Monopoly and Regulation Chapter 12 Slides by Pamela L. Hall Western Washington University ©2005, Southwestern Introduction Polar extreme of perfect competition is a market with only one firm supplying output Called a monopoly • Firm with no substitutes (competition) for its output This chapter discusses barriers to entry as cause of monopolies We then develop short-run price and output determination for a profit-maximizing monopoly We derive relationship of a monopoly’s price with market elasticity of demand Based on this relationship, develop Lerner Index for measuring degree of monopoly power We investigate long-run equilibrium for monopolies As well as opportunity cost of capital as a consequence of monopolies earning only long-run normal profits • Based on this long-run equilibrium, we investigate welfare loss from monopoly power In terms of price not equaling marginal cost, firms operating at less than full capacity, and rent-seeking behavior 2 Introduction We discuss and evaluate government regulation to correct potential welfare loss in terms of a market’s contestability Aim in this chapter is to show how a firm with monopoly power will misallocate resources and is inefficient Taxing, regulating, or dismantling monopolies are possible solutions to improving efficiency We hope to provide an understanding of why agents with monopoly power are detrimental to an economy Growth of industrial state in 19th and 20th centuries spawned a wealth of investigations by economists into causes, problems, and potential cures for an economy with monopolies Question applied economists are now attempting to answer is • Whether curing disease (monopoly power) will kill patient (advancing social welfare) If costs of intervening into a market with monopolies (e.g., Microsoft) are more than any benefits received (e.g., advances in computer operating systems) Such intervention is questionable Applied economists actively attempt to measure benefits and costs of various policies designed to promote efficient resource allocation by constraining monopoly-power activities 3 Barriers to Entry Cause of a monopoly is barriers (obstacles) to entry If other firms could enter market, there would likely be no monopoly Barriers to entry are anything that allow existing firms to earn pure profits Without threat of entry by other firms Either legal or technical obstacles One type of a legal monopoly is established by a state or federal government awarding only one firm an exclusive franchise to provide a commodity Government may do so because there are increasing returns to scale over a wide range of output • One firm can supply market more efficiently than two or more firms If society deems that unrestricted competition among firms in an industry is undesirable Government may establish a legal monopoly by granting a firm exclusive rights to operate • For example, patents Technological barriers to entry may result when a firm’s technology results in decreasing LAC over a wide range of output, knowledge of a low-cost productive technique, or control of a strategic resource Termed natural monopolies • Because market forces establish monopoly Sometimes progress can directly impact these natural monopolies 4 Price and Output Determination Objective of monopolies Maximize profits • First determine profit-maximizing output • Then determine price required to sell output Alternatively, they can first determine profit-maximizing price • Then from market demand curve determine level of output that can be sold at this price Resulting profit-maximizing price/output combination will be the same • Regardless of which method is employed Both are based on a monopoly’s determining its equilibrium price and output given market demand curve Market demand curve is downward sloping If a monopoly reduces output, price it receives for this output will increase 5 Price and Output Determination Monopoly has control over market price A price maker Consider following linear market demand curve AR = p = a – bQ TR = (AR)Q = pQ = aQ – bQ2 MR = ∂TR/∂Q = a – 2bQ = a – bQ – bQ = AR - bQ • Where a, b > 0 For a linear demand curve, MR is twice as steep as AR • Will bisect any horizontal line drawn from vertical axis to AR curve Illustrated in Figure 12.1 6 Figure 12.1 Linear market demand curve 7 Price and Output Determination In Figure 12.1, AR is falling as firm increases output Because consumers are willing and able to purchase more of commodity at lower level of AR (price) Falling AR implies that MR is below it MR is equal to AR plus adjustment factor, -bQ • Given -b < 0 (falling AR), then MR < AR For a given level of output, MR < AR For a firm to sell an additional unit of output it must lower its price on all units to be sold, not just on additional units • Adjustment factor, -bQ, accounts for this condition For each additional output sold, price falls by -b Multiplying this fall in price by number of units sold Results in adjustment to AR for determining MR 8 Profit Maximization Mathematically, short-run profit is maximized by F.O.C. is • ∂/∂Q = ∂TR/∂Q = ∂STC/ ∂Q = 0 = MR(Q) – SMC(Q) = 0 Profit-maximizing monopoly will equate MR to SMC to determine its optimal level of output Profit-maximizing output Q* corresponds to where MR = SMC Illustrated in Figure 