THRESHOLD THEORY – MODELLING RISK ATTITUDE by Tomasz Kasprowicz tkasprow@matbud.com Affiliation: Gemini (non academic) Bobrzyńskiego 23/5, 30-348 Kraków +48 602 25 25 00 Andrzej Bednorz abednorz@gmail.com (no affiliation) Powstańców 6a, 44-362 Bluszczów +48 697 52 22 97 68 CHAPTER 1 DEVELOPMENT OF THRESHOLD THEORY Introduction Behavior under uncertainty One of the basic points of interest to economists is the behavior of people under uncertainty. Analysis of the problem dates back to Daniel Bernoulli (1738), but was developed in the state it is most widely known today by Von Neumann and Morgenstern (1947). The basic concept is that each individual has a utility function that translates uncertain outcomes into expected utility. In the classical approach, the premise is that an agent behaves rationally to maximize his expected utility. Assumptions about the form of the utility function were based on four main observations: (1) people always prefer more wealth to less wealth, which suggests the first derivative of the utility function should be positive. (2) The St. Petersburg paradox (Bernoulli, 1738) suggests a negative second derivative of the function, which is equivalent to risk aversion and decreasing marginal utility of wealth. (3) The Super St. Petersburg paradox (Menger, 1934) suggests that the function should be bounded (4) The Inverse Super St. Petersburg paradox (Musumeci, working paper). Interestingly enough, despite these observations, the utility functions used most commonly to explain decisions under uncertainty have been logarithmic, exponential and quadratic functions, which do not satisfy the third condition. In particular, Markowitz’s (1959) notions of diversification, as well as the CAPM model that was derived from it (Sharpe, 69 1964) are based on the assumption that either agents have quadratic utility functions or the assets’ returns follow a normal distribution. The standard theory does not account for some anomalies (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979) and gambling, which are persistent and widespread. These anomalies were confirmed by laboratory experiments (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979; Grether & Plott, 1979). Some considered these anomalies a result of violation of the rational agent assumption or experiment setup. Others tried to force fit the properties of the function to explain given phenomena (Alais & Hagen, 1979) or include subjective probabilities (Friedman and Savage, 1948). There were also attempts to explain the anomalies by investigating potential market incompleteness (Heaton and Lucas, 1996) or assuming habit formation in consumption patterns (Campbell and Cochrane, 1999). The Threshold Theory developed in this paper uses another route to model human behavior without relying on utility functions. As the theory is based on a real options approach, we assume that the market for traded assets satisfies a no-arbitrage condition and that people are not satiated. The development of a theory seems difficult under such lax assumptions. However, we manage to derive an agent's attitude towards risk based on construction of the agent's portfolio. We define the agent’s portfolio as the set of assets and contingent securities that may affect the agent’s attitude toward risk, in any given decision he is facing. The assets in one’s portfolio may be in the form of shares, currency, real estate, a job, etc. The payoff of contingent claims depends on the 70 value of some underlying asset. It usually takes a monetary form; although in some cases may take another form (pleasure, satisfaction etc.). The contribution of the theory developed in this paper is twofold. First, on a theoretical level, it provides a framework in which the assumption of risk aversion is replaced with a more versatile and general modeling scheme. In particular, Threshold Theory can be useful in all cases involving the decisions of a single individual who cannot diversify his risk, including cases of entrepreneurs and financing of small business. In addition, the modeling scheme provided may be helpful in branches of corporate finance, such as agency theory and signaling theory. Real options It is widely agreed that the real options approach to economic phenomena gives excellent insights. Probably the oldest and the best known successful generalized option modeling1 is Black and Scholes’ (1973) representation of equity as a call option on a company. Further applications of real options followed shortly after that.2 Unfortunately, applications of the real options approach seem to be limited relative to its apparent potential. The main reason for this is the fact that volatility and other estimates for many underlying assets 1 By financial options, we understand financial contracts to buy or sell an underlying asset at the strike price stipulated in the contract in time period also stipulated in the contract. Real options are usually considered assets of corporations originating in the properties of projects a company holds: the option to terminate a project, the option to delay a project, the option to suspend a project etc. Here we are dealing with a much broader view of real options, including also other than the corporate point of view. We include all situations that arise in the case assets held by an individual that have option-like payoffs. We include both monetary and non-monetary payoffs. Therefore, we will use term “generalized real options” instead. 2 These standard real options include: option to abandon, option to expand, option to switch, option to delay. 71 are not available due to infrequent trading or the absence of a market. The literature for practitioners suggests using estimates of the volatility of actively traded assets that are closely related to underlying assets of interest (Amram, Kulatilaka, 1999). However, in most cases basis risk3 seems to be high and this solution seems to be too risky. Threshold Theory avoids this common problem of the real options application because no valuation is made within the model. Because of this, the model may be applied to a wide range of assets including these that are not actively traded. For the same reason, Threshold Theory has very limited application in the field most penetrated by real options – capital budgeting. On the other hand, the theory introduces a generalized real options approach to other fields of finance, in particular corporate governance, signaling and agency theories, and the behavior of undiversified investors. It seems that it is able to give a theoretical explanation for many phenomena observed in the business world, hence providing the discipline with a flexible modeling tool designed to provide predictions and not merely fit the data. The Model Options – review Before we delve into construction of a model we review certain basic but crucial facts about options. Threshold Theory most often uses the Cash-or- 3 Basis risk arises from imperfect correlation of the actual underlying asset of an option and asset used for hedging. 72 Nothing (CoN) binary option, sometimes in combination with the standard call option.4 Following the seminal work of Black and Scholes (1972), subsequent researchers have developed formulae for pricing various types of contingent claims. Others have come up with formulae for cases in which the assumptions of Black and Scholes (henceforth BS) are not met (for review of various variations on BS model see Smith, 1996). A much more flexible approach was presented by Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein (1979). The tremendous theoretical and practical success of this approach suggests that oversimplification in the BS model does not severely affect its accuracy. A Cash-or-Nothing option is a binary option that pays a constant amount A at maturity only if the price of the underlying asset exceeds the exercise price. This option’s price is just the discounted expected payoff. The closed formula for the value of such an option in BS’s world at time t=0 is as follows (Ingersoll, 2000): (2) CoN Ae rT N (d 2) , Where A is the amount paid in case the option finishes ‘in- the-money’, N(d2) is the probability of an option finishing in-the-money (in risk neutral terms). This is exactly the same interpretation as in the case of a vanilla call.5 An Asset-or-Nothing option is an option that pays the value of an asset if the price of an asset exceeds the strike price at maturity and nothing otherwise. 4 Combination of Cash-or-Nothing and standard call option is known as Asset-or-Nothing option (AoN) This type of option has no call and put variety. As this option is a pure jump, we deal only with long and short positions in it. In different words, buying a put is equivalent to writing a call. One may insist that if A is positive then an investor has long position in option, while if A is positive then an investor has short position in option. In such a case one can distinguish between put and call type. 5 73 The closed formula in BS world for the value of such call option at time t=0 is as follows (Ingersoll, 2000): (3) AoN SN (d1) ,6 The relationship between various parameters and the value of an option can be found by taking derivatives of the value function with respect to the parameter of interest. It is known that for vanilla options, the value of an option rises as volatility increases.7 This is not necessarily true for a CoN option though, as the relationship changes with S. The reason for such dependence is that if S>X then there is no reward for finishing more “in the money”, however there is a loss of A if the value of the underlying asset falls below X. Therefore, in such a case additional volatility brings no value from up-side potential and increases the risk of losses. This observation is crucial for Threshold Theory. Figure 1 and 2 illustrate the impact of the change of volatility on the value of a vanilla call and CoN with respect to S for parameters: X=11, T=1, r=2%, A=10. 