costs doctors incur. In perfect competition, a firm will continue producing unless their average variable cost is higher than their marginal costs, like it is for MC2. For a doctor with a MC of MC2, there is no point in the pay structure that they would stay operating, and they would just shut down. As can be seen on the second graph, since the physician supplies services up to the point where MR=MC, when this policy is implemented a doctor who had a total billing of much more than $350,000 will not stop supplying services and shut down their offices when they reach $350,000 in total billings, because for the most part this intersection of MR and MC will lie to the right of the quantity that produces $350,000. (14) Explain what is meant by an intertemporal optimization problem. Question 14 An Inter-temporal optimization problem is a problem in which the object is to find the best of all possible solutions so that an individual’s utilities in both periods can be maximized, subject to the individual’s budget function of the two periods. For example, an individual’s utility function is U (Ct , Ht) in period t, where Ct and Ht stands for the individual’s consumption and health capital in period t respectively. Similarly, the person’s utility function in the next time period, t+1, is U(Ct+1, Ht+1). Then this person’s utility function for these two periods (inter-temporal utility function) is is U (Ct+Ht) +βU(Ct+1, Ht+1), where βis the discount factor. People put less weight on the future than they do on the present. Therefore, they discount tomorrow’s utility. The discount factor is how much weight the person discounts the future utility. The person’s total income that he/she can spend on the consumption and the investment in health capital is Yt=PcCt+PIIr in period t. The total income is how much he/she can allocate in C and I. Similarly, the total income in period t+1 is Yt+1=PcCt+1+PIIt+1. These two functions are the person’s budget constraints. The intertemporal optimization problem here is to maximize the utility function, U (Ct+Ht) +βU(Ct+1, Ht+1), subject to the two budget constraints, Yt=PcCt+PIIr, and Yt+1=PcCt+1+PIIt+1 (15) Explain what is meant by the individual’s discount factor. What it its function in an intertemporal optimization problem. An individual’s discount factor used to determine how much an individual values the future. This can be the value of future consumption, future savings or even the value of future health. This discount factor, normally distinguished by the value of ‘β’ (beta), can range between the values of 0 and 1, where values closer to 0 mean that they do not value the future and values closer to 1 mean that they do value the future. This is determined by the value of the following expression: Β = __1___ 1+p Where p is the discount rate and p is greater than or equal to 0 where a higher level of p means that they value current consumption more, as a higher p value makes the value of B lower. The function of B (beta) in an intertemporal optimization problem is that it tells which way the consumer values their consumption, whether it is in the present period or the future period. In the intertemporal model for health, as discussed in class, it was determined that those who discounted health in the future were generally less healthy in the current period than those who valued health in the future. We also made this connection of those who discount future health are also more likely to discount other decision that require less consumption of either food or leisure or income today for a higher potential in the future, such as pursuing higher education for a higher future income, or saving more money today for consumption in the future. (16) Explain why the Grossman model is referred to as a model of investment in health capital. Why is it an intertemporal optimization problem? The Grossman model is referred to a model of investment health capital because individuals choose how much to invest in health capital today, but these benefits are not seen immediately they are seen tomorrow. It’s an intertemporal optimization problem because it is a utility maximization problem where your making a decision today will affect your well being tomorrow. If someone discounts the future heavily their behavior will reflect this, and it’s the same for someone who discounts the future at a less value. If they value the future less they will choose to consume more today and invest less today. For someone who puts more weight on the future, they will choose to consume less today and invest more today. Individuals will choose their combination of consumption and investment based on which will give them the highest utility.