12.2 • Firm will produce Q* units of output and, given market demand curve QD, it can sell all of this output at p* p* corresponds to level of output Q* that consumers are willing and able to purchase 9 Figure 12.2 Price and output determination for a monopoly 10 Profit Maximization SMC curve for a monopoly determines profit-maximizing price and output However, in contrast to perfect competition, SMC curve above SAVC is not monopoly’s short-run supply curve In Figure 12.2, if SMC curve for a monopoly is a supply curve, at a price of p* Firm would be willing and able to supply Q' units of output • Although firm is able to supply Q' at p*, it is unwilling to supply it Profit-maximizing output is Q* • Firm can sell all output at p* Cannot determine a monopoly’s short-run supply curve without restrictive assumptions Note that same factors that shift a monopoly’s short-run supply curve also shift SMC curve in same direction • Can view SMC curve as a proxy for supply curve 11 Profit Maximization In Figure 12.2, price p* is above SATC* for output level Q* Indicates monopoly is earning a pure profit • Represented by shaded area SATC*p*AB TR is represented by area 0p*AQ* STC is represented by area 0(SATC*)BQ* • Difference is pure profit As illustrated in Figure 12.3, in short run a monopoly can also earn only a normal profit When p* = SATC* • Due to increased input prices or a decrease in demand for its output In this case, TR* = STC*, area 0p*AQ* 12 Figure 12.3 Short-run profit maximization for a monopoly earning a normal profit 13 Profit Maximization In short run, a monopoly can also operate at a loss if demand falls or costs increase Illustrated in Figure 12.4 • Losses represented by shaded area p*(SATC*)BA As long as price is above SAVC a monopoly will continue to operate in short run Monopoly will cover all of its STVC and have some revenue left over for paying a portion of its TFC Monopoly minimizes its losses by operating If price falls below SAVC, monopoly is unable to cover its STVC Will minimize losses by shutting down In summary, a monopoly can earn a pure profit, a normal profit, or can operate at a loss in short run Firm’s level of profit is not an indicator of its degree of monopoly power • Percentage markup in price over marginal cost, (p - SMC )/p, is indicator of monopoly power 14 Figure 12.4 Price and output determination for a monopoly operating at a loss 15 Lerner Index Regardless of its level of monopoly power Firm only operates in elastic portion of demand curve Given SMC > 0, a profit-maximizing firm will equate MR = SMC > 0 Using product rule of differentiation and recalling TR = pQ Relationships of MR to price and to elasticity of market demand are • MR = dTR/dQ = p + (∂p/∂Q)Q MR is equal to price plus adjustment factor 16 Lerner Index For each additional output sold price falls by ∂p/∂Q Multiplying this by number of units sold results in adjustment to AR for determining MR Factoring out price from right-hand side of MR = p + (∂p/∂Q)(Q) yields relationship between MR and elasticity of demand • MR = p[1 + (∂p/∂Q)(Q/p)] = p(1 + 1/D) Where /D = (∂Q/∂p)(p/Q)], own-price elasticity of demand For MR > 0, (1 + 1/D) > 0 • Which implies D < -1 (elastic) If D > 1 (inelastic) • MR = dTR/dQ < 0 Decrease in Q will increase TR Given dSTC/dQ > 0, STC decreases with this decrease in Q Yielding an increase in pure profit Profit-maximizing firm can continue to reduce Q and increase profit within inelastic portion of demand curve Firm will reduce output until it is in elastic portion of demand curve • Where MR = SMC Table 12.1 summarizes relationships between demand elasticity and marginal revenue 17 Table 12.1 Demand Elasticity and Marginal Revenue 18 Lerner Index At MR = SMC MR = p(1 + 1/D) = SMC • Solving for p gives p = SMC/(1 + 1/D) Under perfect competition, a firm is facing a perfectly elastic demand curve • So 1/D = 0, indicating condition of p = SMC for profit maximization Instead, a monopoly charges a higher price Since it only operates on elastic portion of demand curve Then 0 < (1 + 1/D) < 1, so p > SMC A measure of degree of monopoly power is percentage markup in price over marginal cost (p - SMC )/p Specifically, given p(1 + 1/D) = SMC and solving for (p - SMC )/p yields Lerner Index (LI) • LI = (p – SMC)/p = -1/D • Lerner Index varies between 0 and 1 and measures percentage markup in price due to monopoly power Relative difference in price and marginal cost is dependent on elasticity of demand 19 Lerner Index Under perfect competition, p = SMC, D = -, so LI = 0 Firm is exercising zero monopoly power If D = -1, then LI = 1, indicating existence of monopoly power At -1 ≥ D > -, corresponding to 0 < LI ≤ 1, a relative wedge between price and SMC exists Magnitude of this wedge is determined by elasticity of demand • When demand curve becomes less elastic, wedge increases and LI approaches 1 • Wedge for a profit-maximizing firm without close substitutes will be large relative to a firm in a market with many competitors Monopoly is concerned with effect high price has on consumption When consumers react to a price increase by greatly reducing their demand Monopoly will not charge highest price it can for its output • It will determine elasticity of demand for its output and calculate LI