6 Here the reader can see that the regular call option is just a composition of a long call AoN option and short CoN, both with the same strike X. The amount paid off by the CoN option is X. Then the value of AoN is AoN SN (d1) , the value of the CoN is CoN Ae rT N (d 2) but as A=X then rT CoN Xe rT N (d 2) and hence the value of the portfolio is C SN (d1) Xe N (d 2) which is exactly the formula for the value of the standard call. 7 This result is not theoretically valid as BS assumes constant volatility. Instead of derivatives with respekt to volatility we should talk about comparing options of parameters identical except for volatility. However the conclusions are identical hence we proceed with less correct but easier to comprehend ‘derivatives’/ 74 Impact of change in volatility on cash or nothing option 2.5 2 C 1.5 Volatility = 5% 1 Volatility = 10% 0.5 0 9 10 11 12 13 -0.5 S Figure 1 The impact of volatility on the value of a standard call option Impact of change in volatility on cash or nothing option 12 10 8 6 C volatility = 5% 4 voaltility = 10% 2 0 9 9.5 10 10.5 11 11.5 12 12.5 13 -2 S Figure 2 The impact of change in volatility on the value of cash or nothing option 75 Ideas underlying the model Normally, the parameters used in option pricing are exogenously determined. Consider the alternative situation in which we own an option but we have influence on some parameters that determine the value of the option. The influence is not absolute but is limited and can be exercised only at some points in time. In fact, these decisions are the points of interest for Threshold Theory. Which parameters could be interesting from the point of view of model building? An agent may decide to choose different maturities, switch maturities of the options or pick a time of the exercise in case of an American option; however these cases are not taken into consideration in this paper. The risk free rate is a macroeconomic variable determined by the market as a whole and we do not take into consideration this variable either. Exercise price seems to be a good candidate, but that would change the nature of the option contract, creating serious problems in any further development of the model. The two remaining parameters are those that we focus on: the value of the underlying asset and its volatility. If we use our power to change the value of an asset we call it a pure wealth transfer, while a change of volatility we call pure risk change. Do examples exist in which such power is feasible? The answer to this question is “yes” and we present two examples in a subsequent section. 76 Some examples Introduction. Threshold Theory applies option theory to situations that are not normally associated with this type of modeling. Consequently an illustrative example is very helpful in understanding the theory. This is why we start with a simple example and transform it, step by step, into more interesting cases. The case of financial options. We will start with the case of financial options. This familiar ground will allow us to proceed towards examples that are more exotic later. Consider an agent holding in his portfolio two securities: a cash or nothing option written on IBM stock (paying $10 if IBM’s stock price at maturity exceeds $11) and a share of stock in IBM. Note that the underlying asset of the option held is also a part of the portfolio. Figure 3 presents the payoff at maturity to the agent with respect to the value of the underlying asset at maturity. C+S 77 S Figure 3 Payoff at maturity from the portfolio consisting of the cash-ornothing option and its underlying asset (C+S) versus value of option’s underlying asset (S). The following figure presents the value of the portfolio before maturity (assumed parameters: volatility 5%, risk free rate 2%, time to maturity 1 year). 78 C+S C C+ S S Figure 4 The value of a portfolio consisting of a cash-or-nothing option and its underlying asset (C+S) versus value of the underlying asset (S) Now let us investigate what would be the reaction of the agent to changes in volatility and in the value of the underlying asset. This can be done by finding the derivatives of the value of the portfolio in relation to these two variables. The value of the portfolio is: (4) W= S + CoN = S + Ae rT N (d 2) d2 ln( S / X ) (r T 2 2 )T Let us start by differentiating with respect to S 79 (5) d A W 1 e rT e dS S T 2 2 ln( X )( r )T ln(S ) 2 T T 2 /2 The derivative is always positive. This means that the agent will always benefit from an increase in the price of an underlying asset. Now let us consider the influence of changes in volatility. Let us assume that a change in volatility has no impact on the value of an underlying asset.8 Then we can consider the derivative in terms of volatility: 2 ln(S / X ) rT T /2 2 T d A rT ln( S / X ) rT T (6) W e ( )e d 2 2 2 T The middle part of the equation ln( S / X ) rT 1 T determines 2 2 T the sign of the derivative. We are interested in finding the values of the underlying asset for which the derivative is positive or negative; solving W 0 will tell us where the sign changes. ln( S / X ) rT 1 T 2T 0 ln( S ) ln( X ) rT 2 2 2 T (7) S Xe rT e ln( S ) ln( X ) rT T 2 2 Therefore whenever the value of an underlying asset is below Xe rT e 2T 2 the agent benefits from an increase in volatility, and is harmed otherwise. 8 This assumption may seem to be restrictive. In fact, in this particular example this assumption is met. 2T 2 80 Generalized real options cases. The marginal analysis performed above is interesting but seems to have limited importance. So far, we have been analyzing an example (presented at the beginning of this chapter) in which the agent is the recipient of market conditions. Therefore, the analysis reflects only the impact of some exogenous changes on the value of his portfolio. However, in the case of an agent influencing either the volatility or the value of the underlying asset, then such an analysis would be able to predict how the influence would be used. In other words, we could predict whether the influence would be used to decrease or increase value/volatility of the underlying asset. In the example given, such an influence would be clearly used to increase the value of underlying asset in all cases (positive derivative with respect to S); increase volatility in all cases when the value of the underlying asset is below Xe rT e 2T 2 and decrease volatility in cases where the value of the underlying asset is above Xe rT e 2T 2 . Cases in which the investor has an influence on IBM’s stock returns (held by the agent in the example here presented) are exceedingly rare so the predictions seem to be irrelevant. Therefore, analysis is meaningful if: 1) the payoff is of the same nature as in the case presented; 2) the agent exerts some influence over the underlying asset. Now we will attempt to construct such an example, which will serve two purposes: 1) an illustration of how the model may work; 2) setting the foundation for a comparison of Threshold Theory and the Expected Utility Framework. 81 Consider an agent who plans to retire at time T, say in 40 years. However, he may invest towards retirement only today and currently has a fixed amount S 0, say $100,000. No more money can be invested later on and no money can be withdrawn for 40 years. However, the agent has full control over the composition of his investment at each point in time, meaning he can trade securities within the portfolio at any moment. The agent wishes to retire in London, but as prices are much higher there he needs to have at least $X, say $500,000, at retirement in order to be able to afford to do so. The ability to retire in his preferred surroundings gives him pleasure worth $A. Now let us analyze the portfolio held by the agent. He holds: At t=0 an investment worth S0=$100,000 An Asset-or-Nothing option that pays $A, if the value of the underlying asset exceeds X=$500,000 at maturity in T=40 years. The underlying asset is the investment held by the agent. In such a case the agent faces a payoff exactly as in the case of the financial options presented earlier. Also, the agent has some influence on the underlying asset, which is just his portfolio. The agent can change the composition of the portfolio and hence influence its volatility. This violates the BS assumptions of constant volatility. The option described is clearly more valuable than a regular option due to extra flexibility. Hence, the ‘exact’ values developed earlier are not exact and must be treated only as approximations.9 9 More accurate values may be developed via Monte Carlo simulations and this approach should be used if exact values are needed. 