Corporate Governance: Law, Economics & Politics The Determinants of Mergers 1 Empirical Regularities 1) Mergers come in waves USA: Late 1890s, 1920s, 1960s, 1980s, 1990s 2) Merger waves are correlated with increases in share prices and price/earnings ratios 2 Mergers and Average P/E ratio 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1895 1900 1905 1910 1915 1920 1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Year Average P/E Mergers/Population 3 4 5 • Takeovers in the 1980s were characterized by heavy use of leverage. – Firms purchased other firms in leveraged takeovers by borrowing rather than by issuing new stock or using solely cash on hand. – Other firms restructured themselves, borrowing to repurchase their own shares. – Finally, some firms were taken private in leveraged buyouts (LBOs). In an LBO, an investor group, often allied with incumbent management, borrows money to repurchase all of a company's publicly owned shares and takes the company private. Kohlberg, Kravis and Roberts was one of the earliest and most prominent LBO investors. 6 7 • Almost half of all major U.S. companies received "hostile" takeover bids in the 1980s, where hostility is defined as bids pursued without the acquiescence of target management (Mitchell and Mulherin, 1996). • Even those firms that were not actually taken over often decided to restructure in response to hostile pressure, particularly when corporate raiders had purchased large blocks of shares. 8 9 Why Did Corporate Governance and Mergers in the 1990s Look So Different? The Rise of Incentive-based Compensation • Hall and Liebman (1998) find a remarkable increase in equity-based compensation for U.S. CEOs. – From 1980 to 1994, the average annual CEO option grant (valued at issuance) increased almost seven-fold. As a result, equity-based compensation made up almost 50 percent of total CEO compensation in 1994, compared to less than 20 percent in 1980. The effect of the increase in equity-based compensation has been to increase CEO paytoperformance sensitivities by a factor of ten times from 1980 to 1998 (Hall and Liebman, 2000) • Holderness et al. compare equity ownership by officers and directors in 1935 and 1995 and find that equity ownership was substantially greater in 1995 than in 1935. – The results in Hall and Liebman (1998, 2000) combined with those in Holderness, Kroszner and Sheehan (1999) suggest that managerial equity ownership is very high today relative to most of the last century. 10 Forcing a Recognition of the Cost of Capital • The second distinguishing characteristic of leveraged buyouts was to incur enough leverage to force management to view capital as costly, because LBOs have to earn a return on capital sufficient to repay the interest and principal on the debt. – Corporations (and consulting firms) now try increasingly to create a parallel effect through new performance measurement and compensation programs. For example, Stern Stewart markets Economic Value Added (EVA) and the Boston Consulting Group markets Total Business Return (TBR). These programs compare a measure of return on capital, usually the after-tax profit earned by a company or division, to a measure of the cost of capital, like the after-tax profit required by the capital invested 11 Monitoring • The third distinguishing characteristic of LBOs is closer monitoring by shareholders and the board. • There are several reasons it is likely that shareholders monitor management more closely in the 1990s than in the 1980s. – The shareholdings of professional, institutional investors increased substantially. From 1980 to 1996, large institutional investors nearly doubled the share of the stock market they owned from under 30 percent to over 50 percent (Gompers and Metrick, 2001). This change means that professional investors-who have strong incentives to generate greater stock returnsmonitor an increasingly large fraction of U.S. corporations. 12 – In addition, in 1992, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) substantially reduced the costs to shareholders o f mounting proxy contests that challenged management teams. Under the old rules, a shareholder had to file a detailed proxy statement with the SEC before talking to more than ten other shareholders. Under the new rules, shareholders can essentially communicate at any time in any way as long as they send a copy of the substance of the communication to the SEC. The rule change has lowered the cost of coordinating shareholder actions and of blocking management proposals. Not surprisingly, the Business Roundtable-a group o f 200 CEOs of the very largest U.S. companies-and other management organizations were extremely hostile to this rule change when it was proposed. – Shareholder activism has increased in the United States since the late 1980s. Some of the more prominent activists included CALPERS, the Council of Institutional Investors, the LENS Fund, and Michael Price's Mutual Shares. Changes in the proxy rules have made this possible. The evidence on the impact of shareholder activism, however, is mixed. 