Table 12.2 lists measurements of Lerner Index for steel and semiconductor industries 20 Table 12.2 Measurements of the Lerner Index for the Steel and Semiconductor Industries 21 Long-Run Equilibrium Long-run equilibrium for a monopoly is illustrated in Figure 12.5 SATC and LAC curves are tangent at firm’s profitmaximizing output level Q* Where SMC = LMC = MR At this equilibrium output and price (Q*, p*), firm is earning a normal profit In long run, firm can earn only a normal profit If it had been earning a pure profit in short run, when firm is sold in the long run New owners will pay a higher price for firm than if it had been earning only a normal profit • Increases cost of operation Results in upward shift of cost curves 22 Figure 12.5 Long-run equilibrium for a monopoly firm 23 Long-Run Equilibrium Competition for purchasing firm will result in cost curves for new owners shifting up to point of zero pure profit (normal profit) Market price for firm will increase until, in long run, all short-run pure profits are squeezed out p = SATC = LAC Even if firm is not sold, cost of production (in terms of implicit cost) will increase over time In long run, a firm that earned a short-run pure profit will be worth more, say $100,000 Thus, owners of firm have a higher implicit cost of production • Their opportunity cost for operating firm has increased because they could sell firm and receive this increase in price ($100,000) and invest it in another activity Called opportunity cost of capital • If alternative activity had an annual rate of return of 10%, then firm’s implicit cost of production would be $10,000 higher Short-run pure profit is converted into implicit cost Alternatively, if firm had been operating at a loss in short run, firm will not be worth as much Cost curves will shift downward, resulting in a long-run normal profit 24 Long-Run Equilibrium The worth of a monopoly based on its long-run pure-profit potential is called monopoly rents Rent a possible entrant would be willing to pay for monopoly Given positive monopoly rents, associated opportunity cost exists that result in only long-run normal profits Without considering that cost adjusts to rents, it is possible to assume a monopoly will earn a long-run pure profit This fact is particularly important in basic business decision-making Since firms, even those with monopoly power, can only make a pure profit in short run • Owners of firms cannot continue their present activities and expect continued pure profits If they want to continue to reap pure profit, must anticipate market trends So as to sell their firms when conditions are right and be early entrants into markets where firms are earning short-run pure profits However, many individuals or firms either lack this knowledge or are unwilling to act Because they can maximize their utility by staying in a particular activity even if it means earning only a normal profit 25 Welfare Loss from Monopoly Power Major objective of economics is to improve social welfare Thus, market structures that result in economic inefficiency are considered inferior Specifically, a monopoly market structure is inferior to a perfectly competitive market structure based on monopolies’ inefficiency • Monopoly is efficient in terms of both technical and allocative efficiency • Monopoly will produce on production frontier (technical efficiency) and • employ least-cost production (allocative efficiency) However, monopoly is not scale efficient Does not equate price to marginal cost • Thus, monopoly’s long-run equilibrium position is inefficient 26 Welfare Loss from Monopoly Power Inefficiency is characterized by two conditions p* > SMC* = LMC* • Price a household pays for a commodity is marginal utility of consumption Monetary measure of how much an additional unit of a commodity is worth to household • Marginal cost is cost of producing an additional amount of commodity If price is greater than marginal cost society would prefer firm increase output In perfect competition, price is equal to marginal cost What society is willing to pay for an additional unit of output is equal to what it costs society to produce this additional unit But monopoly restricts output and increases price So what society is willing to pay for an additional unit of output is greater than what it costs society to produce this additional unit 27 Welfare Loss from Monopoly Power Second inefficiency of a monopoly Does not operate at full production capacity • At full capacity average cost of production is at a minimum Monopoly does not operate at minimum point of SATC or LAC For an efficient operation, output should increase to full capacity • Fixed costs are spread over too few units of output Results in excess capacity and inefficiency Can represent this inefficiency and associated welfare loss with a monopoly by deadweight loss in consumer and producer surplus 28 Welfare Loss from Monopoly Power As illustrated in Figure 12.6, perfectly competitive equilibrium is QC, pC Economic efficiency is area CAB, where pCAB is consumer surplus and CpCB is producer surplus • A firm with monopoly power restricts output from QC to QM Results in price increasing • Consumer surplus is reduced to pMAE, with firm capturing some of the lost consumer surplus (area pCpMEF) Captured consumer surplus is a measure of firm’s exploitation of consumers • Producer surplus, with monopoly power, is area CpMED Efficiency loss in social welfare is area DEB Deadweight loss resulting from monopoly power provides a signal that some government intervention may be desirable However, it does not suggest a particular course of action • Causes of inefficiency should first be determined • Then a possible set of actions formulated 29 Rent-seeking Behavior There is a further efficiency loss associated with a monopoly Expense incurred to obtain and maintain monopoly power (called rent-seeking behavior) Rent is defined as monopoly’s producer surplus Represented in Figure 12.6 by area CpMED Potential for obtaining this rent may lead firms to engage in rent-seeking behavior Firms may incur both strategic expenses in form of • Erecting barriers to entry or • Administrative expenses such as lobbying government representatives or • Legal defense against antitrust actions 30 Rent-seeking Behavior Extreme case of rent-seeking behavior All monopoly rents will be allocated to this behavior Assuming that all rent-seeking behavior is socially wasteful (has no social value) Actual deadweight loss is area CpMEBD in Figure 12.6 Represents producer surplus (rents) plus deadweight loss DEB All rent-seeking behavior is probably not socially wasteful So including producer surplus as a component of deadweight loss may be used to represent upper boundary of efficiency loss 31 Figure 12.6 Deadweight loss resulting from monopoly power 32 Taxing Rents One proposed solution for inefficiency in monopoly power is to tax monopolies’ profits Either a lump-sum tax or a profit tax would reduce a monopoly’s producer surplus For lump-sum tax system, can represent profit as = pQ - STC – TRT • Where TRT is lump-sum tax corresponding to total tax revenue collected F.O.C. for profit maximization is • ∂ ÷ ∂Q = MR – SMC = 0 No change in optimal level of output or price, or for determining whether a firm should operate Level of profit falls by amount of increase in tax Illustrated in Figure 12.7 by upward shift in TFC and STC curves 33 Figure 12.7 Lump-sum or profit tax 34 Taxing Rents However, inefficiency of monopoly still exists Society still would prefer monopoly to increase output and decrease price Problem of resource misallocation is not solved by a lump-sum tax Because lump-sum tax does not affect allocation of resources Only affects distribution of total economic surplus • By taking some producer surplus away from monopoly and reallocating it to others • Thus, lump-sum tax is only beneficial if reallocation of total surplus improves social welfare By redistributing surplus away from socially wasteful rent-seeking behavior 35 Taxing Rents With a profit tax there is no change in a monopoly’s optimal level of output or price, or for determining whether it should operate Can represent a monopoly’s profit with a profit tax as = pQ – STC – t(pQ – STC) = (1 – t)(pQ – STC) • t is percentage of profit that is taxed F.O.C. is • ∂ ÷ ∂Q = (1 – t)(MR – SMC) = 0 Implies that MR = SMC still remains as condition for profit maximization Level of profit declines by amount of increase in tax Results in an upward shift in TFC and STC curves Since firms are taxed on a percentage of their profits TFC shifts upward for alternative profit levels Neither lump-sum nor profit taxes cure ills of monopoly power But both reduce ability of a monopoly to engage in socially wasteful rent-seeking behavior 36 Franchise City and County of Denver, Colorado, requires three cable channels for public access programming in its franchise agreement with AT&T Broadband This government issuance of a franchise is an alternative pricing policy Generally employed in cable television and radio airwaves markets Right to be a monopoly within a local market or to control some public domain is sold (franchised) Proceeds are rebated to consumers within this market • Rebate either is in form of tax relief or a public good If a competitive auction is used to determine price of franchise Competition will drive up franchise price to where only a normal profit will be earned by the owners However, once a franchise is established, it tends to perpetuate with the same franchise owners in control Any renegotiation tends to occur without competitive bidding Thus, an issuance of a franchise does not cure problems associated with monopoly power • May not even reduce ability of monopoly to engage in rent-seeking behavior Unless franchise is renegotiated with competitive bidding 37 Regulation of Monopoly If a monopoly results in a misallocation of resources, it is inefficient Regulation may be required However, prior to regulation degree of inefficiency should be determined Because cost of regulation may exceed any benefits gained A firm with monopoly power may choose to not exercise its power (called limit price analysis) Either because they are concerned that restricting output and increasing price will result in other firms entering market or That they will be regulated Even threat of entry by another firm or threat of regulation may cause a firm to expand output by equating price to marginal cost and operate efficiently For instance, threat of antitrust actions and