82 Now we may apply marginal analysis to predict the agent’s behavior. A positive derivative with respect to the value of the underlying asset means that the agent would always act to increase the value of his investment. This cannot be done as no additional transfers into the account are allowed. The only influence the agent has on the underlying asset concerns its volatility. Trading securities (assuming 0 transaction costs) has no impact on the value of the underlying asset (investment) but changes its volatility. Hence, the agent will trade securities in a way that increases volatility of the portfolio whenever the value of the underlying asset is below the strike of the option (X), discounted by appropriate amounts.10 We call this point the Threshold Point. The opposite is true when the value of the underlying asset is above the Threshold Point. This behavior is in perfect accordance with common sense. We will illustrate it with a somewhat more extreme example. Imagine a person who needs to have $200 by the end of the week to buy insulin, otherwise she dies. If her wealth is lower than $200 (we ignore discounting), then this person will gladly enter risky investments (even with negative expected value if necessary) if this gives her a chance to end up with more than $200 by the end of the week. Hence, she is willing to pay for risk (or accept investments with a negative expected return). On the other hand if her wealth is higher than $200 then she will prefer to hold her asset in low risk or risk free investments. Any risky investment would have to be rewarded with a positive expected return. 10 In general, the point of change of volatility preference is not exactly discounted at risk free rate strike of the binary option. The adjustment depends on assumptions concerning the stochastic process governing the behavior of the underlying asset. In the BS case, the adjustment is just the expected value of the lognormal distribution. 83 Equivalent analysis may be applied to the base example. The agent will prefer higher volatility (more risky) assets when the value of the investment (the underlying asset) is below the Threshold Point and assets of lower volatility (less risky) when the value of the investment is above the Threshold Point. Another real options example. We will develop another example in the realm of real options. This provides further illustration of the model and also prepares the base for empirical application of the model. Consider an agent who is the CEO of company XYZ. Her salary depends on the stock price of the company on January 1st each year. If the stock price is lower than X=$10 then she is fired and suffers loss of reputation. This means that the present value of her wages in her next job will be lower by $A compared to current conditions. Otherwise she is paid $1 for each dollar that the stock price S exceeds $10. Her portfolio consists of two assets: A cash or nothing option that pays $A in the event of the value of the underlying asset (stock of XYZ) exceeding X=$10 11 Call option on stock XYZ with a strike X=$10 Figure 5 presents the agent’s payoff at maturity and the value of the portfolio before maturity. 11 This in fact is a compound option that pays off another CoN and call with one year to maturity in addition to regular payoff. C+CoN 84 Payoff CoN+C S Figure 5 Payoff and the value of asset or nothing option The influence of the agent on the value of the underlying asset is pretty obvious as exercising this influence is in fact her job. By accepting various projects she influences both the value and the volatility of the underlying asset. Now, using again marginal analysis we will try to predict the behavior of the agent. We assume that A=$10 so these two options blend into an asset or nothing option. The derivative of the value of the portfolio function (W) with respect to the value of the underlying asset is dW (8) dS 1 2 ln(S ) T ln( X )( r T e 2 2 x2 / 2 )T 1 dx e 2T ln(S ) ( T ln( X )( r T 2 2 )T )2 / 2 The entire derivative is always positive. Therefore the CEO will accept all positive NPV projects providing they do not alter the volatility of the company. 85 The derivative of the value function with respect to volatility is: ln(S / X ) rT dW S ln( S / X ) rT T (9) ( )e d 2 2 2 T and T T 2 2 /2 ln( S / X ) rT T determines the sign of the derivative. 2 2 T ln( S / X ) rT 1 T 2T 0 ln( S ) ln( X ) rT 2 2 2 T ln( S ) ln( X ) rT 2T 2 T 2 (10) S Xe rT e 2 Therefore, whenever the stock price is below Xe rT 2T e 2 then the CEO will gladly accept NPV=0 projects that increase the volatility of the firm and also some negative NPV projects, providing volatility increases sufficiently. On the other hand, if the stock price is above Xe rT 2T e 2 then the CEO will accept 0 NPV projects if they lead to a decrease in volatility and if a project leads to an increase of volatility it must be rewarded with sufficient NPV.12 Development of the model We will assume that: an agent is endowed with a contingent security which value depends on the value of the underlying assets (ST) 12 the agent is non-satiated Note this somewhat disturbing result; it seems that not all positive NPV projects will be undertaken and also some negative NPV projects will be undertaken. 86 the agent has some influence on the underlying asset S, in particular the agent can: o change the value of the underlying asset, providing an opportunity exists o change the volatility of the asset, providing an opportunity exists markets are arbitrage free The influence is known by the market and this information is included in the value of the underlying asset. The nature of the influence as well as timing of the opportunities depend on the situation being modeled. Let us review the notation used in this paper T is time to maturity S is the value of underlying assets C is the value of the contingent claim X is the exercise price of the contingent claim A is the amount of money paid out by the CoN option in the event of it finishing in the money. Let us also define: The Threshold Point is the point at which the preference towards volatility changes 13 Positive risk attitude – all situations in which an agent tends to increase the volatility of his portfolio 13 Note that the Threshold Point converges towards the exercise price of the CoN option as expiration of the option approaches. 87 Negative risk attitude - all situations in which an agent tends to decrease the volatility of his portfolio Neutral risk attitude – all situations in which an agent is indifferent to either increasing or decreasing the volatility of his portfolio The agent will act to maximize the value of his portfolio at each point in time. This follows from the assumption of the investor’s non-satiation. Hence, we are able to predict the behavior of an agent when he faces a decision about the influence on the underlying asset. All we need to do is to perform marginal analysis, as described before. A positive derivative with respect to volatility means that the agent will exert his power over the asset in order to increase volatility. A positive derivative with respect to S means that the agent will exert his power over the asset so that the value of the asset increases. Interactions of these derivatives add a certain structure to the model. If the agent’s portfolio consists of multiple assets we may find the derivative of each part separately and add them up. In that way we are able to make predictions in more complicated cases. This is a very general framework that allows us to analyze many types of situations. Here we concentrate on those that include a jump in the payoff function as they allow for the Threshold Point. It is worth noting that there is no need to calculate the exact value of the option and hence that there is no need for exact estimates of the parameters to infer the agent’s decisions. Therefore, the main problem of applications of real options is alleviated. All we need to do is predict the changes in parameters 88 (volatility, value of underlying asset) given the decision, which is considerably easier than finding the values of the parameters. The Threshold Theory and Expected Utility Framework The Threshold Theory is mostly used to predict an agent’s behavior. This is also true in the case of the Expected Utility Framework and sometimes these two theories may be applied in describing similar phenomena. Threshold Theory was constructed to avoid assumption of risk aversion that is in most cases bounded to the Expected Utility approach. The Expected Utility framework is very popular and some researchers may not find it comfortable to detach from it completely. Fortunately, it is even possible to use Threshold Theory within the Expected Utility framework but then analysis must be qualitative, due to interference of utility functions with Threshold Theory. In some special cases a very detailed quantitative description is possible even within the Expected Utility Framework.14 These special cases are: The underlying asset is not a part of the agent’s portfolio and its price is uncorrelated with the agent’s wealth, with the exception of influencing the value of the option held by the agent Underlying assets forms a synthetic option in agent’s portfolio (as in the case of the rather unfortunate diabetic described earlier in this paper). 14 Detailed quantitative analysis is presented for illustrative purposes only and is not required in most applications. 