13 • There also is evidence that boards of public companies have changed in the 1990s and become more active monitors than in the past. – Like top management, directors receive an increasing amount of equity-based compensation. Perry (1999) estimates that the fraction of compensation for directors that is incentive-based increased from 25 percent in 1992 to 39 percent in 1995. Russell Reynolds Associates (1998) report that the use of incentivebased compensation for directors also increased from 1995 to 1997. – Boards of public companies have become somewhat smaller over time (Hermalin and Weisbach, 2000; Wu, 2000). This is interesting because boards of leveraged buyout firms are smaller than otherwise similar firms (Gertner and Kaplan, 1996); and smaller boards are associated with higher valuations (Yermack, 1996). 14 Types of Mergers • Horizontal – involve two firms operating in the same kind of business activity, e.g. Daimler-Chrysler • Vertical – occur between firms in different stages of production operation • Conglomerate – occur between firms engaged in unrelated types of business activity – product-extension: broadens the product lines of firms – geographic market-extension: between firms whose operations have been conducted in non-overlapping geographic areas 15 • The theory of takeovers argues that two market failures can be corrected by the proper functioning of a third market „the market for corporate control“. – Competition in product and input markets may fail, – Within companies free from strong external market pressure, the "separation of ownership and control" identified by Berle and Means (1932) allows managers to pursue investment and cost-padding strategies that fail to maximize the profits of absentee owners-the shareholders. • In both cases, a well-functioning market for corporate control may come to rescue. 16 • Viewing the theory's applicability from a broad historical perspective raises awkward questions: – The "separation of ownership and control," though increasing over time, was found by Berle and Means to be widespread among large U.S. corporations during the 1920s. If managerial deviations from profit maximization were already commonplace then, how can one explain the strong performance of the U.S. industrial economy during the 1950s and 1960s, before efficiency-restoring tender offer takeovers came into vogue? – Also, the tender offer takeover phenomenon is both new and almost uniquely Anglo-American. If takeovers are necessary for efficiency, how have nations such as Japan, West Germany, Switzerland, and France continued to perform strongly, even though hostile takeovers are practically nonexistent there, and stock ownership is often separated from managerial control, as in America and Great Britain? The questions are rhetorical, for no satisfactory answer has been forthcoming. 17 Hypothesis about Mergers There are a big number of hypothesis as to why mergers occur, these can be grouped into two broad categories: 1) Neoclassical theories that assume that managers maximize profits or shareholder wealth and thus that mergers increase either market power or efficiency 2) Non-neoclassical or behavioral theories that posit some other motivation for mergers and/or other consequences. 18 1) Neoclassical Theories a) Market Power Increases b) Efficiency Increases 2) Non-neoclassical or Behavioral a) b) c) d) e) f) g) h) Speculative Motives The Adaptive Firm Hypothesis The Market for Corporate Control The Economic Disturbance Hypothesis Financial Efficiencies The Capital Redeployment Hypothesis The Life-Cycle-Growth-Maximization Hypothesis The Winner’s Curse- Hubris Hypothesis 19 (1a) Market Power Increases Horizontal Mergers – – fewer firms in an industry have greater incentives to cooperate and raise the price In a symmetric Cournot equilibrium, with homogeneous product and all firms having the same, constant unit cost c L – – pc H p H :Herfindahl index :price elasticity of demand for the industry 20 • Since a horizontal merger increases industry concentration, it increases H, it must also increase the industry price-cost margin and profits. • Salant, Switzer and Reynolds (1983) – However, Salant et al. (1983) show that mergers in such a setting are not privately profitable. When all firms have identical costs, they all must have the same size. – The above equation must hold before and after the merger. Since the immediate effect of the merger is to make the merged firm twice as big as ist competitors, it needs to shrink following the merger to return to the new size of ist rivals. – The loss of profits to the merging firms from having to shrink to rejoin the symmetric Cournot equilibrium more than offsets the gain in profits from the increase in price cost margin caused by the increase in H. 21 • Vertical mergers – by increasing the barriers to entry at one or more links in the vertical production chain – Example: a firm which wished to enter into aluminum refining in the USA prior to the Second World War would have found that all known bauxite deposits were owned by ist main competitor ALCOA. ALCOA could easily foreclose the bauxite market to the entrant and thus created an entry barrier. • Conglomerate mergers – multimarket contact (Scott, 1982, 1993) – An increase in concentration leads to a greater increase in profits in a market in which the sellers also face one another in other markets than when such multimarket contact is not present. This motive may also be the cause of purposeful diversification mergers. 22 (1b) Efficiency Increases • Horizontal Mergers AC A B C D E Output 23 • In such an industry, one would expect the merging firms to be smaller than non-merging firms, because the expected cost reductions are greter for pairs of small firms. • Empirical Evidence: – In Belgium, Germany, USA, and UK merging firms were significantly larger than non-merging firms – In France, the Netherlands, and Sweden merging pairs were in significantly different in size from randomly selected nonmerging companies. 