entry of new firms in industry has resulted in cereal industry becoming more competitive • Without government regulation 38 Government Regulation In 1911, U.S. government succeeded in splitting oil monopoly created by Standard Oil into 34 companies In June 7, 2000, a U. S. District Court ruled to split Microsoft Corporation into two smaller companies One to deal with operating systems and another with Internet browsers and software applications Main government policies for addressing inefficiencies of monopoly power Break up firm Regulate it • If LAC is declining over a wide range of output (a natural monopoly), it may not be • feasible to break up monopoly, so regulation is used Alternatively, if LAC is relatively flat over a wide range of output May be more efficient to break up monopoly 39 Government Regulation Regulation policies vary according to type of government Socialist governments tend to regulate through direct government ownership • Example: Indian Airlines, owned by India Capitalist governments will tend to establish public utility commissions to oversee private (non-government) firms Example: power companies within U.S. • Privately owned but publicly regulated Whether a firm is government-owned or private, a mechanism design is required for determining governmentregulated firm’s price and output 40 Government Regulation Three major pricing policies exist for price and output determination Monopoly pricing In Figure 12.8, this is unregulated price and output equilibrium (pM, QM) • Assuming positive monopoly rents, monopoly is earning a long-run pure profit • Monopoly is Pareto inefficient with this pricing policy, because p > LMC Pareto-efficient pricing policy is one that sets p = LMC Called marginal-cost pricing (pe,Qe) A problem with marginal-cost pricing is that firm will operate at a loss • pe is below LACe 41 Figure 12.8 Public utility regulation for a natural monopoly 42 Government Regulation Many public utility agencies avoid this problem by allowing regulated firm to price discriminate Can potentially increase revenue and not operate at a loss A public utility agency using marginal-cost pricing is faced with difficulty of measuring marginal cost versus average cost Calculating average cost requires information on level of total cost and output • Such information is generally available in accounting records Calculating marginal cost not only requires information on level of total cost, but also information on how total cost is changing for a change in output • Information is not generally available in accounting records Relatively difficult to obtain 43 Government Regulation An alternative, second-best pricing policy, is full-cost pricing (or rate-of-return pricing) Most public utilities employ this method Illustrated in Figure 12.8 Under full-cost pricing, public utility agency equates LAC to price (pf, Qf) p = LAC Firm earns a normal profit Output and price are close to Pareto efficient solution Allowing firm to price discriminate may increase output Shifting it closer to Pareto-efficient marginal-cost pricing solution 44 Government Regulation Public utility agency may allow firm to provide price discounts to its larger purchasers Results in larger purchasers increasing their purchases • With an associated increase in total consumer surplus Since discount is only for larger purchasers, it does not affect firm’s other customers • Largest purchasers will face a price equal to firm’s marginal cost for last unit they purchase Because if largest purchaser faced a price greater than marginal cost and the price were lowered Purchaser would purchase an extra unit and seller would sell this extra unit, so both would be better off 45 Government Regulation Full-cost pricing policy includes a competitive (fair) return on investment in capital as a constraint on monopoly’s input choice decision Monopoly’s profit-maximizing decision does not yield the same least-cost combination of capital and labor as does unconstrained decision for the same level of output • Effect is to encourage monopoly to hire more capital and less labor Thus, regulation encourages a monopoly to employ an inefficient capital/labor ratio In an effort to extract more profits under full-cost pricing constraint 46 Contestable Markets A firm with zero sunk cost of operations can enter and exit industry at almost zero cost Potential entrant firms could employ hit-and-run tactics • Hit when pure profits exist and run once they are exhausted Such industries are called contestable markets Depending on contestability of an industry, all natural monopolies may not require regulation If a monopoly that is earning a pure profit does not have large sunk costs, then barriers to entry would be minor • Even threat of entry by other firms may drive monopoly’s price down toward a price that equals average cost This theory indicates that, for industries with limited entry and exit costs, market forces will produce same outcome as full-cost pricing regulation Need to regulate such firms is questionable Theory is employed as a justification for deregulation in telecommunications and airlines And for not pursuing regulation with currently unregulated firms such as computer software firms • One justification for not breaking up Microsoft 47