89 Values of assets are already adjusted for risk and therefore risk aversion (or seeking) is already accounted for (e.g. prices are expressed in terms of utiles) Agents are assumed to be risk neutral In the mentioned cases the agent’s decisions are independent of his risk aversion or risk seeking (as defined by the Expected Utility framework). We encourage to use the Threshold Theory on its own and now we present its properties in comparison to standard model. In the case of Expected Utility, the behavior of a person is determined based on his or her preference towards symmetric bets with an expected value = 0. If a person prefers riskier bets then we describe him or her as risk seeking, otherwise we characterize them as risk averters. In the case of indifference we describe them as risk neutral. It is worth noting the important difference between Threshold Theory and the Expected Utility framework: in the latter, we have to give an agent the choice between two fair bets of different variances in order to decide whether he is a risk averter or a risk seeker. Then this information would be an underlying assumption for the model used to predict his further behavior. Threshold Theory predicts the agent’s attitude towards risk and does not assume it. Agent’s risk attitude follows from the theory and changes accordingly. Therefore, in some cases Threshold Theory may be more flexible and accurate than the traditional framework allowing for functional changes in risk attitude. 90 The decision of an agent in the case of Threshold Theory is easy to predict regardless of the properties of the bet. One just needs to find the expected value of the portfolio given the bet and pick the highest one. To simplify the picture we will present a case with symmetric zero expected value bets only. In such a case we are able to develop many concepts related to the expected utility framework. Now we proceed with a simple analysis of the case of the CoN option. (Parameters: A=10, X=11, S=10, T-t=1, volatility=5% and r=0.5%.) Below is an illustration of the first and second derivatives of the value of the option.15 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 First derivative Second derivative 0.2 0 1 12 23 34 45 56 67 78 89 100111122133144 -0.2 -0.4 Figure 6 First and second derivative of CoN value function with respect to S The first derivative is positive, as we found in an earlier section. The second derivative changes sign close to the threshold. Before the threshold it is 15 Note that this result differs somewhat from the findings in the previous section. This is due to simplifying the assumptions of Arrow’s and Pratt’s measures of risk aversion ARA and RRA. The approach presented here is conducted for comparison only. For modeling, one should use the results presented earlier. 91 positive (positive risk attitude – preference for risk, negative price of risk – the equivalence of risk seeking), after the threshold second derivative is negative (negative risk attitude, positive price of risk, equivalence of risk aversion). The rT change occurs exactly at S0 = X e e 2T 1 2T 2 e . It is important to note that within Threshold Theory risk attitude is an effect of portfolio construction. At the same time the expected utility framework assumes one’s risk preferences. This fundamental difference should be kept in mind when comparing frameworks. This type of set-up gives Threshold Theory extra predicative power that may be useful in modeling certain phenomena. Some inferences arising from the model Equity Black and Scholes (1974) noticed that equity in a leveraged company is similar to a call option on a company as a whole. This observation is very insightful, but also somewhat confusing. The value of a call option increases with volatility, and therefore company owners should exhibit a positive RA regardless of the company’s value (and become risk neutral only when the company’s value goes to infinity). This implies that owners should accept some negative NPV projects providing they are sufficiently volatile. Furthermore, it would be beneficial for shareholders if companies just made fair bets among themselves, since this would increase volatility without any loss of value. Managers should be rewarded by the stock market if they engage in a series of fair bets. In other words, 92 engagement of a company in an infinite series of independent, fair coin flips of any bet size should significantly drive up the stock price. This problem, a variation of which is also known as the “asset substitution problem”, has been recognized before, but only in terms of imminent default. However, when the option model is treated literally, the asset substitution problem can be applicable to all companies. This implies that a Fortune 500 company would gamble all of its wealth on a bet with negative expected return (providing that the variance of returns is big enough); such an implication is very disturbing and does not find support in real life. Moreover, if such a model is correct then dominating capital budgeting schemes are incomplete. Neither NPV nor real options approaches take into consideration the possibilities mentioned above, which implies that practitioners are taught techniques that do not maximize investors’ wealth. Furthermore, this framework shows that the investment policy of a company depends on leverage, violating one of MM’s assumptions.16 Threshold Theory offers a solution to the problem illustrated in the “Fortune 500” example. Let’s assume that S is the total value of a company, X the face value of the debt, A the bankruptcy costs, and T the maturity of the debt. In such a situation, negative risk attitude is exhibited even before the value of the company reaches the threshold X and the problem vanishes. A positive RA, before the threshold is reached, is consistent with our standard understanding of an asset substitution problem. 16 This fact cannot be solved within the new framework and actually opens up interesting possibilities for further research 93 Bond holders pay most of the bankruptcy costs as they are the ones that receive the assets of the company net of these costs. Therefore it is not obvious why such costs would influence equity holders. One answer is related to diversification of investors. In such a case equity holders will bear the costs of bankruptcy. As Haugen and Senbet (1978) noted in such a case, in line with Coase’s (1960) theory, the parties should renegotiate the contract in order to avoid bankruptcy costs. However, if there are multiple parties involved then negotiation costs may be higher than bankruptcy costs. The “underinvestment” (Myers, 1977) problem is also easy to comprehend within this framework. The problem is: in the case of high leverage not all positive NPV projects are accepted as most benefits accrue to debt holders. Threshold Theory stipulates even stronger implications. If the value of the company is much smaller than the Threshold, then many positive NPV projects will not be accepted because they are not risky enough. The reason is that in such cases there is negative price of risk before threshold is crossed because, before the threshold is reached, there is a negative price on risk for the owners. If no threshold is included in the model, underinvestment would exist for any value of the company which again is inconsistent with empirics. Agency theory and signaling Agency theory is one of the basic ideas in modern finance and the assumption of self-interest is appealing to a rational decision making paradigm. Threshold theory presents a modeling tool for this type of study. For the sake of 94 illustration, let’s assume that the CEO of a company would be fired at the Annual Meeting of Shareholders if the stock price is less than a pre-specified value (critical value). Furthermore, if the CEO is fired, the present value of income for the CEO drops (due to damaged reputation). In such a case, we are dealing with a cash–or-nothing option on stock S with the threshold at critical value X of the stock price, and the value of the decrease in the present value of salary equal to A. If we further assume that there exists some pay-performance sensitivity, we can construct such a portfolio wherein the contingent security becomes an assetor-nothing option. This is very convenient, as closed valuation formulas for both types of options exist and hence risk attitude in various situations may be assessed. In this framework, many other phenomena are easy to explain. For example, the hypothesis of managerialism states that managers derive some kind of utility from managing bigger assets. From a Threshold Theory perspective, however, this behavior is more clear, as accumulation of assets (especially of cash or risk free assets) while the CEO has negative RA moves the stock price further from the threshold and decreases company-specific volatility if additional assets are uncorrelated with existing business (cash, most securities, diversifying mergers). This maximizes the CEO’s option value assuming that the threshold does not change. Similarly, value-destroying diversifying mergers will be performed in the event of a drop in S being more than offset by the increase in the manager’s option value due to a decrease of volatility.17 17 In case we drop the assumption of constant threshold we have to take into consideration how the threshold changes in relation to company’s assets size. 95 Other problems, such as CEO entrenchment and pay performance sensitivity, may be explained in natural and simple ways. More complicated phenomena, including dividend announcements and signaling effects, require more study and modeling. Several existing papers have used a logic similar to the one used in the development of Threshold Theory, such as Degeorge, Patel, Zeckhauser (1999). In this study, the authors found that managers manage earnings if earnings are not up to the expectations of the market (thresholds were set at: 0, recent years’ earnings and analysts’ consensus). In this case managers were trying to influence the value of the underlying asset (earnings) of their option to remain employed at the cost of increased volatility in the future. The slight deviation from the approach presented in this paper is that the underlying asset used for modeling is earnings instead of stock price. However the authors point to the close relationship between these variables. 