24 • Vertical mergers • Can increase the efficiency of the merging firms by eliminating steps in the production process, which reduces the transaction costs from bargaining due to asset specificity • Asset Specificity refers to the relative lack of transferability of assets intended for use in a given transaction to other uses. Highly specific assets represent sunk costs that have relatively little value beyond their use in the context of a specific transaction. Williamson has suggested six main types of asset specificity: – Site, physical asset, human asset, brand names, dedicated assets, temporal specificity • High asset specificity requires strong contracts or internalization to combat the threat of opportunism. • Small subcontractors locating and investing next to only customer who could potentially turn to alternative suppliers (site- and physical asset specificity). 25 General Motors and Fisher Body 1919-1926 After a 10 year contractual agreement was signed in 1919, GM's demand for closed-body cars increased to extent that it became unhappy with the contractual price provisions and "urged Fisher to locate its body plants adjacent to GM assembly plants, thereby to realize transportation and inventory economies." [Williamson, AJS, p.561] Finally, Fisher Body was merged into GM in 1926 after Fisher had resisted GM's locational demands. As Coase recalls: "I was told [by GM officials] that the main reason for the acquisition was to make sure that the body plants were located next to General Motors assembly plants." [Coase, "The Nature of the Firm: Origin", in: Williamson & Winter, eds., The Nature of the Firm. 1993, p.43.] 26 • Conglomerate Mergers – Economies of scope (ESC) arise when the production of two different products by the same firm leads to lower production costs for one or both products. – Example: warehousing and delivery of products – Formally, ESC is said to exist if the cost function is subadditive C(x1, x2) < C(x1,0) + C(0, x2) 27 (2a) Speculative Motives • Studies of early merger waves often mention “promoters’ profits as a cause for mergers. During these waves men like J.P. Morgan often approached corporate managers and suggested a possible merger. They earned large fees for their advice and for other services they rendered to facilitate and finance the deals. • Underwriters of the securities floated in the great merger that created the United States Steel Corp. In 1901, earned fees of $575.5 million – over $1 billion in today‘s dollars (The Economist, April 27, 1991, p. 11). • Michael Milken 28 Fee Revenue from underwriting and M&A transactions in 1998 (Saunders and Srinivasan, 2001 ) Fee Revenue from Underwriting (equity & debt) (1) Fee Revenue from Merger Advice (2) (2) / (1) Morgan Stanley 1253.8 302.9 19.50% Goldman Sachs 1087.8 531.2 32.80% Merrill Lynch 1496.9 321.3 17.70% 386 287.4 42.70% DLJ 491.8 200 28.90% Citibank 913.2 189.1 17.20% Lehman 516.3 199.2 27.80% J.P. Morgan 358.9 70.9 16.50% Bankers Trust 252.2 56.9 18.40% NationsBank Montgomery 132.7 26.2 16.50% Average 688.9 218.5 23.80% Total 6889.6 2185.1 31.72% Investment Bank Credit Suisse First Boston 29 (2b) The Adaptive (Failing Firm) Hypothesis • Donald Dewey (1961): – mergers as a civilized alternative to bankruptcy • John McGowan (1965): – An adaptive theory to account for why small firms are typically the targets in mergers and why the much more competitive US and UK economies had more mergers than the less competitive ones. • Two implications: – Mergers should follow a counter-cyclical pattern. Why don’t we see merger waves during recessions? – Profit rates of acquirers should be higher than targets • Empirical Evidence – Most studies of mergers in the USA have found that acquired firms have the same average profit rates as similar non-acquired companies – During the conglomerate merger wave acquiring companies had below average profit rates and also profit rates lower than the firms they acquired. 30 Characteristics of Acquiring and Target Companies, 1980-1998 Gugler, Mueller, Yurtoglu, and Zulehner (2003) Profit rate Number of Mergers Acquirer Target 1,967 0.029 0.019 United Kingdom 379 0.066 0.039 Continental Europe 172 0.035 0.033 Japan 16 0.011 0.030 Australia/N.Zealand/Canada 172 0.024 0.027 Rest of the World 47 0.052 0.013 2,753 0.034 0.023 United States of America All mergers 31 (2c) The Market for Corporate Control • Mt: market value of the firm in year t • Kt: the value of the assets of the firm in year t • If Mt > Kt: the assets bundled together as a firm are worth more than their sum as measured by Kt. • Marris (1963, 1964) called Mt / Kt the valuation ratio, Vt • Tobin (1969) measured Kt as the replacement cost of the firm’s asset and called qt = Mt / Kt. • Manne (1965): • Buyers in the market for corporate control would step in whenever Vt falls short of its maximum value, and thus that this process ensures that corporate assets are managed by the most competent managers and those intend shareholder wealth maximization. 