96 CHAPTER 2 APPLICATION OF THRESHOLD THEORY TO CORPORATE GOVERNANCE Introduction Threshold Theory was designed to explain some anomalies unaccounted for by the Expected Utility Framework, but can it be used for empirical research? We believe that this is definitely the case. Here we would like to present one possible application of the Threshold Theory.18 Description of the model and development of a testable hypothesis As noted earlier in this paper, a part of the human wealth of a manager may be modeled by a composition of a cash-or-nothing option and a vanilla call, each with stock of the managed company as an underlying asset. The strike of both options is set at the level of the stock price at which the majority of shareholders would become sufficiently unhappy and fire the manager. The call option reflects the performance-based part of salary, while the cash-or-nothing option reflects the reputational loss in case the manager is fired (which translates in lower future personal earnings).19 According to Threshold Theory, the manager 18 19 I would like to thank Wallace N. Davidson III for noticing this possible application. For a detailed description of this case please refer to section II.3.4 of Chapter 1 97 should exhibit a positive risk attitude if the stock price is below the threshold 20 and a negative risk attitude if the stock price is higher than the threshold. However, if the manager decides to retire in the near future, then his portfolio changes as there is no loss due to damage to his reputation because reputation is no longer needed. Therefore, the cash or nothing option is no longer in the manager’s portfolio and all that is left is a vanilla call option. In such a case the manager should exhibit positive risk attitude at all levels of the stock price. Hence, managers close to retirement are more likely to undertake actions that increase risks to the company. This inference is supported by Davidson, Xie, Xu, Ning (2005) who find that CEOs nearing voluntary retirement tend to engage in earnings management. This is a long-run volatility-increasing behavior, which also intends to influence value of the underlying asset. This sort of behavior is in line with the theory. In this study, we aim to check whether managers exhibit other types of risky behavior as retirement nears. The overall riskiness of the company cannot be measured with beta alone as it omits the idiosyncratic risk. Therefore, as a proxy of total risk we will use the volatility of the stock price. According to the Threshold Theory, after the decision concerning retirement is made the manager should tend to increase the volatility of the company as a whole. Of course, the moment of such a decision is unobservable but managers usually are not able to adjust the volatility immediately; therefore, the process of volatility adjustment, as well as coming to the final decision, should take at least some time. To measure changes in 20 The threshold point is discounted strike further modified depending on type on diffusion process governing the behavior of the underlying asset. In the case of the Weiner process, the threshold is further adjusted by the expected value of lognormal distribution (see section II.3) 98 volatility we compare volatility in years preceding the year of voluntary turnover (t -1 to t-3). Therefore, the testable hypothesis is: H0: If a company’s CEO is close to retirement then relative to company’s peers the volatility of the stock price should be increasing over time. Methodology and data This study focus on a sample of companies in which the CEO voluntarily stepped down. The Executive Compensation Database was used to identify CEO turnovers between 1995 and 2007. The following screening criteria were used: Executive Compensation Database indicates that the reason for the turnover was retirement, CEO was 60 or older, CEO had at least 4 years tenure when leaving the office.21 This screening yielded 98 observations. In order to further assure that the turnover was planned, or it was the last CEO position held by an individual, we screen whether the individual held another position after retiring at any company. Moreover we screened press releases obtained from Lexis – Nexis concerning the turnover of CEOs aged 60-65 in order to eliminate forced turnovers disguised as retirements. In this way we seek to assure that there is little or no jump in the CEO’s payoff function. These additional screens reduce the sample size to 96 observations. The study investigates whether the total firm risk, proxied by volatility, changes over time. The time series nature of the test precludes effective use of 21 This also assures that there was no CEO turnover during the test period. 99 regression analysis in such study. There is no prediction concerning development of the process over time but only concerning its general direction (in particular increasing volatility). Therefore, it seems sufficient to compare volatility at given points in time using a paired t-test.22 We used yearly periods and the set under investigation consists of years t to t-3 where t is year of retirement. To have a basis for comparison, the changes in volatility will be compared against volatility of matched companies. This comparison calls for a methodology of picking the match as well as control variables. In this study the inclusion of control variables is somewhat complicated. There are several types of variables influencing volatility that should be considered. 1. Variables that represent tools that the CEO may use to change the company’s volatility. These include but are not limited to: leverage, R&D spending, earnings management, etc. Such variables should not be included in the test. This is because if we remove the influence of such variables then we would be unable to detect any meaningful relationship between CEO characteristics and volatility. By removing the influence of the tools that CEO may use to change volatility, we also remove the link between CEO and volatility. 2. Variables that may determine the level of volatility that are not easily controlled by the CEO. These are the variables that should be controlled 22 Paired t-test is represented as t n1 dˆ 0 sd / n , where d is difference in values of variables between pairs, µ0 is difference tested under null (in this paper always 0), sd is standard deviation of observed differences and n is number of pairs. 100 in the test as they may vary between companies and obscure the results. These variables are: Industry The industry life-cycle is known to be related to stock price volatility (Mazzucato & Tancioni, working paper; Mazzucato & Semmler, 2002) CEO age and compensation In general, the risk appetite is believed to be related to the agent’s age (MacCrimmon, Wehrung, 1990); at the same time, the current level of compensation may determine the potential loss in case of being fired (A. Rashad Abdel-khalik, working paper). Such person specific variables should be controlled for as they may influence the behavior of the CEO. In particular retiring CEOs are typically old and this fact may bias the results. Furthermore, compensation may be highly correlated with CEO wealth, which in turn may influence the risk attitude. 3. Variables that may affect the pace of changes in the volatility need to be included in the tests. As we are investigating the changes of the volatility over time we have to take into consideration whether CEOs of the compared companies are able to manipulate the volatility to a similar extent. The variables in question are firm specific: 101 It is much easier to manipulate characteristics of a smaller company. Therefore, when companies are compared they should be of a similar size. Companies with comparably higher/lower volatility at the beginning of the comparison period may have a hard time to increase/decrease its volatility even further. Therefore, compared companies should have comparable volatility to start with. The screening variables from the third group are the ones best suited for specifying the match for each company in the original sample. We also include industry to be one of the variables used for picking a match as this is a categorical variable and therefore not well suited for regression analysis. We picked a match in the following way. Each company in the original sample will be assigned a peer. The first screen will have two basic conditions: - the same industry (4-digit SIC code) – to accommodate potential temporal changes in volatility within industry - no CEO turnover in the investigated period The second screen will include screening variables from the group 3 - similar size at the beginning of (t – 3) – to ensure that the pace of volatility change is comparable, assuming that it is harder to change the volatility of bigger companies. Size will be measured as market value of equity on the month of turnover as measured by Compustat. - similar volatility at the beginning of (t – 3) – to make sure that companies we are comparing are of similar risk at the start of the period under the 102 investigation and also to eliminate influence of possible mean reversion in the volatility process. Volatility was measured as the standard deviation of the daily returns of each company’s market value in a given year. The similarity of volatility and size will be assessed using normalized Euclidean distance and Mahalanobis (1936) distance which resulted in identical matches in all but one case. The peer was selected as the one with the smallest distance to the data point in the turnover sample out of all companies that were identified with screen 1.23 Data concerning size were pulled from the Compustat. Data on the stock performance was obtained from CRSP. Data on executive age and compensation were obtained from the Executive Compensation Database. Lack of suitable matches reduced sample size to 65 observations. Table 3 presents the main statistics of the samples. 23 We have also used Euclidean distance on normalized variables, which is equivalent to Mahalanobis distance with assumed zero covariance between the variables. The matches assigned were the same for all but one company. 103 Table 1 Summary statistics of retirement and matched sample t-3 t-2 t-1 t Average retirement sample volatility 2.11% 2.15% 2.06% 2.20% Average matched sample volatility 2.16% 2.33% 2.14% 2.13% Median retirement sample CEO age 65 Median matching sample CEO age 59 Average retirement sample market size ($ mln) 4143 Average matched sample market size ($ mln) 2234 Average retirement sample CEO total annual compensation ($ ths) 3819 4457 4110 4780 2632 2893 3318 4377 Average matched sample CEO total annual compensation ($ ths) The data provides two sets of information. Firstly, the matching procedure provided a close match with respect to average starting volatility; however the retirement sample companies are almost twice as big as matched companies. Finally, we observed a much higher median of CEO age in the retirement sample which also should be expected due to imposed constraints on CEO age, as well as the fact that retiring individuals are usually elder. After the match was identified we investigated the influence of the CEO’s characteristics. To do so we ran a regression of observed volatility on CEO’s age and compensation.24 The form of the regression is as follows: Vol 0 1 Age 2 Compensation 3 Re tirement 24 Total compensation is defined as Executive Compensation Database TDC1 variable consisting of (Salary + Bonus + Other Annual + Restricted Stock Grants + LTIP Payouts + All Other + Value of Option Grants) 104 Where Age denotes CEO age, Compensation is total compensation received in a given calendar year and Retirement is a dummy that takes a value of 1 if the observation comes from the retirement sample. The dummy was introduced because the event of retirement, which is hypothesized to have influence on volatility, is highly related to the age of the CEO. The regression sample consists of all observations from the matched sample (t-3 to t) for which all necessary data is available and all observations from the retirement sample for which all necessary data is available except for the year of retirement (t-3 to t1). The results of the regression are presented in Table 4 Table 2 Results of the regression of volatility on age and compensation Variable Coefficient p-value Age β1=-0.0001 19% β2=-8.87E-08 69% β3=0.0013 27% Observations =403 p-value of F = 45% Compensation Retirement R2=8.1% The regression shows that the CEO’s age and compensation are not significant determinants of firm’s volatility. Therefore further analysis will be performed on unadjusted variables. The difference between adjusted volatilities was computed. The evolution of average distance between volatilities is presented in Figure 7. 105 0.003 0.002 0.001 vol - s.e. 0 t-3 -0.001 t-2 t-1 t0 volatility vol - s.e. -0.002 -0.003 -0.004 Figure 7 Evolution of volatility differentia between retirement and matched sample We can observe peculiar development of the process. The volatility differential increases for the last three years before CEO retirement which supports Threshold theory. No year-to-year changes are statistically significant, but the difference between the peak at t and the trough at t-2 is significant at the 10% level for a two-sided test (p-value of 6.6%). The result implies that on average the retirement decision might be made two years prior to the retirement. The final step is an investigation of changes in systematic risk. Betas were calculated using S&P500 as a proxy for the market portfolio. The changes in beta differentials are neither significant on year to year basis nor comparing extreme values. 106 CHAPTER 3 THRESHOLD THEORY AND SOCCER STRATEGIES Introduction Threshold Theory is potentially applicable to behavior well outside of economics and finance. Here we would like to present an analysis of football strategies. Football, also known in the USA as soccer, is a sport played between two teams. The aim of the game is to place a round ball in the opponent’s goal. Players, except for the goalkeeper in his own goal area, are not allowed to touch the ball with their hands. The game takes 90 minutes divided into two 45 minute periods. The team that scores more goals wins the game. If both teams score the same number of goals, the game is a draw. In some cases a draw is not permitted and the game is extended into two extra 15 minute periods. If this extra time does not bring a resolution the result is determined by penalty shots. Each team consists of eleven players; one goalkeeper and ten field players. There are few restrictions on a player’s position, but three main roles evolved: strikers or forwards are the offensive players, midfielders whose role is to pass the ball to forwards, and defenders who specialize in preventing their opponents from scoring. Usually three substitutions per game are allowed. 107 Often matches are a part of larger competitions that determine the best among a group of teams. There are two main systems used to determine the best team which are the cup or the league competition. In the cup competition, the teams are paired and the losing team quits the tournament (draws are not permitted). The teams that remain in the tournament after the first round are paired again and the cycle repeats until only one team remains. This is the team that wins the tournament. In the league competition, each team plays with each competing team twice (at home and away). Each match won earns the team 3 points while draws earn the team 1 point. The team that gathers the most points at the end of the season wins the competition. In case there is a draw other criteria are used, including goal difference and number of goals scored. It is not as apparent as in previous cases, but here the Threshold Theory may come in handy in modeling behavior of football strategy setters. Teams face a non-continuous payoff: scoring just one goal more than the opponent results in a game won. Each extra goal does not significantly change the general outcome of the game. The most important thing is who won; by how many goals is of secondary importance. Therefore, we observe a huge jump in payoff from a game played at the threshold level of a draw. The Threshold Theory predicts that teams should use riskier strategies when under the threshold (losing) and safer strategies when past the threshold (winning), and this is the hypothesis tested in this section of the paper. 108 Model and tests In order to evaluate the behavior of soccer strategy makers we need to collect data; starting composition of teams, time of all of the goals scored, and the substitutions of players. Such data for the UK Premier League 2006/2007 games was obtained from the ESPN website. The testing of the hypothesis requires data concerning results and riskiness of strategies employed. The riskiness of a strategy must be measured by a proxy. The approach used will be based on indexing the players. Each player receives a number of points dependent on their role in the field. We assume that points assigned are: 0 for a goalkeeper, 1 for a defender, 2 for a midfielder and 3 for a forwarder. We define a strategy employed by a team by the sum of points of players at a given time. The sum of points indicates how offensive the strategy is with higher marks indicating a more offensive strategy. An offensive strategy increases the probability of scoring a goal, but at the expense of a weakened defense and a larger vulnerability to counterstrikes. Hence such a strategy should increase the volatility of the game’s score and may be seen as riskier than defensive strategies. In particular we expect that when the teams employ riskier strategies we would observe more goals. More goals per fixed time of the game translate into higher volatility of the result. In order to verify this conjecture we analyze the relationship between sum of strategies employed by the teams and number of goals scored per minute of game. Figure 8 presents main findings of the analysis. 109 0.04 y = 0,0012x - 0,016 R² = 0,5444 0.035 0.03 0.025 0.02 0.015 0.01 0.005 0 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 Figure 8 Relationship between sum of strategies employed by both teams and average number of goals scored per minute The observed relationship is positive and the sum of strategies employed is able to explain over 50% of variation in average goals scored per minute and p-value of the t-statistics of strategy variable is less than 2%. The correlation between the variables is in excess of 70%. The results reassure that the use of the riskiness of strategy construct is indeed strongly related to the volatility of underlying process. The first step we undertake is to define the measurement of a match result at a given point of time. The most intuitive one is Differential = goals scored by the team investigated minus goals scored by the opposing team. It allows us to group results in more meaningful categories than regular match results for the following reasons: 110 The Differential can be measured on an interval scale in contrast to regular match results that are ordered pairs.25 Differential transforms a two-dimensional variable into a scalar, which is easier to manipulate. 