32 • Smiley (1976): – Actual market values of acquired companies are compared to a projected value (control group). – The market values of takeover targets began to fall below their predicted values on average 10 years before the takeover, and that the cumulative decline was 50% of predicted values. • Other Studies – have found the shares of acquiring firms to be underperforming prior to their takeover (Mandelker, 1974; Langetieg, 1978; Asquith, 1983; Malatesta, 1983) – Exception Dodd and Ruback (1977) 33 (2d) The Economic Disturbance Hypothesis • Gort (1969) – a group of non-holders suddenly raises its expectations about firm B’s future profits. If these non-holders are managers of another firm, the transaction takes the form of a merger. – Mergers under this hypothesis are more likely to happen in periods in which stock market experiences rapid changes in value. – Consistent with the wave pattern – But also consistent with merger waves during sudden drops in stock market values (even more intense merger activity!) 34 (2e) Financial Efficiencies Savings on Borrowing Costs Riskpooling 35 (2f) The Capital Redeployment Hypothesis • Weston (1970) – Similar to financial efficiencies argument, but goes beyond it by positing ongoing potential gains from a central management team’s ability to monitor the investment opportunities of each division and shift capital across them. 36 (2g) The Life-Cycle Growth Maximization Hypothesis • Mueller (1969) – Mergers are the quickest way to grow and diversify and thus an attractive way for managers with limited time horizons to achieve growth. – Predictions • diversification mergers by mature firms 37 • Direct Evidence by Harford (1999): – Cash rich firms are more likely to acquire – Their acquisitions are more likely to be diversifying – The abnormal price reaction is negative and lower for bidders who are cash rich – Operating performance deteriorates after mergers by cash rich companies 38 (2h) The Winner’s Curse –Hubris hypothesis • There are a number of bidders • The bidder with the highest valuation acquires the target • With rational expectations, the expected true value of the target should be at the mean of the distribution • The winner will bid too much! • Why bid then? • Roll (1986): • Because managers of acquiring firms suffer from hubris, excessive pride and arrogance. 39 Testing Competing Hypotheses about the Determinants of Mergers Three categories of hypotheses 1) Synergy • • • • e.g., a horizontal merger that increases the market power of the two merging companies The ynergistic gains arise from specific characteristics of the two merging firms. It is reasonable to assume that both firms share these gains, since each firm‘s participation in the merger is required for there be any gains at all. A weaker assumption would be simply that the shareholders of both firms benefit from the merger. 40 2) Market for Corporate Control • • • • All of the gains from the merger are tied to the target firm. In principle, any other firm could buy the target and replace its managers and obtain the wealth increase from its action. If the bidding for the target continues until the target‘s share price rises by enough to reflect all of the gains from replacing ist management, the bidder‘s shareholders will experience no gain from the merger. Target‘s shareholders receive positive welath increases Bidders‘ gains average zero and are unrelated to the gains to the targets. 41 2) Managerial Discretion • • • • • There are no net gains from the mergers Each dollar paid to the target shareholders represents a dollar loss to the acquirers‘ shareholders. Thus, the gains to the target‘s and bidder‘s shareholders should be inversely related. It is not possible to distinguish a merger motivated by pure hubris from one stemming from managerial empirebuilding. In both cases, the targets‘ gains are bidders‘ losses. It is also possible, however, that managerial hubris may arise with mergers that do generate positive net wealth gains. Out of overoptimism the bidder pays too much for the target. In such a mixed case, we would expect a net positive gain from the merger, but a loss to the bidder. Moreover, the bigger the gain to the target, the more likely it is that the bidder overbid, and the bigger ist expected loss. 42 Tests: Mueller and Sirower (2002) G: Gain to the bidder in dollars over a 24-month period beginning with the month of the merger P: Premium paid to the target‘s shareholders in dollars VT: Market value of the target firm G P e f VT VT 43 The predicted coefficients Hypothesis Synergy (SH) Market for Corporate Control (MCCH) Managerial discretion (MDH) Prediction without Hubris Hypothesis Prediction with Hubris Hypothesis e=0, f=1 e<>0, f<1 e=0, f=0 e<>0, f<0 e=0, f=-1 e=0, f=-1 44 Relationship between gains to acquirers and premia paid to targets e f N / R2 e Contested 0.03 -0.21 (0.06) (0.19) -1.94 (1.13) (1.84) 44 / -0.023 0.26 -2.23 (0.97) (2.81) -0.68 (0.79) (1.00) 45 / 0.051 0.09 -1.34 (0.32) (1.68) -1.46 (1.42) (1.75) 123 / 0.015 Unrelated (3 Digit) 95 / -0.000 0.13 -2.54 (0.31) (2.23) Cash Only 0.49 124 / 0.053 Single Bidder Related (3 Digit) 0.20 N / R2 Uncontested Multiple Bidders 0.48 f 73 / 0.052 Noncash (mixed) 90 / 0.023 0.05 -2.48 (0.16) (2.38) 78 / 0.057 45 • The mean gain to the bidders is -$50 • The variance around this mean is $ 3,579,664 million • Are you willing to play in a game in which – the expected winnings are -$50 – you might lose as much as $10, 000,000 – You might also win as much as $13,000,000 • These are summary statistics from the above sample, except that they are measured in millions. • Why do managers of these firms undertake such gambles? – Hubris? Averages do not apply them – Managerial discretion? They are gambling with other peoples money! 46