0 on the scale used will always indicate a single threshold of interest instead of multiple indications of game results (e.g. 0-0, 1-1, 2-2 etc) Before we proceed to testing the hypothesis we should first relate the situation to the Threshold Theory in a more rigorous way so the test is properly specified. In particular we have to define the nature of the underlying asset and the type of option. For the purpose of modeling we will assume that the teams are only interested in winning a match. The value of Differential at the end of the game (option expiration) is of secondary importance as long as the sign is preserved. In most league games this should be the case because Differential over number of matches is important only in rare cases when there is a tie on the final league table of results.26 Under such assumptions we are dealing with two cash-or-nothing options. The first one pays off 1 point for the total score table if Differential is equal or greater than 0. The second option pays off 2 points if Differential is greater than 0. The payoff of the portfolio and the value of the portfolio before maturity are illustrated in Figure 9.27 In fact Differential is a set of equivalence classes with respect to relation “~”, defined as (x,y)~(a,b) iff xy=a-b, on the set of results, which preserves ordering. 26 In case of cup tournaments, such assumption is fully met as only winning teams participate in further stages of tournament. 27 For simulation purposes we assumed BS based valuation of binary options with volatility 5%, risk free rate 2%, t=1, and Differential=0 at S=10 25 111 3.5 3 2.5 2 Payoff 1.5 Portfol io 1 0.5 0 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Figure 9 Payoff and value of the portfolio for soccer example Clearly, we deal here with two thresholds but they are stacked one on the other hence their influence should magnify. The point of a draw is the only situation where thresholds may affect behavior in a different manner and hence the predictions at this point are unclear. Differential=0 will be treated separately in the tests. For each Differential we will find the average strategy used by teams. The average strategy is defined as time weighted average of all strategies employed for each observation of the Differential. Assuming that strategies which are more offensive result in a higher volatility of the Differential, the hypothesis will be confirmed if the average value of strategy for positive values of Differential is significantly lower than for negative values of Differential. Such comparison will 112 be performed using a standard t-test. Figure 10 present the relationship between Differential and average strategy. Average strategy 19 35000 18.5 30000 18 25000 17.5 20000 17 15000 16.5 10000 16 5000 15.5 Duration… 0 -8 15 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 Figure 10 Relationship between Differential and average strategy employed We can observe that average strategy employed is higher if a team is under the threshold, and fluctuates at low levels if a team is at or above the threshold. This would indicate that a draw is perceived to be as important to maintain as a wining position. Secondly, we observe strange behavior in case the Differential is below -4 and above 4. It is important to indicate that these cases are very rare (in fact they have the duration of about 0.1% of total duration of games in the sample) and therefore are easily influenced by outliers. Moreover, as the number of goals scored per match is in general very low (in sample at hand we observe an average of less than 2.5 goals per game and a median of 2 113 goals per game) then it seems clear that losing by 5 goals takes away any hope of winning. The flight to safety is possibly a defense against utter shame. On the other hand, winning by 5 goals is equal to almost sure victory and provides a possibility of trying more exotic tactics on actual opponent. The statistical testing of difference of means presents some challenge as it is hard to decide on the number of observations. On one hand, each minute (or even second) of the game is a separate observation, however, such observations are hardly independent. On the other hand, there are 380 separate games observed so possibly the sample size should be set at this level. However, averaging data over the game would remove most of the observed variability. Therefore, we define one observation for the purpose of this statistical test as each time period in which given Differential was observed. This means that we effectively divide each game into uninterrupted strips of time during which one and only one value of Differential was observed. It could be argued that such partition does not entirely eliminate the problem of independence as two (or more) stripes of given Differential may occur during one game. However, one should note that even if such event occurs then those two stripes of time are divided by at least one other stripe of time (and two goals) so both observations are spaced in time and hence, to some extent, may be considered independent. Two goal separation also gives some reassurance. Starting Differential is always 0 (which is not taken into consideration in the tests) and with a median of 2 goals scored we may safely conclude that at least half of the sample is free of 114 the problem. Proceeding in this manner we have identified 2510 non-0-length strips,28 of which 726 are under the threshold and 726 are above the threshold. Table 5 presents p-values of two-sided t-test that compare average strategy employed by teams below, at, and over the threshold. Table 3 p-values of t-tests of mean strategies employed by the teams under the threshold at the threshold 0.03% over the threshold 0.03% at the threshold 74% The tests confirm the implication of the visual inspection. In particular, the average strategy employed above the threshold is significantly higher than the average strategy employed below the threshold. The average strategy employed when at the threshold is undistinguishable from the average strategy employed when above threshold, but is significantly different from the average strategy employed when below the threshold. This supports the hypothesis derived from the theory. It may be claimed that more offensive strategies are simply less effective than defensive ones. Therefore, teams that employ such strategies tend to lose and that is why we observe more offensive strategies under the threshold. In other words, one may claim that strategy determines Differential and not the other way around. In such a case we could observe these results without any deliberate actions on the side of the teams. There are at least two arguments to 28 Zero length strips arise if a goal was scored in the last minute of the game. Such stripes are removed from the analysis. 115 refute such approach. Firstly, if offensive strategies were inferior then nobody would use them in the first place. Secondly, if this is a case then the graph would have to be symmetric around a Differential of 0. Clearly it is not, which implies that either losing teams are switching to more risky strategies or winners are switching to safer strategies (or both do the switch simultaneously). In order to further address such doubts we will take into consideration exchanging players with more defensive role with players that will take on more offensive role and vice versa at various values of Differential. If offensive players enter the field more often when a team is losing and defensive players enter the field more often when a team is winning, then the hypothesis is confirmed. The player entering the field will be considered more offensive if he has more points assigned to him than the player leaving the field. This approach does not take into consideration the starting strategies and general preferred set-up of particular teams hence it is able to further address the reverse causality issue. Table 6 presents the data concerning player exchanges at various levels of the threshold, while Table 7 presents net player changes. Change denoted as -2 is a change of defender for forwarder, -1 is a change of defender for midfielder or midfielder for forwarder, 0 is change of a player of the same type, 1 is change of forwarder for midfielder or midfielder for defender, and 2 is a change of forwarder for defender. 116 Threshold Table 4 Number of player changes with respect to threshold values -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 -2 -1 1 1 3 6 17 17 7 2 1 3 3 20 40 94 86 36 21 4 Changes 0 5 36 94 211 358 187 108 41 17 3 1 1 2 11 64 134 109 32 16 10 2 2 2 17 32 8 1 2 Threshold Table 5 Number of net player changes with respect to threshold values -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 -2 0 1 0 0 0 9 16 5 2 1 0 Net changes -1 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 54 0 20 0 11 0 2 0 0 0 1 1 0 8 44 94 15 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 0 1 14 26 0 0 0 0 0 0 Clearly the substitutions of defensive players for offensive players are much more dominant when the team is winning and the opposite is true when the team is losing. These conjectures are confirmed by the two sided tests of proportions with the p-value much lower than 0.1%.29 The behavior of teams at a 29 This is true for both in case of confidence interval consistent version and chi-squared goodness of fit test. The sample was partitioned into three groups: winning situation, draw, losing situation. The same partition is kept for later tests. 117 draw is inconclusive in this setting. This refutes the reverse causality argument and further supports the theory. So far we have modeled a strategy to be conditioned exclusively on the Differential. However, it seems reasonable that the strategy of a team depends also on the strategy employed by the opponent. Inclusion of this factor requires a somewhat more complicated model. Let us assume that goals scored by a given team are distributed according to Poisson process with parameter λ. This parameter depends on how offensive a team’s strategy is (with more offensive strategies increasing λ) and how defensive the strategy of the opponent is (with more defensive strategies decreasing λ). Let us define: f is a function valuing the effectiveness of the offense of a given strategy (identical for each team) b f(b)≠0 g is a function valuing the effectiveness of the defense of a given strategy (identical for each team) b g(b)≠0 a is a strategy deployed by team A b is a strategy deployed by team B We expect the first derivative of f to be positive and the first derivative of g to be negative. We assume that f (a) and that each team A playing with team g (b) B will tend to maximize the quotient A f (a) g (a) , which translates into finding B g (b) f (b) an optimal point at which the probability of scoring a goal is high but does not expose their own goal too much. Taking the natural logarithm of both sides, we 118 arrive at the result ln A ln B ln f (a) ln g (a) ln f (b) ln g (b) F (a) F (b) , with F ( x) ln f ( x) ln g ( x) . At the same time team B will try to maximize the reciprocal of the quotient B which translates into maximizing A ln B ln A ln f (b) ln f (a) ln g (b) ln g (a) F (b) F (a) . We will construct a function Λ(x, y) = ln x ln y for x, y being possible strategies, basing on λs obtained from the data.30 The anti-symmetry property derived earlier ensures that: Λ(x,y)= -Λ(y,x) and Λ(x,x)=0. This indicates that we are dealing with a zerosum game.31 Changes of players indicate a change of strategy and hence we will examine changes of players again but now from a slightly wider perspective. If a change of a player results in an increase of the quotient then such a change is a natural reaction to increase a team’s odds of winning. However, if a change of strategy results in a decrease of the quotient then the team plays sub-optimally. In particular, if a new player is more offensive than the replaced one then the team has a higher probability to score a goal but the probability of losing a goal is increased proportionally more. This is clearly a shift towards a more risky strategy. The opposite is true if a more defensive player enters the field. If shifts towards a more risky strategy are more frequent when a team is losing and shifts towards a safer strategy are more frequent when a team is winning then the hypothesis will be confirmed. Tables 8 and 9 present results of this analysis. In fact, Λ is a matrix that defines game space. The geometry of Λ determines optimal choice of strategies. 31 If additive relation is used to define λ (λ=f(a)-g(b)) then we arrive at the same conclusions about Λ. However the geometry of game space may be somewhat altered. For robustness, we have also used additive approach and, the change of specifications does not materially influence test’s results. 30 119 Table 6 Number of player changes with respect to threshold values, game theory approach Threshold -2 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 1 5 7 12 4 1 1 Changes -1 1 3 12 24 50 52 20 11 3 1 1 3 27 60 41 12 6 6 2 2 1 4 12 3 1 Table 7 Number of net player changes with respect to threshold values, game theory approach Threshold -2 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 4 11 4 1 1 Net Changes -1 1 2 15 36 1 3 7 9 40 14 5 1 Here the picture is even clearer than in the case of the previous test. Suboptimal, defense enhancing player changes take place much more often when a team is winning and offense enhancing player changes take place much more often when a team is losing. This is particularly visible on the net changes table where the distinction is very clear-cut. Moreover, we can much easier observe that teams playing at the threshold behave very similar to winning 120 teams. Yet statistical tests reveal at the significance level better than 0.1% that proportion of changes in each group (winning vs. draw vs. losing) is different. This suggests, unlike the first test, that at the threshold the risk attitude is less positive than in the case of winning teams, which is consistent with the theory. The possible weak point of this test is that it assumes that all teams have similar offensive and defensive effectiveness with various strategies. However, some teams may be better with an offensive play while others excel in a defensive play. The initial strategy may be an indicator of such preferences. Therefore, we will use starting strategies as a point with Λ(a,a)=0. Both strategies will be rescaled so their values are equal to the target value a which is equal to the integer closest to the average of both strategies initially employed. Tables 10 and 11 present results of the tests. Table 8 Number of player changes with respect to threshold values, Threshold modified game theory approach -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 -2 1 1 3 5 11 9 5 1 1 Changes -1 1 1 8 19 45 46 19 15 2 1 1 3 48 79 55 18 9 8 2 2 1 6 8 3 1 121 Table 9 Number of net player changes with respect to threshold values, Threshold modified game theory approach -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 -2 1 8 8 5 1 1 Net changes -1 1 2 2 40 60 10 3 3 28 10 7 The results remain unchanged including significance levels of statistical tests. 122 REFERENCE LIST Abdel-khalik, A.R. Earnings Volatility and Risk Aversion, working paper Allais, M., & Hagen, O. (Eds.). (1979). Expected Utility Hypotheses and the Allais Paradox: Contemporary Discussions of Decisions Under Uncertainty With Allais’ Rejoinder. Dordrecht: D. Reindel Publishing. Amram, M., & Kulatilaka, N. (1999). Real Options, Managing Strategic Investment in an Uncertain World. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Arrow, K.J. (1971). Essays in the Theory of Risk Bearing Amsterdam: NorthHolland. Bernoulli, D. (1738). Specimen theoriae nova de mensura sortis., Commentarii academiae scientarium imperiales Petropolitanae. Vol. 5. Black, F. & Scholes M. (1972). The Valuation of Option Contracts and a Test of Market Efficiency. Journal of Finance, May Black, F. & Scholes M. (1973). The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. Journal of Political Economy , May-June Campbell, J.Y. & Cochrane J.H. (1999). By Force of Habit: A Consumption Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 107 Coase, R. (1960) The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics Cox J.C., Ross S.A. & Rubinstein M. (1979) Option Pricing: A Simplified Approach. Journal of Financial Economics. September 123 Davidson III, W.N. Xie B. Xu W. & Ning Y. (2005) The Influence of Executive Age, Career Horizon and Incentives on Pre-Turnover Earnings Management. working paper Degeorge, F. Patel J. & Zeckhauser R. (1999). Earnings Management to Exceed Thresholds. Journal of Business. January Friedman, M. &. Savage L.J (1948). The Utility Analysis of Choices Involving Risk. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 56. Grether D. & Plott C. (1979). Economic Theory of Choice and the Preference Reversal Phenomenon. The American Economic Review, September Haugen R. A. & Senbet L. W. (1978). The Insignificance of Bankruptcy Costs to the Theory of Optimal Capital Structure. The Journal of Finance, May Heaton, J. & Lucas D. (1996). Evaluating the Effects of Incomplete Markets on Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing. Journal of Political Economy, 54, Ingersoll, E.J. Jr. (2000). Digital Contracts: Simple Tool for Pricing Complex Derivatives, The Journal of Business, January Kahneman, D. & Tversky A. (1979). Prospect theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk. Econometrica, March. MacCrimmon, K. R. & Wehrung D. A. (1990). “Characteristics of Risk Taking Executives”, Management Science, April. Mahalanobis, P.C. (1936). On the generalized distance in statistics, Proceedings of the National Institute of Science of India 12 Markowitz, H.M. (1959). Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investment, New Haven: Yale University Press 124 Mazzucato, M. & Semmler W. (2002). The Determinants of Stock Price Changes: An Industry Study, Nonlinear Dynamics, Psychology, and Life Sciences, April Mazzucato, M. & Tancioni M. Stock Price Volatility and Patent Citation Dynamics: the case of the pharmaceutical industry. working paper Menger, K. (1934). Das Unsicherheitsmoment in der Wertlehre. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, Vol 4, No. 4 Myers, S. (1977) “Determinants of Corporate Borrowing”, Journal of Financial Economics Musumeci, J. “The Reverse Super St. Petersburg Paradox”, working paper Pratt, J.W. (1964) “Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large”, Econometrica, January-April Sharpe, W.F. (1964). Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk. Journal of Finance, September Smith, C. (1976) "Option pricing : A review," Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 3(1-2). Von Neumann, J. & Morgenstern O. (1947). Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. New Jersey: Princeton University Press